Economics: Market Structure Notes
Economics: Market Structure Notes
Market Structures
CHAPTER
Perfect Competition
173
Why is the demand curve horizontal for a firm in a perfectly competitive market?
Perfect Competition
Firms sell goods and services under different market conditions, which economists call market structures. A market structure describes the key traits of
a market, including the number of firms, the similarity of the products they
sell, and the ease of entry into and exit from the market. Examination of the
business sector of our economy reveals firms operating in different market
structures. In this chapter and the two chapters that follow, we will study
four market structures. The first is perfect competition, to which this entire
chapter is devoted. Perfect, or pure, competition is a market structure characterized by (1) a large number of small firms, (2) a homogeneous product,
and (3) very easy entry into or exit from the market. Lets discuss each of
these characteristics.
Market structure
A classification system for the key
traits of a market, including the
number of firms, the similarity
of the products they sell, and the
ease of entry into and exit from
the market.
Perfect competition
A market structure characterized
by (1) a large number of small
firms, (2) a homogenous product,
and (3) very easy entry into or exit
from the market. Perfect competition is also referred to as pure
competition.
174
Very Easy Entry and Exit. Very easy entry into a market means that a
new firm faces no barriers to entry. Barriers can be financial, technical, or
government-imposed barriers, such as licenses, permits, and patents. Anyone who wants to try his or her hand at raising ostriches needs only a plot
of land and feed.
Conclusion Perfect competition requires that resources be completely
mobile to freely enter or exit a market.
No real-world market exactly fits the three assumptions of perfect competition. The perfectly competitive market structure is a theoretical or ideal
model, but some actual markets do approximate the model fairly closely.
Examples include farm products markets, the stock market, and the foreign
exchange market.
For model-building purposes, suppose a firm operates in a market that conforms to all three of the requirements for perfect competition. This means
that the perfectly competitive firm is a price taker. A price taker is a seller
that has no control over the price of the product it sells. From the individual
firms perspective, the price of its products is determined by market supply
and demand conditions over which the firm has no influence. Look again at
the characteristics of a perfectly competitive firm: a small firm that is one
among many firms, sells a homogeneous product, and is exposed to competition from new firms entering the market. These conditions make it impossible for the perfectly competitive firm to have the market power to affect the
market price. Instead, the firm must adjust to or take the market price.
Exhibit 1 is a graphical presentation of the relationship between the market supply and demand for electronic components and the demand curve facing a firm in a perfectly competitive market. Here we will assume that the
electronic components industry is perfectly competitive, keeping in mind that
the real-world market does not exactly fit the model. Exhibit 1(a) shows
market supply and demand curves for the quantity of output per hour. The
theoretical framework for this model was explained in Chapter 4. The equilibrium price is $70 per unit, and the equilibrium quantity is 60,000 units
per hour.
Because the perfectly competitive firm takes the equilibrium price, the
individual firms demand curve in Exhibit 1(b) is perfectly elastic (horizontal) at the $70 market equilibrium price. (Note the difference between the
firms units per hour and the industrys thousands of units per hour.) Recall
from Chapter 5 that when a firm facing a perfectly elastic demand curve
tries to raise its price one penny higher than $70, no buyer will purchase its
product [Exhibit 2(a) in Chapter 5.] The reason is that many other firms are
selling the same product at $70 per unit. Hence, the perfectly competitive
firm will not set the price above the prevailing market price and risk selling
zero output. Nor will the firm set the price below the market price because
the firm can sell all it wants to at the going price; therefore, a lower price
would reduce the firms revenue.
EXHIBIT 1
The Market Price and Demand for the Perfectly Competitive Firm
(b) Individual firm demand
120
Market
supply
80
70
60
Market
demand
40
100
Price per unit
(dollars)
120
100
80
70
Demand
60
40
20
175
20
20
40
60
80
100
120
Quantity of output
(thousands of units per hour)
10
12
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
In part (a), the market equilibrium price is $70 per unit. The perfectly competitive firm in part (b) is a
price taker because it is so small relative to the market. At $70, the individual firm faces a horizontal
demand curve, D. This means that the firms demand curve is perfectly elastic. If the firm raises its price
even one penny, it will sell zero output.
