ECON118 Practice Problems Answers
ECON118 Practice Problems Answers
1. 25%. 1.65/(sqrt(1.44)*sqrt(1.21))=1.65/(1.2*1.1)=1.25.
2. A.
3. B.
4. A.
5. D. 6000/200=30 150/15=10.
6. A, D, E
7. C.
8. C.
9. C.
10. E.
11. 1/4. Sort people from the poorest to the richest. Then, the first quarter of the
population will earn nothing. So, the Lorenz curve passes through (1/4, 0). Lorenz
curve also goes through (0,0) and (1,1). Hence, the area between the Lorenz curve and
the 45 degree line is just the area of a triangle with a base of 1/4 and a height of 1,
which is 1/2*1/4*1=1/8. The Gini coefficient is twice this area, which is 1/8*2=1/4.
12. D.
13. 0.4. (9/10+8/10+3/10)/5=0.4
14. C.
15. D.
16. A.
17. 20%. -10+12/(1+r)=0. Solving, r=0.2
18. C.
19. C.
20. bch.
21. ej.
22. bfe.
23. D.
24. 5 1/2*1+1/2*9=5
25. 4 Expected utility=1/2*10.5+1/2*90.5=2. So, the certainty equivalent amount
satisfies M0.5=2. Solving for M, we have M=4.
26. 5/9 if M=1 and 5 if M=9. We must have (M-CV) 0.5 90.5=M 0.5 40.5. If M=1,
(1-CV) 0.5=2/3. So, CV=5/9. If M=9, (9-CV) 0.5=2. So, CV=5
27. compensating, contingent, valuation
28.3/2 if M=1 and 45/4 if M=9. We must have M0.5 90.5=(M+EV) 0.5 40.5. If M=1,
(1+EV) 0.5=3/2. So, EV=5/4. If M=9, (9+EV) 0.5=9/2. So, EV=45/4.
29. A, C.
Ch1. A.2 a.
The level of GDP per capita in each country, measured in its own currency
is
(CPUs per capita Price) + (IC per capita Price) = GDP per capita.
Therefore, Richlands GDP per capita is 46 and Poorlands GDP per capita is 13.
b. The market exchange rate is determined by the law of one price. As CPUs are the
only traded good, the price of computers should be the same. Consequently, the
exchange rate must be
3 Richland dollars to 2 Poorland dollar.
c. To find the ratio of GDP per capita between Richland and Poorland, we must first
convert GDP denominations into the same currency. In the analysis that follows, I
choose to convert GDP denominations into Poorland dollars, but converting to
Richland dollars is equally correct, similar, and will yield the same result. From
Part (a), we convert Richlands GDP per capita, denominated in Richland dollars,
into Poorland dollars by multiplying GDP per capita with the market exchange rate.
Since from Part (b), we know 3 Richland dollars equals 2 Poorland dollar, we
multiply 2/3 to Richlands GDP per capita, yielding 30.67 Poorland dollars. Thus,
the ratio of Richland GDP per capita to Poorland GDP per capita is 2:36:1.
d. A natural basket to use is 6 computers and 1 ice cream. The cost of this basket in
Richland
is 23 Richland dollars. The cost of this basket in Poorland is 13 Poorland dollars.
Equating
the costs of baskets to be one price, the purchasing power parity exchange rate
must be
23 Richland dollars:13 Poorland dollars.
e. To find the ratio of GDP per capita between Richland and Poorland, we must first
convert GDP denominations into the same currency. In the analysis that follows, I
choose to convert GDP denominations into Poorland dollars, but converting to
Richland dollars is equally correct, similar, and will yield the same result. From
Part (a), we convert Richlands GDP per capita, denominated in Richland dollars,
into Poorland dollars by multiplying GDP per capita with the PPP exchange rate.
Since from Part (d), we know 23 Richland dollars equals 13 Poorland dollars, we
multiply 13/23 to Richlands GDP per capita, yielding 26 Poorland dollars. Thus
the ratio of Richland GDP per capita to Poorland GDP per capita is 2:1.
Ch 3. 2. To find the steady-state value of the country, we refer to Equation (3.3) on page 63.
yss = A
1
1
1
.
Simplifying the above equation, we get yss = 5.To find the current output per
worker, we substitute in k = 900 into the production function to get:
.
That is, the current output is 30 whereas the steady-state output level is 5.
Therefore, we conclude that y > yss so the country is above its steady-state level of output
per worker.
