Impact of Globalization
Impact of Globalization
1. INTRODUCTION
In the last decade, global financial markets and intermediaries have faced
several costly and contagious financial crises. There have been abrupt declines
in asset prices (for example, global equity markets in 1987, real estate values
in the late 1980s and early 1990s, and global bond markets in 1994); major
bouts of volatility in the foreign exchange markets (for example, the European
exchange rate mechanism (ERM) crises in 1992-93, the dollar-yen market in
early 1995); an exchange rate crisis together with a debt crisis in the emerging
markets in early 1995; and a number of costly banking problems in several
industrial and some key emerging market countries. In addition, there has been
a string of serious, albeit nonsystemic problems in individual institutions
around the world (Barings, Bank of Credit and Commerce International,
Daiwa Bank, Metallgese Uschaft, Orange County, and Sumitomo
Corporation). Although many factors have contributed, including
macroeconomic policies and management control failures, these events appear
to have been a by-product of the transformation and restructuring of
international finance that has taken place during the last ten years, including
the increase in competition that accompanied the liberalisation of the financial
sector in most of the major industrial countries, and developing countries; the
integration of capital markets; the increasing dominance of institutional
investors; the development of new financial techniques and instruments,
particularly in the derivatives area; and the growth of the emerging markets.
1
Associate Professor of Finance, Department of Economics and Finance, University of New
Orleans.
72
73
Fourth, the world savings rates are smaller. Alongside the development of
more integrated capital markets, savings rates have declined in virtually every
major industrial country. According to official estimates, total national
savings, including households, businesses, and governments, declined from an
average of 23% of GDP for the major industrial countries for 1974-79 to
20.4% during the decade of the 1980s. The savings rate fell for every major
industrial country except West Germany, where it held roughly steady. One
important consequence of this decline has been a historically high cost of
capital.
Fifth, there exists a large role of government debt in national capital
markets. High real long-term interest rates, averaging 5% per annum or more
in most major industrial countries, are also a product of the continuing largescale borrowing requirements of many governments, the debt of which
dominates most domestic fixed-income markets.
In sum, while deregulation and globalisation of capital markets have
provided some benefits in terms of greater flexibility and efficiency, the
preservation of the safety and soundness of the financial system requires a
more forceful and internationally co-ordinated supervisory presence.
3. THE GLOBAL CAPITAL MARKET DURING 1870-1939 PERIOD
The 1870-1939 period was dominated by the London financial market as a
source of capital for other countries. Europes industrial revolution produced a
strong demand for food and raw materials, which could be satisfied only by
investment in many other parts of the world. Expansion of railroads and other
infrastructure was externally financed, and foreign investors were repaid later
from the resulting export earnings. Some of the countries where these
investments were made--such as Argentina, Australia, Canada, and the United
States--were able to buy imports of manufactures from the more industrialised
countries in Europe. Then, as now, this growing economic interdependence
was facilitated by international finance.
What was unique about the years 1870-1914 was the scale of international
finance. Over the period as a whole, Great Britain invested 3% of its GNP
abroad, reaching a peak of 10% just before World War 1. Its net receipts of
investment income from abroad were in the range of 5 to 8% of GNP,
implying that new foreign investment did not keep up fully with inflows of
interest and dividends. As a proportion of British savings, capital outflows
ranged between 25 and 40%. France and Germany also invested heavily
74
abroad, though not as much as Britain. By the late nineteenth century, French
and German gross capital exports were averaging 2 to 3% of GNP.
The nature of the capital flows varied considerably in 1870-1914. The
largest single group included the market-oriented investments, largely
undertaken by Britain, in the resource-rich countries of North America, Latin
America, and Oceania. In 1914, these accounted for 70% of Britains total
foreign investments and more than half of all gross foreign assets. A second
group, accounting for a quarter of all foreign investment, involved investments
in Russia and other Eastern European countries and in Scandinavia; France
and Germany were the principal investors. A third group covered the primarily
politically motivated investments in China, Egypt, India, Turkey, and some
African colonies. These three groups received capital at different times, so
new regions were financially linked with the world economy only gradually.