176
(2)
(3)
(4)
Total
revenue
Total
cost
Profit
[(2) (3)]
$ 0
$100
$100
70
150
80
2
3
140
210
184
208
44
(5)
Marginal
cost
[(3)/(1)]
(6)
Marginal
revenue
[(2)/(1)]
$ 50
$70
34
70
24
70
19
280
227
53
70
23
350
250
100
70
30
420
280
140
70
38
490
318
172
70
48
560
366
194
70
59
630
425
205
70
75
10
700
500
200
70
95
11
770
595
175
70
117
12
840
712
128
70
presented in previous chapters. The total cost figures in column 3 are taken
from Exhibit 3 in Chapter 7. Total fixed cost at zero output is $100.
Total revenue is reported in column 2 of Exhibit 2 and is computed as
the product price times the quantity. In this case, we assume the market
equilibrium price is $70 per unit, as determined in Exhibit 1. Because Computech is a price taker, the total revenue from selling 1 unit is $70, from selling 2 units is $140, and so on. Subtracting total cost in column 3 from total
revenue in column 2 gives the total profit or loss (column 4) that the firm
earns at each level of output. From zero to 2 units, the firm incurs losses,
and then a break-even point (zero economic profit) occurs at about 3 units
per hour. If the firm produces 9 units per hour, it earns the maximum profit
of $205 per hour. As output expands, between 9 and 12 units of output, the
firms profit diminishes. Exhibit 3 illustrates graphically that the maximum
profit occurs where the vertical distance between the total revenue and the
total cost curves is at a maximum.
EXHIBIT 3
177
700
Total
cost
600
Total
500
revenue
and
400
total
cost
(dollars) 300
Maximum
profit = $205
200
Maximum
profit output
100
Loss
0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
(b) Profit
200
150
100
Profit
(dollars)
Profit =
$205
50
0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
50
Maximum
profit output
100
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
178
EXHIBIT 4
179
120
MC
100
Price and 80
cost per
70
unit
(dollars) 60
MR = MC
MR
Profit
= $205
ATC
AVC
40
20
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
(b) Profit
200
150
100
Profit
(dollars)
50
Profit
= $205
0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
50
100
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
In addition to comparing
total revenue and total cost,
a firm can find the profitmaximizing level of output
by comparing marginal revenue and marginal cost. As
shown in part (a), profit is
at a maximum where marginal revenue equals marginal
cost at $70 per unit. The
intersection of the marginal
revenue and the marginal cost
curves establishes the profitmaximizing output at 9 units
per hour.
A profit curve is depicted
separately in part (b) to
show that the maximum
profit occurs when the firm
produces at the level of output corresponding to the
marginal revenue equals
marginal cost point.
180
EXHIBIT 5
181
120
MC
100
Price and 80
cost per
unit
(dollars) 60
50
Loss
= $70
ATC
AVC
35
20
MR
MR = MC
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
(b) Loss
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
50
Loss
100
(dollars)
Loss = $70
150
200
250
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
Note that although the price is not high enough to pay the average total
cost, the price is high enough to pay the average variable cost. Each unit sold
also contributes to paying a portion of the average fixed cost, which is the
vertical distance between the ATC and the AVC curves. This analysis leads us
to extend the MR MC rule: The firm maximizes profit or minimizes loss
by producing the output where marginal revenue equals marginal cost.
182
C
CH
H EE C
CK
KP
PO
O II N
NT
T
EXHIBIT 6
183
120
MC
110
100
90
Price and 80
cost per
70
unit
(dollars) 60
ATC
Shutdown
point
50
AVC
40
MR
25
10
0
10 11 12
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
CAUSATION CHAIN
Firm will
shut down
If the price rises to $45, represented in the exhibit by MR2, the firm
breaks even and earns a normal profit at point B with an output of 7 units
per hour. As the marginal revenue curve rises, the firms supply curve is
traced by moving upward along its MC curve. At a price of $90, point C is
reached. Now MR3 intersects the MC curve at an output of 10 units per
hour, and the firm earns an economic profit. If the price rises higher than
$90, the firm will continue to increase the quantity supplied and increase its
maximum profit.
We can now define a perfectly competitive firms short-run supply curve.
