Ntroductory Ooks: Bibliography Collected by The Editors
Ntroductory Ooks: Bibliography Collected by The Editors
INTRODUCTORY BOOKS
Copyright 1999 Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest
Adams, Michael (1981), Oekonomische Analyse des Zivilprozesses (Economic Analysis of Civil
Procedure), Koenigstein, Athenaeum-Verlag.
Algra, N.E. (1991), The Relations Between Law and Economics, Cahiers Rechtstheorie en
Encyclopedie van het recht, Nr. 2.
Arruada, Benito (1996), Analisis contractual de la empresa: Una introduccion aplicada
(Contractual Analysis of the Firm: An Applied Introduction), 5(3) Revista Europea de
Direccion y Economia de la Empresa.
Barnes, David W. and Stout, Lynn A. (1992a), Economic Foundations of Regulation and Antitrust
Law, Minneapolis, West Publishing.
Barnes, David W. and Stout, Lynn A. (1992b), Economics of Property Rights and Nuisance Law,
Minneapolis, West Publishing.
Barnes, David W. and Stout, Lynn A. (1992c), Economics of Constitutional Law and Public
Choice, Minneapolis, West Publishing.
Barnes, David W. and Stout, Lynn A. (1992d), Economic Analysis of Tort Law, Minneapolis, West
Publishing.
Barnes, David W. and Stout, Lynn A. (1992e), Cases and Materials on Law and Economics,
Minneapolis, West Publishing.
Barnes, David W. and Stout, Lynn A. (1992f), Economics of Contract Law, Minneapolis, West
Publishing.
Bergel, J.-L. (1989), Thorie Gnrale du Droit (General Theory of Law), Dalloz, Coll. Mthode
du droit.
Bowles, Roger A. (1982), Law and the Economy, Oxford, Martin Robertson, 239 p.
Cabrillac Remy (1995), Introduction Gnrale au Droit (General Introduction of Law), Dalloz, 23
p.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1987), The Words of an Orange Seller (in Chinese), Taipei: Yuan-Liou
Publishing Company, Ltd..
Chiancone, Aldo and Porrini, Donatella (1996), Lezioni di Analisi Economica del Diritto (Lessons
of Economic Analysis of Law), Torino, Giappichelli.
Cooter, Robert D. and Ulen, Thomas S. (1988), Law and Economics, Scott Foresman. Reprinted in
Japanese translation by Prof. Shozo Ota, introduction by Prof. Koji Shimdo, published by
Shoji-Homu in 1989.
Crafton, Steven M. and Brinig, Margaret F. (1994), Quantitative Methods for Lawyers, Durham
(NC), Carolina Academic Press.
Dnes, Antony W. (1996), Economics of Law, London, Sweet & Maxwell.
Gallo, Paolo (1998), Analisi Economica del Diritto (Economic Analysis of Law), Torino,
Giappichelli.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1995), Oikonomika kai Dikaio: Oikonomika gia Nomikous, tomos:
Methodologika kai Oikonomika Themelia (Law and Economics: Economics for Lawyers, vol.
I: Methodological and Economic Foundations), Athens-Komotini, Ant. N. Sakkoulas
Publications.
1
2 Introductory Books 0000
Ghestin Jacques (1994), Trait de droit civil (Treat of Civil Law), 84-85.
Hirsch, Werner Z. (1979), Law and Economics: An Introductory Analysis, San Diego, Academic
Press, 275 p.
Holzhauer, Rudi W., Teijl, Rob et al. (1995), Inleiding Rechtseconomie (Introduction to Law and
Economics), Arnhem, Gouda Quint.
Holzhauer, Rudi W., Teijl, Rob et al (1989), Inleiding Rechtseconomie (Introduction to Law and
Economics), Arnhem, Gouda Quint, 345 p.
Hondius, E.H. et al. (1991), Rechtseconomie en Recht: Kennismaking met een Vakgebied in
Opkomst (Law and Economics and Law: Getting to Know an Emerging Discipline), Zwolle,
Tjeenk Willink, 201 p.
Hwang, Chun-Sin and Kan, Steven S. (1994), Principles of Economics Cooperating for Mutual
Prosperity and Progress, Taipei, Shin Lu Bookstore.
Jovanovic, Aleksandra (1998), Uvod u Ekonomsku Analizu Prava (Introduction to Economic
Analysis of Law), Belgrade, Pravni fakultet.
Kan, Steven S. (1994), Principles of Economics Cooperating for Mutual Prosperity and
Progress, Taipei, Shin Lu Bookstore.
Kanniainen, Vesa and Mtt, Kalle (eds) (1996), Nkkulmia Oikeustaloustieteeseen
(Perspectives on Law and Economics), Helsinki, Gaudeamus.
Kaplow, Louis (1987), Optimal Transition Policy: Replacing Horizontal Equity with an Ex Ante
Incentives Perspective, Dissertation accepted by Harvard University Department of
Economics.
Labus Miroljub (1995), Osnovi ekonomije: Savremene Teorije i Primena (Foundation Economics:
Contemporary Theories and Application), Jugoslovenska knjiga, Belgrade.
Lande, Robert H., Lafferty, Ronald N. and Kirkwood, John (1984), Impact Evaluations of Federal
Trade Commission Vertical Restraints Cases, FTC Publication. Nineteen Journal Reprints for
Antitrust Law and Economics 1 (1986).
Lehmann, Michael (1983), Buergerliches Recht und Handelsrecht - eine juristische und
oekonomische Analyse, Stuttgart, Poeschel.
Lemennicier, Bertrand (1991), Economie du Droit (Economics of Law), Paris, Ed. Cujas, 177 p.
Mackaay, Ejan (1982), Economics of Information and Law, Dordrecht, Kluwer, 293 p.
Markovits, Richard S. (1982), Law and Economic Theory, Oxford, Centre for Socio-Legal Studies.
Mercado Pacheco, Pedro (1994), El Anlisis Econmico del Derecho. Una reconstruccin terica
(Law and Economics. A Theoretical Reconstruction), Madrid, Centro de Estudios
Constitucionales.
Mercuro, Nicholas and Ryan, Tim (1984), Law, Economics, and Public Policy, Greenwood, JAI
Press.
Miceli, Thomas J. (1996), Economics of the Law: Torts, Contracts, Property, Litigation, Oxford,
Oxford University Press.
Murphy, Jeffrie G. and Coleman, Jules L. (1984), The Philosophy of Law: An Introduction to
Jurisprudence, Totowa, Rowman and Allenheld.
Nagel, Bernhard (1993), Wirtschaftsrecht I, Grundrechte und Einfhrung in das Brgerliche
Recht, 3 edn (Basic Rights and an Introduction into the Private Law), Mnchen, Lehrbuch.
0000 Introductory Books 3
Torres Lopez, Juan (1987), Anlisis Econmico del Derecho. Panorama doctrinal (Survey on
Law and Economics), Madrid, Editorial Tecnos.
Tullock, Gordon (1971), The Logic of the Law, New York, Basic Books, 278 p.
Van Velthoven, Ben C.J., Van Wijck, Peter W. et al. (1997), Recht en Efficintie (Law and
Efficiency), Deventer, Kluwer, 337 p.
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1990), The Economics of Law - An Introductory Text, London, Institute of
Economic Affairs, 95 p. (Hobart Paperback).
Vodinelic, V. Vladimir (1991), Gradjansko Pravo - Uvodne Teme (Civil Law - Introductory
Themes), Belgrade.
Weise, Peter, Eger, Thomas, Brandes, Wolfgang and Kraft, M. (1993), Neue Mikrokonomie (New
Microeconomics), Heidelberg, Physica.
0010
INTRODUCTORY ARTICLES
Copyright 1999 Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest
Adams, Michael (1986), Der Irrtum ber knftige Sachverhalte - Anwendungsbeispiel und
Einfrhung in die konomische Analyse des Rechts, RECHT, Zeitschrift fr juristische
Ausbildung und Praxis, 14-23.
Albert, Hans (1986), Law as an Instrument of Rational Choice, in Daintith, Terence and Teubner,
Gunther (eds), Contract and Organisation: Legal Analysis in the Law, Berlin, Walter de
Gruyter, 25-51.
Alpa, Guido (1983), Interpretazione economica del Diritto (Economic Interpretation of Law), in X
(ed.), Voce del Novissimo Digesto Italiano, Torino, UTET, 315-324.
Alpa, Guido (1984), Diritto e Analisi Economica (a proposito di un recente libro di R. Bowles)
(Law and Economic Analysis, With Regard to a Recent Book by R. Bowles), Diritto dell
impresa, 111-120.
Aprile, Ercole (1989), Regolamentazione dei Fenomeni Economici e Analisi Economica degli
Strumenti Giuridici: Spunti per una Riflessione (Regulation of Economic Phenomena and
Economic Analysis of Legal Instruments: Hints for a Reflection), Nuovo Diritto, 505-521.
Arruada, Benito (1991), Nobel al Giro Coasiano (Nobel to the Coasian Turn), 41 Revista de
Economa, 122-126.
Assmann, Heinz-Dieter (1989), Kommentar on Ott, Allokationseffizienz, Rechtsdogmatik und
Rechtsprechung, in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), Allekationseffizienz in der
Rechtsordnung, Berlin, Springer, 45-49.
Bakker, Luit M. et al. (1996), Economie en Recht: van Confrontatie naar Integratie (Economics
and Law: From Confrontation to Integration), in Van de Hoek, M.P. (ed.), Opstellen
aangeboden aan prof. dr. C. Rijnvos, Groningen, Wolters-Noordhoff, 102-111.
Barbera, Salvador (1989), Los derechos individuales en el anlisis econmico (Individual rights
and economic analysis), 38 Economistas.
Behrens, Peter (1981), Aspekte einer konomischen Theorie des Rechts (Aspects of an Economic
Theory of Law), 12 Rechtstheorie, 472-490.
Behrens, Peter (1988), ber das Verhltnis der Rechtswissen schaft zur Nationalkonomie: Die
konomischen Grundlagen des Rechts (On the Interrelationship between Law and
Economics), in Boettcher, Erik, Herder-Dorneich, Philipp and Schenk, Karl-Ernst (eds),
Jahrbuch fr neue politische konomie 7, Tbingen, Mohr, 209-228.
Bongaerts, Jan C. (1986), Inleiding tot de Economische Analyse van het Recht met Toepassing op
het Contractenrecht en het Aansprakelijkheidsrecht, Inzonderheid de Milieuramp te Bhopal
(Introduction to Economic Analysis of Law, with Applications to Contract and Tort Law, and
in Particular to the Environmental Disaster in Bhopal), in Van Den Bergh, Roger (ed.),
Verslagboek Eerste Werkvergadering Recht en Economie, Antwerpen, Leerstoel A. Van
Melkebeke, Handelshogeschool, 5-20.
5
6 Introductory Articles 0010
Cabrillo, Francisco (1987), ?Por Qu un Anlisis Econmico del Derecho? (Why an Economic
Analysis of Law?), 58 Revista de Occidente, 37-46.
Cabrillo, Francisco (1990), Una Nueva Frontera: El Anlisis Econmico del Derecho (A New
Frontier: Law and Economics), 687 Informacin Comercial Espaola, 9-22.
Calsamiglia, Albert (1988), Justicia, Eficiencia y Derecho (Equity, Efficiency and the Law), 1
Revista del Centro de Estudios Constitucionales, 327 ff.
Campbell, C. and Wiles, P. (1976), The Study of Law in Society, 10 Law and Society Review,
547-578.
Casas Pardo, Jos, Las Estructuras Federal y Fiscal de las Democracias Representativa y Directa
como Modelos para una Union Europea Federal (Federal and Fiscal Structures in
Representative and Direct Democracies as Models for a Federal European Union), in X (ed.),
Actas de las Jornadas de Estudio sobre La Constitucion espaola y el ordenamineto
comunitario europeo (II), Direccin General del Servicio Juridico del Estado, Ministerio de
Justicia.
Casas Pardo, Jos, Algunas Consideraciones sobre la Teora de la Eleccin Pblica (Some
Considerations on Public Choice Theory), in Beltran, Lucas, Libro Homanaje, Madrid,
Editorial Moneda y Credito.
Casas Pardo, Jos, The Spanish Transition to Democracy: a Public Choice Approach, in
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (ed.), The Political Economy of Structural Change, Cheltenham, Edward
Elgar.
Casas Pardo, Jos (forthcoming), El Contractualismo-Constitucionalismo Liberal de James M.
Buchanan (James M. Buchanans Liberal Contractualism-Constitutionalism), in Cortina, A.
(ed.), tica de los Negocios, Bancaja, Valencia, Fundacin Etnor.
Casas Pardo, Jos (1979), El Control de los Efectos Econmicos Externos por Medio de la
Imposicin (Controlling Externalities with Taxation), Revista de Derecho Financiero y
Hacienda Pblica.
Casas Pardo, Jos (1984), Estudio Introductorio (Introductory Study), in Buchanan, James M. and
Tollison, Robert D. (eds), Anlisis Econmico de los Polticos (Economic Analysis of the
Politicians), Madrid, Instituto de Estudios Econmicos.
Casas Pardo, Jos (1987), Laudatio Academica, in Casas Pardo, J. and Bru Parra, S. (eds),
Economa y Poltica (Economics and Politics), Valencia, Servei de Publicacions, Universitat de
Valencia.
Casas Pardo, Jos (1991), Sobre la Relevancia de la Economa Constitucional (About the
Relevance of Constitutional Economy), in X (ed.), Homenaje al Prof. D. Carlos Otero Daz,
Universidad de Santiago de Compostela.
Casas Pardo, Jos (1993), Anlisis Econmico de las Instituciones y de las Reglas (Economic
Analysis of the Institutions and Rules), in Puy Fraga, P. (ed.), Anlisis econmico del
Derecho y de la Poltica, Santiago de Compostela, Fundacin Alfredo Braas.
Casas Pardo, Jos (1995a), Introduccin (Introduction), in Casas Pardo, J. and Schneider, F. (eds),
Current Issues in Public Choice, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
Casas Pardo, Jos (1995b), Does Ethical Proceduralism Underly Buchanans Constitutional
Contractualism?, in Casas Pardo, J. and Schneider, F. (eds), Current Issues in Public Choice,
Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
Casas Pardo, Jos and Brennan, Geoffrey (1978), A Reading of the Spanish Constitution, 1
Constitutional Political Economy.
8 Introductory Articles 0010
Casas Pardo, Jos and Brennan, Geoffrey (1990), La Constitucin espaola a la luz de la
Economa poltica de las constituciones (The Spanish Constitution from the Political Economy
of Constitutions Approach), 116-3 Hacienda Pblica Espaola.
Casas Pardo, Jos and Fernndez Cainzos, J., Las Contituciones Econmica y Fiscal en la
Constitucin Espaola de 1978 (The Economic and Fiscal Constitutions into the Spanish
Constitution of 1978), in Alvarez Conde, E. (ed.), La Constitucin espaola de 1978 diez
aos despues, Madrid, Tecnos.
Casas Pardo, Jos and Fernndez Cainzos, J. (1995), La Imposicin a Traves de la Regulacin en
Espaa: Un intento de medir la imposicin implicita en el sistema financiero espaol en la
dcada 1977-1987 (Taxation Through Regulation in Spain: An Effort to Measure Implicit
Taxation in the Spanish Financial System between 1977-1987), in X (ed.), Estudios de
Derecho Mercantil en Homenaje al Prof. Manuel Broseta Pont, Tirant lo Blanch, Valecia.
Casas Pardo, Jos and Navarro, Puchades M. (forthcoming), La Perspectiva de la Public Choice
en el Anlisis de la Actuacin de los Entes Pblicos (Public Choice Approach and the
Behaviour of Public Enterprises), in X (ed.), Actas del II Congreso Espaol de Ciencia
Politica y de la Administracin.
Casas Pardo, Jos and Sainz Snchez, E. (1995), La Coaccin de las Instituciones Colectivas
(Compelling Collective Institutions), in Sainz Snchez, E. (ed.), Las Organizaciones como
sistemas Constitucionales, Granada, Ensayos sobre el Modelo de Gestin Burocratica de la
Universidad Pblica, Mtodo Ediciones.
Cherot, Jean-Yves (1987a), Trois Thses de lAnalyses Economique du Droit (Three Theses of
Economic Analysis of Law), Revue de la Recherche Juridique.
Cherot, Jean-Yves (1987b), Trois Thses sur lAnalyse Economique du Droit - Quelques Usages
de lApproche Economique des Rgles Juridiques (Three Theses on Economic Analysis of Law
- Some Uses of the Economic Approach to Legal Rules), 2 Revue de la Recherche Juridique.
Cooter, Robert D. (1982a), The Cost of Coase, 11 Journal of Legal Studies, 1-33. Reprinted in
Donahue, Charles Jr, Kauper, Thomas E. and Martin, Peter W., Property: An Introduction to
the Concept and the Institution, 1992. Reprinted in Ackerman, Bruce, Ellickson, Robert and
Rose, Carol, Foundations of Property Law, 1995. Reprinted in Medema, Steven G. (ed.), The
Legacy of Ronald Coase in Economic Analysis, Aldershot, Edward Elgar Publishing, 96-128.
Cooter, Robert D. (1982b), Law and the Imperialism of Economics: An Introduction to the
Economic Analysis of Law by Reviewing Some Major Books, 29 UCLA Law Review,
1260-1269.
Cooter, Robert D. (1985), Prices and Sanctions, 84 Columbia Law Review, 1523-1560.
Cooter, Robert D. (1993), Diritto ed Economia (Law and Economics), Istituto DellEnciclopedia
Italiana, Fondata Da Giovanni Treccani, 98-106.
Cooter, Robert D. (1994), Laws and Prices: How Economics Contributed to Law By
Misunderstanding Morality, 3 Iuris: Quaderns de Poltica Jurdica, 35-36.
Cooter, Robert D. (1995), Law and Unified Social Theory, 22 Law and Society, 50-67. Reprinted
in Galligan, D.J. (ed.), Socio-Legal Studies in Context: The Oxford Centre Past and Future,
Blackwell Publishers, Oxford, 1995, pp. 50-67.
Cooter, Robert D. and Rubinfeld, Daniel L. (1989), Economic Analysis of Legal Disputes and
Their Resolution, 27 Journal of Economic Literature, 1067-1097.
0010 Introductory Articles 9
Reprinted in Posner, Richard A. and Parisi, Francesco (eds), Law and Economics, Edward
Elgar, 1996 forthcoming.
Cooter, Robert D. and Rubinfeld, Daniel L. (1990), Trial Courts: An Economic Perspective, 24
Law and Society Review, 533 ff.
Cortenraad, Wouter H.F.M. (1996), Rechtseconomie Bestaat Niet (Theres no Such Thing as Law
and Economics), 71 Nederlands Juristen Blad, 963-967.
Cosentino, Fabrizio (1990), Analisi Economica del Eiritto: Ritorno al Futuro? (Economic Analysis
of Law: Back to the Future?), 5 Foro Italiano, 153-156.
Crombach, H.F.M. and Van Dun, Frank (1990), Recht en Economie in Utopia: een
Rechtsfilosofisch Gedachtenexperiment (Law and Economics in Utopia: a Mental Experiment
in Legal Philosophy), 4 Rechtsgeleerd Magazijn Themis, 167-176.
De Bock, Ruth (1990), Inleiding (Introduction), 39(10) Ars Aequi in Bock, Ruth de et al. (eds),
Themanummer Rechtseconomie, 607-613.
De Bock, Ruth et al. (1990), Themanummer Rechtseconomie (Special Issue Law and Economics),
39(10) Ars Aequi, 607-804.
De Geest, Gerrit (1990), Public Choice en Rechtseconomie (Public Choice and Law and
Economics), 39(10) Ars Aequi in Bock, Ruth de et al. (eds), Themanummer Rechtseconomie,
666-673.
Dnes, Antony W. (1992), Franchising, in Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray and Newman, Peter
(eds), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance, London, Macmillan.
Dnes, Antony W. (1994a), Law and Economics, 10 Policy, 39-42.
Dnes, Antony W. (1994b), Legal Economics, 2 Hume Papers on Public Policy, 56-62.
Dooyeweerd, H. (1949), De Sociologische Verhouding tussen Recht en Economie en het Probleem
van het Zogeheten Economisch Recht (The Sociological Relationship Between Law and
Economics and the Problem of So-called Economic Law), in Dooyeweerd, H. (ed.),
Opstellen op het gebied van Recht, Staat en Maatschappij, Amsterdam, Bakker, 221-264.
Dorndorf, Eberhard (1995), Modelle des Rechtssystems in der konomischen Analyse des Rechts
(Models of the Legal System in Law and Economics), in X. (ed.), konomie und Gesellschaft.
Jahrbuch 11, Markt, Norm und Moral, Frankfurt/New York, 127-159.
Duggan, A.J. (1989a), New Directions in Legal Theory: Law and Economics, 63 Law Institute
Journal, 852-853.
Duggan, A.J. (1989b), Law and Economics in Australia, 1 Legal Education Review, 37-41.
Eger, Thomas (1989), Einfhrung in die konomische Analyse des Rechts (Introduction to the
Economic Analysis of Law), in Nagel, B. (ed.), Wirtschaftsrecht II, Mnchen, Oldenborg,
18-35.
Eide, Erling (1992), Rettskonomi - en Introduksjon (Law and Economics - an introduction), 4
Jussens Venner, 193-224.
Fezer, Karl-Heinz (1986), Aspekte einer Rechtskritik an der Economic Analysis of Law und am
Property Rights Approach (Critcal Aspects of the Economic Analysis of Law and the Property
Rights Approach from a Lawyers Viewpoint), 41 Juristenzeitung, 817-824.
Fezer, Karl-Heinz (1988), Nochmals, Kritik an der konomischen Analyse des Rechts (More
Critics on Law and Economics), 43 Juristenzeitung, 223 ff.
10 Introductory Articles 0010
Field, A.J. (1991), Do Legal Systems Matter?, 28(1) Explorations in Economic History, 1-35.
Fluet, Claude (1990), LAnalyse Economique du Droit (Economic Analysis of Law), 43(3)
conomie Applique, 53-66.
Garoupa, Nuno (1997), The Theory of Optimal Law Enforcement, 11 Journal of Economic
Surveys, 267-295.
Gay, David E.R. (1979), A Curriculum Note on the New Law and Economics, Papers and
Proceedings of the Southwestern Society of Economists, 59-66.
Gay, David E.R. (1981a), Towards a Theory of Entitlements in Comparative Economics, 25
Rivista Internazionale di Scienze Economiche e Commerciali, 1021-1028.
Gay, David E.R. (1981b), Entitlements and Public Policy, 18 Social Science Journal, 87-100.
Gay, David E.R. (1992), Teaching Privatization in the Soviet Union: An Experimental Economics
Approach, 1 Classroom Expernomics, 5-6.
Gay, David E.R. (1994), Incentives and Privatization: An Experimental Economics Approach, 22
Atlantic Economic Journal, 79 ff.
Gay, David E.R. and Waters, Alan R. (1982), On the Economic Theory of Legal Systems, 29
Rivista Internazionale di Scienze Economiche e Commerciali, 433-441.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1998), Oi Theoretikes Vaseis tes Oikonomikes Analyses tou Dikaiou (The
Theoretical Bases of Economic Analysis of Law), 46 Nomiko Vema.
Georgakopoulos, Nicholas L. (1995), Peri Tmematikou Daneismou apo ten Amerikani ke Nomike
Skepse (On the Partial Borrowing from the American Legal Thought), 43 Nomiko Vema,
799-807.
Guest, Stephen F.D. (1984), The Economics of Law, Current Legal Problems, 233-245.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1996), Neofileleutherismos, Dikaio ten Oikonomike Analyse ton Thesmon:
Eisagoge ste Melete ton Neon Oikonomikon Theorion gia to Dikaio, ten Koinonia kai ten
Politike (The so-called Neo-Liberalism, the Law and the Economic Analysis of Institutions:
Introduction to the Study of the New Economic Theories on Law, Society and Politics), 6
Aissymnetes.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1997), Eisagoge sten Oikonomike Analyse tou Dikaiou (Introduction to the
Economic Analysis of Law), Aristotle University of Thessaloniki School of Law and
Economics, Department of History, Philosophy and Sociology of Law.
Hayashida, Seimei (1992), Ho to Keizai, Keizaibunseki, Hihan to Paradaimu (Law and
Economics, Economic Analysis, its Critique and Paradigm), 42 Hokudai Hogaku Ronshu
(Hokkaido Law Review), 905-956. Part 2 pp. 1234-1272.
Heyne, Paul (1984), The Economics of Law: Economic Imperialism in Negligence Law, No Fault
Insurance, Occupational Licensing and Criminology: Comment, 67 Australian Economic
Review, 109-112.
Hollander, Abraham and Mackaay, Ejan (1980), Are Judges Economists at Heart?, in Ciampi,
Costanino (ed.), Artificial Intelligence and Legal Information Systems, Amsterdam, North
Holland, 129-149.
Hondius, E.H., Schippers, Joop J. and Siegers, Jacques J. (eds) (1991), Rechtseconomie: Brug
tussen twee disciplines (Law and Economics: Bridge between two Disciplines), in Hondius,
E.H., Schippers, J.J. and Siegers, J.J. (eds), Rechtseconomie en Recht, Zwolle, Tjeenk Willink,
1-7.
0010 Introductory Articles 11
Hotz, Beat (1982), konomische Analyse des Rechts - eine Skeptische Betrachtung (Economic
Analysis of Law - A Sceptical Reflection), 34 Wirtschaft und Recht, 293-314.
Johnsen, D. Bruce (1994), Property Rights to Investment Research: The Agency Costs of Soft
Dollar Brokerage, 11 Yale Journal on Regulation, 75-113.
Johnsen, D. Bruce (1995), The Quasi-Rent Structure of Corporate Entreprise: A Transaction Cost
Theory, 44 Emory Law Journal, 1277 ff.
Johnsen, D. Bruce, Habib, Michel A. and Naik, Narayan Y. (forthcoming), Spin-offs and
Information, Journal of Financial Intermediation.
Jongbloed, A.W. (1993), Recht, Economie en Rechtseconomie (Law, Economics and Law and
Economics), 85(10) Rechtsstrijd, 204-210.
Kanniainen, Vesa, Mtt, Kalle and Heimonen, Matti (1995), Oikeustaloustiede - Law and
Economics, Oikeus, 107-124.
Karakantas, Stylianos (1973), Oikonomia kai Dikaion (Law and Economics), 27
Harmenopoulos, 257-265.
Kirby, M.D. (1981), Economics and Law: Symbiosis, 23 Reform, 86-90.
Kirchner, Christian (1978), konomische Analyse des Rechts, Interdisziplinre Zusammenarbeit
von konomie und Rechtswissenschaft (Economic Analysis of Law and Interdisciplinary
Cooperation of Jurisprudence and Economics), in Assmann, Heinz-Dieter, Kirchner, Christian
and Schanze, Erich (eds), konomische Analyse des Rechts, Kronberg, Athenum, 75-91.
Kitch, Edmund W. (1983), The Intellectual Foundations of Law and Economics', 33 Journal of
Legal Education, 184-196.
Kleinewefers, Henner (1987), konomische Theorie des Rechts, ber Unterschiede Zwischen dem
konomischen und dem Juristischen Denken (Economic Theory of Law, on the Differences
between), in X (ed.), Staat und Gesellschaft, Festschrift fr Leo Schrm, Fribourg,
Universittsverlag, 83-116.
Koboldt, Christian, Leder, Mathias and Schmidtchen, Dieter (1992), konomische Analyse des
Rechts (Law and Economics), 7 Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Studium.
Koboldt, Christian, Leder, Mathias and Schmidtchen, Dieter (1995), konomische Analyse des
Rechts (Law and Economics), in Nobert, Berthold (ed.), Allgemeine Wirtschaftstheorie,
Mnchen, 355-384.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1984), The Great Image of Authority, 36 Stanford Law Review, 349 ff.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1985), Lanalyse conomique Du Droit (The Economic Analysis of Law),
118-119 Revue de Synthese, 313 ff.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1986), Economic Analysis of Law, 16 Materiali per una Storia della
Cultura Giuridica, 233 ff.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1988), Economique (Analyse - du droit), in Arnaud, Andr-Jean (ed.),
Dictionnaire Encyclopedique de Theorie et de Sociologie du Droit, Librairie General de
Droit et de Jurisprudence.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1992), Analise Economica do Direito, 43(2) Sub Judica: Justica e
Sociedade.
Ktz, Hein (1993), Die konomische Analyse des Rechts (Law and Economics), Zeitschrift fr
die gesamte Versicherungswissenschaft, 57-70.
Kozyris, Phaedon I. (1991), Treis Provlematismoi sten Amerikanike Theoria tou Dikaiou (Three
Conjectures in American Jurisprudence), 39 Nomiko Vema, 715-728.
12 Introductory Articles 0010
Kozyris, Phaedon I. (1996), Protaseis Dianemetikes Dikaiosynes sto Telos tes Istorias: Ta Kyria
Erotemata me Apla Logia (Proposals of Distributive Justice in the End of History: Basic
Questions Made Easy), 3 Kritike Epitheorese, 23-81.
Kunz, Harald (1987), Recht und konomie (Law and Economics), 39 Arbeitgeber.
Larson, Bruce A. and Bromley, Daniel W. (1990), Property Rights, Externalities, and Resource
Degradation: Locating the Tragedy, 33 Journal of Development Economics, 235-362.
Liakopoulos, Thanases (1982), Dikaio kai Oikonomia (Law and Economics), 2 Dikaio kai
Politike, 111-133.
Llebot Majo, Jos Oriol (1996), Doctrina y Teora de la Empresa en el Derecho Mercantil (Una
Aproximacin al Significado de la Teora Contractual de la Empresa) (Doctrine and Theory of
the Firm in Contract Law Approaching the Meaning of Corporate Contractual Theory), 210
Revista de Derecho Mercantil, 319-388.
Llewellyn, Karl N. (1925), The Effect of Legal Institutions upon Economics, 15 American
Economic Review, 665-683.
Loukopoulos, Andreas D. (1962), Emporikon Dikaion kai oi Neoi Prosanatolismoi tes Oikonomias
(Commercial Law and the New Directions of Economy), 29 Ephemeris ton Hellenon
Nomikon, 353-362.
Mackaay, Ejan (1986), La Rgle Juridique Observe par le Prisme de lEconomiste - une Histoire
Stylise du Mouvement dAnalyse Economique du Droit (Law Observed through an
Economists Eyeglass - A Stylised History of the Law and Economics Movement), 1 Revue
internationale de Droit Economique, 43-88.
Mackaay, Ejan (1988a), LOrdre Spontan Comme Fondement du Droit - un Survol des Modles
de lmergence des Rgles dans une Socit Civile (Spontaneous Order as Foundation of Law -
A Survey of Models of the Emergence of Rules in Civil Society), 22 Revue Juridique Themis,
347-383.
Mackaay, Ejan (1988b), Het Recht Bezien door de Bril van de Economist - Een Gestyleerd
Overzicht van de Rechtseconomie (Law Seen Through Economists Glasses: An Overview),
Rechtsgeleerd Magazijn Themis, 411-452.
Mackaay, Ejan (1991), Verschuivingen in De Rechtseconomie (Shifts in Law and Economics), 66
Nederlands Juristenblad, 1505-1521.
Manne, Henry G. (1994), Le Origini Intellettuali di una Scuola di Analisi Economica del Diritto,
12 Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato, 167-181.
Mantzoufas, Georgios A. (1960), Oikonomikon Dikaion (Economic Law), in X (ed.), Oikomike
kai Logistike Egkyklopedeia (Encyclopedia of Economics and Accounting), Athens.
Mas-Colell, Andreu (1994), LAnlisi Econmica i el Dret (The Economic Analysis and the Law),
3 Iuris, 73-84.
Mengaroni, F. (1988), Analisi Economica del Diritto (Economic Analysis of Law), 1
Enciclopedia Giuridica, 1-9.
Mercuro, Nicholas (1986), Contributions to Law and Economics: A Survey of Recent Books,
17(4) Journal of Economic Education, 295-309.
Mercuro, Nicholas (1989), Towards a Comparative Institutional Approach to the Study of Law and
Economics, in Mercuro, Nicholas (ed.), Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic
Publishers, 1-26.
Mercuro, Nicholas and Medema, Steven G. (1995), Schools of Thought in Law and Economics: A
Kuhnian Competition, in Malloy, Robin P. and Braun, Christopher K. (eds),
0010 Introductory Articles 13
Law and Economics: New and Critical Perspectives, New York, Peter Lang, 65-126.
Mohr, K. and Wehrt, Klaus (1995), Einbau der konomischen Analyse des Rechts in ein
Juristisches Fallgutachten (Implementing the Economic Analysis of Law into a Legal
Opinion), 10 JURA, 536-542.
Mouly, Christian (1987), Prsentation du Colloque sur lAnalyse Economique du Droit
(Introduction to the Symposium of Economic Analysis of Law), Revue de la Recherche
Juridique, 413 ff.
Nentjes, Andries (1987), De Economie van het Recht (The Economy of the Law), oratie
Groningen, s.l., 18 p.
Ogus, Anthony I. (1980), Economics, Liberty and the Common Law, 18 Journal of Society of
Public Teachers of Law, 42-57.
Oker-Blom, Max (1980), Jurionomi eller Rtten i Ekonomiskt Perspektiv (Law and Economics or
Law from the Economic Perspective), Tidskrift utgiven av Juridiska Freningen i Finland,
245-265.
Oppetit, B. (1992), Droit et Economie (Law and Economics), 37 Archives de Philosophie du
Droit. Nouvelle serie, 17 ff.
Ott, Claus (1989), Allokationseffizienz, Rechtsdogmatik und Rechtsprechung - die Immanente
konomische Rationalitt des Zivilrechts (Allocative Efficiency, Legal Dogmatics and
Jurisprudence - The Immanent Rationality of Private Laws), in Ott, Claus and Schfer,
Hans-Bernd (eds), Allekationseffizienz in der Rechtsordnung, Berlin, Springer, 25-44.
Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (1988), Die konomische Analyse des Rechts. Irrweg oder
Chance wissenschaftlicher Rechtserkenntnis? (The Economic Analysis of Law. Wrong Track or
Chance), Juristenzeitung, 213-223.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1982), Luci ed Ombre Nell Analisi Economica del Diritto (Appunti in Margine
ad un Libro Recente) (Lights and Shadows in Law and Economics - Notes about a Recent
Book), 2 Rivista di Diritto Civile, 718-728.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1987), Analisi Economica del Diritto (Economic Analysis of Law), 1 Digesto
Civile, 309-320.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1988), Tutela Specifica e Tutela per Equivalente nella Prospettiva dellAnalisi
Economica del Diritto (Specific Performance and Damages: An EAL Perspective),
Quadrimestre, 76-97.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1989), Un Moderno Minotauro: Law and Economics (A Modern Minotaur:
Law and Economics), Economia, Societ e Istituzioni, 519-534.
Pasquini, Nello (1983), Interpretazione Giuridica e Analisi Economica - in Margine ad un
Reading Recente (Legal Interpretation and Economic Analysis with Recent Reading),
Rivista trimestrale di Diritto e Procedura Civile, 288-300.
Pastor, Santos (1984), Una Introduccin al Anlisis Econmico del Derecho (An Introduction to
Law and Economics), 89 Hacienda Pblica Espaola.
Pastor, Santos (1989), Economa y Sistema Jurdico. Una Introduccin al Anlisis Econmico
del Derecho (Economics and the Legal System. An Introduction to Economic Analysis of
Law), Madrid, Tecnos.
Pastor, Santos and Pintos, Jess (1992), La Economa y el Derecho: una Colaboracin Difcil pero
Provechosa (The Interaction Between Law and Economics: Problems and Progress), 13
Revista de Economa, 96-100.
14 Introductory Articles 0010
Paz-Ares, Cndido (1985), Seguridad Jurdica y Seguridad del Trfico (Legal Certainty and
Exhange Certainty), Revista de Derecho Mercantil.
Phillips, A. (1956), Concentration, Scale, and Technological Change in Selected Manufacturing
Industries, 1899-1939', 4(3) Journal of Industrial Economics, 179-193.
Phillips, A. (1957), Price Discrimination and the Large Firm: Hobsons Choice in the Pectin
Industry, 43(5) Virginia Law Review, 685-696.
Phillips, A. (1959), A Critique of U.S. Experience with Price-Fixing and the Per Se Rule, 8(3)
Journal of Industrial Economics, 13-32. Reprinted in Blumner, S.M. and Hefner, D.L. (eds),
Readings in the Regulation of Business.
Phillips, A. (1960), A Theory of Interfirm Organization, 74(4) Quarterly Journal of Economics,
602-613. Reprinted in Evans, M.D. (ed.), Interorganizational Relations, New York, Penguin
Books, 1976.
Phillips, A. (1961), Policy Implications of the Theory of Interfirm Organization, 51(2) American
Economic Review, 245-254.
Phillips, A. (1964a), Competition, Confusion and Commercial Banking, 19(1) Journal of
Finance, 32-45.
Phillips, A. (1964b), Reciprocity Under the Antitrust Laws: Observations on Hales Comment,
133(1) University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 77-79. Reprinted in 4(4) Journal of Reprints
for Antitrust Law and Economics, 1973.
Phillips, A. (1965), Market Structure, Innovation and Investment, in Alderson, W., Terpstra, V.
and Shapiro, S.V. (eds), Patents and Progress, Homewood IL, Richard D. Irwin, 37-58.
Phillips, A. (1967a), Structural and Regulatory Reform for Commercial Banking, in Hart, A.G.,
Pontecorvo, J. and Shay, R. (eds), Issues in Banking and Monetary Analysis, New York, Holt,
Rinehart and Winston, 7-30.
Phillips, A. (1967b), Bank Mergers, Branching and Holding Companies in the Commonwealth of
Pennsylvania, 115(4) Pennsylvania Law Review, 560-588.
Phillips, A. (1968), An Attempt to Synthesize Some Recent Contributions to the Theory of the
Firm, in Phillips, A. and Williamson, O.E. (eds), Prices: Issues in Theory, Practice and
Public Policy, Philadelphia PA, University of Pennsylvania Press, 32-44. Reprinted in Narver,
John C. and Savitt, Ronald (eds), Conceptual Readings in the Market Economy, Boston, Holt,
Rinehart and Winston, 1971.
Phillips, A. (1970a), Structure, Conduct and Performance - and Performance, Conduct and
Structure?, in Markham, J.W. and Papanek, G. (eds), Industrial Organization and Economic
Development: Essays in Honor of Edward S. Mason, Boston, Houghton Mifflin, 26-37.
Phillips, A. (1970b), Antitrust Policies: Could they be Tools of the Establishment?, in Sichel,
Werner (ed.), Antitrust Policy and Economy Welfare, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan
Press, 54-80.
Phillips, A. (1971a), Technological Change in the Regulated Industries, in Capron, William (ed.),
Technological Change in the Regulated Industries, Washington, Brookings Institution,
123-165.
Phillips, A. (1971b), Patents, Potential Competition and Technological Progress, 56(2) American
Economic Review, 301-310. Reprinted in 3 The Journal of Reprints for Antitrust Law and
Economics, 1971.
0010 Introductory Articles 15
Phillips, A. and Hall, George R. (1960), The Salk Vaccine Case: Parallelism, Conspiracy and
Other Hypotheses, 45(4) Virginia Law Review, 717-728.
Phillips, A. and Stevenson, Rodney E. (1974), The Historical Development of Industrial
Organization, 6(3) History of Political Economy, 324-342.
Picot, Arnold and Dietl, Helmut (1993), Neue Institutionenkonomie und Recht (New Institutional
Economics and Law), in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Analyse des
Unternehmensrechts, Beitrge zum 3. Travemnder Symposium zur konomischen Analyse
des Rechts, Heidelberg, Physica Verlag, 306-330.
Polinsky, A. Mitchell (1974), Economic Analysis as a Potentially Defective Product: A Buyers
Guide to Posners Economic Analysis of Law, 87 Harvard Law Review, 1655-1681.
Posner, Richard A. (1975), The Economic Approach to Law, 53 Texas Law Review, 757-782.
Posner, Richard A. (1979), Some Uses and Abuses of Economics in Law, 46 University of
Chicago Law Review, 281-306.
Posner, Richard A. (1987), The Law and Economics Movement, 77 American Economic Review.
Papers and Proceedings, 1-13.
Prasad, Ravi (1993), Recent Developments in Regulation and Its Review, Office of Regulation
Review.
Prasad, Ravi (1995), Regulation and its Review 1994-95', Office of Regulation Review.
Prisching, Manfred (1979), konomische Rechtslehre? ber die Prmissen und Grenzen des
Economic Approach im Recht (Economic Jurisprudence? On the Premisses and Limits of the
Economic Approach to Law), in Freisitzer, Kurt, Holzer, Hans Ludwig, Mantl, Wolfgang and
Hflechner, Walter (eds), Reformen des Rechts. Festschrift zur 200-Jahr-Feier der
Rechtswissenschaftlichen Fakult der Universitt Graz, Graz, Akademische Druck u.
Verlagsanstalt, 995-1020.
Pulitini, Francesco (1967), Regole Giuridiche e Teoria Economica (Law and Economic Theory),
Politica del Diritto, 297-310.
Raes, Koen (1990), Het Recht van de Schaarste (The Law of Scarcety), 16 Recht en Kritiek,
380-394.
Raes, Koen and Willekens, Harry (1994), Grondproblemen en Mogelijkheden (Basic Problems
and Options), in Raes, Koen and Willekens, H. (eds), Economische Verklaringen van het
Recht, Den Haag, VUGA, 9-43.
Rahmsdorf, Detlev W. and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (1980), konomische Analyse des Rechts - Ein
Gegentrend? (Economic Analysis of Law - A Controversy?), in Voigt, R. (ed.),
Verrechtlichung, Kningstein/Ts., Athenum, 94-108.
Raiteri, Monica (1988), Giustizia Distributiva e Funzione Giudiziaria: Qualche Osservazione nella
Prospettiva della Analisi Economica del Diritto (Distributive Justice and the Judicial Function,
So), Materiali per una storia della cultura giuridica, 209-228.
Rodano, Giorgio (1989), Il Giudice e lEfficienza del Mercato. Riflessioni di un Economista su un
Libro di Diritto Comparato (The Judge and the Efficiency of the Market. An Eco), Rivista
Critica del Diritto Privato, 293-312.
Rokas, Ioannis (1980), Oikonomike kai Nomike Episteme: Eisagogikes Paratereseis epi ton
Scheseon Oikonomias kai Dikaiou (Economics and Legal Science: Introductory Remarks on
the Relations between Economy and Law), in Zepos, P., Rammos G., Rokas K. and
0010 Introductory Articles 17
Sevic, Zeljko (1996), Law and Economics I: Ekonomska analiza prava svojine u tranziciji (Law
and Economics I: Economic Analysis of the Property Rights in Transition), Pravni zivot .
Sevic, Zeljko (1997a), Svetska Trgovinska Organizacija: Pravni i institucionalni aspekti (World
Trade Organization: Legal and Institutional Aspects), 52(1-2) Finansije, 139-146.
Sevic, Zeljko (1997b), Law and Economics of (Economic) Policy Reform, in Sevic, Zeljko and
Wright, Glendal (eds), Transition in Central and Eastern Europe, Belgrade, YASF Student
Cultural Centre, 152-172.
Sevic, Zeljko and Zorica, Vukasinovic (1997), Reforma Drzavne Uprave: Pravno-ekonomska i
Finansijska Analiza (Civil Service Reform: Law and Economics and Financial Management
Analyses), 46(9) Pravni zivot, 815-831.
Sinde Monteiro, Jorge (1981), Analise Economica do Direito (Economic Analysis of Law), 57
Boletim da Faculdade de Direito de Universidade de Coimbra, 247-251.
Sjaastad, Espen and Bromley, Daniel W. (1997), Indigenous Land Rights in Sub-Saharan Africa:
Appropriation, Security and Investment Demand, 25 World Development, 549-562.
Skogh, Gran (1982), Den Osynliga Handen och Lagens Lnga Arm (The Invisible Hand and the
Laws Long Arm), 8 Ekonomisk Debatt.
Stankovic Vladeta (1991), Pravo Privrednog Sistema (Law of the Economic System), 1-3 Anali
Pravnog fakulteta u Beogradu, 277-288.
Stolz, Peter (1983), Das Wiedererwachte Interesse der konomie an Rechtlichen und Politischen
Institutionen (The Renewed Interest of Economics in Legal and Political Institutions), 119
Schweizerische Zeitschrift fr Volkswirtschaft und Statistik, 49-67.
Stout, Lynn A. (1981), Note: The Case for Mandatory Separate Filing by Married Persons, 91
Yale Law Journal, 363-382.
Stout, Lynn A. (1990), Are Takeover Premiums Really Premiums? Market Price, Fair Value, and
Corporate Law, 99 Yale Law Journal, 1235-1296.
Stout, Lynn A. (1992), Strict Scrutiny and Social Choice: An Economic Inquiry Into Fundamental
Rights and Suspect Classifications, 80 Georgetown Law Journal, 1787-1834.
Stout, Lynn A. (1993), Poverty and Failure in the Market for Human Capital, Georgetown Law
Journal, 1947-1959.
Stout, Lynn A. (1996), Insurance or Gambling? Derivatives Trading in a World of Risk and
Uncertainty, 39 Brookings Review.
Strasser, Kurt A., Bard, Robert L. and Arthur, H. Thomas (1982), A Readers Guide to the Uses
and Limits of Economic Analysis with Emphasis on Corporation Law, 33 Mercer Law
Review, 571-593.
Strowel, Alain (1987), Utilitarisme et Approche Economique dans la Thorie du Droit. Autour de
Bentham et de Posner (Utilitarianism and Economic Approach in Legal Theory. On Bentham
and Posner), 18 Revue Interdisciplinaire dEtudes Juridiques, 1-45.
Supper, Meinhard (1988), Das Niedersterreichische Landesrecht und die konomische Analyse
des Rechts (The Law of the Province of Lower Austria and the Economic Analysis of Law), in
Funk, Bernd-Christian (Project Management), (ed.), Deregulierung und Entbrokratisierung
am Beispiel, Vienna, Austrian Economic Publishers Company, 43-48.
0010 Introductory Articles 19
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1982), Cost-Benefit and Law Reform in Australia, 32 New Law Journal,
893-897.
Verloren Van Themaat, Pieter (1988), Economie Gezien door Juristen (Economics, Seen by
Lawyers), in X (ed.), Mededelingen van de Afdeling Letterkunde, Nieuwe Reeks, Amsterdam,
Koninklijke Nederlandse Akademie van Wetenschappen, 229-258.
Watrin, Christian (1995), Nutzen und Kosten des Rechts (Economics of Law), in Mantl, Wolfgang
(ed.), Effizienz der Gesetzesproduktion, Abbau der Regelungsdichte im internationalen
Vergleich Schriftenreihe des Zentrums fr angewandte Politikforschung Bd. 7, Wien,
239-244.
Weigel, Wolfgang (1990), konomie und Recht - Eine Einfhrung (Economics and Law - An
Introduction), 31(3-4) Das ffentliche Haushaltswesen in sterreich, 169-198.
Weigel, Wolfgang (1991), konomie und Recht - Eine Einfhrung (Law and Economics, a
Primer), in Weigel, Wolfgang (ed.), Economic Analysis of Law - A Collection of
Applications, Vienna, sterreichischer Wirtschaftsverlag, 13-37.
Weise, Peter (1991), Effizienz und Menschenwrde - Ein Gegensatz? Anmerkungen zu einer
Kontroverse zwischen Ott/Schfer und Fezer (Efficiency and Human Dignity - a Contradiction?
Remarks on a Controversy between Ott, Schfer and Fezer), in Ott, C. and Schfer, H.-B.
(eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts. Beitrge zur konomischen Analyse des
Rechts. Heidelberg/New York, Springer 1991, Springer, 18-34.
Weth, Stefan (1996), Die Justiz - ein Ungeliebtes Kind? (Jurisdiction - an Unloved Kid?), Neue
Juristische Wochenschrift, 2427 ff.
Wilberforce, Lord (1978), Law and Economics, in Harvey, B.W. (ed.), The Lawyer and Justice,
London, Sweet and Maxwell.
Williams, A. (1975), Collaboration between Economists and Lawyers in Policy Analysis, 13
Journal of Society of Public Teachers of Law, 212-218.
Xue-Lascoux, Zhiqun and Bromley, Daniel W. (1996), Necessity and Purpose in Chinese
Agriculture: 1949-95', 24 Oxford Development Studies, 261-280.
0020
MONOGRAPHS
Copyright 1999 Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest
21
22 Monographs 0020
Blair, Roger D. and Kaserman, David L. (1983), Law and Economics of Vertical Integration and
Control, New York, Academic Press, 211 p.
Blumstein, J. et al. (eds) (1978), Deterrence and Incapacitation: Estimating the Effe, Washington,
National Academy of Sciences.
Bork, Robert H. (1978), The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with Itself, New York, Basic
Books, 468 p.
