Economics
Economics
in
Business Administration
Study Manual
ECONOMICS
abc
ECONOMICS
Contents
Study
Unit
Title
Syllabus
Page
1
2
3
6
11
13
17
18
21
32
36
39
40
44
51
54
Costs of Production
Factor and Input Costs
Economic Costs
External Costs and Benefits
Costs and the Growth of Organisations
Small Firms in the Modern Economy
57
58
67
68
70
73
77
78
80
86
92
97
Contents (Continued)
Study
Unit
Title
Page
101
102
103
104
108
110
113
117
118
119
125
128
131
135
139
140
142
147
148
Liquidity Preference
Options for Holding Wealth
The Keynesian View of Liquidity Preference
The Supply of Money
Implications of Liquidity Preference
Changes in Liquidity Preference
153
154
155
158
160
164
10
165
166
170
173
175
175
176
177
178
11
181
182
186
186
193
Contents (Continued)
Study
Unit
Title
Page
12
203
204
204
205
208
212
13
219
220
221
223
224
226
229
14
231
232
236
242
15
247
248
250
256
257
16
265
266
277
281
17
287
288
290
293
297
301
18
Foreign Exchange
International Money
Exchange Rates and Exchange Rate Systems
311
312
314
2.
3.
Understand the general macroeconomic environment and its effect upon business organisations
and their markets.
4.
Define the problem of scarcity, opportunity cost, the functioning of free market, command and
mixed economies and the difference between macroeconomics and microeconomics.
2.
Describe and interpret the basic theory of consumer behaviour and demand including the
concept of utility, the law of diminishing marginal utility, the distinction between Giffen,
inferior and normal goods, the distinction between substitute and complementary goods, the
difference between individual and market demand, and the notion and measurement of
elasticity (own-price, cross and income elasticity).
3.
Employ the theory of supply from a fundamental understanding of costs; define the difference
between the short-run and the long-run; differentiate between fixed, sunk and variable costs;
derive marginal, average and total costs; understand the nature and relevance of economies and
diseconomies of scale and the concept of elasticity of supply.
4.
Describe the application of supply and demand analysis to the working of markets both in
equilibrium and disequilibrium, including examination of the effects of price restrictions,
quotas, subsidies and taxation.
5.
Examine the effect of different markets structures (perfect competition, monopoly, monopolistic
competition and oligopoly) upon the conduct (particularly pricing policy) and performance of
profit maximising and non-profit maximising (sales revenue, market share and managerial
utility maximising) business organisations, and give examples of the forms and effects of
government intervention in this area.
Copyright ABE
ii
6.
Understand how exchange rates are determined, the main alternative exchange rate regimes and
their advantages and disadvantages. Explain the rationale for international trade agreements
and organisations (e.g. the World Trade Organisation), tariffs, quotas and other measures of
trade protectionism.
7.
Evaluate national income as a measure of societal well being and derive it through its various
methods of measurement. Explain the main components of National Income Accounts
(Consumption, Investment, Government Expenditure and Foreign Trade).
8.
Explain the determination of the equilibrium levels of national income in terms of the simple
Keynesian macroeconomic model.
9.
Describe the functions of money and the role of the banking system in the creation of money.
Explain the relationship between the money supply, growth and inflation.
10.
Understand and interpret the main objectives of government macroeconomic policy and the
rationale for the various policies used to achieve these objectives. Employ the aggregate supply
and demand model to analyse the likely effects of fiscal and monetary policy upon output,
employment, the price level, and the balance of payments.
11.
Explain the fundamental principles of comparative advantages and specialisation and their
relevance to international trade. Explain the terms of trade, balance of trade and balance of
payments accounts.
Method of Assessment
By written examination. The pass mark is 40%. Time allowed 3 hours.
The question paper will contain:
Section A is composed of eight short-answer compulsory questions and Section B contains five
questions from which three must be attempted. Section A is worth 40% of the total marks available
and Section B 60% of the total marks.
Reading List:
Essential Reading
Introduction to Positive
Economics
Copyright ABE
iii
Additional Reading
Economics
Economics
Dictionary of Economics
The Economic Review
Copyright RRC
(McGraw-Hill)
(Penguin)
(Harvester-Wheatsheaf)
Study Unit 1
The Economic Problem and Production
Contents
A.
B.
C.
Page
Nature of production
Production Factors
Production Function
Total Product
D.
Production possibilities
11
E.
13
13
14
15
Consumer Sovereignty
15
Licensed to ABE
How resources should be used in order to produce the desired goods and services
These questions of production and distribution are problems because for most human societies
peoples aspirations or wants are unlimited we often seem to want more of everything whereas the
resources available are scarce. This term has a rather special meaning in economics. When we say
that resources are scarce we do not mean necessarily that they are in short supply though often, of
course, they are but that we cannot make unlimited use of them. In particular when we use, for
example, land for one purpose, say as a road, then that land cannot, at the same time, be used for
anything else. In this sense, virtually all resources are scarce: your time and energy, for example,
since you cannot at the same time read this study unit and watch a football match or play football.
Licensed to ABE
health and hospital services in Britain led to many strains and disputes. One reason for this was the
transfer of decision-making power from senior medical staff to non-medical managers, whose
perception of the opportunity costs of the various options available was likely to be very different
from that of the medical specialists.
Throughout history societies have experimented with many different forms and structures for
decision-making in relation to the allocation of the total resources available to the community.
Through much of the twentieth century there has been conflict between the planned economy, with
decisions taken mostly by political institutions, and the market economy, where decisions are taken
mainly by individuals and groups operating in markets where they can choose to buy or not to buy the
goods and services offered by suppliers according to their own assessment of the benefits and
opportunity costs of the many choices with which they are faced. As the century draws to a close it is
the market operation that is in the ascendancy, and this course is concerned mainly with the operation
of markets and the market economy. At the same time we need to recognise that market choices have
certain limitations and social consequences which cannot be ignored. All the major market
economies have important public sectors within which choices are made through various kinds of
non-market institutions and structures, and economics is able to make a significant contribution to
understanding these.
B. NATURE OF PRODUCTION
Economic Goods and Free Goods
The term goods is frequently used in a general sense to include services, as long as it does not
cause confusion or ambiguity. It is used in this wide sense in this section.
Goods are economic if scarce resources have to be used to obtain or modify them so that they are of
use, i.e. have utility, for people. They are free if they can be enjoyed or used without any sacrifice of
resources. A few minutes reflection will probably convince you that most goods are economic in the
sense just outlined. The air we breathe under normal conditions is free, but not when it has to be
purified or kept at a constant and bearable pressure in an airliner. Rainwater, when it falls in the open
on growing crops, is free but not when it has to be carried to the crops along irrigation channels or
purified to make it safe for humans to drink. Free goods are indeed very precious and people are
becoming increasingly aware of the costs of destroying them by their activities, e.g. by polluting the
air in the areas where we live.
Production Factors
Since there are very few free goods most have to be modified in some way before they become
capable of satisfying a human want. The process of want satisfaction can also be termed the creation
of utility or usefulness and is also what we understand by production. In its widest economic sense
production includes any human effort directed towards the satisfaction of peoples wants. It can be as
simple as picking berries, busking to entertain a theatre queue or washing clothes in a stream, or as
involved as manufacturing a jet airliner or performing open heart surgery.
Production is simple when it involves the use of very few scarce resources but much more involved
and complex when it involves a long chain of interrelated activities and a wide range of resources.
We now need to examine this general term resources, or economic resources, more closely. The
resources employed in the processes of production are usually called the factors of production and,
for simplicity, these can be grouped into a few simple classifications. Economists usually identify the
following production factors.
Licensed to ABE
Land
This is used in two senses:
(a)
The space occupied to carry out any production process, e.g. space for a factory or office
(b)
The basic resources within land, sea or air which can be extracted for productive use,
e.g. metal ores, coal and oil.
Labour
Any mental or physical effort used in a production process. Some economists see labour as the
ultimate production factor since nothing happens without the intervention of labour. Even the
most advanced computer owes its powers ultimately to some human programmer or group of
programmers.
Capital
This is also used in several senses, and again we can identify two main categories:
(a)
Real capital consists of the tools, equipment and human skills employed in production.
It can be either physical capital, e.g. factory buildings, machines or equipment, or human
capital the accumulated skill, knowledge and experience without which physical
capital cannot achieve its full productive potential.
(b)
Financial capital is the fund of money which, in a modern society, is usually needed to
acquire and develop real capital, both physical and human.
Notice how closely related all the production factors are. Most production requires some
combination of all the factors. Only labour can function purely on its own, if we ignore the need for
space. A singer or story teller can entertain with voice alone, but will usually give more pleasure with
the aid of a musical instrument and is likely to benefit from earlier investment in some kind of
training. The hairdresser requires a least a pair of scissors!
Much of economic history is the story of peoples success in increasing the quantity and quality of
production through the accumulation of human capital and the development of technically advanced
physical capital. I can dig a small hole in the ground with my bare hands, but creating the Channel
Tunnel between Britain and France has required a vast amount of very advanced physical capital
together with a great deal of human skill and knowledge.
Modern firms depend for their survival and success on both their physical and their human resources.
While some of us may feel that the current trend to replace the business term personnel
management by human resource management is in some degree dehumanising, others welcome it
as a sign that firms are recognising the importance of its employee skills as human capital.
Licensed to ABE
In an age of small business organisations, owned and managed by one person or family, this seemed
quite a reasonable explanation. The skilled worker who gives up secure and often well-paid
employment to take the risks of starting and running a business is most likely to be showing
enterprise and is prepared to take risks in the hope of achieving profits above the level of his or her
previous wage. Many modern firms have been formed in the recent past by initiators, innovators and
risk takers of the kind that certainly fit the usual definition of the business entrepreneur. Their names
appear constantly in the business press. Few would wish to deny that profit has been and often
remains the spur that drives them.
Nevertheless this identification of enterprise in terms of individual risk-taking raises a great many
problems when we attempt to apply it generally to the modern business environment. Much
contemporary business activity is controlled by large companies such as BT, Shell, BP and Unilever.
Who are the entrepreneurs in such organisations? Are they rewarded by profits? How do these
companies recruit and foster enterprise? You, yourself, may work in a large organisation. Can you
reconcile the traditional economic concept of enterprise as a factor of production with your
observations of the structure of your company?
No one doubts the importance of enterprise and profit in modern business but their traditional
explanation in terms of the fourth production factor is at best incomplete and at worst actually
dangerous, in that it may be used to justify the very large salaries which company chief executives
seem able to award themselves in Britain and the USA.
We shall return to the question of profit in Study Unit 5.
Licensed to ABE
short run they mean that period during which at least one production factor, usually capital, is fixed,
e.g. one shop, one factory, one passenger coach. By long run they mean that period when it is
possible to vary all the factors of production, e.g. increase the number of shops, factories or passenger
coaches. Sometimes you may find the short and long run referred to as short and long term. This is
not strictly correct, but the difference in meaning is slight and not important at this stage of study.
Production Function
We can now summarise the main implications of our recognition of factors of production. We can
say that to produce most goods and services we need some combination of land, capital and labour.
At present we can leave out enterprise as this is difficult to quantify. In slightly more formal
language we say that production is a function of land, capital and labour. Using the symbols Q for
production, S for land, K for capital and L for labour, (with for function) this allows us, if we wish,
to use the mathematical expression:
Q = (S, K, L)
For further simplicity, we can leave out land so we can concentrate on just two factors, capital and
labour and, as previously noted, regard capital as a fixed and labour as a variable factor.
Quantity of production
(units per month)
30
70
120
170
220
260
290
310
320
10
320
11
310
Licensed to ABE
The quantity of production measured here in units produced per month and shown as a graph in
Figure 1.1, is, of course, the total product. In this example total product continues to rise until the
tenth worker is added to the business; this worker is unable to increase total product. This is no
reflection on that particular worker who may, in fact, be working very hard. It is simply that, given
the fixed amount of capital, no further increase in productive output is possible. The addition of an
eleventh worker would actually cause a fall in production. It is not difficult to see why this could
happen.
Quantity of production
(units per month)
Marginal Product of
labour
(units per month)
30
30
40
70
50
120
170
220
260
290
310
320
10
320
11
310
50
50
40
30
20
10
0
10
The marginal product of labour is the change in total product resulting from a change in the
amount of labour employed. It is called marginal because it is the change at the edge, and the term
marginal is used in economics to denote a change in the total of one variable which results from a
single unit change in another variable. Here the total is quantity of production resulting from changes
in the number of workers employed.
The marginal product column shows the difference in the total product column at each level of
employment. Notice that the marginal value is shown midway between the values for total product
Licensed to ABE
and number of workers. This is because it shows the change that takes place as we move from one
level of employment to the next. In Figure 1.1 the marginal product is represented by the vertical
distance between each step in production as each worker is added.
The sum of the marginal product values up to each level of worker is equal to the total product at that
level.
Figure 1.1
Notice how these marginal product values change as total product rises: one worker alone can
produce 30 units but another enables the business to increase production by 40 units and one more by
50 units. There are many ways in which this increase might be achieved, e.g. by specialisation and by
freeing the manager to improve administration, purchasing and selling. However, these increases
cannot continue and the additional third, fourth and fifth workers all add a constant amount to
production. Thereafter, further workers, while still increasing production, do so by diminishing
amounts until the tenth worker adds nothing to the total. At this level of labour employment
production has reached its maximum, and the eleventh worker actually provides a negative return
total production falls. Perhaps people get in each others way or cause distraction and confusion. If
the business owner wishes to continue to expand production, thought must be given to increasing
capital through more buildings and/or equipment. Short-run expansion at this level of capital has to
cease. Only by increasing the fixed factors can further growth be achieved.
This example is purely fictional it is not based on an actual firm; but neither is the pattern of change
in marginal product accidental. The figures are chosen deliberately to illustrate some of the most
important principles of economics, the so-called laws of varying proportions and diminishing
returns. It has been constantly observed in all kinds of business activities that when further
increments of one, variable production factor are added to a fixed quantity of another factor, the
additional production achieved is likely, first, to increase, then to remain roughly constant and
eventually to diminish. It is this third stage that is usually of the greatest importance, this is the stage
Licensed to ABE
of diminishing marginal product, more commonly known as diminishing returns. Most firms are
likely to operate under these conditions and it is during this stage that the most difficult managerial
decisions, relating to additional production and the expansion of fixed production factors, have to be
taken.
It must not, of course, be assumed that firms will seek to employ people up to the stage of maximum
product when the marginal product of labour = 0, or on the other hand that they will not take on any
extra employees if diminishing returns are being experienced. The production level at which further
employment ceases to be profitable depends on several other considerations, including the value of
the marginal product, which depends on the revenue gained from product sales, and the cost of
employing labour, made up of wages, labour taxes and compulsory welfare benefits. The higher the
cost of employing labour, the less labour will be employed in the short run and the sooner will
employers seek to replace labour by capital in the form of labour-saving equipment.
Quantity of production
(units per month)
30
70
120
170
220
260
290
310
320
10
320
11
310
Marginal product of
labour
(units per month)
Average product of
labour
(units per month)
30
30.00
40
35.00
50
40.00
50
42.50
50
44.00
40
43.33
30
41.43
20
38.75
10
35.56
0
32.00
10
Licensed to ABE
28.18
10
Figure 1.2
The falling marginal product curve intersects the average product curve at about the 5th worker.
Average product then starts to fall because for more workers marginal product is below average
product.
Notice the relationship between average and marginal product. Average product continues to rise
until it is the same as the falling marginal product, then it falls. This must happen as can easily be
proved mathematically, and you can see it for yourself if you take any set of figures where marginal
product continues to diminish.
Licensed to ABE
11
You should give some thought to the implications of these product relationships for business costs:
we will examine them in Study Unit 4.
D. PRODUCTION POSSIBILITIES
If individual firms are likely to face a point of maximum production as they reach the limits of their
available resources the same is likely to be true of communities, whose total potential product must
also be limited by the resources available to the community and by the level of technology which
enables those resources to be put to productive use.
This idea is frequently illustrated by economists through what is usually termed the production
possibilities frontier (or curve), which is illustrated in Figure 1.3.
The frontier represents the limit of what can be produced by a community from its available resources
and at its current level of production technology. Because we wish to illustrate this through a simple
two-dimensional graph we have to assume just two classes of goods and, for simplicity, we can call
these consumer goods (goods and services for personal and household use) and capital goods (goods
and services for use by production organisations for the production of further goods).
Because resources are scarce in the sense explained earlier in this study unit, we cannot use the same
production factors to produce both sets of goods at the same time. If we want more of one set we
must sacrifice some of the other set. However, the extent of the sacrifice, i.e. the opportunity cost, of
increasing production of each set is unlikely to be constant through each level of production since
some factors are likely to be more efficient at some kinds of production than others. Consequently
the shape of the frontier curve can be assumed to reflect the principle of increasing opportunity
costs. This is shown in Figure 1.3. In this illustration the opportunity cost measured in the lost
opportunity to produce arms is much less at the low level of food production of 2 billion units than at
the much higher level of 9 billion units.
The curve illustrates other features of the production system. For example, the community can
produce any combination of consumer and capital goods within and on the frontier but cannot
produce a combination outside the frontier say at E. If it produces the mixtures represented by
points A, B or C on the frontier all resources (production factors) are fully employed, i.e. there are no
spare or unused resources. The community can produce within the frontier, say at D, but at this point
some production factors must be unemployed.
Licensed to ABE
12
Licensed to ABE
13
It might be that if the firm devoted all its resources to the production of one good instead of to more
than one then it would be able to use them more efficiently. They would then gain from what will
later be described as increasing returns to scale. In this case the curve would be shaped as in Figure
1.4.
Yet another possibility is that the firm could switch resources without any gain or loss in efficiency,
i.e. it would experience constant returns from scale in using its resources. In this case the curve
would be linear (a straight line) as in Figure 1.5.
Quantity of Y
Quantity of X
Figure 1.4
The production possibilities curve for a firm gaining increased efficiency by concentrating on one
product
Licensed to ABE
14
Quantity of Y
Quantity of X
Figure 1.5
The production possibilities curve for a firm which is neither more nor less efficient when it switches
resources from one product to another.
People are also assumed to be rational in their behaviour. Again, we are all capable of the most
irrational actions from time to time but if we behave in a normal manner we are likely to display
rational economic behaviour. For example if, given the choice between, say, cornflakes and muesli
for breakfast we choose cornflakes and if given the choice between, say, muesli and porridge we
choose muesli, then, if we are rational and offered the choice between cornflakes and porridge we
would be expected to choose cornflakes, because we prefer cornflakes to muesli and muesli to
porridge. It would be irrational to choose porridge in preference to cornflakes if we have already
indicated a preference for muesli over porridge and for cornflakes over muesli.
If we accept consistency and rationality in human behaviour then analysis of that behaviour becomes
possible, and we can start to identify patterns and trends and measure the extent to which people are
likely to react to specific changes in the economic environment such as price in ways that we can
identify, predict and measure. If we could not do this the entire study of economics would become
virtually impossible.
Licensed to ABE
15
Consumer Sovereignty
Although the separation between supply and demand as two different forces has been stressed, the
market economy operates on the assumption that, of these forces, consumer demand is dominant.
The market production system is demand-led: supply adjusts to meet demand. In this sense the
consumer is sovereign. Producers who cannot sell their goods at a profit fail and disappear from the
production system. Profit is the driving force of the production system, and profit is achieved by the
ability to produce goods that people will buy at prices that people will pay while enabling the
producer to earn sufficient profit to stay in business and to wish to stay in business. However
strong the demand for goods, if they cannot be produced at a profit they will not, in the long run, be
supplied.
If you have lived all your life in a market economy none of this will seem strange to you. But to
someone who has lived in a command economy where production decisions and the quantity, quality
and distribution of consumer goods have all been determined by the institutions of the state, the full
implications of consumer sovereignty, particularly the implications for individual firms operating in a
competitive market environment, can be very hard to grasp.
In the next five study units we shall be very largely concerned with different aspects of the forces of
demand and supply and how they interact, or sometimes fail to interact, in the market economy.
Licensed to ABE
16
Licensed to ABE
17
Study Unit 2
Consumption and Demand
Contents
A.
B.
C.
D.
Page
Utility
18
Meaning of Utility
18
18
19
Indifference Curves
21
21
22
27
32
32
32
34
35
36
Licensed to ABE
18
A. UTILITY
Meaning of Utility
Economists have always faced problems in explaining clearly why people are prepared to make
sacrifices to obtain many of the goods and services which they evidently wish to have. In a market
economy this difficulty can be stated as Why do we buy the things we do buy? Very often we do
not need them in the strict sense that they are necessary to our survival. In fact our basic needs are
really very small compared with all the things on which we spend our money in advanced market
economies. We can talk in terms of wants and recognise that there seems to be no limit to these
wants. We also have to recognise that at any given time we are likely to want some things more than
others.
What, then, is the quality that goods must possess that make us want to acquire them? Clearly this
will differ with different goods. Some may be pleasant to eat, some attractive to look at, some warm
to wear and so on. The one general term we can apply to all goods and services is that they provide
us with utility. This does not necessarily mean that they are useful in the sense that they help us to
do something we could not do before we had them but simply that we perceive in them some quality
that makes us willing to make some degree of sacrifice (usually of money) in order to acquire them.
Can we, then, measure this utility? In an absolute sense, the answer is almost certainly No. Some
economists have proposed adopting a measure called a util but no-one, not even the European
Commission, has yet proposed that we mark all goods to show how many utils they contain. It is
more practical to think in terms of money value since most of us measure the strength of our desire to
buy something in terms of the price we are prepared to pay for it. When, therefore, an estate agent
asks a potential house buyer, How much are you prepared to offer for this house? the agent is, in
effect, asking the buyer to indicate the value of the utility which the house has for him or her.
More often we find ourselves making comparisons of utility. This arises partly because of the basic
economic problem of unlimited wants and scarce resources, so that ranking our wants so we can
decide what we can afford to buy is for most people an almost daily occurrence; but it also arises
because, in modern advanced economies there is likely to be a range of different goods to satisfy any
particular want. If I want to travel by public transport from Birmingham to Glasgow I could do so by
motor coach, by train, or by air. My want is to get from Birmingham to Glasgow, and three options
offer the utility to satisfy this want. Each involves different sacrifices of money and time and offers
different associated utilities of convenience and comfort. My choice will depend on the resources
available to me (how much money I can afford to pay and how much time I have) and on my
valuation of the utility afforded by each option. Notice, further, that this utility is not an absolute
quality but depends on why I want to make the journey. If it is part of a holiday then I might prefer
the coach or train, but if I am attending a business meeting from which I hope to achieve a financial
benefit and need to be fresh and alert then the air option is likely to offer the greatest utility greater,
probably, than the price of the fare.
All this may seem very involved, but an appreciation of utility and how it can influence our actions
can be a very great help in understanding the true nature of economic demand.
Licensed to ABE
19
similar good we already possess. Suppose I have enough spare cash at the end of the week to buy
either a pair of trousers or a pair of shoes but not both, though I would like both. If I already have an
adequate supply of trousers for the next few months but do not have any spare shoes then, assuming
that their prices are roughly similar, I am likely to buy the shoes. This does not mean that I always
value shoes more highly than trousers but that, considering what I already have at the present time, I
perceive greater utility in some additional shoes than in additional trousers.
By now, especially if you have remembered the explanation of marginal product in Study Unit 1, you
will recognise that I have just given an example of marginal utility, i.e. the change in total utility for
a good or group of goods when there is a change in the quantity of those goods already possessed.
Most of the important decisions relating to the demand for goods and services are influenced by
valuations of marginal utility compared with the prices of these goods. The more pairs of trousers I
possess the less value am I likely to place an obtaining more and the more likely am I to spend my
available money on other things of comparable price whose marginal utilities are higher.
Willingness to buy thus depends on the comparison of marginal utility with price so to some extent it
is reasonable to value utility in terms of price. To return to the original house buyer example, if the
buyer says to the agent, My highest offer is 100,000, then for this buyer the value of the marginal
utility of the house is 100,000. If this is the buyers only house then, of course, it is also the total
utility.
We must also bear in mind that money itself has utility. If I am saving money for a major holiday or
for an expensive durable (long lasting) good such as a house or furniture, then I may place a high
value on money savings and be less inclined to buy trousers and shoes as long as I have enough of
these for my immediate needs. If my income is secure and rising, my valuation of the marginal utility
of money could be low and I am more likely to spend it on goods. If, however, my job is not secure
and redundancy or retirement is a serious possibility, my valuation of the marginal utility of money is
likely to rise and I will spend less on goods and services. You can easily see the implications of this
for the general demand for consumer goods during periods of economic uncertainty when people
think they are likely to have less money in the future. Just as the marginal utility of a good
diminishes as the quantity already possessed rises, so marginal utility rises as the quantity of a good
already possessed falls or is expected to fall in the near future.
Licensed to ABE
20
the price of trousers, i.e. the sacrifice I must make to buy them
my desire for other goods and services, i.e. other marginal utilities ( I would not, for example,
be too pleased to have eight pairs of trousers if I possessed only one shirt, nor would trousers
satisfy my hunger if I did not have enough food to eat)
Only when all these are taken into account would it be possible to estimate how many pairs of
trousers would represent, for me, the best total to try and achieve.
Licensed to ABE
21
Assuming rationality, in the sense explained in Study Unit 1, the most satisfactory quantity of
trousers for me would be where my marginal utility gained from the last 1 spent on trousers just
equalled the marginal utility per 1 spent on all other available goods and services, and where this
also equalled the marginal utility of money. On the assumption that we are valuing utility in
monetary terms the marginal utility of the last 1 of money = 1.
Putting this statement a little more formally as an equation and using the symbols, MUA to denote the
marginal utility for the good A, MUB for the marginal utility for the good B, PA for the price of A, PB
for the price of B and so on, we can say that consumers achieve a position of equilibrium in their
expenditure when for them:
MU N
MU A
MU B
=
=
= 1 (which = the marginal utility of money)
PA
PB
PN
In this state of equilibrium consumers cannot increase their total utility from all goods and services
by any kind of redistribution of spending. Spending more on A and less on B, for example, would
mean that the marginal utility of A would fall and so be less than that of the marginal utility of B,
which would rise and be less than the marginal utility of other goods, including money. Also the
utility gain from A would be less than the utility lost from B so total utility would have fallen. No
one rationally spends 1 to receive less than 1s worth of utility.
You may object that this kind of reasoning takes no account of actions such as making contributions
to charity, but our use of the term utility does embrace such gifts. Presumably we give to a charity
because the act of giving to a use we perceive as worthy, affords us satisfaction. It has, therefore,
utility and can be regarded in the same way as other forms of spending. This means, of course, as
charities and the organisers of national charitable events have discovered, that giving to charity is
also subject to diminishing marginal utility. Aid fatigue is the term sometimes used for this.
B. INDIFFERENCE CURVES
What is an Indifference Curve?
An indifference curve is a graph linking all the combinations of two goods or two groups of goods
which provide the same level of total utility for an individual, group of people or community. It is
called an indifference curve because there is no preference for one combination over any of the
others. All offer the same amount of utility or satisfaction, so that people are indifferent as to which
combination they have.
One curve can, of course, indicate only one level of utility. If the resources available to acquire the
goods were increased people could move to a higher level, and if resources fell they would have to be
satisfied with a lower level. We can, therefore, imagine that any one curve is really part of a map of
very many curves all representing different levels of total utility.
A simple example of an indifference curve is shown in Figure 2.2.
Licensed to ABE
22
Figure 2.2
The figures given here for units of X and Y are purely hypothetical. They are not an actual case and
are intended simply to illustrate a general situation. From the table and the curve we see that the
person whose curve this is would have the same utility from 4 units of X and 1.5 of Y as from 3 units
of X and 2 of Y or from 2 units of X and 3 of Y.
Although these figures are, to some extent, just plucked out of the air, they are also chosen to
illustrate the general shape which we can expect all indifference curves to take, i.e. the curve is
convex to the origin of the graph since it is based on the principle already explained, of diminishing
marginal utility.
According to this curve, when the person has just 1 unit of X but 6 of Y, he or she is prepared to give
up 3 units of Y to gain 1 more unit of X, i.e. 1X has the same value as 6Y. However, when that
person has 3 units of C he or she will only be prepared to give up 0.5Y in return for one more X, i.e.
with 3 units of X possessed, a further unit of X is valued at only 0.5Y. Thus the marginal utility of X
has diminished from 3Y to 0.5Y as more X is accumulated.
You may think this is a rather involved way to illustrate the fairly commonsense principle that most
people readily accept that the more we have of something the less value we put on gaining yet more
of the same and the more we would prefer to have something else. This is all that we mean by
diminishing marginal utility. However, the indifference curve has given rise to a technique of
analysis that is used quite frequently in economics and which often helps to clarify thinking on some
fairly controversial topics.
Licensed to ABE
23
groups of goods. As we noted earlier in this study unit, to be able to estimate how much of a good
people may be prepared to buy, in a market economy, we also need to know:
!
To carry out any kind of indifference curve analysis, therefore, we must take these two factors into
consideration.
Suppose that the price of X is 3 per unit while that of Y is 2 per unit. Suppose also that the amount
of money available for spending on X and Y is limited to 12.
Assuming that the full 12 is spent there is a range of spending possibilities. These are:
!
The whole 12 is used to buy X with nothing spent on Y. At a unit price of X of 3 this would
buy 4 units of X.
The whole 12 is used to buy Y with nothing spent on X. At a unit price of Y of 2 this would
buy 6 units of Y.
These possibilities are illustrated in the linear (straight line) spending possibilities curve of
Figure 2.3. (If you have studied some mathematics you will not be worried by the thought that there
are linear, or straight-line curves. If you have not studied mathematics, you will soon get used to the
expression.) The spending possibilities curve is sometimes called the spending possibilities line, to
help to distinguish it from the indifference curve, and it is also sometimes called the budget line.
Figure 2.3
Licensed to ABE
24
We now have two curves: one, the indifference curve, shows us combinations of X and Y that
provide us with the same level of total utility or satisfaction; the other, the spending possibilities line,
tells us what it is possible to buy at given prices and a given amount of money for spending.
When the two curves are combined, as in Figure 2.4, we see that the only combination on the
indifference curve that we can buy is 2X and 3Y. Had there been less than 12 to spend the spending
possibilities line would not have reached this indifference curve and only a lower level of utility (a
lower curve in the map mentioned earlier) would have been available.
Figure 2.4
Consider now what would happen if the person had 16, not 12 to spend. The spending possibilities
line changes as shown in Figure 2.5. The 16 can be used to obtain more of X or more of Y, or some
new and larger combinations of the two.
Licensed to ABE
25
Figure 2.5
Figure 2.5 also shows how movement to a higher spending possibility line allows movement to a
higher indifference curve, where there is a greater level of total utility or satisfaction. The point
where the new curve just touches the higher spending possibility line is at a level where more of both
X and Y is obtained.
This movement to a higher indifference curve results in more of both X and Y being bought. This is a
reasonable expectation: if our income rises we can spend more on most goods. However, there may
be some exceptions. As incomes rise, peoples pattern of spending may change; the extra income
may permit people to switch spending from some goods to preferred substitutes. The diet of people
on low incomes may include a substantial amount of bread or potatoes, but as their incomes rise they
may choose a more varied diet, spending less on bread or potatoes. If this happens we can say that
bread and potatoes are perceived by such people as inferior goods; they may, perhaps, buy more
fruit, biscuits and other foods.
When this happens there has been a change in the relative preferences between goods and this will be
reflected in a change in the shape of a higher indifference curve, as illustrated in Figure 2.6. Here a
rise in income allows the spending possibilities line to move outwards from AB to A1B1 and the
higher spending permits movement to a preferred combination of goods on the higher indifference
curve I1. This indifference curve is flatter than the lower curve I, which means that X is valued less
highly compared with Y. The amount of X that has to be given up to gain a given amount of Y is less
as you move along I1 than if you move along I. You can see this in Figure 2.7.
Licensed to ABE
26
Figure 2.6
Figure 2.7
Licensed to ABE
27
In curve I the group puts the same ability value on 5 units of X and 5 units of Y as it does on 4 units
of X and 6 units of Y. Thus at this level on indifference curve I, 1 unit of X = 1 unit of Y.
In curve I1 the different group puts the same utility value on 5X and 5Y as it does on 3 units of X and
6 units of Y or 4 units of X and 5.5 units of Y. The flatter curve, therefore, values X at half as much
Y as the steeper curve at the levels examined.
Notice that showing two curves intersecting in this way indicates that they must either reflect the
preferences of different groups or the same group at different times. They cannot possibly relate to
the same group at the same time, since 5X and 5Y cannot at the same time have the same utility as
both 4X and 6Y and 3X and 6Y.
Because of the danger of misleading examiners by appearing to show such an absurdity you should be
careful never to show indifference curves intersecting on the same graph. I have broken this rule in
Figure 2.7 only to give you a simple illustration of the difference between a flat and a steep
indifference curve.
Remember the flatter the indifference curve the greater the preference for the good measured along
the vertical or Y axis; the steeper the indifference curve the greater the preference for the good
measured along the horizontal or X axis. Thus, if the indifference curves get flatter as income and
total utility levels increase, this suggests that people are switching their spending preferences towards
the good or goods measured along the Y axis. If they do this to the extent that the quantity purchased
actually falls following an income rise then the goods on the horizontal axis can be described as
inferior in economic terms.
Licensed to ABE
28
Figure 2.8
The lower indifference curve (dotted in the graph) touches the spending line, to give a package of
rather less X but a little more Y. When using indifference curves in this way remember, as mentioned
earlier in this study unit, to imagine that there is an indifference map containing a mass of curves,
each representing a particular level of total utility or satisfaction. The further away from the origin
(where the axes of the graph meet) we move, the higher the level of utility represented by the curve
because it represents more of both X and Y.
The changes shown in these illustrations all support the earlier statement that a rise in price of a
commodity will lead to a fall in the quantity demanded of that commodity.
In Figure 2.8 a price rise for X resulted in less of X being purchased; this is what we would normally
expect for most goods. However, some economists have argued that this may not always be the case.
They point out that a price change will not only change peoples perception of other goods as
substitutes but will also affect the income that is available for spending, particularly if the price in
question relates to something which is bought regularly and so makes up a significant part of peoples
incomes, especially if the incomes were low. If the price of this basic good rose so that people could
no longer afford to buy preferred substitutes then it is, perhaps, conceivable that they would be forced
to buy more rather than less of the good whose price has risen. In this very special (and extremely
rare) case a price rise could be said to lead to increased purchases while a price fall, by releasing
spendable income to buy preferred goods, could lead to less being bought.
This possibility is illustrated in Figure 2.9, where a reduction in the price of X allows the spending
possibility line AB to move to AC for the same level of income. This allows buyers to achieve the
Licensed to ABE
29
higher level of utility or satisfaction represented by the indifference curve I1 which is higher than the
curve I the highest attainable by spending possibility AB. The preferred combination of X and Y is
now Ox1 and Oy1. This provides more satisfaction than the old combination of Ox and Oy but, as we
see from the diagram, x1 represents a smaller quantity of X than x. Thus people have used the extra
money made available by the price reduction of x to buy more of Y and less of X rather than more of
both, which would have been the case if X had been a normal good.
Figure 2.9
The reason for this is clear from the diagram. The higher indifference curve I1 is flatter than the
lower curve I. Thus X is perceived as being so inferior to Y that even the amount of spendable
income change resulting from the price reduction is sufficient to allow people to switch their buying
to Y from X. Such a good is known as a Giffen good, Giffen being the name of the person who first
drew attention to the possibility.
You will see that this is a very special case and it is extremely difficult to think of an example for
such a possibility in a modern advanced market economy. However, the term Giffen good has
come to be used in a wider sense, which will be explained and discussed in Study Unit 3.
As well as illustrating the so-called Giffen effect, this example also shows that when a goods price
changes there are two consequences, both of which are likely to affect peoples purchases.
(a)
If a price of, say, X changes while the prices of other goods, say Y, Z and so on, stay the same
there is a change in the pattern of relative prices. If good Y is seen as substitute for X, and if
the price of X rises with the price of Y staying unchanged, then X has become dearer compared
with Y and some people who previously bought X are likely to transfer to Y which is now
Licensed to ABE
30
relatively cheaper than before. For X and Y, think of, perhaps, potatoes and rice or tea and
coffee. If the price of tea rises, people will not stop drinking tea but some will start to switch
to coffee when previously they would have drunk tea. We can expect that there will be some
switching of purchases to substitutes when one good becomes relatively more expensive than
its rivals. This is called the substitution effect of the price change.
(b)
As we have seen earlier, if the price of tea rises any given quantity of tea purchased requires
more income than it did before the price rise. This will reduce the amount of income available
for spending on other things, including possible extra purchases of tea. In the same way if, say,
the price of coffee were to fall, this would increase the amount of income available for
spending on other things including extra coffee. This is called the income effect of the price
change.
These two effects together make up the total shift in buying following a price rise or fall. They can
be analysed with the help, once more, of indifference curves.
Look at Figure 2.10. This uses the symbols X and Y as before to show they can apply to any goods
but you can think of X as coffee and Y as tea, if you wish.
Here we see the effect of a reduction in the price of X from 3 per unit to 2 per unit. Y stays at 3
per unit and disposable income stays at 48. The maximum possible purchases of X, assuming no
purchases of Y, rises from 16 to 24 units.
Suppose the original combination of X and Y actually purchased, given the indifference curve I, was:
9Y(27) + 7X(21) = 48 at B, before the price change.
After the change in price, the new combination on the higher indifference curve I1 would be:
913Y(28) + 10X(20) = 48 at A.
To help you understand the income and substitution effects, let us imagine that, after the price
change, available income was reduced to an amount which just allowed consumption to stay on the
lower indifference curve I at C. This is represented by the dotted line which runs parallel to the
second consumption possibility line and which just touches indifference curve I at C. The dotted line
is called the income compensation line. At C, the consumption package would be 8Y + 813X.
Licensed to ABE
31
Figure 2.10
The increased consumption of X between points B and C on the same indifference curve, i.e. from 7
to 813Y units, the result of a movement along the indifference curve, is the substitution effect. It is
the result purely of the change in price of X from 3 to 2, because the total utility gained from
consuming both X and Y has not changed.
Thus, if we consider the actual consumption movement from B to A, we see that it is made up of two
parts. These are the 113Y units rise which we have explained as the substitution effect, plus the 123
units rise which is the result of the increased income available for spending and which has enabled
movement to the higher indifference curve I1.
This increase resulting from movement to a higher level of satisfaction is the income effect, because
the reduction in price of X has provided more spendable income and some of this has been used to
purchase more X.
In this example X and Y are clearly normal goods since the full movement from B to A is the sum of
B to C plus C to A. But suppose X had been an inferior good: in this case the indifference curve I1
would have been flatter and the point of tangency (A) with the consumption possibility line 2 would
have been to the left of C, indicating a reduction in purchases as a result of the income effect. The
total change B to A would then have been the distance B to C minus C to A, i.e. a total somewhere
between B and C to a quantity level of X below 8.33.
Taking this one stage further, consider the possibility of a Giffen good. In this case the inferior nature
of the income effect would have been even greater and the indifference curve I1 even flatter until the
point of tangency A would actually move to the left of the starting point of B and the new level of
purchases of X would be under 7X.
Licensed to ABE
32
Notice that the income effect of a price change can move the level of consumption for the affected
good in either direction.
!
For normal goods (the majority) a rise in income available for spending on the good produces
an increase in purchases. Similarly a fall in income results in a reduction in purchases.
For inferior goods a rise in income available for spending on the goods produces a reduction in
purchases, while a fall in income results in an increase in purchases.
However the substitution effect is always in the same direction, i.e. in the reverse direction to that of
the price change and in favour of the good whose price has become lower relative to the price of the
substitute. In effect the substitution effect is a movement along the indifference curve caused by the
change in gradient of the consumption possibilities line, which is itself caused by the changes in the
relative prices. Thus we can say that:
!
For all goods the substitution effect causes a rise in the consumption of the good whose price
has become relatively lower and a reduction in consumption of the good whose price has
become relatively more expensive.
The Giffen effect, where a price rise produces an increase in consumption and a price fall leads to a
decline in consumption, occurs when the inferior income effect is actually greater than the
substitution effect.
Licensed to ABE
33
possibility lines in Figure 2.11, which also shows the actual consumption of X at the prices of 12,
8.75, 7 and 5, given the indifference curves of the diagram.
Figure 2.11
We see that actual consumption of X, given the relative preferences of X and Y represented by the
indifference curves, rises from 44 units per week at the price of 12 per unit to 96 units per week at
the price of 5 per unit. The actual consumption figures, related to these prices, are shown in Figure
2.12. This graph shows the demand for X at the range of prices 12 to 5. It is the demand curve for
the good X.
Licensed to ABE
34
Figure 2.12
This example illustrates the general shape of the demand curve and the normal relationship between
price and quantity demanded of a product. If all other influences remain constant, we would expect
the quantity demanded to rise as price falls and to fall as price rises. Notice that, in our example, we
have made the following assumptions:
(a)
(b)
Income also stays constant, at 840. Another point to remember is that we are here considering
a flow of demand related to a set period of time. It is always necessary to do this. We cannot
compare a weekly amount at one price directly with a monthly amount at another. When we
change one variable here price to analyse its effect on quantity, we have to keep all other
elements constant, including the time period to which the stated quantity relates. In our
example, this period was a week.