The perfectly competitive firms short-run supply curve is its marginal cost
curve above the minimum point on its average variable cost curve.
Perfectly competitive
firms short-run supply
curve
The firms marginal cost curve
above the minimum point on its
average variable cost curve.
184
EXHIBIT 7
MC
120
110
Supply curve
100
90
Price and
80
cost per
70
unit
(dollars 60
per day)
MR 3
ATC
AVC
MR 2
45
A
30
MR1
20
10
0
5.5
9 10 11 12
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
Understanding that the firms short-run supply curve is the segment of its
MC curve above its AVC curve sets the stage for derivation of the perfectly
competitive industrys short-run supply curve. The perfectly competitive
industrys short-run supply curve is the horizontal summation of the marginal cost curves of all firms in the industry above the minimum point of
each firms average variable cost curve.
In Exhibit 7 in Chapter 3, we drew a market supply curve. Now we will
reconstruct this market, or industry, supply curve using more precision.
Although in perfect competition there are many firms, we suppose for simplicity that the industry has only two firms, Computech and Western Computer Co. Exhibit 8 illustrates the MC curves for these two firms. Each
firms MC curve is drawn for prices above the minimum point on the AVC
curve. At a price of $40, the quantity supplied by Computech is 7 units, and
the quantity supplied by Western Computer Co. is 11 units. Now we horizontally add these two quantities and obtain one point on the industry supply curve corresponding to a price of $40 and 18 units. Following this procedure for all prices, we generate the short-run industry supply curve.
Note that the industry supply curve derived above is based on the
assumption that input prices remain unchanged as output expands. In the
next section, we will learn how changes in input prices affect derivation of
the supply curve.
EXHIBIT 8
MC
Price
and
marginal
cost per
unit
(dollars)
185
S = MC
MC
90
90
90
40
40
40
7
11
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
11
15
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
18
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
26
Assuming input prices remain constant as output expands, the short-run supply curve for an industry is
derived by the horizontal summation of the quantities supplied at each price by all firms in the industry.
In this exhibit, we assume there are only two firms in an industry. At $40, Computech supplies 7 units of
output, and Western Computer Co. supplies 11 units. The quantity supplied by the industry is therefore
18 units. Other points forming the industry short-run supply curve are obtained similarly.
186
EXHIBIT 9
120
110
100
(b) Industry
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
E
Profit
MR
ATC
AVC
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
20
10
0
S = MC
120
MC
Price and cost per unit
(dollars)
10
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
20
40
60
80
100
120
Quantity of output
(thousands of units per hour)
Short-run equilibrium occurs at point E. The intersection of the industry supply and demand curves
shown in part (b) determines the price of $60 facing the firm shown in part (a). Given this equilibrium
price, the firm represented in part (a) establishes its profit-maximizing output at 9 units per hour and
earns an economic profit shown by the shaded area. Note in part (b) that the short-run industry supply
curve is the horizontal summation of the marginal cost curves of all individual firms above their minimum average variable cost points.
EXHIBIT 10
187
130
120
110
100
Price and 90
cost per 80
unit
70
(dollars)
60
50
SRMC
SRATC
LRAC
E
MR
40
30
20
10
0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
CAUSATION CHAIN
Entry and
exit of
firms
Zero long-run
economic
profit
Long-run
equilibrium
rule, the firm produces an equilibrium output of 6 units per hour. At this
output level, the firm earns a normal profit (zero economic profit) because
marginal revenue (price) equals the minimum point on both the short-run
average total cost (SRATC) curve and the long-run average cost (LRAC)
curve. Given the U-shaped LRAC curve, the firm is producing with the optimal factory size.
With SRMC representing short-run marginal cost, the conditions for longrun perfectly competitive equilibrium can also be expressed as an equality:
P MR SRMC SRATC LRAC
As long as none of the variables in the above formula changes, there is no reason for a perfectly competitive firm to change its output level, factory size, or
any aspect of its operation. Everything is just right! Because the typical firm is
in a state of equilibrium, the industry is also at rest. Under long-run equilibrium conditions, there are neither positive economic profits to attract new
firms to enter the industry nor negative economic profits to force existing
firms to leave. In long-run equilibrium, maximum efficiency is achieved. The
188
C
CH
H EE C
CK
KP
PO
O II N
NT
T
Constant-Cost Industry
Constant-cost industry
An industry in which the expansion of industry output by the
entry of new firms has no effect
on the individual firms cost curve.
