Summaries Strategy & Organization Design
Summaries Strategy & Organization Design
samenvattingen
SOD
Week 1
Barney
Why do firms exist The Economist
Summary of Why Do firms exists? from The Economist.
This article is written in celebration of the 100th birthday of Ronald Coase.
The main question for management theorist is Why do firms exists, why is not
everything done by the market?. Classical economists say very little about this
question: they prefer to focus on the sea rather than on the islands. Adam Smith
talked about a pin factory but nobody continued this story.
Until Coarse picked up the pin factory and restored it to its rightful place. He
published many articles but it wasnt until he was 80 that he was rewarded a
Nobel prize. His central insight was that firms exists because going to the market
all the time can impose heavy transaction costs. He was one of the few to look
inside the black box that the firm is.
He is known for his critics on his colleagues because he thought that they were
too theoretical: they should look at what was really going on in the business
instead of looking in their textbooks.
Mr Coases narrow focus on transaction costs provides only a partial explanation
of the power of the firms. It has led to a fierce backlash of management theorists
who argue that activities are conducted within firms not only because markets
fail, but also because firms succeed: they can marshal a wide range of resources
like corporate culture and collective knowledge, that markets cannot access. This
is aligned with the resource-based theory.
So Coases theory of market failure should be complemented by a theory of
organizational advantages.
Smith, 1776
Summary: An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations: Book
I
by Adam Smith
An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nationsis widely
considered to be the first modern work in the field of economics. The work is also
the first comprehensive defense of free market policies
Chapter 1
Of the Division of Labour
The greatest improvement in the productive powers of labour, and the greater part of the skill,
dexterity, and judgment with which it is anywhere directed, or applied, seem to have been the effects
of the division of labour.
The effects of the division of labour, in the general business of society, will be more easily understood
by considering in what manner it operates in some particular manufactures. It is commonly supposed
to be carried furthest in some very trifling ones; not perhaps that it really is carried further in them
than in others of more importance: but in those trifling manufactures which are destined to supply the
small wants of but a small number of people, the whole number of workmen must necessarily be
small; and those employed in every different branch of the work can often be collected into the same
workhouse, and placed at once under the view of the spectator. In those great manufactures, on the
contrary, which are destined to supply the great wants of the great body of the people, every different
branch of the work employs so great a number of workmen that it is impossible to collect them all into
the same workhouse. We can seldom see more, at one time, than those employed in one single branch.
Though in such manufactures, therefore, the work may really be divided into a much greater number
of parts than in those of a more trifling nature, the division is not near so obvious, and has accordingly
been much less observed.
To take an example, therefore, from a very trifling manufacture; but one in which the division of
labour has been very often taken notice of, the trade of the pin-maker; a workman not educated to
this business (which the division of labour has rendered a distinct trade), nor acquainted with the use
of the machinery employed in it (to the invention of which the same division of labour has probably
given occasion), could scarce, perhaps, with his utmost industry, make one pin in a day, and certainly
could not make twenty. But in the way in which this business is now carried on, not only the whole
work is a peculiar trade, but it is divided into a number of branches, of which the greater part are
likewise peculiar trades. One man draws out the wire, another straights it, a third cuts it, a fourth
points it, a fifth grinds it at the top for receiving, the head; to make the head requires two or three
distinct operations; to put it on is a peculiar business, to whiten the pins is another; it is even a trade
by itself to put them into the paper; and the important business of making a pin is, in this manner,
divided into about eighteen distinct operations, which, in some manufactories, are all performed by
distinct hands, though in others the same man will sometimes perform two or three of them. I have
seen a small manufactory of this kind where ten men only were employed, and where some of them
consequently performed two or three distinct operations. But though they were very poor, and
therefore but indifferently accommodated with the necessary machinery, they could, when they exerted
themselves, make among them about twelve pounds of pins in a day. There are in a pound upwards of
four thousand pins of a middling size. Those ten persons, therefore, could make among them upwards
of forty-eight thousand pins in a day. Each person, therefore, making a tenth part of forty-eight
thousand pins, might be considered as making four thousand eight hundred pins in a day. But if they
had all wrought separately and independently, and without any of them having been educated to this
peculiar business, they certainly could not each of them have made twenty, perhaps not one pin in a
day; that is, certainly, not the two hundred and fortieth, perhaps not the four thousand eight hundredth
part of what they are at present capable of performing, in consequence of a proper division and
combination of their different operations.
In every other art and manufacture, the effects of the division of labour are similar to what they are in
this very trifling one; though, in many of them, the labour can neither be so much subdivided, nor
reduced to so great a simplicity of operation. The division of labour, however, so far as it can be
introduced, occasions, in every art, a proportionable increase of the productive powers of labour. The
separation of different trades and employments from one another seems to have taken place in
consequence of this advantage.
This great increase of the quantity of work which, in consequence of the division of labour, the same
number of people are capable of performing, is owing to three different circumstances; first, to the
increase of dexterity in every particular workman; secondly, to the saving of the time which is
commonly lost in passing from one species of work to another; and lastly, to the invention of a
great number of machines which facilitate and abridge labour, and enable one man to do the work of
many.
First, the improvement of the dexterity of the workman necessarily increases the quantity of the work
he can perform; and the division of labour, by reducing every man's business to some one simple
operation, and by making this operation the sole employment of his life, necessarily increased very
much dexterity of the workman. The different operations into which the making of a pin, or of a metal
button, is subdivided, are all of them much more simple, and the dexterity of the person, of whose life
it has been the sole business to perform them, is usually much greater. The rapidity with which some
of the operations of those manufacturers are performed, exceeds what the human hand could, by those
who had never seen them, be supposed capable of acquiring.
Secondly, the advantage which is gained by saving the time commonly lost in passing from one sort of
work to another is much greater than we should at first view be apt to imagine it. It is impossible to
pass very quickly from one kind of work to another that is carried on in a different place and with
quite different tools. Independent, therefore, of his deficiency in point of dexterity, this cause alone
must always reduce considerably the quantity of work which he is capable of performing.
Thirdly, and lastly, everybody must be sensible how much labour is facilitated and abridged by the
application of proper machinery. Men are much more likely to discover easier and readier methods of
attaining any object when the whole attention of their minds is directed towards that single object than
when it is dissipated among a great variety of things. But in consequence of the division of labour, the
whole of every man's attention comes naturally to be directed towards some one very simple object. It
is naturally to be expected, therefore, that some one or other of those who are employed in each
particular branch of labour should soon find out easier and readier methods of performing their own
particular work, wherever the nature of it admits of such improvement.
Coase (1937) - The nature of the firm - foundation of transaction cost economics
Coase defines two types of coordination:
Transactions that take place across markets (through the price mechanism).
Transactions that take place within the firm (the entrepreneur-coordinator allocates the factors
of production between the different uses)
According to Coase (1937) firms exist because there is a cost of using the price
system. The cost to find out what the relevant prices are and a cost to draw up a
separate contract for each market transaction (in a firm the number of contracts
is greatly reduced: long term, transparent prices, lower perceived risk). Under
some circumstances (e.g. high uncertainty) it may be hardly possible or
extremely costly to reach a contractual agreement which may serve as a basis
for a market transaction. Therefore, the relative cost of transacting under the
market or the firm determines which type of coordination is used; transactions
will be executed at the lowest cost.
Authority of entrepreneurs allocate resources inside the firm. Economists argue
that this is still done on the base of price theory (agency theory). In the end,
make or buy decisions include the transaction costs economics as well. Make or
buy decisions are about integrating a business activity either down- or upstream.
Why, if by organizing one can eliminate certain costs and in fact reduce the cost of production, are
there any market transactions at all?
As firms get larger, there may be decreasing returns to the entrepreneur function.
As the transactions which are organized increase, the entrepreneur fails to place the factors of
production in the uses where their value is greatest (fails to make the best use of the factors of
production)
The supply price of one or more of the factors of production may rise, because the other
advantages of a small firm are greater than those of a large firm.
___________________________________________________________________________
2e Samenvatting
Coase: "The Nature of the Firm"
Themes:
In introductory and intermediate economics, firms are assumed to exist, and are
characterized by production functions, cost curves, demand curves, etc.
Observations:
Firms transform inputs into outputs...but so do individuals.
Firms are characterized by employers and employees..but in a way so are
market transactions.
Firms are legal entities...but this is an uninteresting definition that we
won't address.
One can imagine production w/o firms: individual traders exhanging capital and
labor for payment, these being combined and marketed.
Coase's observation: There are costs to using the price mechanism for
coordinating economic activity. "transaction costs" or "marketing costs"
Given this, alternative institutional arrangements may coordinate economic
activity at a lower cost. For example, it may be less costly for an individual to
direct how resources should be used.
(imagine the costs of bargaining within a firm every time your boss tells you to do
something upon which you have not previously agreed!)
Firms exist to economize on the cost of coordinating economic activity.
Firms are characterized by the absence of the price mechanism.
This is an important insight that has been applied toward explaining many
institutions other than firms. Institutions arise in order to economize on
transaction cost (Williamson, etc.) For example, bank clearing houses, commodity
markets, vertical integration, etc.
in another firm
mediated by the market.
MC of organizing one more transaction within the firm equals the cost of using
alternative institutional arrangements.
Under Coase's definition of the firm, do traveling salesmen who sell the
products of only one firm and get paid solely on commission count as
employees? Or are they independent contractors working for themselves?
How about temps (secretaries and receptionists)? Do they work for a firm?
Which one?
Movie theater chains and distributors are often under the same firm name
(under the legal definition). However, when movies come out, they are
offered to exhibitors on a non-discriminatory basis. United Artists theaters
must bid for the right to show motion pictures distributed by United Artists.
By Coase, are they the same firm?
In the Soviet Union, capital was often allocated across firms by
governmental direction. By Coase, were the individual productive
enterprises firms?
How about the different divisions of Bell which used transfer prices to
allocate goods? Does it matter if the price was a market price or set
internally?
Some examples
How would one form a Coaseian explanation for the Disney-ABC/Cap Cities
merger?
The cost of coordinating the economic activity within Disney and ABC separately
was higher than the cost of doing so together under the direction of Disney's
management. Furthermore, it is less costly to do everything that Disney does
managing by fiat than mediated through the price mechanism.
What is a similar explanation for GM's spinning off EDS?
The cost of coordinating economic activity of these firms separately is lower than
the cost of doing so together under GM's direction.
It is in a team use of inputs and a centralized position of some party in the contractual
arrangements of all other inputs. It is the centralized contractual agent in a team productive
process not some superior authoritarian directive or disciplinary power.
Give him title to the net earnings of the team, net of payments to other inputs.
The added incentive for the monitor is the residual product. The monitor earns his
residual through the reduction in shirking that he brings about, not only by the
prices that he agrees to pay the owners of the inputs, but also by observing and
directing the actions or uses of these inputs.
Managing or examining the ways to which inputs are used in team production is a
method of metering the marginal productivity of individual inputs to the teams
output.
The monitor has an entire bundle of rights:
1. To be a residual claimant
2. To observe input behavior
3. To be the central party common to all contract with inputs
4. To alter the membership of the team
5. To sell these rights that defines the ownership of the classical firm.
Two necessary conditions exist for the emergence of the firm on the prior
assumption that more pecuniary wealth enter utility functions:
It has something to do with how human conduct becomes socially organized, but it is not,
whether or not social controls order and organize the conduct of individuals, since such social
controls operate in both types of circumstances.
Art. 7:
Kogut & Zander (1992): Knowledge of the firm, combinative capabilities, and the
replication of technology.
The view in this article is differs radically from that of a firm as a bundle of
contracts that serves to allocate efficiently property rights. Rather, they suggest
that organizations are social communities in which individual and social expertise
Is transformed into economically useful products and services by the application
of a set of higher-order organizing principles Firms exist because they provide
a social community of voluntaristic action structured by organizing principles that
are not reducible by individuals.
[1] This article state that firms share and transfer knowledge of
individuals and groups within an organization better than markets can. This
knowledge consist information (i.e. who knows what) and of know-how (i.e. how
to organize a research team). Firms differ in their information and know-how and
these differences, when they are economically interesting, have persisting effects
on relative performance. Thus, a central characteristic to be explained is the
persisting difference in capabilities, that is, the difficulty in their transfer and
imitation. This can be analyzed over two dimensions: codifiability and complexity.
Codifiability and complexity are related, but not identical.
Central to their argument is that knowledge is held by individuals, but is
also expressed in regularities by which members cooperate in social community
(i.e. groups, organization, or network). If knowledge is only held on individual
level, then firms could change simply by employer turnover. Because we now that
hiring new workers is not equivalent to changing the skills of a firm, an analyses
of what firms can do must understand knowledge as embedded in the
organizational principles by which people cooperate within organizations.
A paradox is identified: efforts by a firm to grow by the replication of its
knowledge (i.e. simplification and codification) enhance the potential for
imitation. While knowledge transfer is a desired strategy in the replication and
growth of the firm, imitation is a principal constrain. In other words, for a firm to
growth, it must develop organizing principles and a widely held and shared code
by which to orchestrate large numbers of people and functions. Whereas the
advantage of reducing costs of intra-or inter-firm technology transfer encourage
1. Given individuals (typically with given preference functions) are assumed. This feature therefore
leads to a neglect of two things:
a. The limits of contracts and exchange, and the necessity of some non-contractual relations,
involving (moral) norms and (tacit) rules. All market-based contractual systems somehow rely on
essentially non-contractual elements (e.g. moral norms + trust) to function.
- Key difference between contractual and competence-based theories of the firm: Coase
(contractual) regards all managerial and entrepreneurial competences as potentially
contractible, whereas Knight (competence) denies that they can all be. In a context of
uncertainty some competences cannot be bought or hired.
interpreted, and different interpretations are always possible, even with the same set of
information. The very act of learning means that not all information is possessed, which would
rule out the assumption of rationality within contractual theories > limited to equilibrium. Within
firms there is interdependence of individual knowledge. Knowledge is embedded in social
structures, and is not immediately transparent. Organizational knowledge interacts with individual
knowledge but is more than the sum of the individual parts. It is context-dependent, culturebound and institutionalized.