Licensed to ABE
35
Figure 2.13
Licensed to ABE
36
Figure 2.14
Licensed to ABE
37
is what I paid. Consequently I gained a surplus of 10p. The value of my sacrifice was less than the
value of the additional utility I gained: the difference was a surplus to me.
Figure 2.15
Since the price of 30p per pound was below my valuation of the marginal utility of a pound of apples
I might decide to buy two or perhaps three pounds. In this case I was valuing the marginal utility of
the additional amount bought above my usual quantity at less than the 40p but still now below 30p.
If, as seems likely, most consumers react in this way then we have no difficulty in accepting the
general shape of the demand curve outlined in the previous section, i.e. that people are prepared to
buy more of a good at a lower than at a higher price.
These ideas are illustrated in Figure 2.15, which shows a normal demand curve for a product the price
of which is 0p. The fact that the demand curve extends to prices higher than 0p indicates that there
are consumers who are willing to pay a higher price. However, if the price charged is 0p, then these
consumers achieve a surplus which is represented by the shaded area.
The demand curve is downward sloping to indicate that more of the product will be bought as the
price falls. This follows the assumption that most people will buy more of a product if they think the
price is favourable. Marginal utility diminishes as the quantity already possessed rises so, to sell
more, the supplier is likely to have to reduce price. Remember, as always, when considering the
effect of one change we make the assumption that other things remain unchanged. In practice they
will not, and in the next study unit we recognise this. My valuation of the marginal utility of apples
will change if I discover that the store has received a large consignment of nectarines and peaches and
is selling these at prices around my marginal utility for these fruits.
Licensed to ABE
38
Licensed to ABE
39
Study Unit 3
Demand and Revenue
Contents
A.
B.
C.
D.
Page
Influences On Demand
40
Flow of Demand
40
40
41
41
41
Market Size
41
41
Taste
42
Expectations
42
Other Influences
42
Summary of Influences
42
42
42
43
44
Total Revenue
44
Average Revenue
45
Marginal Revenue
47
51
Calculation
51
54
54
54
55
55
56
56
Licensed to ABE
40
A. INFLUENCES ON DEMAND
Flow of Demand
The demand curve which we identified in the previous study unit illustrates the quantities of a
product that a group of consumers are prepared to buy at a range of possible prices. We must
remember that these quantities are always related to a time period. Demand is seen in terms of a flow
of purchases over a stated time. A greengrocer, for example, may want to know the weekly quantity
of apples he can sell at a price of 80p per kilo, and compare this with the weekly quantity he could
sell at 90p per kilo. The time is not always shown in simple demand graphs, but we must not forget
its importance. It is not much use being able to sell 100 kilos instead of 50 kilos if it takes three times
as long to do so.
If we clearly understand this idea of demand flow, remembering the points we made in Study Unit 2,
we can go on to identify the various influences which affect that flow.
Licensed to ABE
41
pay for a part-time degree course to enhance career prospects may think it worthwhile, perhaps, to
spend less on entertainment or to put off replacing a car or furniture.
Market Size
Many factors can change market size. A firm selling clothes to teenagers will benefit from any
increase in the numbers of teenagers in the population. Specialist shops selling babies and childrens
wear suffered from the declining birth rate of the early 1970s. Market size can be increased by
improvements in communications and technology. The development of commercial television greatly
increased the market area open to many consumer-goods firms. Increased foreign travel in the 1960s
helped to extend the demand and market area for foreign wines and foods. Improved techniques of
refrigeration extended the market for frozen vegetables.
Licensed to ABE
42
Taste
This is a quality difficult to define. Peoples desire to buy products is the result of many influences,
not all of which are fully understood. Fashions change, and these changes cannot always be caused
by advertising. The successful firm is often the one that is able to make an accurate prediction of
changes in fashion and taste.
Expectations
Expectations of future changes in any of the above influences can affect present demand. For
example, people expecting rising prices will buy now rather than later. On the other hand, if they fear
unemployment and falling incomes, they will cut down their present spending. Notice that these
reactions may actually help to bring about the feared future changes.
Other Influences
Certain products may be subject to special influences other than the ones we have already mentioned.
The demand for soft drinks or for waterproof clothing, for instance, will be influenced by weather
conditions. The demand for private education in an area will be influenced by the reputation of Stateowned schools in that area.
Summary of Influences
All these influences on demand for a product can be expressed in a form of mathematical shorthand.
Thus, we can say that:
Q = (Po, Pa, Yd , N, A, T).
This simply means that the quantity demanded of any product (Q) is a function of, i.e. is dependent
upon (), its own price (Po), the prices of other goods (Pa), disposable income (Yd), market size (N),
marketing effort (A), and customer taste (T).
Licensed to ABE
43
in quantity demanded brought about by a change in one or more of the other influences has to be
represented graphically by a shift in the whole demand curve.
Suppose there is an increase in disposable income which increases the quantity demanded at each
price within a given range. This effect can be shown as in Figure 3.1, where the price remains
constant at 0p but the increase in income has shifted the curve from DD to D1D1, so that the quantity
demanded at 0p rises from 0q to 0q1. A fall in income or a decline in taste, etc. would produce the
reverse result, i.e. a shift from D1D1 to DD.
Remember always to distinguish a movement along a demand curve produced by a change in price
(all other influences remaining unchanged) as shown in Figure 2.14 from a shift in the whole curve,
showing that demand has moved at all prices within the range under consideration.
Figure 3.1
Licensed to ABE
44
Figure 3.2
Now, in the Western world, shopping conditions are such that I cannot leave my belts unpriced and
hope to sort out from the people who visit my shop those willing to pay 5 and those willing to pay
4. If I want to sell more belts and am willing to charge 4, then I must charge this price to everyone.
If I continue to produce even more, I might then find that, to sell the increased quantity, I have to
charge 3. If I go on doing this, I am likely to find that my total revenue starts to fall.
Suppose I find that total revenue rises if I reduce the price from 5 to 4, but falls if I reduce the price
to 3. This will happen if the reduction from 4 to 3 does not produce enough additional sales to
Licensed to ABE
45
make good the loss suffered when I charge 3 to those people who would still have bought at prices
of 5 or 4. My sales schedule at the three prices might, perhaps, be as follows:
Price per belt
Total revenue
200
1,000
280
1,120
340
1,020
This effect can be shown in the form of a simple graph but this time the turning point can be seen
(Figure 3.3). If I try to reduce the price still further, below 3, I shall lose even more revenue.
Figure 3.3
Average Revenue
The term average here is used in its commonest sense that familiar to you, perhaps, in the form of
cricket average or goal average. It is the total revenue divided by the quantity of goods sold. If a
shops weekly revenue from selling broccoli is 600 and it sells 300 kilos in the week, the average
revenue of the broccoli sold is 2 per kilo.
If all goods are sold at the same price in the given time period as, say, with our leather belts then
the average revenue is the same as the price. The average revenue curve for the belts is shown in
Figure 3.4.
Licensed to ABE
46
Figure 3.4
Notice, in this case, that the average revenue curve is really just the same as the demand curve. This
will always be the case where all items sold in the time period are sold at the same price, i.e. where
there is no price discrimination between different customers.
Now, to return to our shopkeeper selling broccoli at 2 per kilo; let us suppose that he is selling every
kilo for 2 and that he finds he can sell as much broccoli as he can handle at that price. He does not
need to reduce his price to increase quantity sold from, say, 200 kilos per week to 300, to 400, and
again to 500 kilos. The average revenue curve in this case is still the same as the demand curve but it
reflects this increasing quantity sold at a constant price. This produces the horizontal line graph
shown in Figure 3.5.
Figure 3.5
Licensed to ABE
47
Marginal Revenue
If the firm is able to maintain a constant price as it increases output, then the additional amount it
receives for each extra unit sold is, of course, that units price. In this case, the price, which is the
same as average revenue, is also the same as the change in total revenue resulting from the sale of the
extra unit. The change in total revenue brought about by a small or unit change in the quantity flow
of sales is known as the marginal revenue.
Marginal revenue is not always the same as the price or average revenue. Remember the example of
the leather belts.
There, an increase in sales from 280 to 340 belts per month produced a fall in total revenue. For the
change in this output range, the marginal revenue must be negative. The reason is the same as for the
fall in total revenue in order to increase sales, the price had to be brought down and, in this case,
the revenue gained on the additional quantity sold was not enough to make good the revenue lost for
customers who would have been prepared to buy at the higher price.
A simple example will show how marginal revenue can change when price has to be reduced in order
to increase the quantity sold. Look at Table 3.1. There are some important features to note about this
table. The marginal revenue column has its figures placed mid-way between the rows. This
emphasises that the marginal revenue relates to the change from one output level to the next. On a
graph, the marginal revenue is also plotted mid-way between the output levels. This is shown in
Figure 3.6.
Licensed to ABE
48
Number of TV sets
sold per week
Total Revenue
600
600
Marginal Revenue
550
2
575
1,150
500
550
1,650
450
525
2,100
400
500
2,500
350
475
2,850
300
450
3,150
250
425
3,400
200
400
3,600
150
10
375
3,750
100
11
350
3,850
50
12
325
3,900
0
13
300
3,900
50
14
275
3,850
Table 3.1
Licensed to ABE
49
Figure 3.6
Look carefully at the price and marginal revenue columns. Notice that, as each additional TV set is
sold, the price (average revenue) falls 25. The fall in marginal revenue for each additional set is
exactly double this 50. In Figure 3.7, we see the marginal and the average revenue curves
together. Notice that, at each price level, the marginal revenue is exactly halfway between the price
axis and the average revenue. Although Figure 3.7 does not continue the average curve until it meets
the quantity axis, we can deduce where it would meet if continued in the same straight line. It would
meet the quantity axis at 25 TV sets twice the marginal revenue quantity when marginal revenue =
0, thus indicating that this supplier would be able to dispose of only 25 sets, even if he did not charge
any price at all.
The average revenue curve cannot, of course, pass below the quantity axis, as we do not expect
suppliers to pay customers to take their goods. The marginal revenue curve can, however, pass into
the negative area of the graph, and so indicate quantities where continued price reductions would
result in an actual fall in total revenue. We can see this clearly from Table 3.1. Marginal revenue
remains positive until 12 sets are sold. The increase from 12 to 13 sets does not change total revenue
at all, so marginal revenue here is zero. If we continue to reduce price and sell 14 sets, then total
revenue falls to 3,850 and marginal revenue indicates the loss as 50.
Licensed to ABE
50
Figure 3.7
The total revenue curve for this table is shown in Figure 3.8. Compare this with Figure 3.7 and see
how the marginal revenue relates to the total revenue at the various numbers of TV sets sold.
This example has illustrated an important rule. Whenever we have a linear average revenue curve,
i.e. where there is a constant relationship between price and quantity changes, resulting in a straightline graph, then the marginal revenue curve is also linear (a straight line) and always bisects (cuts
into two equal halves) the horizontal distance between the price/revenue axis and the average revenue
curve.
Licensed to ABE
51
Figure 3.8
Calculation
This can be denoted by the symbol Ed. It is the relationship between a proportional change in
quantity demanded and a proportional change in price, so that Ed = proportional change in quantity
demanded proportional change in price, or
Q DP
Q
P
where: P = price of the product
Q = quantity demanded of the product
Licensed to ABE
52
the value of Ed will also be negative. In some older text books this used to be ignored but the general
tendency today and the one you should follow is to keep strictly to using this negative sign. So:
!
When the calculation of price elasticity of demand produces a result which is more negative
than 1, i.e. when the proportional change in quantity is greater than the proportional change in
price, we say that demand is price elastic.
When the calculation of price elasticity of demand produces a result which is less negative than
1, i.e. when the proportional change in quantity is less than the proportional change in price,
we say that demand is price inelastic.
When the calculation of price elasticity of demand produces a figure of 1, i.e. when the
proportional change in quantity is equal to the proportional change in price, we say that
demand has unitary elasticity.
The demand for fish is likely to have a price elasticity of around 0.9, that for washing powder about
0.3, and that for eggs around 0.02. These demand elasticities are price inelastic but fish is clearly
much more price-sensitive than eggs. Notice that while the demand for washing powder is price
inelastic that for a particular brand of washing powder might well be price elastic say, around 1.3.
One important feature of price elasticity of demand is that it changes as price changes. Consider the
demand curve shown in Figure 3.9.
At point A, Ed = 1, so that here demand is neither elastic nor inelastic. Here, revenue remains the
same at both prices because the change in price produces exactly the same proportional change, i.e.
Q P
.
=
P
Q
At point B, however, Ed is more negative than 1, so that demand is price elastic, i.e.
Q P
.
>
P
Q
A reduction in price at B results in a more than proportional increase in quantity demanded, so that
there is an increase in total revenue. A firm in this position will increase revenue by reducing price
but lose revenue if it increases price.
At point C, the position is completely reversed and Ed is less negative than 1, so that demand is
price inelastic, i.e.
Q P
.
<
P
Q
A reduction in price here results in a less than proportional increase in quantity demanded, so that
there is a fall in total revenue. A firm in this position will lose revenue by reducing price but gain
revenue by increasing price.
Licensed to ABE
53
Figure 3.9
The point of greatest possible revenue on any linear demand curve is where price elasticity is at unity
(where Ed = 1).
Notice also that the calculations shown in this illustration are made around the mid-point of each
change. Calculations made in this way are called arc elasticity, and they are the correct way to
measure price elasticity, unless we are able to use the necessary mathematical techniques to calculate
point elasticity at a particular point on the demand curve. For all but very small changes, pointelasticity calculations will show different results depending on whether we assume a price rise or a
price fall, and this is confusing and inaccurate. You can test this for yourself if you compare the
calculation for a price rise from 9.50 to 10.50 with a price fall from 10.50 to 9.50.
Licensed to ABE
54
Licensed to ABE
55
goods may fall. In the 1950s, in Britain, demand for motor cycles fell as incomes rose and people
bought cars. As we saw earlier, such goods are known as inferior goods.
Notice that we are referring here to disposable income, i.e. the income left to the consumer after
compulsory deductions have been taken. The most important of these are income tax and National
Insurance contributions. We may also include contributions to pension schemes or to trade unions or
professional bodies, where membership is necessary for employment.
In recent years, some economists have argued that we should really be thinking in terms of
discretionary income. This is the income that is left after all the regular and largely essential
household payments have been made, over which the individual has very little control once a
particular pattern of life has been chosen. The further deductions which would, then, be made to
arrive at discretionary income would be such items as rent or mortgage interest, water rates, essential
fuel charges (gas and/or electricity) and possibly the cost of travelling to and from work. When these
items have all been allowed for, the amount of discretionary income, i.e. the income which people are
genuinely free to spend as they choose, is usually very small in relation to the original gross income.
A high price in relation to income. If a period of saving is required before purchase is possible,
or if consumers have to borrow money to obtain a product, then demand can increase only
when an income rise makes this possible.
If goods are preferred to inferior substitutes, then people may be ready to buy more of these
when income increases make this possible.
Association with a higher living standard than that currently enjoyed is likely to lead to rising
demand when incomes do rise.
In general, the more highly-priced durable goods (household machines, motor vehicles, etc.) and
services are more likely to be income elastic than the staple items of food and clothing. We do not
usually buy twice as much of these if we receive double our former income. On the other hand, our
spending on holidays may increase by far more than double. Increased spending on motor transport
is also associated with rising incomes. Although we have been considering income rises, very similar
comments apply to income reductions. Holidays and motor cars are often the first things to be
sacrificed in the face of a sudden drop in income.
Licensed to ABE
56
Licensed to ABE
57
Study Unit 4
Costs of Production
Contents
A.
58
58
Fixed Costs
58
Variable Costs
59
60
Marginal Costs
61
Long-run Costs
65
B.
Economic Costs
67
C.
68
External Costs
68
External Benefits
68
Economics of Externalities
68
69
70
Returns to Scale
70
Economies of Scale
70
Diseconomies of Scale
71
External Economies
72
73
Economies of Scale
73
Services
75
Recent Trends
75
D.
E.
Page
Licensed to ABE
58
Costs of Production
Fixed Costs
These are the costs of the fixed factors, i.e. those elements which are not being increased as
production or output is being raised. The total fixed costs for a given range of output can be
illustrated in the simple graph shown in Figure 4.1.
Figure 4.1
Examples of fixed costs include rent for land or buildings, the rental charge for telephone or telex,
rates, the salary of a manager, and the fee for a licence to make use of another companys patent. All
these costs can change, but the point is they do not change as production level changes. The cost has
to be met, whatever the level of output and sales.
Licensed to ABE
Costs of Production
59
The graph of average fixed costs, i.e. total fixed costs divided by the number of units of output
produced, is shown in Figure 4.2. This is based on the fixed costs of 10,000 assumed in Figure 4.1.
Notice the steep fall at the lower levels of output, and the much more gentle slope of the curve at
higher levels. Between 140 and 150 units of output per week, the fall in average fixed costs is only
from 71 to 67 (approximately).
Figure 4.2
Variable Costs
These are the costs of inputs which are increased as output increases. They include the costs of basic
materials, of some labour e.g. engineering machinists paid on piece rates (according to the
amount produced) petrol for delivery vehicles, and so on.
The behaviour of variable costs depends on the pattern of production returns. If production is rising
faster than the input of variable elements, then costs are increasing less than proportionally to the rise
in output. This is because each extra unit of input is adding more to production than it is to cost.
This is possible at the lower levels of production represented by 0a in Figure 4.3.
Licensed to ABE
60
Costs of Production
Figure 4.3
Later, costs are likely to rise in the same proportion as output this being the stage of constant
returns, shown between output levels 0a and 0b. Then, as we reach the level of diminishing returns,
costs rise faster (more steeply) than production. This is shown beyond level 0b.
Licensed to ABE
Costs of Production
61
This is the typical shape of the curve in the short run (remember, while fixed costs remain fixed).
Because it falls to a minimum point and then rises, it is often referred to as the U- shaped average
cost curve, although as you can see, a more accurate description is that of an L with its toe turned
upwards. Only if there are particularly severe increasing costs (diminishing returns) to scale, and
fixed costs are a very small proportion of total costs, will the second half of the U be at all steep,
and the efficient firm should never allow itself to reach this position.
The modern firm is more likely to have a high proportion of fixed to total costs, because of the swing
from labour to labour-saving machinery. This movement is described as production becoming more
and more capital-intensive. In this case, we can expect the average total cost curve increasingly to
resemble the average fixed cost curve.
Figure 4.4
Marginal Costs
You have already met marginal utility and marginal revenue the change in total utility or revenue as
output changes. You will not then be surprised to know what marginal cost is the change in total cost
as output changes. Once again, we relate this change to a single unit of output, so that, if we are
moving in steps of ten, as in our cost example so far, we shall have to divide any change from one
step to the next by ten.
Licensed to ABE
62
Costs of Production
Figure 4.5
Table 4.1 is a table of total (fixed plus variable) costs which correspond to our previous graphs. In
this table, further columns have been added to show the change in total cost between each output step
of ten units per week, and then division by ten to produce the marginal cost. Notice that the figures
of the marginal cost column have been placed mid-way between the figures of the other columns, to
emphasise that they relate to a change from one output level to the next.
On a graph, the marginal cost is plotted at the mid-points of the various output levels. You will see
that this has been done in Figure 4.6, which illustrates the marginal costs shown in Table 4.1.
Licensed to ABE
Costs of Production
Quantity
Total Cost
10,000
Marginal Cost
Changes in Total Cost
from One Quantity
(column 3 divided by 10)
Level to the Next
100
10
11,000
1,000
60
20
11,600
600
40
30
12,000
400
100
40
13,000
1,000
100
50
14,000
1,000
100
60
15,000
1,000
100
70
16,000
1,000
100
80
17,000
1,000
115
90
18,150
1,150
135
100
19,500
1,350
165
110
21,150
1,650
210
120
23,250
2,100
275
130
26,000
2,750
355
140
29,550
3,550
445
150
34,000
4,450
Licensed to ABE
63
64
Costs of Production
Figure 4.6
In Figure 4.7, the marginal cost graph has been combined with the average cost graph. Notice where
these two curves intersect.
The rising marginal cost curve cuts the average cost curve roughly at 110 units per week. This is the
output level which we have already noted as the lowest level of the average total cost curve. This
illustrates a rule that you must remember. The rising marginal cost curve always cuts the average cost
curve at its lowest point. If you think a little, you will see that it must do that. If the cost of the last
unit to be produced is less than the average up to that point, then the new average will be a little
lower. If the cost of the last unit is higher than the average up to that point, then the new average will
be a little higher.
Experiment with any simple figures and you will see that this always must be true. This is a
relationship that you must remember, and you must always show the correct intersection when you
draw graphical illustrations.
Licensed to ABE
Costs of Production
65
Figure 4.7
Long-run Costs
In the long run all factors of production may be increased, i.e. no costs are completely fixed. In
practice, of course, the factors which are fixed in the short run will be increased in definite stages
e.g. when a new factory is built, new technology introduced, etc. The graph of fixed costs in the long
run, therefore, appears as in Figure 4.8.
Licensed to ABE
66
Costs of Production
Costs
LONG-RUN
FIXED COSTS
Output
Figure 4.8
The effect of this on the average total cost curve in the long run is shown in Figure 4.9.
Figure 4.9
The flat part of the average cost curve is prolonged. The question, then, is whether this merely
stretches the average cost curve delaying the point of eventual diminishing returns and the rise of
the U shape or whether it can be continued indefinitely in order to prevent the U shape completely
and make the long-run average cost curve L-shaped.
The relationship between short- and long-run average cost curves is sometimes shown as in
Figure 4.10. This emphasises the fact that one reason for the increase in fixed factors and costs is to
overcome the effect of short-run diminishing returns.
Licensed to ABE
Costs of Production
67
Figure 4.10
B. ECONOMIC COSTS
We are now beginning to see production costs from a variety of angles.
!
Opportunity Costs
These were identified in Study Unit 1 and may be defined as the cost of using resources in one
activity measured in terms of the lost opportunity of using them to produce the best alternative
that had to be sacrificed.
Absolute Costs
These are the full costs of the factors used in the activity under consideration. They may be
measured in monetary terms but the real absolute cost is best measured by the actual quantity
of factors used, e.g. the amount of land or the numbers of people employed.
Private Costs
These are the costs actually paid by the producer to the owners or providers of the production
factors employed. They are the costs usually taken into account by the accountant and are
measured in monetary terms, since the accountant has to account for the use of whatever
finance has been entrusted to the production organisation. We have been looking at these costs
in this study unit and have also examined the important distinction between fixed and variable
costs.
External Costs
We will go on to look at these now.
Licensed to ABE
68
Costs of Production
External Costs
Not all the costs of factors used in the production process are paid by the producer as private costs.
Suppose, for example, that, during a dry summer, a farmer watered his crops with water pumped from
a canal, and as a result, the canal level fell and it could no longer be used by waterway travellers.
Unless the farmer paid compensation to the travellers, it is clear that they would be contributing to
the costs of the farmers production. Because these costs are being paid by people external to the
production process, they are called external costs.
We can think of many examples of such costs. Travellers who incur additional fuel and machinewear costs resulting from motorway delays, when these delays are caused by repairs needed to make
good damage brought about by very heavy lorries travelling at high speeds, are contributing to the
costs of transporting goods by these heavy lorries. If a proportion of the cost of road repairs is paid
from general taxation, then all taxpayers are contributing to the costs of road travel even those tax
payers who rarely travel at all.
Other examples of external costs include the poisoning of rivers by industrial waste, the pollution of
sea coasts by waste oil discharged by oil tankers, the sickness and early deaths of workers from
industrial diseases. The list is almost endless, and you can probably add to it from your own
observation. Some costs may even be borne by later generations. In the 20th century, the UK has had
to pay to make good much of the damage caused by 19th-century industry. The schoolchildren of
Aberfan who were killed when an old coal waste tip moved and smothered their school in 1966 paid a
bitter price for the coal produced by their forefathers.
External Benefits
In contrast, it is possible for people to receive benefits from production towards the cost of which
they have not contributed. These are external benefits. If a large firm builds modern roads or
provides other transport facilities which are then available for use by the general community, then
that community gains external benefits. If a business firm provides a good canteen and housing for
its workers and, by improving standards of housing and welfare, improves the health of workers and
their families, then this, too, is an external benefit. We are well aware of cases where firms cause
damage to the environment but there are also cases were firms improve the environment by
renovating property, creating sports grounds, or even parks. The power of a large successful business
firm to bring benefits to a community was well known to such industrialists as the Cadbury family in
Birmingham and the Rowntree family in York.
Economics of Externalities
It might be thought that economists would favour external benefits and dislike external costs but, in
fact, economic theory suggests that all externalities distort the use of resources, and that even external
benefits are probably better provided in other ways. The danger of external costs can easily be
recognised. If, for example, road users, especially heavy goods vehicle users, do not pay the full
costs of their road use but pass some of these on to the rest of the community, then the relative costs
of, say, transporting goods by road as opposed to by rail or water are distorted in favour of road.
Consequently, goods are carried by road transport at a higher cost to the community than it would
have paid if they had been carried, say, by rail. The community is not making the most efficient
possible use of its available resources, and its living standards are lower than they would otherwise
Licensed to ABE
Costs of Production
69
be because some production is being lost. Moreover, the problem tends to increase. If road transport
is artificially cheap, then goods are diverted to road from rail. Road services are overcrowded, and
there is pressure to devote more land to roads. Rail services are under-used. Agricultural and
residential land is lost to roads to carry traffic which could otherwise have been carried by substitute
services.
This is what we mean when we say that externalities distort the use of scarce economic resources.
Legislate to make actions considered undesirable illegal, and enforce the law. In a democracy
such laws must be acceptable to the community as a whole; care must be taken to ensure that
desirable benefits are not lost and that the cost of law enforcement is not out of proportion to
the costs avoided.
Legislate to ensure that producers behave in a socially acceptable way and follow practices
designed to avoid the undesirable external costs. Water and sewerage companies may be
required to achieve certain minimum standards. The costs of complying with the law thus
become private costs and part of the production cost which must be met by users of the goods
and services. All producers then become subject to the same requirements so that none can
gain a competitive advantage by not complying with the standards. If producers have to
compete with foreign imports the government will have to ensure that these imports are subject
to the same minimum standards.
Impose special taxes designed to make some products very expensive and so discourage their
use. There are several objections to this course of action. The government might start to rely
on the revenue from the taxes and so take care to keep them at a level where the products are
still bought and used; the taxes may well then cease to deter or reduce the external costs.
Alternatively the government might impose very high taxes with the result that there is
widespread tax evasion; the cost of collecting the tax and punishing evaders then rises to
impose additional burdens on the community.
Clearly it is more desirable to try and ensure that external costs are removed altogether than that they
should simply become private costs. Even if employers are forced to pay adequate compensation to
workers whose lungs are damaged by dusty manufacturing processes, the workers still suffer.
However, if manufacturers are required to have efficient dust extraction equipment, private costs are
increased but the health of the workers is improved. At the same time care must be taken to ensure
that external costs are not simply exported. For example, one way of dealing with dangerous gases
might be to ensure that they are expelled through very high chimneys, but unfortunately these may
simply redirect the gases to another country for that country to bear the cost.
There is no universal and simple method of dealing with externalities, but on the whole it does appear
that the market economies have been more successful in controlling and reducing undesirable
external costs associated with environmental pollution than have the old command economies. This
is probably because in the more open and consumer-orientated societies producers and government
Licensed to ABE
70
Costs of Production
have had to be willing to respond to pressures from the public when that public has been determined
to eliminate socially unacceptable practices.
Economies of Scale
Real scale economies, as defined above, should be distinguished from purely pecuniary or monetary
economies which do not represent a more efficient use of factors but which are the result of the
superior bargaining power of the large firm in the market. A large customer, for instance, can often
gain discounts greater than can be justified on the grounds of savings in delivery or distribution costs,
and workers in some large firms may be willing to accept a lower wage in return for what is believed
to be greater security of employment or the social prestige of working for a famous organisation.
Real economies the genuine efficiencies in the use of production factors resulting from growth in
the scale of activities can be identified in the following main areas.
(a)
Labour Economies
These result from greater opportunities for the division of labour which increase with the skills
of the work-force, save time and allow greater mechanisation. The automated assembly line in
modern motor-vehicle assembly is an extreme example of this.
(b)
Technical Economies
These result chiefly from the use of specialised capital equipment. Large firms are able to
make use of equipment that could not be fully employed by smaller operations, and large firms
are also able to support reserve machines to avoid disruption following breakdown. A small
firm, using three machines, adds one-third to its capital cost if it tries to add a further machine
to keep in reserve. A large firm employing 20 machines adds only one-twentieth if it decides to
do likewise.
(c)
Marketing Economies
Very great economies are available from large-scale advertising. A television-commercial film
using top stars is very expensive to make, but the cost per potential customer is very low if
essentially the same film can be shown in several different countries. Large firms can also
afford to keep very skilled marketing specialists fully employed.
Licensed to ABE
Costs of Production
(d)
71
Financial Economies
Large firms are able to obtain finance from markets that are denied to small firms, and
multinationals can raise money in many different countries. Nevertheless, although financial
economies still exist, we do have to recognise that finance markets have, in recent years,
become more responsive to the needs of smaller enterprises.
(e)
(f)
Managerial Economies
These arise from the employment of specialised managers and managerial techniques, although
many of these techniques have been developed in order to overcome the problems of managing
large organisations, so that many economists suggest that managerial economies of scale are
often exaggerated and difficult to achieve in practice.
Diseconomies of Scale
Diseconomies of scale are usually associated with the problems rising out of the management and
control of large organisations. Formal communication systems are necessary but are expensive to
maintain. Whereas the manager of a small organisation can see what is going on around him in the
course of his daily work, the manager of a large firm may have to establish an inspection system to
obtain equivalent information which is unlikely to be as reliable.
There can also be a loss of control over managers at the lower levels of the managerial pyramid.
These managers may then pursue their own private objectives e.g. building up the power of their
own department at the expense of efficiency and profitability.
Diseconomies of scale, then, are mostly managerial. If diseconomies just balance economies, i.e.
when a 10% increase in factor inputs produces the same (10%) increase in production output, the
long-run average cost curve will have the L shape of Figure 4.11. If economies of scale continue
roughly to balance diseconomies, this shape may be retained over a long period. If, however,
diseconomies start to rise substantially, then the long-run average cost will again start to rise.
Licensed to ABE
72
Costs of Production
Figure 4.11
Notice here the position of what is called the Minimum Efficient Size (or Scale) (MES), also
known as the Minimum Optimum Scale (MOS). Up to this output level there are significant gains
from internal economies of scale, and firms below the MES are at a cost disadvantage when
competing against those up to or beyond that size. However, beyond the MES, further cost savings
are not significant, and there is no cost advantage in further growth. On the other hand the shape of
the curve can change as firms learn how to overcome sources of inefficiency, in particular managerial
inefficiency, especially when new managerial skills and communication technology are introduced. It
is possible to control very large firms today in ways that would have been impossible half a century
ago. Jet travel and modern telecommunications, not to mention computers and microelectronics,
have transformed management techniques.
External Economies
The economies of scale listed earlier all apply to the individual firm and they are known as internal
economies of scale. There are other economies that are external to the firm and which arise when an
industry grows large or when business firms congregate in a particular area. External economies
usually arise from the development of specialised services available to many firms. For example, an
area containing numbers of small engineering companies may provide opportunities to support one or
more specialised toolmakers. Each engineering company can call on the specialist, without having to
carry the full cost of having its own specialised department. External economies help small firms to
survive in competition with larger organisations. However, if one or two companies become
dominant and they internalise these economies by setting up their own specialised departments which
Licensed to ABE
Costs of Production
73
they are large enough to keep fully employed, then the external economies may be lost to the smaller
firms, which can then no longer survive in the market.
Economies of Scale
A closer look at economies of scale shows that large firms are not always inevitable. If we assume
that the typical successful large company has an L-shaped cost curve, this can still cover a number of
different possibilities.
Figure 4.12 shows two possible long-run average cost curves. It shows that each reaches a point
where further cost reductions as output increases are very small. As noted in the previous section,
this point is known as the minimum efficient size: it is reached at 0b for industry B and 0a for
industry A. We would, therefore, expect firms in industry A to be rather larger than in industry B.
There is no further significant advantage for firms when they grow beyond these points.
This minimum efficient size, of course, must be related to the size of the market. If, for example,
industry B served a much larger market than industry A then we would expect many more firms
competing in B than in A. Some world markets have room only for a very few firms. Here, fixed
costs are very high and only very large organisations can consider entry.
Licensed to ABE
74
Costs of Production
Licensed to ABE
Costs of Production
75
specialised components. These activities are not really comparable and the MES for a component
manufacturer could be much smaller than for vehicle assembly. Nevertheless it is the giant
corporations which dominate the industry. If one of these fails, large numbers of the satellite firms
which supply goods and services to it are also likely to fail. If the dominant firms all prosper, the
satellites also flourish.
Services
Services generally tend to be smaller than manufacturing organisations, although there are, of course,
some very large service firms developing in activities such as the law, accounting and business
consultancy. On the other hand, these large firms tend to serve large-scale customers. A leading
international accountant is not really suited to do the books of the small corner shop. In any case,
the shop would not be able to pay the accountants fees. There will always, therefore, be small local
firms of accountants, solicitors and so on. If any of these meet problems they cannot handle
themselves, then they may be able to call on the specialist services of the giant.
As the service sector of the economy, including the rising leisure services, grows, so the scope for
small firms continues to increase and as already suggested, new technology based on the chip and the
microcomputer is enabling the small firm to achieve a level of administrative efficiency that would
have seemed impossible only a short while ago. A business-owner who can afford to spend around
two to three thousand pounds on a computer, software packages and a good printer can maintain
accounting and secretarial services with just one or two people, whereas the same standard of service
would have required an office of 15 or more people or a very expensive mainframe computer
complete with specialist programmer only a decade or so ago.
Traditionally, the small-firm sector has been seen as the seed-bed of enterprise and the nursery in
which tomorrows giants are reared. The microcomputer industry itself is an example. It was not the
giant computer monopolists that produced the microcomputer but brilliant electronics engineers
working on their own initiative. There will always be scope for the entrepreneurial genius.
Recent Trends
During the 1980s, small firms faced a more favourable financial climate. Small-scale enterprise
became fashionable and received government support through the Business Expansion and Small
Business Loans Guarantee Schemes. The Stock Exchange also sought to make it easier for smaller
companies to raise capital by developing the Unlisted Securities Market (USM) and, for a time, a
Third Market. The USM was closed in the mid-1990s and is to be replaced by an alternative
market which is intended to operate more effectively for smaller companies within the structure of
the Stock Exchange. You should look out for this development and watch its progress.
The environment for small businesses turned increasingly hostile as the boom years turned to
recession and, more recently, to the much deeper depression of the 1990s. Government antiinflationary policies based on high interest rates and attempts to link the value of sterling to the
German mark helped to destroy those firms, large and small, that had expanded over-ambitiously.
The government realised that providing guarantees for firms unable to obtain finance through normal
commercial channels was a sure way of squandering taxpayers money and abandoned earlier
experiments.
Any form of government intervention tends to distort markets. Even socially worthy schemes to
assist the unemployed can create as many problems as they solve. If, for example, an unemployed
person is given government financial help to start a new window-cleaning business in an area where
demand is roughly in equilibrium with supply from existing window cleaners, the entry of a new,
subsidised cleaner is likely to undermine and drive out of business one or more of the established
Licensed to ABE
76
Costs of Production
small firms which do not enjoy government financial help. The result may be that one person leaves
the dole queue and is replaced in it by two others.
The banks also became disillusioned with the small-firm sector and reversed the policies that were
proving to lead to heavy losses. There is still official encouragement for the creation of new small
firms, and the number of people entering self-employment always increases when unemployment
rises, as many people decide that the risks of starting in business are preferable to unemployment; but
no one any longer believes that small firms offer a serious solution to current economic problems.
In an economic depression, large as well as small firms suffer and many companies which had
developed into conglomerates of different, often unrelated, activities as a result of the mergers of the
1960s and 1970s rediscovered the virtues of specialisation and sold, closed or allowed managers to
buy out those enterprises which did not fit into the mainstream of their core activities. Many of
the management buy-outs were heavily dependent on bank finance and a high proportion have
become victims of the depression. Others have survived and prospered once released from the weight
of large company bureaucracy. In spite of the difficulties, there are still large numbers of small firms
and as the 1990s have shown that growth and size are no guarantee of security, fewer of these will
wish to grow too rapidly and become too dependent on borrowed funds.
In recent years earlier tendencies which resulted in large firms internalising specialised activities have
been reversed. Specialist departments which had proved difficult to keep fully employed have been
closed and in many cases the specialists have been helped to form their own businesses, supported
with contracts from their former employers. These newly independent firms are once again able to
provide their specialist services to large and small organisations.
New communications technology is leading to a revival of a very old form of enterprise what may
be seen as a collection of independent firms, all working under the overall guidance of a central,
largely marketing, organisation. Computer software production is often produced on this basis, with
self-employed programmers producing software to detailed requirements set by the central marketing
body.
Many small retailers have found it possible to survive as members of a larger voluntary chain made
up of retailers and wholesalers, e.g. Mace, Spar.
Franchising is another way in which independent traders work under a degree of central control.
These organisational structures all combine some of the advantages of large-scale operation with the
benefits of the small entrepreneur working for him/herself.
Although the life expectancy of the majority of small firms continues to be short, there are nearly
always people willing to fill the gaps left by the casualties. The small firm sector as such continues
to exist and the record of innovation and enterprise from small firms compares favourably with the
large corporations. A healthy and dynamic economy requires a diversity of firms of all sizes and
activities. Most large organisations have occasion to rely on the services of small firms: often they
use them to fulfil contracts which are too small for them to carry out profitably but which are
necessary to retain the goodwill of valued customers. Moreover the continued existence of smaller
rivals can often be a healthy reminder to large corporations that they are neither immortal nor
indispensable. The growth of own-brand labels developed by the large supermarket chains has
provided openings for many smaller manufacturers who could not otherwise have hoped to compete
with the established food corporations.
The flexibility and versatility of the modern market economy, then, depends on the existence of many
different sorts and sizes of organisation, and this diversity is essential to the maintenance of high
living standards and wide employment opportunities.
Licensed to ABE
77
Study Unit 5
Profit, Supply and Expenditure Taxes
Contents
A.
B.
C.
D.
E.
Page
78
78
78
Profit as a Surplus
79
80
Maximisation of Profit
80
Calculation
80
Profit Maximisation
85
Influences on Supply
87
87
Supply Curve
89
89
90
92
92
Calculation of Elasticity
92
93
96
97
97
Effect on Supply
98
Licensed to ABE
78
How do we quantify normal? The usual answer to this question is to suggest that it is the
minimum necessary to keep the entrepreneur in the market. However, this surely depends as
much on conditions in other possible markets as on the amount of profit available in the one
under scrutiny. Firms that have been operating in a particular market for a lengthy period, or
which operate in that market only, face greater costs of transfer to another market than
newcomers, especially those which already operate in many markets. Thus, the minimum
required to keep firm A in the market is unlikely to be the same amount as that sought by firm
B. As economics has become more and more precise, scientific and mathematical, fewer
people have been prepared to accept a concept as vague and unquantifiable as normal profit,
in this sense.
Who is the entrepreneur entitled to normal profit? The early economists who developed the
concept were accustomed to markets containing small, individually owned and controlled
firms, so that the entrepreneur who was the driving force behind the firm was usually
identifiable without much trouble.
Modern markets, on the other hand, are dominated by large, corporate organisations with clear,
bureaucratic, managerial structures. The success of this type of enterprise may lie as much in
Licensed to ABE
79
the ability of managers to reduce risks as to take them and, while individual managers may be
expected to show enterprise in their work, this is rarely rewarded directly with a proportionate
share in profits even if the profit attributable to the enterprise shown could be calculated.
The statistical profit of the organisation belongs legally to the ordinary shareholders, who are
specifically denied any right to share in management and who rarely have much detailed
knowledge of the activities of the organisation. When we further recognise that the large
public company, today, is likely to operate in many markets, in many countries, we have to
agree that all this is impossible to reconcile with the definition of normal profit.
If, however, it is accepted that there is such a thing as normal profit then this implies that there can be
abnormal profit. Some text books do, in fact, describe all profits above the normal as abnormal.
Others, clearly unhappy at the emotive implications of this term, use the less derogatory
supernormal. In either case, the impression is usually given that firms should not be permitted to
earn profits above normal.
Instead of either abnormal or supernormal, some writers have referred to what they call pure profit,
by which they appear to mean any surplus over and above all payments to factors including the
normal profit due to the entrepreneur.
Profit as a Surplus
If we see profit not as a factor payment but as a surplus remaining after the production factors have
been paid for, the question then arises as to who owns, or should own, this surplus.
To Marxist economists the answer is clear. Economic value is created by human labour, without
which there can be no economic activity. The berries growing wild on the bush belong to the picker,
whose labour of picking has turned them into food. Thus any surplus created by work belongs to
those who carry out the work. Profit, therefore, to the Marxist who does not recognise a separate
entrepreneur, belongs to the workers. However, the Marxist recognises that, in the modern capitalist
society where production is organised by the owners of capital and, in the Marxist view, for the
benefit of the owners of capital, profit is, in practice, allocated to the owners of capital.