For the large debtors in the nineteenth century, capital inflows had only a
small weight in their economies. For most decades, capital inflows to the
United States were around 1% of its GNP and never exceeded 6% of its
domestic investment. For the smaller debtors, however, capital inflows as a
proportion of GNP were higher than they are for many developing countries
today. Capital inflows to Canada averaged 7.5% of its GNP, accounting for
between 30% and 50% of annual investment from 1870 to 1910. Ratios were
similar in Australia and the Scandinavian countries. The most striking case
was that of Argentina, where capital inflows annually ranged between 12 and
15% of GNP and financed about 40% of its total investment during the first
two decades of the twentieth century. By contrast, net capital inflows to all
developing countries averaged 2 to 3% of GDP between 1960 and 1973. Since
1973 they have not exceeded 6% of GDP and have financed between 12 and
20% of gross investment.
Differences do not stop with geography and the relative volume of external
finance. In the years 1870-1914, almost all lending came from private sources,
in the form of stock and bond issues. Lending terms were long: maturities of
up to ninety-nine years were not uncommon. Nearly two-thirds of foreign
capital went to finance investment in railroads and utilities.
A large proportion of the flows went to the then relatively high-income
countries; North America, Latin America, and Australia received more than
half of the total. The international capital market in the nineteenth century did
not, and was not designed to, provide poorer countries with access to capital.
For example, even India- though favoured in British capital markets--received
very little investment. Capital was drawn to investments that yielded higher
75
76
77
78
79
stayed there for many years. During the 1950s, this aroused little concern. It
was a commonly held view that there was a dollar shortage and that such
deficits were appropriate for the leading international creditor.
Europes balance of payments improved considerably in 1958, boosting its
foreign reserves. At the end of that year, most European governments declared
their currencies convertible (Japan did the same only in 1964). Capital markets
in Europe and the United States started to integrate, with private capital flows
becoming responsive to movements in interest rates. In the late 1950s,
European banks, notably in London and Switzerland, began to deal in dollars.
This marked the inception of what came to be known as Eurocurrency markets.
The decade had begun with official capital flows contributing to economic
growth and trade expansion; it ended with a growing volume of private capital
flowing between industrial economies.
The post-war years also saw the progressive decolonisation of the
developing countries. The United States and later other industrial countries
began their formal programs of foreign aid. In the early 1950s, the World Bank
shifted its focus from reconstruction to development, though it continued
lending to industrial countries, including Japan, during the 1950s and 1960s. In
1956 the International Finance Corporation (IFC) was created to assist the
private sector in developing countries through loans and equity investments. In
1960 governments formed the International Development Association (IDA) to
provide a multilateral source of concessional finance for low-income
countries. These years also saw the establishment of several regional
development banks, including the Inter-American Development Bank (1959),
the African Development Bank (1964), and the Asian Development Bank
(1966).
For most of the 1960s, the world economy enjoyed a period of largely
untroubled progress. Industrial economies grew by an average of 5% a year,
with little year-to-year variability in growth rates. World trade grew even
faster, at an average of 8.4% a year, helped by the progressive trade
liberalisation policies pursued under the GATT. Inflation rates in industrial
economies as a group varied between 2 and 4% a year, though individual
countries had bouts of more rapid price increases. Nominal interest rates
adjusted for inflation (that is, real interest rates) were usually in the 2 to 3%
range.
Developing countries benefited from these international conditions. As a
group, their output increased by over 5% a year. Some developing countries
grew much faster than others, accentuating the differences in average incomes.
80
Current account deficits were financed chiefly by official flows (loans and
grants), by private direct investment, and by trade finance. Official aid grew by
about 3% a year in real terms in 1950-65. Direct foreign investment also
increased rapidly, as multinational corporations sought new supplies of raw
materials in developing countries. Export credits revived as a source of finance
for developing countries--a mixed blessing, as their relatively short maturities
contributed to debt-servicing problems for many countries.
Several developing countries ran into debt difficulties in the 1950s and
1960s. Between 1956 and 1970, there were seventeen debt reschedulings
involving seven countries (Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Ghana, Indonesia, Peru,
and Turkey), each of them more than once. The reasons for their difficulties
varied. Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Peru, and Turkey shared certain problems:
large budget deficits; rapid inflation and delayed adjustments of the exchange
rate; deteriorating terms of trade; declining export earnings; the accumulation
of short-term external debt. Ghana and Indonesia also had these problems-though more acutely, because they launched large, long-term projects that they
financed with short-term credits and executed inefficiently. In a number of
other cases, including India, debt rescheduling was used to provide increased
capital flows to low-income countries when concessional flows from industrial
economies were constrained.
