100% found this document useful (1 vote)
68 views

Risk Return Summery

risk and return relationship

Uploaded by

Sanaullah Tariq
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as DOCX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
100% found this document useful (1 vote)
68 views

Risk Return Summery

risk and return relationship

Uploaded by

Sanaullah Tariq
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as DOCX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 85

http://people.duke.edu/~charvey/Classes/ba350_1997/diverse/diverse.

htm

WWWFinance

TM

Global Financial Management


Portfolio Analysis and Diversification
Copyright 1997 by Campbell R. Harvey and Stephen Gray. All rights reserved. No part of this lecture may be
reproduced without the permission of the authors.
Latest Revision: February 27, 1997

7.0 Overview
This class provides an overview of individual asset allocation. It is shown that an individual can
reduce the risk of his portfolio without sacrificing any expected return simply by spreading his
wealth over a number of assets in an appropriate way. This technique of diversification is
explained in some detail in terms of a simple two-asset example in order to build intuition.

7.1 Objectives
After completing this class, you should be able to:

Compute the expected return of a portfolio

Compute the variance and standard deviation of the return of a portfolio

Find the composition of the minimum-variance two-asset portfolio

Explain the concept of diversification

Explain how to construct a diversified portfolio in practice

Explain the concept of an efficient frontier

7.2 Introduction

So far in the course, we have not established any benchmarks to compare securities or portfolios
other than expected returns. It is impossible to judge the quality of an investment be simply
looking at its expected returns. For example, consider an advertisement from The Wall Street
Journal which followed the following performance comparison.

The Franklin
Dow Jones
Salomon's High
Cost of Living
Income Fund Industrial Average Grade Bond Index

516%

384%

283%

169%

These average returns over the past 15 years are higher than the Dow Jones Industrial Average
and Salomon's High Grade Bonds. Does this mean that we can beat the market by investing in
Franklin now? The answer is no. The advertisement tells us nothing about the risk of the
Franklin Fund. We will always want to consider risk as well as return. The Franklin Fund stocks
may be very risky and the only way people will hold the component stocks is to have a high
expected return. So we have go beyond returns and develop a model of risk that allows us to
compare stocks and portfolios.
There are many models of risk and expected return. Two popular models are: the Capital Asset
Pricing Model (CAPM) and the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT). We will spend most of our
time examining the Capital Asset Pricing Model. The CAPM was the first of the pricing models
[William Sharpe (1964)] and the most commonly used by practitioners.
The APT or multifactor CAPM (Stephen Ross) is examined in considerable detail in the elective
courses. I will briefly introduce these models after we have finished with the CAPM.

7.3 The Planning Problem


The Capital Asset Pricing Model is an equilibrium model. The prices that exist in the economy
are a result of all consumers maximizing utility and markets clearing, i.e., prices are set such that
supply equals demand. Our goal is to create (model) a simple economy with these ingredients
and see if the pricing function has power to predict actual prices in the economy. A simple
economy involves simple assumptions. After we derive the CAPM, you will note that many
assumptions have been made that are not very realistic. But caution should be taken in judging a
model by its assumptions. It is often better to judge a model by its ability to predict.
The consumers in our model are rational utility maximizers. The objective of each person is to
maximize expected utility of consumption today, plus the expected utility of wealth, E[U(W)],
(future consumption) tomorrow. Mathematically, the consumer chooses c0 consumption today.
Importantly, wi are the portfolio weights for the N assets we could invest in today.

We will also assume that


U' > 0 and U" < 0
These are conditions on the form of the utility function. The first derivative being greater than
zero means that you prefer more wealth to less wealth. This is a property that is not controversial.
The second derivative being negative means that you prefer more to less at a decreasing rate as
wealth gets larger. So you get more utility from a $10,000 increase in your wealth if your
previous wealth was $20,000 rather than $2,000,000.
The variables to be maximized are the control variables. The consumer will be choosing:
consumption today, c0, and investment proportions in N assets, wi. We will assume that one of
these assets, i = 0, is risk free. So the consumer will use his initial wealth for either consumption
today or investment in assets that pay off in the future. A constraint is necessary:

This just says that the sum of today's consumption plus investment in the N assets with price Pi,
cannot exceed initial wealth. This is often referred to as the budget constraint. Tomorrow's
wealth will be determined by the payoffs on the investment strategy. Because these payoffs or
returns are random (except for the risk free asset), tomorrow's wealth will also be random.

7.4 Risk Aversion


One of the foundational principles of microeconomics is that economic agents can be modeled as
risk averse utility maximizers. In Finance, we continue to employ this principle in determining
how investors will evaluate risky investment proposals. In particular we employ two key
assumptions:

Investors prefer more to less.

Investors are risk averse.

A standard utility function that exhibits these two traits is illustrated in Figure 1.

Figure 1

The fact that the utility function is upward sloping indicates that the investor prefers more to less,
no matter how wealthy he might become. The fact that the utility function is concave indicates
that the investor is risk averse, a principle that is illustrated further below.
The following table llustrates in more detail how a risk-averse investor who prefers more to less
may evaluate an investment proposal. In particular, we can define an individual to be risk averse
if he chooses not to undertake an investment that provides a 50/50 chance of an increase or
decrease in wealth of $x. For example, suppose that an investor is faced with a gamble whereby
he bets $100 on the toss of a coin. If it's heads he wins $200, if it's tails he gets nothing. This
gamble creates a 50/50 chance of increasing or decreasing his wealth by $100, so his expected
wealth is unchanged. However, if the investor is risk averse, he will actually pay to avoid being
subjected to this risk.
The bet can be summarized as:

Outcome

Probability

$x

50%

-$x

50%

The investor would be pleased if the outcome turns out to be x, which is illustrated by the
increase in utility on the graph U. However, the investor would be extremely displeased if the
outcome turns out to be -x. The decrease in his utility D when the outcome is -x is far greater

than the increase in his utility when the outcome is +x. This discussion illustrates that in general
a risk averse individual will never take a fair bet.

Example 7.5
Suppose that an investor with initial wealth W0 = 20.5 has the utility function

and is faced with the following investment proposal:

Outcome

Probability

4.5

50%

-4.5

50%

The investor's current utility is (20.5)0.5 = 4.53. If the investment succeeds, the outcome is
+4.5 and the increase in the investor's utility is
D = 4.53 - (20.5-4.5)0.5 = (4.53-4) = 0.53.
Since each outcome occurs with 50% probability, the expected utility of the investor after
undertaking the investment is:

However, the investor currently has utility of U(W0) = U(20.5) = 4.53. Hence, he is worse
off if he undertakes the investment and therefore will not accept it. This is illustrated in the
figure below.
This example illustrates the expected utility rule: If the expected utility E[U(W)] from
owning a proposed investment exceeds the current utility U(W0) without the investment,
then the investment should be undertaken. That is, if E[U(W)] > U(W0) then the investor

will undertake the investment.

Example 7.6
What if the gamble is not fair, so that the odds are stacked in the investor's favor (i.e., xu >
xd)? Whether an individual takes the gamble or not depends on his utility function, and on
his initial wealth.
First, suppose the individual has utility, U(W) = W0.5, initial wealth of 20, and is faced with
the following investment proposal:

Outcome

Probability

+15

50%

-10

50%

In this case, the investment proposal is better than a fair bet and whether an individual
takes it depends on his utility function. What is the expected utility after undertaking the
investment?

His current utility (without the investment) is:


U(W0) = U(20) = (20)0.5 = 4.47
Therefore, since E[U(W)] > U(W0), the investor should accept the investment proposal.

Example 7.7
Now suppose that the individual's utility function is logarithmic so that U(W) = ln W. What
is the expected utility after undertaking the investment?

His current utility (without the investment) is:

U(W0) = U(20) = ln(20) = 3.00


Therefore, since E[U(W)] < U(W0), the investor should not accept the investment proposal.
Finally, suppose that the investor still has log utility, but that his initial wealth is 100
(rather than 20). In this case, the expected utility after undertaking the investment is:

The investor's current utility (without the investment) is U(W0) = ln(100) = 4.60.
Therefore, since E[U(W)] > U(W0), the investor should accept the investment proposal.

This example indicates that different investors have different attitudes toward risk, which is
captured in the form of differently shaped utility functions. Moreover, a single individual, whose
utility function does not change can become more tolerant toward risk as his wealth increases.

7.8 Certainty Equivalent


The certainty equivalent C is the minimum amount of cash that an investor would accept in
exchange for all of his investments and his initial wealth. Having $C cash will make the investor
as well off as having his initial wealth and his investment portfolio. Therefore:
E[U(W)] = U(C)

Example 7.9
Suppose an investor, who has square root utility and initial wealth of $100,000, is deciding
whether or not to buy car insurance. The outcomes and associated probabilities, based on
the investor's driving record are:

Event

No Accident

Loss

Probability

pu = 95%

Accident

-50,000

pd = 5%

First, determine the investor's expected utility if he does not buy insurance:

Next, compute the certainty equivalent so that the investor is just as happy with $C cash as
with having $100,000 and taking the risk of the accident. That is, $C solves:

The investor originally had $100,000 (W0) plus the risk of an accident. If he had
$97,092.07 and was indemnified against the cost of an accident, he would be just as happy.
Therefore, he is prepared to pay $100,000 - 97,092.07 = $2,907.93 for car insurance.

General forms of risk averse, risk neutral and risk loving preference functions are shown below:

Figure 4

Figure 5

figure 6

Click here for a supplementary discussion on the Cost of Risk

7.10 Portfolio Selection


Portfolios of assets can be compared on the basis of their risk and return characteristics. In this
section we consider tools for analyzing portfolios. We need to know how to measure the risk and
return characteristics of a given portfolio of securities.

7.11 Two Asset Case


The expected return of a two asset portfolio is simply a weighted average of the expected returns
of each asset in the portfolio.