If this view is accepted, profit, not interest, becomes the payment to the owners of capital. To the
Marxist, the fact that it is paid to the owners of capital rather than to the rightful owners, the
contributors of labour, is the result of the domination of capital over labour in the modern capitalist
society.
In support of this view it is possible to point to company law, which provides that a companys profit
belongs to the companys shareholders or, more precisely, to the contributors of the risk capital or
equity, the ordinary shareholders in American terminology, the common stock holders. There is
no legal requirement that the company should share its profits with the suppliers of labour
(employees) or with the suppliers of loan capital, who receive their agreed rate of interest.
Still largely accepting this concept of profit as a surplus other economists, some of whom belong to
what has been called the Austrian school, take a very different view of its economic function. They
see it as the driving force of the modern economy and the incentive which has been largely
instrumental in bringing about the enormous improvement in general living standards in the market
economies over the past two centuries. They see the striving for profit as the force that produces new
products, new production technology, new forms of business organisation and new uses for basic
resources. The profit that produces this economic energy and invites people of all kinds to take risks
with their own resources of money, time and futures, is not normal profit but the largest possible
profit that can be made in the circumstances within which business operates. There is no need to
distinguish between normal and abnormal profit. All profit is necessary to stimulate future economic
Licensed to ABE
80
activity and to provide the investment finance necessary to make the activity possible and raise the
level of technology.
Unlike Marxists, the economists who take this view do not see profit as being stolen from workers,
nor do they see any need for labour to be given only the lowest possible wage. Indeed for business
enterprise to succeed, goods and services have to be sold to workers whose incomes are well above
subsistence levels, who have disposable incomes and the freedom to choose how to spend these
incomes and who expect to have rising incomes. Workers therefore, benefit from profitable economic
activity by earning rising wages.
Profit is seen as a balancing item and a result of accounting conventions but should properly
be seen as a return to one or more of the production factors. For example, most of what
accountants show as the profit of the majority of small family firms would better be
described as the proprietors wage for his physical and mental effort and interest on his
personal savings invested in the business.
(b)
The second view sees profit as a reward to enterprise and innovation and a return for the
temporary monopoly achieved by being first in the field with a successful new commercial
idea.
(c)
The third sees profit as a reward for successful risk-taking and, although willingness to take
risks does not always (or often) bring compensating profits, it is usually the hope of earning
such profits that provides the spur to help business people overcome their natural inclination to
avoid risk.
(d)
The fourth view simply takes the third view further; profit is a positive incentive to coax out
the supply of risk-bearing capital. It is the high return sought by providers of what is often
known as venture capital.
(e)
The fifth view regards profit as a return to monopoly, whether natural or achieved by
artificial means. It is this association of abnormal profit with monopoly that has coloured so
much teaching about business profits and objectives.
(f)
The sixth view recognises the Marxist explanation of profit as surplus value which, for Marx,
is properly the reward of the labour that created the value but which, in a capitalist economy, is
appropriated by the owners of capital.
Clearly there is no simple or generally agreed explanation of the economic function of profit, though
most would agree that both profit and a spirit of enterprise are extremely important elements in
modern market economies.
B. MAXIMISATION OF PROFIT
Calculation
We can arrive at the amount of profit for any given level of output in at least two ways. We can
calculate total revenue and total cost and find the difference, or we can calculate the average revenue
and the average cost, find the difference and multiply this by the quantity sold.
Licensed to ABE
81
We shall first consider profit as the difference between total revenue and total cost. Suppose we
return to the example of the last study unit and assume that all units of the product are sold at a given
market price of 210 per unit. Costs remain as before. We can now show total revenue and cost
columns for each range of output up to 150 units per week as in Table 5.1.
Quantity
Total Cost
Total Revenue
(output level 210)
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
110
120
130
140
150
10,000
11,000
11,600
12,000
13,000
14,000
15,000
16,000
17,000
18,150
19,500
21,150
23,250
26,000
29,550
34,000
0
2,100
4,200
6,300
8,400
10,500
12,600
14,700
16,800
18,900
21,000
23,100
25,200
27,300
29,400
31,500
Table 5.1
From this table we can see that revenue exceeds total cost at output levels 90 to 130 units per week.
At all other output levels, total costs are greater than total revenue, so losses would be suffered.
The following table shows the profit at each output level.
Quantity
Profit
90
100
110
120
130
750
1,500
1,950
1,950
1,300
The position is illustrated in Figure 5.1, where the shaded area represents the profit produced when
total revenue is greater than total cost.
Licensed to ABE
82
Figure 5.1
The same position is shown by the average cost and price/average revenue curves of Figure 5.2. In
this case, however, the shaded area does not represent the total profit but the profit per unit of output.
Total profit would be given by multiplying the profit per unit by the number of units produced.
In this example, the firm is selling all units at a given price, so that the total revenue curve continues
to increase though this does not, of course, mean that it is possible to make a profit at output levels
above 130 or so units per week.
Licensed to ABE
83
Figure 5.2
We saw in an earlier study unit that the revenue position could be rather different where the firm had
to reduce price in order to increase output. Such a situation is illustrated in Figure 5.3. No figures
are shown here this is a general model and it shows that the firm can make profits at all output
levels between 0a and 0b.
These levels, where total revenue just equals total cost, are called the break-even output levels or
sometimes break-even points.
It is often more convenient, however, to show the average cost and revenue curves (see Figure 5.4).
If we assume that the firm is selling all units at any given output level at the same price, i.e. is not
discriminating between different customers over price, then the average revenue curve is also the
price/output curve, i.e. the demand curve. In this model, we can also see that the firm makes profits
between output levels 0a and 0b. This is the quantity range where average revenue is greater than
average cost.
Licensed to ABE
84
Figure 5.3
Figure 5.4
Licensed to ABE
85
Profit Maximisation
So far, we have seen the output levels where profits are made, but we have not yet identified the
output level where the largest possible (maximum) profit can be made. However, if we refer back to
our profit table, we see that there are two points where points are at their largest at output levels of
110 and 120 units per week. Here, total profit stays at 1,950. If the firm wants to make the largest
possible profit, it can choose either of these two levels. It is not unusual for profit to have a rather
flat top and stretch across two stages in this way. In other cases it can peak at a single stage.
Now look back at Table 4.1 in the last study unit, which showed marginal costs. Bearing in mind that
we assumed the firm to be selling at a constant price of 210, look at the marginal cost column. We
have explained that, when the firm can sell at a constant price at all levels of output, the price is also
the average and the marginal revenue. Thus, in this case, the firms marginal revenue is 210. If you
look down column 4, you will see that the marginal cost is 210 at the mid-point, representing the
change from output level 110 to 120 units per week. This is precisely the output range where profits
are at their highest level, i.e. 1,950.
This is no accident. It illustrates the general rule that profits are always maximised at the output
levels where marginal cost is equal to marginal revenue.
The general position is illustrated in Figures 5.5 and 5.6. Figure 5.5 shows the case where average
revenue = marginal revenue (constant price at all output levels) and Figure 5.6 shows the sloping
average revenue curve with the marginal revenue curve in the correct position, as we explained
before.
Figure 5.5
In both cases, the argument is the same. It does not matter whether the marginal revenue curve slopes
or not. If the firm produces at output level 0a, i.e. below the level where marginal cost = marginal
revenue, it would pay it to increase output because the revenue received for each additional unit is
greater than the cost of producing that unit. If the firm is producing at output level 0c, above the level
where marginal cost = marginal revenue, then it will pay it to reduce output because revenue lost for
each unit of output sacrificed is less than the cost of its production. Only at output level 0b, where
marginal cost = marginal revenue, will it pay the firm to stay at the same level. It cannot then
increase profit by any change in quantity produced. This is the level where profits are maximised.
Licensed to ABE
86
This is a most important rule which you should remember carefully, i.e. to maximise profits the firm
produces at the output level where marginal cost is equal to marginal revenue.
Figure 5.6
Licensed to ABE
87
C. INFLUENCES ON SUPPLY
Costs and Supply
If we accept that business firms exist to make profits, then we can recognise that there must be a close
link between costs, profits and the willingness of firms to produce the goods and services that
consumers wish to buy. After all, profit is the difference between revenue and costs, so that at any
given price the amount of profit will depend on production costs. If price remains constant and costs
rise, then profit falls and we can expect firms to be less willing to supply goods and services.
Similarly, if costs remain unchanged and price rises, then profits will rise and firms will wish to
supply more in order to secure the increased profit.
We thus have no difficulty in accepting the link between costs and the amount that firms are prepared
to supply at a given price or range of prices. If we accept the aim of profit maximisation, then we can
be a little more precise than this.
Suppose a firm is seeking to maximise profits and can sell all it can produce at the ruling market
price. Suppose, too, that this market price can change. What, then, will be the firms response?
Look at Figure 5.7. The profit-maximising firm will seek to produce at that output level where
marginal cost is equal to price, i.e. at quantity 0q at price 0p, at 0q1 at price 0p1, and 0q2 at price 0p2.
Figure 5.7
Thus, we can see that the firm will increase the quantity it is willing to supply as price increases
and, conversely, reduce quantity as price falls and that the actual change in quantity will be
governed by the marginal cost curve.
Licensed to ABE
88
Under conditions of perfect competition, therefore, the individual firms supply curve is its marginal
cost curve and, consequently, the market supply curve is derived from the sum of the marginal cost
curves of all the firms operating within the market.
This argument continues to hold good when we abandon the assumption of the firm accepting the
market price. If the firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve for its product, and hence a
downward-sloping marginal revenue curve, we still get the same increase in quantity following the
marginal cost curve if we again move the marginal revenue curve outwards, further from the point of
origin. This is shown in Figure 5.8.
Notice, however, that Figure 5.8 is drawn on the assumption that the average revenue curve is moving
outwards evenly and with its slope unchanged. There is no guarantee that this will ever happen in
practice. If the slope of the average revenue curve changes, then so too will the slope of the marginal
revenue curve, and there will no longer be the smooth increase in quantity suggested by Figure 5.8.
For this reason, we cannot say that, in imperfect markets, the market supply curve will represent the
sum of the marginal cost curves of the individual firms. Nevertheless, the general link between
supply and marginal costs remains, although it is unlikely to be as direct as in perfect competition.
Figure 5.8
Here again, a movement of the marginal revenue curve produces a shift in quantity supplied, in
accordance with the marginal cost curve.
You can, if you wish, add the average revenue curves to this graph, and thus show the prices
corresponding to the three quantity levels 0q, 0q1 and 0q2. Remember the relationship between
average and marginal revenue, and remember that price will be shown by the vertical line from any
given quantity level to the average revenue curve.
Licensed to ABE
89
Supply Curve
If we accept this view that firms will seek to increase the quantity supplied if price increases, and
reduce it if price falls, then we can produce a supply curve showing the amounts involved. A supply
curve can be for an individual firm in which case, assuming profit-maximising objectives, it will be
the marginal cost curve or for all firms supplying a particular product, where it will be made up of
the sum of the marginal cost curves of all the firms supplying the product.
However the supply curve is formed, we can accept that its general shape will be as in Figure 5.9.
This shows the general assumption that more will be supplied as the price rises all other influences
remaining the same.
Figure 5.9
Licensed to ABE
90
(b)
Changes in Taxes
If a tax, payable to the government, is charged at any stage of production or on the profits of
the business, then any change in the tax rate will affect the profits anticipated from supply, and
thus affect supply intentions. An increase in a production tax, such as value added tax, will
have the same effect as an increase in factor costs; it will tend to reduce the quantity that firms
are willing to supply at all prices in a given range.
(c)
Changes in Technology
By technology is meant the methods of combining factors and inputs in order to achieve
production. An improvement in technology, which allows a given level of production to be
achieved with fewer factor inputs or with a different combination of factors, so that the total
cost is lower, will tend to increase the quantity likely to be supplied at all prices within the
range. Some types of technology may be possible only if production is required on a large
scale. This can have a marked effect on supply. Thus, small-scale supply may be possible only
at much higher prices than large-scale supply, when the different technology becomes
worthwhile. The result may be to shift the whole supply curve when production reaches the
critical level required for the large-scale technology.
(d)
(e)
Licensed to ABE
91
Figure 5.10
A shift of this type may follow a change in one or more of the influences as described above.
Moreover, several influences may be operating, in different directions. For example, a tax increase
may be depressing supply intentions while an improvement in technology is raising them. The final
result depends on the relative strength of the influences. It is not easy to analyse these effects through
simple graphical models. This is why more advanced studies make rather more use of algebraic
models which can be easily handled by computers, and why you should begin to become familiar
with functional expressions such as the following.
Qs = (P, C, T, v, y, o )
where: Qs = quantity of a product supplied
P
= products price
= business taxes
= level of technology
Licensed to ABE
92
Es =
Q s P PQ s
=
Qs
P
Q s P
Notice that the value of Es is always positive (+). This is because the change of quantity is in the
same direction as the change in price.
Figure 5.11 shows an example of a simple supply-elasticity calculation.
Notice here that figures for both P and Q are obtained from the mid-point of the change in price and
quantity, so that the calculation is the same for both a rise and a fall in price. Notice also that the
result of this particular calculation is that Es = unity (1).
If you calculate values for Es at any other price level on this curve, you should obtain the same
results. The reason for this is explained in the next subsection.
Licensed to ABE
93
Figure 5.11
Licensed to ABE
94
Figure 5.12
From the diagram:
= 1 ,
so,
P
P
= tan and
= tan1
Q
Q
P
P
=
.
Q
Q
But, Es =
=
Q P Q P
Q
P
Q P
P Q
.
Q P
So,
P P
== 1
Q Q
and
Es = 1.
A supply curve which passes through the vertical (price) axis is elastic, and one which passes (or, if
extended, would pass) through the horizontal (quantity) axis is inelastic. This holds regardless of the
slope of the curve, and it applies to the whole curve when this is linear (forming a straight line).
These statements can be proved by the same method as in Figure 5.12. Dont worry if you cant
prove them yourself just remember the position. Examples are given in Figures 5.13 and 5.14.
Licensed to ABE
Figure 5.13
Figure 5.14
Licensed to ABE
95
96
Figure 5.15
When the curve is non-linear, the important point is the direction of the tangent to the curve at the
price level under consideration. This is shown in Figure 5.15.
Licensed to ABE
97
possible. Even the motor-assembly track can be speeded up or slowed down, in response to a
managerial decision, in a matter of hours.
The change in elasticity over time is illustrated in Figure 5.16.
Figure 5.16
An indirect tax is one that is not levied directly on individuals or organisations but is applied
at some stage in the production or distribution of goods or services. It therefore affects prices
and so is paid indirectly, through price, by consumers and income-earners. For this reason
indirect taxes are often referred to as expenditure taxes and are listed as such in the British
national accounts which appear in the annual publication known as The Blue Book of National
Income and Expenditure.
Direct taxes are those levied directly on income or wealth as it is created and are paid by the
income- or wealth-earner to the government. The economic implications of direct taxes are
considered later in the course.
At this stage, however, it should be clear to you that anything that influences market price will have
consequences for both supply and demand, with the result that the final consequences of a tax may
not be what the government intended.
Sometimes, of course, the tax may be imposed with the deliberate intention of influencing supply or
demand, but more often it is levied as just another way to raise the revenue that governments imagine
they need, and they seek to have as little effect as possible on the production system. In practice, any
tax must have an impact, as we shall see.
Licensed to ABE
98
Effect on Supply
The effect on supply of an indirect tax being imposed is illustrated in Figure 5.17. This shows a
supply curve SS, indicating that production can range from 200 units per week at a price of 4 to 800
units at a price of 10.
Suppose a new tax is imposed at 1 per unit. To supply 500 units per week, producers wanted a price
of 7 per unit. After the imposition of the tax, the producers still want to receive 7, but to get this,
the price has to rise to 8 to include the 1 per unit that now has to be paid to the government.
Similarly, to keep production at 700 units per week, the price has to rise from 9 to 10 per unit.
Imposition of the tax thus moves the supply curve to the left (SS to S1S1). The vertical distance
between the curves represents the amount of the tax.
Figure 5.17
Of course, a subsidy paid to the producer moves the supply curve to the right because the argument is
exactly reversed.
In Figure 5.17 the after-tax supply curve S1S1 is parallel to the before-tax curve of SS. This suggests
that the tax or tax increase if flat rate, i.e. the same at all price levels. In practice indirect taxes
such as VAT depend on value and are sometimes known as ad valorem taxes. Usually we would
expect the tax to be expressed as a percentage of value or price, and its amount will therefore increase
Licensed to ABE
99
as price rises. In such cases the gap between the two supply curves will increase at the higher prices
as illustrated in Figure 5.18.
Although suppliers will be seeking to recover the full amount of any additional expenditure tax from
buyers there is no guarantee they will succeed in raising the price sufficiently to achieve this. The
extent to which they can recover the tax or have to absorb it in their total costs through the more
efficient use of their production resources depends largely on the strength of any price resistance
shown by buyers. If buyers cease to buy the product at the increased price suppliers must reconsider
their position. The possible consequences of this interaction between suppliers and buyers are
examined in Study Unit 6.
Figure 5.18
The effect on suppliers intentions of an increase in an expenditure tax of 20%.
Licensed to ABE
100
Licensed to ABE
101
Study Unit 6
Markets and Prices
Contents
A.
B.
C.
D.
E.
F.
Page
Nature of Markets
102
102
Market Area
102
102
103
Functions of Markets
103
Information
103
Establishing Price
103
104
104
Equilibrium Price
104
105
Price Regulation
108
Reasons
108
109
110
110
111
113
113
Subsidies
114
115
Licensed to ABE
102
A. NATURE OF MARKETS
In economics, a market is an area within which the forces of demand and supply for a particular
economic good can communicate and interact, so that the good can be transferred from suppliers to
buyers.
This definition contains a number of important elements which have to be considered whenever we
analyse a particular market or compare one market with another. Let us look at these elements.
Market Area
We need to examine the market area when considering the conditions of a particular market. The
area is that within which communication takes place, and not simply where final negotiation is
arranged. A sale of antiques or fine paintings may take place in a small room in London but,
beforehand, catalogues may have been sent to dealers throughout the world, and many foreign buyers
may be represented by their agents when the sale or auction actually takes place. In contrast, a small
retail shop may be concerned with a market area restricted to a few streets or a single housing estate.
The goods it sells may be available in other shops serving different market areas nearby.
Licensed to ABE
103
Some markets have developed very precise descriptive terms. The use of these terms, for example, in
some of the basic commodity exchanges, enables buyers and sellers to know exactly what quality
goods are being traded.
There can be an effective market only if it is possible to transfer the product from seller to buyer.
Any barrier to transfer will limit the market area.
B. FUNCTIONS OF MARKETS
A market has other purposes, apart from providing the means whereby a good is transferred from
supplier to buyer.
Information
The market serves to convey information about the conditions of supply and demand. I may go to a
furniture store, not just to buy a piece of furniture but to see what furniture is available and at what
price. The better the communication system within the market, the more information I can gain about
what can be bought and the more chance I have of achieving full utility from my purchase.
This communication function works both ways. The market also informs actual and potential
suppliers about the strength and pattern of demand about what people want to acquire and what
level of price they are prepared to pay. Suppliers need this information in order to plan production.
The problem from the suppliers point of view is often that the information comes too late. He has to
make supply decisions before accurate information is available. The supplier wants to know today
what market conditions are going to be like tomorrow. The impossibility of achieving accurate
forecasts all the time is one of the main sources of business risk.
Establishing Price
Arising out of the two-way communication function is a further most important function that of
establishing the price at which the buyer is willing to buy and the supplier willing to supply. How
this may be achieved is the subject of much of the rest of this study unit.
It is such an important function of the market that some large firms ensure that certain markets
continue to operate only because they need a reliable mechanism for price-setting. The large
manufacturing companies do not really need to buy metal on the London Metal Exchange they can
obtain all they need direct from suppliers. But they do need to know the conditions of demand and
supply in the main areas where metal is bought and sold. By keeping the metal exchange in
Licensed to ABE
104
operation, they obtain this information, which provides a price-setting mechanism and so helps to
reduce some of the uncertainties which they have to face in obtaining essential materials.
Equilibrium Price
The equilibrium price is the one at which the intentions of suppliers are just matched by the
intentions of buyers, i.e. where the amount of the good demanded is just equal to the amount
provided. In this state there is no pressure from either supply or demand to move away from this
price, so the market forces are in a state of rest in equilibrium.
We have examined the concepts of supply and demand schedules and curves. If we put supply and
demand schedules and curves together, we can arrive at the equilibrium price, i.e. the market price.
Suppose we have the supply and demand schedules for the product Whizzo as set out in Table 6.1
and illustrated in Figure 6.1.
Price per kilo
1.50
2.00
2.50
3.00
3.50
4.00
4.50
5.00
200
300
400
500
600
700
800
900
700
675
650
625
600
575
550
525
Licensed to ABE
105
Figure 6.1
We can see from the schedules and the graph that it is only at price 3.50 (600 kilos per week) that
the intentions of producers and buyers are the same. At any higher price, producers will be supplying
more than buyers are willing to buy. At any lower price, producers will not be supplying enough
Whizzo to meet demand. 3.50 is the equilibrium price, and 600 kilos per week the equilibrium
quantity. As long as neither set of intentions changes, there is no incentive for any movement away
from this price and quantity, once it is achieved.
Licensed to ABE
106
Price
D
S
O
Quantity
Figure 6.2
(a)
D
P1
P
D1
S
D
O
q1
Quantity
Figure 6.3
Licensed to ABE
107
Price
S1
S
P1
P
S1
D
S
O
q1
Quantity
Figure 6.4
(b)
Licensed to ABE
108
Price
D1
S
D
P1
St+1
P
Pt+1
D1
S
St+1
D
q1
qt+1
Quantity
Figure 6.5
Normally, we expect an increase in demand to raise equilibrium price and quantity. This is the direct
effect. The later reduction in price can result only from a shift in the supply curve, indicating a
completely new set of supply conditions.
A somewhat similar process can be initiated by a change in technology allowing mass production at a
reduced price. Here, there is first a shift outwards in the supply curve. Demand then rises, but not
enough to stop the price from falling. Consider the market for pocket calculators in this light.
D. PRICE REGULATION
Reasons
If price and quantity will always move to an equilibrium provided economic markets are left alone,
we must ask why governments and other agencies should ever wish to intervene. In practice, there
are several reasons, of which the following are among the most common:
(a)
Social Unacceptability
If the price resulting from an unregulated market were considered to be socially unacceptable,
as causing hardship or conflict in the community, attempts might be made to control it. This
could happen in a period of food shortage caused by war and/or climatic disaster, and also if
there were a shortage of housing in urban areas sufficient to cause hardship and increase risks
of disease, crime and other social evils.
(b)
Incomes of Producers
Attempts might be made to maintain high prices if it were desired to raise the income of
producers and their employees. This is one of the motives of the European Unions Common
Agricultural Policy (CAP).
Licensed to ABE
(c)
109
Stability of Supply
Some markets are notoriously unstable because of unplanned variations in supply, caused by
weather and other circumstances beyond the control of producers. In these cases, attempts may
be made to control prices to ensure greater stability in the market.
Figure 6.6
Looking at the diagram, if price is fixed at p1, quantity supplied (qs1) is more than that demanded
(qd1), and there is surplus production.
If price is fixed at p2, quantity demanded (qd2) is more than that supplied (qs2), and there is a
shortage.
Only at price p will quantity supplied = quantity demanded.
Here, we see that any attempt to fix prices at a level other than the market equilibrium price of p will
produce either surplus production (fixed price p1 > p) or a shortage (fixed price p2 < p).
Licensed to ABE
110
We are forced to the conclusion that, on their own, price controls are ineffective. Governments and
other bodies must identify the real problem and seek to solve that. For example, if the problem is
lack of adequate supply (food or housing shortage), then the government must either increase supply,
e.g. by making additional payments, called subsidies, to suppliers, or by entering the market as
producers or importers, or, if these remedies are impossible, it must ration the available supply among
consumers in a way that the community regards as acceptable.
Such measures may be effective, at least for a time, though they may be expensive to administer and
police. The government, or other body, must decide whether the social benefits to be gained from
market regulation justify the cost and opportunity costs of the resources used in maintaining the
regulations. Care must also be taken to ensure that the regulations themselves do not discourage
suppliers to the extent that the basic objects of the policies are defeated. The heavy bureaucracy
created by many schemes in the so-called planned or socialist economies often significantly
discourages total production. If the problem is excess supply, then the government may seek either to
stimulate demand, e.g. by reducing prices through the payment of subsidies, or to reduce supply by
encouraging or paying producers to leave the market, as in the case of European Union measures to
reduce European milk and wine supplies.
The most difficult problems often involve unplanned fluctuations of supply, when the plans of
regulatory bodies can be upset by unusually good or bad crops owing to the weather. If there are
fairly regular cycles of over- and under-production, and demand is reasonably constant, and if it is
possible to store the crops, then the government can apply a mixture of controls over prices and
production combined with purchases of over-production to keep in store for release in periods of
under-production. However, it is found that the guaranteed prices that usually form part of such
policies lead inevitably to steady increases in production, so that the government finds itself storing
quantities of goods that it has little hope of ever releasing for resale, except at very low prices to
people in other parts of the world. It may even have to give away some of the surplus produce. Such
policies then become a heavy burden on taxpayers and lead to hostility from the community.
It is clear that governments which embark on market-intervention policies may, and often do, find that
they become involved in increasingly difficult and expensive measures that do very little to solve the
problems they were meant to eliminate.
Inequalities of Income
One of the virtues claimed for the unregulated market is that it makes the consumer sovereign
and that resource allocation responds to demand pressures. However, if we imagine that
consumers influence allocation by votes cast when they buy or refrain from buying goods and
services, we have to admit that some consumers have more votes than others and large numbers
have very few votes. Markets respond quickly to those groups which have the most purchasing
Licensed to ABE
111
power. This does not always ensure that resources are allocated in ways that meet the social
expectations of the community.
It has always been difficult to ensure that the poorest sections of the community are adequately
housed. Normal commercial suppliers of housing are unwilling to meet this demand because
the people concerned cannot afford to pay the full economic costs of housing, i.e. it is not
usually possible to make a profit from providing housing for the poor. It is much more
profitable to provide second homes for the wealthy. Not only does this offend against many
peoples ideas of social justice, but the housing problem rebounds against the community, for
which it causes extra costs because inadequate housing leads to poor health, disease, crime and
a wide range of social problems that become a charge on the taxpayers. Only the State can
intervene to improve housing for the poor. It cannot do so simply by holding down rents. It
has to promote supply either by setting up State suppliers or by subsidising private suppliers so
that supply becomes profitable.
(b)
(c)
Licensed to ABE
112
(a)
Education
Most would accept the need for all to receive a basic education, but this does not necessarily
mean that all who wish to do so should have the right to free education to doctorate level.
Since there is evidence that, on average (but not, of course, for all individuals) there is a
correlation between income level and length of time spent in full-time education, then
education beyond the minimum represents a personal capital investment and many would argue
that such education should be paid for by those who will benefit from it. Counter arguments
are that the community benefits from the contribution of its most highly skilled and educated
members (e.g. brain surgeons) and should, therefore, pay to obtain the maximum potential from
its scarce human resources, and also that those who earn high incomes normally pay the most
taxes and thus pay eventually for the education they received. There is no clear right or wrong
answer to this debate but you can see that the precise boundaries between the public and
private sector in the supply of goods such as education are not clear-cut and the matter is
arguable.
(b)
Health Care
Another area of public controversy is the provision of health care. The community clearly
needs a health service if only to defend itself against dangerous diseases which could quickly
become plagues if large numbers of people could not afford treatment. Most peoples ideas of
social justice would accept that a person stricken by accident or sickness should receive
treatment regardless of income. However, should this mean that all forms of treatment should
be available for all regardless of income? Should the diseases of greed and over-indulgence be
given the same care as those of poverty and ignorance? If people can afford to pay for
additional treatment or for more comfortable treatment, or non-urgent treatment at times that
suit them rather than at times that suit a bureaucratic administration, is there any reason why
they should not do so? No one passes moral judgment on those who choose to spend their
income on exotic holidays rather than a fortnight at Benidorm, yet many pass such judgment on
those who prefer to pay for a private room when they are in hospital instead of sharing a public
ward.
Clearly many of the arguments surrounding health care involve emotionally charged value
judgments resulting from past social injustices and history, but there are also serious economic
considerations involved. The economist is concerned with the allocation of scarce resources
and we have to recognise that resources devoted to health care are scarce. The march of
technology and medical science has made possible cures and treatments unimaginable when
the National Health Service commenced in the 1940s. Open heart and transplant surgery
require a massive investment in resources but benefit only a relatively few people. The
proportion of old people is far greater than in the 1940s and the demands they make for health
care are proportionally much greater also. Not even the most wealthy and advanced nation can
provide all the resources that would be required to give immediate treatment to all those
wanting it. Difficult allocation decisions have to be made and are made daily.
On the other hand it can be argued that a private health system which permits scarce resources
to be allocated on the basis of ability to pay, or by virtue of employment in a company that
provides health insurance as part of its remuneration, is diverting resources from areas of
greater personal or social need. One person suffers pain so that a consultant can earn a private
income treating a less urgent patient in a private hospital. On the other hand it can be argued
that the private health service brings in resources that would otherwise not be available. The
consultant is willing to work for a relatively low level of pay from the National Health Service
because he or she can have the additional income from private patients. Without this, the best
Licensed to ABE
113
surgeons would possibly go to countries where earnings were higher. Private hospitals relieve
the public health service of many patients and reduce its need for expensive capital equipment.
The debate can again continue with no clear right or wrong.
The basic problem is really one of allocation of scarce resources and the public versus private
health service is only part of a much larger economic and social issue which concerns to whom,
how and on what basis resources should be allocated for health care. How should the
community decide what proportion of available scarce resources should be devoted to the
technically brilliant feats of surgery which bring acclaim to surgeons and enable them to attend
conferences in exotic countries and how much to the unglamorous, humdrum work of caring
for the mentally ill for whom there is no hope of cure and little chance of international laurels
for the carer? The unregulated market will not provide an answer, nor will a medical service
subject to all the usual human vanities and frailties. The answer must eventually come through
the political machinery of the community and the quality of the answer will reflect the health
of that machinery.
Similar issues can be applied to virtually every other public sector and public utility service and you
should give some thought to the allocation problems inherent in, say, police, fire, water, and housing
services.
Figure 6.7
F.
Licensed to ABE
114
Look now at Figure 6.7. Here we show the movement of the supply curve from SS to S1S1 (resulting
from the increase in tax) and the demand curve DeDe. The equilibrium price moves up (from Op to
Op1) but by an amount less than the increase in tax. The amount supplied to the market falls from Oq
to Oq1 and the output/quantity fall is greater than the price rise.
Figure 6.8
Now look at Figure 6.8. Here we have the shift in supply curve SS to S1S1 and a demand curve D1D1.
Again we have an increase in equilibrium price (Op to Op1) and a reduction in quantity supplied (Oq
to Oq1). This time, however, the reduction in quantity is less than the increase in price.
Why the difference in the two situations? You will have noticed that the curve D1D1 is much steeper
than DeDe. This reflects the fact that demand in Figure 6.7 is more price elastic than demand in
Figure 6.8. The two illustrations show that the more price elastic the demand for a product is, the
smaller will be the market-price increase following an increase in indirect tax, and the greater will be
the cutback in supply to the market.
This, after all, is really common sense. Price elasticity indicates the degree of responsiveness of
quantity demanded to any change in price.
Subsidies
The effect of a subsidy will be the exact reverse of that of the tax. Instead of the movement of the
supply curve from SS to S1S1 there is an increase in supply at all prices, i.e. as from S1S1 to SS, and
there will be a reduction in market price, as from Op1 to Op. Such a reduction is likely to have been
the main government objective in arranging the subsidy, particularly if the good is a socially
worthy one such as a basic food in a time of shortage, housing, or a service such as education or
health care.
Licensed to ABE
115
Remember also that the new supply curve need not be exactly parallel to the original before the tax or
subsidy change. If the tax, or subsidy increases with value, i.e. is an ad valorem tax or subsidy, the
gap between the curves will increase as price rises, as illustrated in Figure 5.17.
Licensed to ABE
116
Licensed to ABE
117
Study Unit 7
Market Structures and Competition
Contents
A.
118
B.
Perfect Competition
119
Definition
119
119
121
124
124
Monopoly
125
Definition
125
Sources of Monopoly
125
126
Comment
127
Monopolistic Competition
128
Main Features
128
General Model
129
Comment
130
Oligopoly
131
Price Competition
131
Price Stickiness
131
131
133
Price Leadership
134
135
C.
D.
E.
F.
Page
Licensed to ABE
118
Five or six television channels or stations all offering similar styles of soap serials at the
same peak viewing times, with the result that viewers can choose between stations but not
between types of entertainment.
Four or five multiple stores all offering similar styles and sizes of childrens clothes, with little
to offer buyers wanting different styles or the less common sizes.
Rival buses, some nearly empty, jockeying for custom in the streets of populous cities but little
or no transport to outlying rural areas.
Twelve or more insurance offices all offering cut-price insurance but with policies containing
conditions that are likely to allow the companies to avoid meeting claims for losses that policy
holders thought had been fully covered.
These examples and you can probably think of others suggest that competition can lead to less
genuine choice for consumers or can lead to a reduction in the quality of services provided. This
quality reduction can be very damaging in the financial services sector: competitive banking does not
appear to have improved relationships between the major banks and their customers.
Licensed to ABE
119
We must, therefore, be careful in our assessment of the benefits of competition and be prepared to be
critical when examining some of the traditional economic models of competitive markets. These
models have been developed in the belief that the degree of competition in a market is likely to
influence the behaviour and performance of firms operating in it. In this study unit we look at some
of the best known models, and these provide an essential starting point for understanding the often
complex markets existing in modern economies.
B. PERFECT COMPETITION
Definition
Our first theoretical model covers the situation where the economic market operates in its purest or
most perfect form. Perfect competition is the state of affairs existing in a market totally free from
imperfections in the communication and interaction of the economic forces of supply and demand.
Some writers like to make a distinction between perfect or ideal markets and perfect competition, in
addition to the distinction between the market as an area and competition as a condition found in that
area. They suggest that the conditions for perfect competition are satisfied when the individual firm
is a price-taker, i.e. when it can sell all that it can produce at the market price, which by itself it
cannot alter, and when buyers are indifferent as to which sellers product they buy at that price. Such
a very limited set of requirements would be satisfied when firms in an industry were subject to a
regulated price set by a government or some other regulatory body which had powers to buy goods
unsaleable in the market. This would certainly not be a perfect market.
For true perfect competition to exist, it seems more realistic to stipulate that sellers must be free to
enter and leave the market, so that total supply can change and bring about the equilibrium position.
Just to establish a market price through some form of price regulation would not produce the same
result, unless the regulating body is very sensitive to demand shifts, and production plans can be
adapted quickly.
It seems, then, that full operation of perfect competition can be achieved only in a perfect economic
market, and to put too much emphasis on differences between the two does not really help very much
in our analysis of the main market forces.
Licensed to ABE
120
(b)
(c)
(d)
(e)
Licensed to ABE
121
Figure 7.1
Licensed to ABE
122
Price
S1
S
P1
P
D
S1
S
O
qm1
Output
qm
Figure 7.2
The market equilibrium price then rises assuming that demand remains unchanged. Supposing the
equilibrium price moves up from Op to Op1, this produces the situation for the individual firm
illustrated by Figure 7.3.
Figure 7.3
Now we see that the average revenue at Op1 is higher than average cost at Oc, and the firm is
enjoying profits, represented by the shaded area. Notice that, once again, the most profitable output
to aim at is at Oq, where marginal cost is just equal to marginal revenue.
Licensed to ABE
123
Now, given our earlier assumptions, all firms are making profits. If we have defined cost to include a
normal return to all production factors (including some return to enterprise in the form of a minimum
profit to keep firms in the market and provide necessary capital investment) then this shaded area
profit is an additional or abnormal profit, resulting only from the special market opportunities.
Owing to perfect communication and free entry, new firms will enter the market to take advantage of
these profits. Supply will now increase the supply curve will move to the right and equilibrium
price will fall.
Suppose it falls to a position between Op and Op1, say to Ope where price/average revenue is just
equal to average cost. Now the individual firm is in the position illustrated in Figure 7.4. Here, there
is neither abnormal profit nor loss. We assume that the firms costs include an element of normal
profit, which can be defined as a fair return to the firms enterprise, or sometimes as that amount of
profit which is sufficient to keep firms operating in that market. This normal profit is included,
therefore, in the average cost curve. There is no incentive for firms to move into or out of the market;
there is no reason why supply should shift and, as long as demand remains unchanged, there is no
reason for any movement in this equilibrium balance.
Figure 7.4
It is on the basis of this kind of argument that textbooks and examiners sometimes make much of the
distinction between short-run equilibrium in perfect competition where abnormal profits or losses
can be experienced, and long-run equilibrium where only normal profits (included in the average
total cost curve) are possible. However, we should stress that these are really only partial equilibrium
positions relating to supply alone. The model says nothing about influences on demand which is
often far from stable. A shift in demand will be quickly reflected in a shift in supply to readjust
output to the new market price. Consequently, in markets where demand is inherently unstable as
in the Stock and Commodity Exchanges long-run equilibrium may never be reached as suppliers are
constantly adapting to the shifting market environment.
Licensed to ABE
124
(b)
Efficient use of resources. Notice that, in equilibrium, the bringing together of price and
marginal cost and the elimination of abnormal profit means that producers will produce when
the average cost curve is at its lowest point (where marginal cost equals average cost). There is
then a tendency to encourage producers to reduce average costs as much as possible. This is
equivalent to making the most efficient use of resources.
(c)
Price is equal to marginal cost. Price is the money value of the utility gained by the last or
marginal consumer, i.e. marginal utility. When marginal cost = marginal utility, as in perfect
competition, the cost of producing the last unit is just equal to the value of the utility given by
that unit to its consumer. If this were true in all cases, then the total cost of production would
equal the total value of utility received. This would be the best possible use of all resources, it
is suggested.
Not everyone accepts these arguments, and you should read this section in conjunction with the
discussion of monopoly, later.
One of the arguments against perfect competition is that it prevents producers from making the profit
necessary to provide funds for investment and research, to find better ways of producing goods.
Another argument is that competition can be wasteful, as resources are doing the same things. If
there were fewer competing firms, total costs could be reduced and some resources freed to produce
something else.
Firms dislike perfect competition because, as indicated earlier, prices are unstable. If
communications are good, then supply can adapt very quickly to price changes caused by changes in
demand. The result is that prices are constantly adapting to new equilibrium positions as with the
Stock Exchange, which is still the common textbook example of a market which is close to perfect
competition. In the Stock Exchange, prices change daily, and even hourly.
Manufacturers cannot tolerate swiftly-moving prices like this they could survive in such a market
only if they could keep changing the prices paid for production factors, including the wages paid to
workers. Trade unions have sought to achieve stable jobs and, preferably, rising wages. Producers
then want stable and, preferably, rising prices. Those economists who argue for perfect
competition in the consumer interest, and then for stable wages and secure employment, are being
illogical. These two conditions cannot exist together.
Perfect competition may or may not, therefore, be ideal from a purely economic viewpoint. It is
certainly far from ideal from a social standpoint.
Licensed to ABE
125
C. MONOPOLY
Definition
Monopoly is the opposite extreme to perfect competition. It exists when there is only one supplier
for a particular product and there are no close substitutes for that product.
Again, we have to be careful how we define the product. For example, The Post Office has a
monopoly in the delivery of low-price letter mail in Britain; but it does not have a monopoly in
personal and business communication, and in recent years the volume of letter mail has declined in
the face of competition from the telephone and the fax and from private firms of leaflet distributors.
In the future it is likely to face more competition from E-mail and services using the so-called
information super highway. Historically almost all monopolies are subject to destruction by the
onward march of technology.
Sources of Monopoly
Monopoly can arise in three ways: by operation of the law, by possession of a unique feature, or by
the achievement of market control.
(a)
Operation of Law
This is a very old source of monopoly power. Kings used to sell monopolies in Europe to raise
money, i.e. they sold people the right to be sole suppliers of a necessary product, such as salt,
in a given area. The monopolist could rely on the support of the Kings officers to protect his
monopoly and the profits he could make more than covered the fee he had to pay for his
position.
Today, some countries may grant a company the right to be sole supplier of a product or service
(e.g. telephones) in return for some measure of State inspection and control over profits and
prices. In Britain, before 1979, it was usual for such monopolies to be public corporations
under public ownership and control. This has been changed by the privatisation programme,
which has resulted in a policy of separating regulation from operation. Some important public
utilities, e.g. British Telecom and British Gas, are now legally companies in the private sector
but are subject to government influence as a shareholder, and regulation by separate bodies
such as OFTEL and OFGAS. Similar bodies have been set up for the privatised electricity and
water industries (OFFER and OFWAT respectively).