Creditors rescheduled their loans through ad hoc multilateral groups, such
as the Paris Club. The International Monetary Fund was also involved in
providing extra finance to support policy reforms. In general, creditors did not
incur capital losses; they extended maturities and received interest on
schedule. Borrowers undertook policy reforms designed to bring their balance
of payments into better equilibrium and to establish the basis for economic
growth.
Although the 1960s saw a rapid expansion of world output and trade, some
international monetary problems started to emerge. The United States made
efforts to control capital outflows. Many countries experienced difficulty in
maintaining their exchange rates, notably Britain in the mid-1960s and France
a few years later. The need for reform of the international monetary system
was formally recognised as early as 1963.
By the end of the 1960s, the rate of growth of industrial economies had
begun to slow and inflationary pressures to build up. Continued deficits in the
US balance of payments found their counterpart in surpluses in Europe and
Japan. The dollars exchange rate started to come under pressure. In August
1971, the United States temporarily suspended the convertibility of the dollar
81
82
83
84
system with the admission of the republics that were in the USSR. There are
also enormous needs in Eastern Europe.
Lastly, the start of the post-World War II era was associated with fixed
exchange rates. Although there have been some recent proposals to go back to
fixed exchange rates--or narrow exchange rate bands--the 1990s have been an
era of flexible or floating exchange rates. However, this does not mean that
governments in this decade are willing to take a hands-off view toward
exchange rates. Governments frequently still become involved in supply and
demand management when dealing with exchange rates. Thus, it may be more
accurate to call the 1990s a period of dirty or managed floats than a period
of perfectly free exchange rates. Also, at the start of the post-World War II era,
national regulators were able, for the most part, to cope with the international
side of financial markets. Currently, national regulators are often unable to
cope with this aspect of financial markets.
A key goal of the IMF should be to redefine a credible role for itself in the
management of the international monetary system. While the Fund has proved
to be an effective agent in promoting financial stability and reform in the
developing world, it has yet to be drawn into the policymaking councils of the
industrialised governments. That role is of far greater importance from the
standpoint of the international economy than the quite valuable role that the
Fund has played in promoting a sound financial environment in the developing
world. Also, the Fund is clearly the preferred instrument in promoting the
transition to market economies in the former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe.
Again, however, in terms of the world economy, that role is dwarfed by the
contribution the IMF could make to future economic prosperity and global
growth by bringing about better co-ordination of the monetary and financial
policies of the industrialised countries. The Fund needs to make sure that
monetary and exchange rate policies are conducive to economic growth rather
than the reverse.
In general, a major economic initiative is undertaken only when political
leaders are deeply convinced that the time is right for a change and when key
political constituents appear to be willing to support that shift. The 1990s
probably will see marginal reforms of the international economic system and
not the wholesale and sweeping reforms that took place after World War II.
6. FINANCIAL SYSTEMS IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES
The evolution of financial systems in developing countries reflected their
diverse political and economic histories. Latin American and Mediterranean
85
86
links with the government and the ruling families and were able to seize the
initiative from foreign banks and emerge as the dominant group. After 1949
China built a monobanking system typical of centrally planned economies.
Indigenous bankers and moneylenders were able to meet the borrowing
needs of local traders and farmers by maintaining close personal contact with
them and acquiring intimate knowledge of their operations. Their services
were accessible but expensive. Informal financial institutions, such as rotating
savings and credit associations (ROSCAs), also emerged in most countries.
Indigenous bankers and informal financial institutions, however, could not
mobilise the resources required for industrialisation.
Throughout the nineteenth century, Latin American countries relied too
much on foreign capital. Argentina and a few other countries developed active
mortgage-bond markets and stock exchanges alongside thriving but fragile
banking sectors. Unfortunately, however, recurring financial crises
undermined attempts to develop the system adequately. Finance lagged behind
the regions achievements in infrastructure, agriculture, and mining. Instability
resulted from too much foreign borrowing; the overissue of currency;
imprudent domestic banking; speculation in commodity, securities, and foreign
exchange markets; excess capacity in industry and commerce; regional wars;
and internal political unrest. Many of these were to figure in the debt crisis of
the 1980s.