E[rp] = w1 E[r1] + (1-w1) E[r2]

(Eq 1)

where w1 and (1-w1) = w2 are the percentage of portfolio value invested in each asset.
From basic statistics we also know that the variance of two random variables is a function of the
variance of each variable and the covariance between the variables. This relationship directly
applies in calculating the variance of a two asset portfolio as follows:
(Eq 2)

7.12 The N Asset Case


For an N asset portfolio, the portfolio return is just the sum of the asset returns times the weights
each of the assets has in the portfolio. In matrix notation, this is just the product:
rp = w' r

(Eq 3)

w is a vector containing the respective weights of the N assets. That is, if we have $1 million to
invest and we place $100,000 in security i, then wi = 0.10. We define r as a vector containing the
returns of the N assets. This product can be calculated in Excel using the sumproduct function.
The weights must all sum to one. This means that all money must be allocated.
The portfolio expected return is just the expected asset returns times the weights each of the
assets has in the portfolio.
The portfolio expected return is just the sum of the expected asset returns times the weights each
of the assets has in the portfolio. If E is a vector containing the expected returns of the assets,
then the portfolio's expected return can also be defined in terms of matrix multiplication. In
Excel this operation can also be performed using the sumproduct function.
Ep = w' E
Note that the above formula expands to the formula above for the two asset case.
E(rp) = w1 E(r1) + (1-w1) E(r2)
The portfolio expected excess return is just the expected returns on the assets minus the risk free
return (say a one month Treasury bill) times the weights each of the assets has in the portfolio.
This value can also be expressed as a product of a (1 x N) matrix of weights with a (N x 1) matrix
of excess returns (or in Excel using the sumproduct function).
Xp = w'X

where X represents the expected excess returns on the various assets.


The variance of the portfolio return is a little more complicated when there are more than two
assets. It will still be a function of the weights, variances and covariances, but it is harder to
express as a simple formula. It can be expressed, easily, as a product of matrices:
(Eq 5)
where V is the variance-covariance matrix (variances along diagonal and covariances off the
diagonal). The linear algebra is shown below for the two asset case.

The matrix algebra for the N asset case can easily be implemented in Excel.
The covariance of two portfolio returns, each denoted by their own set of weights, say wa, wb can
also be found using matrix algebra. It is just:
Cova,b = wa' V wb

(Eq 6)

where V is the variance-covariance matrix (variances along diagonal and covariances off the
diagonal).
Recall the formula for correlation. The correlation of portfolios with returns a and b is just the
covariance divided by the product of the standard deviations.

7.13 Distributional Assumptions


Given an optimal choice for today's consumption, c0, the goal of a portfolio is to maximize the
utility (expected) of future consumption provided by wealth at t = 1. This is a hard problem.
Often we need to make a major assumption to simplify the problem. We will assume that asset
returns are jointly normally distributed. The normal distribution has the property that the
distribution can be completely described by two parameters: the mean and variance. The
multivariate normal can be completely described by the means, variances and the covariances
between the different assets.
Note the variances and the covariances of the risk free asset are zero.

A linear combination of normal random variables is normal. Therefore, wealth at t = 1 is


normally distributed. The entire probability distribution of wealth is described by a portfolio's
mean and variance. This all implies that a sufficient set of statistics to discriminate between
portfolios is the mean and variance. This greatly simplifies the portfolio selection problem.

7.14 Other Distributional Assumptions


While most of finance is set in a mean-variance framework (which lends itself to using the
normal distribution), there is some new work going on which tries to capture more general
distributions. Harvey and Siddique (1995) have cast the portfolio selection in terms of meanvariance-skewness. This idea originates with important work in the 1970s. Harvey and Siddique
make the means, variances and skewness dynamic processes which change with economic
conditions. This paper is discussed in Global Tactical Asset Allocation.

7.15 The Effect of Diversification


Now let's consider the effect of diversification. We will examine a portfolio of two assets. From
our formula for variance, we know:

Where

where

is the portfolio variance. For the two asset case:

is the covariance between assets 1 and 2.

We could also write this in terms of correlation:


(Eq 7)
where the sigmas denotes the standard deviation of assets 1 and 2.
For simplicity, assume in the following examples, that the variances of the two assets are equal,
or

and that the portfolio weights are identical, or w1 = w2 = 0.50.

Example 7.16

Perfect Positive Correlation

The first case of interest is that of perfect positive correlation. Using the formula:

This result demonstrates that the portfolio variance is the same as the variance for each
asset. So diversification does not reduce the portfolio variance in this case.

Example 7.17

No Correlation

The second case of interest is that of zero correlation. Again, plugging into the formula:

This result demonstrates that the portfolio variance is half of the variance of the individual
assets. So combining stocks that have less than perfect positive correlation is a strategy
that will reduce the variance of the returns on your portfolio. This is called diversification.

Example 7.18 Perfect Negative Correlation


If two assets could be found which have perfect negative correlation, then we combine
these assets to create a risk free portfolio:

These assets create a perfect hedge. This shows that diversification can be thought of as a
partial hedge of risks.

The following graphs tells the story. Suppose we randomly selected a stock and plotted its
standard deviation. Now we randomly draw another stock and plot the standard deviation of the
equally weighted portfolio. We continue the exercise. Just by randomly selecting stocks we can
decrease portfolio variance.

figure 7

Example 7.19
Suppose Assets 1 and 2 have expected returns and standard deviations as follows:

Security Expected Return Standard Deviation

20%

20%

10%

16%

Furthermore, suppose that the returns of the two securities are perfectly negatively
correlated with
.
What is the expected return and standard deviation of a portfolio with equal weights in
each security?
Here we use equation 1 to compute the expected return of the portfolio:
E[rp] = w1 E[r1]+(1-w1)E[r2]
and since the weight of each asset is w1 = w2 = 0.5, we find that

E[rp] = 0.5 (20%) + 0.5 (10%) = 15%


We use equation 7 to compute the variance of the returns of the portfolio:

Plugging in the values for our 50/50 portfolio yields


(0.52)(0.202) + (0.52)(0.162) + 2 (0.5)(0.5)(0.20)(0.16)(-1) = 0.0004
in which case the standard deviation of the returns of the portfolio is 0.02 = 2%.
Recall that Asset 2 has an expected return of 10% and a standard deviation of 16%. Clearly
this portfolio of equal weights in Asset 1 and Asset 2 is preferred to holding Asset 2 by
itself since the portfolio has an expected return of 15% and a standard deviation of 2%.

Example 7.20
Consider forming a portfolio with three assets.
The expected returns are E' = (0.25, 0.19, 0.12)
(Note: Vectors are usually written as a column. The mark after the E says to take the
transpose of the column, or, in other words, look at it as a row)
The variance-covariance matrix is V

Portfolio 1 weights are w' = (.3, .4, .3)


Portfolio 2 weights are w' = (.1, .6, .3)
1. Calculate the standard deviations for each asset's return.
2. Calculate the correlation between the asset's returns.
3. Calculate the portfolio variances.
4. Calculate the covariance between the portfolios.

Recall that the diagonal elements of the Variance/Covariance matrix contains the
variances. The standard deviations can be found by taking the square roots of those
variances.
(0.090)0.5 = 0.300
(0.100)0.5 = 0.316
(0.010)0.5 = 0.100

The correlation coefficient can be calculated using the following relationship:

The covariances can be found in the V matrix where the covariances between assets j and
k will be in row j, column k (and also in column j, row k).

Solving for the correlation coefficients:

Solving for the portfolio variances is easy, if you know how to multiply matrices using the
following formula:

While matrix multiplication is not difficult, it is also not required for this class. The two
asset case can be solved without matrix multiplication using the following formula:

Matrix multiplication can be performed in Excel using the mmult command. A sample
spreadsheet can be downloaded, and modified to solve this problem. The solution for the
first portfolio is:

The solution for the second portfolio is:

We can use equation 7

to find the covariance between these two portfolios. We could treat each of these portfolios
as a separate asset, and create a new portfolio using equal weights. The variance of the
new portfolio can be found, because it is just a portfolio of our three original assets. The
varainces of the two portfolios can be plugged in to the right hand side of the equation.
That leaves the covariance between the two portfolios as the only unknown. Solving for
that, we find that the covariance between the two portfolios is 0.029040

What is important here?


Much of what is done in this example is at a more advanced mathematical level than
is required for this class. The information is shown here for a few reasons.

Some students have the mathematical background, and seeing the multi-asset

case will help them understand the material better.

Some students will work in portfolio analysis, and will need to find these
values.

There is some insight that can be gained even by those who do not understand
the mathematics.

Instead of being scared off by the mathematics, the following should be taken away
from this example:

It isn't just the risk of the individual assets (variance/standard deviation)


which contribute to the risk of the portfolio, it is also the interaction of the
assets to each other (covariance). A portfolio of two assets which always
move in the same direction are riskier than two assets whose returns are less
dependent on each other.

It is also important to realize that there are solutions to these problems.

It is important to understand the formulas for the two asset case

7.21 Efficient Portfolios


Previously, we made the simplifying assumption that asset returns are multivariate normally
distributed. This assumption implies that individual asset returns are univariate normally
distributed. We make the assumption of normality because it greatly simplifies the portfolio
selection problem. The entire distribution of an individual stock's return can be described by two
parameters: the mean and the variance. We can figure out a portfolio's mean and variance by
examining the means, variances and covariances of the component securities. Most importantly,
we can compare different portfolios on the basis of mean and variance.
Our discussion of utility functions and risk aversion provided two conclusions. First, consumers
like more to less. In terms of a security or portfolio, consumers prefer more return to less return.
Second, consumers prefer less variance to more variance. Remember that the risk averse
consumer will always turn down a fair bet. In terms of a security or portfolio, the consumer will
prefer a portfolio with less variance to another higher variance portfolio with an equal expected
return.
These insights lead to two rules of portfolio selection.

Any investor who chooses to hold a portfolio with variance

will want the portfolio

that has the maximum mean possible among those portfolios that have variance
.