A more limited monopoly power is granted under patent and copyright laws, which are similar
in most countries. The idea of a patent is that the inventor of a new idea shares his knowledge
with the State for the public benefit, in return for a monopoly control over the use of his idea
for a limited number of years. If rival suppliers are unable to develop a competing product
without breaking the patent, this form of monopoly can be very valuable take, for example,
the monopoly enjoyed for some years by the Polaroid instant film-developing process.
(b)
Licensed to ABE
126
(c)
Market Control
It is difficult to achieve total monopoly over supply without the protection of the law, although
it is not unknown especially in the production of some intermediate products. For a number
of years, all the valves for pneumatic tyres on British motor vehicles were produced by one
manufacturer. Such a monopoly rarely lasts very long. When a large rival decides to challenge
the monopolist, there is little that can be done to prevent this.
Figure 7.5
A monopolists output is the total market supply, and the demand for its product is the total market
demand. The firm will thus face a downward-sloping demand curve. If we assume that it is not
practising price discrimination, then this curve will be the price/average revenue curve. The
graphical model is shown in Figure 7.5.
The profit-maximising monopolist will produce at output Oq , where marginal cost equals marginal
revenue, and will charge price Op. Abnormal profit is represented by the shaded area. Oc is the
average cost, so Op Oc is the average profit earned on each unit of product sold.
Licensed to ABE
127
If the firm were to set price to equal marginal cost, which is the position desirable from the consumer
viewpoint, it would produce output Oqw and charge the lower price Opw. This is why the profitmaximising monopolist is said to restrict output and increase price in comparison with a firm
operating in a competitive market.
Comment
There is much evidence that large firms with considerable market power may not maximise profits
but may pursue quite different objectives, such as growth or sales revenue maximisation. The
average cost curve was drawn on the basis that abnormal profit was being made. There is nothing in
the model itself that says that the average cost curve must be this shape and in this position. We can
move it up or down without affecting the other curves, and so alter the profit quite legitimately.
In short, the model proves nothing. It simply illustrates the assumptions made. Notice that, if we
drop the profit-maximising requirement, we can allow the firm to increase output and reduce price,
and so come closer to the consumer-benefiting output level of Oqw. This would also reduce average
cost and allow the firm to make more efficient use of its resources.
In answer to the charge that monopoly is against the public interest because it restricts output and
raises price, the following arguments can be put forward:
(a)
The monopolists size and ability to produce for the whole market enables it to achieve
economies of scale, so that costs are actually lower than they would be under perfect
competition.
(b)
The monopolist employs professional managers who make more efficient use of available
resources than small owner/managers, who often lack managerial skill.
(c)
The monopolist does not maximise profits but is content with just a satisfactory level of profit.
(d)
spend money on research and gather funds for further capital investment;
(ii)
have the incentive to take risks and innovate, and sometimes suffer losses that would
cripple smaller firms.
The position where a monopolist is actually able to charge lower prices than would be possible under
perfect competition is illustrated in Figure 7.6. Here, for simplicity, constant average total costs have
been assumed and the monopolists cost curve is below that of small firms by reason of economies of
scale and improved technology. Assuming that the monopolist seeks to maximise profits, the
appropriate price will be Pm, still higher than the perfectly competitive price of Pc. However, this
could be reduced if the monopolist had some other objective such as maximising growth or revenue.
The revenue-maximising price (Pr), i.e. the price applicable to producing at the quantity level where
marginal revenue is 0, and therefore total revenue is at its maximum, is lower than the perfectly
competitive price of Pc. Notice that, unlike the firm under perfect competition, the monopolist can
charge a range of prices, depending upon the firms objectives, and still make a profit.
Licensed to ABE
128
Figure 7.6: Price and Output Under Perfect Competition and Monopoly
The argument really boils down to a question of performance. Does the monopolist behave against
the community interest or does it achieve levels of efficiency beyond the capacity of small firms
operating in highly competitive markets? There is no clear answer. As the extreme cases of
monopoly are fairly rare in practice, examination is usually made of markets which approach
monopoly conditions.
If the demand curve faced by the monopolist shifts, this will alter the marginal revenue curve and
consequently the profit-maximising output and price. However, we cannot assume that the demand
curve will simply move outwards parallel to the old one. It is possible that its slope may change
(become steeper or less steep). Consequently, while normally we would expect an increase in
demand at all prices to lead to an increase in monopoly price (assuming costs remained unchanged),
we cannot be absolutely sure of this. Try experimenting with differently sloped average revenue
curves. Remember that the marginal revenue must bisect (cut into two equal halves) the horizontal
distance between the average revenue curve and the revenue (vertical) axis. You will find that there
are changes that could produce a reduction in the profit-maximising price!
D. MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION
Main Features
Monopolistic competition still retains many of the features of perfect competition unrestricted entry
to and exit from the market, good (but not perfect) communication and transport conditions,
motivation by economic considerations only, and the perception by buyers that the products of the
various firms are good substitutes for each other.
Licensed to ABE
129
It is in this last point that monopolistic competition differs from perfect competition. Although the
products are considered to be good substitutes, they are not homogeneous. Buyers do express
preference for one sellers product as opposed to anothers.
Sellers seek to increase this preference by differentiating their product through branding (giving it
distinguishing features) and especially by advertising. The greater the degree of preference they can
establish, the stronger the brand loyalty and the greater the freedom gained by the supplier from
needing to follow the market price for that class of product. Success brings an increased degree of
market power and a reduction in price elasticity of demand.
General Model
In the general model of monopolistic competition, however, we assume that the individual firm is not
able to achieve a high degree of price inelasticity, so that the demand curve for the individual product
has only a fairly gentle slope, i.e. there is still a high degree of substitutability between competing
brands. This prevents the individual firm from making monopoly profits. It is still closely governed
by the market price for the class of product. The result is shown in Figure 7.7.
Features of this model are outlined below.
!
There is no abnormal or monopoly profit, i.e. average cost equals price/average revenue at Op
and, as for perfect competition and monopoly, it includes an element of normal profit.
At the profit-maximising output of Oq, average cost is still falling to its minimum at Oc, where
average cost is equal to marginal cost the output level where the rising marginal cost curve
cuts the bottom of the average cost curve.
Price (at Op) is above marginal cost (Om) at the profit-maximising output Oq.
Price is thus higher and output lower than would be the case if price were to be equal to marginal
cost, as in perfect competition. The lack of monopoly profit is the result of competition and the
ability of firms to enter and leave the market.
Licensed to ABE
130
Comment
It can be argued that this market structure is not really in the best interests of either consumers or
business firms, for the following reasons:
!
Price is higher and output lower than would be the case with perfect competition.
The firm is not making the best use of its resources, since average cost is still falling at output
Oq, as we saw a moment ago.
Profits are confined to the normal minimum required to keep firms in the market the amount
included in our definition of costs for the purposes of these market models. They cannot
achieve the profits needed for investment and research or the high output levels necessary for
economies of scale.
It is also argued, however, that consumers are prepared to accept these additional prices and costs in
return for the benefits they receive through greater choice of product the ability to choose between
competing brands and competing suppliers. This competition may also lead to improvements in
product quality and design as well as services to the consumer.
We can expect firms operating in such market conditions to seek to increase their monopoly power
and make their product-demand curves less elastic. They will do this by brand advertising, by
securing favourable treatment from distribution organisations or through technical improvements in
their products. They may be able to keep an advantage by securing patent protection or keeping
processes secret from their competitors.
Licensed to ABE
131
E. OLIGOPOLY
Oligopoly is the market structure where supply is controlled by a few firms which are large in relation
to the market size. Very often the firms are also large by any standards, and are likely to be
oligopolists in several markets. (For example, Unilever is a very large company which supplies major
brands of many grocery products, including Birds Eye frozen foods, and washing products
including, among many others, Surf and Stergene.)
Oligopoly is now commonly found in the advanced industrial countries and a great deal of attention is
paid to it. There is, however, no single model which can be held to apply under all circumstances.
Price Competition
One influence that is thought to be important is the extent to which the products are in price
competition with each other. If there is little price competition and if consumers are not thought to
choose brands on the basis of comparative price (i.e. if cross elasticity of demand is low) then each
oligopolist has a high degree of monopoly control over the demand for his own product.
This will, of course, depend chiefly upon whether the products are regarded by consumers as
homogeneous or whether they consider each brand to be distinct and different. It is unlikely that
consumers will find much to choose between, say, various brands of plain, salted crisps. Cross
elasticity of demand between the brands is thus likely to be high when the crisps are on sale in similar
distribution outlets. If there are price differences, customers will choose according to price.
In these circumstances, suppliers may seek to operate in different sections of the market, e.g. through
different supermarket chains or in hotels and pubs rather than retailers. They may also seek to
differentiate their products through such devices as flavour or by developing novelty shapes or other
related products. You may be familiar with various products which have been developed by the four
major firms in this market.
A full study of oligopoly is likely to embrace problems of prices and non-price competition, and even
the question of how far firms may collude together to limit the extent of competition between
established firms and to protect themselves against possible newcomers to the market.
Price Stickiness
Efforts have been made to produce models based on traditional assumptions of profit maximisation.
One such model seeks to explain the observed tendency that the prices of some goods in oligopolistic
markets remain steady in spite of fluctuations in the prices of basic commodities. This stickiness is
apparent in more normal, less inflationary times. For some years the price of a standard 4-ounce bar
of chocolate remained at 6d (old pence) in spite of frequent movements in the prices of the basic
materials required for chocolate manufacture.
This particular feature of an oligopolistic market for a product still regarded as fairly homogeneous
(in spite of brand advertising) has given rise to the model known as the kinked demand curve.
Licensed to ABE
132
Thus there is a kink around the price of 1 in the demand (unit price or average revenue) curve faced
by the individual oligopolist. At higher prices the curve is more elastic, due to the loss of market
share, than at lower prices where all market shares stay the same. You can see the general shape of
such a kinked curve in Figure 7.8.
Price
per
unit
Quantity
Figure 7.8
Now consider a possible table of revenues resulting from this condition.
Price per Unit
Quantity
Total Revenue
1.40
1.30
10
13.00
1.20
20
24.00
1.10
30
33.00
1.00
40
40.00
Marginal Revenue
(Change in TR)
pence
130
110
90
70
60 or 20
0
0.80
50
40.00
0.60
60
36.00
0.40
70
28.00
0.20
80
16.00
90
40
80
120
160
Licensed to ABE
133
The kink in the average revenue curve, shown in Figure 7.9, occurs at the price of 1 and the quantity
level of 40 units. At prices above 1, demand falls off at the rate of ten units for each 10p rise in
price. At prices below 1, however, demand falls by only five units for each 10p rise in price, i.e. the
unit price has to fall 20p to enable the oligopolist to gain a quantity increase of ten units.
The change in the slope of the average revenue (price) curve results in a similar change in the slope
of the marginal revenue curve and you can see that there are two possible marginal revenues at the
quantity level of 40 units. The higher (60p) results from the continuation downwards of the upper
part of the curve, whilst the lower (20p) results from the upward continuation of the lower part of the
curve. This is clearer on the graph but you should be able to work out the same results from the table.
Remember the marginal revenue levels in the table belong to the midpoints of the quantity changes.
The lower curve is changing at the rate of 40p for each ten units; the upper curve is changing at the
rate of 20p for each ten units.
Figure 7.9
Licensed to ABE
134
level the market clearing price is 100p. Marginal cost can fluctuate anywhere between MC1 and MC2
without altering the profit maximising position.
Remember, however, that this model depends on an assumption of profit-maximising behaviour for
the oligopolist and a high degree of substitution between products. This produces the reactions from
competing oligopolists which we have described (i.e. refusal to follow a price increase but matching a
price reduction). It is not a general model of oligopoly and does not tell us how the sticky price is
arrived at in the first place. There are too many behavioural assumptions for the model to be entirely
satisfactory.
The model does not hold up during periods of severe price inflation, when we would expect firms to
follow their rivals price rises but not any price reductions which they will not expect to be
maintained because of rising costs.
Price Leadership
Another tendency, which does hold during inflation, is for all oligopolists in a market to follow the
price movements of one firm, the price leader. Such leaders can be:
!
The least-cost firm, which can oblige competitors with higher costs to follow its prices, even
though they cannot maximise their own profits at the levels it sets.
A firm which is typical of others in the market and which becomes a barometer of market
conditions. If this firm feels that a price change is necessary, then it is probable that others will
feel the same.
The largest and the dominant firm in the market. The most common model of this situation
assumes that this firm, because of its size and the economies of scale it can achieve, is able to
achieve lower costs than the others. The lower its costs compared with the other firms costs
the greater will be its market share and, consequently, its dominance in the market. This model
is illustrated in Figure 7.10.
Figure 7.10
The market is shared between the dominant firm and smaller firms. The lower the costs of the
dominant firm the greater its share of the market.
Licensed to ABE
135
The dominant firm is aware of the total market demand curve and the cost conditions and
hence the supply curve for the smaller firms in the market.
In Figure 7.10 the demand curve DD is the demand curve for the market and SsSs is the supply curve
for the smaller firms. At price Po these firms are unwilling to supply to the market; it is their
minimum price. At price Ps the smaller firms are able and willing to supply the full market demand at
that price.
This knowledge allows the dominant firm to estimate its own demand curve, which is made up of
market demand at each price less the amount which the smaller firms are able to supply. Thus the
demand for the dominant firms product is nil at price Ps but it is the same as market demand at prices
Po and below. Between these two prices the dominant firm is able to supply the balance between
market demand and supply from the smaller firms.
On the assumption of profit maximisation the dominant firm will wish to supply quantity qd which is
the quantity at which its marginal cost is equal to its marginal revenue. At this quantity level the
dominant firms market clearing and profit maximising price is Pd. If it charges this price the other
firms will have to follow, and market demand at this price is shared on the basis of qd to the dominant
firm and qs to the smaller firms.
Notice that if you raise the dominant firms marginal cost curve you will reduce qd and increase qs.
However, if you lower this curve you will increase the market share going to the dominant firm,
which is thus able to maintain its dominance as long as it is able to keep its costs lower than those of
the smaller firm. We may assume it is able to achieve this through economies of scale, a higher level
of technical knowledge and managerial skill, and by its superior power to secure low prices in the
factor markets.
F.
In the discussions of perfect competition and monopoly, we noted that whereas under perfect
competition long-term survival depended on the firm maximising its profits, whether or not this was
its conscious objective, under monopoly the firm could survive without actually maximising profits.
As long as it made a satisfactory profit it was able to pursue other objectives. We now develop this
point more fully.
Any firm which possesses a substantial degree of market power as a producer and which is large in
relation to the total size of the market in which it operates, will have a product demand curve which is
downward sloping and, if it is successful, is also likely to be able to make profits above the minimum
needed to keep it in the market. Its position may, therefore, be represented by a model similar to that
usually used for monopoly as in Figure 7.11.
This models assumes that the firm does not practise price discrimination, so that its product demand
curve is also its average revenue curve. Assuming that its market power allows it to make profits
above the minimum, there will be a substantial range of output levels and prices between which it can
make profits. This, in Figure 7.11, is the range between output level A (price PA) which is the lower
break-even point where the falling average cost just equals average revenue, and output level C (price
PC) which is the higher break-even point where the rising average cost just equals average revenue.
Licensed to ABE
136
Figure 7.11
The firm in this situation can pursue objectives other than profit maximisation as long as it operates
within this profit range, but, as the model suggests, the range can be very wide.
During the past half century there have been many economists who have argued that large firms,
especially oligopolies, do not maximise profits. Unfortunately there has been no universal agreement
over what objective or objectives they do pursue instead. A number of alternative theories of the firm
have been developed and each of these is based on different assumptions about firms behaviour. For
convenience we can identify two broad groups of theories those that replace profit maximisation by
an assumption that firms seek to maximise something else, and those that abandon any idea of
maximisation in the belief that firms seek to pursue several objectives at the same time and cannot,
therefore, hope to optimise any one.
(a)
Licensed to ABE
137
profit, it would have to produce at an output level somewhere between B and C and charge a
price between PA and PB.
A British economist, Marris, has argued that firms seek to maximise their rate of growth
(expansion) subject to preserving their share values at a level where the firm can hope to be
reasonably safe from the fear of being taken over. If the firm grows too fast, its profit rate
tends to fall and this depresses the share value and brings the risk of take-over. Too slow a rate
of growth is also likely to bring the firm to the notice of take-over raiders, so the firm has to
balance the desire for growth with the need to maintain profits.
There are similarities in the Baumol and Marris theories. Both agree that the firms objectives
are really established by its professional managers, who are free to control the firm as long as
they keep the shareholders satisfied with their dividends and the financial markets satisfied
with their profits. Profit remains important no one doubts that in a market economy but it
is not maximised to the exclusion of other aims that meet managerial ambitions. Managers
like to operate in large firms because size brings prestige, high salaries and a range of other
benefits, so these are pursued, to some extent at the expense of the profits belonging to
shareholders. In the Baumol theory, revenue was seen largely as a way of measuring growth.
The Marris argument is slightly more complex and stresses growth more directly.
Another American economist, Williamson, developed another kind of maximisation but quite
cleverly combined this with the idea that the firm pursued several objectives at the same time.
Again agreeing with the idea that managers were the real controllers of the firm, Williamson
argued that they sought to maximise managerial utility and that this utility was a combination
of the pursuit of profit, growth, measured by the number of people employed, and managerial
perks (all the various expenses, benefits, etc. that movement up the business managerial
ladder tends to bring).
(b)
Satisficing Theories
The rather ugly word satisficing has been coined to express the idea that firms pursue several
different objectives at once. Whereas no one objective can be achieved to complete
satisfaction, the firm aims to pursue each to a degree of tolerable semi-satisfaction, i.e. it
satisfices without fully satisfying. The idea was first given clear expression by the American
economist, Simon, in an influential book, Administrative Behaviour. Simon argued that, in
practice, firms could not even if they wished, hope to maximise anything but rather reacted to
problems as they arose and aimed to keep all those involved in the firm reasonably satisfied so
that the firm could continue to exist.
Following the reasoning of Simon, this idea was developed into a more formal Behavioural
Theory of the Firm by two more American economists, Cyert and March, in a book with that
title. In this theory the firm is seen as a coalition between shareholders, managers and
customers, all of whose support is needed to hold the coalition together. To do so the firm has
to pursue multiple objectives, such as profit, sales growth, market share and products to satisfy
customers as well as the needs of production managers, but no one objective can be pursued to
the exclusion of the others. The firm has to develop a set of behavioural principles to enable it
to hold the coalition together and guide managerial decision-making.
Various other attempts have been made to explain business behaviour but there is no general
agreement as to whether the traditional assumption of profit maximisation should be abandoned and,
if so, what should replace it. The alternative theories sometimes seem to describe actual business
behaviour more realistically, especially in relation to large oligopolists. Firms do pursue growth,
Licensed to ABE
138
often at the expense of profits, take-over battles are commonplace and the salaries and prestige of top
business managers appear to bear little relationship to the profitability of the companies they manage.
On the other hand, an economic theory of the firm should be concerned not only with how firms
actually do behave but also how they should behave, if the economic goals of technical and
allocative efficiency are to be achieved. Unfortunately, the alternative theories appear to suggest that
if firms operate as they predict, they are likely to be less efficient in the full economic sense than if
they pursue profit maximisation the desire to make the largest achievable profit consistent with
market conditions. One thing that has to be remembered always is that profit maximisation does not
mean making very large and anti-social profits, but simply the largest profit possible under prevailing
market conditions. Profit maximisation under perfect competition suggests lower profits than
satisficing behaviour in an oligopolist market. A market economy appears to operate more efficiently
when firms seek to maximise profit. Consequently, most economists continue to work with profitmaximising models, whilst fully recognising that firms do frequently depart from profit-maximising
behaviour in practice.
Licensed to ABE
139
Study Unit 8
Money and the Financial System
Contents
A.
B.
C.
D.
Page
140
140
Functions of Money
141
142
142
142
143
144
144
145
Building Societies
146
146
146
147
147
148
International Links
148
Interest Rates
148
148
150
152
Licensed to ABE
140
portable it will not be much use as an aid to transfer if it cannot easily be moved
divisible it must be capable of reflecting a range of values; animals were once a symbol of
wealth but as money they had limitations a valuation of one and a quarter cows could prove
difficult to pay!
durable saving presents problems if the money saved is likely to die, rot or rust away
controllable preferably in short supply, not too easily obtained and capable of being
controlled by an accepted authority
recognisable if people cannot recognise money as money they are unlikely to accept it very
readily.
One of the oldest forms of money, and one that is still in limited use, is gold. When, from time to
time, the world economy becomes unstable and other forms of money become less acceptable the
price of gold always rises as people turn or return to it as a haven for their threatened savings.
Other precious metals have often been used, especially silver, but this lacks some of the qualities of
gold. Many metals suffer deterioration over time.
To aid recognition, add acceptability and assist in measuring value, many communities over the ages
have fashioned coins from previous, semi-precious and base metals. With the exception of a limited
supply of gold, these are now used mainly for units of low value.
Metal is bulky and expensive to transport in large quantities so, from very early times, traders have
used paper as a more convenient substitute. Paper has always been used in two ways as money:
(a)
As a receipt or representation of precious metal or some more solid form of money and
exchangeable for the preferred form of money under certain conditions. The Bank of England
note still contains the .... promise to pay the bearer on demand the sum of ... .. At one time
the holder could exchange such notes for gold. Today handing over a note at the Bank of
England will only be met with another note, but the promise serves as a reminder that the paper
really just represents money and has no intrinsic value in itself.
(b)
In recent years plastic cards have replaced or supplemented paper as conveyors of instructions to
make payments, and the development of modern telecommunications has made such cards with their
magnetic strips among the most important means of carrying out everyday trading transactions. As
Licensed to ABE
141
information technology continues to advance we can expect these cards to gain further uses but also
to be replaced by direct instructions through computers or over the telephone.
All these convenient forms of payment by simple instruction depend on peoples willingness to hold
their store of money in banks. Early banks actually did store the wealth of their customers in the
form of precious metals but wealth is now stored purely in the form of credit balances recorded in
computer memories. Money is now held in the form of a device that can store and transmit electrical
impulses. Even at this stage it has not yet reached its ultimate form, though in simple terms we can
ignore all present and future methods of transferring and storing money and simply refer to it as
bank credit. In this form we can choose to store it as a bank deposit or use it to make payments by
any of the techniques made available to us by current technology.
Functions of Money
The functions of money are generally summarised as follows:
(a)
Facilitating Exchange
The basic purpose of money, as we have already noted, is to make easier the exchange of goods
or services. Without money, people have to resort to direct exchange or barter, and this is often
wasteful, time-consuming and inefficient. Money allows trade to develop much more freely.
(b)
Measure of Value
Even if people do exchange goods directly, they can be more certain of fair dealing if they can
measure the value of their goods in terms of recognised money. If farmers wish to exchange
pigs and cows, they are helped if they know the values of both in money terms.
(c)
(d)
Store of Value
Finally, money can be kept as a store of value that can be held in reserve for purchases not yet
planned. This value can be held over time as long as money value does not fall.
The importance of acceptability has already been stressed. Without it, money cannot be used in
exchange. This is why a great deal of international trade is carried out in a relatively few generallyacceptable currencies e.g. American dollars, Swiss francs, Japanese yen, German marks, and British
pounds. These currencies are all readily acceptable and transferable in world trade and finance
markets.
We can see that acceptability and transferability depend on the confidence of traders. If this
confidence is lost, then money ceases to have any value, because it cannot fulfil its essential
functions.
The functions that causes the most problems is that of storing value. No form of money in the
modern world has escaped the problem of inflation the tendency for money prices to rise as time
goes by. If all prices rise, then the value of money itself is falling. The difficulty of storing value
Licensed to ABE
142
undermines confidence, acceptability and transferability, and so makes trade generally more difficult
and uncertain.
(b)
M0, the narrowest, made up of notes and coin in circulation with the public + banks till
money + the banks operational balances with the Bank of England
NIBM1, made up of notes and coin + the non-interest-bearing private sector sterling
sight deposits of banks (bank customers non-interest bearing current accounts)
M2, made up of notes and coin + the sterling, retail deposits of banks + the retail
building society shares and deposits + national savings bank ordinary accounts.
M4, made up of notes and coin + all private sector sterling bank and building society
deposits
In 1995 the measures in most use were M0 for narrow money and M4 for broad money. All measures
can be manipulated to some extent by banks, particularly if they are used as the basis for government
money controls. There is also a tendency for governments to stress whichever measure appears to
support whatever policies they are currently pursuing.
Licensed to ABE
143
Safe-keeping of Money
This is the basic function of banking. Many customers still keep jewels and important
documents in bank safes. However, as modern money is now mostly in the form of
transferable credit, this function is chiefly performed through the various types of bank account
held by customers. The current account is used for day-to-day transactions. Other accounts are
usually in the form of time deposits, i.e. deposits where an agreed period of notice is
required for withdrawals without penalty. The longer the period of notice and the higher the
amount deposited the higher the rate of interest paid by the bank. If immediate withdrawal is
required then a certain amount of interest is usually forfeited, though in some accounts
immediate withdrawal is permitted without an interest penalty provided a stated minimum sum
remains in the account. You should obtain details of the range of accounts offered by your own
bank.
(b)
Transfer of Money
Much of the daily work of the retail banks is concerned with making payments through
cheques and other written instructions, including bank giro. Some of the work of money
transfer has now been passed to the credit card companies (themselves mostly owned by the
large banks) but credit card payments still require final settlement by a bank transfer. The large
international banks are deeply involved in foreign payments for the import/export trade. Bills
of exchange are still used extensively in handling trade payments, especially as these are very
closely linked with the extension of credit.
(c)
Lending Money
Banks make most of their profits from lending money. Traditionally they have been chiefly
concerned with short-term loans very short-call (overnight or 24-hour) loans to other
banking institutions, overdrafts, trade loans made by discounting bills of exchange (usually for
up to 60 to 90 days) and commercial loans for up to around two years for business or approved
private projects.
In recent years, banks have been encouraged (by government pressure or by competition) to
lengthen their lending terms. Clearing banks have entered the private house mortgage market
where loans can be made for twenty or more years. Of greater importance to business has been
the increased willingness of banks to lend for periods of between five and ten years for
business capital development.
(d)
Licensed to ABE
144
consultants, banks are also becoming more actively involved in the fringe financial services
such as insurance broking, investment advice and the handling of trusts and estates.
More recently, a number of banks have entered the field of stockbroking. This has been made
possible by the Stock Exchange reforms of October 1986. The retail banks also control a
number of specialised subsidiaries, offering hire purchase, leasing and factoring services to
customers.
!
Factoring is used chiefly in foreign trade. A factor takes over responsibility for a
companys approved trade debts and arranges collection and administration, thus
releasing cash to the company. It is an expensive way of speeding up a firms cash flow
(the speed at which money spent on production is recovered from sales) but worthwhile
if the cash can be used at greater profit than the cost of the factoring service.
Licensed to ABE
145
Consortium banks are those jointly owned by British and foreign banks. The existence of foreign
banks in London has helped to make the large British banks more alive to the threat of potential
competition and the need to keep developing their own services.
The foreign banks are also active in what is termed the eurocurrency market which handles
transactions in the bank deposits of banks held outside the banks countries of origin. Thus the dollar
deposits of an American bank in London form part of the eurodollar market in Britain. Eurocurrency
markets have become a major part of the wholesale banking structure.
Licensed to ABE
146
Building Societies
The main function of these institutions is the provision of funds for house purchase by individual
owner-occupiers. They are also a major channel for the savings of individuals. The societies have
expanded with the huge growth of private home ownership in the United Kingdom. At the same time,
there have been many mergers so that the number of societies has been falling, but their average size
has increased. The larger societies have been seeking to widen the range of their activities, and have
been offering sight deposit, cheque books, cash card, personal lending and other banking-type
services in competition with the banks.
The Building Societies Act 1986 opened the way for the larger building societies to convert to public
companies as full banks, but by 1995 only the Abbey National had taken this route. In that year,
however, Lloyds Bank sought to take over the Cheltenham and Gloucester Building Society. The
Halifax and the Leeds merged, other societies were planning to do so, and it seemed clear that in
various ways the number of independent societies was likely to decline.
Licensed to ABE
(b)
147
Finance Houses
These are mostly dealers in consumer credit or providers of specialised financial services.
They generally obtain their funds through the banking system. Many are now officially
regarded as banks and are classified among Other British banks.
Licensed to ABE
148
with the Governor of the Bank of England. The Chancellor it is suggested, would be taking a great
political risk if he were seen to ignore clear advice given by the Governor, particularly if it was clear
that the advice was ignored in an attempt to gain short-term political advantage.
Another issue over which the Bank of England is likely to exert considerable influence is the question
of monetary union with other countries in the European Union and, associated with this, the matter of
a single European currency. Over this issue the Bank has been seeking to contribute to a serious
debate on the economic issues involved and to separate these from the heated emotional and political
passions that have become aroused.
It is responsible for the stability and integrity of the institutions which make up the banking
system and, in this capacity, it has very clear duties under the Banking Act 1987. In 1991 the
Bank closed down the Bank of Credit and Commerce International (BCCI) in the face of clear
evidence of massive fraud.
It also has a wider duty to control the actual supply of money within the banking system. The
extent to which it seeks to impose monetary controls and the methods chosen for control are
determined in consultation with the government. This is very much a political matter on which
the Bank can only advise. The reasons for monetary controls and the ways in which they may
be exercised are examined later in our studies.
International Links
As the national bank, the Bank of England keeps the nations gold reserves and the international
accounts for money entering and leaving the country, as well as the nations reserves in other
currencies. The Bank of England works closely with the central banks of other nations.
The Bank maintains continuous contacts with the major international banks, especially the
International Monetary Fund (the IMF is probably closest to being a genuine world bank).
The Bank has a duty to maintain the stability of the national currency in its exchange value with other
national currencies, and to co-operate with other countries and international institutions to uphold the
stability of the world financial system. It has a special account which it can use to deal in sterling
and other currencies in order to stabilise demand and supply and control exchange rates, or at least
control the speed at which exchange rates change. This account is called the Exchange Equalisation
Account.
D. INTEREST RATES
Importance of Interest Rates
We have seen how important borrowing and lending are to the workings of a modern economy, and
this dealing in money always takes place at a price. The price of money is interest, and the level of
interest has become an important issue in modern economics. The reasons why interest rates have
gained this importance include the following:
Licensed to ABE
(a)
149
(b)
(c)
they purchase less expensive goods, because a higher proportion of the amount spent
goes on borrowing costs, and
(ii)
the burden of repayments takes up an increased proportion of income leaving less for
other spending. As everyone with a mortgage loan knows only too well, any increase in
the interest charged on the loan reduces the amount of household income left for
spending on other goods and services. If, for any reason, the household cannot meet the
mortgage payments the home may be re-possessed. Changes in the rate of interest have
become of very great importance to large numbers of people.
High interest rates also appear to increase savings partly, no doubt, because of the
discouragement to spending. We shall see later in the course how an increase in saving and a
reduction in consumer spending can have a depressing effect on total business activity. A
prolonged period of very high rates can be an important influence leading to general depression
and increased unemployment.
(d)
Because of the direct impact of interest changes in all these ways, the ability to make changes has
become a major instrument of economic policy in all the main market economies. Since most
Licensed to ABE
150
Licensed to ABE
151
Figure 8.1
In the absence of any other influence, interest rates would be determined by considerations of this
nature. However, other influences are almost always present in the shape of government or central
bank intervention. Because some governments or central banks intervene to move interest rates to
levels thought necessary to achieve their desired economic objectives, other governments also have to
intervene to ensure that their economies are not put at a disadvantage.
Governments or other regulatory bodies are likely to want to push rates higher than the market
equilibrium levels if they wish to restrict demand and production in order to control inflationary
pressures. They may seek to bring rates below the equilibrium if they are faced with high and rising
unemployment and fear a deep recession-depression. By reducing the cost of capital they hope to
encourage business investment and consumer demand for goods and services. No major trading
country can afford to be too far out of line with interest rates in other countries otherwise there would
be a huge movement of capital towards high-rate countries and away from low-rate countries. This
movement would put immense strains on the low-rate countries balance of payments and on its
currency exchange rate. Consequently the freedom of any individual government or central bank is
restricted by the actions of governments and banks in other countries. Finance now circulates in a
genuinely international market.
Licensed to ABE
152
Governments can influence rates either by controlling the stock of capital, usually by measures over
bank lending, or by direct controls over the major banks. Notice that in Figure 10.1 the equilibrium
rate will rise if the cost of capital line moves to the left and fall if it moves to the right. This results
from the general shape of the MEC curve.
The time period over which the loan is made the longer the period the higher the interest rate
required, unless market rates are expected to fall over the period, when long-term rates can
sometimes fall below those for short-term lending.
The ease with which money loaned can be recovered; the greater the degree of liquidity, i.e. the
more speedily and simply the money can be recovered, the lower the rate of interest. Banks
pay a higher rate on deposits where several months notice is required before repayment is
made than on deposits which offer instant access (immediate cash withdrawal).
The credit standing of the borrower large companies with a long record of financial stability
can obtain loans at lower rates than new, small companies.
The degree of risk which, in fact, is the underlying factor in all the above considerations.
Share dividends are not the same as interest payments but very similar principles apply. If you
look at the dividend yield as shown in a share price list in any of the leading daily papers you
will see that the yield (dividend return as a percentage of the price of the share) is much lower
on shares in the most profitable and secure companies than on shares of small companies in the
riskier sectors of activity, e.g. house builders.
You should examine the deposit accounts offered by several of the main banks and see how far the
differences in interest rates offered can be explained by the above factors.
Licensed to ABE
153
Study Unit 9
Liquidity Preference
Contents
A.
154
Physical Assets
154
Financial Securities
154
155
B.
155
C.
158
158
Credit Creation
158
Illustration
158
The Multiplier
159
160
160
161
161
162
164
D.
E.
Page
Licensed to ABE
154
Liquidity Preference
physical assets
financial securities
Physical Assets
Examples would include houses, land, furniture and private cars. Everyone who has wealth of any
kind will have some assets, as these are necessary to everyday life in a modern society, but it is also
possible to hold the wealth you wish to store for the future in the form of assets. In this case your
choice of which assets to hold will be guided less by what you need or find useful in normal life but
by what you think is most likely to hold or increase its value in the future. Since the future is
uncertain you may or may not choose correctly!
Holding wealth in the form of physical assets offers the following advantages:
!
They are likely to be useful or enjoyable as well as valuable and may remain so even if they
lose their value; for example, vintage wine may not increase in value as hoped at the time of
purchase but it is very pleasant to drink.
In periods of inflation or financial-political uncertainty they are likely to hold or increase their
value when money is losing its purchasing power.
They are visible symbols of wealth and status and this can be important for some people.
They can excite envy and attract thieves and if, as a result, they have to be stored in a bank
vault they cannot be enjoyed.
They can be destroyed by fire or accident, or damage may reduce their value.
Keeping physical assets involves costs such as insurance premiums, maintenance, cleaning and
guarding, and these costs can be heavy.
Fashions change, and what is in demand and valuable one year may be considered unattractive
and without value a few years later. This applies particularly to the so called collectibles
such as works of art, coins and postage stamps. Those who bought houses in the late 1980s
know only too well that asset values can fall as well as rise.
Under normal circumstances, therefore, few people with wealth to store are likely to hold all their
wealth in the form of physical assets. This would be an option only when the normal financial system
was in danger of collapsing.
Financial Securities
These are mostly either titles to the ownership of property or to a right to share in the benefits of
property ownership, or they are promises to make a future payment. It is often an advantage to hold a
written title to property because ownership can be transferred by handing over the written title or it
can be used as a security for a loan. Similarly a written promise to make a future payment will also
have a value and the right to receive the payment can be sold to someone else.
Licensed to ABE
Liquidity Preference
155
To be useful as a financial instrument, of course, the promise to pay must carry respect. An
undertaking by a major High Street bank will be more transferable, and therefore useful, than one
signed by an unknown individual. Such promises to pay or to repay a loan or debt on a stated date or
by a stated date, with interest payable to the holder in the meantime, are often known as bonds. With
the apparent decline of inflation in the 1990s, bonds issued by public companies and termed
corporate bonds have returned to investor favour. Bonds issued by the British Government, termed
government bonds or stocks, or gilt-edged securities (gilts) are an important element in the capital
market. Details of these can be obtained from most post offices and their market prices are quoted
daily in the financial press.
Wealth held in the form of bonds and securities, including the ordinary shares of companies, can also
be referred to as loanable funds. Besides ease of transfer, holding wealth in this form has the
advantage that it provides the holder with an income from interest or dividends paid by the issuer of
the securities. This is in contrast with owning physical assets, which incurs costs of maintenance and
insurance. As with any form of wealth there are risks of suffering a loss. For example if a company
which has issued bonds fails and goes into liquidation with insufficient assets to meet its obligations
to bondholders then the bonds are worthless. The bonds of very risky companies are frequently
called junk bonds.
Licensed to ABE
156
Liquidity Preference
(a)
Transactions Motive
This is the desire to hold money because it is needed for the purchase of goods and services
i.e. to carry out trading transactions.
(b)
(c)
Licensed to ABE
Liquidity Preference
157
Figure 9.1
What is high and what is low in relation to interest rates depends on a great many other
considerations, including peoples experiences of rates in recent years. The ten per cent used
in the above example would have been regarded as very high in the early 1960s but very low in
the early 1980s. You should take an interest in the movement of interest rates and in changes
in the prices of bonds (government stocks) while you are studying economics.
This stress on the speculative motive for holding money led Keynes to the belief that the
demand for money does have a direct relationship to interest rates. It was thus possible to draw
a liquidity preference curve of the type shown in Figure 9.1.
Notice that, at the lower rates of interest, the curve flattens out, because no one believes that
the rate is likely to fall further, so there are no takers for bonds and people will wish to see a
rise to a higher rate before there can be any expectation of a fall and a chance for a speculative
gain. This is the liquidity trap which also features in the Keynesian v. monetarist debate, and
which we shall come to shortly.
Licensed to ABE
158
Liquidity Preference
Credit Creation
Banks, in fact, can create credit through lending to their customers, and lending is a most important
and profitable part of a banks activities. When people or firms borrow from the banks, they use the
amount borrowed to make payments to other people or firms, who deposit the payments with their
banks. Suppose I borrow 2,000 from my bank to help buy a new car. When I buy the car, I pay the
Swifta Motor Company. Suppose this company also has its accounts at the same bank. When I pay
my cheque, drawn on the bank, to Swifta, it then pays in my cheque to its own account. In effect, the
bank has created 2,000 in one account (my loan account) and thereby increased the volume of its
customer deposits (through the extra 2,000 paid in by Swifta).
Thus, for the factor capital, we have the peculiar position that demand appears to create its own
supply.
You may think we have cheated by using one bank only in our example but, as long as there is a fairly
closed banking system in a country, the effect will be the same if different banks are involved. In the
UK, the great mass (over 80%) of daily payments pass between the four large clearing banks
(Barclays, Lloyds, National Westminster and Midland), so that this close relationship between
demand, borrowing, depositing and supply does exist.
Illustration
In practice, the banks keep a proportion of all their funds in the form of coin, notes or deposits with
their own bank (the Bank of England), or in loans to other banking institutions, which can very
quickly be recalled. If we call these liquid assets of the banks cash, and assume, for simplicity, that
a country has a system of two banks only, each keeping 10% of its assets in cash, then we can give a
very simple illustration of how the total supply of bank money can grow following the injection of
new money from some outside source.
Suppose that our two banks are A and B, and the initial injection is 100 units, which goes to B. As
customers borrow money to pay to customers of B, and vice versa. The banks are of equal size.
Licensed to ABE
Liquidity Preference
159
Bank A
Customer deposits
Held as:
1,000
Cash
100
Loans
900
1,000
Bank B is in the same position. Then there is an injection of 100 to the deposits of A. Bank A
initially adds this to its cash but idle cash earns no money. As soon as possible, therefore, it lends it
to suitable customers, and its accounts then appear as follows.
Bank A
Customer deposits
Held as:
1,000
Cash
110
Loans
990
1,100
This additional lending soon gets paid into customer deposits of bank B, which also lends 90% of this
increase, so that its accounts appear as:
Bank B
Customer deposits
Held as:
1,090
Cash
109
Loans
981
1,090
Additional loans of 81 units have now been made to customers of bank B, who have made payments
to customers of bank A.
The process continues, and bank As accounts become:
Bank A
Customer deposits
1,181
Held as:
Cash
Loans
118
1,063
1,181
Notice how the total of deposits (and, hence, the total money supply) is increasing, but (because 10%
is being held back all the time) by a decreasing amount at each lending/deposit round.
The Multiplier
This progression is called the bank credit (or money) multiplier. The total increase in our example
will be ten times the amount of the original injection. This is because:
Kb =
1
c
Licensed to ABE
160
Liquidity Preference
As the original injection was 100, the final increase would be 1,000. Thus, the greater the proportion
of customer deposits that the banks are able to lend to other customers, the greater will be the size of
the bank multiplier and the effect of lending on total money supply.
This power of the banks to create money, and the close link between lending money and the
increase in total money supply, are both extremely important issues. You must make sure you fully
understand them.
Because of this close relationship between the demand for and the supply of money, we can suggest
that the supply of money is likely to have very similar features to the demand. Thus, if we believe
that there is a particular relationship between interest rates and the demand for money, then a very
similar relationship can be expected for interest rates and the supply of money.
