Economic Externalities
Economic Externalities
David A. Starrett
Economic Externalities
by David A. Starrett
The concept of externality has played a central role in the economic theory of resource
allocation. The idea behind the concept is simple to state: An externality exists when the actions
of a specified group of economic agents have significant economic repercussions on agents
outside the group. However, there are considerable difficulties in making this concept precise,
mostly having to do with the operational meaning of significant. To illustrate the difficulty,
note that virtually every economic action you take has some impact on some other agent. If I
buy an orange, the seller has more money and less oranges, and there are similar repercussions
for every market transaction. Yet these situations are not ones that any economist would identify
as externality producing. To qualify as externality, there must be an involuntary element in the
repercussions and an associated distortion in economic incentives. Clearly, this extra
requirement eliminates market transactions for which participation is strictly voluntary.
However, what is left is still somewhat amorphous and we find it important to define externality
precisely as an analytic concept.
Many definitions have been suggested for this concept but it is difficult to give a precise
one that covers adequately all of the various examples that have emerged in applications.
Indeed, here we find it necessary to divide the concept into at least two subcategories with
separate definitions: Direct Externalities and Indirect Externalities. We will discuss these
categories separately though later we will see that the line between them is not always distinct.
I Direct Externalities
We will say that a direct externality exists whenever a choice variable of one agent (or
decision-making group) enters into the direct objective function of some other agent(s). Clearly,
when there is an externality in this sense, the associated choice made will have involuntary
impacts on the affected agent(s). This definition encompasses many of the best known examples.
In the case of air pollution, the smoke put into the air by a factory helps to determine ambient air
quality, a variable that enters into the utility functions of resident consumers. In the case of road
congestion, one drivers decision to enter a crowded highway affects average traffic speed which
in turn affects the utility of other users. The externality of the commons also fits within this
definition. When many ranchers graze their cattle on a piece of open land, the decision by one
rancher to add to his herd will lower the amount of forage available to others, which in turn
lowers the productivity (and hence profits) of other ranchers. We discuss first this class of
externality and its implications for economic allocation. Later we will argue that the concept
needs to be generalized somewhat to include other situations that generate similar outcome
characteristics.
1. Externalities and inefficiency
M RS
h
ac
U
U
h
h
/ a
U
/ c
U
i
i
/ a
M RS
/ c
i
ac
(Here, agent h has a lower tolerance for garbage than agent i.) The outcome is inefficient since
agent i can give some amounts of both consumption and garbage to agent h in such a way as to
make them both better off.
But now suppose that society establishes and enforces a property right whereby I cannot
dump on you without your permission. Then, persons with isolated sites have incentives to offer
dumping services for compensation from those with comparatively high disutility. Indeed, if
agent i is able to set the terms of an arrangement with agent h, she will collect the first unit of
garbage for a fee equal to MRSach and enjoy the full surplus: MRSach - MRSaci. More generally,
both parties are winners as long as the price is set between their relative disutilities, so economic
efficiency is improved. Further, we would expect such trades to continue until all differences in
tolerance are eliminated (thus establishing a common collection price). As long as none of the
parties involved have enough power to influence the market clearing price, the outcome will be
an efficient allocation of garbage. Letting Pg represent this price, agent h will choose her net
consumption vectors to
Max Uh(cgh, ch), subject to p ch + Pg cgh = 0.
U /
dr d
d
l(s)
/
d s d s .
ds
Presumably, we can observe the residential density [l(s)] and the rent gradient [r(s)] from market
data. Thus, assuming the air quality and transport cost gradients can be identified from
engineering and environmental studies, we can measure the marginal value of air quality.