Similarly, any investor who chooses a portfolio with mean E[rp] will want the portfolio
with the minimum variance possible among those with mean E[rp].

A portfolio that satisfies these conditions is known as an efficient portfolio. A portfolio is


inefficient if there exists another portfolio with:

7.22 The Efficient Frontier


Build a two asset efficient frontier using a Java program.
Build a multiasset efficient frontier using a Java program.
We will now consider an example of the effects of diversification. Previously, we combined
securities and looked at the effect on the portfolio variance for different correlation coefficients
between the securities. We found that using equal weights in the two portfolios, a lower
correlation coefficient led to lower portfolio variance. In this example, we will look at a given
correlation and vary the portfolio weights to trace the effect on the portfolio variance.
The example comes from a classic article by Bodie and Rosansky, "Risk and Return in
Commodity Futures" which was published in the Financial Analysts Journal in 1980. We will
trace out the return and standard deviation of a portfolio of common stocks and futures. A
number of tables are presented.

Table 1 and Table 2 document the cumulative wealth relatives and the year by year rates
of return of five portfolios from 1949 to 1976.

Table 3 provides mean returns and standard deviations for these portfolio.

Table 4 gives the correlation matrix for the different returns.

Table 5 provides returns on selected common stock-commodity futures portfolios.

Example 7.23

We will be concerned with the common stocks and the commodity futures. Note that the
common stocks have a -24% correlation with the commodity futures. Previously, we
showed that combining two portfolios with a zero correlation reduced the variance of the
portfolio. This was referred to as diversification. The common stocks and futures have
negative correlation. This suggests that holding both in a portfolio will produce a portfolio
variance that is less than the variance of the individual components.
Let's calculate the portfolio means and standard deviations. The two formulas that are
relevant are:
E[rp] = w1 E[r1] + (1-w1) E[r2]
and

We are given that for Asset 1, the common stocks:

Also, Asset 2, the commodity futures:

We are also given the correlation coefficient and the variances can easily be calculated:

The next step is to calculate the portfolio mean and standard deviation for various weights.

Portfolio 1 (w1 = 1 w2 = 0)
The mean return is:
E[rp1] = 1 (13.05) + 0 (13.83) = 13.05%

The standard deviation is:

Portfolio 2 (w1 = 0.8 w2 = 0.2)


The mean return is:
E[rp2] = 0.8 (13.05) + 0.2 (13.83) = 13.21%
The standard deviation is:

Portfolio 3 (w1 = 0.6 w2 = 0.4)


The mean return is:
E[rp3] = 0.6 (13.05) + 0.4 (13.83) = 13.36%
The standard deviation is:

Portfolio 4 (w1 = 0.4 w2 = 0.6)


The mean return is:
E[rp4] = 0.4 (13.05) + 0.6 (13.83) = 13.52%
The standard deviation is:

Portfolio 5 (w1 = 0.2 w2 = 0.8)


The mean return is:
E[rp5] = 0.2 (13.05) + 0.8 (13.83) = 13.67%
The standard deviation is:

Portfolio 6 (w1 = 0 w2 = 1)
The mean return is:
E[rp3] = 0 (13.05) + 1 (13.83) = 13.83%
The standard deviation is:

These calculations verify the numbers presented in Table 5.


The following graph shows the risk and return.

Note that with the negative correlation between the assets, the amount invested in the
component securities has a large effect on the portfolio variance.

7.24 The Efficient Frontier with Different Levels of Correlation


The next item is to look at the effect of different levels of correlations on the portfolio variance.
Let's develop a better grasp of where these portfolios should lie in the mean-standard deviation
space. In order to do this, assume that there are only two securities, q (1) and s (2). The expected
return on the portfolio is:
E[rp] = w1 E[r1] + (1-w1) E[r2]
The standard deviation on the portfolio is:

Write this in terms of the correlation coefficient.

So now we can start to map out the frontier.

7.25 Perfect Positive Correlation

Consider a number of simple cases. First, if the correlation between the two securities is one,
then the standard deviation on the portfolio is:
(Eq 8)
because

This result has a simple geometric interpretation. If we plot the mean and standard deviation of
the two securities, then a straight line between the two securities represents the set of portfolios
available. The point q below represents the situation where w = 1 where as the point s represents
the situation where w = 0. Note that diversification when the correlation between the securities is
one is ineffective.

Figure 9: portfolio options (correlation = 1)

7.26 Perfect Negative Correlation


The second straightforward situation is when the correlation between the two securities is
negative one. The standard deviation of the portfolio is:

(Eq 9)
This immediately implies that we can drive the standard deviation of the portfolio to zero by
choosing the right weights. Setting the left-hand side equal to zero, we can solve for w:

This point corresponds to the point y on the diagram. The expected return of this portfolio will
be:

Figure 10: portfolio options (correlation = -1)

7.27 Correlation between -1 and +1


Finally, consider the case where the returns of the two assets are neither perfectly positively nor
perfectly negatively correlated. Without loss of generality, assume that Asset 2 has lower
variance than Asset 1, as depicted in Figures 11 and 12. In this case, two results are possible. If

there exists some portfolio of Assets 1 and 2 that has higher expected return and lower variance
than Asset 2. That is, in this case there are gains from diversification. The possible portfolios lie
on a parabola that has a turning point between Assets 1 and 2, as depicted in Figure 11.

Figure 11: Portfolio options with benefits from diversification


Alternatively, if

there does not exist any portfolio of Assets 1 and 2 that has higher expected return and lower
variance than Asset 2. That is, in this case there are no gains from diversification.
The possible portfolios lie on a parabola that has no turning point between Assets 1 and 2, as
depicted in Figure 12.

Figure 12: Portfolio options without benefits from diversification

7.28 Proof of claims


To prove these claims, we find the minimum variance portfolio and show that where

the minimum variance portfolio has lower variance and higher expected return than Asset
2. The minimum variance portfolio is found by solving:
(Eq 10)
which has the first order condition

Now the portfolio will have less risk than Asset 2 alone whenever

which was to be shown.

Now let's consider the weights w. There is no restriction on the sign of w. Therefore, a negative
w can be considered a short sale of security q. The dotted line extension of the lines in figure 13
represent short sales. Note that you can change the perfect positive correlation into negative
correlation with the short sale provision.

Figure 13
More realistically, the correlation between the securities will between positive one and negative
one. The curve on the diagram plots the possible portfolios with a correlation between zero and
one.
Notice that any part of the curve that has a positive slope must be concave. Consider the counter
example between u and v on the diagram. With a dashed line, I have drawn a convex segment. Is
this a possible frontier? It turns out that the answer is no. We can consider u and v as separate
portfolios of q and s. We know that the most extreme situation (farthest to the right) would be a
correlation of positive one between these two portfolios. Hence, it is impossible to have any
curve to the right of the straight line extreme case. So the frontier will be concave for all positive
slopes.
Now lets be more precise. We have defined the mean-variance frontier. After plotting all the
portfolio combinations, the points farthest the left are minimum variance. But consumers will
only care about a certain portion of the frontier -- the portion with a positive slope. The
negatively sloped part of the frontier implies a lower return for greater standard deviation. Our

investors will not buy that trade-off. The positively sloped portion is called the efficient frontier.
Portfolios on this frontier are referred to as mean--variance efficient. These portfolios maximize
the expected return on the portfolio for a given variance. So there are dual properties of efficient
portfolios:
No other portfolio with the same expected return has a lower standard deviation of return.
No other portfolio with the same standard deviation of return has a higher expected return
These properties are reflected in all the portfolios in the efficient frontier. The opportunity set for
investors follows. Because of our assumptions about investors, only the positively sloping
portion of the minimum variance curve is held. The solid line represents the efficient frontier.
Note that I have also included arrows representing the direction of the investors' preferences
(more return and less risk).

Figure 14

Figure 15

Example 7.29

Suppose Assets 1 and 2 have expected returns and standard deviations as follows:

Asset

Expected Return

Standars Deviation

20%

20%

10%

16%

Also assume that the returns of the two securities are perfectly negatively correlated
. What is the composition of the minimum variance portfolio and what is its
expected return and variance?
Here we use the result that if

and we set

then the portfolio variance is zero. In this case,


w1 = (16)/(20+16) = 0.44
which implies that 56% of the funds invested in the portfolio should be invested in Asset 2.
The expected return of this portfolio is given by equation 1
E[rp] = (0.44) 20 + (0.56) 10 = 14.44%
To check that the portfolio variance is indeed zero we use equation 7
= (0.44)2(20)2 + (0.56)2(16)2 + 2(0.44)(0.56)(-1)(20)(16) = 0

Example 7.30
Suppose that the correlation between the returns of the two assets from the previous

example is

What is the minimum variance portfolio that can be formed from assets 1 and 2 and what
is the expected return and standard deviation of the 50/50 portfolio?
Finding the minimum variance portfolio is straightforward -- since the two assets are
perfectly positively correlated, there are no gains from diversification and the minimum
variance portfolio will be the portfolio that puts all the weight on Asset 2 (which has the
lower variance) and zero weight on Asset 1. This portfolio amounts to holding Asset 2 by
itself and yields an expected return of 10% and has a standard deviation of 16%.
A portfolio of equal weights of Asset 1 and Asset 2 has expected return of
E[rp] = (0.5) 20 + (0.5) 10 = 15%
The variance of this portfolio is given by
(0.5)2(20)2 + (0.5)2(16)2 + 2 (0.5)(0.5)(1)(20)(16) = 324
so the standard deviation is 18%.