Bowman, Ward S., Jr (1973), Patent and Antitrust Law: A Legal and Economic Approach,
Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Breyer, Stephen G. (1982), Regulation and its Reform, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press,
472 p.
Bromley, Daniel W. (1989), Economic Interests and Institutions: The Conceptual Foundations of
Public Policy, Oxford, Blackwell.
Bromley, Daniel W. (1991), Environment and Economy: Property Rights and Public Policy,
Cambridge, MA, Blackwell.
Burrows, Paul (1979), The Economic Theory of Pollution Control, Oxford, Martin Robertson, 192
p.
Button, Kenneth J. (1990), Airline Deregulation: International Experiences, New York, New
York University Press, 191 p.
Calabresi, Guido (1970), The Costs of Accidents: A Legal and Economic Analysis, New Haven,
Yale University Press, 340 p.
Calabresi, Guido and Bobbitt, Philip (1978), Tragic Choices: The Conflicts Society Confronts in
the Allocation of Tragically Scarce Resources, New York, W.W. Norton, 252 p.
Campbell, David and Clay, Susan, Long-Term Contracting: A Research Bibliography and Review
of the Literature, Oxford, Centre for Socio-Legal Studies.
Campbell, Rita Ricardo (1976), Food Safety Regulations: A Study of the Use and Li, Washington,
American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research.
Casper, Gerhard and Posner, Richard A. (1976), The Workload of the Supreme Court, Chicago,
American Bar Foundation.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1969), A Theory of Share Tenancy, Chicago, University of Chicago Press,
188 p.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1978), The Myth of Social Costs: A Critique of Welfare Economics and the
Implications for Public Policy, London, Institute of Economic Affairs, 93 p.
Coleman, Jules L. (1988), Markets, Morals and the Law, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press,
393 p.
Crain, W. Mark (1980), Vehicle Safety Inspection Systems - How Effective?, Washington,
American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research.
Crandall, Robert W. (1983), Controlling Industrial Pollution: The Economics and Politics of
Clean Air, Washington, Brookings Institution, 199 p.
Crandall, Robert W. et al. (1986), Regulating the Automobile, Washington, Brookings Institution,
202 p.
Crew, Michael A. and Kleindorfer, Paul R. (1986), The Economics of Public Utility Regulation,
Cambridge (MA), MIT Press, 304 p.
Culyer, A.J. (1973), The Economics of Social Policy, London, Martin Robertson, 268 p.
Dahlman, Carl J. (1980), The Open Field System and Beyond: A Property Right, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press, 234 p.
0020 Monographs 23
Dales, John H. (1968), Pollution, Property and Prices: An Essay in Policy, Toronto, University of
Toronto Press, 111 p.
Danzon, Patricia M. (1985), Medical Malpractice: Theory, Evidence, and Public , Cambridge,
MA, Harvard University Press, 264 p.
De Clercq, Marc and Naert, Frank (1985), De Politieke Markt (The Political Market), Antwerpen,
Kluwer, 163 p.
De Geest, Gerrit (1994), Economische Analyse van het Contracten- en Quasi-contractenrecht:
een Onderzoek naar de Wetenschappelijke Waarde van de Rechtseconomie (Economic
Analysis of Contract Law and Quasi Contract Law: A Study on the Scientic Value of Law and
Economics), Antwerpen, Maklu, 568 p.
Demsetz, Harold (1982), Economic, Legal and Political Dimensions of Competition, Amsterdam,
North-Holland, 125 p.
Derthick, Martha and Quirck, Paul J. (1985), Why the Regulators Chose to Deregulate, in Noll,
Roger G. (ed.), Regulatory Policy and the Social Sciences, Berkeley, University of California
Press, 200-231.
Dewees, Donald N., Everson, C.K. and Sims, W.A. (1975), Economic Analysis of Environmental
Policies, Toronto, University of Toronto Press, 175 p.
Dilnot, Andrew (1989), The Economics of Social Security, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 287 p.
Djuricin, Dragan (1994), Privrede u tranziciji: Privatizacija i Povezane Teme (Economies in
Transition: Privatization and Related Issues), Decije novine, Gornji Milanovac.
Douglas, George W. and Miller, J.C. (1974), Economic Regulation of Domestic Air Transport:
Theory and Policy, Washington, Brookings Institution.
Dudek, Daniel J. and Wiener, Jonathan Baert (1996), Joint Implementation, Transaction Costs,
and Climate Change, Paris, OECD.
Eckert, Ross D. (1979), The Enclosure of Ocean Resources: Economics and the Law of the Sea,
Stanford, Hoover Institute Press, Stanford University, 390 p.
Eggertsson, Thrainn (1990), Economic Behaviour and Institutions, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press, 385 p.
Einhorn, Michael A. (ed.) (1991), Price Caps and Incentive Regulation in Telecommunications,
Dordrecht, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 244 p.
Emons, Winand (1987), On the Economic Theory of Warranties, Bonn, 84 p.
Faure, Michael G. and Van den Bergh, Roger (1989), Objectieve Aansprakelijkheid, Verplichte
Verzekering en Veiligheidsregulering (Strict Liability, Mandatory Insurance and Safety
Regulation), Antwerpen, Maklu, 386 p.
Fischel, William A. (1985), The Economics of Zoning Laws: A Property Rights Approach to
American Land Use Controls, Baltimore , MD, John Hopkins University Press, 372 p.
Fleisher, B. (1966), The Economics of Delinquency, New York, Quadrangle.
Frey, Bruno S. (1990), konomie ist Sozialwissenschaft. Die Anwendung der (Economics is a
Social Science. The Use of Economic), Mnchen, Vahlen.
Gaay Fortman, Bastiaan De (1966), Theory of Competition Policy: A Confrontation of Economic,
Political and Legal Principles, Amsterdam, North-Holland, 341 p.
Gay, David E.R. (1975), Property Rights and Adam Smith, 33 Review of Social Economy,
177-179.
Gellhorn, Ernest A. (1976), Antitrust Law and Economics, St. Paul, West Publishing Company,
472 p.
24 Monographs 0020
Ghosh, D., Lees, D. and Seal, W. (1976), The Economics of Personal Injury, Westmead, Saxon
House, 6 p.
Gibbs, J. (1975), Crime, Punishment and Deterrence, New York, Elsevier.
Gimpel-Hinteregger, Monika (1994), Grundfragen der Umwelthaftung (Fundamental Issues in
Environmental Liabiltiy), Vienna, Manz.
Grabowski, Henry G. (1976), Drug Regulation and Innovation: Empirical Evidence, Washington,
American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 82 p.
Grether, David M., Isaac, R. Mark and Plott, Charles R. (1989), The Allocation of Scarce
Resources. Experimental Economics and the Problem of Allocating Airport Slots, Boulder,
CO, Westview Press, 333 p.
Hahn, Robert (1989), A Primer on Environmental Policy Design, New York, Harwood Academic,
135 p.
Halpern, Paul J. and Carr, Jack L. (1981), Liability Rules and Insurance Markets, Ottawa,
Consumer and Corporate Affairs Canada.
Harris, Richard A. and Milkis, Sidney M. (1989), The Politics of Regulatory Change: A Tale of
Two Agencies, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 331 p.
Hartley, K. and Maynard, Alan (1982), The Costs and Benefits of Regulating New Product
Development in the UK Pharmaceutical Industry, London, Office of Health Economics.
Hayashida, Seimei (1996), Ho to Keizaigaku no Horiron (Law and Economics as Legal Theory),
Hokudai Tosho Kankokai (Hokkaido University Press).
Hellaman, D.A. (1980), The Economics of Crime, New York, St. Martins Press.
Hellman, Daryl A. and Alper, Neil O. (1990), Economics of Crime: Theory and Practice,
Needham Heights, Simon and Schuster, Ginn Press, 226 p.
Hess, James D. (1983), The Economics of Organisation, Amsterdam, North-Holland, 284 p.
Hiber, Dragor (1998), Svojina u Tranziciji (Property in Transition), Belgrade, Pravni fakultet.
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (1988), Economics and Institutions, Cambridge, Polity Press, 365 p.
Huber, Peter W. (1988), Liability. The Legal Revolution and its Consequences, New York, Basic
Books, 260 p.
Ippolito, Richard A. (1989), The Economics of Pension Insurance, Homewood, Irwin for the
University of Pennsylvania, Wharton School, Pension Research Council, 270 p.
Ivic, Aleksandar and Maksimovic, Ivan (1984), Drustvena Svojina i Samoupravljanje I (Social
Property and Self-Management I), Belgrade, Pravni fakultet.
Jackson, Thomas H. (1986), The Logic and Limits of Bankruptcy Law, Cambridge (MA), Harvard
University Press, 287 p.
Johnson, Bruce M. (1985), Taking Care of Business: The Economics of Crime by Heroin
Abusers, Lexington, MA, Lexington Books, 278 p.
Joskow, Paul L. and Schmalensee, Richard L. (1983), Markets for Power: An Analysis of Electric
Utility, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press, 269 p.
Kahn, Alfred E. (1988), The Economics of Regulation: Principles and Institutions, Cambridge,
MA, MIT Press, 559 p.
Kaufer, Erich (1989), The Economics of the Patent System, Chur, Harwood Academic, 66 p.
0020 Monographs 25
Kaufmann, Peter J. (1986), Passing Off and Misappropriation: An Economic and , Max Planck
Institute for Foreign and International Patent, Copyright and Competition Law,
VCH-Weinheim, Reerfield Beach.
Kaysen, Carl and Turner, Donald F. (1959), Antitrust Policy: An Economic and Legal Analysis,
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press, 345 p.
Kleiman, Mark A.R. (1989), Marijuana: Costs of Abuse, Costs of Control, Westport, Greenwood,
197 p.
Klitgaard, Robert (1988), Controlling Corruption, Berkeley, University of California Press, 220 p.
Kneese, Allan V. and Schultze, Charles L. (1975), Pollution, Prices and Public Policy, Brookings,
Washington, DC, 125 p.
Laband, David N. and Heinbuch, Deborah Hendry (1987), Blue Laws: The History, Economics,
and Politics of Sunday Closing Laws, Lexington, MA, Lexington Books, 232 p.
Landes, William M. and Posner, Richard A. (1987), The Economic Structure of Tort Law,
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press, 330 p.
Lehmann, Michael (1983), Brgerliches Recht und Handelsrecht - eine juristische und
konomische Analyse ausgewhlter Probleme fr Wirtschaftswissenschaftler und
interdisziplinr interessierte Juristen unter besonderer Bercksichtigung der
"konomischen Analyse des Rechts" und (Civil Law and Commercial Law - a Legal and
Economic Analysis of Selected Problems for Lawyers with an Economic and Interdisciplinary
Interest with Special Attention to the Economic Analysis of Law and the "Theory of Property
Rights"), Stuttgart, Poeschel, 329 p.
Lepage, Henri (1984), Pourquoi la proprit? (Why Property?), Paris, Pluriel.
Leube, Kurt R. and Moore, Thomas Gale (1986), The Essence of Stigler, Stanford, Hoover Institute
Press, Stanford University, 377 p.
Libecap, Gary D. (1989), Contracting for Property Rights, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press, 132 p.
Luken, Ralph A. (1991), Efficiency in Environmental Regulation, Dordrecht, Kluwer, 400 p.
Luksetich, William and White, Michael (1982), Crime and Public Policy: An Economic
Approach, Boston, Little Brown.
Macauley, Molly K. and Portney, Paul R. (1984), Property Rights in Orbit Regulation,
Washington, American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research.
Madzar, Ljubomir (1972), Osnovi Teorije Proizvodnje (Basics of the Theory of Production),
Belgrade, Institut ekonomskih nauka.
Madzar, Ljubomir (1995), Svojina i Reforma (Property and Reform), Belgrade, Institut
ekonomskih nauka.
Malloy, Robin Paul (1990), Law and Economics. A Comparative Approach to Theory and
Practice, St. Paul, West Publishing Company, 166 p.
Mataja, Victor (1888), Das Recht des Schadenersatzes vom Standpunkte der Nationalkonomie
(The Law of Compensation from the Standpoint of Economics), Leipzig.
Medema, Steven G. (1994), Ronald H. Coase, London, MacMillan.
Mendeloff, John M. (1988), The Dilemma of Toxic Substance Regulation: How Overregulation
Causes Underregulation at OSHA, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press, 321 p.
26 Monographs 0020
Mercuro, Nicholas and Medema, Steven G. (1997), From Posner to Post-Modernism, Princeton,
Princeton University Press.
Mercuro, Nicholas and Ryan, Thimothy P. (1984), Law, Economics and Public Policy,
Greenwood, JAI Press, 184 p.
Miller, James C., III (1989), The Economist as Reformer: Revamping the FTC, 1981, Washington,
American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 110 p.
Moore, Thomas G. (1976), Trucking Regulation. Lessons from Europe, Washington, American
Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 148 p.
Morrison, Steven A. and Winston, Clifford (1986), The Economic Effects of Airline Deregulation,
Washington, Brookings Institution, 84 p.
Munch, Patricia (1977), Costs and Benefits of the Tort System if Viewed as, Santa Monica,
Institute for Civil Justice, Rand Corporation.
Myhrman, Johan, Petrn, Gustav and Strmholm, Stig (1987), Marknadsekonomins Rttsliga
Grundvalar (The Legal Foundations of the Market Economy), Timbro.
Needham, Douglas (1983), The Economics and Politics of Regulation: A Behavioral Approach,
Boston, Little Brown, 482 p.
Neely, Richard (1988), The Product Liability Mess: How Business Can Be Rescued from the
Politics of the State Courts, New York, Free Press, 181 p.
Olson, Walter (ed.) (1988), New Directions in Liability Law, New York, The Academy of Political
Science, 214 p.
Orlic, V. Miodrag and Rajovic, Veroljub (1984), Drustvena Svojina i Samoupravljanje II (Social
Property and Self-Management II), Belgrade, Pravni fakultet.
Otto, Hans-Jochen (1982), Generalprvention und externe Verhaltenskontrolle, Wandel vom
Sociologischen zum konomischen Paradigma in der Nordamerikanischen Kriminologie?
(General Prevention and External Control of Behavior, Evolution from Sociological to
Economic Paradigm in the North American Criminology?), Freiburg, Max-Planck-Institut fr
auslndisches internationales Strafrecht, 323 p.
Owen, Bruce M. and Braeutigam, Ronald R. (1978), The Regulation Game: Strategic Use of the
Administrative Process, Cambridge, MA, Ballinger, 271 p.
Papps, Ivy (1980), For Love or Money? A Preliminary Economic Analysis, London, Institute of
Economic Affairs, 63 p. (Hobart Paperback No.86).
Pejovich, Svetozar (1990), The Economics of Property Rights: Towards a Theory, Dordrecht,
Kluwer, 224 p.
Peltzman, Sam (1975), Regulation of Pharmaceutical Innovation, Washington, American
Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 118 p.
Penrose, E.T. (1951), The Economics of the International Patent System, Baltimore, MD, John
Hopkins University Press.
Peterson, Wallace C. (1991), Transfer Spending, Taxes, and the American Welfare, Dordrecht,
Kluwer, 192 p.
Pigou, A.C. (1932), The Economics of Welfare, London, Macmillan, 876 p.
Polinsky, A. Mitchell (1989), An Introduction to Law and Economics (2nd edn), Boston: Little,
Brown and Company, 153 p.
Poole, Robert W., Jr (1982), Instead of Regulation, Lexington, KY, Heath, 404 p.
Poole, Robert W., Jr (ed.) (1985), Unnatural Monopolies: The Case for Deregulating Public
Utilities, Lexington, MA, Lexington Books, 224 p.
Posner, Richard A. (1976), Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective, Chicago, University of
Chicago Press, 262 p.
0020 Monographs 27
Posner, Richard A. (1981), The Economics of Justice, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press,
415 p.
Posner, Richard A. (1985), The Federal Courts: Crisis and Reform, Cambridge, MA, Harvard
University Press, 365 p.
Priddat, Birger (1988), Das Geld und die Vernunft. ber John Lockes Versuch einer
naturrechtlich begrndeten konomie (Money and Reason. On John Lockes Natural
Right-Based Economics), Frankfurt am Main, Peter D. Lang.
Priddat, Birger (1993), konomie und Macht. John Locke. Neue Aspekte (Economy and Power.
John Locke. New Aspects), in Gephardt, J. and Mnclker, H. (eds), Brgerschaft und
Herrschaft. Zum Verhltnis von Demokratie und Macht im Antiken und Neuzeitlichen
Politischen Denken, Baden-Baden, Nomos.
Pyle, David J. (1983), The Economics of Crime and Law Enforcement, London, MacMillan, 216
p.
Pyle, David J. (1989), Tax Evasion and the Black Economy, New York, St. Martins Press, 212 p.
Ramseyer, J. Mark and Rosenbluth, Frances M. (1995), The Politics of Oligarchy: Institutional
Choice in Imperial Japan, New York, Cambridge University Press.
Raufer, Roger K. and Feldman, Stephen L. (1987), Acid Rain and Emissions Trading:
Implementing a Market Approach to Pollution Control, Totowa, Rowman and Allenheld, 161
p.
Rea, Samuel A., Jr. (1981), Disability Insurance and Public Policy, Toronto, University of
Toronto Press.
Rea, Samuel A., Jr. and James E. (1977), Pesando, Public and Private Pensions in Canada: An
Economic Analysis, Toronto, University of Toronto Press.
Reuter, Peter (1983), Disorganized Crime: The Economics of the Visible Hand, London, MIT
Press, 233 p.
Ringen, Stein (1987), The Possibility of Politics: A Study in the Political Economy of the Welfare
State, Oxford, Clarendon, 303 p.
Robert, Philippe and Godefroy, Thierry (1977), Le Cot du Crime ou lEconomie Poursuivant le
Crime (The Cost of Crime or Economics Prosecuting Crime), Genve, Masson, 225 p.
Rogers, A.J. (1973), The Economics of Crime, Illinois, Dryden Press.
Rowley, Charles K. (1966), The British Monopolies Commission, London, Allen and Unwin.
Rowley, Charles K. (1973), Antitrust and Economic Efficiency, London, Macmillan, 95 p.
Rowley, Charles K. (1992), The Right to Justice: The Political Economy of Legal Services in the
United States, Aldershot, Edward Elgar.
Rowley, Charles K. and Ogus, Anthony I. (1984), Prepayments and Insolvency, London, Office of
Fair Trading.
Rowley, Charles K. and Yarrow, G.K. (1978), Evolution of Concentration in the United Kingdom
Cement Industry, Commission of the European Communities. French edition 1979.
Rubin, Paul H. (1983), Business Firms and the Common Law. The Evolution of Efficient Rules,
New York, Praeger, 189 p.
28 Monographs 0020
Rubin, Paul H. (1993), Private Mechanisms for the Creation of Efficient Institutions for Market
Economies, in Somogyi, Laszlo (ed.), The Political Economy of The Transition Process In
Eastern Europe, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
Rubin, Paul H. (1994), Growing A Legal System in the Post-Communist Economies, 27 Cornell
International Law Journal, 1-47.
Rubin, Paul H. and Tesche, Jean, Enforcement of Agreements in Russia, in Sachs, Jeffrey (ed.),
The Rule of Law and Economic Reform in Russia, Boulder, Westview Press, 912 ff.
Sagoff, Mark (1988), The Economy of the Earth: Philosophy, Law, and the Environment,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 271 p.
Santini, Gerardo (1979), Il Commercio (Trading), Bologna, Il Mulino, 364 p.
Santini, Gerardo (1987), I Servizi. Saggio di Economia del Diritto (The Services. An Example of
an Economic Approach t), Bologna, Il Mulino, 562 p.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1982), Institutional Choice und Ordnungstheorie (Institutional Choice and
Theory of Order), Tbingen, Mohr, 39 p.
Scheppele, Kim Lane (1988), Legal Secrets, Equality and Efficiency in the Common Law,
Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 363 p.
Scherer, Frederic M. (1977), The Economic Effects of Compulsory Patent Licensing, New York,
New York University Press.
Schmid, A. Allan (1987), Property, Power, and Public Choice: An Inquiry into Law and
Economics, Westport, Greenwood, 332 p.
Schmidt, Ingo and Rittaler, Jan B. (1989), A Critical Evaluation of the Chicago School of
Antitrust Analysis, Dordrecht, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 132 p.
Schmidt, Peter and Witte, Ann Dryden (1984), An Economic Analysis of Crime and Justice:
Theory, Methods, and Applications, New York, Academic Press, 416 p.
Shavell, Steven (1987), Economic Analysis of Accident Law, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press, 312 p.
Shaviro, Daniel N. (1993), Federalism in Taxation: The Case for Greater Uniformity,
Washington, AEI Press.
Shaviro, Daniel N. (1995), Budget Deficits and the Intergenerational Distribution of Lifetime
Consumption, University of Chicago Law and Economics Working Paper, No. 29.
Shepherd, William G. (1985), Public Policies Toward Business, Homewood, IL, Richard D. Irwin,
541 p.
Simonich, William L. (1991), Government Antismoking Policies, New York, Peter Lang, 300 p.
Smith, Peter and Swann, Dennis (1979), Protecting the Consumer - An Economic and Legal
Analysis, Oxford, Martin Robertson, 286 p.
Snow, Marcellus S. (1986), Marketplace for Telecommunications: Regulation and Deregulation
in Industrialized Democracies, New York, Longman, 304 p.
Swann, Dennis (1988), The Retreat of the State: Deregulation and Privatization in the U.K. and
U.S., Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press, 344 p.
Tabasz, Thomas F. (1975), Toward an Economics of Prisons, Lexington, KY, Heath.
Taylor, Charles T. and Silbertson, Z.A. (1973), The Economic Impact of the Patent System,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
0020 Monographs 29
31
32 Book Reviews 0030
Eide, Erling (1984), Book review of Gran Skogh, 1982, Marknadens Villkor, Tidsskrift for
Rettsvitenskap, 318-319.
Eide, Erling (1986), Book review of Nils Nygaard, 1985, Skatt og Skade, Tidsskrift for
Rettsvitenskap, 708-712.
Fisch, Jill E. (1995), Review Essay: Picking A Winner (reviewing Roberta Romano, The Genius of
American Corporate Law), 20 Journal of Corporate Law, 451-474.
Gay, David E.R. (1975), Book Review of The Economics of Property Rights, ed. by Furubotn and
Pejovich, 42 Southern Economic Journal, 162-164.
Gay, David E.R. (1976), Book Review of Henry Manne, The Economics of Legal Relationships,
42 Southern Economic Journal, 765-766.
Gay, David E.R. (1977a), Book Review of Government Controls and the Free Market, ed. by
Svetozar Pejovich, 44 Southern Economic Journal, 407-409.
Gay, David E.R. (1977b), Book Review of Capitalism and Freedom: Problems and Prospects,
ed. by Selden, 37 Zeitschrift fr Nationalokonomie, 423-424.
Gay, David E.R. (1978), Book Review of Economic Forces at Work, Armen Alchian, 31 Kyklos,
504-505.
Gay, David E.R. (1979), Economic Legalism: A Survey of the Naissance of the New Law and
Economics, 3 Midsouth Journal of Economics, 65-70.
Gay, David E.R. (1979), Book Review of Adam Smith and The Wealth of Nations: Bicentennial
Essays 1776-1976, ed. by Fred Glahe, 32 Kyklos, 629-630.
Gay, David E.R. (1981a), Book Review of Regulation, Economics, and the Law, Bernhard H.
Siegan, 39 Review of Social Economy, 92-94.
Gay, David E.R. (1981b), Book Review of Moral Revolution and Economic Science: The
Demise of Laissez-Faire in Ninteenth Century British Political Economy, Ellen Frankel
Paul, 48 Southern Economic Journal, 530-531.
Gay, David E.R. (1982a), Book Review of Mercantilism as a Rent-Seeking Society: Economic
Regulation in Historical Perspective, Robert B. Ekelund and Robert D. Tollison, 35 Kyklos,
732-733.
Gay, David E.R. (1982b), Book Review of The Role of Government in a Free Society, Phil
Gramm, 50 Southern Economic Journal, 916-917.
Gay, David E.R. (1982c), Book Review of Theories of Property: From Aristotle to the Present,
Anthony Parel and Thomas Flanagan, 15 History of Political Economy, 281-283.
Gay, David E.R. and Stanley, Tom D. (1992), Introduction Review of the Fatal Conceit: The
Error of Socialism, Friedrich A. Hayek, 71 Social Science Quarterly, 400-401.
Gay, David E.R. and Waligorski, Conrad (1981), Book Review of The State as a Firm: Economic
Forces in Political Development, David Auster and Morris Silver, 34 Kyklos, 110-111.
Johnsen, D. Bruce, Easterbrook, Frank H. and Fishel, Daniel R. (1993), The Economic Structure
of Corporate Law, 525 Annals of American Academy of Political and Social Science, 200 ff.
Kitch, Edmund W. (1968), Review of Benjamin Kaplan, An Unhurried View of Copyright, 20
Stanford Law Review, 794 ff.
Kitch, Edmund W. (1981), Review of Chapter 11 of Volume XI of the International Encyclopedia
of Comparative Law: Legal Consequences of State Regulation, 9 International Journal of
Law Libraries, 230 ff.
0030 Book Reviews 33
Kitch, Edmund W. (1982), Review of Kripke, The SEC and Corporate Disclosure: Regulation in
Search of a Purpose, 47 University of Chicago Law Review, 394 ff.
Kitch, Edmund W. (1984), Review of Cento G. Veljanovski, The New Law and Economics: A
Research Review, 4 International Review of Law and Economics, 229 ff.
Kitch, Edmund W. (1990), Review of Kim Lane Scheppele, Legal Secrets: Equality and
Efficiency in the Common Law, 28 Journal of Economic Literature, 1770 ff.
Kitch, Edmund W. (1993), Review of Anne M. Khademian, The SEC and Capital Market
Regulation: The Politics of Expertise, 10 Yale Journal on Regulation, 589-594.
Lande, Robert H. (1988), Antitrust Law and Economics: Responding to an Ivory Tower Critique,
57 University of Cincinnati Law Review, 235 ff.
Lipford, Jody (1997), Lansing Pollock: The Free Society (Book Review), 8 Constitutional
Political Economy, 169-171.
McGuire, Robert A. (1989), Review of Liberty, Property, and the Foundations of the American
Constitution, by Ellen Frankel Paul and Dickman, Howard, 49 Journal of Economic History,
1046-1048.
McGuire, Robert A. (1998), Review of The Constitution in Congress: The Federalist Period,
1789-1801, by David P. Currie, 58 Journal of Economic History.
Mercuro, Nicholas (1977), Book Review: Environmental Controls, R.A. Leone, Lexington,
Lexington Books, 1979, 12(3) Review of Business and Economic Research, 91-92.
Mercuro, Nicholas (1978), Book Review: When Values Conflict, L.H. Tribe et al. (eds),
Cambridge, Ballinger Publishing Co., 1976, 12 Journal of Economic Issues, 187-189.
Mercuro, Nicholas (1980), Book Review: The Economics of Natural Resources, Richard
Lecomber, New York, John Wiley and Sons, 1979, 47(1) Southern Economic Journal,
265-267.
Mercuro, Nicholas (1984), Book Review: Ethics, Economics and the Law, J. Ronald Pennock and
John W. Chapman, New York, New York University Press, 1982, 42(2) Review of Social
Economy, 192-199.
Mercuro, Nicholas (1986a), Book Review: Research in Law and Economics: Normative Law and
Economics, Vol. 7, ZERBE, Richard O., Jr (ed.), (Greenwich, JAI Press, 1985), 20 Journal of
Economic Issues, 146-151.
Mercuro, Nicholas (1986b), Contributions to Law and Economics: A Survey of Recent Books,
17(4) Journal of Economic Education, 295-309.
Parisi, Francesco (1994), Autonomy and Private Ordering in Contract Law: Review Essay, 1
European Journal of Law and Economics, 213-227.
Parisi, Francesco (1998), Book Review: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the
Law, 19 International Review of Law and Economics.
Parisi, Francesco (1998), The Constitutional and Political Economy of Trade Protection: Review
Essay, 5 European Journal of Law and Economics, 67-79.
Parisi, Francesco and Ricci, Paolo F. (1991), Environmental Policy in the 1990s: Review Essay,
18 Ecology Law Quarterly, 459-484.
Peltzman, Sam (1968), Review of Gerald C. Fischer, American Banking Structure, 41 Journal of
Business.
34 Book Reviews 0030
Van den Hauwe, Ludwig (1995), Review of: Flair and de Boussieu, Fiscal Policy, Taxation and
the Financial System in an Increasingly Integrated Europe, 85 Public Choice, 400-405.
Van den Hauwe, Ludwig (1996), Economic Methodology and the Economic Analysis of Law
(Book Review), 3 European Journal of Law and Economics, 97-103.
Van den Hauwe, Ludwig (1998), German Income Tax Policy Between Equity and Efficiency, 5
European Journal of Law and Economics, 267-279.
Verkerke, J. Hoult (1991), Free to Search, 105 Harvard Law Review, 2080-2097.
Weissel, Erwin (1991), Das juristische Denken und das Denken der Juristen. Bemerkungen eines
konomen zu K.G. Wurzels Rechtswissenschaft als Socialwissenschaftler (Legal Reasoning
and the Reasoning of Lawyers - Some Remarks from an Economists Perspective regarding K.G.
Wurzels Legal Science as a Social Science), 6 Zeitschrift fr Rechtsvergleichung.
Weissel, Erwin (1994), Wettbewerb als Pflicht und Recht. Eine Buchbesprechung (Competition as
a Duty and a Claim), 5 Zeitschrift fr Rechtsvergleichung.
Yandle, Bruce (1997), Charles K. Rowley: The Political Economy of the Minimal State, 8 (1)
Constitutional Political Economy, 93-95.
0040
SYMPOSIA
Copyright 1999 Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest
Arnott, Richard J. and Mintz, Jack M. (eds) (1987), Rent Control: The Internation Experience.
Proceedings of a Conference Held at Queen's University, 31 August 4 September 1987,
Kingston, Queens University, John Deutsch Institute for the Study of Economic Policy, 176 p.
Atias, Christian (1987), La Distinction du Patrimonial et de lExtra-Patrimonial et lAnalyse
Economique du Droit: un Utile Face Face (The Distinction between Patrimonial and
Extra-patrimonial Rights and the Economic Analysis of Law), Revue de la Recherche
Juridique.
Bebchuck, Lucian Ayre (ed.) (1990), Corporate Law and Economic Analysis, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press, 320 p.
Blair, Roger D. and Rubin, Stephen (eds) (1980), Regulating the Professions: A Public-Policy
Symposium, Lexington, MA, Lexington Books, 328 p.
Buxbaum, Hertig and Hirsch, Hopt (eds), European Economic and Business Law, Legal and
Economic Analyses on Integration and Harmonization, Berlin, 401 p.
Carmichael, H. Lorne (1988), Incentives in Academics: Why is there Tenure?, 96 Journal of
Political Economy, 453-472.
Centi, Jean-Pierre, Quel Critre dEfficience pour lAnalyse Economique du Droit? (Which
Efficiency Criterion for Economic Analysis of Law), Revue de la Recherche Juridique.
Chamberlin, Edward H. (ed.) (1954), Monopoly, and Competition and Their Regulation, New
York, 549 p.
Cherot, Jean-Yves (1987), Trois thses de lanalyses conomique du droit (Three Thesis of
Economic Analysis of Law), Revue de la Recherche Juridique.
Conference (1985), Critical Issues in Tort Law Reform: A Search for Principles. A Conference
Sponsored by the Program in Civil Liability, Yale Law School, 14 Journal of Legal Studies,
459-818.
Cranston, Ross and Schick, Anne (eds) (1982), Law and Economics, Canberra, Australian National
University, 220 p.
Dale, Richard (ed.) (1986), Financial Deregulation: The Proceedings of a Conference held by the
David Hume Institute in May 1986, Cambridge, Woodhead-Faulkner.
Dorn, James A. and Manne, Henry G. (eds) (1987), Economic Liberties and the Judiciary, Fairfax,
George Mason University Press, 392 p.
Faure, Michael G. and Van den Bergh, Roger (eds) (1989), Essays in Law and Economics:
Corporations, Accident Prevention and Compensation for Losses, Antwerpen, Maklu, 232 p.
Gay, David E.R. and Stanley, Tom D. (1992), Introduction Review of the Fatal Conceit: The Error
of Socialism, Friedrich A. Hayek, 71 Social Science Quarterly, 400-401.
Heertje, A. and et al. (1991), Law and Welfare Economics: op het Raakvlak van Economie en
Recht (Law and Welfare Economics: Where Economics and Law Touch), Bundel n.a.v. het
gelijknamige Symposium op 24 oktober 1990.
36
0040 Symposia 37
Ippolito, Pauline M. and Scheffman, David T. (eds) (1986), Empirical Approaches to Consumer
Protection Economics, Washington, Federal Trade Commission.
Litan, Robert E. and Winston, Clifford (eds) (1988), Liability: Perspectives and Policy,
Washington, Brookings Institution, 248 p.
Mackaay, Ejan (1987), Le Juriste a-t-il le Droit dIgnorer lEconomiste? (May Lawyers Ignore
Economists?), Revue de la Recherche Juridique.
Mathewson, G. Frank, Trebilcock, Michael J. and Walker, Michael A. (eds) (1990), The Law and
Economics of Competition Policy, Vancouver, Fraser Institute, 443 p.
Mouly, Christian (1987), Prsentation du Colloque sur lAnalyse Economique du Droit
(Introduction to the Symposium of Economic Analysis of Law), Revue de la Recherche
Juridique, 413 ff.
Mouly, Christian (1995), Analyse Economique du Droit Rgissant le Transfert de Proprit
(Economic Analysis of Law Governing the Transfer of Property), in X (ed.), Faut-il Retarder
le Transfert de Proprit ?, JCP d. E, 6 ff.
Nutzinger, Hans G. and Backhaus, Jrgen G. (eds) (1989), Codetermination: A Discussion of
Different Approaches, Berlin, Springer, 309 p.
Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds) (1989), Allekationseffizienz in der Rechtsordnung
(Allocative Efficiency in Legal Order. Contribution), Berlin, Springer, 306 p.
Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds) (1991), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts.
Beitrge zum 2. Travemnder Symposium zur konomischen Analyse des Rechts, 21.-26.
Mrz 1990 (Economic Problems of Civil Law. Contributions to the Second Travemnder
Symposium on Economic Analysis of Law), Berlin, Springer, 347 p.
Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds) (1994), konomische Analyse der Rechtlichen
Organisation von Innovationen, Beitrge zum 4. Travemnder Symposiun zur
konomischen Analyse des Rechts 1994 (Economic Analysis of the Law of Innovations),
Heidelberg, Physica.
Pardolesi, Roberto and Van den Bergh, Roger (eds) (1991), Law and Economics: Some Further
Insights, Milano, Giuffr, 205 p.
Parisi, Francesco (1998), Book Review: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law,
19 International Review of Law and Economics.
Pethig, Rudiger and Schlieper, Ulrich (eds) (1987), Efficiency, Institutions, and Economic Policy:
Proceedings of a Workshop Held by the Sonderforschungsbereich 5 at the University of
Mannheim, New York, Springer, 225 p.
Rizzo, Mario J. (ed.) (1987), Symposium on Causation in the Law of Torts, 63 Chicago-Kent
Law Review, 397-680.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der and Skogh, Gran (eds) (1986), Law and Economics and
the Economics of Legal Regulation, Dordrecht, Kluwer, 230 p.
Shaviro, Daniel N. (1993), Commentary: Uneasiness and Capital Gains, 48 Tax Law Review,
393-417.
Skogh, Gran (ed.) (1978), Law and Economics. Report from a Symposium in Lund, Lund,
Juridiska Freningen, 231 p.
Slayton, Philip and Trebilcock, Michael J. (eds) (1978), The Professions and Public Policy,
Toronto, University of Toronto Faculty of Law, 346 p.
Stewart, Marion B. (ed.) (1987), Energy Deregulation and Economic Growth: Proceedin, New
Brunswick, Rutgers, Bureau of Economic Research.
38 Symposia 0040
Stout, Lynn A. (1992), Strict Scrutiny and Social Choice: An Economic Inquiry into Fundamental
Rights and Suspect Classifications, 80 Georgetown Law Journal, 1787-1834.
Stout, Lynn A. (1993), Poverty and Failure in the Market for Human Capital, 81 Georgetown
Law Journal, 1947-1959.
Stout, Lynn A. (1995), Betting the Bank: How Derivatives Trading under Conditions of
Uncertainty can Increase Risks and Erode Returns in Financial Markets, 21 Journal of
Corporate Law, 53 ff.
Stout, Lynn A. (1996), Type I Error, Type II Error, and the Private Securities Litigation Reform
Act, 38 Arizona Law Review, 711 ff.
Stout, Lynn A. (1997a), How Efficient Markets Undervalue Stocks: CAPM and ECMH in a World
of Uncertainty and Disagreement, Cardozo Law Review.
Stout, Lynn A. (1997b), Technology, Transactions Costs, and Investor Welfare: Is a Motley Fool
Born Every Minute?, 75 Washington University Law Quarterly, 791 ff.
Stout, Lynn A. (1997c), Irrational Expectations, Journal of Legal Theory.
Symposium (1970), Products Liability: Economic Analysis and the Law, 38 University of
Chicago Law Review, 1-141.
Symposium (1976), Deregulation, 57 Indiana Law Journal, 682-755.
Symposium (1977), The Economics of Bankruptcy Reform, 41(4) Law and Contemporary
Problems.
Symposium (1978), Symposium on Posners Theory of Privacy, Georgia Law Review.
Symposium (1979), Regulation and Innovation, 43(1) Law and Contemporary Problems.
Symposium (1980a), Symposium on Efficiency as a Legal Concern, 8 Hofstra Law Review,
485-972.
Symposium (1980b), The Law and Economics of Privacy. A Conference Sponsored by the Center
for the Study of the Economy and the State, 9 Journal of Legal Studies, 621-842.
Symposium (1981a), Managing the Transition to Deregulation, 44(1) Law and Contemporary
Problems.
Symposium (1981b), The Implications of Social Choice Theory for Legal Decision-Making, 9
Hofstra Law Review.
Symposium (1983a), The Place of Economics in Legal Education, 33 Journal of Legal
Education, 183-376.
Symposium (1983b), Redistribution of Income through Regulation in Housing, 32 Emory Law
Journal, 767-819.
Symposium (1984a), The Alis Corporate Governance Proposals: Law and Economics, 8
Delaware Journal of Corporate Law.
Symposium (1984b), Attorney Fees Shifting, 47(1) Law and Contemporary Problems, 1-354.
Symposium (1985a), Alternative Compensation Schemes and Tort Theory, 73(3) California Law
Review, 548-1042.
Symposium (1985b), Symposium on Law and Economics, 85 Columbia Law Review, 899-1119.
Symposium (1986), Medical Malpractice: Can the Private Sector Find Relief?, 49(2) Law and
Contemporary Problems, 1-348.
0040 Symposia 39
Symposium (1987), Conference on the Law and Economics of Procedure, 3 Journal of Law,
Economics, and Organization, 143-447.
Symposium (1988a), The Crisis in Legal Theory and the Revival of Classical Jurisprudence, 73
Cornell Law Review, 281-446.
Symposium (1988b), Rent Control and the Theory of Efficient Regulation, 54 Brooklyn Law
Review, 729-739.
Symposium (1988c), Symposium on Takings, 88 Columbia Law Review, 1581-1794.
Symposium (1989a), Empirical Approaches to Market Power, 32(S) Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-275.
Symposium (1989b), Symposium on Post-Chicago Law and Economics, 65 Chicago-Kent Law
Review, 1-191.
Symposium (1989c), Non-Posnerian Law and Economics, 12 Hamline Law Review, 197-410.
Symposium (1989d), Issues in Civil Procedure: Advancing the Dialogue, 69 Boston University
Law Review, 467-779.
Symposium (1990), Different Approaches to the Economics of Institutions, 146 Journal of
Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 1-235.
Symposium (1991a), Symposium on New Views on Antitrust, 147 Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics, 1-239.
Symposium (1991b), The Economics of Liability, 5(3) Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3-136.
Symposium (1996), Oikonomike Analyse tou Dikaiou (Economic Analysis of Law), 6
Aissymnetes.
Symposium (Meurer, Michael) (ed.) (1989), Economics of Contract Law, Law and
Contemporary Problems.
Van den Bergh, Roger (ed.) (1986), Verslagboek Eerste Werkvergadering Recht en Economie
(Conference Volume First Workshop in Law and Economics), Antwerpen, Leerstoel A. Van
Melkebeke, Handelshogeschool, 72 p.
Weigel, Wolfgang and Austrian Economic Chamber (eds) (1991), Economic Analysis of Law - a
Collection of Application, Vienna, Austrian Economic Publishing Company, 295 p.
Williams, Stephen F. (1973), Optimizing Water Use: The Return Flow Issue, 44 University of
Colorado Law Review, 301-321.
X (1979), Conference: Private Alternatives to the Judicial Process. Proceedings of A Seminar
Sponsored by the Liberty Fund and Administered by the Law and Economics Center of the
University of Miami School of Law, 8 Journal of Legal Studies, 231-415.
X (1984), Conference: Catastrophic Personal Injuries - A Conference Sponsored By the Hoover
Institution, 13 Journal of Legal Studies, 415-622.
X (1987), Conference: Conference on the Law and Economics of Procedure, 3 Journal of Law,
Economics, and Organization, 143-372.
X (1990), Conference: The Organization of Political Institutions, 6(S) Journal of Law,
Economics, and Organization, 1-332.
X (1990), Conference: The Law and Economics of Risk, 19 Journal of Legal Studies, 531-849.
Zerbe, Richard O., Jr (ed.) (1984), Symposium: Antitrust and Regulation, 6 Research in Law and
Economics, 292 ff.
0050
COLLECTIONS OF (NEW) ARTICLES
Copyright 1999 Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest
Albon, Robert P. (ed.) (1980), Rent Control. Costs and Consequences. Essays on the , St.
Leonards, Centre for Independent Studies.
Andreano, Ralph and Siegfried, John J. (eds) (1980), The Economics of Crime, Cambridge,
Schenkman, 426 p.
Aoki, Masahiko et al. (eds) (1989), The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties, London, Sage, 358 p.
Assmann, Heinz-Dieter, Kirchner, Christian and Schanze, Erich (eds) (1978), konomische
Analyse des Rechts (Economic Analysis of Law), Kronberg, Athenum, 369 p.
Bailey, Elizabeth E. (ed.) (1987), Public Regulation: New Perspectives on Institution, Cambridge,
MA, MIT Press, 404 p.
Baily, Mary Ann and Cikins, Warren I. (eds) (1985), The Effects of Litigation on Health Care
Costs, Washington, Brookings Institution.
Becker, Gary S. and Landes, William M. (eds) (1974), Essays in the Economics of Crime and
Punishment, New York, Columbia University Press, 268 p.
Block, Walter E. (ed.) (1990), Economics and the Environment: A Reconciliation, Vancouver,
Fraser Institute, 332 p.
Block, Walter E. and Olson, Edgar (eds) (1981), Rent Control. Myths and Realities. International
Evidence of the Effects of Rent Contol in Six Contries, Vancouver, Fraser Institute, 335 p.
Block, Walter E. and Walker, Michael (eds) (1982), Discrimination, Affirmative Action, and
Equal Opportunity - An Economic and Social Perspective, Vancouver, Fraser Institute, 271 p.
Boettcher, Erik, Herder-Dorneich, Philipp, Schenk, Karl-Ernst and Schmidtchen, Dieter (eds)
(1991), Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, 10. Band, Systemvergleich und
Ordnungspolitik (Comparative Analysis of Economic Systems and Constitutional Policy),
Tbingen.
Bollard, Alan and Buckle, Robert (eds) (1987), Economic Liberalisation in New Zealand,
Wellington, Allen and Unwin, 364 p.
Bouckaert, Boudewijn and De Geest, Gerrit (eds) (1995), Essays in Law and Economics II:
Contract Law, Regulation, and Reflections on Law and Economics, Antwerpen, Maklu, 306
p.
Bromley, Daniel W. et al. (eds) (1992), Making the Commons Work: Theory, Practice, and
Policy, San Francisco, ICS Press.
Bromley, Daniel W. and Segerson, Kathleen (eds) (1992), The Social Response to Environmental
Risk: Policy Formulation in an Age of Uncertainty, Boston, Kluwer.
Buchanan, James M., Tollison, Robert D. and Tullock, Gordon (eds) (1980), Toward a Theory of
the Rent Seeking Society, College Station, Texas A&M; University Press.
Burrows, Paul and Veljanovski, Cento G. (eds) (1981), The Economic Approach to Law, London,
Butterworths, 343 p.
40
0050 Collections of (New) Articles 41
Button, Kenneth J. and Swann, Dennis (eds) (1989), The Age of Regulatory Reform, Oxford,
Oxford University Press, 339 p.
Calvani, Terry and Siegfried, John J. (eds) (1979), Economic Analysis and Antitrust, Boston, Little
Brown.
Campbell, David and Vincent-Jones, Peter (eds) (1997), Contract and Economic Organisation:
Socio-legal Initiatives, Aldershot, Dartmouth.
Clarkson, Kenneth W. and Martin, Donald L. (eds) (1979), The Economics of Nonproprietary
Institutions (Supplement 1 to Research in Law and Economics), Greenwood, JAI Press, 330 p.
Collard, David (ed.) (1989), Fiscal Policy: Essays in Honour of Cedric Sandford, Aldershot,
Gower, 173 p.
Comanor, William S. et al. (1991), Competition Policy in Europe and North America: Economic
Issues and Institutions, New York, Harwood, 260 p.
Crew, Michael A. (ed.) (1985), Analyzing the Impact of Regulatory Change in Publi, Lexington,
MA, Lexington Books.
Crew, Michael A. (ed.) (1987), Regulating Utilities in an Era of Deregulation, New York, St.
Martins Press, 201 p.
Crew, Michael A. (ed.) (1989), Deregulation and Diversification of Utilities, Dordrecht, Kluwer,
206 p.
Crew, Michael A. (ed.) (1991), Competition and the Regulation of Utilities, Dordrecht, Kluwer,
224 p.
Crew, Michael A. and Kleindorfer, Paul R. (eds) (1991), Competition and Innovation in Postal
Services, Dordrecht, Kluwer, 304 p.
Daintith, Terence C. (ed.) (1988), Law as an Instrument of Economic Policy: Comparative and
Critical Approaches, Berlin, Walter de Gruyter, 432 p.
Daintith, Terence C. and Teubner, Gunther (1986), Sociological Jurisprudence and Legal
Economics: Risks and Rewards, in Daintith, Terence and Teubner, Gunther (eds), Contract
and Organisation: Legal Analysis in the Light of Economic and Social Theory, Berlin,
Walter de Gruyter, 3-22.
Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray and Newman, Peter (eds) (1987), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary
of Economics, London, Macmillan, 4093 p.
Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray and Newman, Peter (eds) (1989), The New Palgrave: Invisible
Hand, London, Macmillan, 283 p.
Economistas (1989), Los derechos de propriedad en el anlisis econmico (Property Rights in
Economic Analysis;(journal)).
Einhorn, Michael A. (ed.) (1991), Price Caps and Incentive Regulation in Telecommunications,
Dordrecht, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 244 p.
Finsinger, Jrg and Pauly, Mark V. (eds) (1986), The Economics of Insurance Regulation: A
Cross-National Study, New York, St Martins Press, 300 p.
Gustafsson, B.A. and Klevmarken, N. Anders (eds) (1989), The Political Economy of Social
Security, Amsterdam, North-Holland, 240 p.
Hardin, Garrett and Baden, John A. (eds) (1977), Managing the Commons, San Francisco,
Freeman, 294 p.
Heineke, J.M. (ed.) (1978), Economic Models of Criminal Behaviour, Amsterdam, North-Holland,
391 p.
42 Collections of (New) Articles 0050
Herder-Dorneich, Philipp, Schenk, Karl-Ernst and Schmidtchen, Dieter (eds) (1993), Neue
Politische konomie von Normen und Institutionen (New Political Economics of Norms and
Institutions), 12 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie.
Herder-Dorneich, Philipp, Schenk, Karl-Ernst and Schmidtchen, Dieter (eds) (1994), Neue
Politische konomie der Regulierung, Deregulierung und Privatisierung (New Political
Economics of Regulation, Deregulation, and Privatization), 13 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische
konomie.
Johnsen, D. Bruce (1992), The Incentive Effects of Soft Dollar Brokerage, in Lehn, Kenneth and
Kamphuis, Robert (eds), Modernizing US Securities Regulations: Economic and Legal
Perspectives, 511-519.
Lange, Peter and Regini, Marino (eds) (1989), State, Market, and Social Regulation: New
Perspectives on Italy, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 295 p.
Litan, Robert E. and Winston, Clifford (eds) (1988), Liability: Perspectives and Policy,
Washington, Brookings Institution, 248 p.
Magoulas, Georgios and Simon, Jrgen (eds) (1985), Recht und konomie beim
Konsumentenschutz und Konsumentenkredit (Law and Economics of Consumer Protection
and C), Baden-Baden, Nomos, 436 p.