4. This Denoting each variable by the appropriate country subscript, we write Equation 3.3
from page 63 in ratio form. That is,
Since productivity , A, and depreciation, , are the same, we can cancel them and
rewrite the previous ratio with the appropriate values: 1 = 0.1, 2 = 0.2, and
setting =1/3.
Therefore, when =1/3, the ratio is 0.707 and when =1/2, the ratio is 0.50.
a. First we find the steady-state level of capital per worker. Using the values for investment,
= 0.25, depreciation, = 0.05, productivity, A = 1, and = 0.5, we get,
kss =
(1)(0.25) 1 0.5
=
0.05
= 52 = 25.
That is, the steady-state level of capital per worker is 25. Plugging in kss into the
production function we get the steady-state level of output per worker to be:
1
Year
Capital
Output
Investment
Depreciation
Change in Capital
Stock
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
16.00
16.20
16.40
16.59
16.78
16.96
17.14
17.32
4.00
4.02
4.05
4.07
4.10
4.12
4.14
4.16
1.00
1.01
1.01
1.02
1.02
1.03
1.04
1.04
0.08
0.81
0.82
0.83
0.84
0.85
0.86
0.87
0.20
0.20
0.19
0.19
0.19
0.18
0.18
0.17
y2
4.02
1 =
1 = 0.005.
4
y1
g=
That is, output per worker grew at a rate of 0.5 percent between years 1 and 2.
(Using exact values, the growth rate is approximately 0.62 percent for years 1 and
2.)
y8
4.16
1 =
1 = 0.0048.
y
4.14
7
g=
That is, output per worker grew at a rate of 0.48 percent between years 7 and 8.
(Using exact values, the growth rate is approximately 0.52 percent for years 7 and
8.)
e. The speed of growth has changed from 0.50 percent to 0.48 percent implying that
growth has slowed down at a rate of 4 percent. Thus, as a country reaches their
steady-state value, the rate
of growth slows.
Ch 4. 4. In a randomized controlled trial, one would have to randomly vary either the
quantity or the quality of children in a treatment group and compare the children in
this treatment group to children in a control group. For example, providing enhanced
education to the treatment group represents an exogenous downward shock to the
cost of having higher quality children. Providing family planning to a treatment group
would represent an exogenous downward shock to the quantity of children. Using
twins would be a good natural experiment. Since twin births are basically random,
they provide an identifying exogenous variation of quantity. One can compare the
quality of children who were born as twins to the quality of children who were born
alone.
5. To calculate the steady-state level ratio of income per capita, we first find the
steady-state level for each country and then divide one by the other. The steady-state
level ratio for Country X to Y is given by:
We now substitute in the values X = 25%, nX = 0, and X = 10% for Country X, and for
Country Y, we use the values Y = 5%, nY = 5%, and Y = 10%. Also, set =1/3 and Ai =
A. This yields
Therefore, we conclude the ratio of Country Xs steady-state level of income per capita
to Country Ys to be near 2.74.
8.
a)
TFR = 4.
9.
a.
b. First, we divide both sides of the production function by L and rearrange to get:
Y L2 X 2 X
y= =
=
L
L
L
2
,
Therefore,
L=
X
.
y2
c. In the steady state, the growth rate of population is zero, L = 0. Using this value
and rearranging the first equation, we solve for the steady-state value of income per
capita:
L = 0 = y 100,
yss = 100
X
1,000,000
=
= 100.
2
yss
(100)2
A.1.
a. To calculate life expectancy at birth, we must find the area under the survivorship
function.
This amounts to solving the equation:
30
80
30
In discrete time analysis, we can extrapolate that the probability of being alive from
age 0 to 29 is 1; the probability of being alive from age 30 to 79 is 0.5; and the
probability of being alive from age 80 to infinity is 0. Summing these probabilities,
we get:
29
79
30
80
1dx = 20.
20
In discrete time analysis, we can extrapolate that the average number of children
per woman from age 20 to 39 is one and the average number of children per
woman for any other age is zero. Summing these probabilities, we get:
19
39
20
40
F (i) = 0 + 1 + 0 = 0 + 20 + 0 = 20.
i
39
20
30
That is, the rate of reproduction is 15. Adjusting this value by , the fraction of live
births that are girls, we conclude that the net rate of reproduction is 15.
A.2.