Example 7.31
Suppose that the correlation between the returns of the two assets from the previous
example is
What is the expected return and standard deviation of a portfolio with equal weights in
each security? And what is the composition of the minimum variance portfolio?
The expected return of the portfolio is given by:
E[rp] = (0.5) 20 + (0.5) 10 = 15%
The variance of the portfolio can be calculated as
(0.5)2(20)2 + (0.5)2(16)2 + 2(0.5)(0.5)(0.5)(20)(16) = 244
So, the standard deviation is 15.62%
Recall that Asset 2 has an expected return of 10% and a standard deviation of 16%. Clearly
this portfolio of equal weights in Asset 1 and Asset 2 is preferred to holding Asset 2 by
itself since the portfolio has an expected return of 15% and a standard deviation of

15.62%.
One way to find the minimum variance portfolio is to allow the weight to vary between 0
and 1 (from no investment in Asset 1 to all of our wealth in Asset 1) and examine the
resulting portfolio. The expected returns and standard deviation of rates of return are as
follows:

Weight
(Asset 1)

Weight
(Asset 2)

Exptected
Return

Standard
Deviation

0.00

1.00

10.00

16.00

0.10

0.90

11.00

15.50

0.20

0.80

12.00

15.20

0.30

0.70

13.00

15.12

0.40

0.60

14.00

15.26

0.50

0.50

15.00

15.62

0.60

0.40

16.00

16.18

0.70

0.30

17.00

16.92

0.80

0.20

18.00

17.82

0.90

0.10

19.00

18.85

1.00

0.00

20.00

20.00

From this table we conclude that the minimum variance portfolio is given by setting w1
equal to (roughly) 0.3, that is investing 30% in Asset 1 and 70% in Asset 2.
An alternative way to find the minimum variance portfolio is to use the result established
above. Therefore, the minimum variance portfolio in this case is

With 28.57 percent of our wealth in Asset 1 and 71.43 percent of our wealth in Asset 2, the
expected portfolio return is 12.86% and the standard deviation of the portfolio return is
15.12%.

7.32 Risk Aversion and Portfolio Choice


We have talked about efficient portfolios being determined by the investors' preferences for more
return to less return and less risk to more risk. Now let's consider individual investors. All
investors are assumed to be risk averse and like more to less. On the following page the efficient
frontier is drawn and a set of indifference curves for an investor. The optimal portfolio for this
particular investor is at the point of tangency between the indifference curve and the efficient
frontier. [Note the indifference curves can never be tangent to the inefficient portion of the
frontier].

Figure 16
This is the optimal portfolio for one particular individual. Another person may be less tolerant of
risk or very risk averse. This person's indifference curves are drawn below. Note that the optimal
portfolio for this person has the smallest possible standard deviation.

Figure 17
The next graph shows a set of indifference curves for a person that has high risk tolerance or low
risk aversion. Note that this does not mean that the person is a risk lover. The utility function is
still concave (risk aversion) but it is close to linear for very low risk aversion. The tangency point
on the indifference map shows this person choosing an efficient portfolio that has a large
standard deviation compared to the other portfolios but note that the expected return is also
higher.

Figure 18

7.33 Mean-Variance Geometry with a Risk Free Security


Now consider the introduction of a riskless security like a Treasury Bill. Suppose we invest in a
combination of a portfolio on the efficient set (derived without the riskless security) and the
riskless security. We can calculate the expected return and the standard deviation on this new
portfolio.
E[rp] = (1-w) Rf + w Ee

(Eq 11)
(Eq 12)

Where Rf represents the risk free security, Ee represents the expected return of the portfolio on
the efficient frontier and w is the proportion of funds invested in the risky security.

Figure 19
It is clear that the only portfolio on the old efficient frontier that is desirable is the tangency
portfolio. If we chose another portfolio like A or B, this opportunity set is not efficient because
for a given variance, you do not maximize the expected return.

Figure 20
Now, I mentioned the old efficient frontier and it is time to clarify what this means. By
introducing a new security, the riskfree security, we have to redraw the efficient set. It turns out
that the new efficient set is the straight line from the riskfree rate to the tangency portfolio and
beyond. If you are on the line to the right of the tangency portfolio, you are borrowing at the
riskfree rate (note we are assuming that borrowing and lending rates are the same) and investing
in the tangency portfolio. If you are at the point Rf on the y-axis, this means that you have none
your money (w = 0) in the risky asset. If you are at the point M, then all of your money is in the

portfolio of risky assets (w = 1) -- which is the tangency portfolio. The line that forms this new
efficient set is called the Capital Market Line.
So with a risky asset, there is only one optimal combination of risky investments for each
investor. Diagrams are provided that show the optimal portfolio choice for individuals of
average, low and high risk tolerance. The optimal portfolio is the tangency of the indifference
curve to the efficient set.

Figure 21

Figure 22
If all investors agree upon Ee,
and Rf then that optimal risky asset mix is the same for all (and
must be the market portfolio). This is a fundamental point and provides the basis for the asset
pricing theory. The implication is that only two funds are held by every investor: a fund

comprised of the riskfree instrument and a fund which is the market portfolio. We call this the 2
fund theorem. If people agree on the expected returns and variance-covariance matrix, then they
will see the same efficient frontier. With the riskfree asset, there is only one portfolio of risky
assets that is efficient. This does not mean that the only investment portfolio that is held is M. We
know that people have differing degrees of risk aversion. What is implied that there is only one
portfolio of risky assets held in conjunction with the riskfree asset. This portfolio of risky assets
is the value weighted market portfolio.

7.34 The Sharpe Measure


Consider investment in a riskless asset with a return of Rf and standard deviation of zero and a
risky asset with mean return of Ee and standard deviation of
. Let the portfolio weight for the
risky asset be w and the portfolio weight for the risk free asset must be 1-w. Now let's calculate
the portfolio mean and standard deviation. We know the formulas for the portfolio mean and
standard deviation for two assets:
E[rp] = (1-w) Rf + w Ee

We can also write the expected returns equation as:


E[rp] = Rf + w (Ee - Rf )
But we know from the standard deviation equation:

Substitute this formula for w into the expected returns equation.

The term

is called the Sharpe Measure [Named after [William Sharpe] It is used to evaluate investments.
Below is a graph depicting the expected return--standard deviation space. The Sharpe measure is

the slope of the line from Rf (rise is (E-Rf) over run which is STD). The intercept is the riskfree
rate, Rf.

Figure 23
The higher the Sharpe measure is the better the security looks. On the graph we could combine a
strategy of borrowing and buying portfolio A to achieve the same expected return as portfolio B
with a much smaller variance.
Let's consider a specific example. Suppose:

Just looking at portfolio A and B it is unclear which is the best investment. B has the higher
return -- but it also has a higher variance. Let's first consider the Sharpe measures:

The measure suggests that portfolio B is dominated by a strategy of borrowing and holding
portfolio A. Let's check this out by calculating the standard deviation of a levered portfolio of A
that has exactly the same expected return as B:
0.25 = w (0.20) + (1-w) 0.08
Solving for weight w:
w = 0.17/0.12 = 1.4167
This suggests that a strategy of investing 141.67% of your money in A and borrowing 41.67% at
the rate of Rf = 8% will deliver a portfolio return of 25% which is exactly the portfolio return for
B. Now lets check the standard deviation of this levered portfolio:

Note that the other terms in the portfolio variance drop out because the variance of the riskfree
asset is zero. We are left with a portfolio standard deviation of 28.33% which is lower than the
30% for portfolio B. The levered portfolio that contains A has the same mean as B but a lower
standard deviation. As a result, the levered portfolio with A is preferred to the investment in B.
We can expand the analysis to include the all asset available in the market. We showed last time
that only the positively sloped portion of the minimum variance frontier of risky assets satisfied
our portfolio selection rules. Now let's introduce the riskfree asset into the analysis. We can use
the tools that we developed above the discriminate among the portfolios on the efficient frontier
of risky assets. We will search for combination of the riskfree asset and some risky portfolio that
delivers the highest Sharpe measure. We know that the Sharpe measure is just the slope of the
line that is drawn from the riskfree rate on the expected return axis. The portfolio with the
highest Sharpe measure is the tangency portfolio.
So the best possible mean and standard deviation combinations are from the riskless and
tangency portfolio. If 100% of your wealth is invested in the riskless asset, then your return is Rf
and the standard deviation is zero. If 50% of your wealth is invested in the riskless asset and 50%
of your wealth is in the tangency portfolio, then your portfolio lies in between R_f and M on the
straight line. If 100% of your money is in the tangency portfolio, the your expected return is the
expected return on the tangency portfolio and your standard deviation is the standard deviation
on the tangency portfolio. Finally, if you borrow money at the riskless rate and combine your
borrowing with your initial wealth to buy the tangency portfolio, then your portfolio is to the
right of M on the straight line. This straight line is called the Capital Market Line.

Since total lending equals total borrowing in the economy, the tangency portfolio is the market
portfolio. The market portfolio represents total invested wealth in risky assets. It is a portfolio
with weights defined to be the total value of the asset divided by the total value of all risky
assets. These weights are referred to as value weights.

Figure 24
Click here for a supplemental discussion and mathematical derivation of optimal portfolio
choice.

7.35 Common Sense Diversification


Whereas the benefits of diversification can be achieved through random selection of a number of
stocks, a number of common sense procedures can be usefully employed to construct a
diversified portfolio. For example:

Diversify across industries: Investing in a number of different stocks within the same
industry does not generate a diversified portfolio since the returns of firms within an
industry tend to be highly correlated. Diversification benefits can be increased by
selecting stocks from different industries.

Diversify across industry groups: Some industries themselves can be highly correlated
with other industries and hence diversification benefits can be maximized by selecting
stocks from those industries that tend to move in opposite directions or have very little
correlation with each other.

Diversify across geographical regions: Companies whose operations are in the same
geographical region are subject to the same risks in terms of natural disasters and state or
local tax changes. These risks can be diversified by investing in companies whose
operations are not in the same geographical region.

Diversify across economies: Stocks in the same country tend to be more highly correlated
than stocks across different countries. This is because many taxation and regulatory
issues apply to all stocks in a particular country. International diversification provides a
means for diversifying these risks.