Maksimovic, Ivan (ed.) (1992), Transformacija Svojinskih Odnosa - Teorijski i Empirijski Aspekti
(Transformation of Property Rights - Theoretical and Empirical Issues), Belgrade, Srpska
akademija nauka i umetnosti (SANU).
Martin, Donald L. and Schwartz, Warren F. (eds) (1977), Deregulating American Industry: Legal
and Economic Problems, Lexington, MA, Lexington Books, 120 p.
McKee, David L. (ed.) (1989), Hostile Takeovers: Issues in Public and Corporate Policy, New
York, Greenwood Press, 179 p.
McPheters, Lee R. and Strange, W.B. (eds) (1976), The Economics of Crime and Law
Enforcement, Springfield, Charles Thomas.
Mercuro, Nicholas (ed.) (1989), Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 264 p.
Meyer, John R. and Oster, Clinton V., Jr (eds) (1981), Airline Deregulation: The Early
Experience, Boston, Auburn House.
Miller, James C., III and Yandle, Bruce (eds) (1979), Benefit-Cost Analysis of Social Regulation,
Washington, American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research.
Mintz, Jack M. and Whalley, John (eds) (1989), The Economic Impacts of Tax Reform, Toronto,
Canadian Tax Foundation, 463 p.
Moorhouse, John C. (ed.) (1986), Electric Power: Deregulation and the Public Intere, San
Francisco, Pacific Research Institute for Public Policy.
Moses, Leon N. and Savage, Ian (eds) (1989), Transportation Safety in an Age of Deregulation,
Oxford, Oxford University Press, 368 p.
Nicklisch, Fritz (ed.) (1987), Der Komplexe Langzeitvertrag. Strukturen und Internationale
Schiedsgerichtsbarkeit (The Complex Long-Term Contract. Structures and International
Arbitration), Heidelberg, Mller Juristischer Verlag, 597 p.
Noll, Roger G. (ed.) (1985), Regulatory Policy and the Social Sciences, Berkeley, University of
California Press, 400 p.
Parisi, Francesco and Giacobbe, Giovanni (1999), Analisi Economica e Libert Contrattuali,
Giuffr.
Peacock, Alan T. and Forte, Francesco (eds) (1981), The Political Economy of Taxation, Oxford,
Blackwell, 211 p.
0050 Collections of (New) Articles 43
Pennock, J. Roland and Chapman, John W. (eds) (1982), Ethics, Economics and the Law (Nomos
24), New York, New York University Press, 323 p.
Peretz, Paul (ed.) (1987), The Politics of American Economic Policy Making, New York, Armonk,
M.E. Sharpe, 454 p.
Peskin, Henry M., Portney, Paul R. and Kneese, Allan V. (eds) (1981), Environmental Regulation
and the U.S. Economy, Baltimore, MD, John Hopkins University Press, 163 p.
Phillips, A. (ed.) (1965), Perpectives on Antitrust Policy, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Phillips, A. (1975), Promoting Competition in Regulated Markets, Washington, Brookings
Institution.
Phillips, A. and Williamson, Oliver E. (eds) (1968), Prices: Issues in Theory, Practice and Public
Policy, Philadelphia, PA, University of Pennsylvania Press.
Prichard, J. Robert S., Stanbury, W.T. and Wilson, Thomas A. (eds) (1979), Canadian
Competition Policy - Essays in Law and Economics, Toronto, Butterworths.
Raes, Koen and Willekens, Harry (1994), Economische Verklaringen van het Recht (Economic
Explanations of Law), .
Roin, Julie, A. (1988), United they Stand, Divided they Fall: Public Choice Theory and the Tax
Code, 74 Cornell Law Review, 62-134.
Roin, Julie, A. (1989), The Grand Illusion: A Neutral System for the Taxation of International
Transactions, 75 Virginia Law Review, 919 ff.
Roin, Julie, A. (1995), Rethinking Tax Treaties in a Strategic World with Disparate Tax Systems,
81 Virginia Law Review, 1753 ff.
Roin, Julie, A. (1997), The U.S. Response to HIV: Alternative Explanations and the Lessons of
Succes, 82 Virginia Law Review, 1511 ff.
Rottenberg, Simon (ed.) (1973), The Economics of Crime and Punishment, Washington, American
Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 232 p.
Rottenberg, Simon (ed.) (1978), The Economics of Medical Malpractice, Washington, American
Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 293 p.
Rottenberg, Simon (ed.) (1980), Occupational Licensure Regulation, Washington, American
Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 354 p.
Rottenberg, Simon (ed.) (1981), The Economics of Legal Mininum Wages, Washington, American
Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 534 p.
Schfer, Hans-Bernd and Wehrt, Klaus (eds) (1989), Die konomisierung der
Sozialwissenschaften: Sechs Wortmeldungen (Economics in Social Sciences: Six
Contributions), Frankfurt am Main, Campus Verlag, 182 p.
Schelling, Thomas C. (ed.) (1983), Incentives for Environmental Protection, Cambridge, MA,
MIT Press, 355 p.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst, Schmidtchen, Dieter and Streit, Manfred E. (eds) (1996), Vom Hoheitsstaat
zum Konsensualstaat, Neue Formen der Kooperation zwischen Staat und Privaten Jahrbuch
fr Neue Politische konomie 15 (From Sovereignity to Consensus, New Forms of
Cooperation Between State and Citizens), Tbingen, Mohr.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst, Schmidtchen, Dieter and Streit, Manfred E. (eds) (1997), Neue Politische
konomie der Integration und ffnung von Infrastrukturnetzen Jahrbuch fr Neue
Politische konomie 16 (Integration of and Access to Infrastructural Networks), Tbingen,
Mohr.
44 Collections of (New) Articles 0050
Shogren, Jason F. (ed.) (1989), The Political Economy of Government Regulation, Dordrecht,
Kluwer, 210 p.
Siegan, Bernard H. (ed.) (1977), The Interactions of Economics and the Law, Lexington, MA,
Lexington Books, 171 p.
Sirkin, Gerald (ed.) (1981), Lexeconomics - The Interactions of Law and Economics, Boston,
Nijhoff, 271 p.
Skogh, Gran (ed.) (1978), Law and Economics. Report from a Symposium in Lund, Lund,
Juridiska Freningen, 231 p.
Theeuwes, Jules J.M., Van Velthoven, Ben C.J. and Winters, J.K. E.A. (1989), Recht en Economie
(Law and Economics), Amsterdam, Addison-Wesley, 294 p.
Weidenbaum, Murray L. and Chilton, Kenneth W. (eds) (1988), Public Policy toward Corporate
Takeovers, New Brunswick, NJ, Transaction, 176 p.
Weisbrod, Burton A., Handler, Joel F. and Komesar, Neil K. (eds) (1978), Public Interest Law: An
Economic and Institutional, Berkeley, University of California Press, 580 p.
Weiss, Leonard W. and Klass, Michael W. (eds) (1986), Regulatory Reform: What Actually
Happened, Boston, Little Brown.
Wills, Robert L., Caswell, Julie A. and Culbertson, John D. (eds) (1987), Issues after a Century of
Federal Competition Policy, Lexington, MA, Lexington Books, 387 p.
X (1990), Special Issue on Law and Economics, Ars Aequi, 603-804.
Zec, Miodrag, Mijatovic Bosko and Nebojsa Savic (eds) (1994), Privatizacija Nuznost ili Sloboda
Izbora (Privatization Necessity or Freedom of Choice), Belgrade, Ekonomski institut and
Jugoslovenska knjiga.
0060
READERS
Copyright 1999 Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest
Alexander, Larry (ed.) (1991), Contract Law. Volumes I and II, Aldershot, Dartmouth, 1140 p.
Assmann, Heinz-Dieter, Kirchner, Christian and Schanze, Erich (1978), konomische Analyse des
Rechts (Economic Analysis of Law), Kronberg, Athenum.
Coase, Ronald H. (1988), The Firm, the Market and the Law, Chicago, University of Chicago
Press, 217 p.
Demsetz, Harold (1988), Ownership, Control, and the Firm. The Organization, Oxford,
Blackwell, 300 p.
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Pejovich, Svetozar (eds) (1974), The Economics of Property Rights,
Cambridge, MA, Ballinger, 367 p.
Goetz, Charles J. (1984), Law and Economics: Cases and Materials, St. Paul, West Publishing
Company.
Goldberg, Victor P. (ed.) (1989), Readings in the Economics of Contract Law, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press, 252 p.
Kaplan, L.J. and Kessler, P. (eds) (1976), An Economic Analysis of Crime: Selected Readings,
Springfield, Charles Thomas.
Kronman, Anthony T. and Posner, Richard A. (eds) (1979), The Economics of Contract Law,
Boston, Little Brown, 274 p.
Kuperberg, Mark and Beitz, Charles R. (eds) (1983), Law, Economics and Philosophy - A Criticial
Introduction; with Applications to the Law of Torts, Totowa, Rowman and Allenheld, 284 p.
Manne, Henry G. (ed.) (1977), The Economics of Legal Relationships: Readings in the Theory of
Property Rights, St. Paul, West Publishing Company, 660 p.
Ogus, Anthony I. and Veljanovski, Cento G. (eds) (1984), Readings in the Economics of Law and
Regulation, Oxford, Clarendon, 361 p.
Parisi, Francesco (1998), The Economic Structure of the Law (The Collected Papers of Richard A.
Posner: Volume I), Cheltenham and Lyme, Edward Elgar, 354 p.
Parisi, Francesco (1998), The Economics of Private Law (The Collected Papers of Richard A.
Posner: Volume II), Cheltenham and Lyme, Edward Elgar, 380 p.
Parisi, Francesco (1998), The Economics of Public Law (The Collected Papers of Richard A.
Posner: Volume III), Cheltenham and Lyme, Edward Elgar, 409 p.
Parisi, Francesco and Giacobbe, Giovanni (1999), Analisi Economica e Libert Contrattuali,
Giuffr.
Parisi, Francesco and Posner Richard A. (1997), International Library of Critical Writings in
Economics, Volume I: Theoretical and Methodological Foundations, Cheltenham and Lyme,
Edward Elgar.
Parisi, Francesco and Posner Richard A. (1997), International Library of Critical Writings in
Europe, Volume II: Contracts, Torts and Criminal Law, Cheltenham and Lyme, Edward
Elgar.
45
46 Readers 0060
Parisi, Francesco and Posner Richard A. (1997), International Library of Critical Writings in
Europe, Volume III: Other Areas of Private and Public Law, Cheltenham and Lyme, Edward Elgar.
Posner, Richard A. (ed.) (1977), Tort Law: Cases and Economic Analysis, Boston, Little Brown.
Posner, Richard A. and Scott, Kenneth E. (eds) (1980), Economics of Corporation Law and
Securities Regulation, Boston, Little Brown, 384 p.
Rabin, Robert L. (ed.) (1976), Perspectives on Tort Law, Boston, Little Brown.
Rubin, Paul H. (1983), Business Firms and The Common Law,.
Schreuders, Wicher and Holzhauer, Rudi W. (1993), Teksten Rechtseconomie (Readings in Law
and Economics), Arnhem, Gouda Quint, 461 p.
Stigler, George J. (1975), The Citizen and the State. Essays on Regulation, Chicago, University of
Chicago Press, 209 p.
Stigler, George J. (ed.) (1988), Chicago Studies in Political Economy, Chicago, University of
Chicago Press, 641 p.
Teijl, Rob and Holzhauer, Rudi W. (eds) (1991), Teksten Rechtseconomie (Readings in Law and
Economics), Arnhem, Gouda Quint, 549 p.
0070
BIBLIOGRAPHIES
Copyright 1999 Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest
Bouckaert, Boudewijn and De Geest, Gerrit (eds.) (1992), Bibliography of Law and Economics,
Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 684 p.
Buchanan, James M. (1987), Bibliography of James M. Buchanans Publications, 1949-1986, 89
Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 17-37.
Campbell, David and Clay, Susan (1976), Long-Term Contracting: A Research Bibliography and
Review of the Literature, Oxford, Centre for Socio-Legal Studies.
Chiorazzi, Michael and others (1988), Empirical Studies in Civil Procedure: A Selected Annotated
Bibliography, 51(3) Law and Contemporary Problems, 87-207.
Foley, Patrick, Shaked, Avner and Sutton, John (1981), The Economics of the Professions. An
Introductory Guide to the Literature, London, London School of Economics, 107 p.
Goehlert, Robert and Gunderson, Nels (1987), Government Regulation of Business: An
Information , Phoenix, Oryx Press, 425 p.
Hoffman, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1985), Experimental Law and Economics: An
Introduction, 85 Columbia Law Review, 991-1036.
McGee, Robert W. (1983), Data Processing Department Practices, Bibliography, National
Association of Accountants.
McGee, Robert W. (1983), Deferred Taxation, Bibliography, National Association of
Accountants.
McGee, Robert W. (1984), Accounting for Software, Bibliography, National Association of
Accountants.
McGee, Robert W. and Greaves, Bettina Bien (1993), Mises: An Annotated Bibliography,
Foundation for Economic Education, 405 p.
Parisi, Francesco (1998a), The Economic Structure of the Law (The Collected Papers of Richard A.
Posner: Volume I), Ashgate, Edward Elgar, 354 p.
Parisi, Francesco (1998b), The Economics of Private Law (The Collected Papers of Richard A.
Posner: Volume II), Ashgate, Edward Elgar, 380 p.
Parisi, Francesco (1998c), The Economics of Public Law (The Collected Papers of Richard A.
Posner: Volume III), Ashgate, Edward Elgar, 409 p.
Parisi, Francesco and Frezza, Giampaolo (1998a), Pietro Trimarchi, in Backhaus, Jrgen G. (ed.),
Elgar Companion to Law and Economics, Ashgate, Edward Elgar.
Parisi, Francesco and Frezza, Giampaolo (1998b), Achille Loria (1847-1943), in Backhaus,
Jrgen G. (ed.), Elgar Companion to Law and Economics, Ashgate, Edward Elgar.
Parisi, Francesco and Frezza, Giampaolo (1998c), Augusto Graziani (1865-1938), in Backhaus,
Jrgen G. (ed.), Elgar Companion to Law and Economics, Ashgate, Edward Elgar.
Parisi, Francesco and Frezza, Giampaolo (1998d), Cesare Beccaria (1738-1794), in McCay,
Bonnie J. and Acheson, James M. (eds), The Question of the Commons: The Culture and
Ecology of Communal Resources, Tucson (AZ), University of Arizona.
47
48 Bibliographies 0070
Parisi, Francesco and Posner, Richard A. (1997a), Law and Economics: An Introduction, in
Posner, Richard A. and Parisi, Francesco (eds), Law and Economics, Ashgate, Edward Elgar,
3-57.
Parisi, Francesco and Posner, Richard A. (1997b), Scuole e Tendenze nella Analisi Economica del
Diritto, 15 Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato.
Parisi, Francesco and Posner Richard A. (1999), Analisi Economica del Diritto Pubblico e
Commerciale: Una Bibliografia Annotata, in X (ed.), Biblioteca della Libert.
Priddat, Birger (1990), Hegel als konom (Hegel as an Economist), 403 Volkswirtschaftliche
Schriften.
Pyle, David J. (1979), The Economics of Crime and Law Enforcement: A Selective Biblipography
(and Supplement 1980), SSRC Public Sector Study Group, Bibliography Series, 216 p.
Samuels, Warren J. (1965), Law and Economic Policy: A Bibliographical Survey, 58 Law
Library Journal, 230-252.
Samuels, Warren J. (1972), Law and Economics: A Bibliographical Survey 1965-72, 66 Law
Library Journal, 96-110.
Sinder, Janet (1987), Economists as Judges: A Selective, Annotated Bibliography, 50(4) Law and
Contemporary Problems, 279-286.
Snow, Marcellus S. and Jussawalla, Meheroo (1986), Telecommunication Economics and
International Regulatory Policy: An Annotated Bibliography, New York, Greenwood Press,
216 p.
Stanbury, W.T. and Tretheway, Michael W. (1986), Airline Deregulation: A Bibliography, 22
Logistics and Transportation Review, 449-489.
Templeton, Virginia Evans and Taubenfeld, Howard J. (1987), World Environment Law
Bibliography: Non Periodical Literature in Law and the Social Sciences Published Since
1970 in Various Languages with Selected Reviews and Annotations from Periodicals,
Littleton, Rothman, 480 p.
Van den Hauwe, Ludwig (1993), Review of Bouckaert & De Geest, Bibliography of Law and
Economics, 77 Public Choice, 917-919.
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1984), Economics of the Common Law: A Bibliography, Oxford, Centre
for Socio-Legal Studies, 59 p.
0080
DOCTORAL OR MASTERS THESES
Copyright 1999 Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest
Adams, Michael (1981), Oekonomische Analyse des Zivilprozesses (Economic Analysis of Civil
Procedure), Koenigstein, Athenaeum-Verlag.
Evangelopoulos, Panagiotis (1996), E Analyse ton Periousiakon Dikaiomaton kai e Ideologia tes
Eleutheres Agoras (Property Rights Analysis and Free-Market Ideology), 6 Aissymnetes.
Fabre-Magnan Muriel (1990), De lObligation dInformation dans les Contrats (The Obligation
of Information in Contracts), L.G.D.J.
Freyer, Susanne (1994), Umwelthaftung aus der Sicht der konomischen Analyse des Rechts
(Environmental Liability from a Law and Economics Perspective), Doctoral Dissertation.
Garoupa, Nuno (1997), Essays on the Theory of Optimal Law Enforcement, University of York,
Phil. Thesis.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1998), An Economic Theory of Greek Contract Law, PhD Thesis, University
of Chicago Law School.
Manitakis, Antonios (1975), LAntinomie entre la Libert du Commerce et de lIndustrie et la
Rgulation Administrative de lconomie: En Droit Belge et en Droit Franais, Bruxelles,
Centre Interuniversitaire de Droit Public.
McGee, Robert W. (1993), Explorations in Law and Economics from a Rights Perspective, The
Union Institute, 221 p.
Moine, I. (1997), Les choses hors commerce. Une approche de la personne humaine juridique
(Things Apart from Commerce. An Approach of Juridical Humane Persons), L.G.D.J.
Poughon, Jean-Michel (1987), Histoire doctrinale de lchange, (Doctrinal History of Exchange),
L.G.D.J.
Raaschou-Nielsen, Agnete (1988), Institutionel ndring og konomisk Teori (Institutional
Change and Economic Theory), Kbenhavn, PhD thesis, Det Statsvidenskablige Fagrd.
Riis, Thomas (1996), Ophavsret og retskonomi (Copyright and Law and Economics), Gadjura,
PhD thesis.
Roemer, Andrs (1994), An Interdisciplinary Approach to Federal Waters and Institutions: The
Mexican Case, UP/Michigan Publishers.
Ryssdal, Stray A.C. (1995), Legal Realism and Economics as Behavior - A Scandinavian Look at
the Economic Analysis of Law, Oslo, Juridisk Forlag.
Sevic, Zeljko (1994), Pravni Status Centralne Banke u Savremenoj Trzisnoj Privredi (Status of
the Central Bank in a Contemporary Market Economy), Belgrade, Faculty of Law, University
of Belgrade.
Zenati, F. (1981), Essai sur la Nature Juridique de la Proprit, Contribution la Thorie
Juridique du Droit Subjectif, (Essay on the Juridical Nature of Property, Contributions to the
Juridical Theory of Subjective Rights).
49
0100
ORGANIZATION OF RESEARCH AND
TEACHING
Claus Ott
Professor of Law at theUniversity of Hamburg
Tina Neuling
Research Assistant at theUniversity of Hamburg
Copyright 1999 Claus Ott and Tina Neuling
Abstract
Law and economics is quite a new field of research but there is a noticeable
increase in its influence in both legal and economic scholarship. In the
following chapter information is given about different aspects of the
organization of research and teaching in this area, in particular about the
institutions, the current state of law and economics in academic life all over the
world, the basic publications providing more detailed information, Law and
Economics Associations, and law and economics on the Internet.
JEL classification: K00
Keywords: law and economics, Academic Programs, Teaching, Research,
Research Institutes, law and economics Associations
1. Introduction
Law and economics is a relatively new field of research, and therefore it is only
slowly becoming an established part of the curricula at universities and colleges
throughout the world. However, there is a clear movement towards employing
the tools of law and economics in academic programs and in special research
institutes more and more. While most of the literature describing and
discussing these influences concentrates on developments at law schools, the
field is also being explored in traditional departments of economics. Overall,
there is a noticeable increase in the influence of law and economics in both
legal and economic scholarship. Nevertheless, the relative importance of the
field is still heavily debated. For example, it is often discussed whether or not
the economic analysis of law can or cannot provide for a new understanding of
the law, and how economic tools have changed the classical study of the law.
One extensive discussion about the role of law and economics in legal
education has been published in the Journal of Legal Education. In that
edition, various opinions are presented in fourteen articles covering about 200
50
0100 Organization of Research and Teaching 51
pages. The original debate was held at a symposium in 1983 entitled The Place
of Economics in Legal Education (Symposium, 1983). The primary focus of
the articles is the relevance of economics on legal thought in general (see
Becker, 1983, Breyer, 1983; Calabresi, 1983; Cooter, 1983; Hansmann, 1983;
Michelmann, 1983; and Priest, 1983). However, some of the authors also
discuss the practical application of law and economics in teaching (see Doyle,
1982; Gelhorn and Robinson, 1983; Klevorick, 1983; Schwartz, M., 1983;
Schwartz W., 1983; Summers, 1983; and Trebilcock, 1983). In 1981 a similar
symposium was held at Yale University, and in the papers presented at that
conference (published in the Yale Law Journal) the authors - among them
Ackerman (1981), Posner (1981) and Priest (1981), analyzed the current state
of legal scholarship. Law and economics was only one of the focuses of
discussions there, and the influence of other disciplines which were noticeable
in legal scholarship was also discussed. One example of a similar symposium
convened outside of the United States is that of the 1991 symposium Economic
Analysis in Civil Law Countries: Past, Present, Future (see Cooter and
Gordley, 1991). There, scholars from different countries provided information
about the influence of law and economics in their respective home countries.
See Mattei and Pardolesi (1991) report on Italy, Kirchner (1991) report on
Germany, Hertig (1991) report on Switzerland (pointing out the apparent lack
of a law and economics movement in Switzerland), Ota (1991) report on Japan,
Pastor (1991) report on Spain, Skogh (1991) report on Sweden, and Weigel
(1991) report on Austria.
One interesting approach to measuring the actual influence of law and
economics has been taken by Landes and Posner (1993). In their article, the
authors present a quantitative study in which they analyze citations to show the
extent to which economics has in fact influenced legal scholarship.
The following chapters will provide a short overview over different methods
of teaching law and economics, and how the research in this area continues to
be promoted throughout the world. Since academic programs are constantly
changing and many different programs and institutions are still in their
developmental stages, only representative examples will be presented here.
Much information concerning specific programs or classes can be obtained in
detail from the home pages of the respective universities/institutions on the
Internet, and can be located through the main search engines. Greater detail
about specific countries can furthermore be found in chapters 0305-0395 of this
volume, in which the law and economics movements in different countries are
presented.
52 Organization of Research and Teaching 0100
Though law and economics is also part of the curricula of many departments
of economics, most programs in law and economics are organized by private
and public law schools. However, economics scholars often actively participate,
and several law schools and departments of economics or business work
together in joint programs. Quite often, professors of economics are asked to
join law school faculties and to teach there on a permanent basis. Furthermore,
there are numerous special institutes formed of both law and economics faculty
members.
There are a variety of possibilities to study and teach law and economics at
different academic levels and to different audiences. As stated above, it can be
taught in law schools, in university-based departments of economics, or at
special research institutes. At universities, law and economics can be taught at
an undergraduate, graduate or postgraduate level. Finally, law and economics
can either be integrated into regular law school courses, or there can be special
course offerings either as optional courses or within a separate program.
At law schools, law and economics may be integrated into the traditional law
school curriculum. This can be accomplished by first providing an introduction
into the basic principles of economics, and later on by encouraging the use of
the economic tools learned. This approach is favored by some American law
schools where the law and economics approach is an essential tool for
understanding the law courses offered in subsequent years. In such programs,
basic economics courses and later on economic analysis of different areas of the
law are often mandatory requirements.
The most progressive steps so far have been taken by the American George
Mason University School of Law in Arlington, Virginia (George Mason
University School of Law, 3401 North Fairfax Drive, Arlington, VA
22201-4498, USA). This program emphasizes application of the law and
economics approach to the entire study of the law. Almost all of the courses at
George Mason use economic theory as their primary method of analysis.
More commonly, however, law schools employ economic tools only
within the framework of certain specific courses. Law and economics ideas can
and are - at least in the United States - typically treated in the classic law and
economic courses (for example antitrust law or corporate law). These courses
have served as the traditional forum for the application of the law and
economics approach. There exists, however, a growing tendency towards
employing law and economics in more and more non-traditional law courses
(for example torts, real property, contracts or civil procedure). Today, law and
0100 Organization of Research and Teaching 53
economics is being integrated more and more into the traditional core curricula
of legal studies. This expansion is often referred to as the New Law and
economics. A brief description of the so-called New Law and economics can
be found in Calabresi (1983), and Veljanovski (1982) also gives a good
overview over this approach. On the other hand, Kirchner (1991) refers back
to the previous tradition in Germany of interdisciplinary research in the field
of law and economics which was more or less confined to cartel law, and traces
the introduction of new law and economics into legal research and teaching
back in the 1970s.
A detailed exposition on what law and economics scholars and economists
currently think lawyers should know about economics can be found in Whaples,
Morriss and Moorhouse (1998). In preparing this report the authors conducted
a survey to find out which concepts the scholars interviewed deemed to be
necessary in the teaching of law and economics courses, and what major
articles they would recommend for a required reading list.
Law and economics can, of course, be integrated into classical economics
courses. However, this approach is more rare and less information about it is
available.
France, Italy, the Netherlands, Spain, and the United Kingdom. In Austria the
University of Innsbruck offers a course in Economic Analysis of Law in
addition to fundamental classes in economics for law-students. At the
Katholieke Universiteit Leuven in Belgium an English language course entitled
Economic Analysis of Law is offered which is based upon a microeconomics
and game-theory methodology. Also, the University of Ghent in Belgium offers
a course entitled Rechtseconomie to both law and economics students. In
France, the University of Montpellier also offers special classes in law and
economics. The University of Trento in Italy has an optional class called
Topics of Economic Analysis of the Law. All of these are simply examples of
current courses being offered in Europe.
The early situation in the Netherlands is described in more detail by
Holzhauer and Teijl (1989). Recently, the growing influence of law and
economics in the Dutch legal education has become noticeable. Nowadays, law
and economics is often offered as a basic introductory course. Examples can be
found at the relevant Internet home sites of the Erasmus University of
Rotterdam. The earlier status of law and economics at Spanish law schools is
described in Pastor (1988) as well as Pastor (1991).
Other countries where the study of law and economics is especially
emphasized include the United States, and also Israel, Canada, Australia and
New Zealand. Gelhorn and Robinson (1983) review the development of
economic science in US law schools and comment on that developments
relevance. Lovett (1974) also addresses the role of economics in American law
schools and closely examines the curricula at several law schools in the United
States. The Buchmann Faculty of Law at Tel-Aviv University has classes where
law and economics are combined at the undergraduate level as well as at the
graduate level. Trebilcock (1983) provides information about the changes at
law schools in Canada. He points out that the influence of law and economics
in Canadian legal education is limited as compared to the United States and
presents possible explanations for this. The author himself, however, actively
participates in promoting law and economics scholarship in Canada. Doyle
(1982) extensively examines lecture courses in law and economics offered at an
undergraduate level in Australia.
The most recent developments regarding law and economics in various
countries are described in the chapter 0300 Survey of Non-English Language
Publications. One example of a course in law and economics offered to students
of economics is the course Analisis Economico del Derecho at the
Universidad Carlos III de Madrid in Madrid, Spain. Professor Santos Pastor,
who teaches this class, also wrote the above-cited article Teaching Economics
to Law Students (Pastor, 1988).
0100 Organization of Research and Teaching 55
Still another possibility exists, namely the teaching of law and economics in a
separate program specializing in law and economics. The ERASMUS
Programme in law and economics is a one-year European postgraduate
program for lawyers and economists leading to the academic degree of
European Master in Law and Economics. It is jointly organized by 19 partner
universities within the European Union. The University of Haifa, Israel is also
an associate member. Special courses in law and economics are offered at ten
of the partner universities. The programs partners (T = partner and teaching
unit) are the universities of Aix-en-Provence (T), Berlin, Copenhagen, Ghent
(T), Glasgow, Haifa, Hamburg (T), Leiden (T), Linkping (T), Madrid (T),
Manchester (T), Milan, Paris, Rome, Rotterdam (T), Stockholm (T), Tampere,
Thessaloniki, Valladolid, and Vienna (T). The ERASMUS Programme in law
and economics is presently coordinated from the University of Hamburg
(C.Ott).
The University of Utrecht is an example of a law school offering a
postgraduate program leading to a degree in law and economics (Utrecht LLM
Office, Faculty of Law, Utrecht University, Janskerhof 3, 3512 BK Utrecht, The
Netherlands). This program is open to both law school and economics program
graduates. Students of economics may complete specialized legal courses and
are able to obtain a Master of Sciences title.
In the United States, one of the most important programs is the John M.
Olin Program in law and economics at the University of Chicago. In that
program law and economics ideas have been taught for over 50 years. The
significant achievements of that program are described by Coase (1993). At the
American College of Law at Syracuse University in New York (Syracuse
University College of Law, Office of Admissions and Financial Aid, Suite 212,
Syracuse, NY 13244-1030, USA) another form of specialization can be found.
Students are able to participate in a program of studies offering a special Law
and Economics Concentration. During their normal studies of the law, students
are required to take five core courses involving law and economics topics and
three elective courses. Once these requirements have been met the students are
awarded a special certificate in recognition that they have completed this
special concentration.
At the Faculty of Law at the University of Toronto (Faculty of Law,
University of Toronto, 78 Queens Park, Toronto, Ontario, Canada, M5 S 2
C5), where Professor Trebilcock teaches, instructors from the Faculty of Law,
the Department of Economics and the Faculty of Management work together.
The program offers students special study and research opportunities in a
variety of courses, and brings to the Faculty important law and economics
scholars through the programs law and economics Workshops and the Visiting
Professorship in Law and Economics.
56 Organization of Research and Teaching 0100
6. Teaching Materials
The basic teaching materials for all law and economic classes are the two
classic textbooks: Posner, Economic Analysis of Law (1998), now in its fifth
edition, and Cooter and Ulen, Law and Economics (1996), now in its second
edition. In addition, other textbooks intended to provide a basis for academic
studies in law and economics have been published. Recent examples include
Schfer and Ott, Lehrbuch der konomischen Analyse des Rechts (1995),
now in its second edition and also available in Spanish, Miceli, The Economics
of the Law (1998), Katz, Foundations of the Economic Approach to Law
(1998), Dau-Schmidt and Ulen, Law and Economics Anthology (1998),
Posner, and Parisi, Law and Economics (1997) a three volume set, Mercuro
and Medema, Economics and the Law: From Posner to Post-Modernism
(1997), and Dnes, The Economics of Law (1996). Earlier examples of such
works include Manne, The Economics of Legal Relationships (1975),
Tullock, The Logic of the Law (1971), and Bowles, Law and the Economy
(1982). These textbooks all share the common characteristic that they are
specifically designed to serve as textbooks for law-students. Other literature -
of course - can and is also applied in classrooms. The literature identified above
can be found in the bibliography in Chapter 0000 Introductory Books.
Examples of how the law and economics approach can be used to analyze
specific cases in the classroom are Schfer and Strck (1983) and Walz and
Wienstroh (1983), both published in Walz and Rascher-Friesenhausen (1983),
and Wehrt and Mohr (1995).
0100 Organization of Research and Teaching 57
Research in the area of law and economics is becoming more and more
noticeable. There exists an expanding body of literature (books, theses,
dissertations, working papers, and journals), and researchers from all over the
world regularly meet at academic conferences, workshops and through various
law and economics associations. Universities all over the world also host
periodic conferences and discussion groups which have a law and economics
focus. At several universities special research centers dedicated to law and
economics exist.
In the United States - the birthplace of law and economics - research centers in
law and economics are quite common. The universities identified above which
offer law and economics courses also maintain extensive research facilities.
Thus, at Yale, the University of California-Berkeley or at the University of
Chicago research in the field of law and economics is strongly supported and
promoted. Workshops and conferences are also currently being offered at the
Georgetown University Law Center in Washington, DC. At Georgetown, a law
and economics Workshop exists in which students, faculty, and outside
speakers regularly present their work. In addition, special academic conferences
are organized on a regular basis. Another prominent center of research in the
US is the Business, law and economics Center of the John M. Olin School of
Business at Washington University in St. Louis, Missouri. The Olin Center,
which was founded in 1991, focuses its research on how law, economics, and
politics converge to influence private business.
Research in the field of law and economics is not only undertaken at certain
universities or law schools. For example, the Institute for Civil Justice in the
United States, which is an independent research program within RAND (1700
0100 Organization of Research and Teaching 59
students are publishing theses emphasizing law and economics. This is a trend
which is recognizable throughout the world (see 0080 Doctoral or Masters
Theses). The number of professional journals dealing with law and economics
topics is also constantly increasing. Some of these journals are now being listed
in the world wide web, making it possible for a much larger audience to scan
through the publications table of contents with just a few mouse clicks. The
Internet also allows researchers and scholars to exchange information in real
time and at a comparably low cost. Since 1994, the George Mason University
has established an on-line discussion forum on law and economics topics called
Econlaw. Forum participants can easily exchange opinions and download the
work of their colleagues from their respective web-sites. All of these
developments demonstrate that research as well as teaching in the field of law
and economics is becoming more and more a global phenomenon.
Acknowledgements
Ackerman, Bruce A. (1981), Comment: The Marketplace of Ideas,90 Yale Law Journal, 1131-1148.
Alpa, Guido (1995), Istituzioni di Diritto privato (Institutes of private law), Torino, UTET.
Becker, Edward R. (1983), The Uses of Law and Economics by Judges, 33 Journal of Legal
Education, 306-310.
Beveridge, W. (1921), Economics as a Liberal Education, 1 Economica, 2-19.
Breyer, Stephen G. (1983), Economics for Lawyers and Judges, 33 Journal of Legal Education,
294-305.
Brietzke, Paul H. (1986), Another Law and Economics, 9 Research in Law and Economics, 57-109.
Calabresi, Guido (1978), On the General State of Law and Economics Research Today and Its Current
Problems and Prospects, in Skogh, Gran (ed.), Law and Economics. Report from a Symposium
in Lund, Lund, Juridiska Freningen, 9-16.
Calabresi, Guido (1983), Thoughts on the Future of Economics in Legal Education, 33 Journal of
Legal Education, 359-364.
Coase, Ronald H. (1993), Law and Economics at Chicago, 36 Journal of Law and Economics,
239-254.
Cooter, Robert D. (1983), Comment, 33 Journal of Legal Education, 237-238.
0100 Organization of Research and Teaching 61
Cooter, Robert D. (1991), Economic Theories of Legal Liability (Italian translation:Le teorie
economiche della risponsibilit efficenza produttiva: alcuni contributi su noti argomenti
379-409), 5 Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11-30. Reprinted in Medema, Steven G. (ed.),
The Legacy of Ronald Coase in Economic Analysis, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham and
Lyme. Italian translation: Le teorie economiche della risponsabilit legale, published in
Gianandrea Goisis.
Cooter, Robert D. and Gordley, James (1991), Economic Analysis in Civil Law Countries: Past,
Present, Future - Introduction to a Symposium, 11 International Review of Law and Economics,
261-263.
Doyle, D.A. (1982), Alternative Teaching Strategies in Law and Economics Courses: Compression,
Thematization and the Corporate Field, in Cranston, Ross and Schick, Anne (eds), Law and
Economics, Canberra, Australian National University, 208-273.
Gay, David E.R. (1979), A Curriculum Note on the New Law and Economics, XXXPapers and
Proceedings of the Southwestern Society of Economists, 59-66.
Gelhorn, Ernest and Robinson, Glen O. (1983), The Role of Economic Analysis in Legal Education,
33 Journal of Legal Education, 247-273.
Hansmann, Henry B. (1983), The Current State of Law and Economics Scholarship, 33 Journal of
Legal Education, 217-236.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1997), Eisagoge sten oikonomike analyse tou dikaiou (Introduction to the
Economic Analysis of Law), Aristotle University of Thessaloniki School of Law and Economics,
Department of History, Philosophy and Sociology of Law.
Hertig, Gerard (1991), Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries: Switzerland, 11 International
Review of Law and Economics, 293-300.
Holzhauer, Rudi W. and Teijl, Rob (1989), Rechtseconomie in Nederland (Law and Economics in the
Netherlands), 38(4) Ars Aequi, 248-252.
Kirchner, Christian (1991), The Difficult Reception of Law and Economics in Germany, 11
International Review of Law and Economics, 277-292.
Kitch, Edmund W. (1980), The Law and Economics Programme, 26 University of Chicago Law
School Record, 42-44.
Klevorick, Alvin K. (1983), Reflections on The Current State of Law-and-Economics Scholarship,
33 Journal of Legal Education, 239-246.
Ktz, Hein (1977), konomische analyse van rechtsproblemen - Entwurf einer Lehrveranstaltung fr
Juristen, in Horn, N. and Tieze, R. (eds), Sozialwissenschaften im Studium des Rechts, Mnchen,
234-244.
Krier, James E. (1974), Economics in the Law School, 22 University of Pennsylvania Law Review,
1664-1705.
Lande, Robert H. (1992), A Law and Economics Perspective on a Traditional Torts Case: Insights
for Classroom and Courtroom, 57 Missouri Law Review, 399 ff.
Landes, William M. and Posner, Richard A. (1993), The Influence of Economics of Law: A
Quantitative Study, 36 Journal of Law and Economics, 385-424.
Lovett, W.A. (1974), Economic Analysis and its Role in Legal Education, 26 Journal of Legal
Education, 385-421.
Mackaay, Ejan (1987), Le juriste a-t-il le droit dignorer leconomiste? (May Lawyers Ignore
Economists?), Revue de la Recherche Juridique, 419-427.
Manne, Henry G. (1994), Le origini intellettuali di una scuola di anlisi economica del diritto, 12
Rivista critica del diritto privato, 167-181.
62 Organization of Research and Teaching 0100
Mattei, Ugo and Pardolesi, Roberto (1991), Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries: A
Comparative Approach, 11 International Review of Law and Economics, 265-275.
Meyer, Justus and Mller, Wolfgang (1990), konomischen Analyse des Rechts (Report on the
Summer Schools in Economic Analysis of Law in Saarbrcken), 1990 Juristische Schulung,
157-157.
Michelman, Frank I. (1983), Reflections on Professional Education, Legal Scholarship, and the
Law-and-Economics Movement, 33 Journal of Legal Education, 197-216.
Ota, Shozo (1991), Law and Economics in Japan: Hatching Stage, 11 International Review of Law
and Economics, 301-308.
Pastor, Santos (1988), La enseanza de la economa en las facultades de Derecho (Teaching
Economics to Law Students), in Ruiz-Huerta, Jess and Loscos, Javier (eds), Revista de la
Facultad de Derecho.
Pastor, Santos (1991), Law and Economics in Spain, 11 International Review of Law and
Economics, 309-317.
Posner, Richard A. and Parisi, Francesco (1997), Law and Economics: An Introduction, in Posner,
Richard A. and Parisi, Francesco (ed.s), Law and Economics, Cheltenham and Lyme, Edward
Elgar, 3-57.
Posner, Richard A. (1981), The Present Situation in Legal Scholarship, 90 Yale Law Journal,
1113-1130.
Posner, Richard A. (1989), The Future of Law and Economics: A Comment on Ellickson, 65
Chicago-Kent Law Review, 57-62.
Priest, George L. (1981), The New Scientism in Legal Scholarship: A Comment on Clark and Posner,
90 Yale Law Journal, 1284-1295.
Priest, George L. (1983), Social Science Theory and Legal Education: The Law School as University,
33 Journal of Legal Education, 437-441.
Priest, George L. (1991), Preface: Law and Economics after Europes Revolution, in Weigel,
Wolfgang (ed.), Economic Analysis of Law - A Collection of Applications, Vienna,
sterreichischer Wirtschaftsverlag, 5-7.
Rose, Jonathan (1995), The MacCrate Report: A Restatement of Legal Education - the Need for
Reflection and Horse Sense, 44 Journal of Legal Education, 548 ff.
Rowley, Charles K. (1981), Social Sciences and the Law: The Relevance of Economic Theories, 1
Oxford Journal of Legal Studies, 391-405.
Rowley, Charles K. (1985), Supreme Court Economic Review, 5 International Review of Law and
Economics, 107-119.
Salop, Steven C. (1988), Evaluating Uncertain Evidence with Sir Thomas Bayes: A Note for Teachers:
Response, 2 Journal of Economic Perspectives, 178-179.
Schfer, Hans-Bernd (1990), Vom Nutzen und Nachteil der konomie im Rechtsstudium (Advantages
and Disadvantages of Economics in Legal Education), in X (ed.), Juristenausbildung - erneut
berdacht (New Thoughts on Legal Eduction), 294-321.
Schfer, Hans-Bernd and Struck, Gerhard (1983), Schlammbeseitigung auf der Bundesstrasse.
Geschftsfhrung ohne Auftrag, Deliktsrecht, negatorische Haftung. konomische Analyse des
Rechts (The Case of the Mud Removal at the Federal Highway), in Walz, W. Rainer and
Rascher-Friesenhausen, Hein (eds), Sozialwissenschaften im Zivilrecht: Flle und Lsungen in
Ausbildung und Prfung, Neuwied und Darmstadt, Luchterhand, 119-132.
Schwartz, Murray L. (1983), Economics in Legal Education, 33 Journal of Legal Education,
365-368.
0100 Organization of Research and Teaching 63
Schwartz, Warren F. (1983), The Future of Economics in Legal Education: The Prospects for a New
Model Curriculum, 33 Journal of Legal Education, 314-336.
Sheehan, Michael F. (1988), Institutionalists Before Regulatory Commissions: The Value of Doing
in Thinking, Teaching, and Writing, 22 Journal of Economic Issues, 1169-1178.
Sousa Franco, Atnio (1992), Anlise Econmica do Direito: Exerccio Intelectual ou Fonte de
Ensinamento? (Economic Analysis of Law), 2 Sub Judice, 63-70.
Stevens, Robert (1983), Law School. Legal Education in America from the 1850s to the 1980s,
Chapel Hill, University of North Carolina Press, 334 p.
Stigler, George J. (1982), Economists and Public Policy, 13 Regulation, 13-17.
Summers, Robert S. (1983), The Future of Economics in Legal Education: Limits and Constraints,
33 Journal of Legal Education, 337-358.
Symposium (1983), The Place of Economics in Legal Education, 33 Journal of Legal Education,
183-376.
Trebilcock, Michael J. (1983), The Prospects of Law and Economics : A Canadian Perspective, 33
Journal of Legal Education, 288-290.
Ulen, Thomas S. (1989), Law and Economics: Settled Issues and Open Questions, in Mercuro,
Nicholas (ed.), Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 201-231.
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1982), The New Law and Economics. A Research Review, Oxford, Centre for
Socio-Legal Studies, 169 p.
Vracar, K. Stevan (1994), Preispitivanja pravne metodologije: Nagovestaji drzavno-pravnog
integralizma (Reexamination of the Legal Methodology: Indications of State-Legal Integralism),
Naucna knjiga, Belgrade.
Walz, Rainer W. (1983), Die Fehlgeschlagene Investition (The Case of the Investment Failure), in
Walz, Rainer W. And Rascher-Friesenhausen, Hein (eds), Sozialwissenschaften im Zivilrecht:
Flle und Lsungen in Ausbildung und Prfung, Neuwied und Darmstadt, Luchterhand, 52-75.
Walz, W. Rainer and Rascher-Friesenhausen, Hein (eds) (1983), Sozialwissenschaften im Zivilrecht,
Flle und Lsu (Social Science in Civil Law, Cases and Answers), Neuwied und Darmstadt,
Luchterhand.
Walz, W. Rainer and Wienstroh, Claas (1983), Die Fehlgeschlagene Investition (The Case of the
Investment Failure), in Walz, W. Rainer and Rascher-Friesenhausen, Hein (eds),
Sozialwissenschaften im Zivilrecht: Flle und Lsungen in Ausbildung und Prfung, Neuwied
und Darmstadt, Luchterhand, 52-75.
Whaples, Robert, Morriss, Andrew P. and Moorhouse, John C. (1998), What Should Lawyers Know
about Economics?, 48 Journal of Legal Education, 120-124.
Wehrt, Klaus and Mohr, Klaus (1995), Der Einbau der konomischen Analyse des Rechts in ein
juristisches Fallgutachten (Including the Economic Analysis of Law in Legal Reasoning), 1995
Jura, 536-542.
Wiegang, Wolfgang (1988), Die Rezeption amerikanischen Rechts (The Reception of American
Law), in X (ed.), Die schweizerische Rechtsordung in ihren internationalen Bezgen, Bern,
Haupt, 229-262.
Wills, Robert L. (1987), Economists and Competition Policy: A Case Study, in Wills, Robert L. and
Caswell, Julie A. (eds), Issues after a Century of Federal Competition Policy, Lexington, MA,
Lexington Books, 3-8.
64 Organization of Research and Teaching 0100
Wilson, G. (1980), Socio-Legal Research in Germany, London, Social Science Research Council.
X (1982), No Anti-Antitrust Bias at the Law and Economics Center: Federal Judges cant be
Brainwashed , 14 Antitrust Law and Economics Review, 15-70.
X (1983), Foreword: Chicago Economics, the FTC, and the Education of the Federal Judiciary, 15
Antitrust Law and Economics Review, 1-8.
Other References
Bowles, Roger (1982), Law and the Economy, Oxford, Martin Robertson.
Cooter, Robert and Ulen, Thomas S. (1996), Law and Economics, Glenview, Scott Foresmann (2nd
ed).
Dau-Schmidt, Kenneth and Ulen, Thomas S. (1998), Law and Economics Anthology, Ohio, Anderson
Publishing
Dnes, Antony W. (1996), The Economics of Law, International Thomson Business Press.
Hertig, Grard (1991), Switzerland, 11 International Review of Law and Economics, 293-300.
Katz, Avery Wiener (1998), Foundations of the Economic Approach to Law, Oxford, Oxford
University Press.
Kirchner, Christian (1991), The Difficult Reception of Law and Economics in Germany, 11
International Review of Law and Economics, 277-292.
Manne, Henry (1975), The Economics of Legal Relationships. Readings in the Theory of Property
Rights, St. Paul, West Publishing Company.
Mercuro, Nicholas and Medema, Steven G. (1997), Economics and the Law: from Posner to
Post-Modernism, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Miceli, Thomas J. (1998), Economics of the Law: Torts, Contracts, Property, Litigation, Oxford,
Oxford University Press.
Ota, Shozo (1991), Law and Economics in Japan: Hatching Stage, 11 International Review of Law
and Economics, 301-308.
Pastor, Santos (1991), Law and Economics in Spain, 11 International Review of Law and
Economics, 309-317.
Posner, Richard, (1998), Economic Analysis of Law, Boston, Aspen Publishers (5th edn).
Posner, Richard A. and Parisi, Francesco (1997), Law and Economics, Cheltenham and Lyme, Edward
Elgar.
Schfer, Hans Bernd and Ott, Claus (1995), Lehrbuch der konomischen Analyse des Rechts
(Handbook of Economic Analysis of Civil Law), Berlin, Springer (2nd edn).
Skogh, Gran (1991), Law and Economics in Sweden, 11 International Review of Law and
Economics, 319-324.
Tullock, Gordon (1971), The Logic of the Law, New York, Basic Books.
Weigel, Wolfgang (1991) Prospects for Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries: Austria, 11
International Review of Law and Economics, 325-329.
0200
HISTORY OF LAW AND ECONOMICS
Ejan Mackaay
Professor of Law
University of Montreal
Copyright 1999 Ejan Mackaay
Abstract
1. Introduction
The economic analysis of law, or law and economics, may be defined as the
application of economic theory and econometric methods to examine the
formation, structure, processes and impact of law and legal institutions
(Rowley, 1989b, p. 125). It explicitly considers legal institutions not as given
outside the economic system but as variables within it, and looks at the effects
of changing one or more of them upon other elements of the system. In the
economic analysis of law, legal institutions are treated not as fixed outside the
economic system, but as belonging to the choices to be explained.
This approach is advocated not merely for legal rules with an obvious link
to economic realities such as competition, economic organisation, prices and
profits, and income distribution, which translate into competition law,
65
66 History of Law and Economics 0200
industrial regulation, labour law and tax law. Law and economics has the
ambition of applying the economic approach not merely to these areas of
economic regulation readily associated with economics, but to all areas of law,
in particular to the core of the common law.
The current incarnation of law and economics originated in the United
States in the late 1950s and found acceptance amongst the legal community
from the 1970s onwards, as a result, in particular, of the writings of Richard A.