EXHIBIT 11
189
120
110
100
90
80
70
(b) Industry
SRATC
SRMC
LRAC
MR2
E
MR1
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
S1
120
110
100
90
80
70
E2
E1
E3
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
S2
Long-run
supply curve
D2
D1
20
40 50 60
80 90 100
120
Quantity of output
(thousands of units per hour)
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
CAUSATION CHAIN
Increase in
demand sets
a higher
equilibrium price
Entry of new
firms
increases
supply
Initial
equilibrium
price is
restored
Perfectly
elastic longrun supply
curve
Part (b) shows an industry in equilibrium at point E1, producing 50,000 units per hour and selling them
for $60 per unit. In part (a), the firm is in equilibrium, producing 6 units per hour and earning a normal
profit. Then industry demand increases from D1 to D2, and the equilibrium price rises to $80. Industry
output rises temporarily to 70,000 units per hour and the individual firm increases output to 7 units per
hour. Firms are now earning an economic profit, which attracts new firms into the industry. In the long
run, the entry of these firms causes the short-run supply curve to shift rightward from S1 to S2, the price is
reestablished at $60, and a new industry equilibrium point, E3, is established. At E3, industry output rises
to 90,000 units per hour, and the firms output returns to 6 units per hour. Now the typical firm earns a
normal profit, and new firms stop entering the industry. Connecting point E1 to point E3 generates the
long-run supply curve.
190
Decreasing-Cost Industry
Decreasing-cost industry
An industry in which the expansion of industry output by the
entry of new firms decreases the
individual firms cost curve (cost
curve shifts downward).
Input prices fall as new firms enter a decreasing-cost industry, and output
expands. A decreasing-cost industry is an industry in which the expansion
of industry output by the entry of new firms decreases each individual firms
cost curve (cost curve shifts downward). For example, as production of electronic components expands, the price of computer chips may decline. The
reason is that greater sales volume allows the suppliers to achieve economies of scale and lower their input prices to firms in the electronic component industry. Exhibit 12 illustrates the adjustment process of an increase
in demand based on the assumption that our example is a decreasing-cost
industry.
Conclusion The long-run supply curve in a perfectly competitive
decreasing-cost industry is downward sloping.
Increasing-Cost Industry
Increasing-cost industry
An industry in which the expansion of industry output by the
entry of new firms increases the
individual firms cost curve (cost
curve shifts upward).
Firms in increasing-cost
industries, such as housing construction, in the
long run encounter increased costs
as output expands. To learn more
about the economics of housing
construction, visit the National
Association of Home Builders
(NAHB) (http://www.nahb.com/).
In an increasing-cost industry, input prices rise as new firms enter the industry, and output expands. As this type of industry uses more labor and
machines, the demand for greater quantities of these inputs drives up input
prices. An increasing-cost industry is an industry in which the expansion of
industry output by the entry of new firms increases the individual firms cost
curve (cost curve shifts upward). Suppose the electronic component disc
business uses a significant proportion of all electrical engineers in the country. In this case, electrical engineering salaries will rise as firms hire more
electrical engineers to expand industry output. In practice, most industries
are increasing-cost industries, and, therefore, the long-run supply curve is
upward sloping.