Diversify across asset classes: Investing across asset classes such as stocks, bonds, and
real property also produces diversification benefits. The returns of two stocks tend to be
more highly correlated, on average, than the returns of a stock and a bond or a stock and
an investment in real estate.

WWWFinance

TM

Global Financial Management


Portfolio Analysis and Diversification
Copyright 1997 by Campbell R. Harvey and Stephen Gray. All rights reserved. No part of this lecture may be
reproduced without the permission of the authors.
Latest Revision: February 27, 1997

7.0 Overview
This class provides an overview of individual asset allocation. It is shown that an individual can
reduce the risk of his portfolio without sacrificing any expected return simply by spreading his
wealth over a number of assets in an appropriate way. This technique of diversification is
explained in some detail in terms of a simple two-asset example in order to build intuition.

7.1 Objectives
After completing this class, you should be able to:

Compute the expected return of a portfolio

Compute the variance and standard deviation of the return of a portfolio

Find the composition of the minimum-variance two-asset portfolio

Explain the concept of diversification

Explain how to construct a diversified portfolio in practice

Explain the concept of an efficient frontier

7.2 Introduction
So far in the course, we have not established any benchmarks to compare securities or portfolios
other than expected returns. It is impossible to judge the quality of an investment be simply
looking at its expected returns. For example, consider an advertisement from The Wall Street
Journal which followed the following performance comparison.

The Franklin
Dow Jones
Salomon's High
Cost of Living
Income Fund Industrial Average Grade Bond Index

516%

384%

283%

169%

These average returns over the past 15 years are higher than the Dow Jones Industrial Average
and Salomon's High Grade Bonds. Does this mean that we can beat the market by investing in
Franklin now? The answer is no. The advertisement tells us nothing about the risk of the
Franklin Fund. We will always want to consider risk as well as return. The Franklin Fund stocks
may be very risky and the only way people will hold the component stocks is to have a high
expected return. So we have go beyond returns and develop a model of risk that allows us to
compare stocks and portfolios.
There are many models of risk and expected return. Two popular models are: the Capital Asset
Pricing Model (CAPM) and the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT). We will spend most of our
time examining the Capital Asset Pricing Model. The CAPM was the first of the pricing models
[William Sharpe (1964)] and the most commonly used by practitioners.
The APT or multifactor CAPM (Stephen Ross) is examined in considerable detail in the elective
courses. I will briefly introduce these models after we have finished with the CAPM.

7.3 The Planning Problem


The Capital Asset Pricing Model is an equilibrium model. The prices that exist in the economy
are a result of all consumers maximizing utility and markets clearing, i.e., prices are set such that
supply equals demand. Our goal is to create (model) a simple economy with these ingredients
and see if the pricing function has power to predict actual prices in the economy. A simple

economy involves simple assumptions. After we derive the CAPM, you will note that many
assumptions have been made that are not very realistic. But caution should be taken in judging a
model by its assumptions. It is often better to judge a model by its ability to predict.
The consumers in our model are rational utility maximizers. The objective of each person is to
maximize expected utility of consumption today, plus the expected utility of wealth, E[U(W)],
(future consumption) tomorrow. Mathematically, the consumer chooses c0 consumption today.
Importantly, wi are the portfolio weights for the N assets we could invest in today.
We will also assume that
U' > 0 and U" < 0
These are conditions on the form of the utility function. The first derivative being greater than
zero means that you prefer more wealth to less wealth. This is a property that is not controversial.
The second derivative being negative means that you prefer more to less at a decreasing rate as
wealth gets larger. So you get more utility from a $10,000 increase in your wealth if your
previous wealth was $20,000 rather than $2,000,000.
The variables to be maximized are the control variables. The consumer will be choosing:
consumption today, c0, and investment proportions in N assets, wi. We will assume that one of
these assets, i = 0, is risk free. So the consumer will use his initial wealth for either consumption
today or investment in assets that pay off in the future. A constraint is necessary:

This just says that the sum of today's consumption plus investment in the N assets with price Pi,
cannot exceed initial wealth. This is often referred to as the budget constraint. Tomorrow's
wealth will be determined by the payoffs on the investment strategy. Because these payoffs or
returns are random (except for the risk free asset), tomorrow's wealth will also be random.

7.4 Risk Aversion


One of the foundational principles of microeconomics is that economic agents can be modeled as
risk averse utility maximizers. In Finance, we continue to employ this principle in determining
how investors will evaluate risky investment proposals. In particular we employ two key
assumptions:

Investors prefer more to less.

Investors are risk averse.

A standard utility function that exhibits these two traits is illustrated in Figure 1.

Figure 1

The fact that the utility function is upward sloping indicates that the investor prefers more to less,
no matter how wealthy he might become. The fact that the utility function is concave indicates
that the investor is risk averse, a principle that is illustrated further below.
The following table llustrates in more detail how a risk-averse investor who prefers more to less
may evaluate an investment proposal. In particular, we can define an individual to be risk averse
if he chooses not to undertake an investment that provides a 50/50 chance of an increase or
decrease in wealth of $x. For example, suppose that an investor is faced with a gamble whereby
he bets $100 on the toss of a coin. If it's heads he wins $200, if it's tails he gets nothing. This
gamble creates a 50/50 chance of increasing or decreasing his wealth by $100, so his expected
wealth is unchanged. However, if the investor is risk averse, he will actually pay to avoid being
subjected to this risk.
The bet can be summarized as:

Outcome

Probability

$x

50%

-$x

50%

The investor would be pleased if the outcome turns out to be x, which is illustrated by the
increase in utility on the graph U. However, the investor would be extremely displeased if the
outcome turns out to be -x. The decrease in his utility D when the outcome is -x is far greater

than the increase in his utility when the outcome is +x. This discussion illustrates that in general
a risk averse individual will never take a fair bet.

Example 7.5
Suppose that an investor with initial wealth W0 = 20.5 has the utility function

and is faced with the following investment proposal:

Outcome

Probability

4.5

50%

-4.5

50%

The investor's current utility is (20.5)0.5 = 4.53. If the investment succeeds, the outcome is
+4.5 and the increase in the investor's utility is
D = 4.53 - (20.5-4.5)0.5 = (4.53-4) = 0.53.
Since each outcome occurs with 50% probability, the expected utility of the investor after
undertaking the investment is:

However, the investor currently has utility of U(W0) = U(20.5) = 4.53. Hence, he is worse
off if he undertakes the investment and therefore will not accept it. This is illustrated in the
figure below.
This example illustrates the expected utility rule: If the expected utility E[U(W)] from
owning a proposed investment exceeds the current utility U(W0) without the investment,
then the investment should be undertaken. That is, if E[U(W)] > U(W0) then the investor

will undertake the investment.

Example 7.6
What if the gamble is not fair, so that the odds are stacked in the investor's favor (i.e., xu >
xd)? Whether an individual takes the gamble or not depends on his utility function, and on
his initial wealth.
First, suppose the individual has utility, U(W) = W0.5, initial wealth of 20, and is faced with
the following investment proposal:

Outcome

Probability

+15

50%

-10

50%

In this case, the investment proposal is better than a fair bet and whether an individual
takes it depends on his utility function. What is the expected utility after undertaking the
investment?

His current utility (without the investment) is:


U(W0) = U(20) = (20)0.5 = 4.47
Therefore, since E[U(W)] > U(W0), the investor should accept the investment proposal.

Example 7.7
Now suppose that the individual's utility function is logarithmic so that U(W) = ln W. What
is the expected utility after undertaking the investment?

His current utility (without the investment) is:

U(W0) = U(20) = ln(20) = 3.00


Therefore, since E[U(W)] < U(W0), the investor should not accept the investment proposal.
Finally, suppose that the investor still has log utility, but that his initial wealth is 100
(rather than 20). In this case, the expected utility after undertaking the investment is:

The investor's current utility (without the investment) is U(W0) = ln(100) = 4.60.
Therefore, since E[U(W)] > U(W0), the investor should accept the investment proposal.

This example indicates that different investors have different attitudes toward risk, which is
captured in the form of differently shaped utility functions. Moreover, a single individual, whose
utility function does not change can become more tolerant toward risk as his wealth increases.

7.8 Certainty Equivalent


The certainty equivalent C is the minimum amount of cash that an investor would accept in
exchange for all of his investments and his initial wealth. Having $C cash will make the investor
as well off as having his initial wealth and his investment portfolio. Therefore:
E[U(W)] = U(C)

Example 7.9
Suppose an investor, who has square root utility and initial wealth of $100,000, is deciding
whether or not to buy car insurance. The outcomes and associated probabilities, based on
the investor's driving record are:

Event

No Accident

Loss

Probability

pu = 95%

Accident

-50,000

pd = 5%

First, determine the investor's expected utility if he does not buy insurance:

Next, compute the certainty equivalent so that the investor is just as happy with $C cash as
with having $100,000 and taking the risk of the accident. That is, $C solves:

The investor originally had $100,000 (W0) plus the risk of an accident. If he had
$97,092.07 and was indemnified against the cost of an accident, he would be just as happy.
Therefore, he is prepared to pay $100,000 - 97,092.07 = $2,907.93 for car insurance.

General forms of risk averse, risk neutral and risk loving preference functions are shown below:

Figure 4

Figure 5

figure 6

Click here for a supplementary discussion on the Cost of Risk

7.10 Portfolio Selection


Portfolios of assets can be compared on the basis of their risk and return characteristics. In this
section we consider tools for analyzing portfolios. We need to know how to measure the risk and
return characteristics of a given portfolio of securities.

7.11 Two Asset Case


The expected return of a two asset portfolio is simply a weighted average of the expected returns
of each asset in the portfolio.