Latin American economies ran for long periods with inconvertible paper
money, high inflation, and depreciating exchange rates. Producers and
exporters of primary commodities welcomed this; they stood to benefit and
had a strong hold on government policies. Latin American countries
occasionally suspended the servicing of their external debt. Foreign lenders,
however, were usually lenient, probably because the region had immense
potential for profitable investment. Major international houses arranged socalled funding loans, such as the Brazilian loan of 1898, which had many
features in common with the multiyear rescheduling agreements of recent
years. In contrast, foreign lenders imposed strict controls on the finances of
many other countries, such as China, Egypt, Greece, and Turkey. Their
governments were forced to cede revenues from stamp and customs duties and
from state monopolies (on salt, matches, and tobacco) until the debts were
fully repaid.
World War I and the depression of the 1930s played havoc with the world
economy. Latin American countries were particularly affected by the
development of man-made raw materials and the transformation of the British
87
88
89
total. Africa, Asia and Middle East and Europe constituted roughly 30% (See
Table 4: Source: IMF).
There has been a lot of fluctuations in the volume of world trade between
1986 and 1996. The volume of world trade increased from 1986 to 1988,
decreased in 1990 and 1991, increased in 1992, decreased in 1993, increased
in 1994 and declined in 1995 and 1996. World trade prices of manufactures
have not followed a steady pattern as well. It increased in 1987, decreased in
1988 and 1989, increased in 1990, decreased in 1991, increased in 1992,
decreased in 1993, increased in 1994 and 1995 and decreased in 1996. Oil
prices dropped substantially by 117% from 1987 to 1988, increased
significantly by 205% in 1989, increased slightly in 1990, dropped in 1991,
increased in 1992, dropped in 1993, increased from 1994 to 1995 then dropped
in 1996. World trade prices for nonfuel primary commodities increased from
1986 to 1988, dropped from 1989 to 1990, increased in 1991 and 1992,
dropped in 1993, increased in 1994 and dropped in 1995 and 1996. Overall,
world trade volumes and prices have been very unstable between 1986 to 1996
(See Table 5: Source: IMF).
There has been a lot of fluctuations in the pattern of payment balances on
current account for industrial countries, developing countries and countries in
transition. For industrial countries, their payments balances increased by
10.67% from 1987 to 1988, declined by 47.7% in 1989 and further dropped by
21.2% in 1990. Thereafter, from 1991 to 1996, there was an upward trend with
a significant increase of 155.3% in 1993. While the payments balances on
current account of industrial countries have had an upward trend, the overall
payment balances of developing countries have steadily declined from 1987 to
1996 with significant increases only in 1989 and 1990. For countries in
transition, there has also been a downward trend in the pattern of payments
balances from 1987 to 1996 with a significant decrease of 197% in 1990.
Despite the fluctuations, the figures show that the total payments balances on
current account have been on a downward trend with a significant increase
only in 1993 which is probably due to the increase from the industrial
countries (See Table 6: Source: IMF).
We can divide the discussion of external financing situation of developing
countries according to their various criteria. In the predominant export
criterion, the total net external financing of fuel exports decreased by 35% in
1988, increased by 316% from 1988 to 1991, decreased by 11% in 1992,
increased by 27% in 1993, declined by 78% in 1994, further dropped by 42%
in 1995 and rose by 146% in 1996. Except for the fall in 1988, we could say
that there was an upward trend in the external financing of fuel export from
90
1987 to 1991. The trend from 1992 to 1996 has been mixed with increases and
decreases. For net external financing of nonfuel exports, there was a steady
increase from 1987 to 1993, and a downward trend thereafter.
According to financial criteria, for net creditor countries, the total net
external financing decreased substantially from 1986 to 1990 by 112%, it
increased in 1991 and 1992, declined in 1993 and 1994, and increased in 1995
and 1996. For net debtor countries, the net external financing increased
steadily from 1987 to 1993 by a total of 448%, declined by 34% in 1994 and
increased by 7% in 1996. For market borrowers, the net external financing
increased steadily from 1987 to 1993, declined in 1994 and 1995 and increased
slightly in 1996. For diversified borrowers, the net external financing
increased from 1987 to 1990, decreased in 1991, increased in 1992 and 1993,
decreased in 1994 and increased in 1995 and 1996. Overall, except for the
decreases in 1991 and 1994, the net external financing for diversified
borrowers has followed an upward trend from 1987 to 1996. For official
borrowers, the net external financing fluctuated between 1987 and 1996. There
was an upward trend from 1987 to 1989 with a total increase of 49%, a
decrease of 27% from 1989 to 1991, no change in 1991 and 1992, increase of
58% from 1992 and 1994, and a decline of 34% in 1994 and 1996. For
countries with recent debt-servicing difficulties, except for the decrease in
1989, the overall net external financing increased steadily from 1987 to 1993,
decreased in 1994 and 1995 and increased in 1996. For countries without debtservicing difficulties, the net external financing increased steadily from 1987
to 1993, declined in 1994 and 1995, and increased in 1996 (See Table 7:
Source: IMF).