Licensed to ABE
Liquidity Preference
161
Monetarist view of demand for goods and services and changes in interest rate
Interest
rate
%
i1
i
total expenditure
(demand for goods
and services)
q1
Quantity of goods
and services
Figure 9.2
If interest rate rises from 0i to 0i1, the demand for goods and services falls from 0q, to 0q1, because
people are attracted towards buying bonds and other income-yielding securities.
Licensed to ABE
162
Liquidity Preference
Licensed to ABE
Liquidity Preference
163
Figure 9.3
The position according to the monetarist view is very different, although the mechanism is the same.
Demand remains largely unaffected by the shift in supply and the change in interest rate which is,
thus, pushed up higher than in the Keynesian view. This steep rise in rate produces a major reduction
in the interest-responsive demand for goods and services.
These are very marked contrasts, in effect, and you would expect the debate to be settled fairly easily
by research into actual interest-rate and money-supply changes. In practice, economists research
faces a great many practical difficulties not least, as we shall see, the problem of actually defining
and measuring money supply!
There are also other influences operating both on interest rates and on the demand for money, and
there are further problems in distinguishing between short and long-term effects. Even after many
years of economic management by a monetarist government, following the changes of 1979, there
is still much uncertainty, and the debate is far from resolved.
Licensed to ABE
164
Liquidity Preference
You may now also see that our analysis has to take into account some important modifications
resulting from the way money is handled in the actual finance markets, so that, before we go further
into this general debate over monetarism and the effect of government attempts to control the
economy according to monetarist principles, we should pause and examine the structure of the
finance market within which money and the supply and demand for money actually interact.
If the supply of loanable funds falls we would expect interest rates to rise and this would
increase the investment costs faced by business firms and tend to reduce their investment
intentions.
If expenditure on goods and services falls, this would reduce the aggregate level of consumer
expenditure and lead to a reduction in business investment. Firms invest in order to increase
future production. There is no point increasing future production if current expenditure on
goods and services is falling. The reduction in investment would have a depressing effect on
the equilibrium level of national income through the investment accelerator and multiplier.
This process and the terms investment multiplier and investment accelerator are explained in
Study Unit 11. At this stage it is simply necessary to recognise that any reduction in investment is
likely to depress the general level of economic activity in a country.
Licensed to ABE
165
Study Unit 10
The National Economy
Contents
A.
166
166
166
166
168
169
169
National Product
170
170
171
173
National Expenditure
173
Calculation of GDP
173
174
D.
National Income
175
E.
Equality of Measures
175
F.
176
176
177
Making Comparisons
177
177
Limited Accuracy
177
178
178
178
B.
C.
G.
H.
Page
Licensed to ABE
166
That production and consumption are separate production being organised by business or
government organisations, and consumption being decided by individuals, families and
households. The family is, thus, seen as purely a consumption and social unit, and not as a
production/consumption/social unit, as it would be in an agrarian (farming) economy.
That most of the goods and services produced are exchanged through a market system, with
households paying money to buy products, and firms paying money for the use of production
factors.
That a proportion of production is organised by the state and its agencies, and paid for by
revenue raised by the state from the community.
This system can be illustrated in the form of two circular flow diagrams. One shows the flow of
goods and services the productive activities of production factors (Figure 10.1(a)), while the other
(Figure 10.1(b)) shows the counterflow of money which oils the really important flow of production
and consumption. Notice that, for simplicity, we use the terms firms for production organisations,
and households for the individuals and families who consume what is produced. These diagrams
assume that the total volume of production is immediately and totally consumed, i.e. there is nothing
to enlarge or diminish this continuous circular flow.
Notice that firms are seen as hiring the production factors, which are owned by households, which
then supply the labour, capital and land employed in production, and purchase the goods and services
produced.
Licensed to ABE
Figure 10.1
Licensed to ABE
167
168
Given this proposition and retaining our simplified model of the economy, we can then see that any
increase in income is apportioned between consumption and saving. The amount of any increase in
income which is consumed is often referred to as the marginal propensity to consume. It may also
form the basis for an equation which helps us to determine the level of consumption for any given
level of national income. For example, we may say that:
C = 300 + 0.75Y
This is then termed the consumption function. If you have studied mathematics, the term function
will be familiar to you.
Given this function, i.e. the direct relationship between total consumption and total income we can
calculate values for C for any level of Y. If Y = 1,000, then C = 300 + (1,000) = 1,050. At this
level, people are trying to consume more than their total income and will have to use up past savings
or borrow from another country. At the income level of 4,000, C = 300 + (4,000) = 3,300. This
means that savings will equal 700, i.e. 4,000 3,300.
In this example, the 300 is a constant; it is the minimum amount of consumption required by the
community, whatever the level of income. Total consumption is made up of this minimum plus a
proportion of total income. The greater the marginal propensity to consume, the higher will be the
proportion of total income that is consumed at any given income level. If the marginal propensity to
consume remains the same at all income levels, then this will also be the proportion of Y that is
consumed in the equation.
Not all the income received by households is immediately spent on goods and services; some
income is saved.
(b)
Another part of total income of households is not actually spent on goods and services but
handed over to government authorities as taxation, either taken directly from income or
indirectly when certain goods and services are purchased. At this stage, all forms of taxation
are considered together. We shall examine forms of taxation later.
(c)
Yet another portion of income is spent on goods and services produced by other national
economies, i.e. it is spent on imports from other countries.
(d)
Firms enter the general flow as buyers of goods and services, such as factories, machines and
research, in their efforts to increase their capacity to produce. We call this investment or
capital accumulation.
(e)
The government must be seen as a separate force which produces goods and services on behalf
of the community as a whole e.g. it builds roads, schools and hospitals, and it provides forces
to maintain law and order and defence against external aggression. We can combine all these
activities under the heading government expenditure.
(f)
Firms supply other countries with exports of their products. Trade is a two-way process.
We can regard modifications (a) to (c) as leakages from the main flow of economic activity, because
they reduce the purchasing power of total incomes, and (d) to (f) as injections into the flow, because
they increase total purchasing power and demand. This concept of leaks from and injections into the
main flow is illustrated in Figure 10.2.
Licensed to ABE
169
Figure 10.2
Licensed to ABE
170
The total based on factor cost is the one normally used. It is considered to be the fairer reflection of
true expenditure on goods and services. After all, total expenditure includes government spending on
final consumption, and much of this is paid for from expenditure taxes. If we value GDP at market
prices, then we are, in effect, counting in expenditure taxes twice once when they are paid by the
consumer, and once when they are used to pay for goods and services by the various government
bodies. Similar adjustments need to be made to take account of subsidies. These are payments made
by Government to producers and have the effect of reducing market prices. To obtain the true cost of
goods and services any subsidies need to be added back. Thus, to convert GDP from market prices to
factor costs indirect taxes are deducted and subsidies are added. In the summary accounts this
process is usually referred to as the factor cost adjustment.
The treatment of direct (mostly income and profits) taxes appears, on the surface, to be rather
different, but the effect is the same i.e. to ensure that total incomes are a fair reflection of the
incomes actually earned in the course of producing the national product.
Income and profits taxes are not deducted from employment incomes, nor from the trading profits of
companies and the trading surpluses of government-owned bodies.
The gross incomes, profits and surpluses are the true incomes actually paid by the production
organisations.
On the other hand, no account is taken in the summary totals of incomes from pensions,
unemployment benefits or other state welfare payments. These incomes are not received in return for
a contribution to production. They are transfer payments being transfers from the income of a
contributor to the production process to someone who is a non-producer. (No moral judgment is
intended here. The non-producer may have been a valuable past producer, or he may become a
valuable future producer. Our concern is to arrive at a true valuation of production in the year of
account.)
The accounts do, of course, include the incomes of those in the employment of state organisations,
even though their incomes may have been paid for out of income taxes. This does not matter the
incomes of state employees are earned in return for their work which is included as part of total
production, and the process is no different, in principle, from any other use of income to provide an
income to another in return for goods or services. If I use part of my income to pay for my
daughters dancing lessons, then those payments are included again in the accounts as part of the
dancing teachers income. If part of my income is taken from me to pay the salary of a teacher in my
daughters comprehensive school, then, again, these payments are included in the national accounts.
The only difference is that the state directs what I shall pay towards teaching in the school, whereas I
choose whether or not to pay for dancing lessons. In each case, the payments are made in return for
services which contribute towards the production of the national product. What is not included as a
further income is the payment made out of my taxes towards the unemployment benefit paid to my
unemployed nephew. His income is not earned in the course of producing anything, and it is ignored,
as though it were a voluntary contribution from me to him.
B. NATIONAL PRODUCT
Avoiding Double Counting Value Added
The National Product is the sum of the values of all the goods and services produced by a community
within a recognised time period normally a calendar year. However, we cannot simply add up the
values of all goods and services produced by all business organisations in the country. If we did this,
we would be counting some things more than once. For example, a set of screws may be made by
Licensed to ABE
171
firm A, sold to firm B which makes timing equipment, which, in turn, is sold to firm C a motorvehicle assembler. The completed vehicle is then sold to firm D, a motor distributor.
The final price of the vehicle includes the cost of the screws but, if we added up the total value of the
products sold by firms A, B, C and D, we would find that we had counted the screws four times.
One possibility might be to add up only the value of the product sold by the final distribution firm,
but this might not give us a very accurate result, because our motor distributor does not always know
whether he is selling to a householder or to a small business firm which will use the vehicle for
business purposes and includes its cost in the value of the goods or services it produces. There would
also be considerable problems of allowing for goods imported and exported.
The solution actually adopted is to count the value added to inputs by all firms producing outputs.
This is now much easier than in the past, because of the introduction of Value Added Tax. All firms
paying the tax, in effect, are also reporting their value added to the taxation authorities. In very
simple terms, the value added by each firm is the difference between the revenue it obtains from
selling its product and the cost of all goods and services purchased from other firms. In this way, the
screws of our original example are counted only in the value added of firm A. They are excluded
from the totals obtained from firms B, C and D. Notice that value added includes the cost of labour
employed by each firm in adding value to the inputs it purchases.
We shall go on to show how public sector spending contributes to the Gross National Product.
However, there is a reservation that should be made when we consider the public sector. This
concerns what are often called transfer payments. Consider, for example, what happens when a
person receives unemployment or some similar social security benefit. This is not a payment made in
return for work performed or services provided. It is a transfer to the unemployed person through
taxation from the income earned by people in employment. If we counted the unemployment benefit
into the National Product in addition to the full income of those who, in effect, are making the
transfer, then we would be double-counting the amount. Incomes are counted as part of National
Product only if they are earned by some contribution to economic activity, e.g. by employment or by
making capital available to government or business. Payments received by way of transfer through
taxation are not included in the total though, of course, they have to be taken into account when we
examine how the total National Product or Income is distributed.
A similar transfer payment within the private sector takes place when parents give pocket-money to
their children. The income has been earned by the parent and is simply transferred to the child. Total
national accounts, therefore, do not include childrens pocket money! Of course, the transfer
payments taking place through the public sector are much larger, and it is important that we
understand why they should be excluded from the final totals.
Licensed to ABE
172
1993
%
1.99
1.82
10,373
7.41
2.13
12,147
23.68
20.77
118,294
3.18
2.46
13,994
Construction
5.83
5.13
29,221
12.26
13.76
78,348
7.22
8.12
46,263
18.17
23.52
133,956
6.81
6.71
38,199
8.42
10.09
57,457
5.03
5.49
31,292
100.00
100.00
56,544
Industry sector
Manufacturing
Total
1993
million
-23,741
317
546,120
The item adjustment for financial services requires explanation. The gross figure of (23,741m)
for banking and finance services includes interest payments received from financial companies and
other institutions. These payments should really be deducted from the totals of other industries to
which they relate but, as this is impossible, the only way to adjust the total is by including this special
item.
One further adjustment is made to these figures. As we see in this study unit, the total of Gross
Domestic Product is calculated in three ways, corresponding to three different points in the same
circular flow of activity. Because they are measuring the same thing, each total should be the same.
In practice, errors and omissions are inevitable so they are never quite the same. No one measure is
considered to be more accurate than the other so each is adjusted by a statistical discrepancy to
bring them all to the same figure. In this case the corrected figure for total Gross Domestic Product is
546,120m.
This total represents the value of the economic activity of the community, measured from the output
of business and government organisations. This figure is termed Gross Domestic Product (GDP).
The basis on which this figure is valued does not include indirect taxes and government subsidies, so
Licensed to ABE
173
that it is assumed to be valued at factor cost, i.e. at the cost of the factor inputs, not at the prices
paid by final consumers.
Notice also that, in this calculation, there is no separate identification of imports and exports. This
would be too difficult when counting business output of firms operating within the country. In
practice, we would expect the figures to include the value of goods and services which have been
produced for export, but not to include those produced in other countries. Domestic product
represents the value added from the home or domestic activities of production organisations in both
the private and public sectors.
C. NATIONAL EXPENDITURE
Calculation of GDP
The main items of total expenditure were identified earlier as the main flow of household
consumption plus the injections of business investment, government spending and export demand.
Licensed to ABE
174
The concept is reflected in the Blue Book totals, which, in 1994, identified the National Product by
category of expenditure, as follows:
National Product by category of expenditure for 1993:
million
Consumers expenditure
346,162
128,786
87,025
561,973
Consumers expenditure is the same as the household expenditure already explained. Total
government spending is shown exclusive of capital investment. For example, it includes the running
costs of the Health Service but not the cost of building hospitals. This capital investment or
formation is combined with private sector investment to produce the third item in the table, gross
domestic capital formation.
This figure is not the same as domestic product calculated from industrial and government output,
because of the effect of imports and exports. Consumer and other spending will include spending on
goods and services produced in other countries (imports) but will not include the value of goods and
services sold to other countries. However, when we add on a figure of 150,504 million for exports,
deduct 166,266 million for imports and then also deduct a statistical discrepancy adjustment of
91 million, we obtain the total for gross domestic product calculated from expenditure of 546,120
million, the same figure calculated from product by industry.
The basis of valuation is factor cost, because the effect of taxes and subsidies on expenditure has
been removed. In fact, the National Income Blue Book also gives tables for Gross Domestic Product
calculated by category of expenditure at market prices. Further figures are then given for factor
cost adjustment. These are the total of taxes on expenditure to be deducted from Gross Domestic
Product, and of subsidies to be added. The result is Gross Domestic Product at factor cost.
For example, in 1993 the factor cost adjustment required:
Deducting
Taxes on expenditure
91,361 million
An allowance for net property income from abroad, i.e. earnings of British organisations
operating in other countries less the amount earned in the UK by foreign-owned organisations.
In 1993, there was a net inflow of this income of 3,062m and when this is added to gross
domestic product it produces a total of 549,182m. This is known as the Gross National
Product.
Licensed to ABE
(b)
175
An allowance for capital consumption, i.e. the using-up of capital investments made in past
years (e.g. the deterioration of roads, factories, etc.). In 1993, this was estimated to total about
65,023m. Thus, when this figure is deducted from the Gross National Product of 549,182m,
there remains a total for net National Product at factor cost (National Income) of
484,159m.
In practice, the figure most commonly used for international comparisons, etc. is that for Gross
National Product largely because the capital consumption figure has to be estimated, and different
countries use different methods of estimation.
D. NATIONAL INCOME
We noted earlier that total factor incomes suffered leaks from savings, taxes and import spending
before they were transformed into expenditure. The main Blue Book totals do not, in fact, show these
items directly, although they can be calculated from figures published in the book. Instead, they show
the Gross National Product by category of income. The totals are of gross incomes, so they include
taxation, savings and money which will be spent on imports. The categories of income are as below
again using figures for 1993 from the 1994 edition of the Blue Book:
million
Income from employment
352,896
61,346
73,397
3,415
294
52,872
3,942
2,359
319
546,120
Notice that these correspond broadly to the rewards to factors of production. Income from
employment is the return to labour, as is most of the income from self-employment though this may
include some return to business owners capital. Company profits and government organisation
(including public corporation) surpluses may be seen as the reward to capital, while rent is the return
to land, including certain property on the land.
As we are concerned with incomes earned within the country, we do not have to make any
adjustments for imports and exports.
E. EQUALITY OF MEASURES
Notice that the Blue Book and countries other than the UK use similar calculations takes care to
emphasise the equality (or, more strictly, the identity) of the three measures by:
Licensed to ABE
176
(a)
ensuring that each is brought to the same total, where necessary by the device of a statistical
adjustment; and
(b)
labelling each set of summary accounts as National or Domestic Product thus stressing that
it is the same flow of activity that is being measured, whether by category of expenditure,
category of income or class of industry.
This also emphasises that it is the real product, i.e. the flow of actual goods and services, that is
important, rather than the flow of money through income and expenditure patterns.
Thus, the national account supports the concept of National Product and its circular flow. Remember
that total gross incomes were distributed by households as: consumer expenditure, savings, taxation
and spending on imports.
At the same time, total expenditure received additions (injections) from: investment, government
spending, and spending on exports by foreign countries. Bearing in mind that total income and total
expenditure are different ways of looking at what is, essentially, the same flow, we can use symbols to
state an equation. We have already used E for total expenditure and Y for total income. In addition
to these, it is usual to make use of the following:
S = savings;
I = investment;
T = taxation;
M = imports.
and
E = C+I+G+X
F.
Licensed to ABE
177
The second part of the answer lies in the changed economic role of the government. After the Great
Depression of the 1930s, there was a widespread belief that the government could, and should, seek
to become involved in some degree of economic planning. If a government is to try to manage the
national economy, it needs national accounts, just as much as business managers need business
accounts for the firms the activities of which they are seeking to control.
Making Comparisons
Accounting records make comparisons possible. We can find out whether the economy is operating
more or less effectively than in the past, or more or less efficiently than the economies of other
countries. As we shall see in the next section, care has to be taken in making comparisons but,
without national accounting figures, no comparison is possible at all. For example, when we look at
the UK experience over the last decade in the light of, say, the West German experience over the
same period, we can see that there have been very different results arising from different policies and
objectives.
One very practical use for national income figures is as a basis for a number of United Nations
calculations. Member contributions to some UN institutions depend on national product. National
income and product figures are the starting point for many UN investigations designed to improve the
economic and social performance of poorer countries.
Limited Accuracy
It is, clearly, impossible to compile details of all the many economic activities in a modern
community. The desire to evade taxes is one of many reasons why some activities remain firmly
hidden from official eyes. The extent of the hidden, or black economy is sometimes put as high as
7% of the official economy. Business organisations come and go, and it is not easy to estimate the
size of activity in new industries or the extent to which older activities may be declining. We have
seen that the three measures of the British national product can be made to balance only with the help
of a statistical adjustment. Considering the huge amounts involved the proportional differences that
have to be reconciled are remarkably small. In countries able to devote fewer resources to statistical
services the margin of error is likely to be rather greater.
Remember that we are dealing with large aggregates or total figures, and these can conceal very wide
variations. For example, if, on the basis of our accounts, we say that the average income per head of
Licensed to ABE
178
the population is x, we should not imagine that the majority of people will be earning that figure.
Some will be earning much more and some much less. Some of the richest people in the world come
from the poorest countries. For a developing country, any average is likely to be very misleading in
view of the very great social, regional and other differences that exist.
Some countries may have an interest in ensuring that figures are not too accurate. A country hoping
to obtain maximum help from, and make the smallest possible contribution to, United Nations
institutions will wish to keep its national income figures as low as possible.
There is also the problem of comparing accounts when these are prepared in different national
currencies. International figures are usually converted to United States dollars at official rates of
exchange. Such official rates are often very different from the rates ruling in unofficial currency
markets.
Licensed to ABE
179
particular care when we make comparisons between countries with different economic and social
systems, or attempt to measure changes over long periods of time.
Imagine an extreme case an attempt to compare average living standards between 1880 and 1990.
There were no aircraft, television sets, radios or private motor cars in 1880! These are so
fundamental to the pattern of life today that we cannot really even begin to make any sensible
comparison. At best, we can only compare different aspects of life, e.g. working conditions, for
particular groups of workers.
Moreover, when we talk about the standard of living, there are important aspects that cannot be
measured in terms of economic activity. A man may have a higher real income in 1993 than his father
had in 1963, but if he is unemployed and has little prospect of employment, is his standard of living
any higher? Opportunities for travel, for changing employment, freedom of speech and religion,
freedom to walk the streets without fear of violent crime, arbitrary arrest or political coercion, all
these are elements in the standard of living which are not included in any Gross National product
calculations. The matters of working hours and leisure time are also ignored.
Economists are sometimes accused of placing too much weight on measures of quantity and on
money values, and not taking sufficient notice of quality and the values that money cannot measure.
Increasingly, however, economists are recognising the limitations of the concepts and measures they
use. As long as we bear these in mind, then we can make effective use of national accounts and
recognise that these are an essential starting point for any study of national economy. We would not
expect a set of company accounts to tell the full story of a large business enterprise but, equally, if we
wanted to examine the enterprise, we would be foolish not to include in that examination a very close
scrutiny of the company accounts. In the same way, we find a great deal of invaluable information in
the national accounts of a country.
Licensed to ABE
180
Licensed to ABE
181
Study Unit 11
Determination of National Product and Implications of
Investment
Contents
A.
182
Equilibrium Conditions
182
182
184
B.
186
C.
186
186
187
189
190
191
192
193
193
193
194
195
196
196
200
D.
Page
Licensed to ABE
182
Licensed to ABE
183
Figure 11.1
This is at the income level Oye, where the intentions curve intersects the dotted 45 line. What
happens, however, if this equilibrium is disturbed?
(a)
(b)
Licensed to ABE
184
stocks rise, and customers are not around to buy the goods and services on offer. Traders
needing money to meet current expenses will cut prices to achieve sales. Firms, seeing stocks
of unsold goods rise, will reduce production, lay off workers and cut overtime working.
Incomes will fall through declining wages and falling business profits. There will be a
movement downwards towards the equilibrium level Oye. Only at this level will there be no
pressures for moving either up or down, because only here does total income = total output =
total expenditure.
They spend because they have income available for spending and because, perhaps, they
expect future incomes to rise.
(ii)
(iii)
They may also spend because they expect prices to rise and the cost of credit may be less
than the amount of the expected price rise.
(iv)
Pressure to spend may also come from advertising and the marketing efforts of firms
wishing to maintain high levels of production and sales. Social attitudes may also
encourage a high level of spending, especially in a period when the level of social
security payments is high and money is losing its value and discouraging saving.
(v)
On the other hand, saving may be encouraged and spending discouraged by falling
incomes and rising unemployment, by controls on credit and the expansion of money,
and by expectations that prices may fall.
(vi)
People may also be forced to spend less and save more in order to pay off or reduce the
burden of past debts after a period of high spending. This tendency was clearly evident
during the early years of the 1990s after the spending and house purchase boom of the
1980s.
(vii) The depressed, low consumption years of the early 1990s also showed the importance of
house purchase as a foundation for general household consumption. When house
purchase and building activity is high and people are moving homes they also spend on
Licensed to ABE
185
house furnishings, household equipment and so on. When there is little activity in the
housing market all these associated household consumer durable markets are depressed.
Employment and incomes fall in the affected industries and the economic depression
deepens.
(viii) Savings may also be contractual, i.e. people undertake to save regular amounts out of
income through schemes arranged with insurance offices, building societies, etc. The
motives for contractual saving are to provide for retirement, for substantial future
purchases, for precautionary motives, or simply because of social habit the belief that
saving is a moral duty.
Some of these motives correspond with the influences on the demand for products, which we
identified in earlier study units. The general influences on total or aggregate spending and
saving can change over time, so that the amount saved from any given volume of income can
also change. Relationships between the amount consumed and saved and total incomes are
examined later in this study unit.
(b)
(ii)
(iii)
the cost of investment is falling and expected to continue to fall the main element in
this being the level of interest rates charged on borrowed finance.
Notice here that the influences on the level of investment are mostly not directly related to the
level of current income. For our purposes at this stage, therefore, we do not regard the level of
investment as being dependent on income levels. This is in contrast to the level of saving
which, provided other influences are constant, is directly related to the level of income.
Note that business firms, in making investment decisions, stress the importance of estimates of future
revenues related to present costs and how these are affected by expectations of future demand levels
and the costs of capital (linked to market rates of interest). You should remember that investment
decisions involve making judgments about the future, about future markets and about future
economic conditions and government policies. The future can never be forecast with accuracy but
the greater the degree of uncertainty about the future the higher are the risks of business investment
and the less the amount of investment undertaken. Political uncertainties and lack of confidence in
Licensed to ABE
186
the government can be as damaging to investment as market uncertainties, the two, in practice, being
closely related.
Licensed to ABE
187
which they believe households will buy for consumption. Remember, too, that prices, and stock
levels, may change as national income moves into equilibrium.
Investment
and savings
Savings
Investment
i
+
o
National
income (Y)
Figure 11.2
Now let us see what happens when there is a change in the level of investment. Look at Figure 11.3.
Here, investment rises, at all income levels, from Oi to Oi1. As a result, we see that the equilibrium
level of income, where actual investment equals actual savings, moves up from Oe to Oe1.
Investment
and savings
Savings
i1
Investment 1
Investment
+
o
e1
National
income (Y)
Figure 11.3
Licensed to ABE
188
Investment
and savings
b
d
Investment 1
i1
i
+
o
Investment
c
e
e1
National
income
e2
Figure 11.4
This shows an increase in the level of investment at all income levels, from Oi to Oi1, but now we
have two savings curves ab and cd. Given the savings curve ab, the increase in investment lifts the
equilibrium level of national income from Oe to Oe1, but, if the savings curve is cd, then the same
increase in investment produces the larger income increase from Oe to Oe2.
We can now state the following.
!
The amount of increase/decrease in national income brought about by the change in investment
will depend on the slope of the savings curve i.e. on the amount of any increase in income
which is saved.
The more acute the angle of the savings curve, the less is the increase in savings from each additional
1 of income. What is really being represented in this diagram is the multiplying effect of an initial
increase in business investment. Suppose that firm A decides to buy an additional machine. This
stimulates activity from the machine manufacturer, who increases production and pays additional
incomes to his workers who, in turn, decide to increase their spending, which stimulates more activity
from other firms, and so on. We can visualise successive rounds of increased activity, but as some
part of each round of extra income is saved, the next round is slightly smaller than the last, until the
increases become too small to be significant, and the progression comes to an end.
The less the amount saved, the greater will be the total increase. For example, suppose there is an
initial increase of 100. The following table shows how this may be multiplied.
Licensed to ABE
189
In column A, 3/4 of each extra round of income is consumed and 1/4 saved, and in column B, 4/5 is
spent on consumption and only 1/5 saved.
A
B
(savings 1/4) (savings 1/5)
Initial
2nd round
3rd round
4th round
5th round
100
75
56
42
32
100
80
64
51
41
Total so far
305
336
These figures are rounded. If we were to produce completely accurate figures and carry on the tables,
we would find that A would arrive at a total of 400 and B at a total of 500. If you have an electronic
calculator, you can test this for yourself. These figures should suggest something to you.
!
An initial increase of 100, increased by successive additions of 3/4, arrives at a final total of
400.
An initial increase of 100, increased by successive additions of 4/5, arrives at a final total of
500.
Putting this another way, if the amount saved or held back from each successive increase is 1/4, then
the initial increase is multiplied by 4; if the successive increases are reduced by 1/5, the initial
increase is multiplied by 5. It looks as though the multiplying effect is the reciprocal of the amount
held back from each successive increase. This, indeed, is the case.
Y
I
1
1
=
s 1 c
Licensed to ABE
190
Y 1
1
= =
J w s + t + m
Suppose that, out of each additional 1 of national income, 1/10 is saved, 3/10 is taxed and 2/10 spent
on imports. Then:
s = 1/10; t = 3/10; m = 2/10
w(s + t + m) = 6/10
K, then, is 1/w which here is 10/6 = 123
a very much smaller value than the investment multiplier, which would have been 10, in this example.
Figure 11.5
Licensed to ABE
191
Figure 11.6
Licensed to ABE
192
Thus, the attempt by the community to save more has resulted in the community actually saving less
because the total level of aggregate income has fallen. Remember this is the result for the community
as a whole. Some individual households will have increased their savings but others will be saving
less because they have suffered loss of income and may will be unemployed as a result of the fall in
national income and aggregate investment. This is the paradox of thrift in action. This is one case
where the macroeconomy, i.e. the economy as a whole behaves differently from the microeconomy,
i.e. individual firms and households. A virtue for the individual is not necessarily a virtue for the
whole community, a concept that some influential politicians have found difficult to grasp.
This example also illustrates the possibility that the fear of recession can become self-fulfilling. If
people anticipate that their incomes are likely to fall in the future and start to save more and consume
less, their actions can lead to reduced production, investment and employment.
Licensed to ABE
193
year 20 new machines ten in order to replace those worn out, and ten additional ones to cope with
the new demand. The demand for machinery will thus increase by 100% because of a mere 10%
increase in demand for consumer goods.
It is the surge in increased investment spending that gives the accelerator its name.
However, there is a danger here. If consumption continues to rise at a constant rate, then investment,
after the initial burst, will stay the same. In order that net productive investment should increase,
consumption has to continue to increase at a faster rate. If it starts to level off, then investment will
fall away. Firms do not need to buy more machines if their production capacity is sufficient to cope
with expected demand. A fall in net investment now starts the accelerator in reverse it becomes a
decelerator, forcing a decline in national income. This decline has been caused by nothing more than
a levelling of demand and a consequent halt in new business investment.
Licensed to ABE
194
amount of additional capital invested, then, we can make a direct comparison between this and the
rate of interest which firms have to pay to obtain capital, which, for the sake of simplicity, we can
equate with the cost of capital.
We can also describe this return on business capital as a measure of the efficiency of that capital.
Thus, the additional return achieved by an additional unit of capital will be the marginal efficiency
of capital (MEC). In the short term, and taking the economy as a whole, we can assume that
additional amounts of capital take place with the total supply of labour and land remaining constant.
Now, if we add additional inputs of one production factor, with the other factors remaining fixed,
then the law of diminishing marginal returns will eventually come into effect. Thus, the greater the
amount of capital already employed, the less will be the marginal efficiency, as more and more capital
is added. We can, therefore, expect the marginal efficiency of capital to fall as the quantity of capital
employed by the community rises. This is illustrated in the graph of Figure 11.7.
Figure 11.7
Licensed to ABE
195
Now, we can also expect profit-maximising firms to seek to employ additional capital, up to the point
where its marginal efficiency, as explained above, is equal to its cost. Thus, the marginal efficiency
of capital curve of Figure 11.8 is also the demand for investment finance curve, assuming that
business as a whole is seeking to maximise profits.
To derive the pure rate of interest, then, we need to relate the supply of capital to the marginal
efficiency curve, and the point where these are at the same quantity level will establish the pure rate
of interest. We can, of course, present the argument in a slightly different way. If we take the view
that the rate of interest is determined by a different set of market forces, or by the government, then
the same reasoning will suggest to us the quantity of capital that will be employed, if investment
finance supply and demand are allowed to reach equilibrium freely.
This idea is illustrated in the model of Figure 11.8, where the equilibrium rate of pure interest is Oi,
and the equilibrium quantity of capital invested where supply = demand is OK.
Figure 11.8
Licensed to ABE
196
an increasing supply. We know, however, that this does not happen. This suggests that the marginal
efficiency of capital curve must also be moving in the long run, to counteract any tendency for a fall.
That this does, in fact, happen is not difficult to imagine and explain. In the long run, the level of
technology is changing and there is an increase in the size of the labour force. It is the increase in the
level of technology that has the main effect, however, on the return earned by additional capital
investment. As long as human beings continue to innovate, to push back the frontiers of knowledge
and of what it is technically possible to achieve, then we can see no reason why the marginal
efficiency should fall in the long run. Given this long-run condition, we can suggest that the demand
for capital is likely to remain high. This does not preclude the possibility that, for limited periods and
for special economic or political reasons, the yield from capital investment will fall and so, the
MEC curve and interest rates will fall, for short periods. There will also be short-run cyclical
movements, caused by the investment accelerator, as described in Section C of this study unit.
It is also likely that investment demand will be higher in some economies than in others. In those
economies where the MEC curve is high, we can expect the demand for capital also to be high. On
the other hand, multinational companies may be able to raise capital in countries where the MEC and
interest rates are low, and employ it where they are higher. Such considerations serve to warn us that
the simple models of Figures 11.7 and 11.8 are not, in themselves, sufficient to give full explanations
of complex finance markets. They do, however, give us a foundation on which we can build more
detailed knowledge.
At this stage you should revise Study Unit 8, with particular reference to interest rates, and give some
thought to the question of a governments freedom to set what interest rates it chooses or thinks is in
the best interests of the economy.
Licensed to ABE
197
the reduced interest rate on the lower diagram. If all the national income equilibrium levels
corresponding to the full range of likely interest rates are recorded we then produce the IS curve as
shown in the lower part of the diagram.
Licensed to ABE
198
Figure 11.9
Notice that a movement along this IS curve represents a movement of equilibrium income produced
by a change in interest rate. If there is a change in the relationship between interest rates and the
level of aggregate demand then there will be a shift in the IS curve. The position and the slope of the
Licensed to ABE
199
IS curve is thus the result of the interaction of interest rates and levels of aggregate demand. The
more responsive the aggregate demand to changes in interest rates the less steep is the slope of the IS
schedule. You can test this easily by moving the curve AD1 higher when you will see that the level
Oe1 will move to the right and the IS curve will get flatter. Thus, a steep IS curve indicates that
aggregate demand is not very responsive to interest rate changes. Dropping AD1 moves Oe1 to the
left and the IS curve becomes steeper.
Figure 11.10
The real money supply is assumed to be fixed at quantity L on the left side of the diagram for a
national income level of Y shown on the right side of the diagram. At this income level the demand
for money balances is represented by the curve LD and demand is equal to supply at the interest rate
Or. At any higher rate demand will be less than supply; at any lower rate demand will be greater than
supply. At a higher income level, say Y1, the demand for money balances rises to LD1 and this
demand is equal to (in equilibrium with) supply at the higher interest rate Or1. Plotting the interest
rates Or and Or1 for the income levels Y and Y1, provides a section of the LM curve which can be
extended by plotting the interest rates for different income levels where the demand for and supply of
money balances are in equilibrium.
Notice that as income levels rise the interest rate required to maintain equilibrium in the money
market also rises. The higher the level of demand for money for each income level, the steeper will
be the LM curve. Also if the demand for money is interest rate inelastic the LM curve is again likely
to be steep. On the other hand if the demand for money is not very responsive to changes in income
Licensed to ABE
200
but interest rate elastic then the LM curve will be flatter. You can check for yourself the effect on the
LM curve of different movements and slopes of the LD curves.
The LM schedule is based on the assumption that the supply of real money is fixed. If there is an
increase in the supply of real money balances the vertical supply curve, L, moves to the right. Clearly
this reduces the interest rates required to bring supply and demand into equilibrium and these changes
will shift the LM curve to the right. This effect is illustrated in Figure 11.11.
Figure 11.11
In this diagram the LM schedule LM is produced from the supply of money, L, and demand for
money LD at income level Y, in equilibrium at interest rate Or. At the higher income level Y1 the
demand for money rises to LD1, and the new equilibrium is achieved at interest rate Or1. When the
supply of money balances rises to L1 the interest rates required to maintain equilibrium between
money demand and supply fall from Or to Or2 and from Or1 to Or3. This fall in interest rates
produces a shift to the right in the LM curve from LM to LM1. This suggests that a higher income
level is required to maintain equilibrium between money supply and demand at each interest rate.
A fall in the money supply can be expected to have the reverse effect, i.e. a reduction in money
balances from L1 to L will shift the LM curve to the left from LM1 to LM.
Licensed to ABE
201
Figure 11.12
Only at income level Y and interest rate Or will both markets be in equilibrium. At higher interest
rates equilibrium in the money market will require higher income levels than those at which there is
equilibrium in the goods market. At lower interest rates money market equilibrium is achieved at
lower income levels than those where there is equilibrium in the goods market.
This model has implications for government policy. If, for example the government injects additional
demand into the real economy and does so without altering the money supply then the additional
demand will shift the IS schedule to the right. This is shown as a shift from IS to IS1 in Figure 11.13.
Since there is no change in money supply the LM schedule remains at LM and the new equilibrium is
achieved at the higher interest rate of Or1 and higher income level Y1. If the government does not
want interest rates to rise it could increase money supply sufficiently to shift the LM curve from LM
to LM1. This will maintain the interest rate at Or and will encourage national income to rise to Y2.
Suppose the government allows money supply to rise, say from LM to LM1 in Figure 11.13, without
any change in government taxes or spending. The IS schedule remains unchanged at IS. The LM
curve moves to the right and a fall in interest rate to Or2 is required to restore full equilibrium at
income level Y1. Thus an increase in the supply of money will reduce interest rates and increase the
equilibrium level of income.
Licensed to ABE
202
Figure 11.13
In practice the government is likely to be cautious over these changes because they are likely to have
further implications. Any change in policy that sets in motion changes in interest rates, aggregate
demand and income levels will create expectations relating to employment, prices and wages and
these are likely to influence the income and demand relationships. Achieving full equilibrium in both
the goods and money markets is a more difficult and uncertain process than the basic IS-LM model
suggests.
Licensed to ABE
203
Study Unit 12
The Deflationary and Inflationary Gaps
Contents
A.
204
204
B.
204
C.
205
Possible Causes
205
Consequences
206
207
208
209
Consequences
210
211
212
Measurement of Unemployment
212
Measurement of Inflation
213
214
217
Special Indices
217
D.
E.
Page
Licensed to ABE
204
Licensed to ABE
205
Figure 12.1
Suppose that possible output of goods and services available for purchase by the community, given
full employment of all those seeking work, would push up income to level Of. However, at this level
of income there is a gap between the 45 line and the C + J curve. This gap indicates that possible
expenditure at this income level is greater than intended spending from the total forces of
consumption, investment, government and exports.
Possible Causes
Strict classical and monetarist economists believe that a deflationary gap would not exist if both
product and factor markets were free to perform their basic functions of bringing supply into
equilibrium with demand through changes in price. Closing a gap by the operation of market forces
alone would imply significant reductions in wages. However, wage incomes are a major influence on
the level of consumer demand so that any large scale reduction in wage levels would further depress
the Consumption element in aggregate demand. Fear of future unemployment and falling incomes
would also depress demand and, of course, business investment so that there is no guarantee that
greater wage flexibility in a modern economy would close the gap. It could make it larger. Actions
of business firms in making workers redundant and deliberately creating an atmosphere of insecurity
Licensed to ABE
206
in their workforces to keep wage levels restrained could be one of the initial causes of the
deflationary gap.
Government action to reduce spending and to reduce the size of the public sector in the economy
could have a similar effect both in reducing the G element in aggregate demand and in undermining
consumer and business confidence in the future of the economy and so causing the gap and making it
wider.
Consequences
The immediate and most visible consequence is a rise in unemployment and lengthening of the time
that the unemployed remain out of work. This is the feature that made the Great Depression of the
1930s such a searing experience for all those who experienced it and which shaped economic and
political attitudes for a generation until memories of the depression became submerged beneath the
more recent and longer-lasting experience of inflation. Long-term unemployment creates severe
social and personal problems as well as being a cruel waste of potentially productive economic
resources. In Keynesian thinking it is something that governments can and should seek to remedy
and preferably avoid altogether.
However, labour is not the only factor of production. In a severe economic depression all factors are
unemployed or underemployed. Land goes out of cultivation, business premises remain empty and
deteriorate and machines lie idle and rust. It would be wrong to compare the British economic
recession of the early 1990s with the 1930s but there are some similarities. We have become familiar
with uncultivated land in the form of land set aside under European Union arrangements an
indication of a European gap between demand and potential supply, and the sight of large numbers of
houses and business premises for sale and to let.
If supply is greater than demand in the factor and major product markets we would expect prices to
fall. In some markets, notably the private house and business property markets, there have been price
reductions. However, property is regarded as a form of wealth rather than as a consumer good and
price reductions for private houses are not welcomed by households in the way that price reductions
for, say, furniture or private cars would be welcomed. People feel poorer when the value of their
homes falls, especially if they have mortgage loans that are larger than their homes current market
values a trend known as negative equity. Under these conditions home movements and
associated purchases are much reduced and, in general consumer spending is depressed.
In the 1930s, most prices fell over several years and many people, including those with secure
employment and/or fixed incomes enjoyed stability and rising living standards. Insecurity and
poverty mainly affected manual workers, especially unskilled workers who had to compete fiercely
for the few jobs which became vacant. The majority of white collar and professional workers, then
a much smaller proportion of the working population than today, were secure and relatively well off.
This increased social divisions and greatly aggravated the class hostilities that were to affect attitudes
in politics and the labour market for much of the next half century.
In the recession of the 1990s, however, insecurity and unemployment is much more widely
distributed through all the occupations and social classes. This is largely because the second
industrial revolution based on microelectronics has had its biggest impact on white-collar workers
and on those whose work involved processing and transferring information and taking fairly routine
decisions based on the flow of information. Computers have taken over most of this work and entire
levels of management and clerical support work have disappeared over a wide range of industries.