E[rp] = w1 E[r1] + (1-w1) E[r2]

(Eq 1)

where w1 and (1-w1) = w2 are the percentage of portfolio value invested in each asset.
From basic statistics we also know that the variance of two random variables is a function of the
variance of each variable and the covariance between the variables. This relationship directly
applies in calculating the variance of a two asset portfolio as follows:
(Eq 2)

7.12 The N Asset Case


For an N asset portfolio, the portfolio return is just the sum of the asset returns times the weights
each of the assets has in the portfolio. In matrix notation, this is just the product:
rp = w' r

(Eq 3)

w is a vector containing the respective weights of the N assets. That is, if we have $1 million to
invest and we place $100,000 in security i, then wi = 0.10. We define r as a vector containing the
returns of the N assets. This product can be calculated in Excel using the sumproduct function.
The weights must all sum to one. This means that all money must be allocated.
The portfolio expected return is just the expected asset returns times the weights each of the
assets has in the portfolio.
The portfolio expected return is just the sum of the expected asset returns times the weights each
of the assets has in the portfolio. If E is a vector containing the expected returns of the assets,
then the portfolio's expected return can also be defined in terms of matrix multiplication. In
Excel this operation can also be performed using the sumproduct function.
Ep = w' E
Note that the above formula expands to the formula above for the two asset case.
E(rp) = w1 E(r1) + (1-w1) E(r2)
The portfolio expected excess return is just the expected returns on the assets minus the risk free
return (say a one month Treasury bill) times the weights each of the assets has in the portfolio.
This value can also be expressed as a product of a (1 x N) matrix of weights with a (N x 1) matrix
of excess returns (or in Excel using the sumproduct function).
Xp = w'X

where X represents the expected excess returns on the various assets.


The variance of the portfolio return is a little more complicated when there are more than two
assets. It will still be a function of the weights, variances and covariances, but it is harder to
express as a simple formula. It can be expressed, easily, as a product of matrices:
(Eq 5)
where V is the variance-covariance matrix (variances along diagonal and covariances off the
diagonal). The linear algebra is shown below for the two asset case.

The matrix algebra for the N asset case can easily be implemented in Excel.
The covariance of two portfolio returns, each denoted by their own set of weights, say wa, wb can
also be found using matrix algebra. It is just:
Cova,b = wa' V wb

(Eq 6)

where V is the variance-covariance matrix (variances along diagonal and covariances off the
diagonal).
Recall the formula for correlation. The correlation of portfolios with returns a and b is just the
covariance divided by the product of the standard deviations.

7.13 Distributional Assumptions


Given an optimal choice for today's consumption, c0, the goal of a portfolio is to maximize the
utility (expected) of future consumption provided by wealth at t = 1. This is a hard problem.
Often we need to make a major assumption to simplify the problem. We will assume that asset
returns are jointly normally distributed. The normal distribution has the property that the
distribution can be completely described by two parameters: the mean and variance. The
multivariate normal can be completely described by the means, variances and the covariances
between the different assets.
Note the variances and the covariances of the risk free asset are zero.

A linear combination of normal random variables is normal. Therefore, wealth at t = 1 is


normally distributed. The entire probability distribution of wealth is described by a portfolio's
mean and variance. This all implies that a sufficient set of statistics to discriminate between
portfolios is the mean and variance. This greatly simplifies the portfolio selection problem.

7.14 Other Distributional Assumptions


While most of finance is set in a mean-variance framework (which lends itself to using the
normal distribution), there is some new work going on which tries to capture more general
distributions. Harvey and Siddique (1995) have cast the portfolio selection in terms of meanvariance-skewness. This idea originates with important work in the 1970s. Harvey and Siddique
make the means, variances and skewness dynamic processes which change with economic
conditions. This paper is discussed in Global Tactical Asset Allocation.

7.15 The Effect of Diversification


Now let's consider the effect of diversification. We will examine a portfolio of two assets. From
our formula for variance, we know:

Where

where

is the portfolio variance. For the two asset case:

is the covariance between assets 1 and 2.

We could also write this in terms of correlation:


(Eq 7)
where the sigmas denotes the standard deviation of assets 1 and 2.
For simplicity, assume in the following examples, that the variances of the two assets are equal,
or

and that the portfolio weights are identical, or w1 = w2 = 0.50.

Example 7.16

Perfect Positive Correlation

The first case of interest is that of perfect positive correlation. Using the formula:

This result demonstrates that the portfolio variance is the same as the variance for each
asset. So diversification does not reduce the portfolio variance in this case.

Example 7.17

No Correlation

The second case of interest is that of zero correlation. Again, plugging into the formula:

This result demonstrates that the portfolio variance is half of the variance of the individual
assets. So combining stocks that have less than perfect positive correlation is a strategy
that will reduce the variance of the returns on your portfolio. This is called diversification.

Example 7.18 Perfect Negative Correlation


If two assets could be found which have perfect negative correlation, then we combine
these assets to create a risk free portfolio:

These assets create a perfect hedge. This shows that diversification can be thought of as a
partial hedge of risks.

The following graphs tells the story. Suppose we randomly selected a stock and plotted its
standard deviation. Now we randomly draw another stock and plot the standard deviation of the
equally weighted portfolio. We continue the exercise. Just by randomly selecting stocks we can
decrease portfolio variance.

figure 7

Example 7.19
Suppose Assets 1 and 2 have expected returns and standard deviations as follows:

Security Expected Return Standard Deviation

20%

20%

10%

16%

Furthermore, suppose that the returns of the two securities are perfectly negatively
correlated with
.
What is the expected return and standard deviation of a portfolio with equal weights in
each security?
Here we use equation 1 to compute the expected return of the portfolio:
E[rp] = w1 E[r1]+(1-w1)E[r2]
and since the weight of each asset is w1 = w2 = 0.5, we find that

E[rp] = 0.5 (20%) + 0.5 (10%) = 15%


We use equation 7 to compute the variance of the returns of the portfolio:

Plugging in the values for our 50/50 portfolio yields


(0.52)(0.202) + (0.52)(0.162) + 2 (0.5)(0.5)(0.20)(0.16)(-1) = 0.0004
in which case the standard deviation of the returns of the portfolio is 0.02 = 2%.
Recall that Asset 2 has an expected return of 10% and a standard deviation of 16%. Clearly
this portfolio of equal weights in Asset 1 and Asset 2 is preferred to holding Asset 2 by
itself since the portfolio has an expected return of 15% and a standard deviation of 2%.

Example 7.20
Consider forming a portfolio with three assets.
The expected returns are E' = (0.25, 0.19, 0.12)
(Note: Vectors are usually written as a column. The mark after the E says to take the
transpose of the column, or, in other words, look at it as a row)
The variance-covariance matrix is V

Portfolio 1 weights are w' = (.3, .4, .3)


Portfolio 2 weights are w' = (.1, .6, .3)
1. Calculate the standard deviations for each asset's return.
2. Calculate the correlation between the asset's returns.
3. Calculate the portfolio variances.
4. Calculate the covariance between the portfolios.

Recall that the diagonal elements of the Variance/Covariance matrix contains the
variances. The standard deviations can be found by taking the square roots of those
variances.
(0.090)0.5 = 0.300
(0.100)0.5 = 0.316
(0.010)0.5 = 0.100

The correlation coefficient can be calculated using the following relationship:

The covariances can be found in the V matrix where the covariances between assets j and
k will be in row j, column k (and also in column j, row k).

Solving for the correlation coefficients:

Solving for the portfolio variances is easy, if you know how to multiply matrices using the
following formula:

While matrix multiplication is not difficult, it is also not required for this class. The two
asset case can be solved without matrix multiplication using the following formula:

Matrix multiplication can be performed in Excel using the mmult command. A sample
spreadsheet can be downloaded, and modified to solve this problem. The solution for the
first portfolio is:

The solution for the second portfolio is:

We can use equation 7

to find the covariance between these two portfolios. We could treat each of these portfolios
as a separate asset, and create a new portfolio using equal weights. The variance of the
new portfolio can be found, because it is just a portfolio of our three original assets. The
varainces of the two portfolios can be plugged in to the right hand side of the equation.
That leaves the covariance between the two portfolios as the only unknown. Solving for
that, we find that the covariance between the two portfolios is 0.029040

What is important here?


Much of what is done in this example is at a more advanced mathematical level than
is required for this class. The information is shown here for a few reasons.

Some students have the mathematical background, and seeing the multi-asset

case will help them understand the material better.

Some students will work in portfolio analysis, and will need to find these
values.

There is some insight that can be gained even by those who do not understand
the mathematics.

Instead of being scared off by the mathematics, the following should be taken away
from this example:

It isn't just the risk of the individual assets (variance/standard deviation)


which contribute to the risk of the portfolio, it is also the interaction of the
assets to each other (covariance). A portfolio of two assets which always
move in the same direction are riskier than two assets whose returns are less
dependent on each other.

It is also important to realize that there are solutions to these problems.

It is important to understand the formulas for the two asset case

7.21 Efficient Portfolios


Previously, we made the simplifying assumption that asset returns are multivariate normally
distributed. This assumption implies that individual asset returns are univariate normally
distributed. We make the assumption of normality because it greatly simplifies the portfolio
selection problem. The entire distribution of an individual stock's return can be described by two
parameters: the mean and the variance. We can figure out a portfolio's mean and variance by
examining the means, variances and covariances of the component securities. Most importantly,
we can compare different portfolios on the basis of mean and variance.
Our discussion of utility functions and risk aversion provided two conclusions. First, consumers
like more to less. In terms of a security or portfolio, consumers prefer more return to less return.
Second, consumers prefer less variance to more variance. Remember that the risk averse
consumer will always turn down a fair bet. In terms of a security or portfolio, the consumer will
prefer a portfolio with less variance to another higher variance portfolio with an equal expected
return.
These insights lead to two rules of portfolio selection.

Any investor who chooses to hold a portfolio with variance

will want the portfolio

that has the maximum mean possible among those portfolios that have variance
.

Similarly, any investor who chooses a portfolio with mean E[rp] will want the portfolio
with the minimum variance possible among those with mean E[rp].