Posner. It has been presented at times as an altogether novel introduction of
concepts and methods of a neighbouring science into law, in that it addresses
questions across the entire range of legal subject matter, including much
non-market behaviour (Posner, 1975a, p. 759).
This view may overstate the originality of the movement. Recent historical
research has shown that already in nineteenth century Europe, there existed a
broad scholarly movement whose ambition was to show how a better
understanding of law could be gained by using economic concepts and methods
(Englard, 1990; Pearson, 1997). Holmess oft-cited exhortation to legal
scholars, in 1897, to turn to economics and statistics: For the rational study of
the law the black-letter man may be the man of the present, but the man of the
future is the man of statistics and the master of economics (Holmes, 1897, p.
469) may have pulled the American branch into the limelight. But if
Hovenkamp (1990) is to be believed, Holmes merely gave voice to a
development which had already reached the United States in the 1880s and
continued well into the twentieth century. This movement is known - rather too
little as Pearson contends (1997, pp. 159-161) - as institutional economics
(Duxbury; 1995; Pearson, 1997, p. vii; Medema, 1998). But this is not the only
connection between law and economics prior to the current movement. At the
University of Chicago, where the current movement originated, there was, from
1940s onwards, an earlier infusion of economic ideas into law, associated with
the name of Aaron Director.
It is instructive to look at these earlier branches of law and economics to
understand the reasons for both their initial attraction and their ultimate
decline. In a broader context, the question has recently been raised why the
winds turned and intellectual leadership in legal theory moved from
Continental Europe to the United States (Mattei, 1994c). For the current
movement, a deeper historical perspective should make one wary of the belief
that present understanding provides a definitive account of the legal system.
Such caution is in order at a time when, in one scholars words (Ellickson,
1989, p. 26), law and economics is no longer growing as a scholarly or
curricular force within the leading American law schools. Instead, it is simply
holding previously won ground. Study of the earlier movements may point us
to the research agenda to adopt if we wish the current one to continue.
Law and economics borrows concepts and methods from economics proper. It
inherits the controversies to which they are subject in the mother discipline. In
0200 History of Law and Economics 67
economics proper, the question has recently been raised of what has gone
wrong in the discipline (Boettke, 1997): even half a generation ago the
neoclassical model reigned supreme and virtually unquestioned; now
economists appear divided on their theoretical framework.
This debate spills over into the economic analysis of law. Since the 1980s,
gone is the beautiful consensus about method and agenda, generated by the first
editions of Posners textbook (1972b, 1977) solidly based on neoclassical
economic insights. Besides the Chicago approach, various shades of
institutional (Benson, 1994; Mercuro and Medema, 1997, chs 4 and 5;
Samuels, 1990, 1998a, 1998b, 1998c; Samuels and Mercuro, 1984; Samuels
ans Rutherford, 1998; Samuels and Schmid, 1981; Schmid, 1989a, 1989b,
1994; Teijl and Holzhauer, 1990) or neo-institutional (Alston, Eggertsson and
North, 1996; Coase, 1984, 1992; Eggertsson, 1990; Furubotn, 1989, 1993;
Furubotn and Richter, 1992, 1997; Knight, 1992; Langlois, 1986; Medema,
1989; Mercuro, 1989; North, 1984, 1986, 1991, 1993, 1994, 1995, 1996;
Williamson, 1985, 1986, 1996) approach to law and economics have come to
the fore, as has the Austrian approach (Barnett, 1992, 1998; Benson, 1994;
Boettke, 1994; Bouckaert, 1984; Boudreaux, 1994; Hayek, 1973, 1976, 1979;
Kinsella, 1995; Leoni, 1991; Lepage, 1985; Ogus, 1989; Rizzo, 1979b, 1980a,
1980b, 1980c, 1980d, 1981, 1982a, 1982b, 1985, 1987; Rizzo and Arnold,
1980, 1987; Rowley, 1989a, 1989b; Rowley and Brough, 1987; Schmidtchen,
1993; Teijl and Holzhauer, 1997; Thornton, 1991; Vanberg, 1998a; Voigt,
1992; Wonnell, 1986). These approaches emphasise the interest of historical
studies, which received a powerful endorsement when the 1993 Nobel prize for
economics was awarded to two economic historians, Douglass North and
Robert Fogel (North, 1994).
Since Posners initial impetus, the sources from which the law and
economics movement may draw inspiration have broadened. They now also
include the public choice school, bringing an economic approach to political
processes, and game theory, which has become a rallying point for the social
sciences in that it applies rational choice ideas to the interaction of two or more
actors, or indeed a multitude of them with the attendant opportunities for free-
rider and hold-out strategies.
For the purpose of exposition, it will be helpful to divide the history of law
and economics into phases. Duxbury (1995, p. 340) cautions against the danger
of historical reductionism in such periodisation. Simplicity of exposition makes
it nonetheless worthwhile in my view.
2. Precursors
Such an understanding was the ambition of what may be called the first wave
of law and economics. This movement, if indeed it may be properly called that,
given the relative heterogeneity of viewpoints, was European in origin, but
reached the United States through the (older) institutionalist movement. It has
been given prominence in a recent historical study entitled Origins of Law and
Economics by Heath Pearson, with the subtitle The Economists New Science
of Law Movement 1830-1930 (Pearson, 1997, p. 44, referring to earlier studies).
What follows relies mainly on this study to describe the movement(see also
Hutter, 1982; Englard, 1990). For the American branch, the (old)
institutionalist school, useful sources are Duxbury (1995, pp. 316-330), who
questions whether it is proper to speak of a movement (Duxbury, 1995, p. 318),
as well as Hovenkamp (1990), Medema (1998) and Mercuro and Medema
(1997, Ch. 4).
The key question the proponents of the movement addressed was how
property and other rights were determined, historically and functionally, across
different societies. The earlier answer of sixteenth and seventeenth century
philosophers, that these rights were given as a matter of natural law, logically
prior to any positive legal system, seemed to them unsatisfactory. It could not
account for the variations of rights in time and space. Changes in property
rights, in their view, should be expected to reflect changes in economic
conditions. What they were seeking to develop was an explanatory science of
rights (Pearson, 1997, p. 33).
The movement originated amongst economists. Prominent amongst them
were the Germans belonging to what came to be known as the German
Historical School (Pearson, 1997, p. 95). The conjunction of political economy
and law in the discipline called Staatswissenschaft may have stimulated their
contribution. There were contributions in many other countries as well: Austria,
Belgium, England, France, Italy, the Netherlands, the United States. Pearson
(1997, p. 170-175) lists more than one hundred names of participants in the
movement. Only some of these are still remembered today: John R. Commons,
Gustave de Molinari, Carl Menger, Gustav Schmoller, Werner Sombart,
Adolph Wagner (Hutter, 1982).
The core thesis of the movement, that rights were contingent upon
economic and social conditions, came to be widely accepted. When Marx
insisted on it in his writings from 1859 onwards, he was expressing accepted
wisdom. By the 1870s the movement gained foothold amongst legal scholars:
Wilhelm Arnold, Otto von Gierke, Rudolph von Jhering, to mention a few in
Germany, and Henry Maine ([1861] 1977), in England. Englard (1990) has
drawn attention to the contribution of the Austrian scholar Victor Mataja to the
economic analysis of liability for damages a century ago. Scholars in other
70 History of Law and Economics 0200
countries were drawn to the movement as well and one may properly consider
it cosmopolitan (Pearson, 1997, p. 33).
The adherents of this approach engaged in a variety of historical studies of
rights in land and contractual arrangements for its exploitation. The studies
showed how the institutions varied, for instance according to the density of
population, the quality of the soil and the type of exploitation. They
investigated what was subject to individual rights, what was left as commons
and what sharing rules were applicable to the latter. One finds here
considerations of relative transactions costs familiar in current law and
economics studies, but also acceptance of the wisdom embodied in institutions
which have evolved in the course of history, a theme reflected in Hayeks work
in our day (Pearson, 1997, pp. 43-70). The explanations proposed may be
properly called economic in that they rely on costs and benefits to individuals,
who choose rationally in an environment of scarce resources. These are to this
day the pillars of economic reasoning.
What caused the decline of the movement? Pearson (1997, p. 131) attributes
it mainly to two factors. One is the increasing specialisation amongst social
scientists, which led economists to restrict their attention to matters
unquestionably related to markets. They studied the workings of the economy
within a framework of given legal institutions.
The other factor were the excessive claims made for the movement and the
increasing fuzziness of the economic methodology on which it relied. In part,
this may be due to the poor state of development of economic science itself: the
marginalist revolution took place only in the last part of the nineteenth
century. Perhaps as a result, some members of the movement let themselves be
tempted to explore explanations that strayed increasingly away from the strictly
individualist rational choice model to holist concepts such as national spirit,
socio-psychic motives and collective will (Commons) or to the
psychological-moral life of nations (Schmoller) (Pearson, 1997, pp. 72, 153,
158). As the economics profession specialised, such explanations seemed more
and more heretical to economists (Pearson, 1997, p. 153).
The difficulty is well expressed in what Blaug has to say on institutionalism,
which is at the root of the American branch of the first wave of law and
economics: A much better description of the working methodology of
institutionalists is storytelling ... Storytelling makes use of the method that
historians call colligation, the bundling together of facts, low-level
generalizations, high level theories, and value judgements in a coherent
narrative, held together by a glue of an implicit set of beliefs and attitudes that
the author shares with his readers (Blaug, 1980, p. 126). Coase is even more
dismissive: The American institutionalists were not theoretical but
anti-theoretical, particularly where classical economic theory was concerned.
0200 History of Law and Economics 71
It will be helpful, in dealing with the current law and economics movement, to
distinguish several periods: the beginnings, paradigm proposed (1958-1973),
paradigm accepted (1973-1980), paradigm questioned (1976-1983) and the
movement shaken (from 1983 onwards).
4.1 Beginnings
As early as the 1930s, there are studies pointing to a revival of the link between
law and economics on a different footing. Some of these have remained part of
modern day law and economics. In the UK, Arnold Plant looked at the
economics of intellectual property (1934a, 1934b and 1953); Ronald Coase, his
pupil (Coase, 1994, pp. 176 f.) and one of the founders of the current
movement, published as a young researcher his famous study on the nature of
the firm (Coase, 1937). But the veritable revival of law and economics occurred
at the University of Chicago, in 1940s, under the inspiring leadership of Aaron
Director (Duxbury, 1995, p. 341; Levi, 1966; Meltzer, 1966). Economic science
72 History of Law and Economics 0200
itself was by that time undergoing change which led to the neo classical
synthesis. The finest overview of this period is unquestionably Duxburys
(1995, Ch. 5).
Aaron Director was in the unusual position of an economist appointed to the
Chicago Law School, to succeed Henry Simons, who was also an economist. At
the Department of Economics at Chicago, he had a number of remarkable
colleagues, amongst whom one counts Frank Knight, George Stigler and
Milton Friedman. The Chicago group came to adopt a distinct approach to
economic analysis, which insisted on generating testable predictions and on
conducting empirical research for the purpose of such tests (Reder, 1987).
Indeed, the defining traits of Chicago neo-classicals - the suspicion of
government and the insistence that markets protect rational individual choice
and self-determination - reflect a distinctively American style of individualist
ideology (Duxbury, 1995, p. 418).
Directors problem at the Law School was how to turn his lawyer colleagues
round to taking economic analysis seriously. Director, a brilliant economist,
applied economic insights to legal cases, in particular in antitrust law
(Duxbury, 1995, pp. 343-344; Manne, 1993, p. 5 f.). Accepted wisdom at the
time, stemming from the depression and the New Deal, held that in order to
achieve effective competition, industry had to be closely supervised and
regulated. Director showed this conclusion in most cases to be unwarranted,
indeed counterproductive: monopoly was more often alleged than it was
effectively present and detrimental to consumer interests. The field has
continued to interest Chicagoans (Bork, 1978; Bowman, 1973; Posner, 1976).
The battle about the role of antitrust law continues to this day; McChesney and
Shughart II (1995) consider the debate in 1997-1998 over the pressure being
put on Microsoft for its alleged monopolisation of the computer software
market by tying its web browser, called Internet Explorer, with its already
domineering Windows operating system. Directors efforts led, during the
1940s and 1950s, to a variety of studies of other legal subjects with clear
economic connotations: corporate law, bankruptcy, securities regulation, labour
law, income tax, public utility regulation and torts.
Posner and others, writing the history of law and economics at Chicago
years later, designate this period as the old law and economics (Posner,
1975a, p. 758; also Ackerman, 1984, p. 63; Kitch, 1983a; Mercuro and
Medema, 1997, p. 193; Veljanovski, 1982, p. 7). They contrast it with the
new law and economics emerging in the 1960s, whose research agenda was
to apply economics to core legal doctrines and subjects such as contract,
property, tort and criminal law (Duxbury, 1995, p. 340). About the new
movement, Rowley (1989b, p. 125) observes its distinctive feature is the
application of market economics to legal institutions, rules, and procedures
which in certain areas (notably in tort and in crime) are not conventionally seen
to influence market behavior, but which indeed are defined in terms of market
failure.
0200 History of Law and Economics 73
The contrast between the old and the new economics is perhaps
overblown (Duxbury, 1995, pp. 340-341), but contains a grain of truth. Several
events mark the overstepping of traditional boundaries of economics,
characteristic of the new law and economics. One influence is surely Gary
Beckers initiatives to analyse non-market behaviour with economic tools:
starting with his 1955 doctoral dissertation on Discrimination in the Market
Place and broadening in his later work on the economics of crime, of the
family, on human capital and alleged (ir)rational behaviour (Becker, 1957,
1962, 1975, 1976, 1981). Years later, he summarised his approach as follows:
Indeed, I have come to the position that the economic approach is a
comprehensive one that is applicable to all human behavior, be it behavior
involving money prices or imputed shadow prices, repeated or infrequent
decisions, large or minor decisions, emotional or mechanical ends (Becker,
1976, p. 8).
After initial indifference, Beckers thesis came gradually to be seen as a
significant contribution to economics and indeed was the justification for the
Nobel prize in 1992. Posner is of the view that Beckers insistence on the
relevance of economics to a surprising range of nonmarket behavior (including
charity, love, and addiction), as well as his specific contributions to the
economic analysis of crime, racial discrimination, and marriage and divorce,
opened to economic analysis large areas of the legal system not reached by
Calabresis and Coases studies of property rights and liability rules (Posner,
1998, p. 26; quoted by Duxbury, 1995, p. 396; Posner, 1993).
During the same period - the late 1940s and the 1950s - several other
studies opened up fields which later became part of law and economics. For the
public choice movement one could point to Duncan Blacks writings (1948a,
1948b, 1958) on committees and elections in Britain. In 1954 Scott Gordon
(1954, 1958) published a study on the economics of managing a scarce resource
in common property, the fisheries, from which the economics of the
environment later developed. The next year, Tiebout (1956), studying
competition amongst local authorities through expenditures appealing to their
taxpayers, unwittingly laid the foundation for what later became the economics
of federalism as a system of competition amongst governments. Downs (1957),
with his economic theory of democracy, opened the field of the economics of
political institutions more broadly and was followed shortly by Buchanan and
Tullocks (1962) classic Calculus of Consent, which started the public choice
school.
Duxbury (1995, pp. 379, 417) emphasises that law and economics should
not be considered a direct descendant of American legal realism. While it
shares with that movement the view that for a better understanding of law one
must rely on the social sciences and on empirical study, practitioners of law and
economics are much more precise than were the realists about where to borrow
- from economics; from other social sciences to the extent that they adopt the
rational choice model - and about the agenda for empirical research flowing
74 History of Law and Economics 0200
from that position. The canons for conducting empirical research have also
been considerably refined since the time when the realists were active.
4.2 Paradigm Proposed: Economics into the Main Areas of Law (1958-1973)
A visible step in the emergence of law and economics at Chicago was the
creation, in 1958, of the Journal of Law and Economics, with Aaron Director
as its first editor. Soon afterwards, Coase moved to Chicago and became its
editor. In 1960 he published his seminal article on social cost in that journal
(Coase, 1960). Demsetz was amongst the earliest scholars realising the
significance of the article. He underscored it in a series of perceptive articles
(Demsetz, 1964, 1966, 1967, 1972a, 1972b). He first used the term the Coase
theorem (1972b, Pt II).
The article is usually taken to stand for the proposition that externalities are
no ground for government intervention, but merely indicate that property rights
are not adequately specified. When they are, and provided parties to the
externality can costlessly negotiate, specification of rights is sufficient for
attaining the optimal (efficient) outcome; the particular way in which the
rights are allocated between the parties is indifferent to the economic outcome.
The article is also important for drawing attention to the concept of transaction
costs. In Coases examples the concept was simple enough: transaction costs
encompass the cost of identifying potential contract partners, of coming to an
agreement with them and of policing the solution. Transaction costs prevent
apparently profitable deals from being consummated. They concern both
information problems and problems of strategic behaviour resulting from the
impossibility to fully supervise ones contract partner or from difficulties of
collective action. The concept has been extended to regulatory contexts and
to the operation of government itself. Its meaning has thereby been singularly
expanded. Precisely what is now meant by transaction costs is a matter of
debate. One may expect the reduction of transaction costs to be an important
concern in law and changes in legal institutions to reflect the discovery of ways
to lower transaction costs.
A second seminal article was a paper by Alchian, then at the Rand
Corporation in California, on the rationale for property rights, which was
circulated in the late 1950s but published only several years later (Alchian,
1965). It looked at the effects of differences between private and public
ownership and treated them as economic variables that could be manipulated.
Calabresi, at Yale, published a third, equally fundamental, paper on tort law as
a system for inducing the proper level of caution in activities liable to cause
damage to other persons, considering the cost of the damage as well as the cost
of administering the system (Calabresi, 1961).
These papers struck the fancy of a number of economists and became the
seeds for a flurry of articles on legal subjects such as property rights, torts,
contracts and procedure, for example Alchian and Demsetz (1969, 1972, 1973);
0200 History of Law and Economics 75
Calabresi (1965a, 1965b, 1970); Calabresi and Melamed (1972); Calabresi and
Hirschoff (1972); Cheung (1968, 1969a, 1969b, 1972, 1973); Dales (1968a,
1968b); De Alessi (1969); Demsetz (1964, 1966, 1967, 1968, 1969, 1972a,
1972b); Furubotn and Pejovich (1972, 1974); Landes (1971); McKean (1970a,
1970b); Oi (1973); Pejovich (1971, 1972); Peltzman (1973); Posner (1972a,
1973a, 1973b); Stigler (1970). The University of Chicago Law Review
published the proceedings of a symposium on product liability in its 1970 issue.
Manne (1962, 1965, 1966a, 1966b, 1967) published books and papers on
corporation law, controversially taking the defence of insider trading. Samuels
(1965, 1973) published two extensive bibliographies of publications dealing
with law and economics, broadly casting his net, but showing nonetheless how
much literature had been generated in the space of a decade.
The literature in this period was mostly the work of economists. The focus
on property rights earned it amongst economists the label property rights
approach, even where it dealt with contractual practices, products liability or
forms of industrial regulation. The term faded away in later years for the more
encompassing one of economic analysis of law.
Most contributors in the early days subscribed to the views of the Chicago
school of neoclassical economics (Duxbury, 1995, p. 369; Mercuro and
Medema, 1997, Ch. 2). The contributions of the Chicago group altogether
overshadowed those by economists of other persuasions, such as Leoni, ([1961]
1991); Samuels (1971, 1972); Schmid (1965) or Stewart Macaulay, a
lawyer-sociologist, who published a remarkable study on informal contractual
relations, which has since become a classic (Macaulay, 1963). The success of
the Chicago approach persisted in later periods. Hayeks Law, Legislation and
Liberty (1973, 1976, 1979) for instance, published contemporaneously with
Posners textbook on law and economics (Posner, 1972b, 1977), went
essentially unnoticed at the time amongst the law and economics community,
even though Hayek received the Nobel prize for economics in 1974. In
retrospect this may seem a regrettable example of tunnel vision; looked at in the
perspective of the time, it testifies to the intense enthusiasm generated by the
research agenda the Chicago School proposed and to the dynamism and
persuasiveness of its proponents.
A few contributors in this early period were lawyers. The names of
Calabresi and Manne come to mind. Participation of lawyers is essential since,
as we saw above, convincing lawyers turned out to be the critical point in the
evolution of the first wave of law and economics, a century earlier. Calabresi
played a key role here: The distinctive quality of Calabresis work was to show
the power of simple economic principles to rationalise a whole body of law, and
to develop a coherent basis for its reform (Veljanovski, 1990, p. 21). Manne
contributed in a different way by organising, from 1971 on, short intensive
training seminars in economics for lawyers and judges, and in law for
economists (Manne, 1993, p. 10; Duxbury, 1995, p. 359).
76 History of Law and Economics 0200
4.3 Paradigm Accepted: law and economics into the Law Schools (1973-1980)
Three events signal a change in the movement in the direction of capturing the
hearts and imagination of lawyers: the foundation, in 1972, of the Journal of
Legal Studies; the first publication, of Posners (1972b; second edition 1977)
introduction to the economic analysis of law, both at the Law School of the
University of Chicago; the organisation, from 1971 on, of Henry Mannes
already mentioned Economics Institutes for Law Professors, short intensive
seminars in economics for lawyers, be they judges, practitioners or law teachers
(Manne, 1993, p. 10). Together, one might say, they mark the entrance of law
and economics into law schools in the United States.
Posners book was written by a lawyer for lawyers in a clear and
straightforward style. It steered clear of economic jargon and adopted the
lawyers well-known distinctions amongst fields of law. It analysed well-known
legal doctrines across the entire spectrum of the law. Posners Economic
Analysis of Law, which first appeared in 1973, sounded most explicitly the
modern theme of economic imperialism: You name the legal field, and I will
show you how a few fundamental principles of price theory dictate its implicit
economic structure (Epstein, 1997, p. 1168). While these features no doubt
contributed to its success, the decisive factor may well have lain in the
substance of the book: the efficiency thesis of the common law.
In earlier contributions, law and economics scholars had shown that
different institutions - property rights, contractual arrangements, liability rules
- could be looked at as in some sense the best option, that is the efficient
solution in neo-classical economic terminology. Private property rights
generally create better incentives for husbanding scarce resources than do
common property or freely available objects. Owners of orchards might be
thought to profit freely from the activity of bees pollinating their trees, an
externality which some used as a textbook example to show the need for
government regulation; closer study showed, however, a practice of contracts
between bee keepers and tree owners, making it profitable for both to place
beehives near the orchard as needed (Cheung, 1973). Liability rules in tort
could be shown not merely to redress the balance disturbed by the tort, but also
to create the proper incentives for those whose activity might cause damage to
others, to observe care to the extent that its cost is lower than that of the
damage thereby prevented (Posner, 1972a).
Posner generalised this idea across the spectrum of the law. Already in the
first edition of his book, he put forth the thesis that all rules of the traditional
common law reflected such an efficiency logic and that, as a matter of
normative judgement, it was desirable that they do so: pursuit of efficiency,
here as elsewhere, aims at avoiding waste or maximising the wealth of society.
The thesis yields an alluring research agenda: to tease out, using concepts
borrowed from neoclassical economics, what would be the efficient rules
throughout the domains of the traditional common law and to determine
0200 History of Law and Economics 77
whether the common law in fact conforms to this logic. The research
programme was attractive to lawyers because the neoclassical machinery as it
was presented in Posners book looked easy enough to learn and to apply to
legal problems.
It is essentially this research programme which has occupied the law and
economics community through the 1970s, it is difficult to say whether it is the
descriptive or the normative component which provided the greater attraction.
Posner himself has been amongst the most ardent defenders of his own thesis.
He maintains it, in only slightly weakened form, in the fourth edition of his
book, in 1992, presenting the common law as a system of rules for inducing
people to behave efficiently, not only in explicit markets but across the whole
range of social interactions. In settings in which the cost of voluntary
transactions is low, common law doctrines create incentives for people to
channel their transactions through the market. ... In settings where the cost of
allocating resources by voluntary transactions is prohibitively high, making the
market an infeasible method of allocating resources, the common law prices
behavior in such a way as to mimic the market. (Posner, 1992a, p. 252; quoted
by Duxbury, 1995, pp. 410-411).
Can one discern a pattern amongst the many viewpoints now represented
within law and economics broadly written? I venture to list a few common
themes, most of them proposed as enrichments of the Chicago law and
economics research agenda, rather than as alternatives to it: the role of
institutions; historical studies; strategic behaviour in human interaction; limited
rationality of human actors; uncertainty and entrepreneurship; the contributions
of public choice and game theory; the relationship between the law and
economics and the sociology of law.
In considering these possible enrichments, it is well to keep in mind the
causes of the decline of the first wave of law and economics. They justify
Posners admonition that too many bells and whistles will stop the analytic
engine in its tracks. ... A commitment to a relatively simple economic model,
one that does not supply a facile explanation for every regularity (or peculiarity)
in human behavior, forces the analyst to think hard before discarding the
possibility that the behavior under scrutiny may indeed be rational in a
straightforward sense. By the same token, a too-great readiness to abandon the
simple model in favor of alternative approaches to behavior at the first sign of
difficulty carries the risk of overlooking promising avenues for economic
analysis (Posner, 1989, pp. 60, 62). But against it Backhaus and Stephen
(1994, pp. 6-7) argue, presenting the new European Journal of Law and
Economics in 1994, that considerable disappointment with the lack of
usefulness for practical economic policy of much rigorous theoretical work in
economics has resulted in a resurgence of institutionally rich economic work.
5.1 Institutions
The important role of institutions has been stressed in many corners: the older
institutionalists such as Samuels (1971, 1972, 1974, 1975, 1976b), Samuels and
Schmid (1981) and Schmid (1965, 1976, 1978); and the newer ones such as
Williamson (1985, 1986, 1996), Eggertsson (1990, 1993, 1996), Alston,
Eggertsson and North (1996) and Komesar (1997), the economic historians
(Bouckaert, 1996, 1997; Libecap, 1986, 1989, 1992, 1993a, 1993b; Milgrom,
North and Weingast, 1997; North, 1984, 1986, 1991, 1993, 1994, 1995; North
and Wallis, 1994; North and Weingast, 1996; Weingast, 1993, 1995), the
management literature (Knight, 1992; Knight and Sened, 1995; Miller, 1992;
Gomez, 1996), Austrian economists linking to Carl Mengers contributions
(Langlois, 1986, p. 247; Rizzo, 1985), political scientists (Elster, 1989, p. 147).
Coase himself, whose 1937 article on the firm may be considered the first
contribution in modern law and economics insisting on the role of institutions,
has explicitly sided with these concerns (1937, 1992, 1993): It makes little
sense for economists to discuss the process of exchange without specifying the
82 History of Law and Economics 0200
institutional setting within which the trading takes place since this affects the
incentives to produce and the costs of transacting. I think this is now beginning
to be recognised and has been made crystal clear by what is going on in Eastern
Europe today. (Coase, 1994, p. 12). Indeed one may consider that all of law
and economics, in as much as it seeks to elucidate the rationale of existing legal
rules, engages in institutional analysis.
To understand what an institution is, start with the neoclassical model. The
model supposes that agents are informed about potential trades, that profitable
agreements are reached without delay or posturing and that deals are faithfully
performed. These are, to be sure, simplifying assumptions to make the model
manageable. They allow one to construct arguments about how social optimal
arrangements (efficiency) come about.
In this model there is no need for the fixity that institutions provide.
Because most of the formal economic models of competition, exchange, and
equilibrium have ignored ignorance and lack of costless full and perfect
information, many institutions of our economic system, institutions that are
productive in creating knowledge more cheaply than otherwise have been
erroneously treated as parasitic appendages. The explanation of use of money,
expertise with dealing in a good as a middleman specialist with a trademark or
brand name, reputability or goodwill, along with advertising of ones wares
(and even unemployment) is often misunderstood. All these can be derived
from the same information cost factors that give rise to use of an intermediary
medium of exchange (Alchian, 1977, p. 123). If human beings were
omniscient, most markets would make no sense. After all, theres no reason to
trade stocks if everyone knows the true value of every company. But people are
not omniscient. And markets are the best way yet devised to overcome human
limitations in deciding what to build, buy, or sell (Browning and Reiss, 1998,
p. 100).
Institutions answer the observation that in reality, situations are often too
complicated for ordinary economic actors to find the theoretically optimal
arrangement and are simplified to be manageable. When it is costly to
transact, then institutions matter. And it is costly to transact. ... Institutions are
the humanly devised constraints that structure human interaction. They are
made up of formal constraints (e.g., rules, laws, constitutions), informal
constraints (e.g., norms of behavior, conventions, self-imposed codes of
conduct), and their enforcement characteristics (North, 1996, p. 344).
Institutions simplify the decision problem for economic actors, by imposing
restraints on each persons conduct which render it substantially predictable to
others. Institutions are, in an important sense, congealed social knowledge. By
following institutionally-sanctioned patterns of behavior, separate individuals
are able to coordinate more completely their actions and plans. This is because
institutions often limit the options available to an individual thereby reducing
0200 History of Law and Economics 83
the uncertainty about what others are going to do (ODriscoll Jr and Rizzo,
1996, p. xxii).
Institutions are rules in a broad sense. Heiner (1983) has attempted to
formalise the reasons for using rules, both heuristic rules in individual decision
making and social rules in human interactions. Their virtue lies in the relative
fixity they provide. But the fixity is also their weakness. At the time of its
creation, an institution may be chosen so as to provide generally the best
trade-off in the face of the circumstances of the moment. As circumstances
change, institutions may come to represent less than optimal trade-offs and yet
their fixity prevents them from being instantly adjusted. The benefit of fixity
and predictability is bought at the risk of ill fit over time.
Institutions constitute an enrichment of the law and economics agenda. The
research programme they imply is not radically incompatible with the
optimisation (efficiency) idea inherent in the neo classical agenda. But
rather than assuming immediate optimisation to be the goal of all decisions
within the economic system, an institutional agenda would admit institutions
as constraints on optimisation and would consider change of institutions an
independent goal. The general effort to take account of information asymmetry
and other transaction costs, while preserving the assumption that individuals
maximize utility, is coming to be called neoinstitutional economics (Riker
and Weimer, 1993, p. 84)
5.2 History
The institutional agenda sketched above quite logically leads to an increased
interest in historical studies: institutions provide fixity in the short run and
evolve in the longer run. They leave a trace which we can study. Change of
institutions points to a change in the relevant transaction costs visible to
interested parties. North (1981, 1986, 1989, 1994, 1995) has explicitly drawn
attention to the connection between institutions and history.
Historical studies give an empirical dimension to law and economics work,
which may have been lacking in earlier law and economics work, which
focused on the function of different legal rules. Law and economics has been
too theoretical, says Becker (Roundtable, 1997, p. 1137). To this Epstein (1997,
p. 1173) adds that the easy conquests of theory and practice have already been
made. ... But precisely because knowledge is so great, the law of diminishing
returns explains why new advances are so hard to come by. For Epstein, the
greatest hope for advancement, barring any major unforeseen conceptual
breakthrough, is from more attentive study to the evolution - be it by growth or
decline, or both - of particular institutions and social arrangements (Epstein,
1997, p. 1174)
Quite a few historical studies in law and economics have appeared over the
past few years, such as Aftalion (1987, 1990); Alston, Eggertsson and North
84 History of Law and Economics 0200
end of the decade, it had found its way to the German speaking (Horn 1976;
Assmann, Kirchner and Schanze, 1978; Opp, 1979; Lehmann, 1983; Schller,
1983; Behrens, 1984) and the Benelux countries (Mackaay, 1980, 1982;
Bouckaert, 1984). Mattei and Pardolesi (1991) mention interest for law and
economics comparative law scholars in Italy already in the early 1960s, but
without much practical echo until decades later. France has lagged behind,
because, most unfortunately, an early contribution to law and economics (Rosa
and Aftalion, 1977) became labelled as right-wing ideology without proper
claim to scientific status (Andreff et al. 1982; Mackaay 1987). Peculiarities of
the French higher education system with its centralised administration and
control of appointment and promotion of law professors, providing little
incentive for the reception of intellectual ideas originating outside France, may
have reinforced this unfortunate development. Remarkable law and economics
publications such as Lepage (1985) and Lemennicier (1988) have been by and
large ignored by the legal community.
The reception in these countries appears to follow a common pattern. An
early sparkling publication triggers broader interest amongst legal scholars. In
England (Attiyah, 1970) introduced the British reader to Calabresis
economics, igniting interest among lawyers in the reform of the tort system and
the efficiency of accident compensation schemes (Veljanovski, 1990, p. 25).
In Germany, this role was played by a small book of readings produced by three
young scholars, who spent a year in the US (Assmann, Kirchner and Schanze,
1978). Perhaps reception in Germany was helped by the earlier Ordo-liberal or
Freiburg school of law and economics, founded in the 1930s and influential
after the Second World War, which included well-known scholars and
politicians such as Walter Eucken, Wilhelm Roepke, Ludwig Erhard, Franz
Bhm (Backhaus, 1996; Behrens, 1984, p. 8 f., 1993; Grossekettler, 1996;
Lenel, 1996; Streit, 1992; Vanberg, 1998b).
Consolidation takes place as law and economics is taught in the law schools
(and not only in the economics departments) and young scholars choose a law
and economics subject for their thesis. The Erasmus exchange programme in
law and economics has probably exerted a positive influence in Europe. So have
the European Law and Economics Association and, in its sphere, the Canadian
Law and Economics Association.
One must wonder whether law and economics generates outside the United
States as much interest as it had earlier on and continues to do in the US. In
1991, Kirchner answered this question in the negative for Germany, in spite of
the substantial literature in German on the subject. Looking to the future,
Cooter and Gordley (1991, p. 262) conclude that [b]oth Kirchner and Mattei,
however, see the economic approach to law as the opponent of what remains
of nineteenth-century formalism. For the economic approach to be successful,
then, it must convince its critics that it can avoid the evils of formalism without
86 History of Law and Economics 0200
causing new evils of its own. Its success, then, may require not only openness
by traditional legal scholars to a new method, but also creative adaptation of
that method by its practitioners.
which all knowledge and know-how is presumed given and all potential
transactions are presumed to have been considered. For the Austrians, all this
knowledge is not given, but must be discovered. The essence of the economic
problem is the discovery of new products, services and ways of doing things.
The Austrians are concerned to determine the conditions required for that
discovery process. This has consequences for the scope of competition law.
The advantage secured by a superior product may initially give a firm
something of practical monopoly in its market. In the Austrian view, this is no
cause for intervention. So long as the monopoly is contestable, in the sense that
no legal impediment stops a newcomer from offering a new product which
consumers accept as a substitute for the supposedly monopolistic product, the
very success of the apparent monopoly is the carrot which draws competition
and drives innovation. Austrians see competition as a discovery process and,
one may add, the reverse as well: discovery will most readily take place through
competition.
Development of a niche through an innovation and subsequent imitation
and dissipation of the niche and search for new ones is the essence of the
competitive discovery process. Breaking up such monopolies because of
excessive market share would, on an Austrian analysis, have the effect of
stifling innovation. The literature on competition law, at least in the United
States, is coming round to this dynamic view of competition and innovation,
giving credence to the Austrian ideas (Barnett, 1992; Kirzner, 1973, 1979,
1985, 1997; McChesney and Shughart II, 1985; Nelson and Winter, 1982;
Schmidtchen, 1993).
The Austrian views differ from the neoclassical synthesis in other important
respects as well. Hayek has insisted on the subjective nature of information
economic actors use in making their plans and reaching their decisions (Hayek,
1948; Kirzner, 1984; ODriscoll Jr and Rizzo, 1996; Barnett, 1998).
Information about production and consumption plans is revealed and
continuously updated through the price mechanism. One cannot correctly gauge
this information outside the transactions in which it is revealed through the
market. This is no less true for the judges in our system, than it was, fatally, for
government officials running the former socialist republics. Austrians generally
take a dim view of judicial re-engineering of contracts.
How much Austrian and Chicago neoclassical economics actually differ is
a matter of debate. Paqu (1985) submits that the distance is smaller than it
appears to be. Boettke (1997) sees neoclassical economics as the product of a
set of simplifying assumptions about innovation and competition introduced in
classical political economy, which made possible the rapid mathematisation of
the discipline, but entailed a lack of realism which, in his view, is fatal.
Austrian economics has, in his eyes and those of Behrens (1984, p. 22),
remained faithful to the older but richer tradition of political economy.
88 History of Law and Economics 0200
The consequences of the Austrian views for law and economics differ
significantly from those reached in a neoclassical perspective (Rizzo, 1980c,
1985; Bouckaert, 1984; Teijl and Holzhauer, 1997). For instance, comparisons
of prevention costs for tortfeasors with accident costs for victims, as the Hand
test for negligence law would require, are without a foundation on an Austrian
view, which for that reason tends to favour strict liability or no liability. The
implications of Austrian views for civil law have been explored in some detail
and compared to those of Chicago neoclassical views in a recent doctoral thesis
in Rotterdam (Teijl and Holzhauer, 1997).
6. Conclusion
This survey leads to two major findings. The first is that the idea of applying
economic concepts to gain a better understanding of law is much older than the
current movement, which its proponents date back to the late 1950s. The
second finding concerns the current movement. After virtually unquestioned
dominance and astonishing success of the Chicago approach in the 1960s and
1970s, since about 1980 practitioners of law and economics no longer sing in
a single voice.
With respect to the earlier attempts at law and economics, it should be
observed that they had declined by the 1930s and find no clear echo in the
current movement, outside the work of modern institutionalists such as Samuels
and Schmid. Various reasons are given: their methodology became increasingly
fuzzy; in the end they failed to convince lawyers, in the absence of a
straightforward methodology and telling insights into the nature of legal
phenomena. Perhaps, too, the problems they addressed and the solutions they
proposed - generally more government intervention - no longer appeared
relevant to the legal community.
These observations feed into the second finding, the astounding variety of
viewpoints now represented within law and economics broadly written. Will
this cacophony drive law and economics into oblivion? It ought not to, since
law and economics of whatever stripe still offers insights into a broad range of
legal phenomena from contracts, torts and property to commercial law,
constitutional law, criminal law and even family law. The task is to convince
lawyers that this is a useful, indeed an essential, supplement to traditional
lawyering skills. Where law changes rapidly, as it does in our day, lawyers are
inevitably involved in policymaking of some sort. The record of lawyers
managing such change on the strength of legal skills and legal practice alone
is disappointing at best (Posner, 1987b, pp. 769-771).
0200 History of Law and Economics 93
131). But unnecessary and ill-timed interference can do great harm; reform
should be undertaken warily and on the basis of the best knowledge available.
All theories may turn out to be misguided in the face of later research. Practical
policy decisions must be made on the basis of such imperfect knowledge. How
essential law and economics is may be gleaned from the experience in Middle
and East European countries after the restoration of democracy. Advice about
what institutions to create appears to have been given often by economists
without appreciation for the dynamics of the law and by lawyers with too little
knowledge of the workings of the economy. The pains of transition have been
prolonged as a result.
Lawyer-economists should only presume to offer policy advice to minister
to the ills of society as the discipline acquires solid empirical bearings. It is not
sufficient to criticise accepted wisdom and to propose plausible enrichments of
the theory, as the debates around 1980 have done. The crucial point is for the
discipline to engage in empirical work capable of disproving false tenets. Only
in this way can we hope to discover what is indisputable in law and economics,
and make its message last. We shall see whether Coase was right in his
assessment that [i]ndeed, work is going forward at such a pace that I do not
consider it overoptimistic to believe that the main outlines of the subject will
be drawn within five or ten years. (Coase, 1994, p. 12).
Acknowledgements
Writing the history of law and economics has turned out to be an arduous task.
Sustenance as well as helpful suggestions were provided by Boudewijn
Bouckaert, Gerrit De Geest and Frdrick Charette in particular. Eric Schanze,
Ronald Kirstein, Stphane Rousseau, Stefan Voigt and two anonymous referees
provided constructive comment. I assume nonetheless full responsibility for the
structure of the text and the weight given to different periods and movements.
Ackerman, Bruce A. (1984), Reconstructing American Law, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press.
Aftalion, Florin (1987), Lconomie de la Rvolution Franaise (The Economics of the French
Revolution), Paris, Hachette.
Aftalion, Florin (1990), The French Revolution - An Economic Explanation, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press and Paris, ditions de la Maison de lHomme.
Ajani, Gianmaria and Mattei, Ugo (1995), Codifying Property Law in the Process of Transition: Some
Suggestions from Comparative Law and Economics,19 Hastings International and Comparative
Law Review, 117-137.
0200 History of Law and Economics 95
Alchian, Armen A. (1965), Some Economics of Property Rights, 30 Il Politico, 816-829 reprinted in
Alchian, Armen A. (ed.) (1977), Some Economics of Property Rights, Economic Forces at Work,
Indianapolis, Liberty Press, 127-149.
Alchian, Armen A. (1977), Why Money?, in Alchian, Armen A. (ed.), Economic Forces at Work,
Indianapolis, LibertyPress, 111-123.
Alchian, Armen A. and Demsetz, Harold (1969), Corporate Management and Property Rights, in
Manne, Henry G. (ed.), Economic Policy and the Regulation of Corporate Securities,
Washington, DC, American Entreprise Institute, 337-360.
Alchian, Armen A. and Demsetz, Harold (1972), Production, Information Costs, and Economic
Organization, 62 American Economic Review, 777-795.
Alchian, Armen A. and Demsetz, Harold (1973), The Property Rights Paradigm, 33 Journal of
Economic History, 16-27.
Alston, Lee J., Eggertsson, Thrinn and North, Douglass C. (eds) (1996), Empirical Studies in
Institutional Change, New York, Cambridge University Press.
Andreff, Wladimir et al. (eds) (1982), Lconomie Fiction - Contre les Nouveaux conomistes, Paris,
Franois Maspero.
Anonymous (1978), Annals of Science - DNA, The New Yorker, 4 December 1978.
Assmann, Heinz-Dieter, Kirchner, Christian and Schanze, Erich (eds) (1978), konomische Analyse
des Rechts, Kronberg/Ts., Athenum Verlag GmbH.
Atiyah, Patrick S. (1970), Accidents, Compensation and the Law, London, Weidenfeld and Nicolson.
Axelrod, Robert (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation, New York, Basic Books.
Backhaus, Juergen (1996), Franz Bhm Issue, 3 European Journal of Law and Economics,
297-376.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. and Stephen, Frank H. (1994), The Purpose of the European Journal of Law
and Economics and the Intentions of Its Editors, 1 European Journal of Law and Economics,
5-7.
Backhaus, Jrgen and Wagner, Richard E. (1987), The Cameralists: A Public Choice Perspective,
53 Public Choice, 3-20.
Baechler, Jean (1995a), Le Capitalisme - 1. Les Origines (Capitalism - 1. Origins), Paris, Gallimard.
Baechler, Jean (1995b), Le Capitalisme - 2. Lconomie Capitaliste (Capitalism - 2. The Capitalist
Economy), Paris, Gallimard.
Bailey, Martin J. (1992), Approximate Optimality of Aboriginal Property Rights, 35 Journal of Law
and Economics, 183-198.
Baird, Douglas G., Gertner, Robert H. and Picker, Randall C. (1994), Game Theory and the Law,
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Baker, C. Edwin (1975), The Ideology of Economic Analysis of Law, 5 Philosophy and Public
Affairs, 3-48.
Baker, C. Edwin (1980), Starting Points in the Economic Analysis of Law, 8 Hofstra Law Review,
939-972.
Barnett, Randy E. (1989), Foreword: Post-Chicago Law and Economics, 65 Chicago-Kent Law
Review, 1-21.
Barnett, Randy E. (1992), The Function of Several Property and Freedom of Contract, in Paul, Ellen
Frankel, Jr, Fred D. Miller and Paul, Jeffrey (eds), Economic Rights, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press and the Social Philosophy and Policy Foundation, Bowling Green, OH, 62-94.
96 History of Law and Economics 0200
Barnett, Randy E. (1998), The Structure of Liberty - Justice and the Rule of Law, Oxford, Clarendon
Press.
Barry, Norman P. (1996), Classical Liberalism in the Age of Post-Communism, Cheltenham, UK,
Edward Elgar, 6-17.
Beccaria, Cesare and Bellamy, Richard ([1764] 1995), On Crimes and Punishments and Other
Writings, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Becker, Gary S. (1957), The Economics of Discrimination, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Becker, Gary S. (1962), Irrational Behavior and Economic Theory,70 Journal of Political Economy,
1-18.
Becker, Gary S. (1975), Human Capital - A Theoretical and Emplrlcal Analysis with Special
Reference to Education, New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, (2nd edn).
Becker, Gary S. (1976), The Economic Approach to Human Behavior, Chicago, The University of
Chicago Press.
Becker, Gary S. (1981), A Treatise on the Family, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Becker, Gary S. (1983), A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence,
98 Quarterly Journal of Economics, 371-400.
Becker, Gary S. (1985), Public Policies, Pressure Groups, and Dead Weights Costs, 28 Journal of
Public Economics, 330-347.
Becker, Gary S. (1986), The Public Interest Hypothesis Revisited: A New Test of Peltzman's Theory
of Regulation, 49 Public Choice, 223-234.
Behrens, Peter (1984), Die konomischen Grundlagen des Rechts - Politische konomie als
Rationale Jurisprudenz (The Economic Foundations of Law - Political Economy as Rational
Jurisprudence), Tbingen, J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck).
Behrens, Peter (1993), Legalism, Economism, and Professional Attitudes Toward Institutional Design
- Comment, 149 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics , 141-147.
Beito, David T. (1990), Mutual Aid for Social Welfare: The Case of American Fraternal Societies,
4 Critical Review, 709-736.
Bentham, Jeremy, ([1789] 1948), An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation, New
York, Hafner.
Benson, Bruce L. (1994), Legal Philosophy, in Boettke, Peter J. (ed.), The Elgar Companion to
Austrian Economics, Hants, UK, Edward Elgar, 270-275.
Birmingham, Robert L. (1968), Legal and Moral Duty in Game Theory: Common Law Contract and
Chinese Analogies, 18 Buffalo Law Review, 99-117.
Black, Duncan (1948a), The Rationale of Group Decision-Making, 56 Journal of Political
Economy, 23-34.
Black, Duncan (1948b), The Decisions of a Committee Using a Special Majority, 16 Econometrica,
245-261.
Black, Duncan (1958), The Theory of Committees and Elections, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press.
Blaug, Mark (1980), The Methodology of Economics - or How Economists Explain, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
Boettke, Peter J. (ed.) (1994), The Elgar Companion to Austrian Economics, Hants, UK, Edward
Elgar.
Boettke, Peter J. (1997), Where did Economics Go Wrong? Equilibrium as a Flight from Reality, 11
Critical Review, 11-64.
0200 History of Law and Economics 97
Booth, William James, Booth, Patrick and Meadwell, Hudson (eds) (1993), Politics and Rationality,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Bork, Robert H. (1978), The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with Itself, New York, Basic Books.
Bouckaert, Boudewijn (1984), Recht op Zoek naar Economie? - Prolegomena tot een Economische
Analyse van het Recht (Law Looking for Economics? - Preliminary Considerations for an
Economic Analysis of Law), Gent, E.Storia-Scientia.
Bouckaert, Boudewijn (1987), LAnalyse conomique du Droit: vers un Renouveau de la Science
Juridique? (Economic Analysis of Law: Towards a Renewal in Legal Science?), 18 Revue
Interdisciplinaire dtudes Juridiques, 47-61.
Bouckaert, Boudewijn (1990a), Jeter un Pont entre volution et Droit Naturel (Building a Bridge
Between Evolution and Natural Law), 1 Journal des conomistes et des tudes Humaines,
193-195.
Bouckaert, Boudewijn (1990b), What is Property?, 13 Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy,
775-816.
Bouckaert, Boudewijn (1991), La Responsabilit Civile comme Base Institutionnelle dune Protection
Spontane de lEnvironnement, (Tort Law as Institutional Basis for Spontaneous Protection of the
Environment), 2 Journal des conomistes et des tudes Humaines, 315-335.
Bouckaert, Boudewijn (1994), Misschien Geen Vrienden, Waarschijnlijk Wel Bondgenoten.
Bedenkingen over de Nauwe Kloof tussen de Rechtssociologie van het Handelen en de
Rechtseconomie van de Sociale Cooperatie (Perhaps not Friends, but surely Allies. Reflections on
the Narrow Gap beteen the Legal Sociology of Human Action and the Law and Economics of
Social Co-operation), in Raes, K. and Willekens, H. (eds), Economische Verklaringen van het
Recht (Economic Explanations of Law), Den Haag, Vuga, 44-74.
Bouckaert, Boudewijn (1996), City Air Sets One Free: Medieval Cities as Voluntary Political and
Economic Communities, in Beito, David (ed.), The Voluntary City, San Francisco, The
Independent Institute.
Bouckaert, Boudewijn (1997), Between the Market and the State: The World of Medieval Cities, in
Radnitzky, Gerard (ed.), Values and Social Order - Vol. 3. Voluntary versus Coercive Orders,
Aldershot, Avebury, 213-241.