Potential aggregate supply has been increased by these technological changes but the rise in
unemployment, much of it concealed by widespread early retirement has kept consumer demand
constrained so that the 1990s have been marked by a persistent deflationary gap. Although money
Licensed to ABE
207
wage levels, on average, have not generally fallen, by the mid 1990s, annual rises were very much
lower than those considered normal in the previous two decades. This deflationary gap has helped to
widen the gap between the highest and lowest income earners but between these extremes the average
differences are still relatively small and most workers have been affected by an increased level of job
insecurity.
Figure 12.2
Since business investment (I) levels are a consequence of firms experience of past and current
consumer demand and their view of the probable future trend of this demand and are also dependent
on net export levels, the potential for lifting I when C is depressed is limited. However, there is one
other element within total aggregate demand which is not necessarily an inevitable part of the
business cycle government spending (G). Government spending is the result of political decisions
that can be taken independently of the national income and consumer demand, if the government
abandons the principle of the balanced budget (spending = taxation revenue). This, of course, is
government spending on such projects as road and communications development.
The possible result of increasing government spending is shown by the movement in the C + J curve
in Figure 12.1. Here, we see that the rise from C + J to C + J1, brought about by an increase in
government spending, is able to close the deflationary gap and remove large-scale unemployment.
This, very broadly, was the type of remedy advocated by Keynes for the massive unemployment
problem of the 1930s.
Licensed to ABE
208
Unemployment in Britain did start to fall when government spending began to increase in the face of
approaching war, in the late 1930s. However, a remedy that was developed in the 1930s does not
necessarily apply quite so simply in the very different economic conditions of today, and we need to
examine the whole problem much more carefully (which we shall do in subsequent study units).
Modern Keynesians now recognise that continued demand stimulation policies aimed at closing the
deflationary gap by accepting an unbalanced budget and relatively high levels of government
borrowing can have inflationary effects leading eventually to the problem of stagflation when both
unemployment and prices rise together.
Keynesians now accept that the demand-management policies of the 1950s and 1960s contributed to
the high inflation suffered in the 1970s. Most are prepared to agree that they had understated a
number of consequences of government measures to keep unemployment low. These included:
!
The rapid expansion of the public sector fed by injections of government spending and relative
contraction of the private sector as this became uncompetitive in world markets. Expansion of
public spending beyond the capacity of tax revenues to sustain it led to large amounts of
government borrowing. These combined to increase inflationary pressures in the economy.
Long periods of low unemployment and a belief that governments would always act to avoid
high unemployment gave labour unions an inflated view of their own power. Union pressure to
raise wages and achieve generous legislation to provide job security in spite of increased
competition in world markets aggravated the problem of stagflation and delayed the
improvements in labour productivity that were needed to increase domestic production and
slow down the decline in exports and rises in imports experienced during the 1970s.
Modern Keynesians also recognise that the technological revolution of microelectronics has
fundamentally changed the structure of industry and shifted the long-run labour to capital ratio in
modern production in favour of capital. They accept, therefore, that the very low levels of
unemployment of the 1950s and 1960s are unlikely to return in the foreseeable future and that
industrial practices have to become more efficient if firms are to compete successfully in world
markets.
At the same time, Keynesians have retained their basic belief in the duty and ability of government to
intervene to mitigate the social effects of economic cycles and the consequences of technological
change. They do not believe that unregulated markets will always lead to equilibrium conditions
acceptable to modern society and they continue to place importance on the public sector provision of
those goods and services that are inadequately provided by private sector markets.
Licensed to ABE
209
Figure 12.3
Here, total demand, from all the forces represented by the C + J curve, is forcing an equilibrium level
of national income above the level of total production and real spending that is possible given full
employment at income level Of. The pressure to buy goods and services that are not being produced
forces up prices. In this situation, total spending intentions cannot be fulfilled, so that actual
spending is lower than intended.
Licensed to ABE
210
(b)
Why, if it is the function of a market economy for supply to respond to demand, is the
production system unable to meet total demand?
In their extreme forms, Keynesians and Monetarists have given conflicting answers to these
questions. Today, they are closer together but still place different emphasis on different aspects. At
this stage these differences are just outlined.
Keynesians have blamed excess demand on excess income which is running ahead of potential
production. More recently they have been prepared to accept that money supply and government
borrowing have also played a significant part in stimulating demand.
Monetarists have tended to blame excessive demand on excess money supply for reasons that are
explained later but they have also linked this with rising wage levels made possible by business
borrowing. They have also linked excess money supply to government spending and borrowing.
The original Keynesian model of the inflationary gap assumed that the production system could
respond to rising demand up to the point where all production factors were fully employed. A
significant inflationary gap would only appear when the equilibrium level of national product rose
above the full employment level. This basic model offered little scope for a convincing explanation
for the stagflation of the 1970s and early 1980s when both inflation and unemployment were rising.
Consequently Keynesians have had to accept deficiencies in the production system at levels below
full employment. As already explained they have tended to emphasise problems arising from a period
of rapid structural change caused by the contemporary technological revolution.
Monetarists have traditionally been more prepared to see inflation and unemployment as associated
rather than opposing problems of a troubled economy. Not only do they regard inflation as a cause of
unemployment because of its effect on business productivity and ability to compete in world markets
but they also see inflation as being partly caused by defects in the supply side of the economy that
encourages people to remain unemployed even though there is excess demand in the economy.
Inefficient factor markets permit unused production capacity to remain unused in spite of high levels
of demand. However, they have had to recognise the deflationary and unemployment consequences
of their monetary and market reform/supply side policies aimed at reducing inflation. Inflation
control has proved a far more difficult economic and social problem than the monetarists anticipated.
Consequences
In the 1950s and early 1960s when inflation rates were low by later standards and when the economy
was growing at unexpectedly encouraging levels, it was not uncommon for observers to comment that
a low rate of inflation might be healthy and stimulating for an economy. However, as earlier
explained, inflation tends to feed on itself and can suddenly rise out of control unless measures are
taken to impose checks. The common socio-economic problems arising from inflation have tended to
be identified as:
!
Countries with inflation rates higher than their trading partners and/or rivals soon price
themselves out of increasingly competitive world markets. Exports fall and imports rise so that
an international payments problem undermines the currency in ways that are discussed more
fully in a later unit. To this extent inflation leads to rising unemployment.
Confidence is lost in the stability of the domestic currency and financial structure. Savings fall
and there is a flight of capital in spite of any financial exchange controls that might be
imposed. In extreme cases a flight from money to physical goods fuels further inflation.
As long as most incomes rise faster than prices people can be misled by an impression of rising
wealth, particularly when high value fixed assets such as houses and land gain high monetary
values. However, as more and more sections of the population fail to maintain the real
Licensed to ABE
211
(inflation adjusted) value of their incomes and living standards fall for a growing number of
people there is a big increase in social discontent. In extreme cases there is civil conflict,
destruction of property and loss of lives. At this stage there is a danger of complete social and
political breakdown with unpredictable consequences.
During the period of high and rising inflation of the 1970s there were still those who defended
inflation as being preferable to high unemployment and who argued that there would be no
undesirable consequences if all financial payments and obligations were to be index linked, i.e. if
all monetary values were periodically adjusted by an agreed inflation measure. Some even argued
that this would itself gradually bring down the rate of inflation since there would be nothing to gain
from raising prices when costs also rose at the same rate.
In practice, experience soon showed that although some degree of indexation was able to preserve the
value of some obligations such as real yields on savings and the purchasing power of pensions,
inflation itself is too complex and uneven in its effects for it to be simply indexed away into
insignificance. It also became clear that the low inflation countries such as Germany and Japan were
able to enjoy more successful economic growth and higher living standards than the high inflation
countries such as Britain and Italy. Indexation was, of course, no cure for the international trade
problems of the high inflation countries.
By the 1980s there was widespread agreement throughout Western Europe that inflation was a major
economic problem that governments had to solve and there was sufficient popular support for this
that governments could risk taking measures that they knew would increase unemployment. Few
people recognised the full implications of the anti-inflation policies they were embarking on. People
were prepared to tolerate high unemployment largely because the social consequences of being
without a job had been much reduced by the social welfare provisions that had been made possible by
a prolonged period of relatively high economic growth and a demographic and economic structure
that kept a rising proportion of older people small in relation to the large numbers of economically
active people born in the baby boom post second world war years and the growth in numbers of
working women.
By the 1990s, however, social, economic and demographic conditions were changing. Economic
growth, in the face of increased competition from the newer industrial nations, especially those in
Asia, was likely to slow and the cost of the social welfare structure was becoming a heavy burden.
Cuts would have to be made if heavy taxes and government borrowing were to be avoided. People
started to re-learn the social hardships of unemployment and these hardships were no longer confined
to the low paid manual workers. In the early years of the next century governments would face the
added burden of a rapidly rising proportion of economically inactive older people with costly health
care needs, as the post-war babies started to approach retirement age or were being forced into early
retirement by governments anxious to increase business efficiency without too high a rise in
published measures of unemployment. By the mid-1990s most Western European countries were
starting to cut social welfare obligations reversing the trend of the previous half century.
Licensed to ABE
212
seized on prices and incomes policies as offering a politically acceptable escape from the dilemma.
The policies depended on restraint from employers, labour unions and the governments in an attempt
to keep income increases close to the rate of economic growth, i.e. they sought to keep the rise in
demand as close as possible to the rate of production (supply) increase.
The failure of these policies left Keynesians with little credible and politically acceptable answer to
inflation and prepared the way for a fresh approach from a government influenced by monetaristclassical economic beliefs. The new policies were based on measures to remove impediments to the
interaction of supply and demand in both product and factor markets, weakening the influence and
reducing the relative spending and borrowing of the government and tolerating a degree of
unemployment in the effort to make the supply side of the economy more efficient and competitive in
world markets. Supporters of these policies can claim some success in closing the inflationary gap
but this success has not been rewarded by political popularity. This lack of success is due to several
factors including:
!
the widening gap between the very rich and very poor and increased employment insecurity
among all sections of the working population;
the reduction in asset, especially private home, values and the very great hardship this has
brought to large numbers of people who became first time home owners in the 1980s;
an increasing realisation that the social welfare structure constructed over the past half century
is under threat of being dismantled.
These three developments together have created a climate of uncertainty and real fear of the future.
For the past five decades people have believed that general living standards were rising and would
continue to rise in spite of temporary difficulties. People expected their personal incomes and wealth
to rise while sharing in general improvements to the State provision of social welfare. These
expectations are now being reversed. The burden of taxation has not been significantly reduced. In
total it was increased but more and more people are being expected to contribute to the cost of their
childrens education, to their own health care and to their own future pensions. In this general
environment of increasing insecurity people are understandably thinking that far too high a price has
been paid for what may yet prove to be a brief and temporary relief from inflation.
Measurement of Unemployment
There can be no accurate measurement unless we are clear about what precisely is being measured.
People are unemployed if they think of themselves as unemployed, i.e. if they seriously want to work,
are prepared to work but cannot find a job. Even this very simple attempt at a definition presents
problems. If a person is trained as an architect and is fully qualified to work as an architect but can
only obtain a job as a building labourer, waitress or shop assistant, that person, quite understandably
is likely to consider himself or herself as unemployed but will not be registered as such in official
records. Another person may have left the workforce to have a family and bring up young children
Licensed to ABE
213
and then, after some years seek to return to employment but find it impossible to obtain suitable
employment. Yet another may have been put under considerable pressure by an employer to accept
voluntary early retirement and may be receiving an employment pension but, should the
opportunity arise would prefer to be employed. None of these is likely to appear in the official
figures of the unemployed in Britain and other countries using roughly similar measures to those in
Britain.
British unemployment figures are based on those registered, and entitled to receive unemployment or
social welfare benefits as unemployed. Consequently it is frequently argued that these official figures
significantly underestimate the true unemployment total because they do not include those who are
not entitled or likely to become entitled to benefits and who are not, therefore registered. These
include those:
(a)
who have been out of the workforce for some years (mainly women), or who have never been
regularly employed, but who seriously wish to enter employment but cannot find work;
(b)
who have retired before the normal retirement age and who, if aged 60 or over are not
registered as unemployed. Many people under the age of 60, in receipt of pensions or other
incomes over a certain figure will also be ineligible for unemployment benefits and are
unlikely to appear in unemployment figures;
(c)
who would wish to be fully or regularly employed if they had the opportunity but are in
currently part time or temporary employment. This group includes many women and older
men and also young people in work experience or training schemes;
(d)
who would wish to be in employment if work were available but are remaining in full-time
education.
At the same time it is also argued that the official British figures may overstate the true amount of
unemployment by including some who receive benefit but who are not seeking work. These would
include people who:
(e)
intend to withdraw from the workforce for some time, for personal or family reasons but who
are entitled to unemployment benefits for a limited period;
(f)
No one knows the actual size of any of these groups and estimates vary considerably. The true size of
the unemployed population is thus not known though changes in the figure for the recorded
unemployed are likely to be a reasonably accurate indication of changes in the true total.
Some countries, including the USA, base their unemployment figures on estimates obtained from
regular surveys. These figures will include people who are not entitled to social welfare payments
but they arouse even more suspicions of official manipulation than totals based on the officially
registered.
Measurement of Inflation
In most countries official figures intended to measure inflation are obtained from some kind of index
of price movements. It is, therefore, price, rather than wage inflation that is normally measured. As
with unemployment statistics, the methods of compiling the price indices, their content and the
recording of price changes differ considerably between countries. Comparisons which do not take
into account these differences can be misleading.
Licensed to ABE
214
The measure most commonly quoted in Britain is the All Items Index of Retail Prices. This is a
weighted average of separate price indices for different classes of goods and services. The weights
are revised annually in the light of information provided by a continuous survey of household
expenditure which records the spending habits of a sample selection of households in the country.
1968
1984
1986
All items
1,000
1,000
1,000
263
201
185
Alcoholic drink
63
75
82
Tobacco
66
36
40
Housing
121
149
153
62
65
62
59
69
63
89
70
75
120
158
157
Miscellaneous goods
60
76
81
Services
56
65
58
41
36
44
Food
Notice the increased importance of spending on services, housing, durable household goods
and transport; the reduced importance of spending on the basic necessities of food, clothing
and footwear; and the very steep relative fall of spending on tobacco. The group weights were
used to calculate the all items price change and it was this figure which was quoted so
extensively.
The basis of weighting and some of the elements of the Index were changed in 1987 and a new
Index commenced on 13 January 1987. Consequently, figures post 1986 are not comparable
with those up to that year. Table 12.2 shows the new main classes for which monthly figures
are produced. It is clear from these that pre-1987 trends have largely continued.
Licensed to ABE
215
Table 12.2
Revised Weightings for the Retail Price Index
1987
1990
1992
1995
1,000
1,000
1,000
1,000
213
205
199
184
114
111
116
111
335
346
344
356
Personal expenditure
112
108
99
93
226
230
242
256
974
976
978
978
833
842
848
861
26
24
22
22
Non-seasonal food
141
134
130
117
843
815
828
57
139
132
127
123
Total weights
Seasonal food
Nationalised industries
Consumer durables
(c)
The movement of the all items Index to 1987 is shown in Figure 12.4. This shows the very steep
rise in inflation in the period 1974-1987 in Great Britain.
Licensed to ABE
216
1988
106.9
1989
115.2
1990
126.1
1991
133.5
1992
138.5
1993
140.7
1994
144.1
Notice that people have continued to spend an increased proportion of their income on housing and
household expenditure and on travel and leisure, while the proportion of income spent on food,
alcohol and tobacco has continued to fall.
Licensed to ABE
217
These, of course, are very broad averages and by no means all people follow the general trend.
Nevertheless, it is clear that the main direction of spending towards services and housing, with
food, clothing and other basic goods taking up a smaller proportion of total spending has been
roughly the same for many years. Remember that these figures concern the proportion of total
spending. People may be spending more money on food but as incomes rise food can still make up a
smaller proportion of total expenditure.
Special Indices
Some of the class indices that make up the all items index are used by business organisations when
these are more relevant to their needs than the more general average. For example, some insurance
offices have used the consumer durables price index as a basis for index linking household contents
insurance policies.
Licensed to ABE
218
A number of professional and trade bodies keep their own indices of prices that are important to
them. An example of such an index is the House Rebuilding Cost Index published by the Building
Cost Information Service of the Royal Institution of Chartered Surveyors. This index is used by
many insurance offices for index linking household building insurance policies.
When compiling the Retail Price Index the official British statistical services disregard the recorded
spending of very low and very high income households, the precise income limits being revised
regularly. The reason for this is that their spending patterns are not typical of the main body of the
population. Nevertheless, it is recognised that the government and those concerned with low income
families need to know how these families are affected by price movements and how these movements
relate to changes in pensions and social welfare payments. A high proportion of low income
households are those of the elderly, especially those pensioners with little income other than the basic
State pension. Attempts are, therefore, made to maintain a separate pensioners index based on the
recorded spending habits of pensioners. These efforts are sometimes criticised on the grounds that
the different spending pattern of pensioners is the result of their relatively low incomes. Most would
probably adopt a different expenditure pattern if they could afford to do so. Thus, to have a separate
pensioners index and to use this as a basis for adjusting pensions would simply reinforce the
disadvantages suffered by this group. Moreover, as a result of the changing pattern of retirement the
term pensioner is becoming much harder to define. It no longer relates just to those over the
qualifying age for State pensions but includes large numbers of younger people who have taken, or
been pressured into taking early retirement and other older workers made redundant and unable to
return to the workforce. The range of incomes of pensioners is also much wider than in the past.
Although the majority are still wholly or mainly dependent on State benefits, a growing number now
have substantial occupational pensions. It is still true that the spending patterns of older people are
likely to differ significantly from those of younger people, but earlier assumptions that a pensioner
was someone living on a bare subsistence income, most of which was spent on food and household
fuel, no longer applies to large numbers of those who regard themselves as pensioners.
We should always remember that all indices are averages and they do not necessarily record the
experiences of any particular individual or group of individuals. Nevertheless, they do provide a
means of measuring actual price movements in a systematic way and as long as people understand
their limitations they are extremely helpful to those who seek to serve the community either through
business or public administration.
Licensed to ABE
219
Study Unit 13
Classical and Monetarist Economics
Contents
A.
220
B.
221
C.
223
D.
224
224
225
226
226
227
228
228
229
Theoretical Problems
229
Practical Problems
229
E.
F.
Page
Licensed to ABE
220
Licensed to ABE
221
they regard supply side reforms in the structure of factor, especially labour, markets to be crucial to
success in improving economic efficiency and curing inflation. Because of the social and political
consequences of high unemployment, there can be only a gradual return to a full employment
equilibrium, so that, from a position of rapid monetary expansion and inflation, a government must
gain gradual control over money supply, and bring it down gradually by allowing smaller and smaller
successive increases over a period of time. Trade-union and big-business power may be among the
causes of slow reaction time in a modern economy but they cannot be wished away, and it is better to
adopt gradualist policies than to risk a severe recession.
Licensed to ABE
222
During the 1980s more attention in Britain was paid towards efforts to make labour markets more
flexible by reducing the power of trade unions and making them more accountable to the wishes of
their members. It was felt that unions were preventing wage levels from reflecting changing
conditions of demand and supply in labour markets and encouraging attitudes among workers that
encouraged them to resist change and made them less adaptable to changing technology and the
movement of labour market forces.
It was argued that unemployment was increased by unions and by outdated labour attitudes and
practices. This is illustrated in Figure 13.1.
Figure 13.1
This model shows the demand for labour curve and a supply curve (Supply of Workers) to the left of
the curve representing the total Work Force (defined as the total of workers in employment added to
those officially registered as unemployed and claiming unemployment benefits). The supply curve
indicates a supply below the work force because some people will be out of work for frictional
reasons, for structural reasons (demand shifts and changes in production technology) and because of
worker reluctance to accept the full implications of changes in the labour market. It is not difficult to
understand this reluctance. A worker who has enjoyed a skilled and respected job for many years
loses income, social standing and self-respect when that skill is destroyed by changes in production
Licensed to ABE
223
Union power should be reduced so that they are unable to push the wage rate above the
equilibrium level and so unable to create the kind of involuntary unemployment represented by
the E-D gap of Figure 13.1. In Britain a series of statutes in the 1980s reduced union
immunities and made it more difficult for them to take industrial action without first ensuring
that they had the support of a majority of members obtained by fairly conducted ballot.
Licensed to ABE
224
Individual workers should be put under greater pressure to take jobs that are available even at
lower wage levels. In Britain the governments of the 1980s felt that workers were able to stay
unemployed longer than was desirable from an economic viewpoint, because of the financial
protection afforded by rights to a range of unemployment and social security payments. The
range and scale of these benefits have been reduced by a series of measures in the 1980s and
1990s. In 1995 the British Government announced the withdrawal of some important rights to
housing benefits for unemployed workers with mortgage liabilities. However this development
has put increased pressure on an already depressed housing market and seems likely to increase
unemployment by reducing product demand and hence the demand for labour in the many
product markets associated with housing. One of the arguments for earlier Keynesian inspired
measures for maintaining income levels for those out of work was that these helped to prevent
falls in household consumption and this held up aggregate demand and the demand for labour.
It appears that, by 1995, the monetarist measures to restore market forces and pressures to
labour markets were recreating the kind of problems which had led to the Keynesian demandmanagement policies of the 1950s and leading to renewed interest in Keynesian models.
Employers should be put under pressure to prevent them meeting union demands for wage
rises. It was argued that firms were able to finance wage claims by borrowing until they were
able to adjust prices. Consequently if credit were made more expensive firms would find it
more difficult to do this and would have more incentive to resist paying higher wages. The fact
that their capital costs were increased would also put them under pressure to reduce their
labour costs. This element in the monetarist anti-inflationary policy leads to the core of
monetarist thinking and this is examined in the next section.
Licensed to ABE
225
There is a further modification that many modern monetarists would make to this argument. This
recognises that prices tend to be flexible upwards but not downwards: thus, it is argued, if money
supply is increased, then average prices will rise as already indicated; however, if money supply is
reduced sharply, then prices do not fall. The variable that has to give in this situation is T (or Q), i.e.
total output in the economy, as firms cut back production and consequently employ fewer workers.
The implication of this is that an attempt to cure inflation by a sudden and sharp reduction in money
supply will tend instead to an increase in unemployment rather than a check or reversal in price rises.
The reasons for this ratchet effect for prices are that large firms are reluctant to reduce their product
prices, and trade unions and workers resist strongly any suggestion of a reduction in wages.
Licensed to ABE
226
Price
Supply
D1
D
P1
P
D1
D
A similar implication follows from the money equation if we assume that, when money supply falls,
prices do not fall. Then, if V continues to be constant, it is T (or Q) that has to be reduced to restore
the equation. A reduction in total quantity of goods and services has the same effect of reducing
employment.
It is not, of course, necessary to take the extreme position of assuming that supply is vertical in the
face of shifts in demand, to accept that much of the result of an increase in demand will be felt in
price rises. If you simply make the supply curve steeply-sloping, then, although the consequences are
a little less extreme, there is still a major increase in price or a shift in supply, if you examine a
demand fall.
Licensed to ABE
227
may be expected to lend less. If the banks lend less, then the volume of deposits will rise more
slowly, and money expansion may be checked.
A government may, therefore, seek to influence general interest rates. Until August 1981, the Bank of
England set its own minimum lending rate (MLR). This was the rate at which it was prepared to lend
money to other approved banks and, because the Bank of England is at the centre of the banking and
financial system, all other rates had to follow any change in MLR. The Bank of England no longer
announces a set minimum lending rate but it still operates as the lender of last resort to the banking
system, and is able to influence the interest rates charged by the main banks.
From about 1985, it became clear that the British government was exerting stronger control on
interest rates through the Bank of England. By 1989, the Bank of England was making little attempt
to conceal occasions when it was putting pressure on the commercial banks to raise interest rates and
the Chancellor was no longer pretending that this was not an active instrument, perhaps the only
instrument, of Government monetary policy, particularly when severe inflation returned in 1988/9.
When, however, the problem had changed to one of rising unemployment and falling business output
in the early 1990s the Government again sought to use interest rates to revive the economy. Once
forced out of the European Monetary System in the Autumn of 1992, the government used its
influence to bring interest rates down in an attempt to revive both consumer and business confidence.
In the mid-1990s, the Chancellor of the Exchequer responded to calls that the Bank of England
should be given more independence over its handling of monetary policy by undertaking to publish
(after a delay of six weeks) the minutes of his regular monthly meeting with the Governor of the Bank
of England. This gave greater prominence to these meetings and ensured that any disagreement over
interest rate policy between the Government and the Bank would be open to public debate and the
Chancellor would have to have sound reasons for overriding the wishes of the Bank. That there are
likely to be disagreements from time to time is not surprising. The Banks duty is to pursue one
element of economic policy only to curb inflation. The Bank is not under any obligation to take
account of any wider economic or social consequences of policies designed to control inflation. The
Government must, of course take all considerations into account, especially the possible effects on
unemployment, foreign trade and conditions in the domestic housing market. In the view of the
British Government the full economic responsibilities of government cannot be passed over to an
institution such as the central bank which has only a limited economic function.
It may withdraw certain assets from the banks, and so force them to call in loans to replace
necessary cash requirements. The Bank of England, for example, has the power to call for
special deposits to be made by the banks, and to disallow inclusion of these deposits in any
necessary banking ratios. Under the 1981 regulations, all institutions with normal customer
deposits of 10m or more are required to hold % of these deposits in the form of non-interestbearing balances at the Bank of England.
(b)
It may itself establish which ratios the banks should maintain, and define which assets
should be included in which ratios. Before 1981, a reserve/assets ratio was set for British
banks by the Bank of England. (This was abandoned in 1981 but fresh measures could be
introduced, if thought desirable.)
Licensed to ABE
228
(c)
It may influence ratios by its own actions the central bank may conduct open-market
operations. These involve buying and selling government securities on the open market. The
Bank of England always keeps a store of government bonds (known as tap stock because the
Bank can release or hold stock like turning a tap on and off). If it offers some of its tap stock to
the public at an attractive price, people will buy and pay for the bonds with cheques drawn on
commercial banks. In this way, money can be withdrawn from the commercial banking system
and kept in the central bank. If the Bank buys bonds, then the opposite happens, and the supply
of money in the commercial banking system is increased. (In Britain, open-market operations
are used more to influence the day-to-day supply of money required by commerce, rather than
to impose major credit or monetary controls.)
Licensed to ABE
F.
229
Theoretical Problems
The first problem faced by monetarists is that their basic theory is not generally accepted by all
economists. No one doubts that a massive increase in the supply of money without any
corresponding increase in the output of goods and services will result in an increase in prices, but it is
the closeness and inevitability of the relationship between increases in money supply, increases in
total demand and increases in prices that Keynesians and others find hard to accept; and some of the
other implications of monetarism, particularly those relating to unemployment, arouse considerable
dislike.
You might think that this argument should be fairly easy to settle. After all, if the relationship
between money supply and prices is so close, then it should be easy to prove by reasonably simple
statistical analysis. Unfortunately, proof is not so simple. As already noted, there is disagreement,
even among monetarists, regarding the speed with which the economy adjusts to changes in money
supply, and the introduction of time-lags between these changes and changes in prices makes
certainty difficult to achieve. Professor Friedman, among others, has shown clearly that there is a
close correlation between increases in money supply and price increases but, because of the timeintervals between the two sets of changes, this does not prove that a change in money supply must
always increase prices to a particular extent. If a close correlation is found between two sets or series
of data (say, between A and B), then there are the following possibilities.
Changes in A cause changes in B; changes in B cause changes in A; changes in both A and B are
caused by some other influence, say C; the correlation is accidental, so that A and B are not closely
related at all.
It is possible, therefore, that the correlation between money-supply rises and price rises is the result
of the expansion of money, made necessary by the increased prices caused by some other force.
Practical Problems
There are further problems, in the sense that money, as we have seen, is difficult to measure, and even
more difficult to control.
Monetarists are sometimes accused of choosing whatever measure of money most closely appears to
suit their particular purpose, and changing the measure when it no longer serves that purpose. The
British government has, several times, changed the measure used as the basis for its various monetary
targets. In the early 1990s it was publishing two measures, M0 for narrow money and M4 for broad
money (including building society deposits), but by this time it was admitting that attempts to base
policy on the performance of just a very few economic indicators were likely to be self-defeating. It
claimed that the measures of money supply were just two of a range of indicators that needed to be
taken into account when taking economic policy decisions.
Controlling the money supply has proved extremely difficult for many governments. The problem
tends to revolve around what is known as disintermediation.
When banks carry out their normal functions of lending to one set of customers the money deposited
with them by others, they are acting as intermediaries. If, because of government attempts to control
the money supply, their normal lending operations are put under strict controls, with penalties for
lending above stated limits, then disintermediation tends to take place. This takes three main forms:
Licensed to ABE
230
(a)
Firms develop ways of lending between themselves without the intervention of banks, by
simply extending trade credit or arranging deals whereby the debt of A to B is transferred to
enable B to settle his liabilities to C.
(b)
The business of lending and arranging credit passes from the controlled banks to other
financial institutions which are outside the existing credit controls; the growth of secondary
banking in the 1960s and 1970s owes much to the limitations placed on the activities of the
primary banks by governments seeking to control bank lending, and hence the money supply.
(c)
The banks themselves develop new ways to create credit that are outside the existing control
regulations. Among the more notorious devices used by British banks was the expansion of
commercial bills of exchange to evade controls over the simpler lending by overdraft.
The modern financial system has become so sophisticated and complex that attempts to impose tight
controls of lending and credit creation are likely to lead to increasingly devious methods of
disintermediation, with the main consequence that the price of borrowing and handling money is
pushed up, and borrowing by new and adventurous firms tends to be stopped, while established firms
which have forged close links with their banks or which have their own connections with the finance
markets have no trouble in acquiring the finance they desire.
Attempts to control money supply have been compared with efforts to squeeze a balloon. Such
efforts serve only to distort its shape; the amount of air in the balloon remains unchanged.
Some attempts to achieve monetary controls have failed because these have tended to put pressure on
the private sector of the economy while, at the same time, the government itself has been increasing
its own borrowing and, in so far as this borrowing has involved the issue of Treasury bills and bonds
which have been taken up by the banks, this has increased bank credit and the money supply.
The only effective way of restricting money supply appears to be the use of interest rates but these
have such a wide and indiscriminate effect that, as had become clear by 1992, they can turn inflation
into severe recession with all the social misery that results from high unemployment and the
repossession of peoples homes. By the mid 1990s there were very few economists prepared to claim
that a government could manage a modern economy using only monetary instruments of control.
Licensed to ABE
231
Study Unit 14
Government and the National Product
Contents
A.
B.
C.
Page
232
232
233
234
236
Types of Tax
236
237
238
239
240
240
241
242
243
243
244
Licensed to ABE
232
Licensed to ABE
233
12,633
4.63
Defence
24,384
8.94
14,979
5.49
Education
33,885
12.42
Health
36,863
13.51
Social security
93,180
34.15
10,939
4.01
3,705
1.36
954
0.35
3,930
1.44
1,529
0.56
6,838
2.51
4,977
1.82
24,053
8.82
272,849
100.00
Other expenditure
(mostly debt interest and non-trading capital consumption)
Total expenditure
60.08%
(apparent error
due to rounding)
Total general government expenditure (at current prices) for 1993 is broken down into broad classes
in the above table. This shows very clearly that a little over 60% of the total is accounted for by just
three major areas of spending. These are:
!
social security (which by itself accounts for over a third of all spending);
health; and
education.
It is not difficult to understand why these three sectors all feature so often as topics of political
controversy. It is not just monetarist economic theorists that are concerned about the amount of
social security spending. Any responsible government has to examine this huge element in its budget
and we have to recognise that the same problem now faces all the Western market economies which
developed strong social welfare structures in the years of strong economic growth and relatively
young, vigorous populations in the period 1950-1975.
However, when we try to learn from the Blue Book of United Kingdom National Accounts more
precise details of this social security spending the picture becomes a little confused. In view of the
importance of this item the confusion is rather disappointing. The total 1993 amount of 93,180
Licensed to ABE
234
million for social security expenditure is dominated by 80,392 million described as current grants
to the personal sector, i.e. they are transfer payments of one kind or another. Clearly they include
unemployment benefit, childrens allowances, social welfare payments and state pensions.
Unfortunately it is not possible from the Blue Book tables to produce a breakdown of benefits that
fits the total figure of 80,392 million. By far the largest amount is termed social security funds
benefits and this is made up of such items as retirement pensions, widows benefits relating to
unemployment, sickness, invalidity, maternity and so on. Supplementary benefit and income support
payments are another large item in social security spending. The largest single item appears to be for
retirement pensions. Again we can understand the concern of Western governments at the
implications to their budgets of the bulge in the number of elderly people expected from around the
years 2010 onwards and their anxiety to change the pension rules while the proportion of older voters
remains small enough to override without too rough a political storm.
raising revenue from taxes or the sale of licences (permissions to carry out restricted
activities);
borrowing
(a)
Selling Assets
The most notable modern example of this has been the British privatisation programme for the
nationalised industries, mostly public utilities and major companies which had been taken over
by the State for various reasons in the past. It proved such a fruitful source of finance in the
1980s that other governments have sought to copy this example. If there is one certainty in
political life it is that when one government discovers a rich source of funds others, whatever
their political complexion, will certainly copy it. The only problem with this course of action
is that assets, once sold are not available for sale again. By 1995, there were no significant
trouble-free assets left for the British Government to sell. The nations family silver had
gone. If some enterprising politician can discover a way to sell the equivalent of homing
pigeons no doubt the attempt will be made. A near equivalent might be for a future government
to change the ordinary shares in the privatised utilities into fixed term debentures which could
be reissued periodically in constantly devalued currency.
Licensed to ABE
(b)
235
(c)
taxes on income roughly equivalent to what economists like to call direct taxes;
local taxes unlike some countries Britain has only one major local tax which is now
levied on the ownership and occupation of property and is known as the Council Tax.
These taxes and their economic implications are examined more fully in the next section of this
unit.
(d)
Licensed to ABE
236
Direct Taxes
These are called direct because they are levied directly on to people in accordance with the
income they receive or the wealth they create, inherit or transfer. Income tax itself is the main
generator of revenue for the government in this class and the most direct since all employees
have the tax deducted from their pay by employers who act as tax collectors for the
government. The earnings of the self-employed and those with investment income are assessed
separately. The British government is currently moving towards a system of self-assessment
similar to that operated in the USA.
Limited companies are legal entities in their own right and corporation tax is levied on their
profits. This is another major direct tax.
Government statistics treat taxes on capital as a separate class but for our purposes we can
regard them as direct taxes. The main types are capital gains tax, levied when financial and
physical assets are transferred and inheritance tax, levied on the estates of people when they
die. Recognition that capital gains tax is a form of income tax is implicit in the move by the
British Government in the summer of 1995 to tax the capital gains of investors in the
Governments bonds (known as gilts, or gilt-edged securities) as income.
The locally levied and collected council tax can also be regarded as a direct tax. It is a tax on
the ownership or occupation of property and rights to property have traditionally been regarded
as a form of income or wealth. It is also similar to an income or wealth tax in that the more
valuable the property owned the higher the amount of tax likely to be paid.
(b)
Indirect Taxes
These are called indirect because they are not levied directly on the people who eventually
bear the burden, or incidence of the tax but are levied on goods or services when they are
traded. They thus become a production cost which, along with all other costs, has to be
included within the price charged to the ultimate consumer.
Most are taxes on expenditure levied at some stage when goods or services are traded. The
best known is Value Added Tax (VAT). As goods pass between firms as they go through the
production process each firm purchasing goods and services pays VAT but is able to offset the
tax paid against the tax it collects when the goods are sold on to the next firm or to the
consumer. In effect, therefore, firms pay just the amount of tax levied on the value they add to
the inputs they purchase. Only the final consumer has to pay tax levied on the full, final total
value.
Other common taxes include customs duty paid when foreign goods enter the country, or in the
case of members of the European Union (EU), when goods produced outside the EU enter the
EU for the first time. Some goods, such as beers and wines are taxed when they are first
produced and these taxes are known as excise duty. A number of goods are subject to special
taxes. These include motor vehicles and hydrocarbon oils.
Although there is supposed to be a single EU market in goods (but not services) member
countries levy taxes, including VAT, at different rates and this provides considerable
Licensed to ABE
237
opportunities for smuggling and corrupt practices. This is not a new problem. Throughout
recorded history governments have constantly devised new forms of taxation while the
governed have been equally diligent in devising new ways to avoid paying taxes. Everyone
recognises that taxation is an unfortunate necessity. Very few of us want to pay a penny more
than is absolutely necessary. Most of us harbour some degree of dislike for the fact that we
have to hand over a proportion of our earnings to governments to spend in ways which we
often feel powerless to control. We also have to recognise that tax evasion is a crime and
punishable as such but tax avoidance is a major industry employing some of the best brains in
the financial services. The line between the two is sometimes so thin and delicate that
references are common to tax avoision.
(c)
Payroll Taxes
Governments have always sought new ways to impose taxes. For a period the British
government had a selective employment tax (SET) largely as a device to tax services which
were then untaxed in contrast to indirect taxes on goods. At that time unemployment was not a
problem and the government could use the excuse that an employment tax would encourage
employers to make more productive and efficient use of labour.
Entry to the European Community and the adoption of value added tax which applied to all
forms of production allowed the unpopular SET to be abandoned but a more general
employment or payroll tax still exists in the form of national insurance contributions paid both
by employers and employees. For a long time this was less disliked than income tax because
people felt that they were paying for benefits in the form of health and injury insurances and
for retirement pensions.
Today, however, there is a widespread realisation that the level of national insurance premiums
is not guided by any principle of insurance, and that the contributions simply go into the
governments current revenue. Health service costs and State pensions are also paid as current
expenditure. There are no State insurance or pension funds.
Consequently no one now disputes that national insurance contributions are anything other
than a payroll tax. Proposals have been made to abolish them and raise the levels of income
tax and VAT but governments are notorious for not abolishing taxes if they can possibly avoid
doing so and they fear the public hostility to the high rates of VAT and income tax that would
be necessary. We are unlikely to see the end of national insurance contributions in the near
future.
Licensed to ABE
238
For the economy as a whole the effect of a rise in direct tax will depend on the aggregate marginal
propensities to consume and to save bearing in mind that people cannot always make significant
changes in their consumption patterns quickly. However desirable it may be to have a smaller house
and lower mortgage payments or reduced travelling costs, it is expensive to move home. This is
especially true in a period of stable or falling house prices. Consumption and savings patterns are
sometimes linked together, e.g. when insurance schemes are tied to house mortgage loans. If these
cannot be changed people may have to reduce consumption on other goods or services. Consequently
we can say that the main effect of a rise in a direct tax will be to reduce consumption of those goods
and services which have a high income elasticity of demand and of those forms of saving which can
be abandoned without suffering financial loss.
Propensities to consume and save are not, of course, fixed and are partly determined by peoples
expectations of the future. If people expect incomes and living standards to rise they may not be too
concerned with a relatively small increase in a tax indeed they may simply press for a speedier or
greater increase in income to make good the loss through tax. One reason given by the British
Government for moving from direct to indirect taxes in the early 1980s was that rises in income tax
tended to add fuel to wage inflation. If, however, they face an uncertain economic future with high
unemployment and widespread job insecurity, a tax rise can have a very damaging effect on
consumption as people try to maintain savings as a hedge against a further drop in income. You are
more likely to carry an umbrella when the sky is dark and overcast than when it is bright and sunny!
If, as part of its fiscal policy to reduce inflation, a government wishes to use direct taxes to reduce
consumer demand the most effective economic measure would be to raise those rates of tax which
most affect the lower income earners since they will have a high marginal propensity to consume and
they will be forced to reduce consumption. However, this may have unacceptable social and political
consequences. These are examined in the next section of this unit.
Licensed to ABE
239
be treated with suspicion and suppliers will want to see firm evidence that a demand increase will be
sustained before they risk expanding employment and production to any significant degree. It takes
longer to build up confidence in the economy than to destroy it.
Figure 14.1
This shows a labour market in which there are payroll taxes or compulsory payments, which have
the same effect. There is a demand curve for labour, indicating the employers wish to employ
workers at a range of wage levels, and there is also a supply curve for labour, indicating workers
willingness to work at the same range of wage levels. Wp Wr is the extent of payroll tax, so that
OWp is the wage cost to the employer and OWr is the net pay received by the worker.
Under these conditions, the employment level will be OLa, which is lower than the level that would
be reached if there were no payroll taxes and the wage paid was the same as the wage actually
received (level OLe). Thus, the difference (Le La) is the amount of unemployment that can be
attributed to payroll taxes. Clearly, the proportion that this bears to total employment depends on:
Licensed to ABE
240
(a)
(b)
In the case of low-paid manual and unskilled workers easily substituted by machines, labour demand
could be fairly elastic and, in the past, the proportion of national insurance costs to total pay has been
high, so that the amount of unemployment caused by the taxes has been thought to be significant.
More recently, the pattern of payments has been changed to reduce their cost in relation to the lowpaid workers and to compensate government revenue by increases in relation to highly-paid, highlyskilled workers whose demand and supply curves are thought to be inelastic at current wage levels.
The total effect should have reduced unemployment, especially among those unskilled workers who
suffer the highest rate of unemployment.