A portfolio that satisfies these conditions is known as an efficient portfolio. A portfolio is


inefficient if there exists another portfolio with:

7.22 The Efficient Frontier


Build a two asset efficient frontier using a Java program.
Build a multiasset efficient frontier using a Java program.
We will now consider an example of the effects of diversification. Previously, we combined
securities and looked at the effect on the portfolio variance for different correlation coefficients
between the securities. We found that using equal weights in the two portfolios, a lower
correlation coefficient led to lower portfolio variance. In this example, we will look at a given
correlation and vary the portfolio weights to trace the effect on the portfolio variance.
The example comes from a classic article by Bodie and Rosansky, "Risk and Return in
Commodity Futures" which was published in the Financial Analysts Journal in 1980. We will
trace out the return and standard deviation of a portfolio of common stocks and futures. A
number of tables are presented.

Table 1 and Table 2 document the cumulative wealth relatives and the year by year rates
of return of five portfolios from 1949 to 1976.

Table 3 provides mean returns and standard deviations for these portfolio.

Table 4 gives the correlation matrix for the different returns.

Table 5 provides returns on selected common stock-commodity futures portfolios.

Example 7.23

We will be concerned with the common stocks and the commodity futures. Note that the
common stocks have a -24% correlation with the commodity futures. Previously, we
showed that combining two portfolios with a zero correlation reduced the variance of the
portfolio. This was referred to as diversification. The common stocks and futures have
negative correlation. This suggests that holding both in a portfolio will produce a portfolio
variance that is less than the variance of the individual components.
Let's calculate the portfolio means and standard deviations. The two formulas that are
relevant are:
E[rp] = w1 E[r1] + (1-w1) E[r2]
and

We are given that for Asset 1, the common stocks:

Also, Asset 2, the commodity futures:

We are also given the correlation coefficient and the variances can easily be calculated:

The next step is to calculate the portfolio mean and standard deviation for various weights.

Portfolio 1 (w1 = 1 w2 = 0)
The mean return is:
E[rp1] = 1 (13.05) + 0 (13.83) = 13.05%

The standard deviation is:

Portfolio 2 (w1 = 0.8 w2 = 0.2)


The mean return is:
E[rp2] = 0.8 (13.05) + 0.2 (13.83) = 13.21%
The standard deviation is:

Portfolio 3 (w1 = 0.6 w2 = 0.4)


The mean return is:
E[rp3] = 0.6 (13.05) + 0.4 (13.83) = 13.36%
The standard deviation is:

Portfolio 4 (w1 = 0.4 w2 = 0.6)


The mean return is:
E[rp4] = 0.4 (13.05) + 0.6 (13.83) = 13.52%
The standard deviation is:

Portfolio 5 (w1 = 0.2 w2 = 0.8)


The mean return is:
E[rp5] = 0.2 (13.05) + 0.8 (13.83) = 13.67%
The standard deviation is:

Portfolio 6 (w1 = 0 w2 = 1)
The mean return is:
E[rp3] = 0 (13.05) + 1 (13.83) = 13.83%
The standard deviation is:

These calculations verify the numbers presented in Table 5.


The following graph shows the risk and return.

Note that with the negative correlation between the assets, the amount invested in the
component securities has a large effect on the portfolio variance.

7.24 The Efficient Frontier with Different Levels of Correlation


The next item is to look at the effect of different levels of correlations on the portfolio variance.
Let's develop a better grasp of where these portfolios should lie in the mean-standard deviation
space. In order to do this, assume that there are only two securities, q (1) and s (2). The expected
return on the portfolio is:
E[rp] = w1 E[r1] + (1-w1) E[r2]
The standard deviation on the portfolio is:

Write this in terms of the correlation coefficient.

So now we can start to map out the frontier.

7.25 Perfect Positive Correlation

Consider a number of simple cases. First, if the correlation between the two securities is one,
then the standard deviation on the portfolio is:
(Eq 8)
because

This result has a simple geometric interpretation. If we plot the mean and standard deviation of
the two securities, then a straight line between the two securities represents the set of portfolios
available. The point q below represents the situation where w = 1 where as the point s represents
the situation where w = 0. Note that diversification when the correlation between the securities is
one is ineffective.

Figure 9: portfolio options (correlation = 1)

7.26 Perfect Negative Correlation


The second straightforward situation is when the correlation between the two securities is
negative one. The standard deviation of the portfolio is:

(Eq 9)
This immediately implies that we can drive the standard deviation of the portfolio to zero by
choosing the right weights. Setting the left-hand side equal to zero, we can solve for w:

This point corresponds to the point y on the diagram. The expected return of this portfolio will
be:

Figure 10: portfolio options (correlation = -1)

7.27 Correlation between -1 and +1


Finally, consider the case where the returns of the two assets are neither perfectly positively nor
perfectly negatively correlated. Without loss of generality, assume that Asset 2 has lower
variance than Asset 1, as depicted in Figures 11 and 12. In this case, two results are possible. If

there exists some portfolio of Assets 1 and 2 that has higher expected return and lower variance
than Asset 2. That is, in this case there are gains from diversification. The possible portfolios lie
on a parabola that has a turning point between Assets 1 and 2, as depicted in Figure 11.

Figure 11: Portfolio options with benefits from diversification


Alternatively, if

there does not exist any portfolio of Assets 1 and 2 that has higher expected return and lower
variance than Asset 2. That is, in this case there are no gains from diversification.
The possible portfolios lie on a parabola that has no turning point between Assets 1 and 2, as
depicted in Figure 12.

Figure 12: Portfolio options without benefits from diversification

7.28 Proof of claims


To prove these claims, we find the minimum variance portfolio and show that where

the minimum variance portfolio has lower variance and higher expected return than Asset
2. The minimum variance portfolio is found by solving:
(Eq 10)
which has the first order condition

Now the portfolio will have less risk than Asset 2 alone whenever

which was to be shown.

Now let's consider the weights w. There is no restriction on the sign of w. Therefore, a negative
w can be considered a short sale of security q. The dotted line extension of the lines in figure 13
represent short sales. Note that you can change the perfect positive correlation into negative
correlation with the short sale provision.

Figure 13
More realistically, the correlation between the securities will between positive one and negative
one. The curve on the diagram plots the possible portfolios with a correlation between zero and
one.
Notice that any part of the curve that has a positive slope must be concave. Consider the counter
example between u and v on the diagram. With a dashed line, I have drawn a convex segment. Is
this a possible frontier? It turns out that the answer is no. We can consider u and v as separate
portfolios of q and s. We know that the most extreme situation (farthest to the right) would be a
correlation of positive one between these two portfolios. Hence, it is impossible to have any
curve to the right of the straight line extreme case. So the frontier will be concave for all positive
slopes.
Now lets be more precise. We have defined the mean-variance frontier. After plotting all the
portfolio combinations, the points farthest the left are minimum variance. But consumers will
only care about a certain portion of the frontier -- the portion with a positive slope. The
negatively sloped part of the frontier implies a lower return for greater standard deviation. Our

investors will not buy that trade-off. The positively sloped portion is called the efficient frontier.
Portfolios on this frontier are referred to as mean--variance efficient. These portfolios maximize
the expected return on the portfolio for a given variance. So there are dual properties of efficient
portfolios:
No other portfolio with the same expected return has a lower standard deviation of return.
No other portfolio with the same standard deviation of return has a higher expected return
These properties are reflected in all the portfolios in the efficient frontier. The opportunity set for
investors follows. Because of our assumptions about investors, only the positively sloping
portion of the minimum variance curve is held. The solid line represents the efficient frontier.
Note that I have also included arrows representing the direction of the investors' preferences
(more return and less risk).

Figure 14

Figure 15

Example 7.29

Suppose Assets 1 and 2 have expected returns and standard deviations as follows:

Asset

Expected Return

Standars Deviation

20%

20%

10%

16%

Also assume that the returns of the two securities are perfectly negatively correlated
. What is the composition of the minimum variance portfolio and what is its
expected return and variance?
Here we use the result that if

and we set

then the portfolio variance is zero. In this case,


w1 = (16)/(20+16) = 0.44
which implies that 56% of the funds invested in the portfolio should be invested in Asset 2.
The expected return of this portfolio is given by equation 1
E[rp] = (0.44) 20 + (0.56) 10 = 14.44%
To check that the portfolio variance is indeed zero we use equation 7
= (0.44)2(20)2 + (0.56)2(16)2 + 2(0.44)(0.56)(-1)(20)(16) = 0

Example 7.30
Suppose that the correlation between the returns of the two assets from the previous

example is

What is the minimum variance portfolio that can be formed from assets 1 and 2 and what
is the expected return and standard deviation of the 50/50 portfolio?
Finding the minimum variance portfolio is straightforward -- since the two assets are
perfectly positively correlated, there are no gains from diversification and the minimum
variance portfolio will be the portfolio that puts all the weight on Asset 2 (which has the
lower variance) and zero weight on Asset 1. This portfolio amounts to holding Asset 2 by
itself and yields an expected return of 10% and has a standard deviation of 16%.
A portfolio of equal weights of Asset 1 and Asset 2 has expected return of
E[rp] = (0.5) 20 + (0.5) 10 = 15%
The variance of this portfolio is given by
(0.5)2(20)2 + (0.5)2(16)2 + 2 (0.5)(0.5)(1)(20)(16) = 324
so the standard deviation is 18%.