3. The focus on comparative static explanations overlooks key dynamic aspects of the problem, notably
learning, innovation, and technological development. This is the most serious problem since the
ability of the firm to foster human learning, technological innovation, and research and development
are important for survival. Dynamic efficiency is essentially about learning and innovation, and,
because of this uncertainty, cannot be reduced simply to static terms. Recognition of the firm as a
means of coping with uncertainty is therefore crucial. Uncertainty is not only about future events
themselves, but also about the opportunities available. A dynamic and open-ended approach
challenges the relevance of a long-run equilibrium and admits an ongoing diversity of outcomes.
The viability of competence-based theories
The following definition of the firm is proposed: an integrated and durable
organization of people devoted to the production of goods or services that are
owned as property under law by the firm.
Corporate culture and learning
Principal argument in this essay: an important but not exclusive factor explaining
the existence, boundaries, nature, and development of the firm is the capacity of
such an organization to protect and develop the competences of the groups and
individuals contained with it, in a changing environment. Accordingly, the firm is
able to form and integrate the individual perceptions, preferences, abilities, and
actions of its personnel.
Individuals cannot always be relied upon to cooperate together in a way which
serves the objectives of the organization as a whole. The firm survives and
functions based on formal and informal relations: legal contracts to keep the firm
together as a unit and to motivate the individuals within it, and informal relations
(cultural + moral norms) vital to the integrity of the firm.
Learning depends on acquired cognitive frameworks, but at the same time it is an
essentially open-ended, provisional, and potentially fallible process. A learning
process therefore involves mistakes which become opportunities to learn.
Organizational learning depends on corporate culture, which is more than shared
Within the competence paradigm, the boundaries of the firm should be understood
in terms of not only transaction costs, but also in terms of learning, path
dependencies, technological opportunities, selection, and complementary assets.
Conclusion
The competence based perspective emphasizes on both dynamic as static
efficiency, and on both production and allocation. This approach differs from Coase
and Williamson, since they explain the existence of the firm exclusively by
transaction costs. They focus on the diminution of costs related to transactions
between given individuals. The problem is then that the existence of the firm
should be viewed as a dynamic process (cost advantages spread through time),
and can thus not be captured by an equilibrium based analysis. It is therefore
dangerous to reduce the character of the firm to contracts and costs alone. An
emphasis on learning should supplement transaction cost explanations. This
however implies that individuals cannot be taken as given while selecting
coordination and governance mechanisms. Learning capacities are related to
cultural development and transmission within organizations, and this provides an
alternative explanation for the existence of the firm. Learning should therefore
take a central place in the analysis of the firm. The relative efficiency and
dynamism of the firm is thus explained not simply in terms of the summation of
lower costs of atomistic transactions, but significantly also by the dynamic
advantages and efficiency of the firm as a whole.
Study questions:
1. What is according to Adam Smith (1776) the cause of the increase of
welfare in industrialized countries? What are the three factors that lead to
it?
2. Why do firms exist according to (1) Coase (1937), (2) Alchian & Demsetz
(1972), (3) Blau & Scott (1962), and (4) Kogut & Zander (1992)? How do
the explanations offered by these various authors differ?
3. How do contractual theories of the firm (of which Coase (1937) and Alchian
& Demsetz (1972) are examples) and competence theories of the firm (of
which Kogut & Zander (1992) is an example) differ from each other (cf.
Hodgson, 1998)?
Week 2
Eisenhardt (1989) - Agency Theory: An Assessment and Review
Agency theory describes the relationship between one party (the principal)
who delegates work to another (the agent), who performs that work, using
the metaphor of a contract. Agency theory is concerned with resolving two
problems that can occur in agency relationships:
1. The agency problem which arises when (a) the desires or goals of
the principal and agent conflict and (b) it is difficult or expensive for
the principal to verify what the agent is actually doing.
2. The problem of risk sharing that arises when the principal and agent
have different attitudes towards risk.
The focus of the theory is on determining the most efficient contract
governing the principal-agent relationship given assumptions about
people, organizations and information. Agency problem: arises with
incomplete principal information, agent may shirk. two options: buy
control systems or reward outcome. However is a behavior-oriented
contract more efficient than an outcome-oriented contract?
Key idea:
Unit of analysis:
Human assumptions:
Organizational
assumptions:
Information
assumption:
Contracting
problems:
Problem domain:
Incentive life-cycles: learning and the division of value in firms, Obloj &
Sengul 2012
This paper argues about the individual and organizational learning mechanisms
leading to the evolution of the division of value between economic actors under a
given contractual arrangement.
In on-going, long term relationships the division of value is ultimately determined
by contractual arrangements. Organizational incentives are concerned both with
incentivizing intended actions (value creation) and specifying the conditions of
value appropriation by employees, they can be seen as an explicit contract
specifying the division of value between a firm and its employees.
The existing work assumes that although the equilibrium division of value can
change per contract, it is static.
However, organizations and individuals can learn how to better respond to a
given incentive regime over time. This provides the possibility that the
effectiveness of that incentive regime as an organizational design instrument is
likely to evolve, even without external changes in the environment. They learn
how to me productive and know how to exploit it.
There are 2 learning mechanisms:
1. Productive learning: employees learn over time and gain experience how to better and
more efficiently conduct tasks induced by incentive instruments, positively
contributing to organizational performance. Leading to a greater value creation.
2. Adverse learning: employees learn over time and gain experience how to exploit a
given incentive design for their own benefit at the expense of the organization.
Employees will appropriate a greater part of the value that they create.
a. Seen as opportunistic behaviour. But adverse learning, or gaming, is different
as it can be learned, not a behavioural trait.
Under a given incentive regime over time, the organizations share of the total
value created will follow an evolutionary trajectory. The introduction of a new
incentive regime will trigger productive and adverse learning that are specific to
a given set of incentives. as the relative attractiveness of productive and adverse
responses to employees changes over time, the evolution of these two
mechanisms will follow different trajectories: productive learning is likely to be
more pronounced than adverse learning early on in the incentive life-cycle, but
over time, their relative prominence should be reversed, and adverse learning
should dominate productive learning. As a result, adverse responses will
outweigh productive responses, and a greater proportion of the value created will
be forfeited due to agency costs.
appropriate as much as possible value. The division of value within a firm in the
regimes lifecycle is static. The division of value between a firm and its
employees can evolve under an incentive regime. When changing to another
incentive regime both the firm and the employees need to learn which activities,
attention and effort will be optimal for them.
Early in the life-cycle of the incentive regime, the marginal reward for advancing
along the productive learning curve is higher than adverse learning. Later in the
life-cycle adverse learning provides a higher marginal reward than productive
learning curve.
Therefore, employees accumulate more experience along the productive
dimensions in the early stages and later accumulates more experience on
learning along the gaming dimension. There are several reasons why:
Changes to incentives occur because any given structure can trigger learning
mechanisms that decrease the effectiveness of the incentive regime over time.
Employees become better at gaming the regime, change of regime resets the
adverse learning by employees.
Taxes, subsidies, tournaments, auctions and other incentives can be structured to induce
selfregarding individuals to act in the common interest when market competition alone would
fail to accomplish this. Constitutions and public policies should be designed for knaves
motivated only by their private interest, but they may turn out to be counterproductive.
Economic incentives may diminish ethical or other reasons for complying with social norms
and contributing to the common good. The effects of material interests and moral sentiments
on behavior are additive rather than interactive. This is called the assumption of separability.
Incentives and Market Failures
When individuals do not take into account the effects of their actions on others (external
effects or spillovers), the result of private decentralized decision-making will be inefficient in
the sense that by implementing some other feasible outcome, at least one individual could be
made better off without anyone being made worse off. There are market
failures. Complete contracts eliminate spillovers,internalize the external
effects by assigning claims and liabilities so that each actor owns all of
the benefits and costs resulting from his or her actions, including those
conferred or imposed on others. Prices would do the work of morals. But,
contracts are hardly ever complete, due to information asymmetry, team
production processes and the voluntary provision of public goods. All of
this is the
case in the labor and capital market: agency theory.
Mechanisms can be designed to find a way to assign to each actor the entire
benefits and costs. Societies address market failures through some combination
of incentive-based design and other regarding motives. The separability
assumption commonly fails. Sometimes, explicit incentives and ethical motives
are complementary, but in most cases incentives undermine ethical motives.
Four reasons have been suggested for the failure of the separability assumption:
Why Moral Sentiments and Material Interests are not separable &
Discussion
When ones person itself is the raw material and its transformation or affirmation
is the objective, the presence of explicit economic incentives may have
unintended effects. People want to cooperate but also want to make sure that
others who did not cooperate would be punished. They do not wish to be
exploited.
Larkin, I., Pierce, L., and Gino, F. 2012. The psychological costs of pay-forperformance: Implications for the strategic compensation of employees
Objectives
Firms seek to maximize profit, and increased compensation affects profitability by
motivating employee effort and attracting more highly skilled employees, while
increasing wages.
Employees seek to maximize utility, influenced by compensation.
Information
Two information asymmetries where the agent knows more than the principal:
about the effort exertion and skill level. Overcoming these asymmetries by
providing incentives for workers to exert effort and self-select by skill level.
Predictions of standard AT
Employees work harder when their pay is based on performance.
Firms are more likely to use performance-based pay when they have less
information about actual employee efforts.
Firms are more likely to use performance-based pay when they have less
information about employee skill level, and/or as employee skill level is more
heterogeneous.
Team-based compensation
Firms are more likely to use team-based performance pay (vs individual pay)
when coordination across workers is important, when free riding is less likely, or
when monitoring costs are low (individual effort is not observable).
Basic predictions of AT
When both effort and output are highly observable, firms prefer to use a set
salary.
When individual skill is not observable, compensation both motivates employees
but also attracts specific types of employees. Firms are more likely to use
performance-based pay when employee skills are not observable compared to
when they are.
INCORPORATING INSIGHTS FROM PSYCHOLOGY AND DECISION
RESEARCH INTO AT
In this section the authors discuss how these psychological factors,
overconfidence and social comparison processes, add costs to performancebased compensation systems.
Perceived inequity in pay can furthermore have a costly asymmetric effect: below
median earners might exit the firm and above median earners may not become
more effective because of the superior pay.
SO: Perceived inequity through wage comparison reduces the effort benefits of
individual pay-for-performance compensation systems and introduces additional
1. Team-based wages: reduces costs of social comparison. This makes it a little more
attractive than predicted by agency theory, which holds that team-based pay will be
based only when there are benefits to coordination across employees that are greater
than the costs of free riding.
2. Scale-based wages: employees are compensated based on seniority, which reduces that
costs of social comparison and overconfidence and are therefore more attractive than
standard AT would predict.
Reducing social comparison costs through intermediate forms of
compensation
Firms with team-based compensation systems keeps the performance-based
incentives, but ties them to the team performance instead of the individual
performance. Reduces wage comparison by equalizing everyones wages in the
same team. However, some issues of social comparison remain, as they only
perceive equality of the pay when they perceive everyones contribution to the
team equal. So contribution in a team should not be highly heterogeneous.
However, there still my occur social comparison between teams. This can be
reduced by scaled wages, employees may view this policy still as unfair but will
not feel personally insulted.
-we attempt to demonstrate how control forms interact, occasionally merge and, sometimes,
contradict each other
Ouchi came up with his three approaches to control in an organization's management:
Market control
Bureaucratic control
Clan control
Study questions:
1. Explain what agency theory is with your own words (including the theorys
assumptions and key propositions/relationships).
2. Based on all the papers, what are the strengths and weaknesses of agency
theory?
3. Under which conditions will designing a compensation system according to
agency theory lead to high value creation for the organization?
Week 3
contributions. When there is a team effort like this, you have information problems: it is hard
to tell who is shirking.
Furthermore, It is possible to meter each input's (laborer's) marginal contribution, either by
observation or specification of the inputs.
The classical firm
One method to reduce shirking is for someone to specialize as a monitor to check the input
performance of team members. But who monitor the monitor? Solution: give the monitor the
residual value. (this can been seen in the current organizations. Stakeholders/shareholder
monitor the firm and receive residual value (e.g. dividends. ). The monitor earns his residual
through the reduction in shrinking that he brings about.
To discipline team members and reduce shirking, the residual claimant must have power to
revice the contract terms and incentives of individual members without having to terminate or
alter every other inputs contract.
It is this entire bundle of rights that resolves the shrinking-information problem of team
production better than does the noncentralized contractual arrangement. The bundle consist
out of:
1. To be a residual claimant
2. To observe input behavior
3. To be the central party common to all contract with inputs
4. To alter the membership of the team
5. To sell these rights, that defines the ownership of the classical firm (capitalist, freeenterprise).
In summary, two condition exist for the emergence of the firm:
1. It is possible to increase productivity through team-oriented production.
2. It is economical to estimate marginal productivity by observing or specifying input
behavior.
Compared to other theories of the firm
This theory builds further upon the insights provided by Ronal Coase & Frank Knight. (e.g.
markers do not operate costless and sometimes firms can work cheaper). To move further
from this, it is necessary to know what is meant by a firm and explain the circumstances under
which the cost of managing resources is low relative to the cost of allocating resources
through market transaction.
Also, this paper also suggests a definition of the classical firm (which was absent before).
Shortest summary, the main message:
The Alchian-Demsetz Approach
Measurement or metering problems are a reason that firms exist , according to Alchian &
Demsetz (1972). Members have an incentive to cooperate because jointly they can produce
more than solely. Shirking among team members increases (shirking = behavior that range
from cheating to merely giving less than ones best effort). When it is not possible to monitor
the individuals contribution, each on the members will be rewarded equally. This will increase
shrinking.
The firm exist so it can monitor the efforts. A hierarchy emerges. But who monitors the
monitor? Solution: give the monitor the residual value. (this can been seen in the current
organizations. Stakeholders/shareholder monitor the firm and receive residual value (e.g.
dividends. )
quality knowledge since else the incentive is not given. This is thus a gain sharing or profit
sharing plan.
Also the incentives do not have to be money but can also be status rewards, put them in the
newsletter for instance. The most effective way is to align its human resource policies with
this new role demanded from employees.
Increasing efficacy
When groups are getting to big people tend to feel that they cannot make a difference by
sharing their knowledge. Therefore increasing efficacy is very important. There are two
distinct types of efficacy: 1) information self-efficacy, the believe that the information is
helpful to co-workers were they to receive it. This expectancy will be higher if individuals
believe the information truly increases the value of the shared good. 2) Connective efficacy is
the belief that others will actually receive the information if it is contributed.