In practice, the change may have had further effects, in particular the encouragement of part-time
working by highly-skilled women workers in computing and similar occupations as, in practice, parttime work is not taxed as heavily as full-time work.
The illustration helps to emphasise the fact that no tax is really neutral in its economic effects.
People will seek to reduce the cost of any tax, and they will change their behaviour in order to reduce
their own burden of tax.
Governments, therefore, need to be aware of the consequences of any tax change, and to try to make
changes that accord with their own economic objectives. In effect, then, all governments have to
have a fiscal policy.
Licensed to ABE
241
Certainty
People should know what their tax liabilities are and be able to calculate their obligations and
plan their finances and expenditure accordingly.
Convenience
The government has a duty to organise its taxation structure so that payment can be made
conveniently.
Economy
The tax should not cost more to collect than it produces in revenue. It may appear difficult to
believe that any government would maintain a tax that reduced its revenue but many have done
so in the past and only an incurable optimist would believe that it will not happen again in the
future.
Equity
Liability to tax should depend on ability to pay. Adam Smith was well aware that many taxes
of his day bore hardest on the less well-off and he was concerned to correct this injustice. In
fact a proportional tax would probably have satisfied his requirement, i.e. if there were a single
percentage rate of income tax for everyone then those with high incomes would pay more than
those with low incomes. However, those who believe that income inequalities should be
removed have extended this canon to suggest that it requires higher income groups to pay a
higher percentage of their income in tax than lower groups. This, it is argued would narrow
the inequalities in disposable (after tax) incomes.
The underlying belief represented by these canons is that taxes should not breed resentment, should
not encourage evasion and should interfere as little as possible in the existing economic and social
structure. Tax is seen as a regrettably necessary burden that should sit as lightly as possible on the
shoulders of the community.
Licensed to ABE
242
A progressive tax is one that takes a proportionally higher percentage of income from the higher
income groups than from the lower. Social reformers, in their pressure to reduce income inequalities
have, of course, favoured progressive taxes.
Any tax can be regressive, progressive or proportional. It depends on how the tax is framed and
collected. The old purchase tax of the 1940s and 50s was a progressive expenditure tax as it was
levied on so-called luxury goods. Inevitably it led to many anomalies and a number of MPs made
popular reputations by exposing these. National insurance contributions are to some extent a direct
tax that is still partly regressive though not as much as in the past when all income earners paid the
same percentage up to a cut off income level. Earnings above this level required no further
contribution from employees.
In practice, British income taxes tend to be progressive in that the rate rises (1995 figures) from 0%,
through 20% and 25% to 40% in successive income bands. Indirect, expenditure taxes such as Value
Added Tax tend to be regressive in that the lower income groups are likely to spend a higher
proportion of their income on goods and services and thus pay a higher proportion of their income in
tax than the higher income earners.
These general statements should be modified to take account of anomalies. Some of the highest
marginal rates of tax are paid by low or below average income groups. For example a very low
income family can pass from a situation of paying no income tax and receiving income support and
other social security benefits to one of paying tax at 20% and losing entitlement to benefits following
a fairly small income increase. People over the ages of 65 and 70 can also lose their age-related
additional personal allowances if their income rises above a certain level. At the critical income level
which by 1995 was well below the average earnings level, they can thus effectively be paying tax at a
very high marginal rate. These anomalies encourage tax evasion and raise collection costs as the
revenue authorities have to take expensive anti-evasion measures or risk widespread evasion which,
in turn, creates a sense of injustice among honest taxpayers.
Notice also that the idea that tax should be an instrument for social reform requires that the additional
taxes collected from the well-off should be used for the benefit of the lower income groups. In
practice there is considerable evidence that the more articulate and better organised and educated
groups tend to gain an increasing share of government social expenditure over time. Schools and
hospitals in the more affluent areas become more effective and offer better services than those in
poorer areas. A higher proportion of the children of the higher income groups make use of higher and
further education facilities than the children of poorer groups. Some observers have argued that
taxation seldom leads to any significant degree of income re-distribution in favour of the poorer
groups and can lead to the opposite effect.
What is very evident is that the heaviest tax burdens tend increasingly to fall on the middle income
groups who receive relatively few of the benefits of social security, suffer from both high expenditure
and high marginal direct tax rates and who do not earn enough to justify employing expensive tax
advisers to arrange the more complex avoision schemes that have enabled the wealthy to maintain
their wealth.
Licensed to ABE
243
and limit expenditure to the constraints of its revenue receipts. Its apparent success in this objective
was, however, achieved by the device of privatisation which brought it large sums of capital which
were treated and spent as revenue. By the early 1990s there was little left to privatise and the
Public Sector Borrowing Requirement (PSBR) again became a major economic issue.
Notes and coin the cash we carry in our pockets is technically considered to be finance lent
to the government. This dates from the origins of the bank note as a receipt of money
deposited with a bank. Although we no longer have to deposit gold or silver with the Bank of
England to obtain a Bank of England note, this still takes the form of a receipt and it continues
to carry the now, meaningless ....promise to pay the bearer on demand the sum of..... The
government could increase its borrowing by ordering the central bank to print more and more
notes. If it did so the notes would soon lose their value and acceptability.
Treasury bills these are a kind of very formal IOU, issued for large sums and sold to banks
and other institutions prepared to lend money to the government on a short-term basis.
Other Government paper bonds, certificates, and other financial instruments sold
directly to the public and not to banks and building societies. The best known of these paper
securities are the national savings certificates and bonds that are issued through post offices or
through the Bonds and Stock Office in Blackpool. The bonds known as gilts (gilt edged
securities) are marketable, i.e. they can be bought and sold through the Stock Exchange at their
current market price. Others can only be bought and sold directly through the Bonds and Stock
Office on terms specified at the time of issue.
During the 1980s the British Government sought to finance as much as possible of its PSBR through
the non-bank, non-building society private sector and the overseas sectors as these sources were
thought to have less effect on the money supply than borrowing from the banks. However, in a highly
complex financial structure such as that of the United Kingdom there is some doubt as to whether that
is really the case. It was also able to increase its revenue income by privatisation, i.e. by the sale of
shares in the former public corporations such as British Telecom, British Gas and British Airways,
when these were turned into public liability companies and transferred technically from the public to
the private sectors of the economy. In doing this the Government was accused of selling the family
silver and there is certainly some doubt as to the long term desirability of treating as revenue the
proceeds of the sale of capital assets.
Licensed to ABE
244
the measure that the finance ministries of all the member countries of the European Community have
agreed to use to measure the performance of the national fiscal policies in the period when members
are supposed to be moving towards a single European currency.
Licensed to ABE
245
It is clear that there will be important economic consequences of a change in government borrowing.
What these are depends on the sources of borrowing and on how and where the borrowed finance is
spent.
Licensed to ABE
246
Licensed to ABE
247
Study Unit 15
Economic Problems and Policies
Contents
A.
B.
C.
D.
Page
248
248
Inflation
248
Unemployment
248
Trade Difficulties
249
Regional Problems
249
250
250
Fiscal Policies
250
252
253
253
Monetary Policies
254
Direct Controls
254
Government Spending
254
256
256
Differences in Priorities
256
Supply-side Policies
257
257
Supply-side Objectives
259
260
262
Encouragement of Competition
262
263
Licensed to ABE
248
Inflation
We have already noted this. Inflation is the term used to describe a condition of constantly-rising
product and factor prices the main factor price being wages: the price of labour. Inflation is a
problem because it makes the production and distribution system less efficient. It creates
uncertainties about costs and it makes planning more difficult and uncertain. It makes long-term
agreements difficult to make, because past agreements become unjust as the value of any agreed
constant payment is steadily reduced. Money is unable to fulfil those functions which depend on
confidence that it will retain its purchasing power and acceptability in the future. Savings lose their
value, and people who have saved for future needs feel a sense of injustice. Countries suffering the
most severe rates of inflation find that their exports become more expensive and difficult to sell in
world markets, while imports become cheaper and grow in volume.
If inflation is not checked, it increases in intensity until prices rise daily and all confidence in money
is lost. Trade reverts to a basis of barter, and all confidence in the financial system collapses. This
condition of hyperinflation is, usually, associated with extreme political and social unrest and
uncertainty for the future.
Unemployment
Unemployment is said to exist when resources, especially people, available and seeking employment
cannot find employment. It is an economic problem, in the sense that the community loses the
production that could have been achieved, had all resources been employed. Unemployment is also a
major social problem because work is an important element in a persons standing in the community.
A person who feels that he ought to be working but who cannot find work often feels rejected by
society and, not uncommonly, resorts to anti-social behaviour.
We have already noted that Keynesians and monetarists have differing views concerning the nature
and causes of unemployment, and it is convenient here to summarise some of these important
differences.
(a)
Both groups agree that there are elements of frictional and structural unemployment but
monetarists believe that the structural element in modern Britain is higher than it need be,
because relatively high unemployment and welfare payments reduce the pressures to adjust to
changing economic conditions. They also believe that social attitudes by trade unions delay
adjustment to change.
Licensed to ABE
249
(b)
(c)
Monetarists believe that the natural rate of unemployment would be very small if markets were
free to operate according to the unrestricted interplay of the normal market forces of supply
and demand. The natural rate of unemployment is that rate which exists when the total demand
for labour is roughly equal to total supply. People are then unemployed for frictional reasons
the normal wear and tear of firms closing, people changing jobs for personal reasons and so on
and structural reasons changes in the labour market caused by shifts in product demand and
changes in production technology. A high rate of unemployment is, therefore, blamed on
imperfections in labour markets. These are seen mainly in terms of failure to understand and to
adjust to structural change, and undue trade union power. They argue that a large part of high
unemployment is voluntary, in the sense that people are waiting for jobs they think suitable,
instead of accepting what is available, and because they support trade union measures which
force wages above the market equilibrium and, so, reduce the demand for labour.
Trade Difficulties
These are closely associated with inflation which increases export and reduces import prices in world
markets. Both Keynesians and monetarists would agree that rising imports indicate a condition
where demand is greater than the supply from the home-production system. However, whereas
Keynesians would concentrate attention on what is perceived as excess demand, monetarists pay
more attention to failings in the supply or production system which they would tend to regard as
inefficient for a variety of reasons, including trade union power, lack of profit incentives, inefficient
management, often associated with monopoly power and bureaucratic barriers to business enterprise.
The UK has suffered from persistent trade problems since the early 1960s. Between 1980 and 1986
these were largely hidden by earnings from North Sea oil but as you will see later in the course there
have been further problems since those years and the UK now imports more manufactured goods than
it exports. The traditional earnings from financial services are no longer as reliable as they have been
in the past so that trade revenues remain very much a problem area for the British economy.
Regional Problems
If you live and work in the United Kingdom, you will, probably, be aware that the central problems of
inflation and unemployment do not affect all areas of the country with equal intensity. In the
southern areas, for example, inflationary pressures seem to be greater, whereas unemployment is,
generally, more severe in the northern areas. If you live in some other country, you are likely to be
aware of similar regional differences. These are regarded as economic problems, because the failure
of some areas to develop as successfully as others suggests that production is being lost through the
under-use or inefficient use of available scarce resources.
People tend to think that they are well or badly off, according to the comparisons they are able to
make with other people. If living standards and employment opportunities are very different in
different regions, there is likely to be social and political discontent. There is also the problem that
large-scale movement of people from one region to another to find employment is a further possible
cause of social trouble, as families are divided and pressures build up on housing and other services
in the more prosperous areas.
Licensed to ABE
250
The regional problem as it relates to the United Kingdom is examined later in this study unit. You
should try to apply similar general principles and arguments to the problems of your own country, if
this is not the UK.
Licensed to ABE
Figure 15.1
Roughly the same idea is illustrated through the familiar supply and demand analysis shown in
Figure 15.2.
Figure 15.2
Licensed to ABE
251
252
If an increase in demand is to reduce unemployment, then it must be assumed that total supply and,
therefore, the demand for labour and other production factors will rise in response to the change in
demand. The extreme Keynesian position assumes that supply will always respond fully to an
increase in demand, as long as there are unemployed resources in the economy. It will cease to do so
only at the full employment level, where all available resources are already employed.
This view produces the total supply curve shaped as in Figure 15.2. It is totally elastic as far as the
full employment level Of, and then it becomes totally inelastic.
Thus, an increase in total demand at any level below Of will result in a rapid increase in supply. In
the model, the increase, following a shift of total demand from DD to D1, is from Os to Os1. The
increase in supply will be achieved by employers increasing production and their employment of
labour, etc.
Licensed to ABE
253
prepared to operate an unbalanced budget, with revenue falling short of expenditure and the
difference made good by borrowing.
Licensed to ABE
254
Nevertheless, the monetarist will also wish to pursue his long-term aim of reducing all taxation, and
he will recognise that this can be achieved (without borrowing and with a balanced budget) only if
government spending is also reduced.
The real objective, then, is to reduce the level of government-controlled activity in the economy,
because this is regarded as being inefficient and a burden that the wealth-creating private sector has
to bear, and that should be kept as light as possible. However, as long as that burden remains high,
the monetarist will see an increase in taxes as a lesser evil than increased borrowing. The fiscal
policy of the monetarist, then, is to try to reduce the burden of taxation but to ensure that tax revenue
is sufficient to meet the level of government spending that has to be maintained.
Fiscal policies are not, then, seen as a primary means of economic management but, simply, as a
means of financing government spending, and an unfortunate necessity required to fulfil the social
and political policies that the government has to honour.
Monetary Policies
The theoretical basis of monetary policy, the money equation and the main elements of monetary
controls were examined in Study Unit 13 and you should make sure you understand how these differ
from fiscal policies. Remember that monetarists and Keynesians share a common belief that the
major cause of inflation is an excess of demand over available supply. However, the Keynesian belief
that demand is mainly a function of the level of income has led traditional Keynesians to rely chiefly
on fiscal measures and later Keynesians to support direct controls over the level of incomes. In
contrast monetarists believe that demand is mainly a function of the availability of money and credit
(money supply) and this has led to their reliance on monetary controls. Experience, however, has
forced an admission that the only element in the package of monetary controls to have any significant
effect is the level of interest rates and this has become the main monetary instrument in the 1990s
with considerable publicity attaching to the regular meetings of the Governor of the Bank of England
and the Chancellor of the Exchequer. Much of the activity in the Stock Exchange has now become a
continuous process of betting on the future movement of interest rates. It is doubtful how far this
contributes to the development of a healthy capital market.
Direct Controls
A government can always obtain the legal powers to control certain aspects of the economy but it
must be remembered that these powers are, usually, only negative. A government can prevent people
or firms from doing certain things but it has considerable difficulty in forcing them into positive
action i.e. actually to do things it wants done, purely by the exercise of its legal powers.
It may be used to encourage people to make their savings available to business enterprise e.g.
through the business-expansion scheme which allows tax relief to be claimed on money invested in
the shares of new or expanding companies, subject to certain conditions. It may also be used to
encourage business investment in modern equipment and technology, or to encourage business firms
to transfer or expand their activities in regions which the government wishes to assist.
Government Spending
Government (public-sector) spending is a major part of total demand, so that, to the Keynesians,
relying on demand management, variations in government spending can be used to influence the level
of national income and product. The Keynesian uses government spending as a counter-cyclical
instrument, so that the government can inject additional demand when household consumption and
business investment are considered to be too low, and reduce public-sector spending when the
economy is thought to be overheating with excess demand from the private sector. In practice, it is
Licensed to ABE
255
easier for governments to increase public-sector spending than to reduce it, as has been discovered
again since 1979.
The monetarist, not believing in demand management, does not recognise the use of public-sector
spending as a means to regulate the total level of economic activity, and he wishes to keep the total of
this spending as low as possible.
However, both Keynesians and monetarists do agree that the pattern of economic activity can be
influenced by government spending decisions. Governments have sought to encourage the
development of the computer industry by assisting investment and by helping schools to buy Britishmade computers. It can influence the development of transport by spending on roads rather than on
the railways. It can also try to help some regions by directing some public activities to them, and
away from London.
For example, a government may stop a firm from building a new factory in a particular place but, if
that firm says that, if it cannot have the factory where it wanted it, then it will not build a new factory
at all, there is very little the government can do. Similarly, a government may prohibit the import
(and, sometimes, the export) of particular goods or goods from (or to ) particular countries but it
cannot force people in foreign countries to buy goods made by its producers.
One of the most controversial examples of the exercise of direct controls by the British government
has been the successive attempts made to regulate wage, and sometimes price, increases. For a few
months in the 1960s, the government even imposed a wage freeze and prohibited all wage
increases. When legal or statutory prices and incomes controls proved unworkable, attempts were
made to secure voluntary agreements between government, employers and trade unions but these
rarely lasted for very long. Regulation of price or factor price without also controlling the forces of
supply and demand is never successful because it must lead to serious distortions in supply and
demand and it threatens to destroy the whole mechanism of the market. During all the periods of
attempted wage regulation, employers and unions found ways of overcoming the controls in order to
keep the labour markets working. Even so, shortages of skilled workers sufficient to hold back the
expansion of some profitable firms and industries have been blamed on these controls which made it
difficult for firms to attract workers into activities requiring long and difficult periods of training
when nearly as high wages could be obtained from less demanding work. Nevertheless, the pay of
people employed in the public sector, which is largely insulated from the forces of supply and
demand, continues to cause problems. There does appear to be a need for guidance from some kind
of authority for public-sector pay. As long as there are not generally-agreed principles and the
government simply relies on its power as an employer, continued disputes and feelings of injustice
are highly likely.
This issue re-appeared in the Autumn Financial Statement of 1992 when the British Government
reacted to its severe economic and financial difficulties by setting a pay rise ceiling for the majority
of public sector workers of 1.5% and strongly criticised the large percentage rises that had been
awarded in the previous few years to many company directors and senior managers. This, of course,
represented a major policy change for a government, which, in the early 1980s, had been so confident
in its belief that unregulated market forces were the universal cure for all economic ills. Observers
with very long memories began to recall the political difficulties encountered by a much earlier
Conservative Chancellor of the Exchequer, Mr Selwyn Lloyd, who had made tentative moves towards
an official policy of pay controls over the public sector by blocking pay rises for hospital nurses at a
time when public sector pay had been falling behind pay in the private sector. Few economists
believed that the 1992 version of pay controls would prove any more effective in economic or
political terms.
Licensed to ABE
256
Governments generally think that they have more power than they actually possess. When controls
are imposed to prevent actions that people would otherwise take, there will be attempts to evade the
controls, and the government may be forced into increasingly difficult, complex and expensive
control measures. Many countries have sought to impose strict import controls, only to discover that
they have created a major smuggling industry, while many of those responsible for maintaining the
controls simply use their powers to increase their personal incomes with bribes from both legal and
illegal traders. We have only to note the problems of seeking to prevent the import of illegal drugs to
see what happens when a government tries to suppress trade for which there is an effective demand.
It is only too clear that a government cannot stop the abuse of drugs just by trying to prevent drugs
imports.
Differences in Priorities
If, to begin with, we adopt the Keynesian position, then it is clear that there has to be some sense of
priorities in choosing objectives. This is because not all can be pursued at once. The Keynesian
would argue that his most important objective is to achieve and maintain full employment but that
this may have to be modified from time to time if inflation or trade difficulties become too serious.
Licensed to ABE
257
However, the main objective is always to avoid large-scale unemployment; and, if this is threatened,
some inflation or trade imbalance may have to be accepted.
Critics of Keynesian economics would suggest that, in practice, governments do little more than react
to a series of crises, lurching between expansion and deflation as each problem becomes steadily
more serious and as the production system becomes increasingly dislocated by sudden shifts in
demand policy. They see the inevitable consequence as uncontrollable inflation which, eventually,
brings about mass unemployment as the production system fails to compete with more efficient
foreign systems.
The monetarist, thus, argues that there is no alternative to controlling inflation and freeing privatesector markets from controls and barriers, so that they can expand production and increase
employment. In the meantime, however, the effect of reducing public-sector activity and restoring a
more competitive and efficient private sector is likely to cause strains and to increase unemployment.
We have seen earlier that monetarists differ in their approach to the timing of policies. Some prefer a
gradual approach, accepting that inflation should not be brought down too swiftly, in order to avoid
the social and political upsets of too rapid a rise in unemployment, while others consider that the
adjustment can be carried out more quickly and that more vigorous methods can be applied to remove
restrictions to industrial markets.
D. SUPPLY-SIDE POLICIES
The disappointing experience of demand management policies when inflation became a major
economic issue and the monetarist argument that demand expansion almost invariably led to inflation
because of the failure of domestic production to respond quickly enough to demand stimulation led to
the development of what became known as supply-side economics. It is monetarists who are most
closely associated with modern approaches to the stimulation of supply. In this approach, supply-side
economics is seen as the use of microeconomic incentives to change the level of full employment, the
level of potential output and the natural rate of unemployment. The objectives are to increase total
production, to increase the productivity of labour, and to make producers more competitive in world
markets. A government pursuing supply-side policies wants business firms to produce more and to
employ more labour but to do so profitably, in competitive markets.
Licensed to ABE
258
Structural unemployment has two related meanings. It arises, on the one hand, from shifting patterns
of demand. If, for example, many women decide to give up wearing jeans and trousers, and instead
choose to wear skirts and dresses, then jeans manufacturers will have to lay off workers, while skirt
manufacturers will be expanding their activities. Different firms in different localities may be
involved, and it is not always possible for workers in the declining activity to move quickly into one
that is expanding.
The other form of structural change is also known as technological change. It arises from changing
production methods, usually from the increased use of machines, including advanced electronic
devices and computer software which can do a great deal of work previously carried out manually.
When this kind of change takes place, there is no immediate compensating expansion in another
activity. New technology always creates new activities and occupations in time but these may be
very different from the old, requiring new and different skills, and they are often located in
completely new areas. Structural unemployment from technological causes can be greater and more
disruptive than that from shifts in demand.
The two types, however, are often related, in the sense that new technology creates new products
which replace old ones. The transistor destroyed the radio-valve industry; the small electronic
calculator destroyed the production of slide rules and mechanical calculating machines. Modern
electronics has, in fact, changed a great deal of product demand, and it has had a very great impact on
the labour market.
It is clear, then, that, if we regard the natural rate of unemployment as being made up of frictional and
structural unemployment, it is likely to be much higher today than it was in the 1950s and the early
1960s, before the current electronics revolution. Where monetarists differ from other, particularly
Keynesian, economists is in their belief that the whole or almost the whole of the actual amount
of unemployment is natural unemployment. If the actual rate of unemployment is seen as being at a
level which is socially and politically unacceptable and economically damaging, in the sense that
production that would be possible at a higher level of employment is being lost then the problem
lies in reducing this natural rate. Monetarists believe that this natural rate is too high, and that it can
be reduced by microeconomic (supply-side) policies.
The effect of the natural rate of unemployment is illustrated in Figure 15.3.
In this model, the curve WP represents the labour force that is available for work, and it is the
working population, recorded as wishing to work.
The curve SL lies to the left of WP, and it represents the actual supply of labour i.e. those workers
prepared to take a job at the wage offered. This supply is less than the working population at each
wage level, because there are always those between jobs (frictionally unemployed) and those who
have not adjusted to the changed structural position in which they are now unable to obtain work at
their previous earnings level, and they still hope to obtain better jobs than those on offer. Given the
demand schedule for labour, the equilibrium employment level is at E at wage rate OW, and the
quantity of workers represented by the distance EZ is the natural rate of unemployment. This
analysis, so far, assumes that the market is left to find its own equilibrium, without outside
intervention. If, in fact, there are trade unions powerful enough to force up the actual wage level
above OW to, say, OWu, then the actual rate of unemployment is increased to UB. On to the natural
rate, as previously defined, which is now AB, there is the additional collectively-agreed
unemployment resulting from trade union influence. This is, normally, regarded as part of the natural
rate of unemployment at the higher wage level.
Licensed to ABE
259
Figure 15.3
Almost the whole of this unemployment (UB) is also seen by supporters of this view as voluntary
unemployment, in the sense that it is the consequence of unwillingness to accept the realities of
market supply and demand, and of individual and collective decisions to achieve what people regard
as acceptable wages, rather than market-determined wages. Those who do obtain these wages may be
regarded as doing so at the expense of those unable to find work at all, because the number of jobs on
offer at wages above market equilibrium is lower than the number of workers seeking those jobs.
Figure 15.3 gives the general analytical model. The actual distances UA, AB and EZ are not based on
any statistical research. Indeed, these are the subject of some controversy, and you can imagine that it
is extremely difficult to produce the actual SL and the total demand for labour schedule.
Clearly then, monetarists and supporters of supply-side theories, take an almost opposite view to
Keynesians of the basic causes of unemployment. Whereas Keynesians see unemployment and
inflation as opposite forms of national income disequilibrium (the deflationary and inflationary gaps)
monetarist/supply-siders see unemployment and inflation as caused by similar forms of market failure
with inflation as the primary result of this failure and helping to produce unemployment by pricing
domestic production and production workers out of employment in world markets. Much supply-side
policy, therefore, depends on removing imperfections, including government intervention, from
product and factor markets.
Supply-side Objectives
If you look again at Figure 15.3 and bear in mind the earlier outline of objectives of supply-side
economics, you will realise that supply-side policies will be designed to shift the SL curve to the right
i.e. increase the number of workers prepared to work at each wage level, and so reduce the natural
Licensed to ABE
260
rate of unemployment, to move the actual demand for labour (and, hence, raise the production level)
further to the right along the demand curve by reducing the gap between union-imposed and the
market-equilibrium level of wages, and shift the demand-for-labour curve to the right by increasing
employers production intentions. A number of possible ways of achieving these results may now be
examined.
Figure 15.4
Here are shown curves for the working population (WP) and the actual supply of labour (LF) and the
demand for labour, as before. If there are income taxes and other payments of the nature of payroll
taxes, as discussed earlier, then the wage cost may be OWg the gross wage paid by employers plus
compulsory payments which employers have to make, whereas the net wage actually received by the
workers is OWn. The vertical distance AB represents the amount of income tax and payroll taxes.
If this distance could be eliminated, the supply and demand for labour would move to the equilibrium
position C, and employment would be at the higher level of OLe. Income and payroll tax reductions
Licensed to ABE
261
would have reduced the amount of unemployment by an extent depending on the slopes of the curves
and the various distances involved.
In practice, the government recognises that this is impossible to achieve for the total labour market
but it may be possible for particular sections of the labour market which currently suffer from high
rates of unemployment, especially in the markets for lower-paid and unskilled workers. This explains
the changes in National Insurance contributions noted in the last study unit and the governments
declared desire to take more workers out of the tax net.
If the pattern of income and payroll taxes is changed to reduce the burden on the low-paid workers, if
necessary at the expense of the more-highly paid, the government will be able to avoid the criticism
often levelled at tax reductions aimed at increasing labour supply i.e. that the supply-of-labour
curve is backward-sloping, so that, above a given wage rate, further increases in net wage will reduce
rather than increase the willingness to work (because above a certain income level workers are more
likely to prefer increased leisure to increased income). As long as the governments fiscal measures
are concentrated on helping those whose net wage is below OW in Figure 15.5, which illustrates this
concept, any achievement in increasing the net wage received by workers will raise the quantity of
labour being offered to producers.
Figure 15.5
Another aspect of supply-side fiscal policy is to increase the rewards of successful business
enterprise. This is likely to involve a number of fiscal measures, including a reduction in the higher
rates of income tax i.e. the rates paid by high-income earners, on the assumption that a high
proportion of these will be employers or business managers who are responsible for making the
decisions that determine the level of output and for achieving business success.
Other aspects of tax reduction may involve granting tax allowances for investment in business
enterprise by individuals and reducing taxes on wealth and capital transfer which supply-side
Licensed to ABE
262
economists would regard as penalties imposed on people who have committed the crime of being
successful in business, of increasing the wealth of the community and the employment opportunities
of others.
Political practicalities may prevent a government from pursuing all its desired policies. For example,
attempts to end or reduce tax concessions for income paid in home-mortgage interest and for pension
contributions in order to finance tax reductions on income and wealth earning were abandoned in the
face of political opposition in 1984/85.
There is a further aspect of fiscal policy on which there is some uncertainty. This concerns the
investment allowances made to business firms which use their earnings to purchase equipment.
These have, traditionally, been favoured on the grounds that they encourage business expansion and
modernisation, and create employment in the capital-goods industries which provide business plant
and equipment. However, in 1984, these allowances were made less favourable, on the grounds that
the government wished to reduce taxes on company profits and that it wished to encourage firms to
make decisions likely to produce profits, rather than simply to save tax. This is in line with supplyside beliefs that seek to encourage profit-seeking enterprise and enterprise likely to be successful in
competitive markets i.e. to reward genuine business efficiency, rather than tax efficiency. The
fact that a high proportion of equipment financed by investment allowances has tended to be
produced in foreign countries may also have influenced government thinking.
Encouragement of Competition
Supply-side economists would regard the possession of undue market power by any organisation,
whether worker or employer, as likely to reduce output and efficiency and raise costs and prices.
Competition and the weakening of monopoly power is, thus, seen as a desirable objective, likely to
lead to increased efficiency and production and, in the long run, to a higher and more secure level of
employment.
By 1980, some of the most powerful of the remaining monopolies, oligopolies and cartels were in the
service industries and the so-called professions. Monopoly and uncompetitive conditions could be
found, for example, in banking, the law, estate agency, and the fringe areas of the health services
Licensed to ABE
263
(e.g. opticians). Since 1980, attempts have been made to increase competition and business
efficiency in these areas, and considerable changes either have taken place or are taking place in
many of the service occupations, especially in finance, where competition has already assumed new
dimensions in sectors as different as building societies and the Stock Exchange, after the reforms of
1986 which allowed stockbrokers to become, if they wished, dealers in shares as market makers
and also allowed banks and other financial institutions to enter the stock market directly as owners of
broking and market making firms.
Licensed to ABE
264
Licensed to ABE
265
Study Unit 16
National Product and International Trade
Contents
A.
B.
C.
Page
266
266
269
269
277
277
277
278
281
Devaluation
281
Deflation
283
Import Controls
284
285
Licensed to ABE
266
total expenditure, which also represents total demand (the desire to spend) can be expressed as
E=C+I+G
Licensed to ABE
267
providing and selling goods and services for export. If, on the other hand, people spend their incomes
on foreign-made goods, then this leads to the creation of jobs and incomes in foreign countries.
Figure 16.1
Another method of illustrating this is as in the graphs of Figures 16.2(a) and (b). In Figure 16.2(a),
we see the effect of increasing injections by net export earnings the equilibrium level of national
income rises from Oe to Oe1.
Licensed to ABE
268
Figure 16.2
In Figure 16.2(b), imports raise the slope of the withdrawals (S + T + M) curve to bring down the
equilibrium income level from (Oe to Oe1). Notice that net exports are shown as a parallel line,
indicating that they do not rise directly as national income rises, whereas imports are shown as having
a greater effect at higher income levels. This is because the consumption element in imports
increases with higher incomes, showing a behaviour pattern similar to that of any other form of
consumption.
Licensed to ABE
269
These illustrations help us to appreciate how imports reduce the value of the national income
multiplier, in the sense that:
(a)
increased consumption on imports makes the withdrawal curve steeper; the value of the
multiplier is 1/w and any increase in the value of w, which represents the steepness of the
withdrawal curve the propensity to withdraw, reduces the value of the reciprocal of w;
(b)
any increase in the import element in business investment spending reduces the net rise in I
and, hence, the injection brought about by I; if a firm buys machines made in another country,
it is not creating jobs in home factories;
(c)
any government spending on imports reduces the value of G to the domestic income in exactly
the same way.
There is nothing strange in any of these propositions. They are exactly what we would expect.
However, we should remember that they all assume that the home and foreign economies are entirely
distinct i.e. that the home economy is not affected in any way by changes in foreign economies. A
little further thought causes us to doubt this. Modern economies are closely interrelated.
It is true that there is no direct relationship between the size of the national income of country A and
the level of exports to country B but, if the two are trading partners, the national income of country B
and its ability to buy goods from A will depend to some extent on its ability to sell its own products to
A. There is a connection, and we should beware of making over-simple deductions from the
apparently obvious propositions above.
The Invisible Trade Account services, transfers and interest, profits and dividends.
It is important to remember that the accounts represent flows of money. These flows are in the
opposite direction to those of goods and services. For example, exports flow out, payment for them
flows in; British ships carry goods for German firms and payment flows in. Capital investment by
UK companies in America is an outflow of money, whereas the purchase by Americans of shares in
British companies is an inflow.
Licensed to ABE
270
billion
Current account
Goods
Exports
Imports
Balance of visible trade
+121.4
134.6
13.2
Services
Exports
Imports
Interest, profits and dividends
IPD receipts
IPD payments
Transfers
Transfer receipts
Transfer payments
Balance of invisible trade
+36.6
31.6
+74.0
71.0
+5.4
10.5
+2.9
10.3
102.9
+49.5
53.4
UK bank transactions
Lending abroad
Borrowing abroad
Net lending and borrowing
+12.7
+23.7
+36.4
0.6
0.1
0.7
10.1
+12.7
+2.6
+8.3
+2.7
(Note: The figures may not add because of rounding)
Table 16.1: The UK Balance of Payments in 1993
Licensed to ABE
(a)
271
Visible Trade
When we think of trade, we usually think first of trade in actual physical goods, such as motor
cars, oil, food. This is, normally, called the trade in visible goods, and the balance between
the value of imports and exports is called the visibles balance. Some writers and
examiners still refer to this as the trade balance or balance of trade so, you should be
prepared to meet this term.
Visible trade is usually classified into a number of broad groups, and it is useful to look at the
composition of UK trade on the basis of these groups. (You should try to obtain similar figures
for your own country, if this is not the United Kingdom.) The main classes are the following:
!
Basic Materials
Sometimes referred to as raw materials, these are the basic metals and commodities
required for manufacturing. The UK has few of these to export and less than 2% of
exports fall into this class, but it accounts for a little under 4% of imports (1993).
Semi-manufactured Goods
In 1993, these accounted for over 29% of exports and over 25% of imports. The
massive trade in components and goods destined to become parts of other goods
illustrates the international nature of modern production. Descriptions such as made in
Britain usually mean assembled in Great Britain from goods made in several other
countries. Much of this trade in semi-manufactured goods represents trade between
different parts of the same large company group. This is called intra-company trade,
and it has become a most important part of total world trade. Its implications are
considered more fully in a later study unit.
If you add up the figures given so far, you will notice that there is a gap for both imports and
exports. This 2% gap, represents commodities and transactions not classified according to any
of the groups (a) to (e), above.
Licensed to ABE
272
(b)
(c)
Invisible Trade
Invisible trade is so called to distinguish it from trade in goods, which are tangible items. It
consists of:
!
Services including sea and air transport, tourism, consultancy and financial services. In
1992 the City of Londons invisible earnings were 10,572 million.
Interest, Profits and Dividend (IPD) comprising interest on borrowing and lending
abroad by UK banks, remitted profits in overseas branches where a UK company has
made a direct investment or to foreign firms investing in British subsidiaries, and
payment of interest and dividend on portfolio investment in stocks and shares.
Transfers of funds to or receipts from other countries for non-trading and noncommercial transactions. The government is responsible for most transfers in the form
of grants to developing countries, subscriptions to international organisations like the
United Nations and net payments to the European Community. Private transfers include
payments to dependants abroad by UK residents, and gifts.
The amount of IPD earnings depends on the amount invested in the past. Direct investment
refers to the purchase of foreign assets. It includes buying control of firms in other countries,
establishing subsidiaries and acquiring land and property. Portfolio investment is in stocks and
shares. IPD receipts are influenced by the level of interest rates and the conditions in the
economy which affect interest and dividend payments.
Profits and dividends in the balance of payments can cause confusion about how they appear in
the accounts. If a British company has a wholly-owned subsidiary overseas which earns a
profit, the invisible earnings are the profit remitted to the UK, but the part of the profit which is
retained in the overseas subsidiary is treated as a capital outflow and appears under direct
investments in the capital account. If the British company does not control the overseas
subsidiary but receives a share of the profit, it only appears in the invisible account.
A more detailed breakdown of the balance of invisibles is shown in Table 16.2. This shows the
main group headings and the actual balances (difference between money going out and money
coming into the country). Study these group headings carefully. You will see that, for the
Licensed to ABE
273
United Kingdom, the largest money outflows are accounted for by general government
transfers, Travel, General Government services and General Government Investment income.
Clearly the public sector develops a substantial deficit with the rest of the world through its
grants to foreign countries and organisations and the cost of foreign aid and for armed forces
overseas. Travel includes both tourism and business travel. The deficit under this heading has
widened considerably in recent years, suggesting that foreign holidays have become more
popular with the British.
The largest inflow of funds comes from the financial services and other services, many of
which are related to industrial and commercial services and invisible exports, such as the
royalties received for pop music, television films, business management services, and so on.
Britain also receives money for licences and patent rights for goods manufactured overseas.
She has become an exporter of skills and know-how, as well as of finished goods.
When you study the table, remember that the service headings Sea transport and Civil
aviation refer to travel on ships and aircraft. Trade in ships and aircraft themselves is, of
course, part of the countrys visible trade.
Note also the heading Investment income. This relates to the earnings received from past
investment in foreign countries less payments to foreign investors in Britain. This net balance
has fluctuated during the past decade and although it continues to provide a substantial inflow
of revenue we must expect the capital investment in British industry by foreign companies to
lead to increased payments of profits to foreign investors.
Table 16.2 shows the visible balances for 1983 to 1993, the main classes of invisibles and the
resulting total balance, which is shown as the current balance of payments.
This figure represents a countrys income or loss following a years general trading with the
rest of the world. The importance of this balance is examined in the next section of this study
unit.
Licensed to ABE
274
Licensed to ABE
(d)
275
(e)
Table 16.3 develops the information in Table 16.1 by providing a summary of the full balance of
payments for the years 1983 to 1993. You will see that, apart from the current balance, there are a
number of other monetary movements which, together, cancel out the current balance. At this stage
of study, you do not need a detailed knowledge of these but note that they include movements of
capital (the capital account), payments to and receipts from the International Monetary Fund (IMF),
and a range of transactions with foreign monetary authorities.
From this table, you can see what is meant when it is said that, in the end, the balance of payments of
a country will always balance, but, in effect, this balance may have to be achieved by borrowing,
from payments from past reserves and with the help of a balancing item which is often quite
substantial! The really important balance, though, is the current one. This shows whether the
country is trading profitably and successfully or not. It is the current balance which is the best
indication of a countrys economic health. No country can overspend its current income and draw on
past savings or borrow from other countries for ever.
Licensed to ABE
276
Licensed to ABE
277
Licensed to ABE
278
Licensed to ABE
Licensed to ABE
279
280
(b)
Economic Weakness
Many economists think that relative price movements are little more than a symptom of
economic conditions, rather than a basic cause of those conditions. For a developing country, a
balance of payments deficit may simply reflect the world-market situation that ensures that
total export earnings for the volume of goods exported are not sufficient to provide enough
money to pay for the goods and services needed for development. The position will be made
worse if:
!
there is a failure in production, resulting from natural disaster or other causes e.g. a
crop failure or internal conflict, or
there is a high demand for imported consumer goods from a section of the population
that has developed a fashion or taste for imported clothes, cars or food.
For an advanced country, the problem may be caused by a weak economic or business
structure, an economy that is less successful than that of competing nations. If production is
cut by poor working methods, under-investment in modern machinery or labour disputes, then
export earnings are likely to fall and imports and the cost of imports rise, almost regardless of
price advances, in favour of the home country. Germany and Japan, for example, have been
consistently more successful in exporting than Britain and the USA.
(c)
Licensed to ABE
281
Devaluation
By devaluation we mean the reduction in the exchange value of a nations currency in terms of
foreign currencies. For example, before devaluation a British pound might be equal to 12 French
francs but, after devaluation, it may be equal to only ten francs.
Devaluation may be allowed to happen through the normal operation of the foreign exchange
markets. If, on these markets, the demand for pounds falls and that for francs rises, the price of the
pound is likely to fall relative to that of the franc.
Alternatively, if exchange rates are fixed by governments, then the governments can change the value
by declaration. In whichever way it is brought about, a devaluation raises the price of imports and
reduces the price of exports, at least in the short term.
Some writers (and examiners) distinguish between devaluation (action by governments when
exchange rates are fixed) and depreciation (fall in value of a currency as a result of market
movements). You should be aware of this but you must also recognise that governments do
intervene in currency markets to try to influence market movements, and a change in interest is
sometimes brought about by a government in a deliberate attempt to change the currency value.
(a)
The J Curve
It is sometimes pointed out that in the very short term firms cannot change their plans. It takes
a little time for traders to react to international price changes resulting from exchange rate
movements. Consequently a swift devaluation or depreciation will increase the prices of
imports and decrease those of exports without changing quantities traded very much. The
immediate effect of the price changes will be to deepen the balance of payments deficit. Fairly
soon, however, plans and trading patterns are modified and we would expect demand for
imports to fall and foreign demand for exports to rise. The result would be to reduce the deficit
and, if the reactions were strong enough, to turn it into a surplus. This is illustrated by what is
usually known as the J curve, as illustrated in Figure 16.3.
Licensed to ABE
282
(c)
Licensed to ABE
283
both prices and wages, thus, erodes the competitive price advantages gained for exports against
imports by the devaluation. If inflation continues at a high rate, the export price advantage
may be lost very quickly.