For Country X and Country Y assume that the survivorship function is that given in
Problem 1. The total fertility rates for both countries are given below.
The total fertility rate is the same for both countries. However, the rate of reproduction
differs.
For Country X,
29
39
20
30
Adjusting for , the net rate of reproduction for Country X is 2. For Country Y,
29
39
20
30
Adjusting for , the net rate of reproduction for Country Y is 1. Therefore, Country X
has a net rate of reproduction twice as large as Country Y, but the survivorship
function for both countries is identical, as well as the total fertility rate for both
countries. This happens because in Country Y everyone decides to have the same
number of children 10 years later than in Country X. However, because the probability
of being alive changes in those 10 years, we have a difference in the net rate of
reproduction.
Ch5. 1.
5.
In 2025: each of the 90 million 020 year-olds from 2005 will have had 1 girl
and moved on to the next age bracket; two-thirds of the 60 million 2140
year-olds will have died; and all the 4160 year-olds will have died. So, the
new female population structure will be 90 million 020 year-olds, 90 million
2140 year olds and 20 million 4160 year-olds. In 2045, this process
continues, so we have 90 million 020 year-olds, 90 million 2140 year-olds,
and 30 million 4160 year-olds. In 2065, the same structure as 2045 exists.
6. Immediately after fertility declines to zero, the working age fraction of the population
will begin to rise. This is because the fraction of the population made up of children will
fall (as some children become adults and are not replaced by new births). The fraction of
the population made up of working-age adults will peak 20 years after the decline in
fertility. At that point, the population will be composed solely of working-age and old
people. From this point onward, the working-age fraction will fall as working age people
grow old and are not replaced. 65 years after the decline in fertility, the working-age
fraction of the population will reach zero.
Ch6 5. The payment to persons with no schooling (1%) is W; the payment to individuals with
partial primary schooling (3.4%) is 1.65W, the payment to individuals with complete
primary schooling (8.8%) is 2.43W; the payment to individuals with incomplete
secondary schooling (22.1%) is 2.77W; the payment to individuals with complete
secondary schooling (43.4%) is 3.16W; the payment to individuals with incomplete
higher schooling (7.6%) is 3.61W; and the payment to individuals with complete higher
schooling (13.7%) is 4.11W. Summing over the entire population, we calculate the total
wages earned by the population:
The relative return to 10 years of schooling is 2.77, and the relative return to 14 years of
schooling is 3.61 (from table 6.2). Denoting hi = 2.77 and h j = 3.61, we can solve for
the steady-state ratio for two countries identical in every respect expect for education as
follows:
Thus, the ratio of output per worker in the steady state is 0.767.
7.
The relative return to 12 years of schooling is 3.16, and the relative return to 4 years of
schooling is 1.65. Writing the steady-state ratio for one country over time and denoting
h1950 = 1.65 and h2000 = 3.16, we get:
Thus, the ratio of steady-state output per worker for this country over time is 1.92. If
over 100 years, the steady-state output has increased by a factor of 1.92, we can solve for
the growth rate, g, by the following calculation.
.
We conclude that the annual average growth rate of output per worker is 1.31
percent.
Ch 11. 4.
level of output per capita is given by the following equation as reproduced from the
chapter.
yss = A
1
1
rw
Given that the world rental price of capital doubles to rw , which is exactly 2rw , we can
write the new steady-state level of output per worker in terms of the previous rental rate.
1
1
yss = A
rw
=A
1
1
2 rw
=A
1
1
1 1 1
2
rw
1 1
=
2
yss .
That is, the new steady-state level of income per capita falls to just over 74 percent of its
original level when the world rental rate of capital doubles in an economy open to the
world capital market.
6. If there is only one auto factory in each country under autarky, then each auto factory
would have a local monopoly, and therefore there will be no competition driving the
auto factory to become efficient. Upon the opening of trade, all the auto factories will
begin competing with each other, and therefore will have an incentive to lower costs and
become as efficient as possible. Cars will become relatively less expensive since they
now cost less to produce and they are sold in a competitive market.
The pizza industry in each country, however, already was competitive because there
were no size barriers to entry. Therefore, trade in pizza is likely to be unchanged, since
the pizza industry already had high efficiency due to tight competition.
Whether the decline in auto prices leads factors to flow into or out of the auto industry
depends on the price elasticity of demand for autos. If demand is inelastic, then as prices
fall due to more efficient auto production, factors will flow out of the industry and the
pizza industry will grow in size.