Feedback mechanisms are thus important, for instance by having rating systems or let the
contributors know how much their knowledge is used.
In addition employees need to be assured that there will be a minimum critical mass of
contributions to the knowledge repository. They dont want to think they are the only one
doing anything. Thus groups can not be to small, but when groups are getting bigger it is
important to let everyone know they are part of the team which leads to them feeling more
involved. Training programs help let employees feel part of the team, it also shows them that
people are thus going to use their information which motivates them to produce more of it.
Promoting group identity and personal responsibility
This is the sense of being part of the group as mentioned earlier. The probability of
cooperating increase when 1) interaction among participants are frequent and durable, 2)
participants are easily identifiable, 3) there is sufficient information available about each
individuals actions (people are not anonymous but have a face).
Communication between members is thus an impotent tool for establishing group identity. A
possible solution to the knowledge-sharing dilemma may be to create knowledge-sharing
groups and make it clear to employees that they belong to a specific group.
Ostrom, E. 2000. Collective action and the evolution of social norms. (2000)
Zero contribution thesis:
Rational self-interested individuals will not act to achieve their common or group interests.
The idea that rational agents are not likely to cooperate, even when that would be to their
mutual benefit, is also shown in the prisoners dilemma.
this dilemma, along with other dilemmas are viewed as collective action problems.
The zero contribution thesis underpins the assumption that individuals cannot overcome
collective action problems and need to have externally enforced rules to achieve their own
long-term self-interest.
! However, this thesis contradicts observations of everyday life. Individuals in all parts of the
world voluntary organize themselves to get the benefits of trade, provide mutual protection
against risks and create and enforce rules to protect natural resources. On the other hand,
research confirms that the temptation to fee-ride is a universal problem and people invest
resources in monitoring and sanctioning the actions of each other.
A substantial gap exist between the theoretical prediction that self-interested
individuals will have extreme difficulty in coordinating collective action and the
reality that such cooperative behavior is widespread. This study will first focus on
experimental evidence and potential theoretical explanations and secondly on realworld evidence.
Laboratory evidence on rational choice in collective action
Models on rational individual action rational egoists have found that this assumption works
well in predicting the outcomes of auctions and competitive market situations. Subjects do not
arrive at the predicted equilibrium in the first round, but behavior closely approximates the
predicted equilibrium by the end of 5 rounds of the experiment. After a huge number of those
experiments 7 general findings can be considered as the core facts;
1) Subjects contribute between 40 and 60 percent of their endowments to the
public good in a one-shot game as well as in the first round of finitely repeated
games.
2) After the first round, contribution levels tend to decay downward, but
remain well above zero. A repeated finding is that over 70 percent of subjects
contribute nothing in the announced last round of a finitely repeated sequence.
3) Those who believe others will cooperate in social dilemmas are more likely
to cooperate themselves. A rational egoist in a public good game, however, should
not in any way be affected by a belief regarding the contribution levels of others.
The dominant strategy is a zero contribution no matter what others do.
4) In general, learning the game better tends to lead to more cooperation, not less.
5) Face-to-face communication in a public good gameas well as in other
types of social dilemmasproduces substantial increases in cooperation that are
sustained across all periods including the last period. Subjects use the time to discuss
the optimal joint strategy, to extract promises from one another, and to give verbal
tongue-lashings when aggregate contributions fall below promised levels.
6) subjects will expend personal resources to punish those who make below-average
contributions to a collective benefit, including the last period of a finitely repeated
game. No rational egoist is predicted to spend anything to punish others, since the
positive impact of such an action is shared equally with others whether or not they also
spend resources on punishing.
7) The rate of contribution to a public good is affected by various contextual factors
including the framing of the situation and the rules used for assigning participants,
increasing competition among them, allowing communication, authorizing sanctioning
systems or allocating benefits.
These facts are hard to explain using the standard theory that all individuals who face
the same game evaluate decisions in the same way!
Building a theory of collective action with multiple types of players
From the experimental findings one can formulate the key assumptions that need to be
included in a revised theory of collective action.
Assumption of two types of norm-using players:
1. Conditional cooperators: individuals who are willing to initiate cooperative action
when they estimate others will reciprocate and repeat these actions as long as a
sufficient proportion of the others involved reciprocate. They will tend to be
trustworthy in collective dilemmas as long as the proportion of others who return trust
is relatively high. They tend to vary in their tolerance to for free riding. When they are
disappointed they will reduce their contributions. If they do so they discourage other
conditional cooperators from further contributions.
2. Willing punishers: these are players that are willing to punish free riders through
verbal rebukes or to use costly material payoffs when available. They might also
reward those who have contributed more than the minimal level. Some conditional
cooperators may also be willing punishers.
Together, conditional cooperators and willing punishers create an opening for
collective action and a mechanism for making it grow.
Evolutionary process
Evolutionary process explains the emerge and survival of multiple types of players. According
to this approach, those carrying the most successful strategies for an environment reproduce at
a higher rate. Eventually the more successful strategies come to prominence in the population.
During the Pleistocene survival was dependent on aggressively seeking individual returns
and solving many day-to-day collective problems. Those who learned how to recognize who
was deceitful and who was a trustworthy reciprocator had advantage over others.
Indirect evolutionary model: players receive objective payoffs, but make decisions based on
the transformation of these material rewards into intrinsic preferences. Those who value
reciprocity, fairness and trustworthiness add a subjective change parameter to actions that are
consistent or not consistent with their norms.
Prisoners dilemma games: if two players trust each other and cooperate, they can both receive
a moderately high payoff. However, if one player cooperates and the other does not, then the
one who did not cooperate receives an even higher payoff, while the other receives little or
nothing. For a rational egoist playing this game, the choice is not to trust, because the
expectation is that the other player will not trust, either. As a result, both players will end up
with lower payoffs than if they had been able to trust and cooperate.
Social norms may lead to individuals behave different than others. Depending on how
strongly they value conformance with (or deviance from) a norm. Rational egoists can be
thought of as having intrinsic payoffs that are the same as objective payoffs, since they do not
value the social norm of reciprocity. Conditional cooperators are trustworthy types and would
have an additional parameter that adds value to the objective payoffs when reciprocating trust
with trustworthiness. Therefore different types of players are likely to gain different objective
returns.
Only trustworthy types would survive in a world with complete information: as new
entrants of the population would adopt the preferences of those who obtained the
higher material payoffs in the past.
Only rational egoist would survive in a world where there is no information about
player types: first players will trust second players as long as the expected return of
meeting trustworthy players exceeds the payoff obtained when neither player trusts
each other.
Norms seem to have a certain staying power in encouraging a growth of the desire to
cooperate. While cooperation enforced by externally imposed rules can disappear very
quickly. Therefore external rules and monitoring can crowd out cooperative behavior.
Worst of all worlds: when external authorities impose rules but are only able to
achieve weak monitoring and sanctioning. The mild degree of monitoring discourages
the formation of social norms, while also making it attractive to deceive and defect
because there is a low risk of being caught.
Field studies of collective action problems find a huge number of contextual variables
conducive or detrimental to collective action:
The type of production and allocation functions; the predictability of resource flows; the
relative scarcity of the good; the size of the group involved; the heterogeneity of the group;
the dependence of the group on the good; common understanding of the group; the size of the
total collective benefit; the marginal contribution by one person to the collective good; the
size of the temptation to free ride; the loss to cooperators when others do not cooperate;
having a choice of participating or not; the presence of leadership; past experience and level
of social capital; the autonomy to make binding rules; and a wide diversity of rules that are
used to change the structure of the situation.
Design principles for self-organized collective action
- The presence of clear boundary rules this enables participants to know who is in and
who is out and thus with whom to cooperate. This is the first step to create more
greater trust and reciprocity.
- Local rules that restrict the amount, timing and technology of harvesting the resource
- If a group of users is going to harvest from a resource over the long run, they must
devise rules related to how much, when, and how different products are to be
harvested, and they need to assess the costs on users of operating a system. If some
users get all the benefits and pay few of the costs, others become unwilling to follow
rules over time.
- Most of the individuals affected by a resource regime can participate in making and
modifying their rules - Fair rules of distribution help to build trusting relationships,
since more individuals are willing to abide by these rules because they participated in
their design and also because they meet shared concepts of fairness. \
- Most long-surviving resource regimes select their own monitors, who are accountable
to the users or are users themselves and who keep an eye on resource conditions as
well as on user behavior.
Resource regimes use graduated sanctions that depend on the seriousness and
context of the offense This enables a regime to warn members that if they do not
conform they will have to pay ever-higher sanctions and may eventually be forced to
leave the community.
Access to rapid, low-cost, local arenas to resolve conflict among users or between
users and officials - Rules, have to be understood to be effective. There are always
situations in which participants can interpret a rule that they have jointly made in
different ways. By devising simple mechanisms to get conflicts aired immediately
and resolutions that are generally known in the community, the number of conflicts
that reduce trust can be reduced.
Minimal recognition of the right to organize by a national or local government
When they dont have this right, participants rely almost entirely on unanimity as the
rule used to change rules. Unanimity as a decision rule for changing rules imposes
high transaction costs and prevents a group from searching for better matched rules at
relatively lower costs.
The presence of governance activities organized in multiple layers of nested
enterprises.- among long-enduring self-governed regimes, smaller-scale organizations
tend to be nested in ever-larger organizations.
Bridoux, F., Coeurderoy, R., and Durand, R. 2011. Heterogeneous motives and collective
value creation.
Introduction
Resource-based view researchers have increasingly paid attention to the role of human
motivation in realizing the value creation potential of resources. Their main argument is that
value creation depends not only on the firms resources but also on the motivation of
employees to leverage these resources. But only individual effort will not be enough; it
requires employee cooperation to create the full potential value. The dilemma is that the
maximization of individual employees material payoffs conflict with the achievement of the
collective goal of creating value for the firm. So what is the best way for managers to solve
this dilemma?
Outline of this article:
First introduce the heterogeneity of employees motives to cooperate in creating value
collectively. (1)
Second, they examine 3 main ideal-type motivational systems that differ with regard to their
sanctioning mechanisms and their understanding rationale for individuals cooperation. (2)
Third, they extend the baseline model by comparing the motivational effect of the three idealtype systems under different conditions of observability of individuals contribution to
collective value creation. (3)
How does this article contribute?
Motives and motivational systems form a significant source of differences between firms. By
analysing the impact of the interplay between a firms motivational system and its employees
mix of motives on collective value creation, it may become clearer what type of system will
work best.
From individual motives to collective value creation (1)
Collective value creation comes from coordinated and cooperative efforts undertaken by
multiple agents within firms to exploit the value created potential of the firms resources.
Recent RBV studies stress the importance of also looking at behavioural micro foundations at
the individual level. If you dont take this into account, you assume that all agents are
homogeneous which causes that you cannot examine differences in the level of employees
motivation to create value while this is presumably a major source of differences of
performances between firms.
Collective value is a public good because its creation benefits the firm as a whole, including
individuals who do not cooperate to create it as well as those who do. It generally occurs
under the conditions of low observability by managers because it is harder for them to assess
both individual contributions and the reasons why contributions vary across individuals.
Because the managers cannot adequately reward every individual for a collective task, selfinterested individuals will tend not to contribute even though cooperation is optimal for the
collective. (public good dilemma).
This suggests that if everybody were self-interested, nobody would ever contribute to the
collective. This contradicts with the outcomes of several studies which show that people are
willing to contribute to the public good. Therefore we introduce motivational foundations at
the individual level that more realistically reflect the social dynamics underlying cooperation
in public good situations than the homogeneous assumptions of either benevolence
(everybody always contributes) or self-interest (nobody ever contributes).
Heterogeneous motives to cooperate and motivational systems
Model of outcome transformation: social psychologists have found that there are 2 classes of
individuals:
- Self-regarding: only care about maximizing own payoffs.
- Reciprocator: care about enhancing both joint payoffs and the fairness of the payoffs.
Behavioural economists have gone further studying one type of reciprocator: the strong
reciprocators. This individual is motivated not only by personal monetary payoffs but also by
others monetary payoffs and by the fairness of the distribution of payoffs across individuals,
and is ready to sanction (un)fairness at a material cost to himself.
In this article they only use self-regard and strong reciprocity as the two motives to cooperate.
Only these two because they have been found to matter most in explaining the level of
cooperation that can be sustained in groups of interacting individuals drawn randomly from
the general public.
A way to influence employees motivation to collectively create value is via the motivation
system. This has 2 different mechanisms: motivational effect and the sorting effect.
Motivational effect: depending on the type they are, individuals react differently to a firms
motivational system. Self-regarding individuals only look at the balance between personal
costs of and personal benefits from cooperating. While strong reciprocator individuals look
not only at their own personal payoffs from cooperating but also to the fairness of the firms
motivational system. Two sources of (un)fairness exist: horizontal (co-workers, free riding)
and vertical (employee versus boss, is the employee being exploited?)
3 types of ideal motivational systems: (2)
1) Homogeneity-based motivational system: based on benevolent cooperation. Assumes that
all individuals are benevolent contributors to the creation of value. There are no sanctioning
mechanisms.
2) Homogeneity-based motivational system: based on individual monetary incentives.
Assumes that all employees are self-regarding. There are only management sanctions.
Managers should provide individual incentives on the basis of individuals contributions.
3) Disciplined cooperation: stems from public good dilemmas. Sanctioning implemented by
strong reciprocators help maintain high levels of cooperation because there are no sanctions
from a vertical authority.
Motivational effect and collective value creation: a baseline model
In this research they compare the 2 types of individuals with the 3 different types of
motivational systems.
In these cases we assume that observability of managers is low while observability by coworkers is high.
Free-rider problems quickly arise in such settings, because even a member who did
not contribute effectively to the firm's revenues imposes a cost on the partnership as a
whole, by reaping the benefits of partnership. As a consequence, monitoring and
early graduated sanctions are considered to be particularly important for ensuring that
partners' individual commitment to contribute remains credible.