For a developing country, both exports and imports are likely to be price inelastic. Thus, the
result of a devaluation, in this case, is to worsen an existing balance of payments deficit. The
devaluation will reduce total export earnings and increase total import costs. Devaluation,
therefore, will not help a developing country with balance of payments problems. It may help
an advanced industrial country but, probably, only in the short term. In itself, it does nothing
to cure the basic economic weakness which gave rise to the trading imbalance in the first place.
(d)
UK Experience
The British experience has been mixed. In the early 1980s, when sterling was valued at a high
rate as the UK started to become an oil-exporting nation, there was a very satisfactory
favourable balance for manufactured goods. This owed much to the depression of those years,
as distribution firms ran down stocks and as consumer demand for exports was also falling.
Manufacturers, however, were as much concerned about the very great fluctuations in rates as
about their level, and there is no doubt that the very large swings in 1984-5 were damaging to
trade. At the same time, it seemed that British manufacturers were suffering from an overpriced sterling, brought about by the oil situation. In 1983, Britains manufacturing account
moved into deficit for the first time since the Industrial Revolution, and in 1984 there was a
manufacturing deficit of around 3,250m. This seemed to indicate that sterling was overvalued
in relation to Britains non-oil trade. This position was probably owing not only to North Sea
oil but also to high interest rates caused by the British governments monetarist economic
policies. By 1988-89 a series of record monthly trade deficits, accompanied by renewed
domestic inflation was calling into question the entire economic strategy being pursued by the
British Government. Nevertheless the Government persisted in a high exchange rate strategy
and reinforced this with entry to the European Exchange Rate Mechanism which required this
rate to be maintained. The Government apparently hoped that exchange rate pressures would
ensure that business firms would resist inflationary tendencies to squeeze inflation out of the
system and make British business more efficient and competitive. However, an overvalued
currency could not be sustained in the long run and sterling was forced out of the ERM in the
Autumn of 1992. Its value quickly fell by about 15% against most other major trading
currencies.
Helped largely by this devaluation, the manufacturing account and the current balance of
payments responded well and the UK was able to follow the USA out of recession before the
other members of the European Union. This experience raised serious doubts about the value
to Britain of full membership of the European Union and helped to set in motion a fierce
political debate that, by mid-1995, was threatening to split the Conservative Party and which
was also a highly controversial issue within the Labour Party.
Deflation
Spending on imports is a form of consumption that is usually regarded as being dependent on the
level of income of a community. The higher the income, the more is likely to be spent on imports.
One way, therefore, to correct a balance of payments deficit is to reduce import levels or, at least, to
stop them rising too fast. A government faced with a balance of payments problem may seek to
reduce disposable income in the hands of consumers, and so reduce all consumption expenditure.
This will cut the demand for imports and also reduce the strength of demand for home-produced
Licensed to ABE
284
goods, so releasing them for export markets if firms can be persuaded to make a bigger export
effort. The government will achieve deflation by:
!
reducing its own spending and the demand for workers in the public sector;
restricting the money supply, so making it difficult for firms to increase wages and raise prices;
seeking to keep down wages or wage increases, with or without co-operation from unions.
This policy is usually successful in the short term but it does produce unemployment and it is,
politically, unpopular. It may also disrupt some sectors of industry, especially durable-goods
manufacturers. Firms may go out of business or invest abroad rather than at home. The result may
then be that, when the period of deflation is relaxed and demand rises again after the balance of
payments problem appears to have been cured, the increased consumer and business investment
demand has to be met from imports to an even greater extent than before the deflation. This leads
rapidly to an even worse balance of payments problem than the one just solved.
For a developing country, deflation is unlikely to be a satisfactory solution, because the imports are
needed for economic development and, if living standards are already very low, any reduction could
lead to violent social and political unrest.
Import Controls
The failure of devaluation and deflation to provide satisfactory long-term cures to Britains balance of
payments difficulties led to a revival of strong demand for control over imports through measures
such as quotas and tariffs.
Supporters of controls suggest that the danger of retaliation is not as great as is often assumed, and
they say that only with the protection of controls can the economy be fully revised. They usually also
suggest that massive government aid would be needed for industrial modernisation and investment,
and that the government would have to have greater controls over industry if it were to provide this
aid. Taxes would also be likely to stay high if this policy were adopted.
Other people remember that it was the attempt of individual countries to impose controls over
imports, yet keep on exporting, that led to the trade wars of the earlier part of the century and these,
in turn, helped to bring about the very severe depression and unemployment of those years. They feel
that the risk of such a tragedy being repeated is too great to allow import controls to be tried.
However, the demand for controls is very strong and, in the face of what are often termed unfair
trading practices of some countries, the chance that Britain may be forced to take some protective
measures must be recognised to be high.
Another danger is that industries do not, in fact reorganise behind the protective barrier and simply
become less competitive and rely on satisfactory home demand. This is why advocates of import
controls also tend to advocate increased public control to force modernisation.
The demand for import controls always increases during an economic recession when there tends to
be strong political pressure from industries with high unemployment rates or suffering from economic
change to be given protection from foreign competition. There was a tendency in the late 1980s and
early 1990s for informal methods of protection the use of various administrative devices to make
importing more difficult and expensive to increase. The GATT (General Agreement on Tariffs and
Trade) negotiations for reducing tariff and other barriers in order to encourage world trade, originally
due to be completed in 1992, encountered many difficulties as governments sought to defend their
own politically powerful groups including of course the farmers.
Licensed to ABE
285
The negotiations were eventually concluded by the end of 1994 and some progress was made towards
further trade liberalisation though these were extremely modest in relation to the three major trading
blocs of the European Union, North America and Japan. At the beginning of 1995 GATT was
replaced by a more structured body, the World Trade Organisation (WTO), which was given limited
powers to enforce agreements and discourage openly protectionist measures. These were quickly
tested by a trading dispute between the USA and Japan though this was resolved without breaching
WTO rules.
Licensed to ABE
286
Licensed to ABE
287
Study Unit 17
The Economics of International Trade
Contents
A.
B.
C.
D.
E.
Page
288
288
288
290
290
290
290
292
293
293
Protection
294
297
Methods of Protection
298
Tariffs
298
Quotas
299
Embargoes
300
300
300
Non-tariff Barriers
301
Exchange Control
301
International Agreements
301
Trading Blocs
301
303
307
Licensed to ABE
288
(b)
Lower Costs
A country can obtain goods which it could not grow or produce itself, and it can also obtain
goods which it could grow or produce but only at higher cost than in other countries.
International trade, by opening up the whole world for trading purposes, increases the size of
the markets for various goods. Production on a larger scale is, then, possible allowing full
advantage to be taken of economies of scale. If Switzerland only made watches for her own,
comparatively small, domestic market, the cost of production per unit would be much higher
than it is in fact, since Switzerland supplies most parts of the world with her watches.
(c)
(d)
A Curb on Monopoly
The existence of international trade is an obstacle to the development of monopolies. Even if
there are monopolies in existence in a country, their control over prices will be limited by the
ever-present threat of foreign competition.
We must, of course, recognise that this threat is often weakened by the development of large
multinational companies, and the tendency for these to limit world competition by agreements
between themselves and by their own power to absorb competitors.
(e)
Licensed to ABE
289
Assume that, for a given outlay (which might be measured in terms of labour and money),
!
Country A apparently has an advantage over country B in the production of both wheat and copper.
Both commodities can be produced more cheaply in country A, as, with a given outlay, more of each
will be produced in A than in B. Will there, then, be any scope at all for international trade? The
answer will be in the affirmative, provided that As advantage over B is not proportionately the same
for both commodities. A country will, thus, tend to specialise in the production of those commodities
in which it has the greatest comparative advantage, or the least comparative disadvantage.
Let us now illustrate this principle with the help of our example. In the absence of international
trade, A will produce 300 units of wheat and 150 units of copper, and for the same outlay, B will
produce 150 units of wheat and 100 units of copper. This makes a total of 450 units of wheat and 250
units of copper. In A, then, the cost of production of wheat is half that of copper, while in B it is 2/3
that of copper. As As comparative advantage in the production of wheat is greater than her advantage
over B in the production of copper, it will pay A to specialise in the growing of wheat and to leave
copper production to B.
Suppose B abandons production of wheat and concentrates on copper, then A can make good the lost
150 units of wheat by transferring half the original outlay from copper to wheat. This still leaves A
producing 75 units of copper, in addition to the increased 100 units of copper in B. Thus,
specialisation in each country has increased copper production without any loss of wheat. Provided
both countries trade with each other to share the increased production, both can gain from
specialisation and trade and A can gain by reducing its production of copper and importing from B,
even though it is more efficient as a copper-producer.
Table 17.1 illustrates the example just described. Here, the given outlay in resources is assumed to
be 20 workers available for producing either commodity.
Table 17.1
(a) Before specialisation
Country A
Product
Country B
Total
Units
Workers
employed
Units
Workers
employed
Units
Wheat
300
10
150
10
450
Copper
150
10
100
10
250
20
20
450
15
450
Copper
75
200
20
275
20
20
The same total resources (40 workers) now produce an additional 25 units of copper, without any loss
of wheat.
Licensed to ABE
290
production factors, including workers, are able to move from one activity to another within
each country i.e. there is factor mobility within countries;
no factors are left unemployed and unproductive as a result of the movement resulting from
increased specialisation;
If, for example, the advantage of country A, in the example above, arises out of superior managerial
skill, then the greatest gains might be achieved by exporting managers from A to B and improving the
standard of production in B.
These are very important qualifications, and they do not always hold good under modern conditions.
Production, today, is often highly specialised, and it is difficult and sometimes impossible to
transfer resources (including workers) from one activity to another within a country. Machines are
often built for one purpose only, and people may take years to retrain, and unions are often hostile to
movement. Many people displaced from one activity are just not able to learn the skills required for
another, expanding, activity. In these circumstances, it is not unusual to find high unemployment in
some sectors of production and a shortage of workers in another.
Licensed to ABE
291
18th century. However, these grew out of trading enterprises. World-scale manufacturing is a
development that belongs more to this century, and especially to the period after the Second World
War.
There are many reasons for this development. Among those most commonly put forward are the
following:
(a)
(b)
(c)
(d)
(e)
Product Life-cycle
If a company builds up a large export trade for a product, and if that trade is directed towards
countries the development of which is a little behind that of the home country, the time is likely
to come when the export market in the developing countries is larger than the domestic market
in the country of manufacture. By this time in the life of the product, it is probable that
competition is developing from firms situated inside, or closer to, the export market, and the
home market may also be starting to decline. It may well be that the production facilities will
need replacing.
At this stage, the manufacturer is likely to consider setting up new production facilities
(factories and machines) in the developing countries, where markets are growing. The
remaining market at home can be fed from imports out of the new factories.
In practice, some or all of these influences may be operating at the same time. The more influences
that do bear on an industry, then, of course, the greater the likelihood that it will become
multinational in character.
Licensed to ABE
292
(f)
Trade Barriers
Some countries and groups of countries discourage imports by tariffs and other trade barriers.
The European Community may be moving towards free trade between members but it has
many barriers to trade with non-members. It has been particularly restrictive against imports
from Japan so that to trade within the EC Japan has had to set up production units within the
Community. To avoid hostility against these units Japanese companies have built up
partnerships with European companies and have consented to use agreed proportions of
Community produced materials and components in their goods.
(b)
Licensed to ABE
293
It is frequently claimed that host countries gain benefits from importing managerial skills and
technical know-how. There is certainly some transfer of managerial skill and technology but
this can be exaggerated, especially where the majority of skilled functions are kept for
nationals of the home country, and where the home country retains full control over all
research and development.
It will be in the interests of the multinationals to keep factor costs low, and for labour to be
non-unionised, so they will not encourage the development of domestic industries which may
prove to be competitors, both in selling products and as employers of production factors. If
factors, especially wage-costs, do start to rise, then the multinational may be able to transfer
production to another country, leaving the original host country worse off than before.
(c)
countries can specialise and increase production safe in the knowledge that they can export
their surplus
Licensed to ABE
294
competition from imports increases efficiency and limits the creation of monopolies
The factors of production are immobile. Land, most labour and invested capital cannot move
between countries. Only enterprise, uncommitted capital and some labour can move to where the
other factors are abundant and production can be organised. Free trade overcomes the immobility of
factors: it permits the free movement of the product of immobile factors so that countries worldwide
can benefit from an abundant factor endowment in any place.
Access to the global market is essential for the 138 developing countries if they are to achieve
economic growth. Trade with the other 23 developed economies would give the developing nations a
large market for their goods and the opportunity to import new technology. Firms could gain
economies of scale and new techniques; competition would increase efficiency; monopolies are
avoided. Production for export helps to diversify the economy: it reduces dependence on what is
often a single crop subject to disasters, like sudden frosts which halve the output of coffee.
Protection
All trading nations engage in some form of trade protection as governments have to face political
pressures from powerful domestic interest groups. At the same time they are often reluctant to admit
that they are imposing barriers so they may avoid the formal measures that would invite retaliation
and invite censure from the World Trade Organisation. Instead they make use of a variety of devices
to delay imports or make them more expensive. These include cumbersome import procedures with
complicated documentation or safety measures with a dubious safety value.
At the same time the more formal measures still survive and are employed by individual countries
and regional groups such as the European Union (EU). The main such measures are:
!
import tariffs, also known as customs duties, which are taxes imposed on goods when they
enter a country or one of a group of countries such as the EU; whereas
We examine these and other forms of protection in the next section of this study unit.
The belief that free trade (trade free from imposed restrictions) should be encouraged as much as
possible is linked closely to the theory of comparative cost advantage. However, the benefits of
comparative advantage have been shown to depend on the existence of competitive markets, absence
of monopoly power, full employment, and ready factor transfer within countries and no factor
transfer between countries. We have, instead, a world economy dominated by the monopoly or
oligopolistic power of the large multinational enterprises, where few industries approach anywhere
near the conditions of perfect competition, where domestic economies are highly specialised, where
there is large-scale unemployment and little factor transfer within countries but important transfers
between countries. In these conditions, we have to ask whether the case for free trade should be
questioned and that for import controls looked at more seriously.
If a country does decide that, in its own case, the possible benefits of controls outweigh the dangers,
the following arguments can be advanced in favour of the use of protectionist measures.
Licensed to ABE
(a)
295
(b)
Licensed to ABE
296
(c)
Increase in Employment
Controls cut imports and, therefore, there may be an increased demand for home-produced
goods, and a resulting increase in employment. Income is directed away from foreign exports
and towards domestic producers. On the other hand, if there is already full employment at
home, such measures will tend to be inflationary in their effects.
(d)
(e)
National Security
Key industries, such as agriculture and those producing goods which are important for the
defence of the country, must be maintained for security reasons. A wide diversity of industries
is important to a country, as it renders her independent of foreign supplies which may be
jeopardised in the event of war.
(f)
(g)
(h)
Licensed to ABE
297
costs are often short of capital so that finance and equipment are frequently scarce and
expensive. Countries with high wage costs but with high levels of labour and managerial skills
and ready access to capital need to adopt different production methods from those applied in
low wage cost countries.
Continued Faith in the Benefits of Free Trade Based on Comparative Cost Advantage
It can be argued that multinational enterprise, unemployment and specialised production
represent modifications and imperfections only, and do not change the fundamental truth and
importance of the benefits to be derived from international specialisation and trade. According
to this view, efforts should be made to reduce the harmful effects of these including efforts to
reduce the monopoly power of large multinationals and to increase trade, not to interfere with
it.
(b)
(c)
Those who favour import controls argue that the case for free trade based on comparative advantage
has been weakened, as already explained. They also argue that controls are no more harmful to world
trade than the other measures which have been used in the past to correct balance of payments
deficits, and much less harmful to domestic production. They may even be less harmful than
deflation and devaluation, because they can be more discriminating. Deflation harms all forms of
production. Deflation also damages domestic industry by reducing total demand, and this tends to
harm some industries more than others. When demand rises again, these industries may not be able to
recover, with the result that imports rise to an even greater extent than before. Successive deflations
produce ever-increasing imports.
Import controls can be applied more heavily in those industries where the home firms are weakest
and, it is argued, help them to recover their lost markets. Where home industries have been
completely lost or very seriously weakened by past policies, it is suggested that state aid may be
necessary to bring about recovery and, in these cases, continued protection would be needed until
they were strong enough to compete again in world markets.
Supporters of import controls argue that, as the total effect is no worse than other measures to reduce
balance of payments deficits, there is no reason why the danger of retaliation would be any greater.
They also suggest that controls have the effect of reducing the propensity to import rather than the
absolute level of imports, and so allow the economy to expand more readily. Any reduction in the
marginal propensity to import will increase the value of the national income multiplier. An
Licensed to ABE
298
expanding economy could actually permit more total imports rather than less as a part of
increased total consumption.
D. METHODS OF PROTECTION
A country which has nevertheless decided to restrict the freedom of international trade can use many
methods. The main methods of protection are:
!
import quotas
embargoes
exchange control.
Tariffs
Tariffs or customs duties are taxes on imported goods and so, of course, they raise money for the
government. The object is to raise the cost of the imported goods so that importers have to raise
prices or accept reduced profits. The imports thus suffer a competitive disadvantage compared with
home produced substitutes. The tariff raises the price paid for the imported good by the domestic
consumer and reduces the quantity purchased thus, domestic producers supply more to the market,
and foreign suppliers provide less, than if there were no tariff.
Customs duties may be imposed by a specific duty of so much per item or per tonne or ad valorem,
which is by value. Specific duties work best for goods of low value and high weight like iron. Ad
valorem duties obviously have more impact as goods increase in value, so they are best applied to
items like jewellery and those whose prices change often.
The amount received by foreign exporters may be the same or less than before the tariff depending on
the elasticity of demand. The more price-elastic the demand for the product, the more the producers
have to absorb the effect of the tax to prevent a loss of sales which would cause them a loss. The
effects of a tariff are shown in Figure 17.1.
Licensed to ABE
299
Areas b and d added together give the net costs of tariff protection to the economy. Tax and the
additional domestic supply remain in the economy.
Not only do consumers pay a higher price and buy less but there is also some loss of economic
welfare because they are forced to buy the domestic product, which restricts their choice.
Quotas
Quotas are restrictions on the quantity of a product which can be imported.
While the purpose of protective customs duties is to restrict the import of goods by making them
more expensive to the home consumer in order to persuade him not to buy them, the purpose of
import quotas is to lay down the exact quantity of a commodity which may be imported in a given
period of time. Import quotas may, but need not, be accompanied by customs duties. If they are, it
means that the limited amount of goods which may be imported is subject to the duty as well. Quotas
first came into prominence during the 1920s and 1930s but they have also been widely used since the
Second World War.
The reasons why some countries prefer to substitute quotas for customs duties or to strengthen
protective duties by quotas are as follows:
Licensed to ABE
300
(a)
(b)
Quotas may generally be altered by administrative means e.g. by an order by the Department
of Trade and Industry. Customs duties are taxes and, as such, they are subject to parliamentary
control. If it is desired to strengthen or to relax protection, a change in customs duties might be
hotly contested in Parliament, while a change in quotas could be brought into effect without
much ado.
(c)
Many pre-war international trade agreements expressly prohibited the participating countries
from changing their existing customs duties, and the imposition of quotas was one way of
getting round this restriction.
(d)
Quotas also lend themselves admirably to a policy of discrimination. With customs duties, the
same rate of duty will, normally, be payable on goods of a certain kind, irrespective of the
country from which they come. A country wishing to reduce the volume of her imports,
however, may wish to cut down imports from a particular source e.g. because the country
concerned has a so-called hard currency, i.e. a currency which is in short supply. This end
may be achieved by a quota scheme under which different countries are allocated different
quotas, the quotas for goods from countries with soft currencies being rather more generous
than those for countries with hard currencies.
(e)
A mistaken argument in favour of quotas, which is occasionally heard, is that quotas, unlike
customs duties, will not lead to higher prices. This argument is wrong because, if a quota is
effective in the sense that it lowers the supply of certain imported goods, these goods will be in
scarce supply in relation to the demand for them, and this situation will, inevitably, lead to
higher prices.
Embargoes
An embargo is a total ban on imports or exports, usually applied for political reasons. A recent
example is the United Nations embargo on exports of armaments to Iraq and on oil exports from Iraq.
Licensed to ABE
301
Non-tariff Barriers
This is a term used to cover a multitude of measures applied to restrict imports, especially where
countries cannot use tariffs and quotas because they belong to GATT or a free trade area. They
include oppressive safety measures like the USA requirement for destructive car tests which would
require the whole annual output of a small specialist manufacturer to be crashed. France attempted to
keep out Far Eastern video recorders by insisting they went through one small, remote customs post
where there were bound to be very long delays in clearing them. In the 1970s Britain required
importers to pay an advance deposit on all goods: this imposed an extra borrowing cost and pushed
up the price of imports. Around the same time the UK had two rates of VAT, the higher rate applied
to goods like motor bikes which were mostly imported.
The term is also applied when discussing trade liberalisation, to all restrictive measures except tariffs.
This is because tariffs are the only measure to be visible and measurable with accuracy. Agreements
to reduce tariffs are pointless if duties are replaced by other measures which are difficult to police.
Exchange Control
Control is enforced in many countries by requiring all buying and selling of foreign exchange to be
done through the central bank; the currency is not convertible into other currencies of the holders
choice. The government can then allocate foreign exchange to whichever activities it considers
should have priority. This is effectively the same as a quota and is subject to the same dangers.
Governments can avoid some of the problems by auctioning off foreign exchange, as was done in
Nigeria. The amount released to auction is determined by the state of the balance of payments.
Governments have also set multiple exchange rates for example the South African rand had a
commercial and a financial rate until 1995 and they can alter the value of the currency to make
exports cheaper and imports dearer. The majority of countries have retained some form of exchange
control; very few have followed Britains 1979 example of abolishing all exchange controls and all
restrictions on the movement of capital.
E. INTERNATIONAL AGREEMENTS
Trading Blocs
Countries can join together in several different ways to obtain the benefits of free trade among
themselves while keeping others out. What is included in the agreement depends on the political will
of the members; they may be unwilling to expose agriculture to competition, or to accept the full
degree of international specialisation which goes with completely free trade. Giving up some control
of their national economies makes it difficult for countries to enter into these agreements.
There are effects on the direction of trade some countries benefit and others lose. These blocs all
have tariff walls which discriminate against imports from non-members. Trade may be diverted by
the tariff from a low-cost producer country which is a non-member to a high-cost member state. The
effects of trading blocs have to be carefully evaluated to see if they really do benefit the citizens of
the member countries and not just protect inefficient producers.
(a)
Types of Bloc
The types of international integration are as follows.
!
Licensed to ABE
302
(b)
Free trade areas are where the members abolish tariffs on trade between themselves,
but each country keeps its own tariff on imports from outside the area. This makes it
necessary to have rules of origin to prevent imports being brought in through the lowest
external tariff country. The North American Free Trade Area and the Association of
South East Asian Nation are examples.
Customs unions have free trade within the area with a common external tariff.
Common markets are customs unions with additional measures to encourage the
mobility of the factors of production and capital. The EC opened its common internal
market on 1 January 1993. Citizens of the member countries can live and work
anywhere in the EC, capital can move freely and there is a continuing programme of
harmonisation of standards and regulations to permit the free flow of goods and services.
The 1991 Maastricht Treaty agreed to a programme to move to economic and monetary
union and to take the first steps towards political union by agreeing common foreign
policies.
Effects of a Bloc
Creating a trade bloc has two major effects:
!
Trade creation when a country which previously placed tariffs on imports from
another member and produced the goods itself, switches to buying such goods from
another member country, this creates trade (although it may cause structural
unemployment).
Trade diversion, when the removal of barriers inside the bloc results in trade being
switched from a more efficient producer outside the union to a less efficient one inside.
In addition to the benefits of trade creation, there are other benefits from setting up a free trade
area.
!
Economies of scale develop because the member countries now have a much larger
home market.
Greater efficiency is enforced because the members industries are exposed to more
competition.
Consumer welfare is increased as people have more, better-quality and cheaper goods,
with more variety, to choose from.
There is more political co-operation as the member countries develop common policies
and become more dependent on each other.
Against this must be set loss of political and economic independence, because the countries
must take into account the policies and rules of the union when deciding their own policies.
The larger the trading bloc, the greater the potential benefits because of the better chance of
including the lowest-cost producer and the bigger opportunities for economies of scale. There
will be more opportunities for trade creation whereas there will have been a lot of duplication,
and large cost differences between the production of the members, before the union. There will
be more to be gained from specialisation. This is especially the case when there were high
tariffs before the union; there would then have been a lot of domestic production for relatively
Licensed to ABE
303
small markets. The lower the external tariffs imposed by the union, the better, as this reduces
the possibilities of trade diversion.
Licensed to ABE
304
cleared the way for Austria, Finland, Norway and Sweden to apply to join the EC. A referendum in
Norway voted to stay out, but the others joined the community in 1995, making the membership 15
countries. Also in 1995, Liechtenstein voted to join the EEA.
Turkey, which signed an association agreement in 1964, is still awaiting a decision on membership,
and Cyprus and Malta also have long-standing applications. In addition, several East European
countries have applied for full membership, and the EC is gearing up for considerable expansion in
the future.
The EC has association agreements with countries having former colonial ties with member states:
these provide for exemption from the common external tariff, and for financial and technical
assistance from the European Development Fund. The Lom Conventions have expanded duty- and
quota-free access to 66 African, Caribbean and Pacific countries. Co-operation agreements are less
comprehensive than association agreements, as they provide merely for intensive economic cooperation; they have been signed with Mediterranean countries.
The original aims of the ECSC, Euratom and EEC treaties were:
!
Since then, a numbers of measures have been taken to develop these aims and give form to the
concept of a common market.
(a)
Removal of technical barriers to trade agreement on basic quality and safety standards,
general acceptance of national testing procedures, opening up of public procurement to
EC-wide tendering, and dismantling of any remaining barriers to the free movement of
workers, services and capital, including mutual recognition of educational qualifications.
Removal of fiscal barriers to trade removal of fiscal checks at frontiers (there is one
VAT documentation system EC-wide), approximation of indirect taxation rates.
It was estimated that economies of scale, job creation and stabilised prices arising from the
creation of the Single European Market would add 5% to Europes industrial output; further
benefits would come from scrapping frontier formalities.
Licensed to ABE
305
There is still a lot to be done to free the market from restrictions. Air traffic is subject to rules
which prevent airlines from picking up passengers at intermediate stops. Freedom of entry to
the telecommunications market is impossible in most countries where it is a state monopoly.
However, the Act did remove 300 restraints and provided for further freeing of trade.
Countries can retain border checks for criminals and illegal immigrants.
(b)
A common European currency by 1999 (which we have already touched on and will
come back to again shortly)
Special rules on social policy because the UK exercised its right to opt out of the
relevant chapter of the Treaty
Rights to citizenship of the European Union (EU) (also, for example, EU citizens not
living in their home countries can vote in local elections in the country in which they
live)
Provisions on co-operation in the fields of justice and home affairs for example, there
is a move to set up a police force co-ordinating body which the French stopped at the last
minute in 1995.
Common Policies
In a number of areas the member states have transferred sovereignty to the Community and
given it power to make and implement its own policies. These include the following.
!
Almost 10% of the total EC workforce is employed in agriculture, the proportion ranging
from 2% in the UK to 26% in Greece. It is a powerful political lobby. The common
agricultural policy (CAP) guarantees a minimum price to farmers through intervention
to buy surpluses when the market price drops below the target price. Threshold prices
are set for imports, which are generally higher than world market prices. A levy is
placed on imports to bring them up to the threshold. Agriculture takes 65% of the
Communitys budget.
The CAP has created the notorious wine lakes and butter and beef mountains, as overproduction was bought and placed into intervention stores, later to be sold off cheaply to
the Soviet Union. Reform of the CAP has led to strict quotas for production and
Licensed to ABE
306
payments to farmers to leave land fallow; pricing of the reduced output is now more
market-oriented. There is a continuing programme of reform, which was given an added
impetus by the GATT agreement on reducing subsidies.
(d)
Competition policy lays down rules for free competition. The European Commission
and the European Court of Justice punish with heavy fines abuse of a dominant market
position to fix prices, to limit output, or to restrict market access or technical
development. The policy also bans or supervises national subsidies to firms or
industries, to prevent them from gaining an unfair advantage. International mergers
which would give a firm a dominant position are scrutinised by the Commission.
Social policy carries out the aims of the Social Charter. It sets aims for use of the Social
Fund, which gets about 8% of the budget. The main priority is job creation. The Fund
provides basic vocational training and specialist training in other areas, for example in
information technology and for the disabled. There is a regional dimension to the Social
Fund spending.
Regional policy controls the use of the Regional fund to target assistance towards
national schemes, so as to stimulate investment and create jobs in less developed regions
and reduce the disparities between rich and poor regions. Regional policy gets about
11% of the budget and targets regions with lagging development, areas affected by
industrial decline, combating long-term and youth unemployment, and structural
adjustment of agricultural areas.
The common commercial policy is concerned with the Communitys relations with the
rest of the world and includes common customs tariffs, customs and trade agreements,
liberalisation of trade with non-member countries, and export policy. The EU negotiated
as a unit in the Uruguay Round of GATT talks on trade liberalisation.
planned or actual government budget deficits should not exceed 3% of GDP at market
prices
the ratio of total government debt should not exceed 60% of GDP at market prices
one-year inflation rates must be within 1.5% of the three best performing economies
one-year long-term interest rates must be within 2% of the three best performing
economies
the currency must have remained within the narrow ERM band for the two previous
years without devaluation.
Licensed to ABE
307
Some softening of the requirements in the Treaty, allowing for the debt ratio to be reducing and
for the annual deficit to be ignored if it is temporary, enabled more countries to meet the
criteria. (Ironically, Britain which has reserved the right to opt out and will hold a
referendum on future membership is one of the few nations able to meet all the criteria.)
The European Central Bank, located in Germany, took over from the European Monetary
Institute and became responsible for monetary policy as part of the European System of Central
Banks (ESCB), the other members being the national central banks. The European Central
Bank has to ensure that the ESCB carries out the tasks imposed on it by Maastricht, namely:
!
to hold and manage the foreign exchange reserves of the member countries of the EC
to promote the smooth operation of the payments system for cross-border monetary
transfers
There will be a four year interim period before the European Central Bank authorises the issue
of bank-notes and coins which would be the sole legal tender (the Euro) in the member states.
The jury is still out on the success of European Monetary Union. There should be benefits to
industry and commerce of all countries in the EC using the same currency, with the problems
and costs of doing business in two currencies disappearing. This should provide an incentive
to trade.
The main debate has been over the implication of a single currency that there would have to be
an integrated fiscal policy to develop and maintain the economic convergence necessary. This
implies that countries would have to give up control of their economic policies. The policy
stance will be likely to be anti-inflationary and may mean high levels of unemployment with
strong economies being obliged to pay for unemployment in the weak, so there would be a
transfer of resources from high-employment countries to the others.
The role and status of the Euro on the worlds money markets is also unclear. It has not fared
well over the first year of its existence, although its loss of value against other currencies has
made Euroland highly competitive against other countries.
Further, by the time that EMU is fully implemented in 2003, there may well have been an
enlargement of the community, and it is unclear how the concept will fare when there are over
20 member states.
Licensed to ABE
308
The World Bank has funded major projects, social development and private enterprises in
developing countries by using the capital subscribed by the member countries as collateral for
its borrowing.
The IMF holds substantial resources, paid in members subscriptions, which can be used to help
countries with balance of payments difficulties. Its establishment represented an amazing
transfer of sovereign powers by countries to an international body during the period of fixed
exchange rates up to 1972, it was given control of exchange rates.
The International Trade Organisation, however, was too much for the 23 countries to accept they
would not give up sovereign power over their trade. The result was the General Agreement on Tariffs
and Trade (GATT), which has no controlling powers but has attempted to get countries to agree to
liberalise trade through a series of conferences.
Trade liberalisation has been carried forward in a series of GATT Rounds (of talks) which started in
1947 and reached the eighth, the Uruguay Round in 1986. By that time, the average level of tariffs
had been reduced from 40% to 7%. GATT had also had considerable success in ending trade
discrimination, but several problems remained where major countries and groups had entrenched
positions.
There are now over 100 members who agree to abide by the most favoured nation rule, which
means that one member which grants trade concessions to another agrees to extend them to all
members of GATT.
The Uruguay Round was carried on in a series of meetings since it started in 1986, but by 1993 had
failed to make progress on certain vital areas like agricultural subsidies and protection for textiles,
which are of interest to developing countries, and intellectual property (patents, etc.) and trade in
services where the developed countries wanted protection.
However there was a last-minute agreement in December 1993 which went far beyond anything
which could have been expected in 1986. The new deal came into force in 1995, eliminating tariffs
on 40% of manufactured goods and reducing others substantially. Non-tariff barriers were also
reduced and a new transparency in international protection established, as easy-to-hide non-tariff
barriers were replaced by published tariffs. A new framework of rules on subsidies, trade restrictions
and public purchases was agreed, agriculture was brought fully into GATT for the first time, and
trade in intellectual property was also be covered for the first time, giving protection to patents,
copyright and trademarks. The French managed to exclude audio-visual services from the deal and
the USA was unwilling to permit the inclusion of maritime services. Financial services were only
partly liberated, with a reciprocity rule applying between countries so that any liberalisation by one
partner has to be matched by the other.
Despite these limitations, the agreement represents the largest-ever liberalisation of trade and is
expected to make the world $6 trillion wealthier developed countries benefit from the removal of
barriers to services, and developing countries from freeing trade in agriculture and textiles. More
optimistic analysts predict that the agreement could create over 400,000 jobs in the EC by the year
2005.
For the longer term, the most significant development may have been the transformation of GATT
into the new World Trade Organisation in 1993, with real powers to police protective practices. The
WTO was, though, immediately faced with a trade dispute between America and Japan over trading
practices and another between America and China over intellectual property, and has been dogged by
Licensed to ABE
309
disputes about the influence of developed countries and multinational companies, and underrepresentation of the interests of developing countries. This has meant that further trade liberalisation
has been limited, although a major agreement was concluded on telecommunications in 1997.
Licensed to ABE
310
Licensed to ABE
311
Study Unit 18
Foreign Exchange
Contents
A.
B.
Page
International Money
312
312
312
312
314
314
314
315
315
316
Licensed to ABE
312
Foreign Exchange
A. INTERNATIONAL MONEY
The Need for International Money
We have seen earlier in the course that anything can serve as money, as long as it is accepted as
money. It will be accepted only as long as it can be readily used to purchase real goods and services.
Money, therefore, ceases to have any value as money when it cannot be easily traded for real goods.
The area of acceptability, thus, becomes extremely important for the value of any form of money, and
this is a point of very great concern for matters of international finance and trade.
Therefore, when one country sells goods to another, it wishes to be paid in a form of money
(currency) which it can readily use to purchase its own goods elsewhere, or which it can change into
its own currency to pay its own workers and suppliers at home.
You might think that it would all be a lot simpler if every country in the world used exactly the same
currency, which would then be universal, and which would not be identified with any one nation.
Licensed to ABE
Foreign Exchange
313
stronger economies than others, and some governments have firmer control over their national
economic and financial systems than others. For simplicity, we can identify four classes of currency
used in international trade.
(a)
(b)
(c)
(d)
Licensed to ABE
314
Foreign Exchange
Trade may often be conducted by barter arrangements with some countries with weak currencies. For
these agreements, some form of acceptable valuation is necessary and, again, the basis of this tends
to be the United States dollar, either directly or indirectly (e.g. through oil).
Licensed to ABE
Foreign Exchange
315
Licensed to ABE
316
Foreign Exchange
In the long term, currency movements are most probably influenced by relative rates of inflation; in
the short term this consideration can be outweighed by other influences such as interest rates, trade
flows and political stability. You should also remember that, as in other markets, buyers and sellers
are as much concerned with the future as with the present and the past. If the market thinks that a
currency is likely to fall in the future it will anticipate that belief by selling now so that expectations
can be self-fulfilling. This does not mean that the market is always right. Anticipations about future
movements are based on past experience so that the market may not recognise that a fundamental
shift has taken place until this becomes completely clear and then it may over-react. For example,
between 1962 and 1992 Britain had a generally poor record in controlling inflation so that by 1995
currency markets remained sceptical about future inflation rates in Britain in spite of the declared
intentions of the British Government and its relative successes between 1992 and 1995. Over a
similar period Japans economic record had been one of spectacular success so that the market
continued to believe that its economic problems of the first half of the 1990s were likely to be
temporary. It is quite feasible that the judgement of the currency markets was wrong in the mid1990s for both countries. The currency traders risked losing a great deal of money if their beliefs
were wrong and only future events will show whether or not they were correct.
Licensed to ABE
Foreign Exchange
317
they provide the stability and reduction in currency risks that traders need if they are to
expand trade and production
Opponents of fixed rate structures point out that periods of apparent exchange rate stability
tend to be punctuated with intense speculative crises and periods of serious and damaging
instability when finance markets realise that a major currency (usually sterling!) has become
overvalued and they suspect that the government does not have the power to prevent a
devaluation. A series of crises led to the abandonment of the Bretton Woods system in the
early 1970s and a similar crisis led to the withdrawal of sterling from the ERM in 1992.
Opponents also point out that the only measures that governments can take to uphold the
exchange value of a currency in the short term are extremely damaging to their domestic
economies and further undermine long term confidence in the currency. A monetarist
government will rely on high interest rates to keep capital in the country but these high rates
can have a devastating effect on consumer demand and business investment as shown in Britain
in the period 1989-1992. A Keynesian government would raise taxation and curb wages and
other incomes and this would have a similar deflationary effect to high interest rates. Clearly a
government seeking to maintain an overvalued currency will damage its own domestic
economy, create high unemployment and destroy business firms. Living standards fall in the
interests of an artificial currency stability which cannot be sustained for more than a short
period.
Currency exchange rates represent the market price of a nations currency. They are the
international traders valuation of the nations production system. Stable exchange rates can
only be achieved when economies are themselves stable, prosperous and competitive in world
markets. A falling exchange rate is the symptom of an unhealthy economy. To prop it up
artificially is like propping up a weak patient and pretending that the patient is fit and well. It
is as dangerous to the economy as it is to a sick person and eventually all such pretences have
to be abandoned.
(b)
Licensed to ABE
318
Foreign Exchange
Licensed to ABE
Foreign Exchange
319
Conversely an increase in supply, with demand remaining the same, would cause the currency
to depreciate and each franc would buy more pounds i.e. the price of a pound has fallen.
Governments have often attempted to manage floating exchange rates: this is called dirty
floating. A government may intervene in the market to buy or sell its currency because it
wants to hold down a rise in the rate, which would affect international competitiveness, or
support a rate to keep foreign investments.
There have been attempts by the major industrial countries to influence the exchange rate of
the US dollar. Many commodities and raw materials, especially oil, are priced worldwide in
dollars; a rise in the value of the dollar for speculative reasons unconnected to trade could
cause inflation. When, in 1991, the dollar rose by a quarter against the deutschmark, the G7
(the seven most industrialised nations) took concerted action to stem the rise by central bank
intervention to sell dollars. In 1995 the dollar was falling against other currencies because of
fears about the effect of the very large US government deficit and the political situation; this
led to a flight into the deutschmark, a rise in its rate and a depreciation of other currencies.
The effect is to make the exports of appreciating countries less competitive and those of
depreciating ones more so this is destabilising and has nothing to do with the trading position
of the countries. Central banks intervened to buy dollars in an attempt to prevent further falls
in the rate.
Even when all the major central banks act together, they cannot have a significant effect on the
foreign exchange market. The sheer size of the markets daily dealings makes the reserves of
the industrialised countries look small. The banks can try to influence the feeling in the market
so that dealers change their attitude to the future of the currency.
The advantages of floating exchange rates are:
!
There is an inbuilt adjustment mechanism. If imports exceed exports, the currency will
depreciate and exports become relatively cheaper in foreign countries, thus helping to
increase exports. There is no need for government intervention.
There is continuous adjustment of the rate, in contrast to the infrequent, large and
disruptive revaluations in fixed systems.
There is no possibility of imported inflation, as the exchange rate adjusts relative prices.
There is no need for large official reserves (unless there is managed floating).
Adjustments to the exchange rate are made by the market: they are not delayed by
political considerations.
They create uncertainty and raise the costs of international activities because of the need
to cover risk.
Changes in the rate may be due to speculation or flight from weakening currencies and
have nothing to do with the trading position of the country. This may make exports
relatively dearer and imports cheaper and cause a payments deficit.
The impact of a change in a floating exchange rate depends on the price elasticities of demand
for exports and imports. If both are elastic, a fall in the rate will reduce imports, which become
Licensed to ABE
320
Foreign Exchange
dearer in the home market, and increase exports, which become cheaper in foreign markets.
The opposite happens if the rate appreciates. If the demand for exports abroad is inelastic, the
effect of a depreciation will be that the volume of exports does not increase but the lower price
earns less foreign exchange. If imports are price-inelastic, the rise in their price does not
reduce demand significantly and more foreign exchange is bought to pay for them: this
worsens the balance of payments. Higher import prices for materials, components and finished
goods may cause inflation.
Licensed to ABE