It is interesting to note that although each country was identical in terms of efficiency
and technology under autarky, and trade did not affect the technology level in any county,
the overall level of efficiency rose due to more competition.
Ch 12.1.
a. Standardization of the length of axles on carts is a form of a public good. Everyone
benefits from improvements in travel, and improvements in travel are beneficial for
growth.
b. A stable currency is a public good.
c. The creation of a national car in Indonesia, the Timor, is an instance of government
failure. Competition is stunted by providing monopoly power to the Suharto
company through protection policies and as a result, incorrectly aligning incentives.
Ultimately, productivity falls and only the Suharto family benefits.
d. Failure to get vaccinated imposes a negative externality, since a sick person is likely
to spread disease to others.
The answer is unclear. On one hand, the imposition of a minimum wage can be an
example of a government failure. The minimum wage can result in the misallocation
of factors among firms and sectors, and in this case, it serves those who do receive
the minimum wage. Growth may be hindered. On the other hand, the minimum
wage may satisfy normative goals of government, that being equality and general
well-being. In this case, the minimum wage is intended to serve everyone by
eliminating low wage abuses by firms. Growth may be positive.
4.a.
Therefore, for markets to clear, the equilibrium price in the absence of a tax is 50 for
the good.
b. At a tax rate of for each good, the quantity demanded for any given price does not
change because the price paid by the consumer remains unaffected. However, the
quantity supplied for any given price decreases to a factor of (1 ), as
government collects from the supplier. Specifically,
Qd = 100 P and Qs = (1 )P.
In equilibrium, the price must be set such that the quantity demand meets the quantity
supplied. Setting Qd = Qs , and solving for P, we get:
100 P = (1 )P
100 = (1 + 1)P
Peq = 100 /(2 ).
The equilibrium price is the value given above. To find the equilibrium quantity for
the price,
we substitute and get,
Qeq = (1 )Peq =
100(1 )
.
(2 )
(1 )1002
.
(2 )2
Recall that
d f ( x ) f ( x )g( x ) f ( x )g( x )
=
.
dx g( x )
g ( x )2
d (1 )100 2
(1 2 )(2 )2 ( 2 )( 2)(2 )
= (100)2
.
2
d (2 )
(2 )4
Setting the above expression equal to zero, rearranging, and dividing out common
terms,
(1 2 )(2 ) = (2)( )2 .
Therefore, solving the above equation gives us: = (2 / 3). At this tax rate,
government revenue will be maximized.
6. a. In the steady-state level of output per worker, the quantities of government capital
per worker and physical capital worker will not change over time. Therefore,
x = 0 = Ak x x, and
k = 0 = (1 ) Ak x k.
Using the values, = = (1/ 3), we now have two equations with two unknowns.
Working through the algebra and solving for the steady-state values of x and k , we
get:
ss
xss =
kss =
A3 (1 ) 2
ss
, and
A3 2 (1 )2
Plugging in our steady-state values into the production function will now yield the
steady-state level of output per worker.
1
1
3
1
3
yss = Ak x =
b. The value of
maximize
A
A
2 (1 )2 3 A3 (1 ) 2 3 A3
( )(1 ).
=
3
3
2
that will maximize output per worker is the same value that will
Ch 13 1. a.
The Lorenz curve for the economy is drawn below. The data for the curve
are as follows. Total wealth in the economy is ($1)(5) + ($3)(5) = $20. The poorest
10 percent of the people own $1/$20, or 5 percent of the wealth. The poorest 20
percent own 10 percent and so forth until the poorest 50 percent. The poorest 60
percent own ($1)(5) + ($3)(1) = $8 dollars. That is, 8/20 or
40 percent of the wealth. The poorest 70 percent own 55 percent; poorest 80 percent
own
70 percent; poorest 90 percent own 85 percent; and finally the entire economy owns
100 percent of total wealth.
Lorenz Curve
100%
90%
Line of Perfect Equality
80%
Lorenz Curve
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
b.
The Gini is constructed by dividing the area between the line of perfect
equality and the Lorenz curve by the entire area under the line of perfect equality. In
our case,
Gini Coefficient =
A
A+ B+C + D
c. To calculate the Gini, we must find the Area of A, B, C and D. For the Area of B, C,
and D, we apply the area formula for triangles.