Boudon, Raymond (1977), Effets Pervers et Ordre Social (Perverse Effects and Social Order), Paris,
Presses Universitaires de France.
Boudreaux, Donald J. (1994), Law and Economics, in Boettke, Peter J. (ed.), The Elgar Companion
to Austrian Economics, Hants, UK, Edward Elgar, 264-269
Bowman, Ward S. (1973), Patent and Antitrust Law: A Legal and Economic Appraisal, Chicago,
University of Chicago Press.
Breton, Albert (1987), Towards a Theory of Competitive Federalism, 3 European Journal of
Political Economy, 263-329.
Breton, Albert (1989), The Growth of Competitive Governments, 22 Canadian Journal of
Economics, 717-749.
Breton, Albert (1996), Competitive Governments - An Economic Theory of Politics and Public
Finance, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Breton, Albert and Scott, Anthony (1978), The Economic Constitution of Federal States, Toronto,
University of Toronto Press.
98 History of Law and Economics 0200
Breton, Albert and Scott, Anthony (1980), The Design of Federations, Montreal, The Institute for
Research on Public Policy.
Browning, John and Reiss, Spencer (1998), Encyclopedia of the New Economy, 6.04 Wired, 93-102.
Buchanan, James M. (1977), Law and the Invisible Hand, in Siegan, Bernard H. (ed.), The
Interaction of Economics and the Law, Lexington, MA, Lexington Books, 127-138.
Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon (1962), The Calculus of Consent - Logical Foundations
of Constitutional Democracy, Ann Arbor, The University of Michigan Press.
Buchanan, James M., Tollison, Robert D. and Tullock, Gordon (eds) (1980), Towards a Theory of the
Rent-Seeking Society, College Station, Texas A&M Press.
Burrows, Paul (1980), The Economic Theory of Pollution Control, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.
Burrows, Paul and Veljanovski, Cento G. (eds) (1981), The Economic Approach to Law, London,
Butterworths.
Burton, John (1980), Epilogue: Externalities, Property Rights, and Public Policy: Private Property
Rights and the Spoliation of Nature, in Cheung, Steven N.S. (ed.), The Myth of Social Cost, San
Francisco, CA, Cato Institute, 53-71.
Calabresi, Guido (1961), Some Thoughts on Risk-Distribution and the Law of Torts, 70 Yale Law
Journal, 499-553.
Calabresi, Guido (1965a), The Decision for Accidents: An Approach to Nonfault Allocation of Costs,
78 Harvard Law Review, 713-774.
Calabresi, Guido (1965b), Transaction Costs, Resource Allocation and Liability Rules - A Comment,
in Manne, Henry G. (ed.), The Economics of Legal Relationships - Readings in the Theory of
Property Rights, St. Paul, MN, West Publishing Cy, pp. 204-211.
Calabresi, Guido (1970), The Cost of Accidents, New Haven, Yale University Press.
Calabresi, Guido and Hirschoff, Jon T. (1972), Toward a Test for Strict Liability in Torts, Yale Law
Journal 81, 1055-1085.
Calabresi, Guido and Melamed, Douglas (1972), Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability:
One View of the Cathedral, 85 Harvard Law Review, 1089-1128.
Carroll, Sidney L. (1979), Research in Law and Economics - volume 1 (Zerbe general editor),
Greenwich, Conn., JAI Press.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1968), Private Property Rights and Sharecropping, Journal of Political
Economy 76, 1107-1122.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1969a), The Theory of Share Tenancy, Chicago, The University of Chicago
Press.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1969b), Transaction Costs, Risk Aversion, and the Choice of Contractual
Arrangements, 12 Journal of Law and Economics, 23-42.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1970), The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of a Non-Exclusive
Resource, 13 Journal of Law and Economics, 49-70.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1972), The Enforcement of Property Rights in Children, and the Marriage
Contract, 82 Economic Journal, 641-657.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1973), The Fable of the Bees: An Economic Investigation, 16 Journal of Law
and Economics, 11-33.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1980), The Myth of Social Cost, San Francisco, CA, Cato Institute.
Coase, Ronald H. (1937), The Nature of the Firm, 4 Economica (n.s.), 386-405 reproduced in Coase
1988, p 33-55.
0200 History of Law and Economics 99
Coase, Ronald H. (1960), The Problem of Social Cost, 3 Journal of Law and Economics, 1-44
(reprinted in Coase, Ronald H. (1988), The Firm, the Market and the Law, Chicago, The
University of Chicago Press 95-156).
Coase, Ronald H. (1974), The Lighthouse in Economics, 17 Journal of Law and Economics,
357-376 (reprinted in Coase, Ronald H. (1988), The Firm, the Market and the Law, Chicago, The
University of Chicago Press 187-213).
Coase, Ronald H. (1978), Economics and Contiguous Disciplines, 7 Journal of Legal Studies,
201-210.
Coase, Ronald H. (1984), The New Institutional Economics, 140 Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics, 229-231.
Coase, Ronald H. (1988), The Firm, the Market and the Law, Chicago, The University of Chicago
Press.
Coase, Ronald H. (1992), The Institutional Structure of Production, 82 American Economic Review,
713-719.
Coase, R.H. (1993), Law and Economics at Chicago, 36(1) Journal of Law and Economics,
239-254.
Coase, Ronald H. (1994), Essays on Economics and Economists, Chicago, The University of Chicago
Press.
Coleman, James S. (1987), Norms as Social Capital, in Radnitzky, Gerard and Bernholz, Peter (eds),
Economic Imperialism - The Economic Method Applied Outside the Field of Economics, New
York, Paragon House, 133-155.
Coleman, James S. (1988), The Problem of Order: Where are Rights to Act Located?, 144 Journal
of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 367-373.
Coleman, James (1990a), Norm-Generating Structures, in Cook, Karen S. and Levi, Margaret (eds),
The Limits of Rationality, Chicago, The University of Chicago Press, 250-273.
Coleman, James S. (1990b), Natural Persons, Corporate Actors, and Constitutions, 2 Constitutional
Political Economy, 81-106.
Coleman, James S. (1990c), Foundations of Social Theory, Cambridge, MA, Belknap Press of
Harvard University Press.
Coleman, James S. (1991), Constructed Organization: First Principles, 7 Journal of Law, Economics,
and Organization, 7-23.
Coleman, James S. (1992), The Economic Approach to Sociology (An ICUS Book), in Radnitzky,
Gerard (ed.), Universal Economics - Assessing the Achievements of the Economic Approach,
New York, Paragon House, 133-148.
Coleman, Jules L. (1982), The Economic Analysis of Law, in Pennock, J. Roland and Chapman, John
W. (eds), Ethics, Economics and Law, New York, New York University Press, 83-103.
Coleman, Jules L. (1989), Afterword: The Rational Choice Approach to Legal Rules, 65
Chicago-Kent Law Review, 177-191.
Cook, Karen S. and Levi, Margaret (1990), The Limits of Rationality, Chicago, The University of
Chicago Press.
Cooter, Robert D. (1995), Law and Unified Social Theory, 22 Journal of Law and Society, 50-67.
Cooter, Robert D. and Gordley, James (1991), Economic Analysis in Civil Law Countries: Past,
Present, Future, 11 International Review of Law and Economics, 261-263.
100 History of Law and Economics 0200
Cooter, Robert and Kornhauser, Lewis (1980), Can Litigation Improve the Law Without the Help of
Judges?, 9 Journal of Legal Studies, 139-163.
Cooter, Robert and Ulen, Thomas (1996), Law and Economics, New York, HarperCollins, (2nd edn).
Cowen, Tyler (1988), The Theory of Market Failure, Fairfax, VA, George Mason University Press.
Cramton, Roger C. (1983), The Place of Economics in Legal Education (Symposium), 33 Journal
of Legal Education, 183-368.
Cranston, R. (1977), Creeping Economism: Some Thoughts on Law and Economics, 4 British
Journal of Law and Society, 103-115.
Daintith, Terence C. and Teubner, Gunther (1986), Sociological Jurisprudence and Legal Economics:
Risks and Rewards, in Daintith, Terence and Teubner, Gunther (eds), Contract and
Organisation: Legal Analysis in the Light of Economic and Social Theory, Berlin, Walter de
Gruyter, 3-22.
Dales, J.H. (1968a), Land, Water, and Ownership, 1 Canadian Journal of Economics, 791.
Dales, J.H. (1968b), Pollution, Property and Prices - An Essay in Policy-Making and Economics,
Toronto, University of Toronto Press.
De Alessi, Louis (1969), Implications of Property Rights for Government Investment Choices, 59
American Economic Review, 13-24.
De Alessi, Louis (1996), Value, Economic Efficiency, and Rules: Some Implicit Biases Against
Individual Liberty, in Bouillon, Hardy (ed.), Libertarians and Liberalism - Essays in Honour
of Gerard Radnitzky, Aldershot, Ashgate, 112-122.
De Alessi, Louis (1997), Value, Efficiency, and Rules: The Limits of Economics, in Radnitzky,
Gerard (ed.), Values and Social Order - Vol. III. Voluntary versus Coercive Orders, Aldershot,
Avebury, 283-304.
De Clerq, Marc and Naert, Frank (1985), De Politieke Markt (The Political Market), Antwerpen,
Kluwer.
De Geest, Gerrit (1995), Toward an Integration of Economic and Sociological Approaches, 2
European Journal of Law and Economics, 301-308.
Demsetz, Harold (1964), The Exchange and Enforcement of Property Rights, 7 Journal of Law and
Economics, 11-26.
Demsetz, Harold (1966), Some Aspects of Property Rights, 9 Journal of Law and Economics, 61-70.
Demsetz, Harold (1967), Towards a Theory of Property Rights, 57 American Economic Review,
347-373.
Demsetz, Harold (1968), The Cost of Transacting, 82 Quarterly Journal of Economics, 33-53.
Demsetz, Harold (1969), Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint, 12 Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-22.
Demsetz, Harold (1972a), Wealth Distribution and the Ownership of Rights, 1 Journal of Legal
Studies, 223-232.
Demsetz, Harold (1972b), When Does the Rule of Liability Matter?, 1 Journal of Legal Studies,
13-28.
Donohue III, John J. (1988), Law and Economics: The Road not Taken, 22 Law and Society Review,
903-926.
Downs, Anthony (1957), An Economic Theory of Democracy, New York, Harper and Row.
0200 History of Law and Economics 101
Dunleavy, Patrick (1991), Democracy, Bureaucracy and Public Choice - Economic Eplanations in
Political Science, Hertfordshire, Harvester Wheatsheaf.
Duxbury, Neil (1995), Patterns of American Jurisprudence, Oxford, Clarendon Press, ch. 5.
Eggertsson, Thrinn (1990), Economic Behavior and Institutions, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press.
Eggertsson, Thrinn (1993), The Economics of Institutions - Avoiding the Open-Field Syndrome and
the Perils of Path Dependence, 36 Acta Sociologica, 3-37.
Eggertsson, Thrinn (1996), A Note on the Economics of Institutions, in Alston, Lee J., Eggertsson,
Thrinn and North, Douglass C. (eds), Empirical Studies in Institutional Change, New York,
Cambridge University Press, 6-24.
EJLE (1995), 2(4) European Journal of Law and Economics, 263-394.
Ekelund, Robert B., Hbert, Robert F. and Tollison, Robert D. (1989), An Economic Model of the
Medieval Church: Usury as a Form of Rent Seeking, 5 Journal of Law, Economics, and
Organization, 307-331.
Ellickson, Robert C. (1987), A Critique of Economic and Sociological Theories of Social Control,
16 Journal of Legal Studies, 67-99, reprinted in Levmore, Saul (ed.) (1994), Foundations of Tort
Law, New York, Oxford University Press, 265-276.
Ellickson, Robert C. (1989), Bringing Culture and Human Frailty to Rational Actors: A Critique of
Classical Law and Economics, 65 Chicago-Kent Law Review, 23-55.
Ellickson, Robert C. (1990), Three Systems of Land-Use Control, 13 Harvard Journal of Law and
Public Policy, 67-71.
Ellickson, Robert C. (1991), Order without Law - How Neighbors Settle Disputes, Boston, Harvard
University Press.
Elster, Jon (1986), Rational Choice, New York, New York University Press.
Elster, Jon (1989), Nuts and Bolts for the Social Sciences, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Englard, Izhak (1990), Victor Matajas Liability for Damages from an Economic Viewpoint: A
Centennial to an Ignored Economic Analysis of Tort, 10 International Review of Law and
Economics, 173-191.
Epstein, Richard A. (1994), On the Optimal Mix of Private and Common Property, in Paul, Ellen
Frankel, Miller Jr, Fred D. and Paul, Jeffrey (eds), Property Rights, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press, 17-41.
Epstein, Richard A. (1995), Simple Rules for a Complex World, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press.
Epstein, Richard A. (1997), Law and Economics: Its Glorious Past and Cloudy Future, 64 University
of Chicago Law Review, 1167-1174.
Farber, Daniel A. and Frickey, Philip P. (1991), Law and Public Choice - A Critical Introduction,
Chicago, The University of Chicago Press.
Fuller, Lon L. (1968), The Anatomy of the Law (Mentor Books), New York, The New American
Library.
Fuller, Lon L. (1969), The Morality of Law, New Haven, Yale University Press.
Fuller, Lon L. (1971), Human Interaction and the Law, in Wolff, Robert Paul (ed.) The Rule of Law,
New York, Simon and Schuster, 171-217.
Furubotn, Eirik (1989), The New Institutional Approach to Economic History, 145 Journal of
Institutional and Theoretical Economics/ Zeitschrift fr die Gesammte Staatswissenschaft, 1-5.
102 History of Law and Economics 0200
Furubotn, Eirik G. (1993), The New Institutional Economics. Recent Progress: Expanding Frontiers,
149 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics/ Zeitschrift fr die Gesammte
Staatswissenschaft, 1-10.
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Pejovich, Svetozar (1972), Property Rights and Economic Theory: A Survey
of Recent Literature, 10 Journal of Economic Literature, 1137-1172.
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Pejovich, Svetozar (1974), The Economics of Property Rights, Cambridge,
MA, Ballinger Publishing Cy.
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Richter, Rudolf (1992), The New Institutional Economics : A Collection of
Articles from the Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, Ann Arbor, Texas A&M
University Press.
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Richter, Rudolf (eds) (1997), Institutions and Economic Theory: The
Contribution of the New Institutional Economics, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press.
Goetz, Charles J. (1987), Public Choice and the Law: The Paradox of Tullock, in Rowley, Charles
K. (ed.), Democracy and Public Choice: Essays in Honor of Gordon Tullock, Oxford, Blackwell,
171-180.
Goldberg, Victor P. (1976a), Toward an Expanded Economic Theory of Contract, in Samuels,
Warren J. (ed.), The Chicago School of Political Economy, East Lansing, Mich., Association of
Evolutionary Economics and Michigan State University, 259-275. Also in 10 Journal of
Economic Issues, 45-61.
Goldberg, Victor P. (1976b), Commons, Clark, and the Emerging Post-Coasian Law and Economics,
10 Journal of Economic Issues, 877-893.
Gomez, Pierre-Yves (1996), Le Gouvernement de l'Entreprise - Modles conomiques de
l'Entreprise et Pratiques de Gestion (The Governance of Business - Economic Models of the
Enterprise and Management Practices), Paris, Interditions,Masson.
Goodman, John C. (1978), An Economic Theory of Evolution of the Common Law, 7 Journal of
Legal Studies, 393-406.
Gordon, H. Scott (1954), The Economic Theory of a Common Property Resource: The Fishery, 62
Journal of Political Economy, 124-142.
Gordon, H. Scott (1958), Economics and the Conservation Question, 1 Journal of Law and
Economics, 110-121.
Green, David G. (1995), Welfare Before the Welfare State: The British Experience, in Ebeling,
Richard M. (ed.), American Perestroika: The Demise of the Welfare State, Hillsdale, Michigan,
Hillsdale College Press, 73-87.
Green, Donald P. and Shapiro, Ian (1994), Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory - A Critique of
Applications in Political Science, New Haven, Yale University Press.
Greif, Avner (1989), Reputation and Coalitions in Medieval Trade: Evidence on Maghribi Traders,
49 Journal of Economic History, 857-882.
Greif, Avner (1993), Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi
Traders+ Coalition, 83 American Economic Review, 525-548.
Greif, Avner (1997), Reputation and Coalitions in Medieval Trade: Evidence on Maghribi Traders,
in Klein, Daniel B. (ed.), Reputation: Studies in the Voluntary Elicitation of Good Conduct, Ann
Arbor, The University of Michigan Press, 137-163.
Greif, Avner, Milgrom, Paul R. and Weingast, Barry R. (1994), Coordination, Commitment, and
Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild, 102 Journal of Political Economy, 745-776.
0200 History of Law and Economics 103
Griffiths, John (1995), Normative and Rational Choice Accounts of Human Social Behavior, 2
European Journal of Law and Economics, 285-299.
Grossekettler, Heinz (1996), Franz Bhm as a Pioneering Champion of an Economic Theory of
Legislative Science, 3 European Journal of Law and Economics, 309-329.
Hgg, P. Gran T. (1997), Theories on the Economics of Regulation: A Survey of the Literature from
a European Perspective, 4 European Journal of Law and Economics, 337-370.
Hahn, Frank and Hollis, Martin (eds) (1979), Philosophy and Economic Theory, Oxford, Oxford
University Press.
Hamilton, Bruce W. (1987), Tiebout: Hypothesis, in Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray and Newman,
Peter (eds), The New Palgrave - The World of Economics, New York, W.W. Norton, 672-677.
Hargreaves Heap, Shaun, Hollis, Martin et al (1992), The Theory of Choice - A Critical Guide,
Oxford, Blackwell.
Harris, Donald R., Ogus, A.I. and Phillips, J. (1979), Contract Remedies and the Consumer Surplus,
95 Law Quarterly Review, 581-610.
Hart, H.L.A. (1977), American Jurisprudence Through English Eyes: The Nightmare and the Noble
Dream, 11 Georgia Law Review , 969-990.
Hayek, F.A. (1948), The Use of Knowledge in Society, in Hayek, F.A. (ed.), Individualism and
Economic Order, Chicago, Henry Regnery Cy, 77-91.
Hayek, F.A. (1968), Competition as a Discovery Procedure, in Hayek, F.A. (ed.), New Studies in
Philosophy, Politics, Economics and the History of Ideas, Chicago, The University of Chicago
Press, 179-190.
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1973), Law, Legislation and Liberty - Volume 1: Rules and Order, Chicago, The
University of Chicago Press.
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1976), Law, Legislation and Liberty - Volume 2: The Mirage of Social Justice,
Chicago, The University of Chicago Press.
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1979), Law, Legislation and Liberty - Volume 3: The Political Order of a Free
People, Chicago, The University of Chicago Press.
Heiner, Ronald A. (1983), The Origin of Predictable Behavior, 73 American Economic Review,
560-595.
Hirshleifer, Jack (1982), Evolutionary Models in Economics and Law: Cooperation versus Conflict
Strategies, in Rubin, Paul H. (ed.), Research in Law and Economics, vol. 4 - Evolutionary
Models in Economics and Law, Greenwich, Conn., JAI Press, 1-60.
Hofstra Symposium (1980), Symposium on Efficiency as a Legal Concern, 8 Hofstra Law Review,
485-972.
Hogarth, Robin M. and Reder, Melvin W. (1986), Rational Choice - The Contrast between
Economics and Psychology, Chicago, The University of Chicago Press.
Hollander, Abraham and Mackaay, Ejan (1982), Are Judges Economists at Heart?, in Ciampi, C.
(ed.), Artificial Intelligence and Legal Information Systems, Volume I, Amsterdam,
North-Holland Publishing, 129-149.
Hollis, Martin (1987), The Cunning of Reason, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Hollis, Martin and Nell, Edward (1975), Rational Economic Man - A Philosophical Critique of
NeoClassical Economics, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Holmes, Oliver Wendell (1897), The Path of the Law, 10 Harvard Law Review, 457-478.
Horn, Norbert (1976), Zur konomischen Rationalitt des Privatrechts. Die Privatrechts Theoretische
Verwertbarkeit der Economics Analysis of Law (On the Economic Rationality of Private Law. On
104 History of Law and Economics 0200
Private-Law Assessment of the Economics Analysis of Law), 176 Archiv fr die Civilistische
Praxis, 307-333.
Hovenkamp, Herbert (1983), The Economics of Legal History, 67 Minnesota Law Review, 645-697.
Hovenkamp, Herbert (1990), The First Great Law and Economics Movement, 42 Stanford Law
Review, 993-1058.
Hume, David ([1740] 1978), A Treatise of Human Nature, Oxford, Clarendon Press, (2nd edn).
Hume, David ([1777] 1987), Idea of a Perfect Commonwealth, in Hume, David (ed.), Essays Moral,
Political and Literary, Indianapolis, Liberty Fund, 512-519.
Hutter, Michael (1982), Early Contributions to Law and Economics - Adolf Wagners Grundlegung,
16 Journal of Economic Issues, 131-147.
Johnston, Jason Scott (1990), Law, Economics, and Post-Realist Explanation, 24 Law and Society
Review, 1217-1254.
Kahneman, Daniel, Slovic, Paul and Tversky, Amos (1982), Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics
and Biases, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Kahneman, Daniel, Knetsch, Jack L. and Thaler, Richard H. (1991), The Endowment Effect, Loss
Aversion, and Status Quo Bias, 5 Journal of Economic Perspectives, 193-206.
Katz, Avery Wiener (1998), Foundations of the Economic Approach to Law, New York, Oxford
University Press.
Kendall, Frances and Louw, Leon (1989), Let the People Govern, Norwood (South Africa), Amagi
Publications.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1989), Recht en Speltheorie - Een Economisch Model voor het Ontstaan van
Staten en Recht (Law and Game Theory - an Economic Model of the Emergence of States and
Law), Lelystad (Pays-Bas), Koninklijke Vermande.
Kinsella, N. Stephan (1995), Legislation and the Discovery of Law in a Free Society, 11 Journal of
Libertarian Studies, 132-181.
Kirchner, Christian (1991), The Difficult Reception of Law and Economics in Germany, 11(3)
International Review of Law and Economics, 277-292.
Kirzner, Israel M. (1973), Competition and Entrepreneurship, Chicago, The University of Chicago
Press.
Kirzner, Israel M. (1979), Perception, Opportunity, and Profit - Studies in the Theory of
Entrepreneurship, Chicago, The University of Chicago Press.
Kirzner, Israel M. (1984), Prices, the Communication of Knowledge, and the Discovery Process, in
Leube, Kurt R. and Zlabinger, Albert H. (eds), The Political Economy of Freedom - Essays in
Honor of F.A. Hayek, Mnchen, Philosophia Verlag, 193-206.
Kirzner, Israel M. (1985), Discovery and the Capitalist Process, Chicago, The University of Chicago
Press.
Kirzner, Israel M. (1997), How Markets Work - Disequilibrium, Entrepreneurship and Discovery,
London, Institute of Economic Affairs.
Kitch, Edmund W. (1983a), The Fire of Truth: A Remembrance of Law and Economics at Chicago,
1932-1970, 26 Journal of Law and Economics, 163-234.
Kitch, Edmund W. (1983b), The Intellectual Foundations of Law and Economics, 33 Journal of
Legal Education, 184-196.
Knetsch, Jack L. (1989), The Endowment Effect and Evidence of Nonreversible Indifference Curves,
79 American Economic Review, 1277-1284.
0200 History of Law and Economics 105
Knetsch, Jack L. and Sinden, J.A. (1984a), Willingness to Pay and Compensation Demanded:
Experimental Evidence of an Unexpected Disparity in Measures of Value, 99 Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 507-521.
Knetsch, Jack L. and Sinden, J.A. (1984b), The Persistence of Evaluation Disparaties, 99 Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 691-695.
Knight, Jack (1992), Institutions and Social Conflict, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Knight, Jack and Sened, Itai (eds) (1995), Explaining Social Institutions, Ann Arbor, University of
Michigan Press.
Komesar, Neil K. (1997), Exploring the Darkness: Law, Economics, and Institutional Choice, 1997
Wisconsin Law Review, 465-474.
Krueger, Anne O. (1974), The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society, 64 American
Economic Review, 291-303.
Landes, William M. (1971), An Economic Analysis of the Courts, 14 Journal of Law and
Economics, 61-107.
Landes, William M. and Posner, Richard A. (1976), Legal Precedent: A Theoretical and Empirical
Analysis, 19 Journal of Law and Economics, 249-307.
Landes, William M. and Posner, Richard A. (1979), Adjudication as a Private Good, 8 Journal of
Legal Studies, 235-284.
Landes, William M. and Posner, Richard A. (1980), Legal Change, Judicial Behavior and the
Diversity Jurisdiction, 9 Journal of Legal Studies, 367-386.
Langlois, Richard N. (1986), Rationality, Institutions, and Explanation, in Langlois, Richard N. (ed.),
Economics as a Process - Essays in the New Institutional Economics, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press, 225-255.
Lehmann, Michael (1983), Brgerliches Recht und Handelsrecht - eine Juristische und
konomische Analyse (Civil and Commercial Law - A Legal and Economic Analysis), Stuttgart,
C.E. Poeschel Verlag.
Lemennicier, Bertrand (1988), Le March du Mariage et de la Famille (The Market of Marriage and
the Family), Paris, Presses Universitaires de France.
Lenel, Hans Otto (1996), The Life and Work of Franz Bhm, 3 European Journal of Law and
Economics, 301-307.
Leo (1985), Editors Foreword, 1 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 3-4.
Leo (1997), Mission statement, 13 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 0 (inside cover).
Leoni, Bruno ([1961] 1991), Freedom and the Law, Indianapolis, LibertyPress, (3rd edn).
Lepage, Henri (1985), Pourquoi la Proprit (Why Property?), Paris, Hachette.
Levi, Edward H. (1966), Aaron Director and the Study of Law and Economics, 9 Journal of Law and
Economics, 3-4.
Levmore, Saul (1986), Rethinking Comparative Law: Variety and Uniformity in Ancient and Modern
Tort Law, 61 Tulane Law Review, 235-287.
Levmore, Saul (1987), Variety and Uniformity in the Treatment of the Good-Faith Purchaser, 16
Journal of Legal Studies, 43-65.
Libecap, Gary D. (1986), Property Rights in Economic History: Implications for Research, 23
Explorations in Economic History, 227-252.
Libecap, Gary D. (1989), Contracting for Property Rights, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
106 History of Law and Economics 0200
Libecap, Gary (1992), Douglass C. North: Institutions and Economic Performance, in Samuels,
Warren J. (ed.), New Horizons in Economic Thought: Appraisals of Leading Economists,
Aldershot, Edward Elgar, 227-298.
Libecap, Gary (1993a), Politics, Institutions, and Institutional Change, 149 Journal of Institutional
and Theoretical Economics, 29-35.
Libecap, Gary (1993b), What Really Happened at Teapot Dome?, in McCloskey, Donald N. (ed.),
Second Thoughts - Myths and Morals of US Economic History, New York, Oxford University
Press,157-162.
Liebhafsky, Harold H. (1976), Price Theory as Jurisprudence: Law and Economics Chicago Style,
10 Journal of Economic Issues, 23-43.
Macaulay, Stewart (1963), Non-Contractual Relations in Business. A Preliminary Study, 28
American Sociological Review, 55-67.
Machiavelli, Niccol (1961), The Prince, Harmondsworth, UK, Penguin Books.
Mackaay, Ejan (1980), Veranderingen in het Stelsel van Vergoeding en Verhaal van Schade -
Economische Kanttekeningen (Changes in the System of Compensation and Recourse for Damages
- Economic Considerations), in:Schade lijden en Schade dragen, Zwolle, W.E.J. Tjeenk Willink,
147-174.
Mackaay, Ejan (1982), Economics of Information and Law, Boston, Kluwer.
Mackaay, Ejan (1986), La Rgle Juridique Observe par le Prisme de lconomiste. Une Histoire
Stylise du Mouvement de lAnalyse conomique du Droit (The Legal Rule Observed Through
the Glasses of the Economist. A Stylised History of the Law and Economics Movement), 1986
Revue Internationale de Droit conomique, 43-83.
Mackaay, Ejan (1987), Le Juriste a-t-il le Droit dIgnorer lconomiste? (May Lawyers Ignore
Economists?), 2 Revue de la Recherche Juridique - Droit Prospectif, 419-427.
Mackaay, Ejan (1988a), Het Recht Bezien door de Bril van de Economist (The Law Observed
Through the Economists Eyeglass), 1988 Rechtsgeleerd Magazijn Themis, 411-452.
Mackaay, Ejan (1988b), LOrdre Spontan Comme Fondement du Droit - Un Survol des Modles de
lmergence des Rgles dans la Socit Civile (Spontaneous Order as the Foundation of Law - An
Overview of Models of the Emergence of Norms in Society), 22 Revue Juridique Thmis,
347-383 and (1989) 3 Revue Internationale de Droit conomique, 247-287.
Mackaay, Ejan (1991), Le Droit Saisi par le Jeu (Law as a Game), 17-18 Droit et Socit, 57-81.
Mackaay, Ejan (1997), The Emergence of Constitutional Rights,8 Constitutional Political Economy,
15-36.
Maine, Henry Sumner ([1861] 1977), Ancient Law, London, Everymans Library.
Manne, Henry G. (1962), The Higher Criticism of the Modern Corporation, 62 Columbia Law
Review, 399-432.
Manne, Henry G. (1965), Mergers and the Market for Corporate Control, 73 Journal of Political
Economy, 110-120.
Manne, Henry G. (1966a), In Defense of Insider Trading, 44 Harvard Business Review, 113-122.
Manne, Henry G. (1966b), Insider Trading and the Stock Market, New York, Free Press.
Manne, Henry G. (1967), Our Two Corporate Systems: Law and Economics, 53 Virginia Law
Review, 259-284.
0200 History of Law and Economics 107
Manne, Henry G. (1993), An Intellectual History of the School of Law George Mason University,
Rapport, Law and Economics Center, School of Law, George Mason University.
March, James G. (1986), Bounded Rationality, Ambiguity, and the Engineering of Choice (Readings
in Social and Political Theory), in Elster, Jon (ed.), Rational Choice, New York, New York
University Press, 143-170.
Mashaw, Jerry L. (1997), Greed, Chaos, and Governance - Using Public Choice to Improve Public
Law, New Haven, Yale University Press.
Mattei, Ugo (1994a), Efficiency as Equity: Insights from Comparative Law and Economics, 18
Hastings International and Comparative Law Review, 157-173.
Mattei, Ugo (1994b), Efficiency in Legal Transplants: An Essay in Comparative Law and Economics,
14 International Review of Law and Economics, 3-19.
Mattei, Ugo (1994c), Why the Wind Changed: Intellectual Leadership in Western Law, 42 American
Journal of Comparative Law, 195-218.
Mattei, Ugo (1995), The Comparative Law and Economics of Penalty Clause in Contracts, 43
American Journal of Comparative Law, 427-444.
Mattei, Ugo (1996), Aspects of Reception of Law, 44 American Journal of Comparative Law,
335-351.
Mattei, Ugo (1997), Comparative Law and Economics, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press.
Mattei, Ugo and Pardolesi, Robert (1991), Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries: A
Comparative Approach, 11 International Review of Law and Economics, 265-275.
McAdams, Richard H. (1997), Comment: Accounting for Norms, 1997 Wisconsin Law Review,
625-637.
McChesney, Fred S. (1987), Rent Extraction and Rent Creation in the Economic Theory of
Regulation, 16 Journal of Legal Studies, 101-118.
McChesney, Fred S. (1997),Money for Nothing - Politicians, Rent Extraction and Political Extortion,
Cambridge, Harvard University Press.
McChesney, Fred S. and Shughart II, William F. (1995), The Causes and Consequences of Antitrust
- The Public-Choice Perspective, Chicago, The University of Chicago Press.
McKean, Roland N. (1970a), Products Liability: Implications of Some Changing Property Rights, 84
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 611-626.
McKean, Roland N. (1970b), Products Liability: Trends and Implications, 38 University of Chicago
Law Review, 3-63.
Medema, Steven G. (1989), Discourse and the Institutional Approach to Law and Economics: Factors
that Separate the Institutional Approach to Law and Economics From Alternative Approaches, 23
Journal of Economic Issues, 417-425.
Medema, Steven G. (1997), The Trial of Homo Economicus: What Law and Economics Tells Us
about the Development of Economic Imperialism, in John B. Davis (ed.), New Economics and
Its History, History of Political Economy, 29 (supplement), 122-142.
Medema, Steven G. (1998), Wandering the Road from Pluralism to Posner: The Transformation of
Law and Economics in the Twentieth Century, in Mary Morgan and Malcolm Rutherford (eds),
The Transformation of American Economics: From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar
Neoclassicism, History of Political Economy, 30 (supplement), 202-224.
Meltzer, Bernard D. (1966), Aaron Director: A Personal Appreciation, 9 Journal of Law and
Economics, 5-6.
108 History of Law and Economics 0200
Mercuro, Nicholas (1989), Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Mercuro, Nicholas and Medema, Steven G. (1997), Economics and the Law: From Posner to
Post-Modernism, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Michelman, Frank I. (1980), Constitutions, Statutes, and the Theory of Efficient Adjudication, 9
Journal of Legal Studies, 431-461.
Migu, Jean-Luc (1993), Federalism and Free Trade, London, Institute of Economic Affairs.
Migu, Jean-Luc (1997), Public Choice in a Federal System, 90 Public Choice, 235-254.
Milgrom, Paul R., North, Douglass C. and Weingast, Barry R. (1997), The Role of Institutions in the
Revival of Trade: Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs, in Klein, Daniel B.
(ed.), Reputation: Studies in the Voluntary Elicitation of Good Conduct, Ann Arbor, The
University of Michigan Press, 243-266.
Miller, Gary J. (1992), Managerial Dilemmas: The Political Economy of Hierarchy (Political
Economy of Decisions and Institutions), Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Mitchell, William C. (1988), Virginia, Rochester and Bloomington: Twenty-five Years of Public
Choice and Political Science, 56 Public Choice, 101-119.
Mitchell, William C. and Simmons, Randy T. (1994), Beyond Politics - Markets, Welfare, and the
Failure of Bureaucracy, Boulder, Westview Press.
Mueller, Dennis C. (1979), Public Choice, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Mueller, Dennis C. (1989), Public Choice II - A revised edition of Public Choice, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
Mueller, Dennis C. (ed.) (1997), Perspectives on Public Choice - A Handbook, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
Nelson, Richard R. and Winter, Sidney G. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change,
Cambridge, MA, The Belknap Press.
Niskanen, William A. (1971), Bureaucracy and Representative Government, Chicago, Aldine Press.
Niskanen Jr, William A. (1994), Bureaucracy and Public Economics, Aldershot, Edward Elgar.
North, Douglass C. (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History, New York, W.W. Norton
and Co.
North, Douglass C. (1984), Transaction Costs, Institutions, and Economic History, 140 Journal of
Institutional and Theoretical Economics/Zeitschrift fr die Gesammte Staatswissenschaft, 7 ff.
North, Douglass C. (1986), The New Institutional Economics, 142 Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics/Zeitschrift fr die Gesammte Staatswissenschaft, 230-237.
North, Douglass C. (1989), A Transaction Cost Approach to the Historical Development of Polities
and Economics, 145 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics/ Zeitschrift fr die
Gesammte Staatswissenschaft, 661-668.
North, Douglass C. (1991), Institutions, 5 Journal of Economic Perspectives, 97-112.
North, Douglass C. (1993), Institutions and Credible Commitment, 149 Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics/Zeitschrift fr die Gesammte Staatswissenschaft, 11-23.
North, Douglass C. (1994), Economic Performance Through Time, 84 American Economic Review,
359-368.
0200 History of Law and Economics 109
North, Douglas C. (1995), Five Propositions about Institutional Change, in Knight, Jack and Sened,
Itai (eds), Explaining Social Institutions, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press, 15-26.
North, Douglass C. (1996), Economic Performance Through Time, in Alston, Lee J., Eggertsson,
Thrinn and North, Douglass C. (eds) Empirical Studies in Institutional Change, New York,
Cambridge University Press, 342-355.
North, Douglass C. and Wallis, J.J. (1994), lntegrating lnstitutional Change and Technical Change in
Economic History. A Transaction Cost Approach, 150 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical
Economics, 609-624.
North, Douglass C. and Weingast, Barry R. (1996), Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution
of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England, in Alston, Lee J.,
Eggertsson, Thrinn and North, Douglass C. (eds), Empirical Studies in Institutional Change,
New York, Cambridge University Press, 134-165.
ODriscoll Jr, Gerald P. and Rizzo, Mario J. (1996), The Economics of Time and Ignorance, London,
Routledge (2nd edn).
Ogus, Anthony I. (1980), Economics, Liberty and the Common Law, 15 Journal of the Society of
Public Teachers of Law, 42-57.
Ogus, Anthony I. (1989), Law and Spontaneous Order: Hayeks Contribution to Legal Theory, 16
Journal of Law and Society, 393-409.
Ogus, Anthony I. (1994), Regulation - Legal Form and Economic Theory, Oxford, Clarendon Press.
Ogus, A.I. and Veljanovski, C.G. (1984), Readings in the Economics of Law and Regulation, Oxford,
Clarendon Press.
Oi, Walter J. (1973), The Economics of Product Safety, 4 Bell Journal of Economics and
Management, 3-28.
Olson, Mancur (1965), The Logic of Collective Action - Public Goods and the Theory of Groups,
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Opp, Karl-Dieter (1979), Emergence and Effects of Social Norms - A Confrontation of Some
Hypotheses of Sociology and Economics, 32 Kyklos, 775-801.
Opp, Karl-Dieter (1982), Evolutionary Emergence of Norms, 21 British Journal of Social
Psychology, 139-149.
Opp, Karl-Dieter (1983), Die Entstehung sozialer Normen, Tbingen, J.C.B. Mohr.
Opp, Karl-Dieter (1988), Spontaneous Order and Tit for Tat. Some Hypotheses and an Empirical
Test, 144 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 374-385.
Opp, Karl-Dieter (1991), Economie et Sociologie: Les Fondements Communs, 2 Journal des
conomistes et des tudes Humaines, 63-82.
Paqu, Karl-Heinz (1985), How Far is Vienna from Chicago - An Essay on the Methodology of Two
Schools of Dogmatic Liberalism, 38 Kyklos, 412-434.
Parisi, Francesco (1995), Toward a Theory of Spontaneous Law, 6 Constitutional Political
Economy, 211-231.
Pearson, Heath (1997), Origins of Law and Economics - The Economists New Science of Law,
1830-1930, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Pejovich, Svetozar (1971), Towards a General Theory of Property Rights, 31 Zeitschrift fr
Nationalkonomie, 141-155.
Pejovich, Svetozar (1972), Towards an Economic Theory of the Creation and Specification of Property
Rights, 30 Review of Social Economics, 309 ff.
110 History of Law and Economics 0200
Peltzman, Sam (1973), An Evaluation of Consumer Protection Legislation: The 1962 Drug
Amendments, 81 Journal of Political Economy, 1049-1091.
Peltzman, Sam (1976), Toward a More General Theory of Regulation, 19 Journal of Law and
Economics, 211-240.
Peltzman, Sam (1989), The Economic Theory of Regulation after a Decade of Deregulation, in
Bailey, Martin and Winston, Clifford (eds), Brookings Papers on Economic Activity:
Microeconomics, Washington DC, Brookings Institution, 1-41.
Pennock, J. Roland and Chapman, John W. (1982), Ethics, Economics and Law, New York, New
York University Press.
Picker, Randal C. (1997), Simple Games in a Complex World: A Generative Approach to the
Adoption of Norms, 64 University of Chicago Law Review, 1225-1288.
Plant, Arnold (1934a), The Economic Aspects of Copyright in Books, 1 Economica, 167-195.
Plant, Arnold (1934b), The Economic Theory Concerning Patents in Inventions,1 Economica, 30-51.
Plant, Arnold (1953), The New Commerce in Ideas and Intellectual Property, London, University of
London.
Posner, Richard A. (1971), Taxation by Regulation, 2 Bell Journal of Economics and Management
Science, 22-50.
Posner, Richard A. (1972a), A Theory of Negligence, 1 Journal of Legal Studies, 29-96.
Posner, Richard A. (1972b), Economic Analysis of Law, Boston, Little, Brown and Co.
Posner, Richard A. (1973a), An Economic Approach to Legal Procedure and Judicial Administration,
2 Journal of Legal Studies, 399 ff.
Posner, Richard A. (1973b), Strict Liability: A Comment, 2 Journal of Legal Studies, 205-221.
Posner, Richard A. (1974), Theories of Economic Regulation, 5 Bell Journal Economics and
Management Science, 335-358.
Posner, Richard A. (1975a), The Economic Approach to Law, 53 Texas Law Review, 757-782.
Posner, Richard A. (1975b), The Social Cost of Monopoly and Regulation, 83 Journal of Political
Economy, 807-827.
Posner, Richard A. (1976), Antitrust Law, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Posner, Richard A. (1977), Economic Analysis of Law, Boston, Little, Brown and Co (2nd edn).
Posner, Richard A. (1981a), A Reply to Some Recent Criticisms of the Efficiency Theory of the
Common Law, 9 Hofstra Law Review, 775-794.
Posner, Richard A. (1981b), The Economics of Justice, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Posner, Richard A. (1986), Economic Analysis of Law, Boston, Little, Brown and Co (3rd edn).
Posner, Richard A. (1987a), The Law and Economics Movement, 77 American Economic Review
(Papers and Proceedings), 1-13.
Posner, Richard A. (1987b), The Decline of Law as an Autonomous Discipline: 1962-1987, 100
Harvard Law Review, 761-780.
Posner, Richard A. (1988a), Law and Literature - A Misunderstood Relation, Cambridge, MA,
Harvard UP.
Posner, Richard A. (1988b), Comment on Donohue, 22 Law and Society Review, 927-929.
0200 History of Law and Economics 111
D. and Paul, Jeffrey (eds), Liberalism and the Economic Order, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press, 79-102.
Rizzo, Mario J. (ed.) (1979a), Time, Uncertainty, and Disequilibrium - Exploration of Autrian
Themes, Lexington, MA, D.C. Heath and Co (Lexington Books).
Rizzo, Mario J. (1979b), Uncertainty, Subjectivity, and the Economic Analysis of Law, in Rizzo,
Mario J. (ed.), Time, Uncertainty, and Disequilibrium - Exploration of Austrian Themes,
Lexington, MA, D.C. Heath and Co (Lexington Books), 71-95.
Rizzo, Mario J. (1980a), Change in the Common Law: Legal and Economic Considerations
(Symposium), 9 Journal of Legal Studies, 189-429.
Rizzo, Mario J. (1980b), Law Amid Flux: The Economics of Negligence and Strict Liability in Tort,
9 Journal of Legal Studies, 291-318.
Rizzo, Mario J. (1980c), The Mirage of Efficiency, 8 Hofstra Law Review, 648-658.
Rizzo, Mario J. (1980d), Can There be a Principle of Explanation in Common Law Decisions: A
Comment on Priest, 9 Journal of Legal Studies, 423-427.
Rizzo, Mario J. (1981), The Imputation Theory of Proximate Cause: An Economic Framework, 15
Georgia Law Review, 1007-1038.
Rizzo, Mario J. (1982a), The Economic Loss Problem: A Comment on Bishop, 2 Oxford Journal of
Legal Studies, 197-206.
Rizzo, Mario J. (1982b), A Theory of Economic Loss in the Law of Torts, 11 Journal of Legal
Studies, 281-310.
Rizzo, Mario J. (1985), Rules versus Cost-Benefit Analysis in the Common Law, 4 Cato Journal,
865-884.
Rizzo, Mario J. (1987), Foreword - Fundamentals of Causation, 63 Chicago-Kent Law Review,
397-680.
Rizzo, Mario J. and Arnold, F.S. (1980), Causal Apportionment in the Law of Torts: An Economic
Theory, 80 Columbia Law Review, 1399-1429.
Rizzo, Mario J. and Arnold, Frank S. (1987), An Economic Framework for Statutory Interpretation,
50 Law and Contemporary Problems, 165-180.
Robertson, John (1987), Scottish Enlightenment, in Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray and Newman,
Peter (eds), The New Palgrave - The World of Economics, New York, W.W. Norton, 634-639.
Roe, Mark J. (1994), Strong Managers, Weak Owners - The Political Roots of American Corporate
Finance, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Rosa, Jean-Jacques and Aftalion, Florin (1977), LEconomie Retrouve - Vieilles Critiques et
Nouvelles Mthodes, Paris, Economica.
Rosenberg, Nathan and Birdzell Jr, L.E. (1986), How the West Grew Rich - The Economic
Transformation of the Industrial World, New York, Basic Books.
Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent (1992), The Fruits of Revolution - Property Rights, Litigation and French
Agriculture, 1700-1860 (Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions), Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
Roundtable (1997), The Future of Law and Economics: Looking Forward - Roundtable Discussion,
64 University of Chicago Law Review, 1132-1165.
Rousseau, Jean Jacques ([1755] 1971), Discours sur Les Sciences et Les Arts - Discours sur
lOrigine des Ingalits, Paris, Flammarion.
Rowley, Charles K. (1988b), Rent-Seeking versus Directly Unproductive Profit-Seeking Activities,
in Rowley, Charles K., Tollison, Robert D. and Tullock, Gordon (eds), The Political Economy of
Rent-Seeking, Boston, Kluwer, 15-25.
0200 History of Law and Economics 113
Rowley, Charles K. (1989a), The Common Law in Public Choice Perspective: A Theoretical and
Institutional Critique, 12 Hamline Law Review, 355-383.
Rowley, Charles K. (1989b), Public Choice and the Economic Analysis of Law, in Nicholas Mercuro
(ed.), Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 123-173.
Rowley, Charles K. and Brough, Wayne (1987), The Efficiency of the Common Law: A New
Institutional Economics Perspective, in Pethig, Rudiger and Schlieper, Ulrich (eds), Efficiency,
Institutions and Economic Policy: Proceedings of a Workshop held by the
Sonderforschungsbereich 5 at the University of Mannheim, June 1986, Berlin, Springer-Verlag,
103-121.
Rowley, Charles K., Tollison, Robert D. and Tullock, Gordon (1988), The Political Economy of
Rent-Seeking, Boston, Kluwer.
Rubin, Paul (1977), Why is the Common Law Efficient?, 6 Journal of Legal Studies, 51-63.
Rubin, Paul H. (1982), Common Law and Statute Law, 11 Journal of Legal Studies, 205-223.
Samuels, Warren J. (1965), Legal-Economic Policy: A Bibliographical Survey, 58 Law Library
Journal, 230-252.
Samuels, Warren J. (1971), The Interrelationship between Legal and Economic Processes, 14 Journal
of Law and Economics, 435-450.
Samuels, Warren J. (1972), In Defense of a Positive Approach to Government as an Economic
Variable, 15 Journal of Law and Economics, 453-459.
Samuels, Warren J. (1973), Legal-Economic Policy: A Bibliographical Survey, 1965-1972, 66 Law
Library Journal, 96-110.
Samuels, Warren J. (1974), The Coase Theorem and the Study of Law and Economics, 14 Natural
Resources Journal, 1-33.
Samuels, Warren J. (1975), John Henry Beales Lectures on Jurisprudence, 1909, 29 University of
Miami Law Review, 260-280.
Samuels, Warren J. (ed.) (1976a), The Chicago School of Political Economy, East Lansing, Mich.,
Association of Evolutionary Economics and Michigan State University.
Samuels, Warren J. (1976b), Introduction: Commons and Clark on Law and Economics, 10 Journal
of Economic Issues, 743-749.
Samuels, Warren J. (1976c), Further Limits to Chicago School Doctrine, in Samuels, Warren J. (ed.),
The Chicago School of Political Economy, East Lansing, Mich., Association of Evolutionary
Economics and Michigan State University, 397-457.
Samuels, Warren J. (1990), Old versus the New Institutionalism, 2 Review of Political Economy,
83-86.
Samuels, Warren J. (1998a), Founding of Institutional Economics, London, Routledge.
Samuels, Warren J. (1998b), Law and Economics: The Early Journal Literature, London, Pickering
and Chatto Ltd.
Samuels, Warren J. (1998c), European Economists of the Early 20th Century vol. 1: Studies of
Neglected Thinkers of Belgium, France, the Netherlands, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar Publishers.
Samuels, Warren J. and Mercuro, Nicholas (1984), Posnerian Law and Economics on the Bench, 4
International Review of Law and Economics, 107-130.
Samuels, Warren J. and Rutherford, Malcolm (1998), Classics in Institutional Economics: The
Founders - 1890-1945 (5 vols), London, Pickering and Chatto Ltd.
114 History of Law and Economics 0200
Samuels, Warren J. and Schmid, A. Allan (1981), Law and Economics: An Institutional Perspective,
Boston, Martinus Nijhoff Publishing.
Schmid, A. Allen (1965), Property, Power and Progress, 41 Land Economics, 275 ff.