In effect, enforcement through negative sanctions can be costly for the sanctioner,
particularly when control is mobilized for the protection of the common good in such a
formally egalitarian body. This can result in:
partners may blame the sanctioner - especially if he/she has personal ties with the
deviant party - for failing to achieve results. The issue thus becomes: how then
does the organization keep costs of enforcement low?
The paper argues that informal processes contribute to maintaining low costs, in
particular the appropriate use of social resources or 'relationships' between members.
As part of what Freidson calls 'the rule of the collegium', members tend to avoid
open face-to-face conflicts, as well as direct and coercive exercises of power.
Therefore, graduated sanctions start with unobtrusive and unsolicited advice and the
spread of gossip. In effect, social ties provide access to infractors and focus their
attention, because they represent the existence of underlying resource dependencies.
References to such actions:
Freidson and Rhea's (1963) - colleagues informally 'talk to' infractors in order
to curb behaviour perceived to be unprofessional or opportunistic.
(Levi
1988),
Colleagues show infractors that lack of conformity has been detected, must be
discussed, and may involve external social costs, such as stopping exchanges at various
levels. Because interdependent partners need social resources to perform effectively, they
are also more exposed to pressures from partners who control these resources. These
processes help peers maintain an enduring collegial organization (Webern1920; Waters
1989).
The second-order free-rider problem can be decomposed into two issues. First,
the cost of sanctioning, and second, the incentive to sanction. The two issues are related
because lower costs will make lower incentives work, but otherwise they are independent.
This paper deals mainly with the first issue. Following the individual's preferences for
sanctioners leads to lowering sanctioning costs because if there is an interest in getting the
infractor going again, then members are sensitive to the efficiency of the sanction. It is also
likely that there is some selective organizational learning involved in the choice of
sanctioners: individual interests lead to lower costs which lead to good joint outcomes,
which reinforce the influence of individual interests on the sanctioning regime. However,
of particular importance to the argument of this paper, social relations among members are
the key to the process of mutual adjustment, i.e. the way in which a formally egalitarian
organization obtains this quasi-voluntary compliance with its rules and agreements.
Hypotheses: The Shape of a Lateral Control Regime
The relationship between cost of control and choices of suitable sanctioners in a
collegial organization plays itself out in the following ways. Members are interested in
getting the infractor going again to the degree that they are dependent on resources
controlled by the infractor. Thus, in the case examined here, partners are interested in
sanctioning what is likely to happen and what is likely to work. Based on this
argument, we can predict:
Hypothesis 1: The more similar members are to infractors in terms of their formal
organizational attributes, the more likely they are to be chosen to act as sanctioners for
these infractors.
is more likely to happen if the cost of interaction is lowered by easy access to the
infractor and by the existence of personal ties between sanctioner and infractor.
it is likely to work if sanctioners tend to be more senior than infractors and if they are
powerful. However, the kind of status carried by these powerful sanctioners
suggests that they are also chosen so as to prevent the possible preferential treatment
for some infractors that is induced by close relationships with them.
Spreading and shifting costs of control helps the organization keep early monitoring and
sanctioning costs low, and therefore try to keep members motivated to carryon monitoring
and sanctioning each other. This lateral control regime can thus help members find an early
solution to the so-called second-order free-rider problem in formally egalitarian
interdependent groups, i.e. the problem of who should bear the costs of enforcing previ ous
agreements. Because it offers a specific organization early enforcement of rules and
decisions, the lateral control regime can indirectly help in ensuring that cooperation
remains possible.
Limitations to the lateral control pattern work:
First, It is only one informal mechanism helping partners choose sanctioners to compel
each other, at an early stage, to contribute the required efforts and resources before they
decide to switch to more formal disciplinary mechanisms (committees, votes, etc.).
The article deals only partially with the second-order free-rider problem and it does
not explore whether and when lateral control is needed.
Also, the article does not deal with graduated sanctions (sanctions of different
severity), only with the lowest level of this graduation ('talking to').
Second, the logic of how a managerial problem is handled in a firm may be specific to its
socio-emotional, or expressive, character - as opposed to a more instrumental, taskoriented problem.
Third, different individual-level behavioural assumptions can be made to explain choices
of sanctioners. Partners choosing sanctioners are indeed sensitive to the issue of costs which
define, in part, the second-order free-rider problem. They rely on various commonalities of
interests among protagonists of the control situation. Thus the lateral control regime can
indeed be said to contribute to group solidarity by reducing the costs of control
(Hechter 1987) for most partners. Nevertheless, senior partners may also be chosen as
sanctioners because they have more traditional legitimacy to intervene on behalf of the
common good. A 'lateral control culture' might also be at work - a set of learned choices
(Swidler 1986) that enable well socialized partners, at this early stage, to match sanctioners
and infractors in a way consistent with the 'rule of the collegium'. Such learned ways would
make the choice of sanctioners more compatible with face saving unobtrusiveness
(choices of sanctioners might have to signal to infractors that the firm is not going out of
its way to remind them of their obligations), stress avoidance of conflict escalation, and
could also be explained by factors attributed to the subjective make-up of actors.
Study questions:
1. What is team production? What problems does it bring?
2. Based on all paper, identify the controls (i.e., motivational devices or tools) managers
could use to encourage cooperation in firms. Discuss the advantages and drawbacks of
these controls.
3. Compare the motivation systems discussed by Bridoux, Coeurderoy and Durand
(2011) and Lazega (2000) to your experience of motivation systems in group/team
projects. What similarities and differences can you see in how control is exercised?
Week 4
Observations:
While the organic systems are not hierarchic in the same sense as are mechanistic,
they remain stratified (i.e. the lead is taken by whoever shows himself most informed
and capable). The location of authority is set by location.
The area of commitment to the concern the extent to which the individual yields
himself as a resource to be used by the working organization is far more extensive in
organic than in mechanistic systems.
The emptying out of significance from hierarchical command system, by which cooperation is ensured and which serves to monitor working organization under a
mechanistic system, is countered by the development of shared beliefs about the
values and goals of the concern.
The two forms of systems represent a polarity, not a dichotomy; there are intermediate
stages between the extremities empirically known to us. Also the relation of one form
to the other is elastic, so that a concern oscillating between relative stability and
relative change may also oscillate between the two forms.
The organic form from departing from the familiar clarity and fixity of the hierarchical
structure, is often experienced by the manager as an uneasy, embarrassed, or chronically
anxious quest for knowledge about what he should be doing, or what is expected from hum,
and similar apprehensiveness about what others are doing. The desire for more definition is
often in effect a wish to have the limits of ones task more nearly defined. It follows that the
more definition is given, the more omniscient the management must be, so that no functions
are left whole or party undischarged, no person is overburdened with undelegated
responsibilities, or left without authority to do his job properly. This requires rules or
traditions of behavior proved over a long time and a equally fixed, stable task.
A second distinctive feature of the organic system is the pervasiveness of the working
organization as an institution (combine with others to serve the general aims of the concern).
The less definition can be given to status and roles, the more the organization becomes
determined by the real tasks of the firm as he sees them than by instruction and routine
Product units
4
6
Differentiation vs. integration
Differentiation = differences in behaviors & thought patterns between specialists
Needed for functional specialist to perform their jobs effectively
Integration = collaboration between specialized units or individuals
When there is more differentiation it is harder to achieve integration, but organizations need
both.
To do this there have to be well-developed means of communication among specialists &
specialist need to be effective in resolving cross-functional conflicts
Recent theories
Recent theories say choice of structure should be based on how it affects differentiation,
integration & specialists ability to communicate, resolve conflicts & make joint decisions.
When there is the right mix between differentiation & integration, there is a better chance of
organization accomplishing economic goals
Case study
Functional structure plant
Differentiation:
o Goal orientation: differentiated & focused goals
o Time orientation: less differentiated & short term
o Formality of structure: less differentiated with more formality
Integration: somewhat less effective
Conflict management: confrontation, smoothing-over, avoidance, restricted
communication pattern
Effectiveness: efficient & stable, less successful in improving capabilities
Employee attitude: satisfaction, less stress, also less involvement
Product structure plant
Differentiation
o Goal orientation: less differentiated & more diffuse
o Time orientation: more differentiated & longer term
o Formality of structure: more differentiated with less formality
Integration: more effective
Conflict management: confrontation of conflict, open face-to-face communications
Effectiveness: successful in improving plant capabilities, less effective ein stable
production
Employee attitude: stress, involvement, less satisfaction
Galbraith, J. R. 1971. Matrix organization designs How to combine functional and project
forms.
Two new forms of organization as response to of high technology:
Free-form conglomerate & matrix organization
Matrix organization; alternative form than project organization and
functional structure
matrix design tries to achieve the benefits of both forms
Functional structure; group together activities which have a common
product, customer, geographic area, business function
(marketing/engineering) or a common process. For example, it minimizes
the number of technical engineers necessary because specialized
resources are shared across products and projects.
Problem: simultaneously completing all tasks on time, while fully using all
resources is impossible
Project organization: facilitates coordination among specialties to
achieve on time completion and meet budget targets. Problems can be
tackled quickly, whereby impact on other specialties is reduced.
Problem: duplication costs, because resources are needed at the same
time. And no one is responsible for the long run technical development of
a specialty.
Problem is that when choosing one organizational form, the benefits of
the of the organizational form are surrendered. If the functional structure is
adopted, the technologies are developed but the projects fall behind
schedule. If the project organization is chosen, there is better cost and
schedule performance, but technologies are not developed as well.
Answer: matrix organization
The Standard Product Co. : Hypothetical company that changed from
functional structure to matrix organization. Standard was selling its
products through functional organization. Every year a number of changes
were made in the product lines. Major management problem was to
coordinate the flow of work form engineering through marketing. Therefore
there were several integrating mechanisms:
Rules and procedures; if everyone follows the rules, the behavior is
integrated without having to maintain an on-ongoing communication
Planning processes; for less repetitive actions, the procedure was not
specified, only the goal that needs to be achieved. In that way individuals
could the procedure appropriate to the goal. Therefore schedules and
budgets were designed
Hierarchical referral; when there are situations for which there are no rules
or there are problems that the goal could not be achieved, then the
problem will be referred upward in the hierarchy.
Direct contact; to prevent top executives to from becoming overloaded
with problems, as many problems as possible were resolved by managers
at lower levels.
of
beliefs
and
traditions
that
surrounds
the
1. Mutual adjustment
Co-ordination of
communication
work
by
the
simple
process
of
informal
Decision what each person will do: how specialized job is, how many
tasks it contains and how much control the person has over tasks.
Jobs that have few and narrow tasks are referred to as horizontally
specialized. Those with many and broad tasks as horizontally
enlarged.
Jobs that involve little control by those who do them are called
vertically specialized. Those which are thoroughly controlled by
the worker are referred to as vertically enlarged.
2. Behavior formalization
-
3. Training
-
As training takes power from all the other parts of the organization
and puts it into the hands of the professional workers themselves,
It takes place informally. But some also take place more formally
through the process known as indoctrination.
5. Unit grouping
-
On what basis are positions and units grouped into larger groups?
What size should each of the units be?
6. Unit size
-
The greater the need for mutual adjustment, the smaller must be
the size of the work unit. When tasks are rather complex yet tightly
coupled, neither direct supervision nor any form of standardization
suffices to effect the necessary co-ordination. It must be co-ordinate
by informal, face-to-face communication among members.
8. Liaison devices
-
to
the
other
design
They are most logically used with work that is (a) horizontally specialized,
since specialization impedes natural coordination (b) complex/
professional (c) interdependent, so that coordination is necessary. Liaison
devices, as agents of mutual adjustment instead of standardization, are
obviously associated with organic structures.
Vertical and horizontal decentralization
Centralized = when all power is located at a single point in the
organization
Decentralized = when the power is dispersed among many individuals
-
Type 1: Centralization
1 Direct supervision clearly constitutes full horizontal centralization, since
all power rests with the managers.
2 Vertically centralization since a dependence on direct supervision for
coordination means that each manager tightly controls those below him.
Type 2: Limited horizontal decentralization (selective)
3 Standardization of work processes through coordination
4 Centralization in the vertical dimension, with a limited and selective
degree of decentralization in the horizontal dimension
Type 3: Limited vertical decentralization (parallel)
5 Reliance on standardization of output
6 Form of vertical decentralization, since a few division managers can
retain the lions share of the power.
Type 4: Horizontal decentralization (parallel)
7 Standardization of skills
8 Professionals can work rather autonomously in large units
Type 5: Selective horizontal and vertical decentralization
9 Experts work in small units and co-ordinate by mutual adjustment
10
Combination of vertical decentralization - delegation to work groups
at different levels in the hierarchy - and horizontal decentralization - a
varying distribution of power within each group.
Type 6: Decentralization
11
12
Purest form of decentralization, the most democratic form of
structure
The situational factors
Age and size of the organization
H1: The older the organization, the more formalized its behavior.
H2: The larger the organization, the more formalized its behavior.
H3: The larger the organization, the more elaborate its structure.
H4: The larger the organization, the larger the size of its average unit.
H5: Structure reflects the age of founding of the industry.
Technical system of production
H6: The more regulating the technical system (the more it controls the
work of the operators), the more formalized the operating work and the
more bureaucratic the structure of the operating core technical systems
that regulate the work of the operators.
H7: The more complex the technical system, the more elaborate the
administrative structure.
H8: The automation of the operating core transforms a bureaucratic
administrative structure into an organic one.
Environment
H9: The more dynamic the environment, the more organic the structure.
H10: The more complex the environment, the more decentralized the
structure.
H11: The more diversified the organizations markets, the greater the
propensity to split it into market-based units, or divisions, given favorable
economies of scale.
H12: Extreme hostility in its environment drives any organization to
centralize its structure temporarily.
H13: Disparities in the environment encourage the organization to
decentralize selectively to differentiated work constellations.
Power
H14: The greater the external control of the organization, the more
centralized and formalized its structure.
H15: The power needs of the members tend to generate structures that
are excessively centralized.
H16: Fashion (haute structure) favors the structure of the day (and of
the culture), sometimes even when inappropriate.
Configurations
These elements seem to cluster naturally in a certain number of ways,
which are called configuration.
5. The adhocracy
-
6. The missionary
-
Strikwerda, J. and Stoelhorst, J.W. 2009. The emergence and evolution of the
multidimensional organization
The multidivisional (M-form), was the most successful organization form in the
twentieth century. Definition of the M-form: Firms that employ the M-form
organize their activities in separate business units and delegate control over the
resources needed to create economic value to the managers of these units.
