Lecture 05 - 06 Notes - Spring 2009 PDF
Lecture 05 - 06 Notes - Spring 2009 PDF
2.1
2.2
(1)
where the left-hand side is the current flow of output, and the right hand
side is equal to a technology parameter A times the capital contribution
times the labor contribution.
Remember that:
K M P K = Y,
so that
K MPK
Y
is the capitals share of output. Figure 3.3 shows that share for a sample
of 53 countries. The average is about 1/3.
=
2.3
zt+1 zt
.
zt
dz
z
/z = = zb;
dt
z
dK
= sY K,
dt
that is: net current capital accumulation is equal to total current investment (itself equal to total savings in equilibrium of the goods market)
minus total current depreciation of the capital stock.
2.4
Steady state
1
sA 1
.
)
This steady state is stable, in the sense that starting from a level of capital
K < K ss , capital will accumulate until the capital stock reaches its steadystate level K = K ss ; similarly, starting from a level of capital K > K ss ,
capital will decumulate until the capital stock reaches K = K ss .
To this steady-state level of capital corresponds a steady state level of
output:
1
s
Y ss = A(K ss ) = A 1 ( ) 1 .
Remarks:
1. This latter equation provides us with a theory of the sources of (longrun) income dierences across countries: in particular (per capita)
GDP across two countries may dier either due to dierences in productivity as captured by A, or because of dierences in savings or
investment rate rate as captured by s. Thus, suppose, that we abstract from dierences in technologies and concentrate in dierences
in savings or investment rates, and compare the predicted ratio of
income per worker in each country to income per worker in the US,
to the ratio of actual incomes between that country and the US. We
are very far from the 450 line. In particular, Uganda should have a
3
GDP per capita of around 33% of US GDP per capita, however the
true ratio is only 3%. Why? Maybe Uganda still lies very far from
its steady-state, whereas US lies close to its steady-state.
2. The Solow model predicts no growth of GDP per capita in the longrun, since output per capita converges to a fixed value Y ss . The
reason for this no-growth in steady state result, is the assumption of
decreasing returns to capital accumulation and therefore of decreasing savings to output ratio, whereas depreciation occurs at a constant
rate; so, eventually, depreciation catches up with savings.
2.5
Convergence
thus since
b = dK /K = sAK 1 ,
K
dt
< 1,
we see that the higher the current level of capital, the lower the growth
rate of the capital stock, and therefore the lower the growth rate of output
since
b
Yb = K.
Thus the country will lower current level of its capital stock will grow faster
than the country with the higher level of its current capital stock. Note
also that the Solow model leads to the following additional predictions:
1. if two countries have the same rate of investment but dierent levels
of income, then the country with lower income will grow faster;
2. if two countries have the same level of income but dierent rates of
investment, then the country with a higher rate of investment will
have higher growth;
3. a country that raises its level of investment will experience an increase
in its growth rate of income.
While the Solow model predicts convergence to the same steady state for
all countries or regions with similar savings rates s, depreciation rates
and productivity parameter A, it does not explain why some countries
manage to converge towards the most advanced countries and why others
4
2.6
Now, let us replace the first equation in the Solow model by this equation,
and put it together with the second equation of the Solow model; we have:
dK
= sA0 K K,
dt
and therefore:
b = sA0 .
K