Example 7.31
Suppose that the correlation between the returns of the two assets from the previous
example is
What is the expected return and standard deviation of a portfolio with equal weights in
each security? And what is the composition of the minimum variance portfolio?
The expected return of the portfolio is given by:
E[rp] = (0.5) 20 + (0.5) 10 = 15%
The variance of the portfolio can be calculated as
(0.5)2(20)2 + (0.5)2(16)2 + 2(0.5)(0.5)(0.5)(20)(16) = 244
So, the standard deviation is 15.62%
Recall that Asset 2 has an expected return of 10% and a standard deviation of 16%. Clearly
this portfolio of equal weights in Asset 1 and Asset 2 is preferred to holding Asset 2 by
itself since the portfolio has an expected return of 15% and a standard deviation of

15.62%.
One way to find the minimum variance portfolio is to allow the weight to vary between 0
and 1 (from no investment in Asset 1 to all of our wealth in Asset 1) and examine the
resulting portfolio. The expected returns and standard deviation of rates of return are as
follows:

Weight
(Asset 1)

Weight
(Asset 2)

Exptected
Return

Standard
Deviation

0.00

1.00

10.00

16.00

0.10

0.90

11.00

15.50

0.20

0.80

12.00

15.20

0.30

0.70

13.00

15.12

0.40

0.60

14.00

15.26

0.50

0.50

15.00

15.62

0.60

0.40

16.00

16.18

0.70

0.30

17.00

16.92

0.80

0.20

18.00

17.82

0.90

0.10

19.00

18.85

1.00

0.00

20.00

20.00

From this table we conclude that the minimum variance portfolio is given by setting w1
equal to (roughly) 0.3, that is investing 30% in Asset 1 and 70% in Asset 2.
An alternative way to find the minimum variance portfolio is to use the result established
above. Therefore, the minimum variance portfolio in this case is

With 28.57 percent of our wealth in Asset 1 and 71.43 percent of our wealth in Asset 2, the
expected portfolio return is 12.86% and the standard deviation of the portfolio return is
15.12%.

7.32 Risk Aversion and Portfolio Choice


We have talked about efficient portfolios being determined by the investors' preferences for more
return to less return and less risk to more risk. Now let's consider individual investors. All
investors are assumed to be risk averse and like more to less. On the following page the efficient
frontier is drawn and a set of indifference curves for an investor. The optimal portfolio for this
particular investor is at the point of tangency between the indifference curve and the efficient
frontier. [Note the indifference curves can never be tangent to the inefficient portion of the
frontier].

Figure 16
This is the optimal portfolio for one particular individual. Another person may be less tolerant of
risk or very risk averse. This person's indifference curves are drawn below. Note that the optimal
portfolio for this person has the smallest possible standard deviation.

Figure 17
The next graph shows a set of indifference curves for a person that has high risk tolerance or low
risk aversion. Note that this does not mean that the person is a risk lover. The utility function is
still concave (risk aversion) but it is close to linear for very low risk aversion. The tangency point
on the indifference map shows this person choosing an efficient portfolio that has a large
standard deviation compared to the other portfolios but note that the expected return is also
higher.

Figure 18

7.33 Mean-Variance Geometry with a Risk Free Security


Now consider the introduction of a riskless security like a Treasury Bill. Suppose we invest in a
combination of a portfolio on the efficient set (derived without the riskless security) and the
riskless security. We can calculate the expected return and the standard deviation on this new
portfolio.
E[rp] = (1-w) Rf + w Ee

(Eq 11)
(Eq 12)

Where Rf represents the risk free security, Ee represents the expected return of the portfolio on
the efficient frontier and w is the proportion of funds invested in the risky security.

Figure 19
It is clear that the only portfolio on the old efficient frontier that is desirable is the tangency
portfolio. If we chose another portfolio like A or B, this opportunity set is not efficient because
for a given variance, you do not maximize the expected return.

Figure 20
Now, I mentioned the old efficient frontier and it is time to clarify what this means. By
introducing a new security, the riskfree security, we have to redraw the efficient set. It turns out
that the new efficient set is the straight line from the riskfree rate to the tangency portfolio and
beyond. If you are on the line to the right of the tangency portfolio, you are borrowing at the
riskfree rate (note we are assuming that borrowing and lending rates are the same) and investing
in the tangency portfolio. If you are at the point Rf on the y-axis, this means that you have none
your money (w = 0) in the risky asset. If you are at the point M, then all of your money is in the

portfolio of risky assets (w = 1) -- which is the tangency portfolio. The line that forms this new
efficient set is called the Capital Market Line.
So with a risky asset, there is only one optimal combination of risky investments for each
investor. Diagrams are provided that show the optimal portfolio choice for individuals of
average, low and high risk tolerance. The optimal portfolio is the tangency of the indifference
curve to the efficient set.

Figure 21

Figure 22
If all investors agree upon Ee,
and Rf then that optimal risky asset mix is the same for all (and
must be the market portfolio). This is a fundamental point and provides the basis for the asset
pricing theory. The implication is that only two funds are held by every investor: a fund

comprised of the riskfree instrument and a fund which is the market portfolio. We call this the 2
fund theorem. If people agree on the expected returns and variance-covariance matrix, then they
will see the same efficient frontier. With the riskfree asset, there is only one portfolio of risky
assets that is efficient. This does not mean that the only investment portfolio that is held is M. We
know that people have differing degrees of risk aversion. What is implied that there is only one
portfolio of risky assets held in conjunction with the riskfree asset. This portfolio of risky assets
is the value weighted market portfolio.

7.34 The Sharpe Measure


Consider investment in a riskless asset with a return of Rf and standard deviation of zero and a
risky asset with mean return of Ee and standard deviation of
. Let the portfolio weight for the
risky asset be w and the portfolio weight for the risk free asset must be 1-w. Now let's calculate
the portfolio mean and standard deviation. We know the formulas for the portfolio mean and
standard deviation for two assets:
E[rp] = (1-w) Rf + w Ee

We can also write the expected returns equation as:


E[rp] = Rf + w (Ee - Rf )
But we know from the standard deviation equation:

Substitute this formula for w into the expected returns equation.

The term

is called the Sharpe Measure [Named after [William Sharpe] It is used to evaluate investments.
Below is a graph depicting the expected return--standard deviation space. The Sharpe measure is

the slope of the line from Rf (rise is (E-Rf) over run which is STD). The intercept is the riskfree
rate, Rf.

Figure 23
The higher the Sharpe measure is the better the security looks. On the graph we could combine a
strategy of borrowing and buying portfolio A to achieve the same expected return as portfolio B
with a much smaller variance.
Let's consider a specific example. Suppose:

Just looking at portfolio A and B it is unclear which is the best investment. B has the higher
return -- but it also has a higher variance. Let's first consider the Sharpe measures:

The measure suggests that portfolio B is dominated by a strategy of borrowing and holding
portfolio A. Let's check this out by calculating the standard deviation of a levered portfolio of A
that has exactly the same expected return as B:
0.25 = w (0.20) + (1-w) 0.08
Solving for weight w:
w = 0.17/0.12 = 1.4167
This suggests that a strategy of investing 141.67% of your money in A and borrowing 41.67% at
the rate of Rf = 8% will deliver a portfolio return of 25% which is exactly the portfolio return for
B. Now lets check the standard deviation of this levered portfolio:

Note that the other terms in the portfolio variance drop out because the variance of the riskfree
asset is zero. We are left with a portfolio standard deviation of 28.33% which is lower than the
30% for portfolio B. The levered portfolio that contains A has the same mean as B but a lower
standard deviation. As a result, the levered portfolio with A is preferred to the investment in B.
We can expand the analysis to include the all asset available in the market. We showed last time
that only the positively sloped portion of the minimum variance frontier of risky assets satisfied
our portfolio selection rules. Now let's introduce the riskfree asset into the analysis. We can use
the tools that we developed above the discriminate among the portfolios on the efficient frontier
of risky assets. We will search for combination of the riskfree asset and some risky portfolio that
delivers the highest Sharpe measure. We know that the Sharpe measure is just the slope of the
line that is drawn from the riskfree rate on the expected return axis. The portfolio with the
highest Sharpe measure is the tangency portfolio.
So the best possible mean and standard deviation combinations are from the riskless and
tangency portfolio. If 100% of your wealth is invested in the riskless asset, then your return is Rf
and the standard deviation is zero. If 50% of your wealth is invested in the riskless asset and 50%
of your wealth is in the tangency portfolio, then your portfolio lies in between R_f and M on the
straight line. If 100% of your money is in the tangency portfolio, the your expected return is the
expected return on the tangency portfolio and your standard deviation is the standard deviation
on the tangency portfolio. Finally, if you borrow money at the riskless rate and combine your
borrowing with your initial wealth to buy the tangency portfolio, then your portfolio is to the
right of M on the straight line. This straight line is called the Capital Market Line.

Since total lending equals total borrowing in the economy, the tangency portfolio is the market
portfolio. The market portfolio represents total invested wealth in risky assets. It is a portfolio
with weights defined to be the total value of the asset divided by the total value of all risky
assets. These weights are referred to as value weights.

Figure 24
Click here for a supplemental discussion and mathematical derivation of optimal portfolio
choice.

7.35 Common Sense Diversification


Whereas the benefits of diversification can be achieved through random selection of a number of
stocks, a number of common sense procedures can be usefully employed to construct a
diversified portfolio. For example:

Diversify across industries: Investing in a number of different stocks within the same
industry does not generate a diversified portfolio since the returns of firms within an
industry tend to be highly correlated. Diversification benefits can be increased by
selecting stocks from different industries.

Diversify across industry groups: Some industries themselves can be highly correlated
with other industries and hence diversification benefits can be maximized by selecting
stocks from those industries that tend to move in opposite directions or have very little
correlation with each other.

Diversify across geographical regions: Companies whose operations are in the same
geographical region are subject to the same risks in terms of natural disasters and state or
local tax changes. These risks can be diversified by investing in companies whose
operations are not in the same geographical region.

Diversify across economies: Stocks in the same country tend to be more highly correlated
than stocks across different countries. This is because many taxation and regulatory
issues apply to all stocks in a particular country. International diversification provides a
means for diversifying these risks.

Diversify across asset classes: Investing across asset classes such as stocks, bonds, and
real property also produces diversification benefits. The returns of two stocks tend to be
more highly correlated, on average, than the returns of a stock and a bond or a stock and
an investment in real estate.

You might also like