Four principles of the M-form:
1.
2.
3.
4.
The M-form assumes that each of the firms customers only needs to deal with
one business unit, and that each of the firms business units can control all
resources needed to serve its market. It is only on these two assumptions that
business units can truly operate independently. These assumptions are violated
as soon as there are opportunities for cross-selling or system integration across
the products of the different business units, complementarities among the
resources of the different business units, or economies of scale in the use of
resources across business units. There is a crucial trade-off involved in choosing
between the unequivocal resource allocation and lines of authority that have led
to the success of the M-form, on the one hand, and the creation and the
exploitation of the kind of synergies that product and financial markets
increasingly require, on the other. Many contemporary firms violate the principle
that is central to the M-form: that business units are self-contained. Most
business units now depend at least in part on resources that are controlled by
other units. This raises fundamental questions about the status of the M-form in
contemporary firms.
The need to exploit synergies across business units was widespread, but it was
unclear which organizational designs are most appropriate to achieve this. This
led to a research project to explore the ways in which leading Dutch
organizations, including subsidiaries of foreign multinationals, have adapted the
M-form to better exploit synergies across business units.
The results of the study illustrate the fundamental tension between the need for
contemporary firms to exploit synergies and their need for clear accountability.
An unexpected finding was that a number of firms in the study have evolved an
organizational form that signals a new way of resolving this tension. These firms
are organized around multiple dimensions (e.g., region, product, and account)
Fjeldstad, D, Snow, C.C, Miles, R.E. and Lettl, C. 2012. The architecture of collaboration.
Firms increasingly face competitive pressures related to rapid and
continuous adaptation to a complex and dynamic and highly
interconnected global environment.
pressing challenges include keeping pace with shorter product life
cycles, incorporating multiple technologies into the design of new
products, co-creating products and services with customers and partners
and leveraging the growth of scientific and technical knowledge in many
sectors.
In response, there are fundamentally new organization designs which are
based on an actor-oriented scheme, which exist of three main
elements.
1) Actors who have the capabilities and values to self-organize
2) Commons where the actors accumulate and share resources
3) Protocols, processes and infrastructures that enable multi-actor
collaboration
In industries where knowledge is complex, growing and widely diffused,
innovation extends beyond the individual firm. To cope with the complexity
of knowledge, many firms use multiparty collaboration, which has been
shown to reduce risk, speed product to market, decrease the cost of
product development and provide access to new markets and
technologies.
traditional organizational forms use hierarchy mechanisms to control
coordination which can constrain collaboration within and across firms.
Architecture: fundamental organization of a system embodied in its
components, their relationships to each other and to the environment, and
the principles guiding its design and evolution.
over time the concept of architecture moved from a focus on design of
specific structures to a focus on principles that foster coherence, growth
and change.
The hierarchical scheme: the dominant scheme used to explain
organization designs.
Hierarchy = a complex system in which each of the subsystems is
subordinated by an authority relation to the system it belongs to.
Hierarchy is used for control and coordination; setting goals and
monitoring the goal fulfillment, allocation of resources, and managing
interdependencies.
Higher level members have the authority to resolve conflicts at
lower levels, because they have a broader view of the organization
Higher level members typically have capabilities related to control
and coordination which supersede (vervangen) those of lower level
members
Higher level units control the goals and actions of subordinate units
(principle-agent relationship)
Simple hierarchy
Functional form: activities are hierarchically controlled, and
interdependencies are managed by forecasting and planning at
higher levels. Strengths are specialization and economies of scale.
Limitations is the ability to accommodate diversity and variability in
the organizations environment.
Divisional form: general motors introduced divisions as an added
layer in the hierarchy that allows for effective adaptation to
differentiated market demand. Benefit is the ability to collect and
process information about customer preferences and requirements
to meet those demands. Thus this form enables exploitation of
economies of scope in the service of differentiated customer
demand. Limitation is constrained resources sharing across divisions.
Matrix forms
Hybrid structure with two or more distinct hierarchies. Market-facing units
draw on different upstream capabilities both in the existing businesses and
in developing and delivering new products and services. Typically
customer facing units have budgets which they use to obtain resources
from the functional dimension of the matrix. The matrix form seeks to
capture both the efficiency and specialization of the functional form and
the customer focus and flexibility of the divisional form.
Multi-firm networks
Firms can chose to focus on their core activities and to outsource noncore
activities to external providers. Result: vertically integrated activities are
performed by multi-firm networks. Benefits are flexibility, the variety of
capabilities that can be assembled and the economies of scale can be
achieved at each activity. Multi-firm networks are hierarchical as they are
organized around a lead firm that works dynamically with network
partners to produce and deliver products and services.
Conclusion; traditional organizational forms vary across three main factors
1. Division of labour: determined by the types of functions needed
2. Number of hierarchical levels: determined by the span of control
3. Number of superiors: reflects variety across functions, product
groups and regions
The actor-oriented scheme
The twenty-first century is marked by globalization of communication,
financial and logistic services, which reduce the costs of interaction and
enables new ways of organization. In addition, there is a need for rapid,
effective responses to opportunities and challenges that put pressure on
hierarchical organizational forms.
Study questions:
1. What are the specific strengths and weaknesses of the various organizational forms
discussed in Burns & Stalker (1961), Walker & Lorsch (1968), Galbraith (1971), and
Mintzberg (i.e. his five configurations)?
2. Mintzberg (1979) discusses six basic coordination mechanisms as possible solutions to
the coordination problem. How do these mechanisms compare to the solutions to the
coordination problem in the different organizational forms discussed by Bartlett &
Ghoshal (1993), Strikwerda & Stoelhorst (2009), and Fjeldstad et al. (2012)?
3. The papers show that over time, as the research on organizational structure matured,
researchers have identified new organizational forms (e.g., the multidimensional form
identified by Strikwerda & Stoelhorst, 2009). Do you think that the literature will soon
have identified all organizational forms? Why or why not?
Week 5
To avoid such a situation, managers adopt costly mechanisms to monitor and enforce
contractual performance.
Main Theoretical predictions
Opportunistic behavior most likely occurs in economic exchange that involve significant
specialized investment.
- As the level of specialized investment increases, the difference between earning and
opportunity costs are created that may be subject to hold up. Meaning that the party
without(or lower) specific investment can take advantage of the vulnerability of the other
party. This creates costly opportunistic bargaining.
- The (potential) victim of these costs can engage in inefficient positioning tactics. This party
will limit, for instance, its specific investment which will lead to decreased economic value
that will be created in the exchange.
Uncertainty
By increasing the number of contingencies that may affect a market contract, uncertainties
raises the potential for opportunistic behavior as well as the expected costs of writing and
enforcing a complete contract.
Uncertainty also increases when a firm is not allowed/able to measure the contribution of any
individual activity. This increases the need for superior monitoring and administrative control.
Organizational forms are
- Unilateral market contracts
- Intermediate or hybrid forms like alliances
- Hierarchical integrated firms
Asset specificity and organizational form
- Site : co-location of facilities to minimize inventory or production costs
- Physical: Co-specialized assets that are customized for a particular purpose
- Human Assets: Employees development of firm specific skills and knowledge
- Dedicated assets: Additional investments in plant or equipment to sell increased output to
particular customer
- Brand name capital: investment in reputation
- Temporal: investment made to facilitate timely response or coordination of human assets
Market failure is particularly likely in situations where both high investment specificity and
uncertainty are present.
RBV
States that firms may enjoy persistent performance advantages due to relative superiority with
which their resources meet the need of customers.
Gives two primary conceptual insights
- It recognizes that factor markets exist wherein firms may develop or buy resources needed
for product market competition
- Points out that the resources that which lead to persistent performance differences are much
broader in nature and more difficult to accumulate than the tangible resources and factors of
production typically emphasized by Neoclassical theory.
Primary assumptions
- Firms are profit maximizing entities directed by bounded rational managers:
Managers are assumed to lack the knowledge foresight and skill to accurately predict and plan
for all the various contingencies that may arise in their search for profitable opportunities
- Firms must make up front investments for the opportunity to engage in the process of
creating new resources whose eventual value is inherently ambiguous and uncertain. Resource
are heterogeneous (firms posses different bundles of resources)
Resources are immobile (these differences between firms resources bundles persist over time).
Main theoretical implications
- RBV suggests that firms may gain temporary competitive advantage by leveraging
valuable- resources that enable firms to develop and implement strategies that have effect on
customers willingness to pay or reduce the opportunity costs of suppliers.
Rare resources wherefrom demand exceeds supply
Non substitutable- can uniquely be used to help conceive and implement a strategy
- RBV indicates that competitive advantage might be sustainable if there are ex post limits to
competition
- RBV states that for a firm to enjoy economic profit it must generate more value from its
resources than expected at time of their acquisition or development. These are ex-ante limits
to competition which exist through uncertainty or if a firm has unusual insight about the
future value of a resource.
- RBV predicts that firms may generate sustained economic profits by continuously
leveraging valuable rare and costly to imitate resources in ways that their competitors cannot
anticipate.
A firm with a unique and valuable productive capacity will be more likely to internalize those
activities that are complementary to its unique features than firms that lack this capability
Firms are agued to be more effective that other governance forms such as markets at
combining and diffusing knowledge because of their superior coordinative attributes and
information processing abilities.
Firms exist because they are better than markets at creating, recombining and transferring
certain types of knowledge.
Firms are able to transfer knowledge that is difficult to understand, codify a lower cost to
wholly owned subsidiaries than to third parties.
Moderating Relationships
When certain conditions exist, the positive effects of peripheral outsourcing and the negative
effects of core outsourcing may be increased or reduced.
- Generic Firm Strategy
Peripheral incrementally lower total cost improved cost position; competitiveness;
superior performance. It is proposed that a cost leadership strategy strengthens the
positive effect (or reduces any negative effect) of peripheral outsourcing on firm
performance.
Additionally, pursuing differentiation strategy stand to gain less. The incremental cost
improvements are less significant to differentiators. It is proposed that a differentiation
strategy weakens the positive effect of peripheral outsourcing on firm performance.
H3: A firms business level strategy moderates the relationship between outsourcing
intensity and firm performance such that, for a cost leader any positive effect of
outsourcing on performance is strengthened, and any negative effect is weakened; and,
for a differentiator, any positive effect weakened and any negative effect is strengthened.
- Environmental Dynamism
The effect of outsourcing may increase with increasing levels of environmental dynamism. By
relying on outsiders for peripheral and near-core activites in more dynamic environments,
firms are able to take advantage of emerging technologies without investing large amounts of
capital in them. When new technologies emerge, outsourcing firms may switch suppliers, to
exploit any cost or quality improvements that may then be available.
May decline in stable environments. 1) benefits associated with changes in tech are much less
pronounced 2) more difficult to avoid the transfer of knowledge associated with shifting
activities to external org.
H4: Environmental dynamism moderates the relationship between outsourcing intensity
and firm performance such that any positive effect of outsourcing on firm performance
is strengthened and any negative effect of outsourcing on firm performance is weakened,
as dynamism increases.
Research Method
-
Results
Neither peripheral outsourcing intensity nor core outsourcing intensity was a significant
predictor of any of financial, innovation or stakeholder performance. Hypothese 1 and 2 were
NOT SUPPORTED.
Firm strategy as moderator. Effects of outsourcing are not the same for firms pursuing
different strategies. For cost leaders, there is a positive relationship btween outsourcing and
performance. The benefits of outsourcing are more fully realized by firms pursuing cost
leadership or innovative differentiation strategies. The finding of cost leader is consistent with
H3, whereas the finding for innovative differentiators is the opposite of what was predicted.
Environmental Dynamism as a Moderator. Contrary to H4, it appears that the benefits of
peripheral outsourcing to the firm performance actualy decline in more dynamic
environments. The finding suggest that firms operating in stable environments have more gain
from outsourcing.
Discussion
Highly likely that outsourcing has an ffect on the individual functionl areas in which it occurs.
This study at firm-level.
Dangers associated with outsourcing may not be as large as they appear (no sign effect on
innovation performance).
Stable environments stakeholder performance was positively related to a firms level of
peripheral outsourcing contradictory reason; transaction costs associated with
negotiating, monitoring and enforcing outsourcing arrangements increase in more dynamic
environments. In rapidly changing environments, powerful suppliers with specialized skills
may be albe to exert higher levels of bargaining power over outsourcing firms.
Limitations
- Generalizability limited
- No firms in introduction-stage only one in declining
- Less than 6 percent had unionized employees
- Firm size may be an issue (larger firms outsource more assumption)
- generalization to service firms might be difficult (this were all manufacturers)
- common method bias (independent and dependent construct are measured entirely with selfreported data
- the measure of outsourcing
- fit among firms outsourcing intensities, business-level, strategies and environments
one can have no reliable information about one's partner's degree of opportunism, and
therefore one has to assume opportunism as a basis for governance, to avoid the hazard
involved.
Williamson does not seem to be aware of the price one pays for opportunism. There is much
evidence in the trust literature that distrust breeds distrust and may even elicit opportunism.
Then the assumption of opportunism may become self-fulfilling, with considerable costs of
contracting and loss of perspective for a fruitful relationship.
Agent based computational economics (ACE), Agents are modeled as adaptive, learning to
revise their assessment of trustworthiness, the weight they attach to it relative to profitability,
and revising their own opportunism. This type of model illustrates that complexity and pathdependence in interactive relations often preclude the achievement of optimal outcomes: those
turn out to be achieved only occasionally.
2.3 Trust and opportunism
Williamson has been ambiguous about trust, trust can be discarded. Scholars accept the
possibility of opportunism but reject Williamson's neglect of trust.
At some level, trust is inevitable. Markets could not work without non-calculative trust.
Complete lack of trust beyond calculative self-interest would prevent one from entering into
any relation.
What is the basis for genuine trust?
*
Trust includes elements of control or deterrence, including both legal coercion and
control by incentives and dependence, as well as elements that go beyond control, as a
basis for 'goodwill' or 'benevolence': if we do not include the latter, we conflate trust
and power. The first (control/deterrence) is part of calculative self-interest, but the
latter (benevolence) is not.