Area of B = (0.5)(0.25)(0.5) = 0.0625
Area of C = (0.5)(0.75)(0.5) = 0.1875
Area of D = (0.5)(0.25) = 0.125
In order to find the Area of A, we first calculate the area under the line of perfect
equality. This is simply a 1 by 1 right triangle implying that the area is 0.5.
Following, we can subtract from this the area under the Lorenz curve to find the
Area of A. Since the area under the Lorenz curve is
B + C + D = 0.0625 + 0.1875 + 0.125 = 0.375, we find the Area of A to be,
Area of A = (Area Under Line of Perfect Equality) (Area Under Lorenz Curve)
= (A + B + C + D) (B + C + D) = (0.5) (0.375) = 0.125.
Now we substitute in these values into our equation from Part (b).
100%
Gini Coefficient =
5.
A
0.125
=
= 0.25.
A+ B+C + D
0.5
In the table, the probability that a mother in the middle-earning third will also have a
daughter in the middle earning third is given by the exact center cell, and is 0.5. When
this process is iterated for two generations, of the 50 percent daughters who are in the
middle, 50 percent of their daughters will also be in the middle third. Therefore, 0.5*0.5
= 25 percent of all grandchildren will have both mothers and grandmothers who were
middle class.
However, it could be the case that the grandmother was middle class, but her daughter
was upper or lower class, and that her daughter was again middle class. So we need to do
this calculation for three sets of people, and then sum the probabilities:
a. P(Middle third grandmother has a bottom third daughter)*P(Bottom third mother has
a middle third daughter) = 0.25*0.25 = 0.0625
b. P(Middle third grandmother has a middle third daughter)*P(Middle third mother has
a middle third daughter) = 0.5*0.5 = 0.25
c. P(Middle third grandmother has an upper third daughter)*P(Upper third mother has a
middle third daughter) = 0.25*0.25 = 0.0625
0.0625 + 0.0625 + 0.25 = 0.375 or 37.5 percent.
Ch 15.3. a. Globalization removes a resource constraint that otherwise would reduce income
per capita
in many countries. For example, a country without good agricultural land can import
food. Globalization also means that some countries are rich based on resources that
can be exported (think of oil in Kuwait) that otherwise would be poor if they had to
rely on what could be produced domestically.
b. One way in which globalization affects the relationship between a countrys
geographic characteristics and its level of income per capita is through the access to
trade. Countries advantageously positioned geographically are likely to experience
higher growth due to
increased trade. Conversely, countries that are geographically isolated are likely to
experience lower growth, as access to trade is costly and limited. For example,
Chinas coastal cities, as
well as countries with eased access to trade have grown rapidly. Additionally,
globalization
may allow access to better technologies and well-suited technologies that increase
income.
c. One way in which globalization may affect the relationship between a countrys
climate and its level of income per capita may be through the transfer of technology
that alleviates the detrimental effects of climate. The U.S. South experienced high
growth rates in income per capita with the introduction of the air conditioner.
Although globalization is not the source of this technology transfer, globalization
likely is able to allow the transfer of such technologies that affect the climate in a
manner that improves the income per capita of the country. Furthermore, technologies
may increase the productivity of agriculture, for instance, given any level of climate.
4.
Ch 16 1. To find the annual growth rate of energy intensity of output over this period,
we utilize the following equation, where a hat over the variable denotes its growth
rate.
I = R y L ,
Therefore,
I = 2% 2% 2% = 2%.
The energy intensity fell by two percent per year over this period.
2.
a. Because the stock of fish St at time t is 20, we use the equation for the
growth in the quantity of fish to determine Gt .
Gt =
Additionally, the stock of fish and the size of the harvest have been constant
for a long period of time. Mathematically, this implies that,
St = St +1 St = Gt Ht = 0.
Setting the above equation to 0 and solving for St , we get St = 50. The
optimal stock of fish that maximizes the growth in the stock of fish will be
50.
At this stock level of fish, we repeat the analysis in Part (a) to arrive at the
maximum sustainable yield.
Gt =
8.
In the short run, a firm is unable to substantially change the mix of factors of production.
Thus a pollution tax will not lower pollution much, but will raise a lot of revenue.
However, in the long run, the firm is able to adjust the factors of production and possibly
innovate processes to increase output and reduce pollution. Firms will substitute away
from pollution-heavy and thus tax burden-heavy factors to a pollution-minimizing and
tax burden-minimizing mix of factors. Pollution will fall, as well as government
revenues from the tax.