14.581 MIT International Trade - Lecture 1: Gains From Trade and The Law of Comparative Advantage (Theory)
14.581 MIT International Trade - Lecture 1: Gains From Trade and The Law of Comparative Advantage (Theory)
Spring 2011
Todays Plan
Course logistics
Todays Plan
Course logistics
Course Logistics
Course Logistics
Recitations: TBA
No required textbooks, but we will frequently use:
Avinash Dixit and Victor Norman, (DN)
Robert Feenstra, Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence
(F)
Elhanan Helpman and Paul Krugman, Market Structure and Foreign
Trade (HKa)
Course Logistics
Course requirements:
Four problem sets: 50% of the course grade
One referee report: 15% of the course grade
One research proposal: 35% of the course grade
Course Logistics
Course outline:
1
General Model
Special Cases: Ricardo, Ricardo-Viner, Heckscher-Ohlin
Topics:
1
2
3
Under every topic we will have one lecture on the theory and then one
on the empirics; the goal is to learn as much as possible about each,
and about their interaction.
Todays Plan
Course logistics
Todays Plan
Course logistics
Central Issues:
How does the integration of good markets aect good prices?
How do changes in good prices, in turn, aect factor prices, factor
allocation, production, and welfare?
Many of these assumptions look very strong, but they can be dealt
with by clever reinterpretations of the model:
Transport costs could be handled by interpreting one of the good as
transportation services.
Factor mobility could be dealt with by dening as a good anything that
can be traded.
Goods and factors can be distinguished by locations, time, and states
of nature.
Perfect competition
Constant returns to scale (CRS)
No distortions
Comments:
We could allow for decreasing returns to scale (DRS) by introducing
hidden factors in xed supply.
Increasing returns to scale (IRS) are a much more severe issue, which
was (partially) addressed by New trade theory.
Todays Plan
Course logistics
Not surprisingly, there are few results that can be derived using only
Assumptions 1-3.
In the next three classes, we will derive sharp predictions for special
cases of the neoclassical trade: Ricardo, Ricardo-Viner, and
Heckscher-Ohlin.
Today, well stick to the general case and show how simple revealed
preference arguments can be used to establish two important results:
1
Basic Environment
Supply
The revenue function
(1)
Demand
The expenditure function
(2)
pc a ,
= py a
r (p, v )
= e (p, u )
by
by
by
by
denition of e
market clearing under autarky
denition of r
equations (1), (2), and trade balance
ua
Comments:
Two inequalities in the previous proof correspond to consumption and
production gains from trade.
Previous inequalities are weak. Equality if kinks in IC or PPF.
Previous proposition only establishes that households always prefer
free trade to autarky. It does not say anything about the
comparisons of trade equilibria.
p a ) c ah
(w
w a )v h .
w a v h . Therefore
wv h + h .
: denition of h
: mc autarky
: zp autarky
: denition r (p, v )
: eq. (1) + zp free trade
Comments:
Good to know we dont need international lump-sum transfers.
Domestic lump-sum transfers remain informationally intensive (where
to nd data on c ah ?)
factor
= w
p
w
= good c ah factor v h
= (p a p ) c ah (w a w ) v h
0,
Comments:
Previous argument only relies on the existence of production gains from
trade.
If there is a kink in the PPF, we know that there arent any...
Similar problem with moving costs (see Feenstra p.185).
Factor taxation still informationally intensive: need to know
endowments per e ciency units, may lead to dierent business taxes.
Todays Plan
Course logistics
Let t n
y1n c nh , ..., yGn c nh denote net exports in country
n.
Let u an and u n denote the utility level of the representative household
in country n under autarky and free trade.
Let p an denote the vector of autarky prices in country n.
Without loss of generality, normalize prices such that:
pg = pgan = 1,
Notations:
cov (x, y )
var (x ) var (y )
n
cov (x, y ) = i =1 (xi x ) (yi
1 n
x =
xi
n i =1
cor (x, y ) =
y)
0.
r (p a , v n ) .
e (p a , u n ) .
r (p a , v n )
e (p a , u n ) .
(3)
e (p a , u na )
(4)
0.
r (p a , v n )
e (p a , u na ) = 0,
(p
pa ) t n
0.
cov (p
pga
p + pa
pa ) t n
G (p
tgn
tn ,
p a , t n ) = (p
pa ) t n .
p a , t n ) = (p
pa ) t n
0.
p a , t n )] = sign [cov (p
p a , t n )] .
Comments:
With 2 goods, each country exports the good in which it has a CA, but
with more goods, this is just a correlation.
Core of the proof is the observation that p a t n
0.
It directly derives from the fact that there are gains from trade. Since
free trade is better than autarky, the vector of consumptions must be
at most barely attainable under autarky (p a y n p a c n ).
For empirical purposes, problem is that we rarely observe autarky...
In future lectures we will look at models which relate p a to (observable)
primitives of the model: technology and factor endowments.