Trust has been defined as the expectation that a partner will not engage in
opportunistic behavior, even in the face of countervailing short-term opportunities and
incentives.
Basis for trusting behavior also lies in routinisation. When things go well for a while
in a relationship , one tends to take at least some of it for granted. Williamson warns
for trust that becomes blind.
competence or a capability?
*
Resources include not abilities but entities, such as tangible assets, intangible assets
such as knowledge in the sense of 'knowing that' and 'knowing why', or 'declarative
knowledge', and access to finance and to markets of inputs and outputs.
Bridging cognitive distance entails the ability to understand and communicate with
people who think differently.
Distance in inter-firm collaboration should not be integrated but maintained. where outside
partners remain immersed in outside relations with others.
Husted, B.W., and Folger, R. 2004. Fairness and transaction costs: The contribution of
organizational justice theory to an integrative model of economic organization
This article integrates two fields that have remained largely independent of one another:
organizational justice and transaction costs economics. Transaction costs consist of search,
bargaining, monitoring, enforcement, and other costs not directly related to the production of
goods or services. Rarely are the social-psychological dimensions of these objective features
taken into account. Although economic transactions are human activities, human behavior in
the economics literature is usually reduced to such simplifying assumptions as shirking and
bounded rationality.
This article argues that transaction costs can also derive from the difficulty of evaluating the
fairness of a specific exchange of goods and services. Fairness refers to the perception by a
person that a decision, outcome, or procedure is both balanced and correct.
The difficulty of perceiving fairness depends on two attributes of the exchange: performance
ambiguity and goal incongruence. Performance ambiguity refers to the difficulty of measuring
performance. Goal incongruence is defined as the degree to which parties to an exchange have
incompatible objectives.
The Impact of Governance Mechanismson the Perception of Fairness
Transaction-cost economics fails to take into account the value-expressive effects of
specific governance mechanisms. These value-expressive effects include a willingness by the
other party to honor mutual rights, which signals a concern for dignity and community and
leads to an inference about the others motives as well-intentioned, fair-minded, and
trustworthy.
The lack of accountability of value-expressive effects leads to three problems: transactioncost economics may lead people to use (a) the wrong governance mechanism or (b) the right
mechanism either for the wrong reason or (c) in the wrong way.
Transaction cost economics may lead people to use the wrong governance mechanism
because TCE does not distinguish between cognitive and interest-driven forms of conflict.
Cognitive conflicts relate to disagreements about matters of facts. Conflicts of interest deal
with disagreements about goals or preferred outcomes. These differences in conflict affect the
perception of the fairness of procedures which differ in the amount of process control and
decision control given to disputants.
Process control refers to the extent and nature of a disputants control over the
presentation of evidence
Decision control is the extent and nature of a disputants control over the actual
decisions made
Additionally, according to Strickland (1958) and Kruglanski (1970) surveillance drives out
trust and thus the perception of fairness. Once you start monitoring someone you start to trust
that person less. As long as trust exists, a trustor will perceive fairness in the trustees
behavior even when such a belief may not be justified in terms of current outcomes.
Trust includes the belief that a trustee does not exploit a trustor even when the
opportunity arises. Thus, there is an implicit belief by the trustor that an exchange with
the trustee is fair
Second, transaction cost economics may lead people to use the right governance mechanism
for the wrong reason because TCE purely acts from a transaction cost perspective. However,
if transactors want procedures to adopt trust and the governance mechanism adopted assumes
that all transactors are self-interested, the governance mechanism will only decrease trust.
Third, transaction cost economics may lead people to use the right governance mechanism in
the wrong way, because transaction-cost economics does not count for the details of dynamic
function. Fairness perceptions are potentially unstable (subject to change over time). Hence,
there is a possibility that the perceptions of unfairness may arise after the governance
mechanism has begun to operate.
Thus, the perception of fairness depends not only upon the presence of a given procedure, but
also upon the way the interaction occurs. When communication dynamics are neglected, the
perception of decisions is unfair, even though appropriate procedures are in place. Hence,
proposition 1:
Proposition 1. When transactors perceive that interactional justice (truthfulness, respect,
justifications, and trust) exists, governance mechanisms will have a more positive impact on
the perception of fairness.
The Impact of the Perception of Fairnesson the Creation of Transaction Costs
Search and bargaining activities are ex ante costs related to putting in place governance
mechanisms that insure that exchanges are fair. Monitoring, renegotiation, and enforcement
costs are ex post costs that arise after reaching an agreement and either guarantee the fairness
of continuing exchange until the terms of the contract are successfully fulfilled. Although
transactions may initially be viewed as fair, unforeseen disturbances may arise that require
further bargaining, monitoring, and enforcement costs in order to reassure the parties that the
exchange continues to be fair.
By failing to give attention to the informal aspects of the transaction, the governance
mechanism may unintentionally increase transaction costs by reducing the perception of
fairness in the exchange because the responses to injustice (shirking, breaching, pilfering,
etc.) imply concrete costs. These responses to injustice constitute an additional set of
transaction costs, which we refer to as fairness- response transaction costs. Hence,
proposition 2:
Proposition 2. The greater the perceived unfairness of a governance mechanism, the greater
the transaction costs created by that governance mechanism.
The Relationship Between Transaction Costs and Governance Design
A single-minded focus on ex ante alignment cannot sufficiently foresee and anticipate to all of
the possible conflicts that a transaction may suffer. As a result of the dynamic, nonequilibrium nature of the relationship, the organization cannot accurately calculate all of the
costs associated with each governance mechanism, and thus leads to the implementation of an
inappropriate structure. Hence, proposition 3:
Proposition 3. The greater the ex post transaction costs created by perceived unfairness, the
more likely that the governance mechanism will fail (be misaligned).
One of the implications of this model is that organizations will become involved in positive
feedback loops. Usually implementation is carried out by the same people, after each change
in governance design. The same people will see different changes in governance design
negatively, and as a result, the perception of fairness in the transaction decreases. This
decreased perception of fairness will increase the fairness-response transaction costs of the
governance mechanism. Consequently, it will be necessary to redesign or restructure to reduce
transaction costs. The firm ends up in a positive feed- back loop where it is constantly
restructuring.
Conclusion
TCEs assumption of opportunism may lead to a self-fulfilling prophecy by creating the
conditions of mistrust it assumes. Justice theory asks us to take a more fine-tuned approach by
taking the assumption of opportunism as a variable that may or may not be present in any
given situation. By taking seriously the tendency of most people to incorporate fairness
considerations into their rationality, justice theory complements and supplements the
structural approach to governance design of transaction-cost economics to allow for an
enactment of governance mechanisms that will in fact reduce transaction costs
Nonetheless, combining resource based and transaction-cost reasoning, Quinn and Hilmer
suggest to simultaneously consider the potential for competitive advantage (resource-based
view) and the degree of strategic vulnerability (transaction-cost economics) in making
decisions on whether to outsource a particular activity. They recommend that managers
answer the following questions:
- What is the potential for obtaining competitive advantage in this activity, taking into
account transaction costs?
- What is the potential vulnerability that could arise from market failure if the activity is
outsourced?
- What can we do to alleviate our vulnerability through structuring arrangements with
suppliers to afford appropriate controls, yet provide for necessary flexibility in
demand?
While these are important questions that may contribute to guiding a firms outsourcing
decision, they do little to help managers understand switching costs during the process of
vertical dis-integration, fail to relate the process of outsourcing to competitive dynamics, and
downplay long-term consequences on maintaining and developing the dynamic capabilities of
the firm.
An Evolutionary Perspective on Vertical Dis-Aggregation
Unlike transaction-cost theory and the resource-based view, evolutionary theory provides the
core of a process theory of economic organization. Although, evolutionary theory has not
focused directly on the question of vertical dis-integration, it yields important insights
relevant to the process of outsourcing. In particular, evolutionary theorists assume three
central elements of evolutionary explanations:
Boundedly rational actors are assumed
The central units of analysis are search processes, problem-solving procedures and
path-dependent learning in organizations
Sensitivity to the contextual embededness of organizational capability maintenance
and development is emphasized
Switching costs during governance change
Even if a company could reliably identify why certain activities should be outsourced, an
evolutionary perspective on governance change suggests that there are at least two process
complications that give cause to switching costs: Governance inseparability and
complementarity of capabilities. The switching costs associated with these problems are
neglected in conventional theories of the firm, but they become obvious in an evolutionary
process perspective.
Governance inseparability: In essence, the authors assert that there are exit barriers on
a governance level because a firms past governance choices significantly influence
the range and types of governance mechanisms that it can adopt in future periods.
In sum, switching costs exist when there are costs in breaking prior commitment and
separating capabilities through interfaces that are tacit, causally ambiguous, socially complex
or taken for granted.
The extent of the market: Whether or not capabilities can be successfully deployed,
however, depends on how easy they can be imitated, protected, challenged by
competitors, or, alternatively supported by complementors. In other words, they
depend on the capability configuration of the competitive and institutional
environment in which the local firm operates; to which it responds; which it may try to
shape, and on which it draws.
Imitation dynamics: Firms engaged in outsourcing face a critical concern: successful
outsourcing often requires putting valuable knowledge-assets at risk. While vertical
dis-integration may help companies to access capabilities that they cannot build in a
reasonable time frame themselves, outsourcing also gives vendors a window to
valuable knowledge that they may leak to other clients, including competitors.
Innovation regime: Outsourcing innovative activities can be complicated to the extent
that one innovative activity depends on simultaneous development of another. While
autonomous innovation can be pursued independently from other innovations, the
benefits of systemic innovation can be realized only in conjunction with related,
complementary innovations. If innovations are of the systemic type in the sense that
simultaneous innovation in a related technology is required, then coordinatedadjustment and information flows between development efforts are required.
Langfield-Smith, K., and Smith, D. 2003. Management control systems and trust in
outsourcing relationships
Abstract
Outsourcing is a form of strategic alliance that has increased in popularity over the past
decade. However, there has been limited research that studies the design of management
control systems (MCS) and the role of trust in such inter-firm relationships. This paper draws
on a model by van der Meer-Kooistra and Vosselman [Acc. Organ. Society 25 (2001) 51] to
examine how control mechanisms and trust are used to achieve control in a single case study
of an electricity company and its outsourced IT operations. An analysis of the characteristics
of the transaction, environment and parties, indicated that the control strategy adopted
appeared to be a trust based pattern of control, rather than a market based or bureaucratic
based pattern. Control was achieved through outcome controls and social controls developing
over time, and through the development of trust, particularly goodwill trust. This paper adds
to the growing knowledge of the design of control systems and trust in outsourcing
relationships.
Globalization and competition create difficulties in developing and maintain expertise and
skills necessary to compete successfully. Outsourcing of core and non-core activities is a form
of strategic alliance. But they come of course with high risk since there are different
objectives and potential for opportunistic behavior. Governance structures such as
management control systems (MCS) and development of trust help reduce risk and decrease
failure.
Outsourcing: contracting of any service or activity to a third party
Design of MCS for outsourcing relationships not very prominent. Outsourcing relationships
encompass uncertainty and risk for both parties, are complex and there is a need for flexibility
and adaptation.
Within-firm control systems
Organizational control system consist of formal, explicitly designed controls AND unwritten
informal, social controls that cannot be designed explicitly.
Formal designed controls: distinction between
- outcome controls (that measure and monitor outputs of operations/ suitable when high
output measurability and low task programmability)
and
- behavior controls (that specify and monitor individuals behavior/ suitable when low output
measurability and high task programmability).
Social controls (clan): develop from shared norms, values and beliefs and rely on
internalization of goals/ suitable when both output measurability and task programmability are
low.
Trust and control systems
Some claim that control mechanisms and trust are complementary, others that control systems
are damaging trust.
Trust is developed over time and is essential to strengthen relationships between partners,
allows alliances to flourish and reduces the possibility of opportunistic behavior.
Characterized as an alternative uncertainty absorption mechanism to provide increased
information, which is important in outsourcing relationships.
Three definitions of trust:
-
Contractual trust: based on honesty, assuming the other party will honor the agreement
(whether in writing or not)
Competence trust: based on perceptions of ability and expertise, expecting a
technically competent partner (in usually specified agreements).
Goodwill trust: perceptions of the partners intention to perform in line with the
specified
agreements
(integrity,
responsibility,
dependability)
Frequency of transaction
Uncertainty
Asset specificity: the degree to which an asset can be redeployed to alternative use
without loosing productive value (also: opportunity loss when a relationship is
terminated early)- in high levels it creates dependency between the parties, increases
switching costs, makes governance situations more difficult.
But: social context?
TCE-based models of management control
Spekl introduces two control archetypes for outsourcing relations: hybrid arms-length
control and hybrid exploratory control.
Van der meer-kooistra & Vosselman identified three management control types for
outsourcing relationships:
-
market based pattern: suits transactions with high task programmability, high output
measurability, low asset specificity, and high task repetition. Market prices linked to
the quality of the output (from the outsourcers side). No detailed contracts but
disciplined by the possibility of returning to the market for competing bids.
Transaction environment: low uncertainty, many available suppliers.
bureaucracy based pattern (~hybrid arms-length): suits transactions with high task
programmability, high output measurability, moderate asset specificity and low-
medium repetitiveness. Controls formal and rigid, detailed contracts that monitor
performance. Contracts are specific and long term, trust mainly important in the early
stages. In order for the ousourccer to be selected he must have high levels of
competence and contractual trust. Transaction environment: low uncertainty,
predictable future
trust based pattern (~hybrid exploratory): suits transactions with low levels of task
programmability, low levels of output measurability, high asset specificity and low
repetition. Transaction environment: highly uncertain and risky and so trust becomes
main control mechanism. Initial selection derives from perceptions of competence,
contractual, and goodwill trust (->also overcomes information asymmetry). Control
systems more informal, also as social controls. Since output and activities cannot be
measured trust is necessary to achieve control.
(Hybrid exploratory control similar except asset specificity is moderate instead of
high. Why?: belief that high asset specificity increases potential opportunistic behavior
and information leakage BUT goodwill trust and contractual trust lessens that.)
In sum:
In a market based pattern, there are no explicit control mechanisms and trust is not relevant in
achieving control.
Under a bureaucratic based pattern, outcome controls and behavior controls are the prime
control mechanisms, and trust plays a minor role in achieving control.