Except for the decrease in 1988, the reserves of developing countries have
followed an upward trend from 1987 to 1996. The ratio of reserves to imports
of goods and services in developing countries remained between the range of
39.1 to 32.1 from 1987 to 1996. It decreased by 16% in 1988, experienced no
significant change from 1988 to 1989, increased by 3% in 1990. Although
there were fluctuations from 1991 to 1996, there was no change that exceeded
7% (See Table 8: Source: IMF).
The net credit and loans from the IMF to developing countries increased
steadily from 1987 to 1991 by a total of 123%, and decreased from 1991 to
1994 by a total of 173%. For countries in transition, the net credits and loans
from IMF increased steadily from 1987 to 1991 by 418% and declined
thereafter. The total decrease between 1992 and 1994 was 41%. Overall, it
could be said that the net credit and loans from the IMF to developing
91
countries and countries in transition had an upward trend from 1987 to 1991
and a downward trend from 1992 to 1994 (See Table 9: Source: IMF).
The amount of external debt of developing countries increased steadily
from 1987 to 1996. Although there were mild fluctuations in the external debt
of countries in transition, there was an overall upward trend from 1987 to
1996. Except for the mild decreases in 1989 and 1992, the amount of debtservice payments of developing countries increased steadily from 1987 to
1995. It declined slightly in 1996. For countries in transition, there were major
fluctuations in the amount of debt-service payments from 1987 to 1996. In
percent of exports of goods and services, the external debt of developing
countries had a downward trend from 1987 to 1996. For countries in transition,
except for the decrease in 1988, the overall external debt in percent of exports
of goods and services showed an upward trend from 1987 to 1994. It declined
in 1995 and 1996--although not substantially. Although there have been
fluctuations, the overall debt-service payments of developing countries in
terms of percent of exports of goods and services has had a downward trend
from 1987 to 1996. For countries in transition the trend has not been that
smooth. Although it maintained stability between 11.4 and 13.3%, there were
significant drops in 1990 and 1993 (See Table 10: Source: IMF).
The overall ratio of external Debt to GDP for developing countries has had
a downward trend from 1987 to 1996. Overall, the interest payments of
developing countries has decreased from 1987 to 1996. There were mild
increases in 1991, 1993 and 1995, but not significant. The amortisation
decreased from 1987 to 1989 and remained stable in 1990. Thereafter it
fluctuated (within a 20% range) (See Tables 11 and 12: Source: IMF).
The net capital inflows to developing countries and countries in Transition
increased in 1991, dropped in 1992, increased in 1993, dropped in 1994 and
increased again in 1995. The foreign direct investment plus portfolio
investment (net) increased steadily from 1990 to 1993, dropped in 1994 and
increased in 1995. The net foreign direct investment increased steadily from
1990 to 1995. The net portfolio investment increased from 1990 to 1993 and
dropped in 1994 and 1995. The total net capital inflows of all other short- and
long-term credits, loans, currency and deposits, etc., had major fluctuations
from 1990 to 1995. It increased from 1990 to 1991, dropped in 1992 and 1993,
increased in 1994 and 1995 (See Table 13: Source: IMF).
There have been fluctuations in the intraregional flows. They decreased by
13% in 1990, increased in 1991, and decreased in 1992. In 1993 it increased
substantially by 192% and continued with an upward trend to 1995. The trend
92
93
loans to corporations of high credit quality, but with risks that were equity-like
in virtually every one of those countries. Hence, it is simple logic that future
financial resource transfers must take the form of equity-related instruments,
and that means yields to permanent investors must be equity-like as well.
By process of elimination, the main untapped source of financing for the
developing countries and the emerging economies of Eastern Europe and the
former Soviet republics is the risk-taking equity investor. Realistically this
cannot be the retail investor who has little or no interest in investing anywhere
but at home. Therefore, it can only be the large institutional equity investor
from the industrial countries--corporate pension funds, other retirement funds,
investment companies and other specialised financial enterprises, and
insurance companies--which must be attracted to unconventional equity
investments. That will require time and fundamental change by those countries
which would like to see a sizeable transfusion of foreign capital to speed their
economic development and some important changes in the industrial world as
well.