Exhibit 13 shows what happens in an increasing-cost industry when an
increase in demand causes output to expand. In part (b), the industry is initially in equilibrium at point E1. As in the previous case, the demand curve
shifts rightward from D1 to D2, establishing a new short-run equilibrium at
E2. This movement upward along short-run industry supply curve S1 raises
the price in the short run from $60 to $80, resulting in profit for the typical
firm. Once again, new firms enter the industry, and the short-run supply
curve shifts rightward from S1 to S2. Part (a) of Exhibit 13 shows that the
EXHIBIT 12
191
120
110
100
(b) Industry
SRATC2
90
80
MR2
70
MR1
MR3
60
50
40
30
S2
110
100
20
10
0
S1
120
SRATC1
Price and cost per unit
(dollars)
E2
90
80
70
E1
E3
60
50
40
30
20
D2
10
0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Longrun
supply
curve
D1
20
40 50 60
80
100
120
Quantity of output
(thousands of units per hour)
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
CAUSATION CHAIN
Increase in
demand sets
a higher
equilibrium price
Entry of new
firms
increases
supply
Equilibrium
price and
ATC
decrease
Downwardsloping
long-run
supply curve
The long-run supply curve for a decreasing-cost industry is downward sloping. The increase in industry
demand shown in part (b) causes the price to rise to $80 in the short run. Temporarily, the individual firm
illustrated in part (a) earns an economic profit. Higher profits attract new firms, and supply increases. As
the industry expands, the average total cost curve for the firm shifts lower, and the firm reestablishes longrun equilibrium at the lower price of $50.
response of the firms SRATC curve to the industrys expansion differs from
the constant-cost industry case. In an increasing-cost industry, the firms
SRATC curve shifts upward from SRATC1 to SRATC2, corresponding to
the new short-run equilibrium at point E3. At this final equilibrium point,
the price of $70 is higher than the initial price of $60. Normal profits are reestablished because profits are squeezed from both the price fall and the rise
in the SRATC curve.
The long-run industry supply curve is drawn by connecting the two
long-run equilibrium points of E1 and E3. Equilibrium point E2 is not a
long-run equilibrium point because it is not established after the entry of
new firms has restored normal profits.
192
EXHIBIT 13
(b) Industry
SRATC1
90
80
MR2
MR3
70
MR1
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
SRATC2
120
110
100
S1
120
110
100
90
80
70
S2
Long-run
supply
curve
E2
E3
E1
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
D2
D1
20
40 50 60
80
100
120
Quantity of output
(thousands of units per hour)
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
CAUSATION CHAIN
Increase in
demand sets
a higher
equilibrium price
Entry of new
firms
increases
supply
Equilibrium
price and
ATC
increase
Upwardsloping
long-run
supply curve
This pair of graphs derives the long-run supply curve based on the assumption that input prices rise as
industry output expands. Part (b) shows that an increase in demand from D1 to D2 causes the price to
increase in the short run from $60 to $80. The individual firm represented in part (a) earns an economic
profit, and new firms enter the industry, causing an increase in industry supply from S1 to S2. As output
expands, input prices rise and push up the firms short-run average total cost curve from SRATC1, to
SRATC2. As a result, a new long-run equilibrium price is established at $70, which is above the initial
equilibrium price. The long-run supply curve for an increasing-cost industry is upward sloping.
Y
YO
OU
U R
R EE T
TH
H EE EE C
CO
ON
NO
OM
M II SS T
T
At $3.50 a pound
for the meat and
$45 a foot for the
hide, an alligator
is worth perhaps
$100 a foot. After
paying for skinning
and processing,
neither hunter nor
landowner gets
rich.3
A 2000 article
in the Dallas Morning News provides
further evidence:
Mark Glass began
raising gators in
1995 south of Atlanta. He stated I can honestly say I
havent made any money yet, but I hope thats about to
change.4
ANALYZE
THE
ISSUE
1. Draw short-run firm and industry competitive equilibriums for a perfectly competitive gator-farming industry before the number of alligator farms in Florida
doubled. For simplicity, assume the gator farm is earning zero economic profit. Now show the short-run
effect of an increase in demand for alligators.
2. Assuming gator farming is perfectly competitive,
explain the long-run competitive equilibrium condition
for the typical gator farmer and the industry as a
whole.
194
KEY CONCEPTS
Perfectly competitive industrys
long-run supply curve
Constant-cost industry
Decreasing-cost industry
Increasing-cost industry
Market structure
Perfect competition
Price taker
Marginal revenue
SUMMARY
Market structure consists of three market characteristics: (1) the number of sellers, (2) the nature of the
product, and (3) the ease of entry into or exit from
the market.
A price-taker firm in perfect competition faces a perfectly elastic demand curve. It can sell all it wishes at
the market-determined price, but it will sell nothing
above the given market price. This is because so many
competitive firms are willing to sell the same product
at the going market price.