Under a trust based pattern, outcome controls and social controls emerge over time, and trust
plays a significant role in achieving control.
1. What are the assumptions of transaction cost theory in its original formulation (TCT)?
What are do Noteboom (2004) and Husted and Folger (2004) criticize in this original
formulation?
2. According to (1) transaction cost theory (TCT), (2) the resource-based
view/competence view, and (3) Mahnkes evolutionary perspective what are the
factors that should be taken into account when choosing the governance form for an
activity? Explain how each of these factors influences the decision to make or buy
according to the theories. Please note that factors are variables in a theory, meaning
that they can be high or low.
3. If a firm has decided to outsource an activity, (1) what are the most important criteria
to choose a firm to outsource to?, (2) what should the outsourcing contract specify?,
(3) how should the outsourcing relationship be managed once the contract is in effect?
Week 6
The Resource View: consistent with the efficient use of resources. It focuses on
heterogeneity amongst firms and is a theory of growth, not equilibrium. Rent-seeking
firms diversify in response to excess capacity in productive factors (resources). As
long as expansion provides a way of more profitably employing its underused
resources, a firm has an incentive to expand. But if they can be efficiently sold in the
market, the rationale for diversification evaporates. A firms level of profit and breadth
of diversification are a function of its resource stock. Because firms are different, they
will have different optimal levels of diversification. For a firm with less specific
resources, profits may be maximized at a relatively high level of diversification even
though a firm with more specific resources could obtain absolutely higher profits with
less diversification.
Goold, M. and Luchs, K. 1993. Why diversify? Four decades of management thinking.
In the 1950s, diversifying companies were seen as anti-competitive, for they cross-subsidized
their different businesses to force competitors from the field. In the 1990s, companies were
seen as being uncompetitive, for they add no value to their businesses. What have we learned
about diversification strategies that work and those that dont?
Diversification and Corporate Strategy in the 1950s and 1960s
An important and enduring justification for the diversified company is the argument that
managers of these companies possess general management skills that contribute to the overall
performance of a firm.
General Management Skills. Different businesses required similar managerial skills. Drucker
encouraged managers to study the principles of management and to acquire knowledge and
analyzetheir performance systematically. This continued into the 60s. Professional managers
might be able to use their skills in different businesses. There was widespread respect for
management skills, and business people were encouraged to apply their general management
skills to improve the effectiveness of charities, universities and government. More and more
business school were founded.
Rise of Conglomerates. During the 60s, the growth of conglomerates with numerous
acquisitions of unrelated businesses across different industries provided laboratory
conditions in which the test of general management skills could take place. It was stated that
success of conglomerates was caused by these skills. But, in Britain, it was more about
identifying and buying companies, whose assets were worth more than their stock market
price and less on the application of sound, underlying general management principles by the
top management group. Berg suggested that corporate strategies based on improving the
performance of a diverse collection of businesses would have important implication for the
practice of management and for public policy. Conglomerates seemed to demonstrate that
specialized skills and practices of corporate general managers enabled them to
manage ever greater complexity and diversity.
Conglomerates and Performance Problems.
By the late 60s, conglomerates were encountering performance problems. Stock prices fell
and conglomerate divestitures were needed. Management skills and the corporate objective of
growth were not sufficient to ensure performance in these companies. There was a lot of
profitless growth, and a new approach to the management of diversity was needed.
Diversification and Corporate Strategy in the 1970s
Increasing attention was devoted to the question of the issues on which general managers
should focus their efforts.
The Concept of Strategy. There was a need for senior managers to focus on the strategies of
their companies. It was more than long-range planning or objective setting: it was a way of
deciding the basic direction of the company and preparing it to meet future challenges.
Christensen stated that strategy could simplify the complex task of top managers. It allowed
them to concentrate on the most important issues and simplified management by providing a
framework for decisions. CEOs rapidly accepted this and many firms established formal
planning systems, which got studied by academics. But, this strategy focused on the business
unit and so it was less relevant in order to
define an overall strategy for diversified firms. Andrews then defined the main task of
corporate level strategy as identifying the businesses in which the firm would compete, and
this was known as corporate strategy. But this did not give much practical guidance, and did
not state how resources should be allocated.
Problems with Resource Allocation.
With many divisions competing for funds, how could a company be sure it was investing in
the best projects for future growth? In practice, divisional managers only proposed projects
with acceptable forecast returns, and corporatelevel managers had little basis on which to
choose among projects. Bower then stated that these decisions should be integrally related to a
businesss strategic product and market decisions. So, portfolio planning was introduced by
BCG and this gained wide acceptance.
Portfolio Planning. Managers had a common framework to compare many different
businesses; they could be classified in terms of their strategic position and opportunities.
Managers could set appropriate objectives and resource allocation strategies for different
businesses, determine the overall cash requirements and generation. Portfolio planning
became the basis of corporate strategy.
Problems with Portfolio Management.
While certain businesses appeared to meet all economic requirements of the corporate
portfolio, they did not fit into the corporate family.
Companies made few changes to adapt. Many firms were taking the wrong approach to some
of their businesses. Different types of businesses had to be managed differently, general
management skills thus werent THAT important any more. Portfolio planning did not answer
the question of what contribution the corporation should make to each of its businesses.
Diversification and Corporate Strategy in the 1980s
There was widespread skepticism about the ability of companies to manage and add value to
diverse, conglomerate portfolios.
Cost Cutting at Headquarters.
Attention shifted to cutting headquarters costs. Firms disbanded central functions or turned
central services into profit centers. Line managers in decentralized units
had more authority. The wave of takeovers caused executives to pay increasing attention to
their companys stock price as analysts and raiders identified value gaps: the difference
between current stock market price of a company and its breakup value.
Value-Based Planning.
Executives devoted themselves to the task of creating shareholder value. They
had a new perspective on the link between stock prices and competitive strategy. A companys
stock price is determined by the value of the strategies of its businesses. But to assess this
value in diversified businesses is hard. Value-based planning offered means of evaluation
using a common framework. Business units make strategic choices on the basis of economic
returns, so corporate management have a basis for making decisions on capital allocation. But
this also has limitations, for it does not provide much insight into the kind of corporate
strategies that should be pursued to meet
these criteria. A higher stock price indicates a reward for creating value, but how can
corporations add value to diverse business portfolios?
Nippa, M., Pidun, U., & Rubner, H. 2011. Corporate Portfolio Management: Appraising
Four Decades of Academic Research1
Corporate portfolio management comprises key corporate-level strategic decisions,
such as entry into new businesses, allocation of scarce resources to different business units,
and liquidation of value-destroying divisions
The Rise and Fall of CPM in Strategic Management Thinking
Three important paradigms emerged that shaped strategic management thinking for almost
three decades and subsequently fostered corporate diversification activities. First, firm growth
was seen as the most important driver of profitability and success. Second, it was believed
that a corporate economy, or hierarchical coordination, would outperform a market economy.
Mainly due to transaction costs and the supposed inherent advantages of strategic planning
and resource allocation. Third, the development of, and belief in, general management skills
and universal principles of management bolstered the idea that managers educated at leading
business schools were optimally qualified to manage multi business firms efficiently. By the
1980s, however, the pendulum of strategic management thinking started to swing back
toward more focused corporate portfolios. A new dominance of theory-based beliefs in the
superiority of markets (invisible hand) over corporations (visible hand) built on theories of
core competencies or capabilities-oriented corporate strategy.
Does Research on Diversification Eviscerate CPM?
The diversification- performance rationales and empirical evidence can be organized into
three categories: value creation from diversification, value destruction from diversification,
or an inverted U form. First, value-enhancing models propose a consistently positive
relationship between diversification and corporate performance. For instance, Market power
advantages such as cross subsidization; Economies of scale and scope regarding multiple-use
resources; Capital market advantages and more efficient allocation; Corporate diversification
reduces risk, or volatility in rates of return. Second, advocates of value-destroying models
refer predominantly to internal transaction costs and principal-agent reasoning, and argue that
the cost of increasing bureaucracy and subsequent coordination and governance costs exceed
the economic benefits of diversification. Third, authors advocating inverted-U models argue
that there is an optimal level of diversification. On the one hand, some argue that there is a
trade-off between benefits and costs of diversification. Multi-business firms that are engaged
in related markets are able to benefit from synergies or the leverage of resources at reasonable
coordination costs, leading to an increase in profitability compared to focused firms and
limited diversifiers. On the other hand, the more a multi-business firm diversifies in
less-related businesses, the more coordination costs soar and benefits decline, leading to
decreasing profitability.
What Are the Major Causes of Scholarly Criticism of CPM, and How Valid Are They?
The following review of the criticism of CPM instruments makes use of broad categories
that show up in the overall picture: on one hand, scholarly contributions that emphasize
conceptual and methodological deficiencies, and on the other, those that focus on
shortcomings and problems with regard to application, implementation, and outcomes.
To start with the first strain of criticism, some question whether management within multibusiness firms can make reliable decisions based on just two variables - market conditions
and company potential relative to competitors - and a single objective, that is cash flow
balance. Also, critics challenge some fundamental assumptions of the original CPM matrices,
such as the objective of maintaining a balanced portfolio in terms of internal cash flows, the
positive correlation between market share and profitability, and the superiority of investments
in industry growth. Finally, scholars frequently criticized the lack of clear definitions, criteria,
and metrics, particularly with regard to the definition of the relevant markets and SBUs or the
scales and dividing lines of the portfolio matrices. A promising strain of CPM research is
based on a theory of traded and non-traded assets. It emphasizes that internal corporate
diversification is justified only if economically positive interdependencies exist, but even in
this case these synergies bear costs in terms of higher risk. They pointed out that products are
risky assets that are not traded currently but could be traded if their external value exceeded
the internal value potential.
Criticism of traditional CPM instruments highlights problems,
deficiencies, and errors associated with the application of CPM methods resulting from (a)
inadvertent or deliberate misapplication of the instrument, (b) blind implementation of the
prescriptive strategies that follow from the analysis, or (c) the general inferiority of strategic
conclusions from CPM matrices. Three small examples of each point of criticism: First,
managers may choose just those market definitions, boundary lines, and evaluation data that
support their general beliefs or interests, resulting in a more favourable position of the
respective SBU in the grid system. Second, dog businesses are not worthless to the
corporation because they often generate unexpected positive cash flows that can nurture at
least one question mark business. Third, SBUs are classified into a limited number of
categories with specific strategic recommendations based on only few simplistic criteria.
Proposing a Research Agenda for Advancing CPM
First, we need to address criticism of existing CPM instruments, from disagreement about the
relevance of corporate diversification at large as well as from gaps in the existing theory.
Additionally, we need to investigate the application of CPM methods as part of strategic
management processes.
Scholars need to develop more sophisticated CPM methods that integrate important
decision variables (e.g., risk, synergies, locus of control in capital markets) and moderators
(e.g., relatedness of SBUs, industry characteristics, market institutions) to generate greater
insight. Also, there is the need to understand the impact of CPM in different institutional
settings. Future research should focus on two things: (a) developing
instruments that support decision makers in better defining markets, scales, and multiple
mapping to reduce ambiguity and arbitrariness and (b) providing managers with guidelines on
important contingencies that affect the appropriateness and applicability of these measures.
There is a lack of theory development in the CPM literature. Exploring ways to use
real options reasoning in this special field of corporate strategy is an area for further theory
development. Theoretical models of the portfolio problem based on risk and return reasoning
offer a promising starting point for developing concepts that integrate corporate
risk management and corporate strategic planning. However, they have to account for
significant differences between financial and corporate portfolio characteristics. Determining
different forms of balance and respective measures may complement this research field. For
instance, balancing exploration and exploitation.
Misaplication of CPM instruments is a main criticism, but research on its causes is
lacking and outdated. Scholars should investigate how satisfied decision makers are with their
approaches to CPM and what is needed to fill apparent deficiencies and gaps. Also, to
distinguish good CPM practices from less effective ones, future research may compare
the CPM approaches and processes of successful multi-business firms with those of their less
successful peers. Finally, future research should also focus on organizational capabilities and
management skills that are required to effectively implement CPM.
SAMENVATTING2
Corporate portofolio management is at the center of corporate strategy.
Rise and fall of CPM in strategic management thinking
A paradigms emerged that shaped strategic management and fostered corporate diversification
activities:
1. firm growth was seen as the most important driver of profitability and success.
2. A (corporate economy/) hierarchical coordination would outperform a market
economy due to transaction costs and (supposed) advantages of strategic planning and
resource allocation.
3. Belief in universal principles of management that boosted the idea that managers
educated at leading business schools were optimally qualified to manage multibusiness firms efficiently.
However usually diversification occurred in related business domains after th mid-1960s
diversification in weak and non-related conglomerate businesses came into favor. And so,
management of diversified corporations had to formulate and implement efficient corporate
strategies to generate and allocate free cash flow, exploit synergies, identify new growth
opportunities and decide whether to sell low-performing businesses. Name most clearly
attached to this emerging portfolio was D. Henderson (BCG matrix/ market growth and
relative market share basic dimensions).
But in the 1980s strategic management thinking switched back to more focused corporate
portfolios.
Why: dominance of theory-based beliefs in the superiority on markets (invisible hand) over
corporations (visible hand) built on theories of core competencies/capabilities oriented
corporate strategy, and thus lost its economic rationale.
Does research on diversification eviscerate CPM?
Diversification-performance link can be divided in 3 categories: value creation from
diversification, value destruction from diversification, or an inverted U.
Value creation drwas on arguments from market power theory, internal capital market
efficiency reasoning, transactions costs theory, portfolio theory.
Advocates of value destruction refer to internatl transaction costs and principal-agent
reasoning and argue that the cost of increasing bureaucracy and subsequent coordination and
governance costs exceed the economic benefits of diversification.
Advocates of the inverted U models argue that there is an optimal level of diversificationmoderately diversified firms outperform both single-business firms and highly diversified
corporations, since the more a multi-business firm diversifies in less- related businesses, the
more coordination costs.
Empirical evidence:
-
directed from mature or slowly growing marets toward high-growth markets appears to be
unfounded.
Also: lack of clear definitions, criteria and metrics with regard to the definition of the relevant
markets and SBUs or the scales and dividing lines of the portfolio matrices.