First, there needs to be moderate economic recovery in the industrial
countries that are now in or near recession and continued moderate expansion
in the rest. Too rapid a rebound, rightly or wrongly, will incite inflationary
concerns; interest rates will be pushed up by financial markets; and the relative
attractiveness of foreign investment will diminish.
Second, there needs to be a pronounced change in the composition of
expenditures in many countries. Most importantly, military spending needs to
be de-emphasised globally. Reductions in military spending are required to
help achieve budgetary balance in the developed countries. The resources,
both human and physical, that are devoted to weaponry need to be made
available to the civilian sector, where they can help enterprises achieve higher
rates of return on capital.
Third, there needs to be a continuing process of rehabilitating the financial
health of deposit institutions. This includes regulatory reforms and capital
infusions into marginally capitalised banks. It also would be helpful to have a
continuation of a positively sloped yield curve, which provides opportunities
for banks to increase their earnings by taking modest interest rate risks, rather
than having to absorb additional credit risk.
Fourth, the developing countries have a lot of work to do in making the
transition to a market-based economy. This includes establishing a reliable
legal system, including a reasonable bankruptcy law, dependable and
94
95
96
The UKs success with its privatisation program has encouraged state selloffs elsewhere in the world. The increase in shares of privatised corporations
around the world has raised the liquidity of the global capital market and the
interest by investors in them. The deliberate underpricing of most issues has
helped the markets willingness to accept privatisation issues. Privatisation,
which involves international distribution, is intensifying the development of
the global market. The process includes a wide marketing effort to investment
institutions. Moreover, the trend towards privatisation is not restricted to the
major economies. Despite the collapse last year in the Mexican market, the
enthusiasm for privatisation issues from Latin America, Asia and Africa has
been undiminished, while investors long-term belief in these markets remains
intact. In 1994 governments from emerging markets raised a total of $17.6
billion, about $2 billion more than in 1993.
Privatisation has led to an increasing tendency for investors to look at the
world in terms of large global industries and to compare stock valuations
across markets. Privatisation has given the world markets large
telecommunications and electric utilities to trade in and compare, while
deregulation and the increase in world trade has put them, and other industries
such as steel, mining, pharmaceuticals and oil, into competition with each
other, in what were once their own protected markets. It is, therefore,
increasingly possible to compare Thyssen with British Steel or Roche with Eli
Lilly and view them as competing investment alternatives. This focus on
global industries is, of course, also making it easier for large multinational
companies to raise both debt and equity on stock markets across the world,
rather than concentrating on the market where their main listings lie.
In addition to the growth in the international equity markets, there has
been a significant expansion in the sources of international debt finance. For
example, total net issues of Euronotes and international bonds soared by 45%
between 1993 and 1994. Announcements of new Euro-securities surged to
$197.2 billion last year. Despite the rise in world interest rates in 1994,
announcements of international bond issues were still equal to $372 billion last
year.
The growth of financial derivative instruments has benefited global
markets by providing liquidity to institutional investors and facilitating
portfolio construction. A major shift between countries can be made cheaply
and quickly through the futures markets, without having to sell the underlying
securities.
97
98
Capital Requirements for market operators (brokers, banks, etc.) are being
stepped up in many countries. The norm is to use Bank of International
Settlement guidelines. This encourages major international investors. Listing
Qualifications increasingly seek to meet international criteria in terms of
financial history, share capital structure and liquidity, etc., though efforts have
been made to create simpler qualifications for small companies. Compliance
with new insider trading and market manipulation rules is being enforced.
Market operatives are being required to pass professional exams to ensure
compliance with best practices, and thereby helping to create universal
professional standards and greater transparency. Membership of exchanges is
increasingly being opened up to foreign participants.
The technological revolution, aided by information services such as
Reuters and Bloomberg, is rapidly improving the dissemination of financial
news and the exchange of information around the world. Other developments
in CD ROMs and interactive communications systems will also facilitate
international communications for financial services.
Screen-based trading systems are not only leading to the demise of
traditional trading floors, but also opening up the possibility of direct access to
markets from overseas locations. For example, a new electronic trading system
is being introduced on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange (CME) in 1996. The
Globex system has been developed in conjunction with Reuters. The CME has
heralded the advance of Globex as the benchmark for the industry, and has
made an effort to sign up other exchanges in a bid to turn Globex into an
industry-wide network. The LIFFE electronic system, APT, has so far been
used to extend the trading day on the London Futures Exchange. Although
only currently used for an hour and half a day, it is likely to be extended to
replace the floor system.