Schmid, A. Allen (1976), The Economics of Property Rights: A Review Article, in Samuels, Warren
J. (ed.), The Chicago School of Political Economy, East Lansing, Mich., Association of
Evolutionary Economics and Michigan State University, 469-479.
Schmid, A. Allan (1978), Property, Power, and Public Choice - An lnquiry into Law and Economics,
New York, NY, Praeger Publishers.
Schmid, A. Allan (1989a), Economy and State: An InstitutionaI Theory of Process and Learning, in
Samuels, Warren (ed.), Fundamentals of the Economic Role of Government, Westport, CT,
Greenwood.
Schmid, A. Allan (1989b), Law and Economics: An lnstitutional Perspective, in Mercuro, Nicholas
(ed.), Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 57-86.
Schmid, A. Allan (1994), Institutional Law and Economics, 1 European Journal of Law and
Economics, 33-51.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1993), Time, Uncertainty, and Subjectivism: Giving More Body to Law and
Economics, 13 International Review of Law and Economics, 61-84.
Schller, Alfred (ed.) (1983), Property Rights und konomische Theorie (Property Rights and
Economic Theory), Mnchen, Verlag Franz Vahlen.
Scully, Gerald W. (1987), The Choice of Law and the Extent of Liberty, 143 Journal of Institutional
and Theoretical Economics, 595-615.
Secretan, Catherine (1990), Les Privilges Berceau de la Libert - La Rvolte des Pays-Bas: aux
Sources de la Pense Politique Moderne (1566-1619) (Privileges as the Mainspring of Liberty
- The Dutch Revolt: Return to the Sources of Modern Political Thought (1566-1619)), Paris, Vrin.
Simon, Herbert A. (1959), Theories of Decision-Making in Economics and Behavioral Science, 49
American Economic Review, 253-283.
Simon, Herbert A. (1972), Theories of Bounded Rationality, in McGuire, C.B. and Radner, Roy
(eds), Decision and Organization: A Volume in Honor of Jacob Marschak, Minneapolis,
University of Minnesota Press (2nd edn), 161-176.
Simon, Herbert A. (1979), From Substantive to Procedural Rationality, in Hahn, Frank and Hollis,
Martin (eds), Philosophy and Economic Theory, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 65-85.
Simon, Herbert A. (1986a), Rationality in Psychology and Economics, in Hogarth, Robin M. and
Reder, Melvin W. (eds), Rational Choice - The Contrast between Economics and Psychology,
Chicago, The University of Chicago Press, 25-40.
Simon, Herbert A. (1986b), Theories of Bounded Rationality, in McGuire, C.B. and Radner, Roy
(eds), Decision and Organization, Minneapolis, University of Minnesota Press (2nd edn),
161-176.
Simpson, A.W.B. (1975), Innovations in Nineteenth Century Contract Law, 91 Law Quarterly
Review, 247 ff.
Simpson, A.W.B. (1979), The Horwitz Thesis and the History of Contracts,46 University of Chicago
Law Review, 533-601.
Simpson, A.W.B. (1985), Quackery and Contract Law: The Case of the Carbolic Smoke Ball, 14
Journal of Legal Studies, 345-389.
Simpson, A.W.B. (1988), Legal Reasoning Anatomized: On Steiners Moral Argument and Social
Vision in the Courts, 13 Law and Social Inquiry, 637 ff.
0200 History of Law and Economics 115
Skogh, Gran (ed.) (1978), Law and Economics - Report from a Symposium in Lund, Sweden 24 -
26 August 1977, Lund, Juridiska Freningen i Lund.
Smith, Adam ([1776] 1937), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, New
York, The Modern Library.
Smith, Adam ([1776] 1982), Lectures on Jurisprudence, Indianapolis, LibertyClassics.
Stearns, Maxwell L. (ed.) (1997), Public Choice and Public Law - Readings and Commentary,
Cincinnati, Anderson Publishing Co.
Stigler, George J. (1970), The Optimum Enforcement of Laws, 68 Journal of Political Economy,
526-536.
Stigler, George J. (1971), The Theory of Economic Regulation, 2 Bell Journal of Economics and
Management Science, 3-21.
Streit, Manfred E. (1992), The Freiburg School of Law and Economics, 148 Journal of Institutional
and Theoretical Economics, 675-704.
Sugden, Robert (1986), The Economics of Rights, Co-operation and Welfare, Oxford, Basil
Blackwell.
Sugden, Robert (1989), Spontaneous Order, 3 Journal of Economic Perspectives, 85-97.
Teijl, Rob and Holzhauer, Rudi W. (1990), Pluriformiteit in de Rechtseconomie: een Verkenning van
Scholen (Pluriformity in Law and Economics: An Exploration of the Schools), 39 Ars Aequi,
617-631.
Teijl, Rob and Holzhauer, Rudi W. (1997), Wisselende Perspectieven in de Rechtseconomie (Varying
Perspectives in Law and Economics), Arnhem, Gouda Quint.
Terrebonne, R.P. (1981), A Strictly Evolutionary Model of Common Law, 10 Journal of Legal
Studies, 397-407.
Thornton, Mark (1991), The Economics of Prohibition, Salt Lake City, University of Utah Press.
Tiebout, Charles M. (1956), A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures, 64 Journal of Political Economy,
416-424.
Tollison, Robert D. (1982), Rent-Seeking: A Survey, 35 Kyklos, 575-602.
Tollison, Robert D. (1987), Is the Theory of Rent-Seeking Here to Stay?, in Rowley, Charles K. (ed.),
Democracy and Public Choice - Essays in Honor of Gordon Tullock, Oxford, Basil Blackwell,
143-157.
Tollison, Robert D. (1997), Rent Seeking, in Mueller, Dennis C. (ed.), Perspectives on Public
Choice - A Handbook, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 506-525.
Trebilcock, Michael J. (1987), The Social Insurance-Deterrence Dilemma of Modern American Tort
Law: A Canadian Perspective on the Liability Insurance Crisis, 24 San Diego Law Review,
929-1002.
Trebilcock, Michael J. (1989), The Future of Tort Law: Mapping the Contours of the Debate, 15
Canadian Business Law Journal, 471-488.
Tullock, Gordon (1987), Rent Seeking, in Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray and Newman, Peter (eds),
The New Palgrave - The World of Economics, New York, W.W. Norton, 604-609.
Tullock, Gordon (1989), Economics of Special Privilege and Rent Seeking, Hingham, MA, Kluwer
Academic Publishers.
Tullock, Gordon (1993), Rent Seeking (The Shaftesbury Papers, 2), Aldershot, Hants, UK, Edward
Elgar.
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel (1974), Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases,
185 Science, 1124-1131.
116 History of Law and Economics 0200
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel (1986a), The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of
Choice (Readings in Social and Political Theory), in Elster, Jon (ed.), Rational Choice, Elster,
New York University Press, 123-141.
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel (1986b), Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions, in
Hogarth, Robin M. and Reder, Melvin W. (eds), Rational Choice - The Contrast between
Economics and Psychology, Chicago, The University of Chicago Press, 67-94.
Tversky, Amos, Slovic, Paul and Kahneman, Daniel (1990), Rational Choice and the Framing of
Decisions, 80 American Economic Review, 215 ff.
Ullmann-Margalit, Edna (1977), The Emergence of Norms, Oxford, Clarendon Press.
Ullmann-Margalit, Edna (1978), Invisible Hand Explanations, 39 Synthese, 263-291.
Umbeck, John R. (1977a), A Theory of Contract Choice and the California Gold Rush, 20 Journal
of Law and Economics, 421437.
Umbeck, John R. (1977b), The California Gold Rush: A Study of Emerging of Property Rights, 14
Explorations in Economic History, 197-226.
Umbeck, John R. (1981a), Might Makes Right: A Theory of the Foundation and Initial Distribution
of Property Rights, 19 Economic Inquiry, 38-59.
Umbeck, John R. (1981b), A Theory of Property Rights with Application to the California Gold Rush,
Ames, Iowa State University Press.
Vanberg, Viktor J. (1994), Carl Mengers Evolutionary and John R. Commons Collective Approach
to Institutions: A Comparison, in Vanberg, Viktor J. (ed.), Rules and Choice in Economics,
London, Routledge, 144-163.
Vanberg, Viktor (1998a), Austrian School of Economics and the Evolution of Institutions, in
Newman, Peter (ed.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, Vol. 1, London,
MacMillan, 134-140.
Vanberg, Viktor (1998b), Freiburg School of Law and Economics, in Newman, Peter (ed.), The New
Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, Vol. 2, London, Mac Millan, 172-179.
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1980), The Economic Approach to Law - A Critical Introduction, 7 British
Journal of Law and Society, 158-193.
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1981), Wealth Maximization, Law and Ethics - On the Limits of Economic
Efficiency, 1 International Review of Law and Economics, 5-28.
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1982), The New Law-and-Economics - A Research Review, Oxford, Centre
for Socio-Legal Studies.
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1990), The Economics of Law - An Introductory Text, London, Institute of
Economic Affairs.
Voigt, Stefan (1992), On the Internal Consistency of Hayeks Evolutionary Oriented Constitutional
Economics - Some General Remarks, 3 Journal des conomistes et des tudes Humaines,
461-476.
Voigt, Stefan (1996), Pure Eclecticism - The Tool Kit of the Constitutional Economist, 7
Constitutional Political Economy, 177-196.
Voigt, Stefan (1997), Positive Constitutional Economics: A Survey, 90 Public Choice, 11-53.
Wagner, Richard E. (1990), To Promote The General Welfare - Market Processes vs. Political
Transfers, San Francisco, CA, Pacific Research Institute for Public Policy.
Webber, Carolyn and Wildavsky, Aaron (1986), A History of Taxation and Expenditure in the
Western World, New York, Simon and Schuster.
0200 History of Law and Economics 117
Abstract
This note concentrates on the state of law and economics in Austria after the
emergence of the economic analysis of law. The long tradition of research in
bringing together legal and economic aspects particularly in the field of
regulation and dating back to the eighteenth century is also adressed. Moreover,
some reasons why modern law and economics have encountered a fairly weak
reception for almost two decades are suggested. Finally, the quite encouraging
development both in teaching and research during the 1990s is emphasized.
JEL classification: A12, K00
Keywords: Austria, law and economics, Paradigms, Teaching, Research
1. General Observations
In Austria, the mutual dependence of economics and law has been recognized
literally for more than two hundred years. However, from the beginning, public
law and, more specifically, regulation - or Wirtschaftsverwaltungsrecht, to use
the appropriate German term - received much more attention than civil law.
Evidence for this assertion is provided by a textbook, entitled The Principles of
Police, Action and Finance, written by one of the most influential counsellors
to the sovereign of the Austrian empire, Joseph von Sonnenfels, which was
published in three volumes beginning in the year 1765, where the term police
refers to public administration, action to private trade and finance to fiscal
issues of government. Here, and in most of the later work treating these issues,
however, there was no common denominator in terms of a distinct
methodology. On the contrary, one of the particular features of modern law and
economics is that legal issues are approached by means of the tools of
microeconomic theory. Taking the latter characteristic as the essential feature
of law and economics, as it is understood nowadays, contrary to the general
concern about economic issues in legal reasoning, the interest in that field of
research in Austria is not very great.
Its reception in the academic sphere is, however, considerably ahead of that
in the secular world. Among scientists, lawyers appear to be more concerned
than economists. This is not surprising, since it is mainly for lawyers that the
118
0305 Law and Economics in Austria 119
2. Predominant Paradigms
One reason for the weak impact of law and economics both in the academic
sphere and civil practice of law seems to be the predominant role of distinct
paradigms in educational training. Legal scholars are basically brought up in
the spirit of legal positivism. Even more recent ideas such as that of a
value-related understanding of law (Bydlinski, 1982) leave hardly any space for
the economic approach to law. Dissenting approaches are rarely considered.
Even in applied research conventional juridical craftsmanship is used; one
typical example is that by the lawyers Aicher and Lessiak (1989) on discount
and competition, which does not contain even one single reference to the
economic analysis of law.
Economists in turn are mainly trained in neoclassical economic theory, as
far as microeconomics is concerned, whereas late Keynesian views predominate
in macroeconomics until recently at least (see Frey and Kirchgssner, 1994, p.
477). Nevertheless, the research programs suggested by scholars of modern law
and economics are occasionally adopted. This can be inferred from the lists of
publications submitted to the present author following a call for submission: in
many of the accompanying letters it is stated that the publications enlisted are
understood as being related to law and economics, without taking into account
the methodology underlying the economic approach to law.
120 Law and Economics in Austria 0305
3. Professional Structure
Lawyers play a predominant role in the Austrian economy. They still hold most
of the leading positions in public administration and in private business. More
recently economists have caught up to some extent, but most of them received
their degrees in business administration, not in economics proper.
However, lawyers receive educational training in basic economics (both
macro and micro) whereas economists are taught basic private and public law
in turn. Moreover, civil servants, who seek achievement to higher posts, must
take supplementary courses in economics as well as distinct fields of law at the
federal academy of administration, irrespective of their university degree.
One reason for the weak reception of the economic approach to law seems to
be a general lack of knowledge about the state of the art. More specifically, the
entire approach is generally associated with the Chicago school, which is held
to be primarily efficiency-orientated, taking the Pareto-efficient allocations of
competitive markets as a reference standard. It is generally agreed that
therefore issues of (social) justice do not receive the attention they deserve in
legal reasoning. These conjectures are supported by the fact that the
predominant references which can be found in the literature are to criticise
Richard Posner, as, for example, in the writings of the most influential authors,
Bydlinsky (1988) and Mayer-Maly (1991).
Consequently it is generally ignored that many outstanding scholars of law
and economics have taken a much broader view than that of the Chicago school
for a long time. It is disturbing to see that their basic ideas have hardly yet
entered university classrooms. Fortunately, there is one exception: the closely
related property rights - public choice approach, as it has been termed by
Goldberg (1980, p. 402) is actually being promoted now in the economic
departments of the universities of Linz, Innsbruck, and Vienna and also in the
department of sociology of the University of Graz. From here, it would only be
a short step to adopt law and economics more generally.With the exception of
the University of Vienna, where regular lectures and seminars are held, this
step has not be taken.
Unfortunately, responses to the questionaire mentioned earlier show that the
situation with respect to teaching is even worse in law schools. There, the ideas
underlying the economic analysis of law are taught only occasionally in the
course of classes held on topics which are traditionally in the domain of law
and economics, such as corporate law, environmental law and criminal law.
0305 Law and Economics in Austria 121
Contrary to the weak overall interest in modern law and economics, the
Austrian economy would offer itself as an ideal playground for scholary work
in that field. It is still highly regulated, with regulations applying to
competition, barriers to entry and administered prices, to name but a few issues.
There is also growing concern about environmental standards accompanied by
an ever-increasing number of legal measures.
More recently predominant policy issues such as privatization of public
utilities and deregulation, as well as the harmonization of the Austrian legal
framework with that of the European Union, create new challenges for both
economists and lawyers. The problems associated with these newly emerging
issues would call for appropriate tools of analysis and advice. Therefore, time
may prepare the ground for a larger perception of the fruitfulness of the
economic approach to law.
In adressing the history of economic thought in the field of modern law and
economics, one must be aware that it is both rooted in and therefore closely
related to a variety of other fields of research. These are nowadays frequently
summarized under the label of New Institutional Economics, and they comprise
many very important contributions, for example on the evolution of social order
and the economic theory of democracy. The most prominent authors associated
with these contributions are Hayek and Schumpeter respectively. Unfortunately
it is beyond the scope of this article to take full account of their work.
Moreover, although they are Austrians by birth and from origin, these authors
- like several others - received adequate acknowledgement for their
pathbreaking contributions abroad only after their emigration from Austria.
Therefore, their pioneering work should be attributed to Austria only with
reservations.
But even with respect to law and economics in a narrow sense, despite its
generally weak reception, Austria may be looked at as an important post of
forerunners: as far back as 1897, Herrmann published a book on Theorie der
Versicherung (Theory of Insurance), in which he introduced ideas which are
quite close to those which a century later became known as the Coase theorem.
Another pioneering work was Rechte und Verhltnisse vom Standpunkt der
Volkswirthschaftslehre (Rights and Relations from the Point of View of
Economics) by Eugen Bhm-Bawerk in 1881. In this small book,
Bhm-Bawerk acknowledges rights and entitlements to be valuable assets. The
title of Victor Matajas book Das Recht des Schadenersatzes vom Standpunkt
der Nationalkonomie (The Law of Damages from an Economic Perspective),
122 Law and Economics in Austria 0305
published in 1888, ought to sound familiar to present day scholars. Finally, the
work of K.G. Wurzel deserves attention here. Writing at the time of World War
One, Wurzel strongly advocated interdisciplinary reasoning for lawyers (see
also Weissel, 1991).
After World War Two, questions of property and wealth were discussed in
the course of both the adoption of ORDO-liberalism and a newly emerging
general interest in the catholic doctrine on social justice and the distribution of
private property (see for example Streissler, 1973). These writings can be seen
as loosely linked to the subject at hand.
During the 1980s, the first writings were published which explicitly
contained reference to the economic analysis of law. A landmark for Austria,
unfortunately with weak impact on the interest in general, however, was the 7th
annual conference of the European Association for law and economics, held in
Vienna in 1989, arranged by the author. It was not until the early 1990s,
though, that the economic analysis of law was explicitly taught for the first time
in classes in the economics department of Vienna university. Occasionally
interdisciplinary seminars were held, and in the Technical University of
Vienna, a group of scientists who had assumed Neoinstitutionalism started a
critical dispute about the relevance of the modern property-rights doctrine.
In Vienna as well as Graz, books by Hafner (1987), Huber (1995) and
Gimpel-Hinteregger (1994) were published, which were basically revised
versions of Habiltation theses and contained reflections on law and
economics.
A research program on Dynamic Models of Optimal Law Enforcement
was established at the Institute for Econometrics, Operation Research and
Systems Theory, University of Technology, which is devoted to the application
of game theory and operations research to the economics of crime, more
specifically corruption and illicit drugs.
Also, more recently, the first doctoral theses have been written explicitly
adressing the approach: Grabenwarter (1994) and Freyer (1994).
Law and economics was finally accepted as complementary course for the
study of both law and economics in 1994. Approximately 20 to 25 scientists are
now working in this field.
Gragnani, A., Rinaldi, S. and Feichtinger, G. (1995), Slow-Fast Limit Cycles in Controlled Drug
Markets, 185 Forschungsbericht/Research Memorandum, Institute for Econometrics, Operation
Research and System Theory, University of Technology, Vienna.
Hafner, Gerhard (1987), Seerechtliche Verteilung von Nutzungsrechten (The Assignment of Property
Rights on the Sea), Vienna-New York, Springer Publishers, 533 p.
Hanreich, Hanspeter (1983), Verbraucherpolitik durch Wettbewerbsrecht (Consumer Policy by
Competition Law), in Korinek, Karl (ed.), Beitrge zum Wirtschaftsrecht, Vienna, Orac
Publishers, 539-560.
Huber, Christian (1990), Schadensbemessung und konomische Analyse des Rechts (The
Measurement of Damage and the Economic Analysis of Law), in Harald Baum, Christoph Engel,
Oliver Remien and Manfred Wenchstern (eds),Jahrbuch Junger Zivilrechtswissenschaftler 1990,
Kapitalmarktrecht, Schadensrecht, Privatrecht und deutsche Einheit, Richard Boorberg Verlag,
133-150.
Huber, Christian (1995), Fragen der Schadensberechnung (Issues in Calculating Damages), Vienna,
Manz, 2nd edn.
Lewisch, Peter (1989), Erwerbsfreiheit und Bedarfsprfung (The Freedom to Earn ones Living as
Subjected to Regulations Concerning Needs), Vienna, Marktwirtschaftliche Schriften des Carl
Menger Institutes, 47 p.
Lewisch, Peter (1995), Punishment, Public Law Enforcement and the Protective State, Vienna-New
York, Springer.
Musger, Gottfried (1991), konomische Analyse der Umwelthaftung (Economic Analysis of
Environmental Liability), in Haureich, Hanspeter and Schwarzer, Stephan (eds), Umwelthaftung,
Vienna, Austrian Economic Publishers Company, 22-41.
Prisching, Manfred (1979), konomische Rechtslehre? ber die Prmissen und Grenzen des Economic
Approach im Recht (Economic Jurisprudenz? On the Premisses and Limits of the Economic
Approach to Law), in Freisitzer, Kurt, Holzer, Hans Ludwig, Mantl, Wolfgang and Hflechner,
Walter (eds), Reformen des Rechts. Festschrift zur 200-Jahr-Feier der Rechtswissenschaftlichen
Fakult der Universitt Graz, Graz, Akademische Druck u. Verlagsanstalt, 995-1020.
Prisching, Manfred (1982), Soziokonomische Bedingungen der Kriminalitt. ber empirische
Divergenzen und theoretische Kontroversen (Socio-economic Conditions of Criminality. On
Empirical Divergencies and Theoretical Controversies), 65 Monatsschrift fr Kriminologie und
Strafrechtsreform, 163-176.
Prisching, Manfred (1983), ber die Karriere einer Handlungstheorie. Der konomische Weg auf dem
Weg durch die Sozialwissenschaften (On the Career of a Behavioral Theory. The Economic Way
on the way through the Social Sciences), 37 Zeitschrift fr philosophische Forschung, 256-274.
Prisching, Manfred (1987), Regeln fr das Handeln. Soziale Entscheidungsmechanismen im
Modernisierungsprozess (Rules for Behavior. Social Decision Mechanisms in Modernization
Process), 18 Rechtstheorie. Zeitschrift fr Logik, Methodenlehre, Kybernetik und Soziologie des
Rechts, 151-181.
Rinaldi, S., Feichtinger, G. and Wirl, F. (1994), Corruption Dynamics in Democratic Systems, 168
Forschungsbericht/Research Memorandum.
Roth, Gabriel (1977), Der Schutzzweck richterlicher Kontrolle von AGB (The Protection Goal of the
Judicial Control of Standard Term Clauses), 4 sterreichische Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftsrecht,
32-37.
0305 Law and Economics in Austria 125
Other References
Aicher, Josef and Lessiak, Rudolf (1989), Rabattgesetz contra Wettbewerb (The Law of Dscounts
versus Competition), Vienna, Carl Menger Institut.
0305 Law and Economics in Austria 127
Abstract
128
0310 Law and Economics in Belgium 129
Yet the average law professor is still not very familiar with the approach.
In the first introductory lectures of their courses, Belgian law professors
traditionally refer to historical and sometimes philosophical literature. In
rare cases only, a Belgian law professor will briefly introduce the students to
the economics of the legal rules. Belgium is of course not unique in this
respect. As in most continental countries, legal science is generally seen as
an autonomous science. In Belgium and France, the Exegetic School,
although officially dead, still has some influence. According to this view,
judges and legal scientists had to follow the legislation as faithfully as
possible and had to leave improvements of the law (de lege ferenda) entirely
to the legislator.
The following sections will survey the current state of law and economics
with respect to education, research and organized conferences and
workshops. Law and economics will be narrowly defined. There is, of
course, much more law and economics in Belgium, if the term includes, for
instance, regulation of industries and industrial organization. In other
words, this survey will pay more attention to new law and economics than
to old law and economics.
2. Education
3. Research
Workshops on law and economics have been held in Antwerp (1986, 1987,
organized by Faure and Van den Bergh), in Ghent (1989, 1994, 1996, 1998
organized by Bouckaert and De Geest), Leuven (1991, organized by
Heremans and Van Cayseele). While the first three were meant to introduce
law and economics to Belgian lawyers, the later workshops were set up for a
more specialized and international audience.
0310 Law and Economics in Belgium 131
Acknowledgements
The author would like to thank Roger Van den Bergh for having organized
the anonymous refereeing procedure.
Andersen, Cecilia (1986), Het Octrooirecht ten dienste van Kleine en Middelgrote Ondernemingen
(Patent Law at the Service of Small and Middle Sized Entreprises), 40 Economisch en Sociaal
Tijdschrift, 613-629.
Baeck, L., Ongena, H. and Cools, J.P. (1987), Begripsbepaling en Situering van het
Dereguleringsverschijnsel in de Geschiedenis van het Economisch Denken (Definition and
Situation of the Deregulation Phenomenon), in X (ed.), 18de Vlaams Wetenschappelijk
Economisch Congres, Brussel 8 en 9 mei 1987, Sociaal-economische Deregulering, Brussel,
V.E.H.U.B., 29-47.
Blauwens, Gust and Van De Voorde, Eddy (1986), Onderzoek naar de Economische Kost van de
Regulering van het Goederenvervoer in Belgi (An Investigation into the Economic Cost of the
Regulation of the Transport of Goods in Belgium), 40 Economisch en Sociaal Tijdschrift,
575-592.
Blauwens, Gust and Van De Voorde, Eddy (1988), Deregulering en de Vraag naar Luchtvervoer
(Deregulation and the Demand for Air Transport), 32 Tijdschrift voor Economie en
Management, 127-142.
Blonk, W.A.G. (1987), Vervoer (Transport), in X (ed.), 18de Vlaams Wetenschappelijk
Economisch Congres, Brussel 8 en 9 mei 1987, Sociaal-economische Deregulering, Brussel,
V.E.H.U.B., 543-560.
Bongaerts, Jan C. (1986), Inleiding tot de Economische Analyse van het Recht met Toepassing op
het Contractenrecht en het Aansprakelijkheidsrecht, Inzonderheid de Milieuramp te Bhopal
(Introduction to Economic Analysis of Law, with Applications to Contract and Tort Law, and
in Particular to the Environmental Disaster in Bhopal), in Van den Bergh, Roger (ed.),
Verslagboek Eerste Werkvergadering Recht en Economie, Antwerpen, Leerstoel A. Van
Melkebeke, Handelshogeschool, 5-20.
Bongaerts, Jan C. (1987), Milieubeleid: Regulering of Aansprakelijkheidsregel? (Environmental
Policy: Regulation or Liability?), Vlaams Jurist Vandaag, 17-22.
Bouckaert, Boudewijn (1984a), Recht op Zoek naar Economie? Prolegomena tot een
Economische Analyse van het Recht (Law in Search of Economics? Introduction to an
Economic Analysis of Law), Gent, Story-Scientia.
132 Law and Economics in Belgium 0310
and Lines: A Reaction to the Criticism of Kruithof towards an Economic Analysis of Law), 50
Rechtskundig Weekblad, 1649-1668.
Van den Bergh, Roger and Heremans, Dirk (1987b), Recht en Economie (Law and Economics),
32 Tijdschrift voor Economie en Management, 139-164.
Van Den Berghe, Lutgart (1987), Financile Instellingen en Markten: 3. Verzekeringen (Financial
Institutions and Markets: Insurance), in X (ed.), 18de Vlaams Wetenschappelijk Economisch
Congres, Brussel 8 en 9 mei 1987, Sociaal-economische Deregulering, Brussel, V.E.H.U.B.,
665-692.
Van Gerven, Walter (1986), Herijken van Economische Wetgeving (over reguleren en dereguleren)
(Re-Stamping of Economic Regulation - on Regulating and Deregulating), 49 Rechtskundig
Weekblad, 286-308.
Van Gerven, Yves (1991), Regulering van Vijandige Overnames. De Amerikaanse Ervaring
(Regulation of Hostile Takeovers: The American Experience), Rechtskundig Weekblad,
791-833.
Van Hulle, K. (1987), Informatie en Markttransparantie (Information and Market Transparency),
in X (ed.), 18de Vlaams Wetenschappelijk Economisch Congres, Brussel 8 en 9 mei 1987,
Sociaal-economische Deregulering, Brussel, V.E.H.U.B., 79-97.
Van Oevelen, Alos (1986), Enige Bedenkingen van een Jurist bij de Economische Analyse van het
Aansprakelijkheidsrecht (Some Considerations of a Jurist on Economic Analys), in Van den
Bergh, Roger (ed.), Verslagboek Eerste Werkvergadering Recht en Economie, Antwerpen,
Leerstoel A. Van Melkebeke, Handelshogeschool, 21-30.
Vanbuggenhout, Willy (1987), De Economische Benadering van het Recht. Haar Nut en Grenzen
voor de Praktijk(bedrijfs)jurist (The Economic Approach of Law: Its Use and Limits for the
Practising Company Lawyer), Vlaams Jurist Vandaag, 27-30.
Vanderveeren, Christine, Van Rompuy, Paul, Heremans, Dirk and Heylen, E. (1987), De
Economische en Monetaire Unie in de Belgische Staatshervorming: Juridische en
Economische Aspecten (The Economic and Monetary Union in the Belgian State Reform:
Legal and Economic Aspects), Antwerpen, Maklu, 250 p.
Vanwildemeersch, J. (1987), Industrie en Milieu (Industry and Environment), in X (ed.), 18de
Vlaams Wetenschappelijk Economisch Congres, Brussel 8 en 9 mei 1987,
Sociaal-economische Deregulering, Brussel, V.E.H.U.B., 399-405.
Vermoes, J. (1987), De Programmaovereenkomst: Regulering of Deregulering? (The Program
Contract: Regulation or Deregulation?), in X (ed.), 18de Vlaams Wetenschappelijk
Economisch Congres, Brussel 8 en 9 mei 1987, Sociaal-economische Deregulering, Brussel,
V.E.H.U.B., 441-454.
Vuchelen, J. En Praet, P. (1987), Diensten en Vrije Beroepen (Services and Free Professions), in X
(ed.), 18de Vlaams Wetenschappelijk Economisch Congres, Brussel 8 en 9 mei 1987,
Sociaal-economische Deregulering, Brussel, V.E.H.U.B., 507-541.
0315
LAW AND ECONOMICS IN DENMARK
Henrik Lando
Associate Professor of Law and Economics at Copenhagen Business School
Copyright 1999 Henrik Lando
Abstract
Law and economics is a small but growing area of research and teaching in
Denmark.
Economic reasoning applied especially to tort law has a long precedent in
Denmark, but often meets with opposition. At the universities, only little
research in law and economics is done within the law faculties and there is no
chair in law and economics. At the business schools the interest among legal
scholars seems greater, as is manifested by the establishment of a law and
economics programme at some of the major business schools. Economists show
an increasing interest in law, and this is largely due to developments within the
theory of industrial organization, mechanism design/contract theory, and
institutional economics.
JEL classification: K00
Keywords: Law and Economics, Research, Teaching
Around 1900, there was a wave of interest in law and economics reasoning
among Scandinavian tort scholars. The inspiration was a book by
lawyer-economist Victor Mataja (a student of Menger) who advocated strict
liability on the basis of the principle of internalization. The wave may be said
to have culminated in the doctoral dissertation of the Danish jurist Henry
Ussing in 1914. He analyzed the question of strict liability vs. negligence in tort
law against the background of neoclassical economic principles. Ussing
advocated strict liability for extraordinary acts which involve unusual danger.
Much of his reasoning was couched in todays modern terms of prevention,
risk-allocation and administration costs. His arguments are modern. For
example, with respect to prevention he mentioned as an argument for strict
liability the problem of non-observability (though he does not use this term),
that is the difficulty for the judge of knowing the particulars of a case, which
means that not all truly sensible precautions will be made under the
negligence rule. He also mentioned that strict liability may induce more
innovation in safety. Ussings main argument for restricting the scope of
139
140 Law and Economics in Denmark 0315
Since Ussings doctoral dissertation in 1914, three doctoral law theses (to be
distinguished from PhD dissertations, the doctorate thesis is usually larger than
a PhD) and one PhD thesis have combined law and economics.
Bo Von Eyben, in Kompensation for personskade (Compensation for
Personal Injury) (1983) discussed the economic approach to tort law at some
length, including references to the works of Ussing, Calabresi and Posner. As
in the textbook mentioned above, the author was sceptical of the value of the
economic approach.
Jens Fejs dissertation (1985) in English translation (1990) was entitled
Monopoly Law and the Market - studies of EC competition law with US
American Antitrust Law as a frame of reference and supported by basic market
economics. He compared American competition policy with that of the
European Common Market (in particular with respect to the use of per se
prohibitions versus the rule of reason) and made extensive reference to
economic theory in his attempt to derive prescriptions.
Jan Schans Christensens doctoral dissertation from 1991, Contested
Take-overs in Danish Law - A Comparative Analysis based on a Law and
Economic Approach discussed the need for legal reform in Denmark to
facilitate contested take-overs.
Thomas Riiss PhD thesis Ophavsret og Retskonomi (Intellectual
Property and Law and Economics) (1996) deals, within an economic model,
with the optimal law of copyrights. His thesis is the first to be written by a
cand.merc.jur which combines law and economics.
The history of Danish economists contributions to law and economics is
difficult to write. Naturally, many economists have been active in designing
laws and regulations, as members for example of expert committees. However,
we will refrain from delving into how economic thought on law has developed
in practice, so to speak. Basic economic research in law seems a recent
phenomenon in Denmark.
0315 Law and Economics in Denmark 141
3. Present Research
The teaching of law and economics has mainly expanded at the Business
School of Copenhagen, the Business School of Aarhus and at lborg
University. In the middle of the 1980s, the three institutions began a law and
economics programme, consisting of a 3-year undergraduate study and 2
years of graduate studies. This is perhaps the main positive development within
law and economics and it is hence worth giving some details about the study.
At the Copenhagen Business School, 588 students are at present enrolled
as law and economics students (373 undergraduate and 215 graduate students),
in rhus the number is 251 (177 undergraduate and 74 graduate students), and
in lborg University the number is approximately 250. At the Copenhagen
Business School the total number of students who have finished their graduate
142 Law and Economics in Denmark 0315
studies from the beginning to the present is 163, in rhus it is 124 and in
lborg it is approximately 160.
Some of the graduate courses are taught jointly by a law scholar and an
economist, for example Tort and Insurance Law and Competition Law, at the
Copenhagen Business School. The programme enjoys a good reputation and
candidates have in general had no problems finding jobs in the private or public
sector. However, it is fair to say that the students are given more training in law
and legal method than in economics. In particular, economic modelling is
given very little attention.
Outside the business schools little is happening in terms of incorporating
law and economics into education, though there are signs of an increasing
interest. At the law faculty of Copenhagen University, a course in law and
economics was established last year, but so far with only a low attendance. In
Aarhus (the second largest city), a similar course was begun some years ago but
it has been abandoned since.
Students of economics are rarely taught law, with the exception of a course
in business law at the undergraduate level at the business schools. Economic
students may, however, obtain credit during their graduate studies for following
courses at the law faculty. In general, however, economists knowledge of law
is very limited at the time they finish their education. Formerly, law was a
first-year mandatory course, but this is no longer so.
Law students are generally taught a first-year course of elementary
economics (although it looks like this course may be cancelled soon at Aarhus
University).
5. The PhDs
It is worth paying attention to the number of PhD students which the subject
attracts, since this number (and the quality of the students in combination with
the quality of the PhD education) is likely to be important for the future of law
and economics in Denmark, even though it must be remembered that some of
the best students study abroad. One can hope, and it seems likely, that the latter
will be of importance in importing law and economics into Denmark.
The number of PhDs working in the field of law and economics is
expanding. As a result of the establishment of the law and economics line of
education mentioned above, this is particularly the case in the business schools.
A handful of graduates with a law and economics degree are presently writing
PhDs, most of them at business schools. Only a couple of these PhDs, however,
combine law and economics in their research, while the rest have mainly
specialized in law. At the law faculties of universities, there is at present only
one PhD student in the field of law and economics (at Copenhagen University,
in contract law).
0315 Law and Economics in Denmark 143
6. Conclusion
Law and economics, that is, the application of economic theory to the field of
law, is a growing area of research and teaching in Denmark. However, the area
is at present small, even in relation to the size of the country.
The following features stand out: economic reasoning applied to law has a
long history in Denmark, but has often met with opposition. At the universities,
only little research in law and economics is done within the law faculties. At
the business schools, the interest among legal scholars seems greater, as is
manifested by the establishment of a law and economics programme at some
of the major business schools.
Albk, Svend, Molgaard, H. Peter and Baltzer Overgaard, Per (1995), Dansk Konkurrenceret og
Vertikal Kontrol (Danish Competition Law and Vertical Control), 133 Nationaltokonomisk
Tidsskrift, 268-283.
Andersen, Peder, Jensen, Vibeke and Birk Mortensen, Jrgen (eds) (1993), Governance by Legal and
Economic Measures, Copenhagen, Gad.
Blegvad, Britt-Mari and Collin, Finn (eds) (1987), Virksomheden mellem konomi og jura (The Firm
between Law and Economics), in Samfundslitteratur 1987.
Christensen, J.S. (1991), Contested Take-overs in Danish Law - A Comparative Analysis based on a
Law and Economic Approach doctoral dissertation discussing the need for legal reform in
Denmark to facilitate contested take-overs, Gad, Kbenham.
Collin, Finn (1987), Integration af Juridiske og konomiske Beslutningsmodeller (Integration of Legal
and Economic Decision models), in Blegvad, Britt-Mari and Collin, Finn (eds), Virksomheden
mellem konomi og jura.
Daintith, Terence C. (1987), Oprettelse og anvendelse af langfristede kontrakter (The Creation and
Use of Longterm Contracts), in Blegvad, Britt-Mari and Collin, Finn (eds), Virksomheden mellem
konomi og jura.
Davis, Jerome, Breinholt Larsen, Finn and Pagh Nielsen, Karen Marie (1984), Offentlig Styring af
Olie-gas Aktiviteter i Grnland (Public Regulation of Oil and Gas Activities in Greenland),
Aarhus University Press.
Davis, Lee N. (1989), Skydd for Innovationer (Protecting Innovations), in Bjurggren, Per-Olof and
Skogh, Gran, Foretaget - et Kontraksekonomisk Analys, Stockholm, SNS forlag, 151-158.
Davis, Lee N. (1991), Patenter og innovationer: Mod et Strategisk Perspektiv. (Patents and
Innovations: Aiming for a Strategic Perspective).
Fej, Jens (1985), Monopol-ret og Marked (Monopoly Law and Market), Kbenhavn, HHK.
Jeppesen, Tim (1995), Miljpolitiske Muligheder i EF (Framing Environmental Policy in the EC),
Nordisk Administrativt Tidsskrift.
Krenchel, Jens Valdemar (1996), Okonomisk ret - om den Retskonomiske Analyse (Analysis of Law
and Economics), 4 Justitia.
144 Law and Economics in Denmark 0315
Lando, Henrik (1996), Hvornr br Objektivt ansvar Glde? Det Retskonomiske bud p et st af
Kriterier for Objketivt Ansvar (When Should Strict Liability Apply? The Law and Economics
Answer), Under Review with Tidsskrift for Retsvidenskab.
Lando, Henrik (1996), Tre Essays om Principper i Rrstatningsretten: Objektivt Ansvar, Culpa-ansvar
og det Offentliges Erstatningsansvar (Three Essays on Tort Law: Strict Liability, Negligence and
Liability of the Public Sector), Working Paper, Institute of Finance.
Larsen, Anders and Olsen, Ole Jess (1995), Konkurrence i Energisektoren og Statslig Regulering
(Competition in the Energy Sector and State Regulation), AKF rapport.
Molgaard, H. Peter, Baltzer Overgaard, Per and Ohlenschlger Madsen, Ole (1996), Den Danske
Konkurrencelov i Moderne Industrikonomisk Belysning (The Danish Law of Competition
analysed in the Perspective of Modern Industrial Economics), Aarhus University Press.
Moller, Michael (1996), Inskydergarantifonden og Redning af Konkurstruede Pengeinstitutter
(Devising a System to Rescue Failing Banks), 5 Finans/Invest.
Moller, Michael and Nielsen, Niels Chr. (1993), En konomisk Analyse af Kbenhavns Kommunes
Hjemfaldspolitik (An Economic Analysis of Repurchase Declarations of the Copenhagen
Community), 2 Nationalokonomisk Tidsskrift.
Moller, Michael and Nielsen, Niels Chr. (1994), Okonomers og Juristers Syn p arv (Economists and
Lawyers View of Inheritance), in Lynge Andersen, Lennart and Mogelvang-Hansen, Peter (eds),
G.E.C. Gad.
Mortensen, Jorgen Birk and Olsen, Ole Jess (1991), Privatisering og Deregulering (Privatisation and
Deregulation), Jurist- og konomforbundets Forlag, 1993.
Nielsen, Niels Chr. (1987), Okonomi, jura og Markedsmekanismer (Law, Economics and the Market
Mechanism), in Blegvad, Britt-Mari and Collin, Finn (eds), Virksomheden mellem konomi og
jura.
Nielsen, Niels Chr. (1993), Minoritetsaktionrbeskyttelse - eller et Velfungerende Marked for
Virksomhedskontrol (Minority Protection or a Well-functioning Market for Corporate Control),
Revision og Regnskabsvsen.
Nielsen, Niels Chr. and Ebbesen, Jan (1993), Stemmelofter - En konomisk Analyse af den Retlige
Analyse (Restrictions on Voting Rights, an Economic Analysis of the Legal Analysis), 6 Juristen,
251-264.
Olsen, Ole Jess (1993), Regulering af Offentlige Forsyningsvirksomheder i Danmark (The Regulation
of Public Utilities in Denmark), Jurist- og konomforbundets Forlag.
Raaschou-Nielsen, Agnete (1988), (Institutional Change and Economic Theory), Kbenhavn, PhD
thesis, Det Statsvidenskablige Fagrd.
Riis, Thomas (1994), Ophavsret og Kulturkonomi i EF (Copyright and the Economics of Culture in
EC), NIR.
Riis, Thomas (1996), Ophavsret og Retskonomi (Intellectual Property and Law and Economics),
PhD thesis.
Riis, Thomas (1996), Copyright and Law and Economics, Gadjura, PhD thesis.
Schledermann, Helmut (1987), Retskonomi for Jurister (Law and Economics for Jurists), Aarhus
University Press.
Svendsen, Gert Tinggaard (1993), Fordele ved et Marked for CO2 -kvoter (Advantages in CO2
Emissions Trading), 7 Samfundskonomen, 5-9.
Svendsen, Gert Tinggaard (1994), Globalt CO2 -marked, 1 Fremtidsorientering, 35-36.
0315 Law and Economics in Denmark 145
Svendsen, Gert Tinggaard (1994), Kvoter og Syreregn (Quotas and Acid Rain), 3 Okonomi & Politik,
33-39.
Svendsen, Gert Tinggaard (1995), Den Stationre Bandit - og Lobbyisme (The Stationary Bandit and
Lobbyism), 3 Okonomi & Politik, 24-31.
Von Eyben et al. (1995), Laerebog i Erstatningsret (Textbook in Tort Law), Jurist s konomabindets
Forlag, p. 35.
Wegener, Morten (1996), Franchising i EU-Konkurrenceretten (Franchising in Perspective of the
EU-Law of Competiton), Forthcoming report winter.
0320
LAW AND ECONOMICS IN FINLAND
Risto Nuolimaa and Pekka Timonen
University of Tampere
Copyright 1999 Risto Nuolimaa and Pekka Timonen
Abstract
This chapter gives an overview of law and economics in Finland and seeks an
explanation for why law and economics arrived late in Finland and then spread
only slowly. In Finland as in the other Nordic countries, legal formalism was
superseded by Scandinavian realism and by the analytical legal research
influenced by this realist school as long ago as the 1940s and 1950s.
In addition, scholars who in a country as small as Finland are few in
number, have had to devote all their efforts to Finnish issues and changes in the
Finnish legal system. European economic integration, however, has been the
main reason for the awakening of interest in law and economics in Finland.
JEL classification: K00
Keywords: Law and Economics, Finland, Legal Realism
1. Background
Until the middle of the 1990s legal research in the field of law and economics
was sporadic in Finland. In economics the situation has been better, though it
has been a field in which only a few scholars have been interested. Since 1994,
however, the gradually increasing volume of research has been produced
mainly by legal scholars and it is this body of work on which this essay will
concentrate. It is based largely on the study by Timonen (1998).
There are several interlinked reasons why law and economics arrived late
in Finland and then spread only slowly.
(1) Jurisprudence in Finland has traditionally been influenced by
developments in the other Nordic countries and in Germany. Thus awareness
of law and economics, yet alone active interest in it, did not spread very
quickly.
(2) Law and economics is intimately connected with the Anglo-American
common law system and so this way of thinking as well as its application seem
somewhat alien in a statute-based legal system. In the Finnish tradition the
written law and travaux prparatoires carry much greater weight than case law
and so research has focussed on the interpretation of current statutory law. This
being the case, it has been possible only to a very limited extent to evaluate the
146
0320 Law and Economics in Finland 147
central question in the common law system: what would be the best (most
efficient) way on a general level to form legal rules.
(3) In the USA law and economics is seen as part of a continuum covering
various trends critical of legal doctrinalism. This is a point emphasized in
particular by Mercuro and Medema (1997). In Finland, as in the other Nordic
countries, legal formalism was superseded by Scandinavian realism and by the
analytical legal research influenced by this realist school as long ago as the
1940s and 1950s (see Stray Ryssdal, 1995, pp. 29-57). A very considerable part
of the pressures for change that Posner (1987) has shown lay behind law and
economics, were dealt with then.
(4) Throughout the 1990s Finnish researchers have been wrestling with the
new legislation and the new questions arising from the EEA agreement and full
EU membership. At the same time the exceptionally severe depression in the
domestic Finnish market and the problems that it caused have given rise to a
debate about reforming or dismantling the Nordic welfare state and this debate
has inevitably raised important legal issues. In other words, scholars, who in
any case in a country as small as Finland are few in number, have had to devote
all their efforts to Finnish issues and changes in the Finnish legal system. They
simply have not had the time and energy to take up new ideas such as law and
economics until they had got a grip on the changes taking place in the Finnish
legal environment and understood their significance. European economic
integration, however, has forced Finnish scholars to seek out a new analytical
apparatus. As Timonen (1997) stresses, this has been the main reason for the
awakening of interest in law and economics in Finland.
The law and economics approach was first presented in Finland in an article
published in 1980 (see Oker-Blom, 1980). It did not, however, arouse much
interest and the whole theme was forgotten in Finland for nearly a decade and
a half, although Timo Rapakko did publish the doctoral thesis he had done in
the USA (Stanford) in Finland (Rapakko, 1987). It might be helpful to point
out here that in Finland doctoral theses have been relatively rare and highly
appreciated. In many subjects they have been written not by young academics
embarking on a career, but by mature scholars in mid-career. Almost without
exception doctoral theses are published. Considerable efforts are now being
made to increase the number of PhDs and to reduce the number of years spent
on doctoral research.
Law and economics research can be said to have got under way in Finland
in 1994. The first economics-based doctoral theses in the field were published
in 1994 and 1995 (see Hgholm, 1994 and Sundgren, 1995). The first law-
148 Law and Economics in Finland 0320
based doctoral theses were published in 1997 (see Timonen, 1997 and Mtt,
1997). So far interdisciplinary discussion and research cooperation has been
meagre.
Otherwise, presentations of the subject for Finnish readers and reports on
research in progress can be found in scholarly articles. In 1995 and 1996
several works were published that presented the approach, see especially
Kanniainen, Mtt and Heimonen (1995). Mostly they describe the
mainstream of law and economics research and explain the basic economic
terminology. The first Finnish textbook on law and economics, Kanniainen and
Mtt (1996) is also a collection of articles, in which each writer treats the
subject from his or her own perspective, the team of writers including experts
in economics as well as law.
From a comparative perspective it is interesting that work on the law and
economics approach in legal studies has begun by using two modes of analysis
that lie outside the mainstream. In Timonen (1997) the questions posed belong
to the branches of law dealing with market behaviour (company, securities and
competition law). The writer questions the suitability of Chicago law and
economics thinking, rooted as it is in neoclassical economics, as a point of
departure for the study of statute-based law and proposes in its place an
approach based on neo-institutional economics. Making use of this, the work
gives a general evaluation of the relationship between markets and regulation
and of the significance of the efficiency argument in legal analysis. Mtt
(1997) applies regulation theory to evaluate environmental taxes and their
efficiency and to examine the development of environmental politics. Of the
trends current within law and economics he has relied most on public choice
thinking.
The first studies that clearly emphasize efficiency arguments and thus best
represent the law and economics approach have yet to see the light of day in
Finland and it is not yet possible to present any overall evaluation. The
approach is, however, spreading rapidly and it can be expected that it will
establish its place as a rightful recognised part of law studies in Finland before
the end of the century.
Hgholm, Kenneth (1994), Essays in the Market for Corporate Control, Helsinki, Swedish School of
Economics and Business Administration.
Kanniainen, Vesa and Mtt, Kalle (eds) (1996), Nkkulmia oikeustaloustieteeseen (Perspectives
on Law and Economics), Helsinki, Gaudeamus.
Kanniainen, Vesa, Mtt, Kalle and Heimonen, Matti (1995), Oikeustaloustiede - law and economics
(Law and Economics), Oikeus, 107-124.
Mtt, Kalle (1997), Environmental Taxes. From an Economic Idea to a Legal Institution, Helsinki,
Finnish Lawyers Publishing.
0320 Law and Economics in Finland 149
Oker-Blom, Max (1980), Jurionomi eller rtten i ekonomiskt perspektiv (Law and Economics or Law
from the Economic Percpective), Tidskrift utgiven av Juridiska Freningen i Finland, 245-265.