120
MC
100
Price and 80
cost per
70
unit
(dollars) 60
MR = MC
MR
Profit
= $205
ATC
AVC
40
800
Total
revenue
700
20
Total
cost
600
Maximum
profit = $205
200
100
Loss
0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
Total
500
revenue
and
400
total
cost
(dollars) 300
Maximum
profit output
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
130
120
110
100
Price and 90
cost per 80
unit
70
(dollars)
60
50
MC
110
Supply curve
100
90
Price and
80
cost per
70
unit
(dollars 60
per day)
ATC
45
SRMC
SRATC
LRAC
E
MR
40
30
20
10
MR 3
AVC
MR 2
120
195
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
A
30
MR1
20
10
0
5.5
9 10 11 12
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
Perfect competition requires that resources be completely mobile to freely enter or exit a market.
196
In perfect competition, if the price is below the minimum point on the AVC curve, each unit produced
would not cover the variable cost per unit. Therefore,
the firm shuts down.
Output
(Q)
Total
fixed
cost
(TFC)
Total
variable
cost
(TVC)
Total
cost
(TC)
Total
revenue
(TR)
Profit
$100
$120
$____
$____
$____
100
200
____
____
____
100
290
____
____
____
100
430
____
____
____
100
590
____
____
____
Price per
unit
(dollars)
MR2
MR1
Quantity of output
(units per hour)
197
ONLINE EXERCISES
Exercise 1
Exercise 3
Exercise 2
CHECKPOINT ANSWERS
Should Motels Offer Rooms at the
Beach for Only $50 a Night?
As long as price exceeds average variable cost, the motel is
better off operating than shutting down. Since $50 is more
than enough to cover the guest-related variable costs of
$45 per room, the firm will operate. The $5 remaining
after covering variable costs can be put toward the $50 of
fixed costs. Were the motel to shut down, it could make
no contribution to these overhead costs. If you said the
Myrtle Beach motels should operate during the winter
because they can get a price that exceeds their average
variable cost, YOU ARE CORRECT.
198
PRACTICE QUIZ
For a visual explanation of the correct answers, visit the
tutorial at http://tucker.swcollege.com.
1. A perfectly competitive market is not characterized by
a. many small firms.
b. a great variety of different products.
c. free entry into and exit from the market.
d. any of the above.
2. Which of the following is a characteristic of perfect
competition?
a. Entry barriers
b. Homogeneous products
c. Expenditures on advertising
d. Quality of service
3. Which of the following are the same at all levels of
output under perfect competition?
a. Marginal cost and marginal revenue
b. Price and marginal revenue
c. Price and marginal cost
d. All of the above
4. If a perfectly competitive firm sells 100 units of
output at a market price of $100 per unit, its
marginal revenue per unit is
a. $1.
b. $100.
c. more than $1, but less than $100.
d. less than $100.
5. Short-run profit maximization for a perfectly competitive firm occurs where the firms marginal cost equals
a. average total cost.
b. average variable cost.
c. marginal revenue.
d. all of the above.
6. A perfectly competitive firm sells its output for $100
per unit, and the minimum average variable cost is
$150 per unit. The firm should
a. increase output.
b. decrease output, but not shut down.
c. maintain its current rate of output.
d. shut down.
7. A perfectly competitive firms supply curve follows the
upward sloping segment of its marginal cost curve
above the
a. average total cost curve.
b. average variable cost curve.
c. average fixed cost curve.
d. average price curve.
MC
20
Price and
cost per
unit
(dollars)
15
ATC
10
AVC
B
A
0
500
1,000
1,500
2,000
2,500
Quantity of output
(units per week)
199
16. Suppose that, in the long run, the price of feature films
rises as the movie production industry expands. We
can conclude that movie production is a(an)
a. increasing-cost industry.
b. constant-cost industry.
c. decreasing-cost industry.
d. marginal-cost industry.
17. Which of the following is true of a perfectly competitive market?
a. If economic profits are earned, then the price
will fall over time.
b. In long-run equilibrium, P MR SRMC
SRATC LRAC.
c. A constant-cost industry exists when the entry of
new firms has no effect on their cost curves.
d. All of the above are true.