At the end of 1993, a new electronic trading system, Bridge, was
established between Cedel and Euroclear thereby eliminating a time delay
between the delivery of securities and payment for them. With the move to
electronic overnight processing, Cedel can settle trades with Euroclear on the
same day.
Such developments will clearly contribute to improving the access of
exchanges to investors around the world, as well as to providing global 24hour trading. They will also bring considerable savings in transaction costs as
well as improving processing speed and accuracy and market liquidity.
99
100
for financial instability; the lack of international rules of the road in key
areas; the inability of national regulators to keep pace with certain financial
innovations; the tendency of many institutions to take on high debt levels that
are not prudent; and the reality that international economic agencies
sometimes lack a clear mandate or mission. Added to these are the issues of
capital shortages and the plight of the Third World.
During periods of global economic stability, such as the 1950s and 1960s,
international finance has contributed significantly to economic growth. Within
the total flows of capital to developing countries, shifts from equity to debt
financing and from official to private sources were to be expected. As
developing economies grow and their structure change, their relations with the
world economy increasingly resemble those of the industrial countries. As
industry expands, as exports shift from primary to manufacturing products, as
the domestic financial system matures, so developing countries increase their
ability to exploit opportunities in international financial markets. However, the
flow of private external capital to developing countries did not increase
slowly, in line with their economic progress. It expanded suddenly in the
1970s and was accompanied by unprecedented imbalances in international
payments. The potential for using foreign capital to expand investment was
therefore limited by the immediate need to pay for dearer oil.
Emerging market countries have been prone to banking problems; the
problems have been costly, and they have the potential to spill across national
borders. Hence, the extension of international supervisory arrangements to
include emerging market countries is important not only to safeguard the
stability of the international financial system, but also to increase the
effectiveness of the surveillance over domestic banking institutions in
emerging markets. The growing internationalisation of the financial sectors in
emerging market countries--including increased access to offshore derivative
transactions for the purpose of blunting the impact of domestic financial
regulations--also implies that a supervisory approach with a national focus will
be inadequate. Furthermore, the extent to which the emerging market countries
will be integrated into the international financial system will depend largely on
their success in raising supervisory standards and the risk-management
capabilities of internationally active financial firms to international standards.
Closer integration of the supervisory authorities in emerging market
countries into a co-operative international arrangement for the supervision of
international banking markets would have at least five main benefits: it would
facilitate the surveillance over international banks on a consolidated basis a
necessary condition for the effective supervision of the banking sector; it
101
102
which they invest. But there will be a policy challenge to keep financial
regionalism from justifying a departure from the liberal, multilateral
environment for world trade that we all benefit from.
REFERENCES
Boote, Anthony R. and Others, Official Market Financing for Developing
Countries, World Economic and Financial Surveys, Washington, International
Monetary Fund, 1995.
Choudhury, Masudul Alam, The Nature of Globalisation and the Muslim
World, Managerial Finance, volume 22, no. 5/6 (1996), pp. 7-30.
Choudhury, Masudul Alam, Islamic Economic Cooperation, London,
MacMillan, and New York, St. Martins Press, 1989.
Claessens, Stijin and Sudarshan Gooptu, edited, Portfolio Investment in
Developing Countries, Washington, D.C., World Bank Discussion Papers, no.
228, 1993.
Dunaway, Steven and Others, Private Market Financing for Developing
Countries, World Economic and Financial Surveys, Washington D.C.,
International Monetary Fund, March 1995.
Folkerts-Landau, David, Takatoshi Ito and Others, International Capital
Markets: Developments, Prospects, and Policy Issues, World Economic and
Financial Surveys, Washington, International Monetary Fund, August 1995.
Eichengreen, Barry, Globalizing Capital: A History of International Monetary
System, Princeton University Press, N.J., USA, 1996.
International Finance Corporation (IFC), Emerging Stock Markets Factbook,
Washington, D.C., 1994, 1995, 1996.
International Monetary Fund, Private Market Financing for Developing
Countries, Washington, D.C., 1995.
International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, 1995, Washington,
D.C., 1996.
International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, 1996, Washington,
D.C., 1996.
103
104
105
106
107
108
109
110
111
112
113
114
115
116
117
118
119
120
121
122
123
124
125
126
127
128
129
130
131
132
133
134
135
136