Rapakko, Timo (1987), Corporate Control and Parent Firms Liability for their Controlled
Subsidiaries: A Study on the Regulation of Corporate Conduct, Helsinki, Helsinki School of
Economics.
Sundgren, Stefan (1995), Bankruptcy Costs and Bankruptcy Code, Helsinki, Swedish School of
Economics and Business Administration.
Timonen, Pekka (1997), Mrysvalta, hinta ja markkinavoima - Julkisesti noteeratun yrityksen
mrysvallan siirtymisen oikeudellinen sntely (Control, Price and Market Power - The
judicial regulation of transfers of control in quoted companies), Helsinki, Finnish Lawyers
Publishing.
Timonen, Pekka (1998), Oikeustaloustiede - mit se on? (Law and Economics - What is it About?),
Lakimies, 100-114.
Other References
Mercuro, Nicholas and Medema, Steven G. (1997), Economics and the Law. From Posner to
Post-Modernism, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Posner, Richard (1987), The Decline of Law as an Autonomous Discipline: 1962-1987, 100 Harvard
Law Review, 761-780.
Stray Ryssdal, A.C. (1995), Legal Realism and Economics as Behaviour. A Scandinavian Look at
Economic Analysis of Law, Oslo, Juridisk Forlag.
0325
LAW AND ECONOMICS IN FRANCE
Lionel Montagn
Assistant in Civil Law
Universit de Montpellier - Faculty of Law
Copyright 1999 Lionel Montagn
Abstract
1. Introduction
Even if the economic analysis of law has been developed well in most common
law countries, as well in countries such as Germany or Sweden on the
European continent, it must be noted that in France this tool is still
underestimated by lawyers. Initially put forward by economists (A) the
economic approach to law did not have the hoped-for success. As the matter of
fact, we just have to look at the number of works published in this field, to see
that the challenge has been ignored by the legal community (B).
150
0325 Law and Economics in France 151
the last few years by certain authors from Montpellier and Aix-en-Provence
(section 3). Despite those efforts, the majority of the legal profession today
seems to remain insensible to this tool.
In the early 1990s one began to see an implicit recognition by various legal
authors of the utility of the economic analysis of the law as a complement to
legal thought, on the same level as sociology or morality. Hence, in the last
edition of his civil law treaty, Ghestin (1994, pp. 84-85) dedicated some pages
152 Law and Economics in France 0325
to law and economics in order to better situate the position of civil law among
the legal disciplines. Fabre-magnan, in her thesis (1990, pp. 50-117) on the
obligation of information in contracts, suggests an economic analysis of this
obligation after having explained the basics of the economic analysis of law.
Also , Cabrillac (1995, p. 23) in his general introduction of law, summarizes
in a few lines the three functions (normative, predictive, critical) of an
economic analysis of law. Finally, on the initiative of economists in
Aix-en-Provence, Le Journal des Economistes et des Etudes humaines was
founded, including, and this is noteworthy, some professors of law in its
scientific committee.
In 1994 an important event occurred that led us to believe that the challenge
set to the legal community more than thirty years ago had finally been accepted.
Indeed, while the economic analysis of law was not taught in any of the French
universities of law (except, perhaps, the DEA Analyse conomique des
institutions which, however, depends on the University of Economics and is
intended for students in economics), Professor C. Mouly started to introduce his
postgraduate students to the utilization of economic tools in legal reasoning,
and at the same time took part in the third-term university Erasmus (now called
Socrates) Program in law and economics. The department of economic theory
of law at the university of law in Montpellier, of which he was the creator and
the director, became the privileged meeting place for economists and jurists
whose common research on the economic approach to contract law and
property rights, augured a much awaited success. Unfortunately, two years
later, Professor Moulys tragic and premature demise was to slow down the
process of development of law and economics in the French legal culture.
The study of legal questions often requires the use of different elements taken
from sociology, history or logical analysis. The jurist uses these for the same
reason that he/she refers to legal linguistics or philosophy of law. But curiously
enough, the utilization of the economic approach to law is neglected. Some
authors assign this marginalization to the absence of publications in French
(see Mackaay 1987a), but this imbalance, we believe, is also, and firstly, due
to a bias jurists have against economics (section 4) and the specific choice of
economic instruments made by the advocate of an economic analysis of law
(section 5).
the economic analysis of law is too narrow in its approach, and so must be
excluded from legal discussions.
Such attitudes are easily explained. A first reason is the separation of the
legal and economic disciplines in our academic system; jurists have little
knowledge of economic analytical tools. Today, a law student does not receive
the basic economic training that he had in the past. Also, the internal division
within the legal discipline increases the effect of a separation between law and
economics. Thus, the only jurists who use economics are those who follow a
training in patrimonial law or in antitrust law.
Secondly, the jurist dislikes in modern economics what he perceives as a
utilitarian approach. Convinced that economists are motivated only by the study
of efficiency, he quickly turns away from their works. This belief is also
reinforced by the use of mathematical or rationalistic language in economics,
and tools that from the point of view of most jurists are incompatible with
social studies. Not having completely mastered the tools of law and economics,
legal authors therefore prefer to ignore this challenge.
Finally, due to insufficient knowledge of the field and his a priori judgment,
the jurist was not in a position to appreciate the latest evolutions in economics.
Hence, he was unable to notice the new conceptions, such as the Austrian
School, according to which, for example, the criteria of efficiency used in law
and economics must not be static but should be dynamic (Centi, 1987). So,
according to this new view, one cannot appreciate the quality of legal rules only
through its capacity to organize the efficient management of the scarcity. One
must also verify whether our legal system adjusts itself appropriately to change
in our environment. Through its recent development the economic analysis of
law could thus oblige the jurist to question the foundations of institutions,
instead of dogmatically affirming solutions directly translated from Latin
adages which are sometimes obsolete.
of the movement, as well as its slight respect for legal assumptions was,
therefore, the object of diatribes from the legal community. The economic
approach was blamed for being an imperialistic tool like sociology under the
influence of Durkheim. But if we look at todays economic analysis of law, this
argument is no longer true; Posner himself has moderated his positions (see
Posner 1992, p. 25) and other movements have been born admitting that the
economic analysis of the law is just a means among others to appreciate the
quality of certain legal rules.
However, the neoclassic foundations on which the movement is founded
further add to the reasons to ignore the economic analysis of the law. The
rationality of the economic agent who is perfectly aware of prices, and operates
calculated choices in order to maximize his pleasure at the least cost, is a
disconcerting model for one who searches solutions in equity and not in utility.
Homo economicus would not be the model of jurists who think the law and
economics to be incompatible, and presume the collaboration between jurists
and economists to be impossible through lack of a common language.
As Mackaay 1987a has written, the language represents a further obstacle
to this collaboration. Indeed, depending on the disciplines, words have different
meanings. The exchange, for example, represents for economists the general
act by which a person gives up a good against another good, whereas for the
jurist it defines a very particular contract. Inversely, some equivalent notions
are expressed using different words: depending on whether the contract allows
one to get rid of uncertainties or not, the economist will use the terms
complete or incomplete contract where the jurist will use the terms perfect
or imperfect contract. Finally, the legal vocabulary finds its origins in Roman
law whereas the economist uses a more recent terminology adapted to a present
and evolutionary world.
C. Conclusion
Acknowledgements
Special thanks to Prof. Pierre Garello for his help and patience.
0325 Law and Economics in France 155
Ackerman, Bruce A. (1986), Deux Sortes de Recherche en Droit et conomie (Two Sorts of Research
in Law and Economics), Revue de la Recherche Juridique, Droit prospectif: lAnalyse conomique
du Droit, 2 colloques, Aix-en-Provence, mai 1986 et Corte, janvier 1986, Presses Universitaires
dAix-Mareille.
Atias, Christian (1987), La Distinction du Patrimonial et de lExtra-Patrimonial et lAnalyse
conomique du Droit: un Utile Face Face (The Distinction between Patrimonial and
Extra-patrimonial Rights and the Economic Analysis of Law), Revue de la Recherche Juridique,
Droit prospectif: lAnalyse conomique du Droit, 2 colloques, Aix-en-Provence, mai 1986 et Corte,
janvier 1986, Presses Universitaires dAix-Mareille, p. 477.
Bastiat, F. (1983), Proprit et Loi (Property and Law), Paris.
Bauch, Matthias (1996), Unternehmensinsolvenzen, Prophylaxe und Bewltigung in Frankreich -
Darstellung und konomische Analyse von Procdure dAlerte, Rglement Amiable und
Redressement et Liquidation Judiciaires (Bankruptcy of Corporations in France - Discussion and
Economic Analysis), Dissertation, Regensburg.
Bergel, J.-L. (1989), Thorie Gnrale du Droit (General Theory of Law), Dalloz, Coll. Mthode du
Droit.
Bergel, J.-L. (1994), La Proprit (Property), Dalloz.
Bienayme, A., Dfense et Illustration dune Rflexion Juridique Intgrant lconomie (Defense and
Illustration of a Legal Reflexion Integrating Economics), 64(6) La Semaine Juridique.
Cabrillac Remy (1995), Introduction Gnrale au Droit (General Introduction of Law), Dalloz, 23
p.
Carbonnier, J. (1983), Flexible Droit, Textes pour une Sociologie du Droit sans Rigueur. (Flexible
Law, Texts for Sociology of Law without Rigour), L.G.D.J.
Carbonnier, J. (1995), Droit Civil. Les Biens (Civil Law. Goods), T. III, P.U.F.
Centi, Jean-Pierre (1987), Quel Critre dfficience pour lAnalyse conomique du Droit (Which
Efficiency Criterion for Economic Analysis of the Law), in Revue de la Recherche Juridique,
Droit Prospectif: lAnalyse conomique du Droit, 2 colloques, Aix-en-Provence, mai 1986 et
Corte, janvier 1986, Presses Universitaires dAix-Mareille, p. 456.
Cherot, Jean-Yves (1987a), Trois Thses sur lAnalyse conomique du Droit - Quelques Usages de
lApproche conomique des Rgles Juridiques (Three Theses on Economic Analysis of Law -
Some Uses of the Economic Approach to Legal Rules), in Revue de la Recherche Juridique,
Droit Prospectif: lAnalyse conomique du Droit, 2 colloques, Aix-en-Provence, mai 1986 et
Corte, janvier 1986, Presses Universitaires dAix-Mareille, p. 443.
Cherot, Jean-Yves (1987b), Elements pour une Thorie de la Rglementation (Elements for a Theory
of Regulation), Revue de la Recherche Juridique, Droit Prospectif: lAnalyse conomique du
Droit, 2 colloques, Aix-en-Provence, mai 1986 et Corte, janvier 1986, Presses Universitaires
dAix-Mareille.
Cherot, Jean-Yves (1990), Les volutions du Droit conomique (The Evolutions of Law and
Economics).
Coulange, Pierre (1990), La Production de Droit (The Production of Legal Rules), 3 Journal des
Economistes et des Etudes Humaines, 277-302.
Dubouchet, P. (1994), Hermneutique et Thorie Normative du Droit (Hermeneutic and Normative
Theory of Law), Presses Universitaires dAix-Marseille, R.R.J., p. 735.
156 Law and Economics in France 0325
Dubouchet, P. (1994), La thorie Normative et le Langage du Juge (The Normative Theory and the
Language of Judge), Presses Universitaires dAix-Marseille, p. 658 .
Duharcourt, Pierre (1988), Thories et Concept de la Rgulation (Regulation as a Theory and as
a Concept), 22(5) Economies et Socits, 135-161.
Encaoua, David and Koebel, Philippe (1987), Rglementation et Drglementation des
Tlcommunications: Leons Anglo-saxonnes et Perspectives dvolution en France (Regulation
and Deregulation of Telecommunications, Anglo-Saxon Lessons and Evolutionary Perspectives
in France) , 38 Revue Economique, 475-520.
Encaoua, David and Moreaux, Michel (1987), LAnalyse Thorique des Problmes de Tarification
et dAllocation des Costs dans les Tlcommunications (The Theoretical Approach to Pricing and
Cost Allocation for Telecommunication Services), 38 Revue Economique, 375-413.
Fabre-magnan Muriel (1990), De lObligation dInformation dans les Contrats (The Obligation of
Information in Contracts), L.G.D.J.
Farjat, G. (1963), LOrdre Public conomique (Economic Public Order), Bibliothque de Droit Priv.
Farjat, G. (1982), Droit Economique (Economic Law), P.U.F.
Fluet, Claude (1987), Fraude Fiscale et Offre de Travail au Noir (Tax Evasion and the Supply of
Unofficial Labour), 63 LActualit Economique, 225-242.
Fluet, Claude (1990), LAnalyse conomique du Droit (Economic Analysis of Law),43(3) conomie
Applique, 53-66.
Fortier, V. (1991), La Fonction Normative des Notions Floues (The Normative Functions of the
Vagueness Notions), Presses Universitaires dAix-Marseille, p. 755.
Garello, Jacques, Lemennicier, Bertrand and Lepage, Henri (1990), Cinq Questions sur les Syndicats
(Five Questions on Labor Unions), Paris, Presses Universitaires de France (PUF).
Garello, P. (1995), Prsentation dun Dbat Fondamental en Science conomique et ses
Implications pour les Rapports entre Droit et conomie (Presentation of Fundamental Debate
in Economics and its Implication in the Relationship between Law and Economics), R.R.J. , Presses
Universitaires dAix-Marseille., 419 p.
Ghestin Jacques (1994), Trait de Droit Civil (Treate of Civil Law), LGDJ , 84-85.
Gridel, J.-P. (1994), Introduction au Droit et au Droit Franais., Notions Fondamentales.
Mthodologie. Synthses (Introduction to the Law and the French Law, Fundamentals notions.
Methodology. Synthesis), Dalloz.
Hannequart, Achille and Greffe, Xavier (1985), Economie des Interventions Sociales (Economics of
Social Interventions), Paris, Economica, 264 p.
Husson, B. (1987), Le Prise de Contrle dEntreprises (Takeovers), Paris, Presses Universitaires de
France (PUF).
Josserand, L. (1937), Un Ordre Juridique Nouveau (A New Juridical Order), Dalloz, 41 p.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1985), Lanalyse Economique Du Droit (The Economic Analysis of Law),
118-119 Revue de Synthese, 313 ff.
Laveleye, Emile De (1891), De la Proprit et de ses Formes Primitives (Property and its Primitive
Forms), in Rottenberg, Simon (ed.), Occupational Licensure and Regulation, Washington (DC),
American Enterprise Institute.
Lemennicier, Bertrand (1980), La Spcialisation des Rles Conjugaux, les Gains du Mariage et la
Perspective du Divorce (Specialization of Conjugal Role, Marital Gains, and Perspective of
Divorce), consommation.
Lemennicier, Bertrand (1982), Les Dterminants de la Mobilit Matrimoniale (The Determinants of
Matrimonial Mobility), consommation.
0325 Law and Economics in France 157
Lemennicier, Bertrand (1987), Indemnits de Licenciement: Assurances tous Risques, Rparation dun
Prjudice ou Impact sur la Libert de Contracter (Damages of Licensing: All Risk Insurance,
Retrieving a Loss or Taxation on the Freedom of Contract), Revue de la Recherche Juridique
Droit Perspectif.
Lemennicier, Bertrand (1988), Le March du Mariage et de la Famille (The Marriage Market and the
Family), Paris, Presses Universitaires de France (PUF), Collection Libre Echange.
Lemennicier, Bertrand (1990), Biothique et Libert (Bio-Ethics and Liberty), 13 Droits: Revue
Franaise de Thorie Juridique, 111-122.
Lemennicier, Bertrand (1991), Economie du Droit (Economics of Law), Paris, Ed. Cujas, 177 p.
Lemennicier, Bertrand and Levy-Garboua (1981), LArbitrage Autarcie-march: une Explication du
Travail Fminin (Arbitration Autarchy-Market: An Explanation of Female Work), consommation.
Lepage, Henri (1984), Pourquoi la Proprit? (Why Property?), Paris.
Liggio, L. P. (1990), Evolution of French Liberal Thought, 1 Journal des Economistes et des Etudes
Humaines, 101 ff.
MacKaay, Ejan (1986), La Rgle Juridique Observe par le Prisme de lconomiste - une Histoire
Stylise du Mouvement dAnalyse conomique du Droit (The Legal Rule Viewed from the
Perspective of the Economist - A Stylized History of the Law and Economics Movement), 1 Revue
Internationale de Droit Economique, 43-88.
MacKaay, Ejan (1987a), Le Juriste a-t-il le Droit dIgnorer lEconomiste? (May Lawyers Ignore
Economists?), Revue de la Recherche Juridique, 419-427.
MacKaay, Ejan (1987b), Le Paradoxe des Droits Acquis (The Paradox of Acquired Rights), in X
(ed.), De lAncienne la Nouvelle conomie. Essais lOccasion de la Dixime Universit
dt de la Nouvelle conomie, Aix-en-Provence, Librairie de lUniversit, 205-219.
MacKaay, Ejan (1989), Les Droits Intellectuels - entre Proprit et Monopole (Intellectual Property
Rights - Between Property and Monopoly), 1 Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines.
Moine, I. (1997), Les Choses hors Commerce. Une Approche de la Personne Humaine Juridique.
(Things Apart from Commerce. An Approach of Juridical Human Person), LGDJ.
Mouly, Christian (1987), Prsentation du Colloque sur lAnalyse conomique du Droit (Introduction
to the Symposium of Economic Analysis of Law), Revue de la Recherche Juridique, 413 ff.
Mouly, Christian (1995), La Proprit (Property), in X (ed.), Droits et Liberts Fondamentaux, 2nd
edn, Dalloz.
Mouly, Christian (1995), Analyse conomique du Droit Rgissant le Transfert de Proprit (Economic
Analysis of Law Governing the Transfer of Property), in X (ed.), Faut-il Retarder le Transfert
de Proprit?, JCP d. E, 6 ff.
Mousseron, Jean-Marc (1987), La Gestion des Risques par le Contrat (Risk Management by
Contract), Revue Trimestrielle de Droit Civil, 481 ff.
Naudet, Jean-Yves and Serment, Laurent (1990), Le Droit de Proprit Garanti par la Convention
Europenne des Droits de lHomme face lAnalyse conomique (Property Law Guaranteed by
the European Convention of Human Rights, in the Light of Economic Analysis), 15 Revue de la
Recherche Juridique Droit Perspectif, 15-50.
Oppetit, B. (1992), Droit et Economie (Law and Economics), 37 Archives de Philosophie du Droit.
Nouvelle serie, 17 ff.
158 Law and Economics in France 0325
Patault, A.-M (1989), Introduction Historique au Droit des Biens. (Historical Introduction to the
Property), Paris, Presses Universitaires de France.
Picard, Pierre (1988), La Tarification Optimale des Tlcommunications: une Prsentation
Synthetique (Optimal Pricing for Telecommunications: An Overview), 0(12) Annales
dEconomie et de Statistique, 27-62.
Playoust, O. (1993), Normativit et Lgitimit du Droit (Normativism and Legitimacy of Law),
Presses Universitaires dAix-Marseille, 193 p.
Point, Patrick (1990), Entreprises, Normes dEnvironnement et Incitations Reduire les Delais de
Mise en Conformit (Firms, Environmental Standards and Incentives to Promote Compliance),
100 Revue dconomique Politique, 260-282.
Posner, Richard A. (1992), Economic Analysis of Law, 4th edn, Little, Brown and Company.
Poughon, Jean-Michel (1987), Histoire Doctrinale de lchange, (Doctrinal History of Exchange),
LGDJ.
Poughon, Jean-Michel (1990), Une Constante Doctrinale: lApproche conomique du Contract, 12
Droits: Revue Franaise de Thorie Juridique, 47-59.
Prychitko, David L. (1990), Methodological Individualism and the Austrian School, 1 Journal des
Economistes et des Etudes Humaines, 171 ff.
Riboud, M. (1988), Altruisme au Sein de la Famille, Croissance conomique et Dmographie
(Altruism in the Family, Economic Growth and Demography), Revue Economique.
Rosa, J.J. (1984), Derglementation et Thorie du Droit (Deregulation and Legal Theory), 33
Politique Economique.
Rothbard, Murray N. (1991), Lthique de la Libert. (The Ethics of Liberty), Les Belles Lettres.
Rouland, Norbert (1985), Lecture Anthropologique et Inter-Culturelle des Systmes Fonciers
(Anthropology and Inter-cultural Reading of Systems of Property), 1 Destins du Droit de
Proprit, 73 ff.
Salaun, Fabienne (1990), Privatisation et Reglementation: le Cas du British Gas (Privatization and
Regulation: The Case of British Gas), 24 Economies et Socits, 453-469.
Savatier Ren (1959), Les Mthamorphoses conomiques et Sociales du Droit Civil Aujourdhui
(The Economic and Sociologic Metamorphoses of Civil Law Today), Paris, Dalloz.
Savatier Ren (1974), La Thorie des Obligations en Droit Priv conomique (The Theory of
Obligations in Private Economic Law), Paris, Dalloz.
Sayag, Alain and Serbat, Henri (1982), LApplication du Droit de la Faillite. Elments pour un Bilan
(The Application of Bankruptcy Law. Data for an Evaluation), Paris, Librairies Techniques.
Schweitzer, Serge (1987), De lAncienne la Nouvelle Economie: Comment Passe-t-on dun
Paradigme lAutre (From Old to New Economics: How One Goes From One Paradigm to
Another), in X (ed.), De lAncienne la Nouvelle conomie. Essais lOccasion de la
Dixime Universit dt de la Nouvelle conomie. Aix-en-Provence 1978-1987,
Aix-en-Provence, Librairie de lUniversit, 257-274.
Seurot, Franois (1987), Analyse conomique de la Libert des Contrats (Economic Analysis of
Freedom of Contracts), in X (ed.), De lAncienne la Nouvelle conomie. Essais
lOccasion de la Dixime Universit dt de la Nouvelle conomie. Aix-en-Provence
1978-1987, Aix-en-Provence, Librairie de lUniversit, 275-281.
Sofer, C. (1985), La Division du Travail entre Hommes et Femmes (The Division of Labour Between
Men and Women), Paris, Economica.
Thret, Bruno (1990), La Place de ltat dans les Thories conomiques Franaises de la Rgulation:
lments Critiques et Repositionnement la Lumire de lHistoire (The Place of the State in
0325 Law and Economics in France 159
French Economic Theories of Regulation; Critical Arguments and New Posture Brought to Light
by History), 43(2) conomie Applique, 43-81.
Waline, M. (1965), Quelques Facteurs Sociologiques de lvolution Actuelle du Droit (Some
Sociologic Factors of Actual Evolution of Law), in X (ed.), Mlanges Offerts Ren Savatier.
Zenati, F. (1981), Essai sur la Nature Juridique de la Proprit, Contribution la Thorie Juridique
du Droit Subjectif. (Essay on the Juridical Nature of Property, Contribution to the Juridical Theory
of Subjective Rights), Thse, Lyon.
Zenati, F. (1993), Pour une Rnovation de la Thorie de Proprit (For a Renovation of the Theory of
Property), RTD civ., 305 p.
Other References
Atias, C. (1993), Droit Civil. Les Biens. (Civil law. Goods), Litec.
Berra, D. (1969), Le Principe de Libre Disposition des Biens en Droit Civil (The Principe of Free
Disposal of Goods), Nancy.
Brocard, L. (1934), Proprit Prive et conomie Nationale (Property and National Economy),
Mlanges Geny, p. 145.
Fromont, M. (1984), Le Droit de Proprit et la Constitution en Allemagne et en France (Property
Rights and Dutch and French Constitution) in Pequignot, G.D. (ed.), LInterventionnisme
conomique de la Puissance Publique, tudes en lHonneur, p. 267.
Gilli, J.-P. (1975), Redfinir le Droit de Proprit. (To Redefine Property Rights), Centre de
Recherche en Urbanisme.
Goyard-fabre, S. (1981), Kant et le Problme du Droit (Kant and the Problem of Law), Coll.
Bibliothque dHistoire de la Philosophie.
Mazeaud, H., L. Mazeaud, et al. (1994), Leons de Droit Civil, Biens, Droits de Proprit et ses
Dmembrements. (Lessons of Civil Law, Goods, Property Rights and their Decomposition),
Montchrestien Tome II..
Ripert, G. (1951), Aspects Juridiques du Capitalisme Moderne (Juridical Aspects of Modern
Capitalism), L.G.D.J.
0330
LAW AND ECONOMICS IN GERMANY
Roland Kirstein
Center for the Study of Law and Economics
University of Saarland
Copyright 1999 Roland Kirstein
Abstract
1. Introduction
Until 25 years ago, research in the field of law and economics in Germany
mainly focussed on competition and regulation. Discussions on the relation
between jurisprudence and economics took place only occasionally, see for
example Sttzel (1966) and Jahr (1966). Since the late 1970s however, the first
German books on other law and economics topics were published, such as Kunz
(1976a) on the economics of individual and collective crime, Behrens (1986)
on Political Economics, and Adams (1981) on procedural law. A collection of
seminal law and economics papers, translated into German, was published by
Assman, Kirchner and Schanze (1978).
Since then, publications by German scholars have covered all fields of law
and economics. Teaching programs were installed and new research
institutions were founded. A lot of these publications were published in
English, although the bibliography attached to this chapter is limited to
contributions in German. Of course, the discussion as well as the bibliography
can only give a brief overview, which does not claim to be complete.
160
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 161
2. German Ordnungspolitik
this field gained more attention (see for example Ott and Schfer (1996) on
plea bargaining, or Schmidtchen and Kirstein (1997), who analyze the
motivational impact of procedural rules on potential litigants.
One of the oldest institutions in Germany working in the field of law and
economics is the Institut fuer Genossenschaftswesen in Mnster, which was
founded in 1947. Nowadays, it is concerned with analyzing different forms of
cooperation, such as franchise contracts, or Genossenschaften (buyer or seller
cooperatives), making use of the framework of New Institutional Economics,
see Bonus (1981b). Also in Mnster, Grossekettler edits the Schriften zur
wirtschaftswissenschaftlichen Analyse des Rechts.
Teaching activities in law and economics started in the early 1970s. Some
interdisciplinary courses have been organized, such as seminars on competition
and cartel law in Stuttgart or in Tbingen. The annual workshop in law and
economics in Maastricht (the Netherlands) was launched by the German
scholar Jrgen Backhaus in 1987. Since 1984, Backhaus has co-edited the
European Journal of Law and Economics.
In Hamburg, Ott and Schfer installed an Erasmus program for
postgraduate students from 18 European countries, and integrated law and
economics into the Law Faculty. Their textbook (Ott and Schfer, 1996) was
recently published in the 4th edition. Since 1988, Ott and Schfer have
organized a biannual conference on law and economics in Travemuende.
Together with R. van den Bergh, they founded an Institute of law and
economics at the University of Hamburg. The same university also hosts a
Center for Research in Law and Innovation, founded by W. Hoffmann-Riem.
Also in Hamburg, P. Behrens, M. Holler, C. Ott, H.-B. Schfer, and W. Walz
edit a law and economics publication series, called Schriftenreihe zur
oekonomischen Analyse des Rechts.
The first annual meeting on New Political Economics took place in 1981.
Nowadays it is organized by K.-E. Schenk, D. Schmidtchen and M. Streit. The
papers of this conference are published in the Jahrbuecher fuer Neue Politische
Oekonomie. D. Schmidtchen has founded the Forschungsstelle fuer die
oekonomische Analyse des Rechts (Center for the Study of Law and
Economics) at the University of Saarbruecken. The recently founded
Max-Planck Institute for Research into Economic Systems in Jena is mainly
concerned with transition economics. Its starting point in the attempt to explain
the change of economic systems is the idea that economic development mainly
depends on the institutional framework (see for example Streit, 1996). The
Walter-Eucken Institut in Freiburg publishes lectures and papers on economic
policy.
164 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
In 1994, B. Nagel, P. Weise and T. Eger founded an Institut fuer Recht und
Oekonomis (Institut for Law and Economics) at the University in Kassel. I.
Schmidt has founded a center for research into competition policy and cartel
law at the university of Stuttgart. In Trier, the Institut fuer Arbeitsrecht und
Arbeitsbeziehungen in der Europischen Gemeinschaft (Institute for Labor Law
and Labor Relations in the EU) uses institutional economics to perform
empirical comparisions of the labor law of different European countries (see
Sadowski and Kurth, 1991).
R. Richter is the founder of the Wallerfangen summer school (nowadays
organized by U. Schweizer), and started the annual Wallerfangen conference,
which in part covers law and economics subjects. The papers presented in this
conference are published in the Journal of Theoretical and Institutional
Economics (JITE), which is now edited by E. Schlicht.
Adams, Michael (1980), konomische Analyse des Sicherungsrechte (Economic Analysis of Security
Law), Knigstein/Ts, Athenaeum, 322 p.
Adams, Michael (1981), konomische Analyse des Zivilprozesses (Economic Analysis of Civil
Procedure), Knigstein/Ts, Athenaeum, 130 p.
Adams, Michael (1983a), Eine Wohlfahrtstheoretische Analyse des Zivilprozesses und der
Rechtsschutzversicherungen (A Welfare Analysis of Civil Procedure and Legal Costs Insurance),
Zeitschrift fr Schweizerisches Recht, 187-208.
Adams, Michael (1983b), Streitgesprch Adams/Blankenburg ber den Einflu der
Rechtsschutzversicherungen auf den Geschftsanfall der Gerichte, veranstaltet vom
Bundesministerium der Justiz (Discussion on the Influence of Legal Costs Insurances on the
Caseload of the Courts), Deutsche Richterzeitung, 353-362.
Adams, Michael (1985), konomische Analyse des Gefhrdungs- und Verschuldenshaftung
(Economic Analysis of Strict and Fault Liability), Heidelberg, R.v Deckers/C.F. Mller, 310 p.
Adams, Michael (1986a), Zur Aufgabe des Haftungsrechts im Umweltschutz (On the Task of Liability
Law for the Protection of the Environment), 99 Zeitschrift fr Zivilprozess, 129-165.
Adams, Michael (1986b), Der Zivilprozess als Folge strategischen Verhaltens (On Civil Procedure as
a Consequence of Strategic Behavior), 7 Zeitschrift fr Rechtssoziologie, 212-225.
Adams, Michael (1986c), Zur Behandlung von Irrtmern und Offenbarungspflichten im Vertragsrecht
(On Mistake and Information Revelation Duties in Contract Law),186 Archiv fr die civilistische
Praxis, 453-489.
Adams, Michael (1986d), Der Irrtum ber Knftige Sachverhalte. Anwendungsbeispiel und
Einfhrung indie konomische Analyse des Rechts (Error about Future Facts), RECHT,
Zeitschrift fr juristische Ausbildung und Praxis, 14-23.
Adams, Michael (1987a), konomische Analyse der Produkthaftung (Economic Analysis of Product
Liability), 87 Der Betriebs-Berater.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 165
Adams, Michael (1987b), Produkthaftung - Wohltat oder Plage - Eine komische Analyse (Product
Liability - Benefit or Plague - An Economic Analysis), 3124 Der Betriebs-Berater.
Adams, Michael (1989a), Das Verursacherprinzip als Leerformel (The Polluter Pays Principe as
Empty Formula), Juristenzeitung, 789-790.
Adams, Michael (1989b), konomische Begrndung des AGB-Gesetzes - Vertrge bei Asymetrischer
Information (The Economic Basis of the German Unfair Contract T), Der Betriebs-Berater,
781-788.
Adams, Michael (1989c), Warum kein Ersatz von Nichtvermgensschden? (Why No Damages for
Nonpecuniary Losses?), in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), Allekationseffizienz in der
Rechtsordnung, Berlin, Springer, 210-217.
Adams, Michael (1989d), Der Markt fr Unternehmenskontrolle und sein Missbrauch (The Market
of Corporate Control and Its Abuse), Die Aktiengesellschaft, 333-338.
Adams, Michael (1990a), Warum das Verursacherprinzip eine leere Worthlse darstellt und von
feinsinnigen Juristen bei Haftungslastentscheidungen im Umweltrecht als ungeeignetes Kriterium
verworfen werden sollte (Why the Polluter Pays Principle Is an Empty Formula and Should be
Disregarded by Sensitive Lawyers when Making Decisions on Liability in Environment Law), in
Haller, M., Hauser, H. and Zch, R. (eds), Ergngzungen, Festschrift Erweiterungsbau der
Hochschule St. Gallen, Haupt, 605-612.
Adams, Michael (1990b), Was spricht gegen eine unbehinderte bertragbarkeit der in
Unternehmengebundenen Ressourcen durch ihre Eigentmer (Arguments against an Unlimited
Transferability of a Firms Resources), Die Aktiengesellschaft, 243-252.
Adams, Michael (1990c), Zur Nichtigkeit von Preisaufschlagverboten in Kreditkartenvertrgen gem
15 GWB (On the Voidness of Supplementary Charges Prohibition Clauses in Contracts on Credit
Cards), Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftsrecht, 632-635.
Adams, Michael (1990d), Hchststimmrechte, Mehrfachstimmrechte und sonstige wundersame
Hindernisse auf dem Markt fr Unternehmenskontrolle (Maximum Voting Right, Multiple Voting
Right, and some Wonderfull Obstacles from the Market of Corporate Control), 35 Die
Aktiengesellschaft, 63-78.
Adams, Michael (1991a), Normen, Standards, Rechte (Norms, Standards, Rights), Juristenzeitung,
941-955.
Adams, Michael (1991b), Wie zerstrt man den Markt fr Rauschgifte? (How to Destroy the Drug
Markets?), Juni Zeitschrift fr Rechtspolitik, 202-204, unvernderter Nachdruck in, Magazin
fr die Polizei, 9/1992 P. 4-6
Adams, Michael (1991c), Das brgerlich-rechtliche Benachteiligungsverbot gem 612 III BGB
(The Prohibition of Discrimination in the German Private Law), Juristenzeitung, 534-539.
Adams, Michael (1991d), Eigentum, Kontrolle und Beschrnkte Haftung (Property, Control and
Limited Liability), in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des
Zivilrechts, Berlin, Springer, 193-225.
Adams, Michael (1992), Den Teufel mit Belzebub austreiben - Wie man den Markt fr
Rauschgiftezerstrt (Excorcise one Evil with Another - How to Destroy the Drug Markets), 12
Kriminalistik, Zeitschrift fr die gesamte kriminalistische Wissenschaft und Praxis, 757-761.
166 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Adams, Michael (1993), Neues vom Drogenmarkt? (News from the Drug Market), 12 Kriminalistik,
Zeitschrift fr die gesamte kriminalistische Wissenschaft und Praxis, 755-757.
Adams, Michael (1994a), Das Bundesarbeitsgericht und das Recht zur Tuschung (The Federal Labor
Court and the Right to Deceive), April Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftsrecht, 499 ff.
Adams, Michael (1994b), Beseitigung der steuerlich bedingten Machtzentralisierung bei
Versicherungsunternehmen durch Einfhrung eines qualifizierten Kontos (Elimination of the
Centralization of Power due to Tax Law by Introducing a Qualified Account), Zeitschrift fr
Wirtschaftsrecht, 1434-1437.
Adams, Michael (1994c), Die Usurpation von Aktionrsbefugnissen mittels Ringverflechtung in der
Deutschland-AG - Vorschlge fr Reformen im Wettbewerbs-, Steuer- und Unternehmensrecht
(The Ursupation of Shareholders Rights by Circle Interlinks in the Germany Stock Corporation.
Proposals for a Reform in Competition Law, Tax Law, and Cooperations Law), Die
Aktiengesellschaft, 148-156.
Adams, Michael (1994d), Heroin an Schtige? - Ein abschlieender Schlagabtausch (Heroin for
Addicts?), Zeitschrift fr Rechtspolitik, 421-426.
Adams, Michael (1994e), Rechte und Normen als Standards, in Tietzel, M. (ed.), Homo
Oeconomicus, XI (3), konomik der Standardisierung, 501-553.
Adams, Michael (1994f), Heroin vom Staat - Kollektiver Wahnsinn oder das gesuchte Konzept zur
Zerstrung des Drogenmarktes? (Provision of Heroin by the State - Social Madness or a Concept
to Destroy the Drug Market), Mrz Zeitschrift fr Rechtspolitik, 106-111.
Adams, Michael (1994g), Macht von Banken und Versicherungen - Wettbewerb im
Finanzdienstleistungssektor-, Stellungnahme zur ffentlichen Anhrung des Deutschen
Bundestages - Ausschu fr Wirtschaft, 8 Dezember 1993 (Power of Banks and Insurances),
Zeitschrift fr Bank- und Brsenrecht, 77-86.
Adams, Michael (1996), Bankenmacht und Deutscher Juristentag - Es empfehlen sich gesetzliche
Manahmen zur Einschrnkung des Einflusses der Kreditinstitute auf Aktiengesellschaften
(Recommendations to Limit the Influence of Banks on Stock Corporations), Zeitschrift fr
Wirtschaftsrecht, 1590-1602.
Adams, Michael (1997), Heroin an Schtige? - Die Ergebnisse des schweizerischen Versuchs einer
kontrollierten Opiatabgabe an Schtige und ihr Vergleich mit den Einwnden der Versuchsgegner
in Deutschland (Heroin for Addicts? Results of a Swiss Experiment of Controlled Distribution of
Opiates and a Comparision to the Objections of the Opponents in Germany), Zeitschrift fr
Rechtspolitik.
Adams, Michael and Shavell, Steven (1990), Zur Strafbarkeit des Versuchs (On the Criminal Liability
for Attempts), Goltdammers Archiv fr Strafrecht, 337-386.
Adomeit, Klaus (1996), Regelungen von Arbeitsbedingungen und konomische Notwendigkeiten
- Eine Untersuchung zu aktuellen Fragen des Deutschen Tarifrechts (Regulations on the
Conditions of Labour and Economic Constraints), Mnchen, Verlag Aktuell, Landsberg am Lech.
Alsmller, Horst (1982), Wettbewerbspolitische Ziele und Kooperationstheoretische Hvpothesen im
Wandel der Zeit: Eine Dogmengeschichtliche Untersuchung von Einstellungen zu
Verbundsystemen und von Grunden fr diese Einstellun gen (Competition Policy Purpose and
Cooperation-Theoretical Hypotheses Through the Times: A Historical Investigation of the
Institutions for Alliance Systems and for the Causes of these Institutions), Tbingen, Mohr, 337
p.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 167
Assmann, Heinz-Dieter (1978), Die Transformationsprobleme des Privatrechts und die konomische
Analyse des Rechts. Chancen und Grenzen der privatrechlichen Verwertbarkeit der konomischen
Analyse des Rechts (Chances and Limitations of the Usability Economic Analysis of Law with
Respect to Private Law)), in Assmann, Heinz-Dieter, Kirchner, Christian and Schanze, Erich (eds),
konomische Analyse des Rechts, Kronberg, Athenum, 21-74.
Assmann, Heinz-Dieter (1983), Entwicklungstendenzen der Prospekthaftung (Tendencies of Liability
for Misleading Information), WM, 138-144.
Assmann, Heinz-Dieter (1985), Prospekthaftung (Liability for Misleading Information Included in
Prospectuses), Kln, Heymann, 456 p.
Assmann, Heinz-Dieter (1988), Multikausale Schden im deutschen Haftungsrecht (Multicausal
Injuries in German Tort Law), in Fenyves, Attila and Weyers, Hans-Leo (eds), Multikausale
Schden im modernen Haftungsrechten, Frankfurt A.M., Metzner, 99-151.
Assmann, Heinz-Dieter (1989), Kommentar on Ott, Allokationseffizienz, Rechtsdogmatik und
Rechtsprechung, in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), Allekationseffizienz in der
Rechtsordnung, Berlin, Springer, 45-49.
Assmann, Heinz-Dieter (1990), Privatrechtliche Tatbestnde der Umwelthaftung in konomischer
Analyse (Economic Analysis of Civil Liability for Pollution), in Wagner, Gerd Rainer (ed.),
Unternehmung und kologische Umwelt, Mnchen, Vahlen, 201-219.
Assmann, Heinz-Dieter, Kirchner, Christian and Schanze, Erich (eds) (1978), konomische Analyse
des Rechts (Economic Analysis of Law), Kronberg, Athenum, 369 p.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (1979), konomik der partizipativen Unternehmung I (Economics of Enterprises
under Worker Participation), Tbingen, Mohr/Siebeck.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (1980), Arbeitsverhltnis und Beschftigung, Politisch-konomische Analyse
zur Bekmpfung der Arbeitslosigkeit (Labor Relation and Employment, A Political Economic
Anaylsis of Actions against Unemployment), Frankfurt, Campus.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (1980a), Wirtschaftsreformen und Unternehmensverfassung, Fortentwicklung
der Institutionen der Mitbestimmung (Economic Reforms and Constitution of Enterprises.
Development of Worker Participation), in Wagener, Hans-Juergen (ed.), Demokratisierung der
Wirtschaft, Mglichkeiten und Grenzen im Kapitalismus, Frankfurt, Campus.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (1980b), Wirtschaftliche Analyse der Entwicklungsmglichkeiten mitbestimmter
Wirtschaftssysteme (Economic Analysis of Co-Determination), in Kappler, Ekkehard (ed.),
Unternehmensstruktur und Unternehmensentwicklung, Freiburg, Rombach, 266-289.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (1980c), Kein Aufruf zur Verteidigung des organisierten Verbrechens (No Call
for a Defence of Organised Crime), 136(4) Zeitschrift fr die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft,
658-672.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (1980d), ffentliche Unternehmen, Zum Wirtschaftsrecht, den Funktionen und
Rechtsformen ffentlicher Unternehmen (On the Business Law, the Functions, and the Legal
Types of Public Enterprises), Frankfurt, Haag und Herchen.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (1981), Die Funktionsfhigkeit der mitbestimmten Grounternehmung (The
Functionability of Large Corporations under Worker Participation), in Issing, Ottmar (ed.),
Zukunftsprobleme der Sozialen Marktwirtschaft. Verhandlungen auf der Jahrestagung der
Gesellschaft fuer Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften/Verein fuer Socialpolitik, in Nrnberg
1980, Berlin, Duncker and Humblot, 213-228.
168 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Brandes, Wolfgang, Buttler, Friedrich, Dorndorf, Eberhard and Walwei, U. (1991), Grenzen der
Kndigungsfreiheit - Kndigungsschutz zwischen Stabilitt und Flexibilitt (Limits of the Freedom
to Terminate Employment Contracts), in Semlinger, K. (ed.), Flexibilitt des Arbeitsmarktes,
Interessen, Wirkungen, Perspektiven, Frankfurt/Main und New York, Campus-Verlag, 111-131.
Brinkmann, Thomas and Kbler, Friedrich (1981), berlegungen zur konomischen Analyse im
Unternehmensrecht (Thoughts on an Economic Enalysis of Company Law), 137 Journal of
Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 681-688.
Brggemeier, Gert (1989), Die Gefhrdungshaftung der Produzenten nach der EG-Richtlinie - ein
Fortschritt der Rechtsentwicklung? (Strict Liability of Producers according to the EC-), in Ott,
Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), Allekationseffizienz in der Rechtsordnung, Berlin, Springer,
228-247.
Buhbe, Matthes (1980), konomische Analyse von Eigentumsrechten - Der Beitrag der Economics
of Property Rights zur Theorie der Institutionen (Economic Analysis of Property Rights - The
Contribution of the Property Rights Approach to the Theory of Institutions), Frankfurt am Main,
Peter D. Lang, 185 p.
Bund, Dorothee (1984), Die konomische Theorie der Verfassung (The Economic Theory of the
Constitution), Baden-Baden, Nomos, 96 p.
Burow, Patrick (1993), Einfhrung in die konomische Analyse des Rechts (An Introduction into Law
and Economics), 1 Juristische Schulung, 8-12.
Buttler, Friedrich and Walwei, U. (1990), Effizienzwirkungen des Kndigungsschutzes (Impacts of
Protection against Dismissal on Efficiency), 23(3) MittAB, 386-393.
Dorndorf, Eberhard (1979), Freie Arbeitsplatzwahl und Recht am Arbeitsergebnis. Zur rechtlichen
Bedeutung des Konflikts zwischen Arbeitsmobilitt und Aneignungsfhigkeit des
Arbeitsprodukts (Free Choice of Employment and the Property Rights on the Output), Frankfurt,
Metzner-Verlag.
Dorndorf, Eberhard (1986), Kreditsicherungsrecht und Wirtschaftsordnung. Zur materiell- und
konkursrechtlichen Dogmatik der Mobiliarsicherungsrechte (Security Law and Economic
Constitution), Heidelberg, Mller Juristischer Verlag.
Dorndorf, Eberhard (1989), Arbeitsmarkttheorie und Arbeitsrechtswissenschaft, Analoge Probleme
und Diskussionsschwerpunkte im Hinblick auf die Funktionsfhigkeit der Arbeitsmrkte (Theory
of Labor Markets and Jurisprudence), in X. (ed.), Whrungsreform und Soziale Marktwirtschaft,
Arbeitstagung des Vereins fr Socialpolitik in Freiburg 1988, Berlin, Duncker and Humblot.
Dorndorf, Eberhard (1992a), Mehr Individualvertragsfreiheit im Arbeitsrecht? (More Freedom for
Individual Employment Contracts?), in Dubler, Wolfgang, Bobke, Manfred and Kehrmann, Karl
(eds), Festschrift fr Albert Gnade, Kln, Bund-Verlag.
Dorndorf, Eberhard (1992b), konomische Analyse des Rechts und Betriebsverfassungsrecht (Law
and Economics and the German Betriebsverfassungsgesetz), 75 Kritische Vierteljahresschrift
fr Gesetzgebung und Rechtswissenschaft, 416-432.
Dorndorf, Eberhard (1995), Modelle des Rechtssystems in der konomischen Analyse des Rechts
(Models of the Legal System in Law and Economics), in X. (ed.), konomie und Gesellschaft.
Jahrbuch 11, Markt, Norm und Moral, Frankfurt/New York, 127-159.
Dorndorf, Eberhard and Frank, Jrgen (1985), Reform des Rechts der Mobiliarsicherheiten. Unter
besonderer Bercksichtigung der knomischen Analyse der Sicherungsrechte (Economic Analysis
of Security Law), Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftsrecht, 65-84.