However, there is no consistency among critics regarding how to overcome vagueness and
ambiguity and only a few scholars propose a conceptual alternative other than modulating and
sophisticating the basic scheme.
Internal corporate diversification is justified only if economically positive interdependencies
exist but even in this case theses synergies bear costs in terms of higher risk.
Criticism regarding misapplication and outcomes
criticism of traditional CPM instruments highlights problems, deficiencies and errors
associated with the application of CPM methods resulting from:
a. inadvertent or deliberate misapplication of the instrument
b. blind implementation of the prescriptive strategies that follow from the analysis
c. the general inferiority of strategic conclusions from CPM matrices.
Wide scope of their interpretation regarding key elements creates for many opportunities for
pursuing individual interests at the cost of overall corporate objectives.
There is empirical proof that dog businesses are not worthless to the corporation because they
often generate unexpected positive cash flows that can nurture at least one question mark.
Even correct application of CPM matrices may lead to inferior decisions and value destruction
because SBUs are classified into limited number of categories with specific strategic
recommendations based on only few simplistic criteria.
Have scholars systematically investigated actual CPM practices and implementation?
Relative few studies, showed that:
-
There is need to actively seek and acquire relevant information based in adequate
organizational structures and sophisticated management processes.
Proposing a research agenda form advancing CPM
Criticizing strategic management tools such as CPM matrices because of oversimplification
requires a clear distinction between instrumental simplification and misleading, logical, or
methodological oversimplification.
Ultimately, oversimplification is more a matter of how managers apply strategic planning
tools than the tools themselves, as these managers have to decide whether additional
information is necessary to substantiate decisions.
Need for the development of more sophisticated CPM methods that integrate important
decision variables and moderators to generate greater insight.
The advancement of concepts such as synergies, parenting advantage, and additional
moderators can add important building blocks.
Most striking gap however is the lack of conceptual approaches, theory-based advancements
and developments of specific theories. Ex. Managing strategic alliances as a portfolio is a
conceptual approach that is promising but unexplored. Thus determining different forms of
balance and respective measures may complement this research field.
that will make a significant difference in growth and will fit with its capabilities. We have
devised six rules to help managers. The rules help managers be
cautious in the search for growth opportunities, avoid costly mistakes and yet be ready to
move decisively when a really promising opportunity emerges.
6 rules
*
If we had put even half the effort into our core businesses that we put into new businesses,
we would have come out ahead.
Unless managements first priority is to maximise the potential from the core, the future
challenge may be survival rather than growth.
*
Rather than focusing on markets that are growing, managers should focus on markets where
they have an advantage and can bring some special resource of competence to the game.
(The exceptions to this advice are where there are dog markets and raregames. Dog
markets exist where there is intense competition and most competitors earn less than their
cost of capital: these should be avoided whether the company has advantages or not. Rare
games exist where new markets open up, with demand
exceeding supply, or where high pricing or outdated processes and habits make it easy for
new, fleet of foot entrants to the market.)
*
2. Is the profit pool for this new business average (yellow) a rare game (green),
or a dog (red)?
Judgments about variables, such as Porters Five Forces, were critical to this assessment.
*
3. Does the company have leaders of this new business (and sponsoring managers
in the parent company) who are especially insightful or skilled (green), average
(yellow) or less skilled (red) than likely competitors?
Judgements about the status, drive, business acumen and knowledge of the market,
technology or business model of the likely leaders were critical to this assessment.
*
Chandler, A.D. 1991. The functions of the HQ unit in the multibusiness firm.
Its essentially a paper discussing the role of HQ in multibusiness firms throughout history.
They discuss some examples from the UK, which are not too important, and some from the
US like GE and IBM, which are quite relevant and could be used as examples in the exam.
Apart from that, Im afraid that there are no real insights about diversification etc. in this
paper.
The historical evolution of the multibusiness firm:
In the interwar years in the United States, but rarely before 1950 in Europe, senior
executives rationalized the management of this multimarket growth through the
adoption of some variations of the M-Form with its corporate headquarters and
integrated product or geographical divisions
The M-form came into being when senior managers operating through existing
centralized, functionally departmentalized U-Form structures realized that they had
neither the time nor the necessary information to coordinate and monitor day-to-day
operations, or to devise and implement long-term plans for the several product lines
There are three major types of management styles used by senior managers at
corporate HQ: Strategic Planning, Strategic Control and Financial Control
The success of the HQ units adopting those styles to their industries characteristics
determine the effective size and boundaries of their enterprises
Strategic planning category companies are by far the least diversified, operate the
smallest number of businesses, have the highest linkages between divisions and the
highest overlap between business units within divisions
Strategic control companies operate more businesses, have fewer overlaps between the
divisions and on the whole have less synergy between the business units
acquisition,
not by
Growth was almost wholly through the buying of new operating units and not through
direct internal investment
Basic function of HQ was then administrative or loss preventive. It was to review the
financial performance of the businesses controlled and to adjust the enterprises
portfolio accordingly (weak sold off, new ones that that met the logic bought)
By the late 1980s companies had learned that growth was limited by the corporate
HQs ability to manage profitably its unrelated operating units
Such controls were effective in service industries and in industries involving relatively
inexpensive production facilities and small R7D expenditures. IN technologically
more complex industries, they had little choice but to concentrate their portfolios in a
small number of groups of related product lines.
The most successful of the conglomerates were those that acquired and managed
companies in industries where financial control alone was sufficient to maintain
profitability
Difference between strategic planning (SP) and strategic control (SC) companies was
that in the first the corporate office played a more decisive role
SC differed from SP companies in that much of the planning developed upon the
divisional HQ
In defining and implementing strategy, long term gains were sacrificed for short term
ones
IBM:
Since the 60s senior management has been committed to heavy investment in R&D
and to the strategic planning and management development necessary to help assure
long-term payback on that investment
At IBM, the entrepreneurial and the administrative functions have been closely
intertwined and have reinforced one another
GE:
Grouped the business into 3 categories: core, high technology and service
Managers of long established core divisions received little planning or direction from
HQ, and were instead controlled through tight budgets and carefully designed strategic
targets
In the new high tech endeavors, Welch and the HQ continued to play a large role in
strategic planning
New strategy has meant concentration on those products for which production,
distribution and continuing improvement GE has developed impressive organizational
capabilities over time
DU PONT:
The stated objective of the reshaping of the HQ was to break down barriers between
operating division and to have top management develop a corporate rather than a
product or functional perspective
Lesson to learn was that moving into new business based on existing capabilities also
meant that you had to develop complementary ones
They learned that the HQ functions varied with the characteristics of the industries in
which they operated
Bartlett C.A. and Ghoshal, S. 1993. Beyond the M-Form: Towards a managerial theory
of the firm.
Note: maybe a bit too much elaborated on ABB (the firm discussed in the paper), but it gives
a more clear view on differences in the old M-form, compared to the beyond M-form
proposed in this article, in practice. The three processes in the figure at the final page are the
fundamental processes in the new form. Good luck.
Large global corporations are innovating a new organizational form, beyond the
multidivisional form knowledge and expertise, rather than capital or scale as key strategic
resource. Firms had problems with adapting their classic organizational structures and
processes. Article highlights differences from this new form, compared with the old M-form.
Firm (ABB) used as a concrete context for framing a broad new organizational model.
New model will be compared with the old model through three lenses:
1. Chandlers structural description to explicate differences in entrepreneurial process,
compared to the M-form
2. Bowers strategic processes model to highlight the horizontal integration process in
comparison to the M-forms vertical information processing mechanisms
3. Behavioral theory of the firm to explain the importance of macrolevel goal-setting and
learning mechanisms as compliments to the microlevel processes in the m-form that
were the focus of Cyert and Marchs analysis.
Chandlers perspective:
Similarities:
-
The new form stays in line with Chandlers prescription for creating reliable
information and data flows to support the lines of authority formalized information
flow which provides accurate data and helps group executives evaluate performance:
a decentralized organization will only work effectively with a good reporting system
that gives higher level managers the opportunity to react in good time.
Not structured on multiple divisions, but around a business/geographic matrix (article,
page 27 for illustration/example). In this way, ABB can be more globally integrated
while they can also react faster in national environments. This is already deviating
from the standard form, but structure wise, this is still mentioned as a similarity.
Differences:
-
90% of people above the 1300 companies was removed (only 100 left),
staff support really thin.
Also radical redeployment of HR 90% of R&D was allocated to the
1300 companies whose expertise are then linked with those of centers
located in other companies and leveraged broadly across the entire
organization.
Every company responsibility of their own balance sheet
All in line to stimulate entrepreneurial processes first level of the new beyond M-form
model:
-
Bowers perspective
Bower describes a process in which the shaping of new strategic inititaitives and the
investment proposals to support them were initied by front-line managers. Middle-level
managers made resource commitments, because projects that reached top management
through the layers were almost never rejected, so practically, middle managers did that. Top
managements controls the structural context the set of organizational forces that influenced
the processes of definition and impetus.
-
In line with ABB top management structured context and developed policies.
Philosophy was described as decentralization under central conditions.
Also front-line managers were the primary developers of new strategic ideas and
investment proposals
Middle managers needed to focus on business planning and resource allocation
Needs expert staff whose primary role is to perform the adversary role in the planning
process
Differences:
However, knowledge is, unlike capital, a resource that is difficult to accumulate at the
corporate level and allocate according to top managements evaluation of strategic need.
Specialized knowledge is far away in the front-line. This needs a powerful horizontal
integration process to ensure that the entire organiation benefits from the specialized resources
and expertise developed in its entrepreneurial units. Therefore, ABB reduced demands placed
on middle managers by the intensive vertical information processing tasks and the complex
politically driven decision making processes that were at the heart of Bowers model.
-
Compared to the middle managers role in Bower, where they focused mainly on planning and
budgetting, within ABB (and the new M-form) that is more internal benchmarking, best
practice identification and technology transfer, all aimed at linked and leveraging the
companys widely distributed resources and capabilities (knowledge especially).
This is the integration process:
-
This broad portfolio of task forces, teams and committees also have had a broader impact on
the organizational and management processes: they have served to develop management
perspectives and relationships in ways that have helped to prevent isolationism and to break
down parochialism and they have become forums in which managers can negotiate
differences and resolve conflicts that are inherent in the matrix structure. These changes in
management motivations and behaviors and their consequences for the organizations goalsetting and learning processes come intro sharp focus in the behavioural theory of the firm
(Cyert & March)
Cyert & Marchs perspective
Cyert & March formulated a behaviour based theory of the firm that challenged many
economists classic assumptions.
-
Quasi-resolution of conflict
o Goals established on the basis of local rationality, using decision rules based on
satisfying rather than maximizing objectives.
Uncertainty avoidance
Problemistic search
Organizational learning
o Fragmented in approach,
With shifts tending to reflect the expansionist inclinations of subunits
rather than systematic reviews by top management.
o Short-term in focus
So long as the environment of the firm is unstable and unpredictably
unstable, the heart of the theory must be the process of short-run
adaptive reactions
o Incremental in nature
Because many of the rules change slowly, it is possible to construct
models of organizational behaviour that postulate only modest changes
in decision rules.
o Captured in standard procedures, this makes them impediments rather than
facilitators of effective renewal in a highly competitive, global environment.
As a result, the process of incremental learning at the microlevel tends to be
framed by a much more macroprocess in which top management plays a key
role (in line with the connection between front line and top management?)
In contrast to the view that firms solve pressing problems rather than develop longe-range
strategy, focus for ABB managers at all levels is placed on developing clear and shared
strategic objectives Corporate vision.
To ensure implementation of this corporate vision, new structures and processes allow
managers at all levels to transfer broad objectives into specific business and market strategies:
-
Managers at all levels examine implications of vision for their particular areas of
responsibility (more close to the entrepreneurial models that Cyert and March
rejected)
Annually updated business strategies become the basis for annual budget targets,
broken into very specific subgoals that are negotiated and agreed between business,
geographic and company managements instead of rather vague objectives with
disagreement and uncertainty.
More rational macroframework for goal setting and learning, capturing them both in the third
core organizational process: the renewal process
-
Front line management: managing the tension between short-term performance and
long-term ambition
Middle management: creating and maintaining organizational trust
Top management: shaping and embedding corporate purpose
Behavioral theory premised on the absence of leadership, while ABBs renewal process is
clearly driven by highly effective leaders at the corporate top level. Top management has gone
from being formulators of corporate strategy to shapers of an institutional purpose with which
all employees can identify and to which they can commit. Instead of being the architects of
formal structure, they have come to see themselves as the developers of organizational
processes that can capture individual initiative and create supporting relationships. From
strategy-structure to a more organic model built around purposes process and people (through
leadership).
A different research perspective
An organization is fundamentally a social structure. Even though actions of and within
organizations may be motivated by a variety of economic and other objectives, they emerge
through processes of social interactions that are shaped by the social structure. Status and
roles become concepts serving to connect culturally defined expectations with the patterned
conduct and relationships that make up a social structure. A much less pathological view of
human nature, compared to economic theories (including shirking, opportunism & inertia).
Article states:
This model assumes that companies ensure positive individual characteristics both by
selecting and promoting those whose personal characteristics predispose them toward the
desired norms of behaviour, and by creating an internal context that encourages people to act
in the way they would as a member of a functional family or a disciplined sporting team.
Thus, the entrepreneurial process is built on the assumption that individuals have the capacity
of personal agency and initiative, then creates the selection devices and support mechanisms
to elicit and encourage such behaviour. Similarly, the integration process both assumes and
shapes collaborative behaviour, and the renewal process is designed to capitalize on the
human motivation to learn while creating a context that drives them to do so.
Important models in the article:
Dyer, J.H., Kale, P. and Singh, H. 2004. When to ally and when to acquire
Study questions:
1. What are the main theoretical perspectives that have been used in the research on
diversification and what are their views on (1) the reasons why firms diversify, and (2)
the performance outcomes of diversification?
2. What are the managerial implications of the thinking about, and research on,
diversification (which lessons for managers can you draw from the diversification
literature)?
3. What do you see as the advantages and disadvantages of the following different modes
of organizational growth: (1) organic growth (i.e. growth realized by developing new
activities within a firm), (2) alliances and joint ventures, (3) acquisitions?