172 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Dorndorf, Eberhard, Brandes, Wolfgang and Buttler, Friedrich (1991), Grenzen der
Kndigungsfreiheit - Kndigungsschutz zwischen Stabilitt und Flexibilitt (Limits of the Right
to Terminate Employment Contracts), in Semlinger, K. (ed.), Flexibilitt des Arbeitsmarktes,
Interessen, Wirkungen, Perspektiven, Frankfurt/Main und New York, Campus-Verlag.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1973), Zum Problem der Angemessenen Barabfindung bei Zwangsweise
Ausscheidenden Anteilseignern (The problem of an adequate lump-sum compensation for
shareholders who are frozen out), 18 Arbeitgeber, 357-365.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1979a), Begrenzte Haftung, Glubigerrisiko und Gesellschafterdarlehen - Zur
Vorschrift des 32a eines neuen GmbHG (Limited liability, creditors risk, and proprietors loans
- Comments to 32a of a new GmbHG), in Heigl, A. and Uecker, P. (eds),
Betriebswirtschaftslehre und Recht, Wiesbaden, Gabler.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1979b), Bilanzielle berschuldungsmessung - Zur Interpretation der Vorschriften
von 92(2) AktG und 64(1) GmbHG (Measurement of overindebtedness - Interpretation of
92(2) AktG and 64(1) GmbHG), Zeitschrift fr Unternehmens- und Gesellschaftsrecht,
553-582.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1981a), Zum Problem der Auslsung insolvenzrechtlicher Verfahren (The
Problem of Triggering Bankruptcy Proceedings), 51 ZfB, 235-257.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1981b), Verschuldung, Konkursrisiko, Kreditvertrge und Marktwert von
Aktiengesellschaften (Debt Financing, Bankruptcy Risk, Credit Agreements and the Market Value
of Stock Corporations), in Ehrlicher, W. and Krmmel, H.-J. (eds), Kredit und Kapital, Berlin,
287-319.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1983), Kreditvertrge, Mobiliarsicherheiten und Vorschlge zu ihrer Reform im
Konkursrecht (Credit Agreements, Personal Securities and Suggestions for a Reform of Bankruptcy
Law), 53 ZfB, 328-349.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1984a), Reorganisation und Glubigeransprche (Reorganization and creditors
claims), 44(3) DBW, 371-391.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1984b), Mobiliarsicherheiten, Kreditvertrge und Insolvenzrecht
(Collateralization of Debt, Credit Agreements and Bankruptcy Law), in Neumann, M. (ed.),
Ansprache, Eigentums- und Verfgungsrechte, Berlin, Duncker and Humblot, 681-704.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1986a), Was kann der Tatbestand der berschuldung leisten? (Overindebtedness
as a Trigger of Insolvency Proceedings), 38 ZfbF, 207-234.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1986b), Zum Problem der wirtschaftlichen Vertretbarkeit von Sozialplnen
(The Problem of Economic Feasibility of Social Compensation Plans), 39 Recht der Arbeit,
115-120.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1987a), konomische Analyse der Rechtsprechung des BGH zur
Sittenwidrigkeit von Sanierungskrediten (Economic Analysis of the Jurisprudence of the Bund),
in X (ed.), Kapitalmarkt und Finanzierung, Jahrestagung des Vereins fr Socialpolitik in
Mnchen, 379-397.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1987b), Kreditsicherheiten und Insolvenzverfahren (Collateralized Debt and
Insolvency Proceedings), 8 Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftsrecht, 205-217.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1987c), Unternehmen und Insolvenz - Zur effizienten Gestaltung des
Kreditisicherungs- und Insolvenzrechts (Entrepreneurship and Insolvency - On the Efficient Shape
of Safeguarding of Credits Law and Insolvency Law), Wiesbaden, Gabler, 424 p.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 173
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1988), Zum Verhltnis von Markt und Regulierung in einem neuen
Insolvenzrecht - Besprechung des Ersten Berichts der Kommission fr Insolvenzrecht (The Relation
of Market and Regulation in the new Bankruptcy Law - Discussion of the first report by the
Kommission fr Insolvenzrecht), 1 DBW, 3-25.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1989), Insolvenzrecht als Versuch marktkonformer Gestaltung von
Verwertungsentscheidungen und Verteilungsregeln (Bankruptcy Law as an Attempt to Organize
Insolvency Proceedings in Line with Market Rules), 10 Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftsrecht, 341-351.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1992a), Insolvenzrechtsreform, Reformkonzeptionen und Aktueller Stand
(Reform of the Bankruptcy Law, Concepts of Reform and State of the Art), 52 DBW, 161-183.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1992b), Mobiliargesicherte Glubiger, Verfahrensbeitrag im Insolvenzverfahren
und Kreditkonditionen (Secured Creditors, Contributions to Bankruptcy Proceedings and Credit
Terms), 46 WM, 1136-1144.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1993), Soll das Insolvenzrecht eine Reorganisation zulassen? (Should
Bankruptcy Law allow Reorganization?), in Gerke, W. (ed.), Planwirtschaft am Ende -
Marktwirtschaft in der Krise? Festschrift fr Wolfram Engels, Stuttgart, 109-137.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1994a), Kapitalerhaltungsrecht, berschuldung und Konsistenz - Besprechung
der berschuldungs-Definition in BGH WM 1992, 1650 (Capital Maintenance, Overindebtedness
and Consistency - Discussion of the Statutory Definition of Overindebtedness by the German
Supreme Court), 48 WM, 1737-1746.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1994b), berschuldung, Zur Konstruktion eines Insolvenztatbestandes im
Spannungsfeld von Kapitalerhaltungsrecht und Kreditmarkt (Overindebtedness, Construction of
an Insolvency Trigger Given the Constraints of Capital Maintenance and Credit Markets), in
Ballwieser, W., Bcking, H.-J., Drukarczyk, J. And Schmidt, R.H. (eds), Bilanzrecht und
Kapitalmarkt. Festschrift fr Adolf Moxter, Dsseldorf, 1231-1258.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1995a), Verwertungsformen und Kosten der Insolvenz (Asset Use and
Bankruptcy Costs), 1 BFuP, 40-58.
Drukarczyk, Jochen (1995b), Gesellschafterdarlehen, Rechtsprechungsgrundstze des BGH und 32a
GmbHG - Einige kritische Anmerkungen (Proprietors Loans, Principles of Jurisdiction of the
German Supreme Court and 32a GmbHG - Critical comments), in Elschen, R., Siegel, Th. and
Wagner, F.W. (eds), Unternehmenstheorie und Besteuerung. Festschrift fr Dieter Schneider,
Wiesbaden, Gabler, 173-202.
Drukarczyk, Jochen and Rieger, Reinhard (1986), Zu den Entscheidungswirkungen von 613a BGB
vor und nach Insolvenz (Consequences of 613a BGB Before and After Insolvency), 2 KTS,
209-242.
Drukarczyk, Jochen, Duttle, Josef and Rieger, Reinhard (1985), Mobiliarsicherheiten - Arten,
Verbreitung,Wirksamkeit (Firms and Collateralization of Debt - Types and Effectiveness), in X.
(ed.), Rechtstatsachenforschung, Kln, Bundesministerium der Justiz.
Duttle, Josef (1986), konomische Analyse dinglicher Sicherheiten - Die Reform der
Mobiliarsicherheiten und Probleme ihrer Behandlung in insolvenzrechtlichen Verfahren
(Economic Analysis of Collateral Securities - The Reform of Personal Securities and Problems of
their Treatment in Bankruptcy Proceedings), Dissertation, Marchal und Matzenbacher,
Wissenschaftsverlag, Krefeld, 1986.
174 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Eger, Thomas (1989), Einfhrung in die konomische Analyse des Rechts (Introduction to the
Economic Analysis of Law), in Nagel, B. (ed.), Wirtschaftsrecht II, Mnchen, Oldenborg, 18-35.
Eger, Thomas (1991a), Vernderungen von Rechtsnormen im Systemvergleich. Eine konomische
Analyse (Changes of Legal Norms in Different Economic Systems. An Economic Analysis), in
Wagener, H.-J. (ed.), Anpassung durch Wandel. Evolution und Transformation von
Wirtschaftssystemen. Schriften des Vereins fr Socialpolitik, Berlin, Duncker and Humblot,
81-99.
Eger, Thomas (1991a), Kommentar (Comment on Finsinger and von Randow, Neue Akivitt), in Ott,
Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin, Springer,
109-114.
Eger, Thomas (1992), Eine konomische Analyse der Zulieferbeziehungen in der Automobilindustrie
(An Economic Analysis of the Relations between Suppliers and Manufacturers in Automotive
Industry), in Nagel, Bernhard, EG-Wettbewerbsrecht und Zulieferbeziehungen in der
Automobilindustrie, Gutachten im Auftrag der EG-Kommission, Generaldirektion Wettbewerb
(IV), Brussel, 1-35.
Eger, Thomas (1994), Kommentar zu Helmut Khler, Erweiterung des gewerblichen Rechtsschutzes
durch UWG-Normen (Comment on Helmut Khler, Extension of Legal Protection of Industrial
Property by UWG-norms), in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), Okonomische Analyse
der rechtlichen Organisation von Innovationen, Tbingen, Mohr, 270-280.
Eger, Thomas (1995a), Wieviel Normierung braucht der Markt? konomische Aspekte der
Vertragsfreiheit (How Many Norms are Necessary for the Market to Operate? Economic Aspects
of Freedom of Contract), in X. (ed.), konomie und Gesellschaft. Jahrbuch 11, Markt, Norm
und Moral, Frankfurt/New York, 45-88.
Eger, Thomas (1995b), Eine konomische Analyse von Langzeitvertrgen (An Economic Analysis
of Long-Term-Contracts), Marburg, Metropolis, 263 p.
Eger, Thomas (1996a), Die Evolution von Recht als Proze der Selbstorganisation (The Evolution of
Law as a Process of Self-organization), in Priddat, B.P. and Wegner, G. (eds), Zwischen
Institution und Evolution. Neue Anstze in der konomischen Theorie, Marburg, Metropolis,
211-244.
Eger, Thomas (1996b), Mglichkeiten und Grenzen des Reputationsmechanismus (Possibilities and
Constraints of Reputation Mechanism), Wirtschaftspraxis, Verwaltungspraxis,
Wirtschaftswissenschaften, 1-10.
Eger, Thomas and Weise, Peter (1990a), Innovation, Imitation und Patentrecht im Systemvergleich
(Innovation, Imitation, and Patent Law in Different Economic Systems), in Gramatzki, H.-E.,
Klinger, F. and Nutzinger, H.G. (eds), Wissenschaft, Technik und Arbeit, Innovationen in Ost und
West, Kassel, VWL-inform, 107-133.
Eger, Thomas and Weise, Peter (1990b), Normen als gesellschaftliche Ordner (Norms as Social
Co-ordination Parameters), in X. (ed.), konomie und Gesellschaft, Jahrbuch 8, Individuelles
Verhalten und kollektive Phnomene, Frankfurt/New York, 65-111.
Eger, Thomas and Weise, Peter (1995), Die Evolution von Normen aus Unordnung, Ein synergetisches
Modell (The Evolution of Norms out of Disorder, Synergetic Model), in X. (ed.), konomie und
Gesellschaft. Jahrbuch 11, Markt, Norm und Moral, Frankfurt/New York, 192-209.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 175
Eger, Thomas, Nagel, Bernhard and Weise, Peter (1991), Effizienz und Menschenwrde - Ein
Gegensatz? (Efficiency and Human Dignity - An Opposition?), in Ott, Claus and Schfer,
Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin, Springer, 18-34.
Eger, Thomas, Nutzinger, Hans G. and Weise, Peter (1993), Eine konomische Analyse der
mitbestimmten Unternehmung (An Economic Analysis of Codetermined Enterprise), in Ott, C. and
Schfer, H.-B. (eds), konomische Analyse des Unternehmensrechts, Heidelberg, Physica,
78-116.
Eggerstedt, Harald (1987), Wettbewerb and Regulierung auf Versicherungsmarkten (Competition and
Regulation in Insurance Markets), 107 Zeitschrift fr Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften,
397-416.
Eggerstedt, Harald (1988), Uber Regulierung und Deregulierung von Versicherungsmarkten. Eine
Replik (On Regulation and Deregulation of Insurance Markets. A Reply), 58 Zeitschrift fr
Betriebswirtschaft, 704-707.
Eickhof, Norbert (1986), Versorgungswirtschaft und Wettbewerbsordnung (Public Utilities and the
Competitive System), in Eucken, Walter and Bohm, Franz (eds), Ordo: Jahrbuch fur die
Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, Stuttgart, Gustav Fischer, 201-218.
Eidenmller, Horst (1993), konomische Effizienzkonzepte in der Rechtsanwendung (The Use of
Efficiency Concepts in Adjudication), in Breidenbach, S., Grundmann, S., Mlbert, P. and Singer,
R. (eds), Jahrbuch Junger Zivilrechtswissenschaftler 1992, Rechtsfortbildung jenseits
klassischer Methodik - Privatautonomie zwischen Status und Kontrakt - Privatrecht und Europa
1992, Stuttgart et al., Boorberg, 11-28.
Eidenmller, Horst (1995a), Effizienz als Rechtsprinzip, Mglichkeiten und Grenzen der
konomischen Analyse des Rechts (Efficiency as a Legal Principle - Possibilities and Limitations
of the Economic Analysis of Law), Tbingen, Mohr/Siebeck.
Eidenmller, Horst (1995b), Neuverhandlungspflichten bei Wegfall der Geschftsgrundlage
(Renegotiation Duties Following a Fundamental Change of Circumstances), 16 Zeitschrift fr
Wirtschaftsrecht, 1063-1071.
Eidenmller, Horst (1995c), Marktwirtschaft, Privatrecht und Verteilungsgerechtigkeit (Market
Economy, Private Law and Distributive Justice), in Pies, I. and Leschke, M. (ed.), John Rawls
politischer Liberalismus, Tbingen, Mohr/Siebeck, 123-127.
Eidenmller, Horst (1996a), Die Banken im Gefangenendilemma, Kooperationspflichten und
Akkordstrungsverbot im Sanierungsrecht (The Banks in a Prisoners Dilemma, Duties to
Cooperate in Bankrupty Workouts), 160 Zeitschrift fr das gesamte Handels- und
Wirtschaftsrecht, 343-373.
Eidenmller, Horst (1996b), Der Insolvenzplan als Vertrag (The Insolvency Plan as a Contract), in
Schenk, Karl-Ernst, Schmidtchen, Dieter and Streit, Manfred E. (eds), Vom Hoheitsstaat zum
Konsensualstaat, Neue Formen der Kooperation zwischen Staat und Privaten Jahrbuch fr
Neue Politische konomie 15, Tbingen, Mohr, 164-192.
Eidenmller, Horst (1997a), konomische und spieltheoretische Grundlagen von
Verhandlung/Mediation (Economic and Game Theoretic Foundations of Negotiation and
Mediation), in Breidenbach, S. and. Henssler, M. (ed.), Mediation fr Juristen,
Konfliktbehandlung ohne gerichtliche Entscheidung, Kln, Otto Schmidt.
Eidenmller, Horst (1997b), Insolvenzbewltigung durch Reorganisation (Reorganization as a Mode
of Coping with Insolvency), in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (ed.), 5. Travemnder
Symposium zur konomischen Analyse des Rechts, Tbingen, Mohr/Siebeck.
176 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Gotthold, Jrgen (1981), Neuere Entwicklungen der Wettbewerbstheorie: Kritische Bemerkungen zur
neo-liberalen Theorie der Wettbewerbspolitik (New Developments in Competition Theory: Critical
Remarks on the Neo-Liberal Theory of Competition Policy), 145 Zeitschrift fr das gesamte
Handels- und Wirtschaftsrecht, 286-340.
Greipel, E. and Taeger, U. (1981), Auswirkungen des Patentschutzes und der Lizenz (Effects of Patent
Protection and License Practice Activity on Competition in Specific Areas of Economic Activity
with Special Reference to the Market Position of Small and Middle Size Companies), Gutachten
erstellt fr das Bundeswirtschaftsministeriu), Gutachten erstellt fr das
Bundeswirtschaftsministerium.
Grossekettler, Heinz (1978), Der Fall Deutsche SB-Kauf kontra adidas. Volkswirtschaftliche
Analyse einer Liefervereinigung (Economic Analysis of a Supply Relation), 9 Wettbewerb in
Recht und Praxis, 619-634.
Grossekettler, Heinz (1981), Die Gesamtwirtschaftliche Problematik Vertraglicher Vertriebssysteme
(The Economic Impact of Contractual Supply Systems), in Ahlert, D. (ed.), Vertragliche
Vertriebssysteme Zwischen Industrie und Handel, Grundzge einer Betriebswirtschaftlichen,
Rechtlichen und Volkswirtschaftlichen Beurteilung, Wiesbaden, Gabler, 225-314.
Grossekettler, Heinz (1984), Verwaltungsstrukturpolitik (Public Administration Structure Policy),
in Ewers, H.-J. and Schuster (ed.), Probleme der Ordnungs- und Strukturpolitik, Gttingen,
16-51.
Grossekettler, Heinz (1986), Options- und Grenzkostenpreise fr Kollektivgter unterschiedlicher Art
und Ordnung. Ein Beitrag zu den Bereitstellungs- und Finanzierungsregeln fr ffentliche
Leistungen (Option Pricing and Marginal Prices for Collective Goods), 43(2) Finanzarchiv,
211-253.
Grossekettler, Heinz (1989), Deregulierung und Privatisierung. Erscheinungsformen,
Legitimationskriterien und politische Verhaltenstendenzen (Deregulation and Privatization),
18(10) Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Studium, 437-445.
Grossekettler, Heinz (1991a), Zur theoretischen Integration der Wettbewerbs- und Finanzpolitik in die
Konzeption des konomischen Liberalismus (On the Integration of Competition Policy and Public
Finance into the Economic Liberalism), 10 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, 103-144.
Grossekettler, Heinz (1991b), Die Versorgung mit Kollektivgtern als ordnungspolitisches Problem
(Public Goods as a Problem of Constitutional Economics), 42 Ordo, 69-89.
Grossekettler, Heinz (1991c), Deregulierung, Entbrokratisierung und Privatisierung (Deregulation,
Debureaucratization, and Privatization), 2 Wirtschafts- und Umweltrecht, 303-310.
Grossekettler, Heinz (1992), Wettbewerb Soweit wie Mglich, Planung Soweit wie Ntig. ber
Voraussetzungen und Entwicklungsmglichkeiten der Schillerschen Beweislastregel (Competition
as far as Possible, Planning as far as Necessary), 73 Schriften der Gesellschaft zur Frderung
der Westflischen Wilhelms-Universitt Mnster, 18-36.
Grossekettler, Heinz (1995), konomische Analyse der interkommunalen Kooperation (Economic
Analysis of Intermunicipal Cooperation), Arbeitspapiere des Instituts fr Genossenschaftswesen
der Universitt Mnster, No. 5, 1995.
Grossekettler, Heinz (1996), Kommentar zu, Klaus-Werner Schatz, Reform von Planungs- und
Genehmigungsverfahren (Comment on, Klaus-Werner Schatz, Reform of Public Planning and
Approval Processes), 15 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, 31-37.
180 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Holler, Manfred J. (1984a), Moral, Markt und Norm. Thesen zur konomischen Theoriebildung
(Morals, Market, and Norms. Theses on the Creation of Economic Theories), in Holler, Manfred
J. (ed.), Homo Oeconomicus 2, Mnchen, Leudemann, 512-558.
Holler, Manfred J. (1984b), Norm, Normsetzung und Wissenschaft (Norms, Norm Setting, and
Science), 39 Universitas, 1145-1152.
Holler, Manfred J. (1989a), Ethik, konomie, Arbeit und der Triumph der Medizin (Ethics,
Economics, Labor, and the Victory of Medicine), in Wieland, K. (ed.), Homo Oeconomicus 5,
Mnchen, Accedo, 41-63.
Holler, Manfred J. (1989b), Komplexe Entscheidungen in Sozialen Institutionen (Complex Decisions
in Social Institutions), in Boettcher, Erik, Herder-Dorneich, Philipp and Schenk, Karl-Ernst (eds),
Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, Tbingen, Mohr, 219-228.
Holler, Manfred J. (1996), Die Rationalitt Strategischer Normierung in Europa (The Rationality of
Strategic Standardization in Europe), in Schenk, Karl-Ernst, Schmidtchen, Dieter and Streit,
Manfred E. (eds), Vom Hoheitsstaat zum Konsensualstaat, Neue Formen der Kooperation
zwischen Staat und Privaten Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie 15, Tbingen, Mohr,
137-153.
Holler, P. (1979), Probleme der Utilitaristischen Strafrechtfertigung (Problems of Utilitarian Criminal
Law Making), Zeitschrift fr die Gesamte Strafrechtswissenschaften, 45-95.
Hoppmann, Erich (1966), Das Konzept der optimalen Wettbewerbsintensitt (The Concept of Optimal
Competition Intensity), 180 Jahrbuch fr Nationalkonomie und Statistik, 286-323.
Hoppmann, Erich (1967a), Wettbewerb als Norm der Wettbewerbspolitik (Competition as Norm for
Competition Policy), 18 Ordo: Jahrbuch fr die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft,
77-94.
Hoppmann, Erich (1967b), Die Funktionsfhigkeit des Wettbewerbs: Bemerkungen zu Kantzenbachs
Erwiderung (The Functionality of Competition: Remarks on Kantzenbachs Reaction), 181
Jahrbuch fr Nationalkonomie und Statistik, 251-264.
Hoppmann, Erich (1968), Zum Problem einer Wirtschaftpolitischen praktikablen Definition des
Wettbewerbs (On the Problem of an Economic and Practical Defin), in Schneider, H.K. (ed.),
Grundlagen der Wettbewerbspolitik, Berlin, 9-49.
Hoppmann, Erich (1970), Neue Wettbewerbspolitik: Vom Wettbewerb zur staatlichen
Mikro-Steuerung: Bemerkungen zu einem neuen Leitbild der Wettbewerbspolitik (New
Competition Policy: From Competition to Govern), 184 Jahrbuch fr Nationalkonomie und
Statistik, 397-416.
Hoppmann, Erich (1988), Wirtschaftsordnung und Wettbewerb (Economic Order and Competition),
Baden-Baden, Nomos, 566 p.
Horn, Norbert (1976), Zur konomischen Rationalitt des Privatrechts. Die privatrechts theoretische
Verwertbarkeit der Economics Analysis of Law (The Economic Rationality of Private Law. On
the), 176 Archiv fr die Civilistische Praxis, 307-333.
Horst, Peter M. (1987), Kapitalanlegerschutz. Haftung bei Emissionen und Vertrieb von
Kapitalanlagen. Eine Juristische und konomische Analyse, Schriftenreihe Law and
Economics, Bd. 2 (Protection of Capital Investors), Mnchen.
184 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Kantzenbach, Erhard (1984), Zehn Jahre Monopolkommission (Ten Years Monopoly Commission),
34 Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 297-301.
Kantzenbach, Erhard (1985), Mehr Wettbewerb im Rundfunk? (More Competition in Broadcasting?),
in Lder, K. (ed.), Rundfunk im Umbruch, Berlin, 161-167.
Kantzenbach, Erhard (1987), Die Vorschlge der Monopolkommission (The Proposals of the
Monopoly Commission), in Rper, B. (ed.), Wettbewerb im Medienbereich Schriften des Vereins
fr Socialpolitik N.F. 162, Berlin, 143-153.
Kantzenbach, Erhard (1988), Zur Anwendbarkeit des Wettbewerbsrechts auf den Rundfunk und zum
Verhltnis von publizistischem und konomischem Wettbewerb (On the Applicability of
Competition Law on Broadcasting and on the Relation of Journalistic and Economic
Competition), in Hoffmann-Riem, Wolfgang (ed.), Materialien zur interdisziplinren
Medienforschung 20, Baden-Baden, 78-83.
Kantzenbach, Erhard (1995), Wettbewerbsrecht und Wettbewerbspolitik in der Europischen Union.
Diskussionsbeitrag zum gleichnamigen Referat von Ernst Joachim Mestmcker (Competition Law
and Competition Policy in the European Union. Comment), in Gerken, Lder (ed.), Europa
zwischen Ordnungswettbewerb und Harmonisierung, Berlin, 213-217.
Kantzenbach, Erhard (1996), Wettbewerbspolitik versus Industriepolitik (Competition Policy vs.
Industrial Policy), in X. (ed.), Maastricht II - Entwicklungschancen und Risiken der EU.
Tagungsband zur Jahresversammlung der Arbeitsgemeinschaft deutscher
wirtschaftswissenschaftlicher Forschungsinstitute Beihefte der Konjunkturpolitik 44, Berlin,
43-47.
Kantzenbach, Erhard and Greiffenberg, G. (1980), Die bertragung des Modells des funktionsfhigen
Wettbewerbs auf die Presse (Transferring the Concept of Functional Competition on the Press),
in Klaue, S. u.a. (eds), Probleme der Pressekonzentration, Baden-Baden, 189-202.
Kantzenbach, Erhard and Kinne, Konstanze (1997), Nationale Zusammenschlukontrolle und
internationale Wettbewerbsfhigkeit von Unternehmen (National Merger Control and International
Competitive Power of Firms), in Kruse, Jrn, Stockmann, Kurt and Vollmer, Lothar (eds),
Wettbewerbspolitik im Spannungsfeld nationaler und internationaler Kartellrechtsordnungen.
Festschrift fr Ingo Schmidt zum 65. Geburtstag, Baden-Baden, Nomos, 67 ff.
Kantzenbach, Erhard and Krger, Reinald (1990), Zur Frage der richtigen Abgrenzung des sachlich
relevanten Markten bei der wettbewerbspolitischen Beurteilung von
Unternehmenszusammenschlssen (On the Question of the Correct Definition of the Relevant
Market at the Judgment of Mergers), 40 Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 472-481.
Kantzenbach, Erhard and Kruse, J. (1989), Kollektive Marktbeherrschung (Collective Market Power),
in Jrgensen, H. And Kantzenbach, E. (eds), Wirtschaftspolitische Studien aus den Instituten fr
Europische Wirtschaftspolitik und fr Industrie- und Gewerbepolitik der Universitt Hamburg
75, Gttingen.
Kantzenbach, Erhard and Otremba, W. (1983), Vertikale Integration und Wettbewerb in der
Minerallindustrie und Petrochemie (Vertical Integration and Competition in the Oil and
Petrochemical Industries), 7 Zeitschrift fr Energiewirtschaft, 74-77.
Kantzenbach, Erhard, Kottmann, Elke and Krger, Reinald (1996), Kollektive Marktbeherrschung.
Neue Industriekonomik und Erfahrungen aus der Europischen Fusionskontrolle,
Verffentlichungen des HWWA-Instituts fr Wirtschaftsforschung Hamburg 28 (Collective
Market Power. New Industrial Economics and Experiences from the European Anti-Merger
Policy), Baden-Baden.
186 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Kaufer, Erich (1966), Kantzenbachs Konzept des funktionsfhigen Wettbewerbs: Ein Kommentar
(Kantenbachs Concept of Functional Competition: A Comment), 179 Jahrbuch fr
Nationalkonomie und Statistik, 481-492.
Kaufer, Erich (1968), Das Konzept der optimalen Wettbewerbsintensitt: Eine Replik (The Concept
of Optimal Competition Intensity: A Reply), 181 Jahrbuch fr Nationalkonomie und Statistik,
242-250.
Kaulmann, Peter (1987), Property rights und Unternehmungstheorie. Stand und Weiterentwicklung
der empirischen Forschung (Property Rights and the Theory of the Firm), 3 Schriftenreihe Law
and Economics.
Kerber, Wolfgang (1992), Innovation, Handlungsrechte und Evolutionrer Marktproze (Innovation,
Property Rights and Evolutionary Market Process), in Witt, Ulrich (ed.), Studien zur
Evolutorischen konomik II, Berlin, 171-195.
Kerber, Wolfgang (1996), Recht als Selektionsumgebung fr evolutorische Wettbewerbsprozesse (Law
as Selection Environment for Evolutionary Competition Processes), in Priddat, B.P. and Wegner,
G. (eds), Zwischen Institution und Evolution. Neue Anstze in der konomischen Theorie,
Marburg, Metropolis, 297-326.
Kilian, W, Picot, Arnold, Neuburger, R., Niggl, J., Scholtes, K.-L. and Seiler, W. (1994), Electronic
Data Interchange (EDI), Aus konomischer und juristischer Sicht, Forschungsbericht zu dem
von der Volkswagen-Stiftung gefrderten Forschungsprojekt ELTRADA (Elektronische
Transaktionen von Dokumenten zwischen Organisationen (Electronic Data Interchange EDI
from the Viewpoint of Economic and Law), Baden-Baden, Nomos.
Kirchner, Christian (1978), konomische Analyse des Rechts, Interdisziplinre Zusammenarbeit von
konomie und Rechtswissenschaft (Economic Analysis of Law and Interdisciplinary Cooperation
of Jurisprudence and Economics), in Assmann, Heinz-Dieter, Kirchner, Christian and Schanze,
Erich (eds), konomische Analyse des Rechts, Kronberg, Athenum, 75-91.
Kirchner, Christian (1980), konomische Analyse des Rechts und Recht der
Wettbewerbsbeschrnkungen (Economic Analysis of Law and Antitrust Law), 144 Zeitschrift
fr das gesamte Handels- und Wirtschaftsrecht, 563-588.
Kirchner, Christian (1984), Ansatze zu einer konomischen Analyse des Konzernrechts (Starting Point
for an Economic Analysis of Large Companies Law), in Boettcher, Erik, Herder- Dorneich,
Philipp and Schenk, Karl-Ernst (eds), Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, Tbingen, Mohr,
223-251.
Kirchner, Christian (1989), Kommentar (Comment on Brggemeier, Die Gefhrdungshaftung der),
in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), Allekationseffizienz in der Rechtsordnung, Berlin,
Springer, 248-253.
Kirchner, Christian (1991a), The Difficult Reception of Law and Economics in Germany, 11
International Review of Law and Economics, 277-292.
Kirchner, Christian (1991b), Comment (on Eger, Nagel and Weise, Effizienz und Menschenwrde),
in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin,
Springer, 35-38.
Kirchner, Christian (1997), Kartellrecht und neue Institutionenkonomik. Interdisziplinre
berlegungen (Antitrust Law and New Institutional Economics. Some Interdisciplinary Ideas),
in Kruse, Jrn, Stockmann, Kurt and Vollmer, Lothar (eds),Wettbewerbspolitik im Spannungsfeld
Nationaler und Internationaler Kartellrechtsordnungen. Festschrift fr Ingo Schmidt zum 65.
Geburtstag, Baden-Baden, Nomos, 33 ff.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 187
Koboldt, Christian and Schmidtchen, Dieter (1991), Copyrights, A und O in Literatur und Musik?
(Copyrights, The Essentials in Literature and Music?), 42 Ordo: Jahrbuch fr die Ordnung von
Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft.
Koboldt, Christian, Leder, Mathias and Schmidtchen, Dieter (1992), konomische Analyse des Rechts
(Law and Economics), 7 Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Studium, 334-342.
Koboldt, Christian, Leder, Mathias and Schmidtchen, Dieter (1995), konomische Analyse des Rechts
(Law and Economics), in Nobert, Berthold (ed.), Allgemeine Wirtschaftstheorie, Mnchen,
355-384.
Koch, Hans-Joachim (1983), Die wirtschaftliche Vertretbarkeit nachtrglicher Anordnungen (The
Economic Justification of Additional Orders), Wirtschaft und Verwaltung, 158-173.
Koch, Harald (1981), Die konomie der Gestaltungsrechte. Mglichkeiten und Grenzen der
konomische Analyse des Rechts am Beispiel von Kndiging und Anfechtung (The Economics
of Dispositive Right. Possibilities), in Bernstein, H., Drobnig, U. and Ktz, H. (eds), Festschrift
fr Konrad Zweigert zum 70. Geburtstag, Tbingen, Mohr, 851-877.
Koch, Lambert T. (1996), Evolutorische Wirtschaftspolitik, Eine elementare Analyse mit
entwicklungspolitischen Beispielen (Evolutionary Economic Policy, An Elementary Analysis with
Examples of Development Policies), Tbingen, Mohr/Siebeck.
Koch, Manfred (1992), Die wirtschaftliche Bettigung der Gemeinden. Ein Beitrag zur
finanzwirtschaftlichen Ordnungspolitik Schriften zur konomischen Analyse des Rechts
(Economic Activities of Local Authorities. A Contribution to the Constitutional Politics of Public
Economics), Berlin, Duncker and Humblot.
Koch, Walter A.S. (1984), Negative Einkommensteuern und Konjunkturpolitik (Negative Income
Taxes and Stabilization Policy), 30 Konjunkturpolitik, 348-373.
Kohl, Helmut (1991), Das Allgemeine Persnlichkeitsrecht als Ausdruck oder Grenze des
Effizienzdenkens im Zivilrecht? (The General Right of Privacy as Expression or Limit To
Efficiency in Private Law?), in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische
Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin, Springer, 41-51.
Kohl, Helmut, Kbler, Friedrich, Walz, W. Rainer and Wstrich, Wolfgang (1974),
Abschreibungsgesellschaften, Kapitalmarkteffizienz und Publizittszwang - Pldoyer fr ein
Vermgensanlagegesetz (Tax Shelter Companies, Efficiency of Capital Markets), 138 Zeitschrift
fr das gesamte Handels- und Wirtschaftsrecht, 1-49.
Khler, Helmut (1980), Vertragsrecht und Property Rights - Theorie, Zur Integration konomischer
Theorien in das Privatrecht (Contract Law and Property Rights Theory - On the Integration of
Economic Theories into Private Law), 144 Zeitschrift fr das gesamte Handels- und
Wirtschaftsrecht, 589-607.
Khler, Helmut (1989), Zur konomischen Analyse der Regeln ber die Geschftsgrundlage (On the
Economic Analysis of the Rules of the Implicit Basis of a Contract), in Ott, Claus and Schfer,
Hans-Bernd (eds), Allokationseffizienz in der Rechtsordnung, Berlin, Springer, 148-162.
Koller, Ingo (1979), Die Risikozurechnung bei Vertragsstrungen in Austauschvertrgen (The Risk
Allocation of Contract Disturbances in Bilateral Contracts), Mnchen, C.H. Beck, 474 p.
Koller, Ingo (1981), Die Verteilung des Scheckflschungsrisikos zwischen Kunde und Bank (The
Division of the False Cheque Risk Between Client and Bank), Neue Juristische Wochenschrift,
2433 ff.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 189
Kruse, J., Stockmann, Kurt and Vollmer, Lothar (eds) (1997), Wettbewerbspolitik im Spannungsfeld
nationaler und internationaler Kartellrechtsordnungen. Festschrift fr Ingo Schmidt zum 65.
Geburtstag, Baden-Baden, Nomos.
Krsselberg, Hans-Gnter (1983), Property Rights-Theorie und Wohlfartskonomik (Property Rights
Theory and Welfare Economics), in Schller, Alfred (ed.), Property Rights und konomische
Theorie, Mnchen, Vahlen, 45-75.
Kbler, Friedrich (1983), Was leistet die Konzeption der Property Rights fr Aktuelle Rechtspolitische
Probleme? (What is the Use of the Conception of Property Rights for Current Political Problems?),
in Neumann, M. (ed.), Ansprache, Eigentums- und Verfgungsrechte, Berlin, Duncker and
Humblot, 105-122.
Kbler, Friedrich (1989), Schluwort: Vergleichende berlegungen zur rechtspraktischen Bedeutung
der konomischen Analyse (Closing Word: Comparitive Considerations on the Meaning of Law
and Economics for Legal Practice), in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds),
Allekationseffizienz in der Rechtsordnung, Berlin, Springer, 293-306.
Kbler, Friedrich (1990), Effizienz als Rechtsprinzip - berlegungen zum Rechtspraktischen Gebrauch
konomischer Argumente (Efficiency as Legal Principle - Considerations for the Legal Practice
Use of Economic Arguments), in Baur, Jrgen F., Hopt, Klaus J. and Mailnder (eds), Festschrift
fr Ernst Steindorff, Berlin, De Gruyter, 687-704.
Kbler, Friedrich, Mendelson, Morris and Mundheim, Robert H. (1990), Die Kosten des Bezugsrechts
- Eine rechtskonomische Analyse des Amerikanischen Erfahrungsmaterials (The Costs of the
Subscription Right - A Legal Economic Analysis of the American Experience), Die
Aktiengesellschaft, 461-475.
Kunz, Harald (1976a), Die konomik Individueller und Organisierter Kriminalitt (The Economics
of Individual and Organized Crime), Kln, Berlin, Bonn, Mnchen, Carl Heymanns Verlag.
Kunz, Harald (1976b), Von einer neuen konomik der Kriminalitt (On a New Economics of Crime),
132 Zeitschrift fr die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft, 282-299.
Kunz, Harald (1976c), Die konomik von Strafverfolgung und Strafvollzug (Economics of
Enforcement and Punishment), 132 Zeitschrift fr die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft, 535-548.
Kunz, Harald (1985a), Marktsystem und Information, Konstitutionelle Unwissenheit als Quelle von
Ordnung (Market System and Information), Tbingen, Mohr/Siebeck.
Kunz, Harald (1985b), Zur Entstehung und Verhaltenswirkung sozialer Normen, mit einigen
Argumenten fr eine konomisch rationale Kriminalpolitik (On the Evolution and the Incentive
Effect of Social Norms, with Some Arguments for an Economic Rational Crime Policy), 68
Monatsschrift fr Kriminologie und Strafsrechtsreform, 202-215.
Kunz, Harald (1987), Recht und konomie (Law and Economics), 39 Arbeitgeber.
Kunz, Harald (1993), Kriminalitt (Crime), in Ramb, B.-T. and Tietzel, M. (ed.), konomische
Verhaltenstheorie, Mnchen, Vahlen.
Kurz, Rudi and Rall, Lothar (1983), Behinderungsmibrauch, Probleme einer ordnungskonformen
Konkretisierung (Abuse of Market Power), Tbingen.
Lampe, Hanes-Eckhard (1979), Wettbewerb. Wettbewerbsbeziehungen. Wettbewerbsintensitt
(Competition. Competition Relations, Competition Intensity), Baden-Baden, Nomos, 317 p.
Leder, Mathias (1992), Der Transaktionskostenansatz - Mglichkeiten und Grenzen (The Transaction
Cost Approach - Possibilities and Boundaries), in Schlieper, Ulrich and Schmidtchen, Dieter (eds),
Makro, Geld und Institutionen, Tbingen, 106-108.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 191
Leder, Mathias (1993), Kommentar zu Rational Choice vs. Adaptive Rule-Following, on the
Behavioral Foundations of the Social Sciences von Victor Vanberg (Comment on Viktor Vanberg,
Rational Choice vs. Adaptive Rule-Following, on the Behavioral Foundations of the Social
Sciences), 12 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, 116-121.
Leder, Mathias (1994), Eingeschrnkt rationales Verhalten, Optimizing versus Satisficing und
regelgebundenes Verhalten (Bounded Rationality, Optimizing versus Satisficing and Rule
Governed Behavior), Discussion Paper der Universitt Witten/Herdecke, 1994.
Leder, Mathias (1996), Kommentar zu Plea-bargaining - der Deal im Strafproze von Claus
Ott/Hans-Bernd Schfer (Comment on Claus Ott and Hans-Bernd Schfer, Plea-bargaining - the
deal in criminal proceedings), 15 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, 132-134.
Leder, Mathias and Schmidtchen, Dieter (1990), Die Produktion von Recht. Ein Literaturaufsatz (The
Production of Law. A Survey), 146 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics,
749-757.
Lehmann, Michael (1980), Die Untersuchungs- und Rgepflicht des Kufers in BGB und HGB.
Rechtsvergleichender berblick - konomische Analyse (The Duty to Examine and Notify a
Defect in the German Civil and Commercial Code. A Comparative Survey - Economic Analysis),
Wertpapiermitteilungen, 1162-1169.
Lehmann, Michael (1981a), Vertragsanbahnung durch Werbung (Contract Preparing through
Promotion), Mnchen, C.H. Beck.
Lehmann, Michael (1981b), Die brgerlich-rechtliche Haftung fr Werbeangaben. Culpa in
contrahendo als Haftungsgrundlage fr Vertragsanbahnende Erklrungen, 36 Der
Betriebs-Berater, 1233-1242.
Lehmann, Michael (1982), konomie, Sozialbiologie - Humanwissenschaften. ber die
Notwendigkeit und Mglichkeit einer Interdisziplinren Grundlagenforschung (Economics, Social
Biology - Human Sciences. About the Necessity and Possibility of an Interdisciplinary
Fundamental Re), Der Betriebs-Berater, 1997-2004.
Lehmann, Michael (1983a), Brgerliches Recht und Handelsrecht - eine juristische und
konomische Analyse ausgewhlter Probleme fr Wirtschaftswissenschaftler und
interdisziplinr interessierte Juristen unter besonderer Bercksichtigung der konomischen
Analyse des Rechts und (Civil Law and Commercial Law - a Legal and Economic Analysis of
Selected Problems for Lawyers with an Economic and Interdisciplinary Interest with a Special
Attention for the Economic Analysis of Law and the Theory of Property Rights), Stuttgart,
Poeschel, 329 p.
Lehmann, Michael (1983b), Eigentum, geistiges Eigentum, gewerbliche Schutzrechte, Property Rights
als Wettbewerbsbeschrnkungen zur Frderung des Wettbewerbs (Property, Intellectual Property,
Commercial Rights of Protection, Property Rights as Restraints of Competition to promote the
Competition), in X (ed.), Gewerblicher Rechtsschutz und Urheberrecht, InternationalerTeil
(Festschrift fr E. Ulmer), 356-362.
Lehmann, Michael (1983c), Patentrecht und Theory der Property Rights, eine konomische und
Juristische Analyse (Patent Law and Property Rights Theory, an Economic and Legal Analysis),
in X (ed.), Festschrift fr R. Franceschelli, Mailand, 35-51.
Lehmann, Michael (1983d), Die missglckte Probefahrt. Vertragsrecht, Quasivertragsrecht,
Deliktrecht. konomische Analyse des Rechts (The Failed Excursion. Contract Law,
Quasi-Contract Law Economic Analysis of Law), in Walz, W. Rainer and Rascher-Friesenhausen,
192 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Hein (eds), Sozialwissenschaften im Zivilrecht: Flle und Lsungen in Ausbild und Prfung,
Neuwied und Darmstadt, Luchterhand, 35-51.
Lehmann, Michael (1983e), Buergerliches Recht und Handelsrecht - eine Juristische und
konomische Analyse, Stuttgart, Poeschel.
Lehmann, Michael (1984), Theorie der Property Rights und Schutz des geistigen und gewerblichen
Eigentums - Wettbewerbsbeschrnkungen zur Frderung des Wettbewerbs (Property Rights Theory
and the Protection of Intellectual Property), in X (ed.), Ansprche, Eigentums- und
Verfgungsrechte, Berlin, Duncker and Humblot, 519-535.
Lehmann, Michael (1986a), Evolution in Biologie, konomie und Jurisprudenz (Evolution in Biology,
Economics and Jurisprudence), 17 Rechtstheorie, 463-477.
Lehmann, Michael (1986b), Das Privileg der beschrnkten Haftung und der Durchgriff im
Gesellschafts- und Konzernrecht. Eine Juristische und konomische Analyse (The Privilege of
Limited Liability and the Peircing of the Corporate Veil in Association and Trust Law), 3
Zeitschrift fr Unternehmens- und Gesellschaftsrecht, 345-370.
Lehmann, Michael (1987), Die UWG-Neuregelungen 1987 - Erluterungen und Kritik (The New
UWG Unfair Competition Rules - Explanations and Critique),89 Gewerblicher Rechtsschutz und
Urheberrecht, 199-214.
Lehmann, Michael (1988a), Verbraucherschutz und Schutz des Schwcheren im Zivilrecht. Eine
juristische und konomische Analyse (Consumer Protection and Protection of the Weaker Party
by the Private Law), in Finsinger and Simon (eds), Recht und Risiko. Juristische und
konomische Analysen, Mnchen, Florentz, 365-389.
Lehmann, Michael (1988b), Juristisch-konomische Kriterien zur Berechnung des Verletzergewinns
bzw. des entgangenen Gewinns (Legal-Economic Criteria for the Calculation of the Profit of the
Injurer Respectively the Lost Profit), 25 Der Betriebs-Berater, 1680-1687.
Lehmann, Michael (1989), Die Zivilrechtliche Haftung fr Werbeangaben bei der Vertragsanbahnung
als Problem der Allokationseffizienz (Civil Liability for Advertising as a Problem of Allocative
Efficiency), in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), Allekationseffizienz in der
Rechtsordnung, Berlin, Springer, 169-184.
Lehmann, Michael (1990a), Just in time: Handels- und ABG- rechtliche Probleme (Just in Time:
Problems in the Law of Commerce and of Unfair Contract Terms), 27 Der Betriebs-Berater,
1849-1855.
Lehmann, Michael (1990b), Das Prinzip Wettbewerb (The Principle of Competition), 2
Juristenzeitung, 61-67.
Lehmann, Michael (1991), Umwelthaftungsrecht dient der Internalisierung negativer Extemalitten,
Kommentar (Environmental Liability Law is to Internalize Negative Externalities. A Comment),
in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin,
Springer, 290-294.
Lehmann, Michael (1992a), Schranken der beschrnkten Haftung. Zur konomischen Legitimation
des Durchgriffs bei der GmbH (Limits of Limited Liability), 4 GmbH-Recht, 200-206.
Lehmann, Michael (1992b), Umwelthaftungsrecht. Ein Beitrag zur Internalisierung von negativen
Externen Effekten (Environmental Liability Law), in Schulz (ed.), kologie und Recht, Kln,
Berlin, Bonn, Mnchen, Carl Heymanns Verlag, 81-89.
Lehmann, Michael (1993), Das Prinzip Wettbewerb. Ein gemeinsames Gesetz der Evolution fr
Biologie, konomie und Wirtschaftsrecht (The Competition Principle. A Common Law of
Evolution for Biology. Economics and Commercial Law), in McGuire, Michl T. (ed.), Der
Faktor Mensch im neuen Europa, Luchterhand, Neuwied et al., 241-258.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 193
Leidig, Guido (1979), Dominante Werbung. Ziele, Wirkungen, rechtliche Gestaltung (Advertising.
Objectives, Effects, Legal Aspects), Frankfurt/M., Bern, Cirencester.
Leidig, Guido (1984a), Aspekte einer kologisch-konomischen Rechtswissenschaft (Aspects of an
Ecologic-Economic Jurisprudence), 39(7) Universitas, 759-765.
Leidig, Guido (1984b), kologisch-konomische Rechtswissenschaft (Ecologic-Economic
Jurisprudence), Frankfurt/M., Bern, New York.
Leidig, Guido (1991), Perspektiven einer kologisch-konomischen Rechtswissenschaft (Perspectives
of an Ecologic-Economic Oriented Jurisprudence), in Voigt, R. (ed.), Das Recht und seine
Wissenschaft 3. ed., Siegen, 105-122.
Leschke, Martin (1993), konomische Verfassungstheorie und Demokratie (Constitutional
Economics and Democracy), Berlin, Duncker and Humblot.
Leschke, Martin (1995a), Konstitutionelle Demokratie und die Europische Union (Constitutional
Democracy and the European Union), 4 List Forum, 394-412.
Leschke, Martin (1995b), Neue Richtlinien fr Europa. Das Urteil des Bundesverfassungsgerichts zum
Vertrag von Maastricht aus Sicht der Konstitutionellen konomik (New Restrictions in Europe,
An Analysis of the Maastricht Judgement of the German Bundesverfassungsgericht from the View
of Constitutional Economics), 44(1) Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftspolitik, 3-28.
Leschke, Martin (1996), Zur institutionellen Ausgestaltung der Europischen Union (How Should the
Institutional Structure of the European Union be Designed?), in Streit, M.E. and Voigt, St. (ed.),
Europa reformieren - konomen und Juristen zur zuknftigen Verfatheit Europas,
Baden-Baden, Nomos, 100-112.
Levmore, Saul and Stuntz, William J. (1991), Rechtsfolgen im Privatrecht und im ffentlichen Recht:
Rechtsvergleichung unter einem Law-and-Economics Blickwinkel (Legal Consequences in Private
and Public Law: Comparative Law from a Law and Economics Viewpoint), in Ott, Claus and
Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin, Springer, 297-314.
Linder, Ludwig (1980), Privatklage und Schadensersatz im Kartellrecht, Eine vergleichende
Untersuchung zum deutschen und amerikanischen Recht (Civil Suit and Damage Compensation
in Antitrust Law, A Comparision of German and American Law), Baden-Baden, Nomos.
Lutter, Marcus and Wahlers, Henning W. (1989), Der Buyout: Amerikanische Flle und die Regeln
des deutschen Rechts (The Buyout: American Cases and the German Rules), 34 Die
Aktiengesellschaft, 1-17.
Magoulas, Georgios (1985), Zur konomischen Analyse des Konsumentenschutzes - unter besonderer
Bercksichtigung Informations- und Risikobezogener Probleme von Konsumen tenmrkten (On
the Economic Analysis of Consumer Protection - With Special Attention for Information and
Risk), in Magoulas, Georgios and Simon, Jrgen (eds), Recht und konomie beim
Konsumentenschutz und Konsumentenkredit, Baden-Baden, Nomos, 23-57.
Magoulas, Georgios (1986), Privatrechtlicher Immissionsschutz, Wucher und konomische Analyses
des Rechts (Civil Law Protection against Harmful Effects on the Environment, Usury and
Economic Analysis), in Simon, Jrgen (ed.), Regulierungsprobleme im Wirtschaftsrecht,
Neuwied und Darmstadt, Luchterhand, 1-24.
Magoulas, Georgios (1989), Verbraucherschutz als Problem Asymmetrischer Informationskosten
(Consumer Protection as a Problem of Asymmetric Information), in Ott, Claus and Schfer,
Hans-Bernd (eds), Allekationseffizienz in der Rechtsordnung, Berlin, Springer, 70-80.
194 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Magoulas, Georgios and Schwartze, Andreas (1986), Das Gesetz ber den Widerruf von
Haustrgeschften und hnlichen Geschften: Eine Rechtliche und konomische Analyse (The
Law Regarding Revocation of Door-to-Door Dealings and Similar Transactions: A Legal and
Economic Analysis), 18(5) Jristische Arbeitsbltter, 225-235.
Magoulas, Georgios and Simon, Jrgen (eds) (1985), Recht und konomie beim Konsumentenschutz
und Konsumentenkredit (Law and Economics of Consumer Protection and C), Baden-Baden,
Nomos, 436 p.
Markert, Kurt (1997), Deutsche Fusionskontrolle im Energeiversorgungsbereich (Merger Control in
the German Public Utilities Sector), in Kruse, Jrn, Stockmann, Kurt and Vollmer, Lothar (eds),
Wettbewerbspolitik im Spannungsfeld nationaler und internationaler Kartellrechtsordnungen.
Festschrift fr Ingo Schmidt zum 65. Geburtstag, Baden-Baden, Nomos, 231 ff.
Meinberg, Volker (1988), Empirische Erkentnissen zum Vollzug des Umweltstrafrechts (Empirical
Insights Concerning the Enforcement of Environmental Criminal Law), 100 Zeitschrift fr die
Gesamte Strafrechtswissenschaften, 112-157.
Meran, Georg (1988), Zur Kontroverse uber die Wettbewerbswirkungen eines Umweltlizenzmarktes
(The Controversy on the Competition on a Market for Environmental Licenses), 108 Zeitschrift
fr Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften, 439-450.
Mestmcker, Ernst-Joachim (1978), Recht und konomisches Gesetz. ber die Grenzen von Staat,
Gesellschaft und Privatautonomie (The Law and Economic Laws), Baden-Baden, Nomos.
Mestmcker, Ernst-Joachim (1988), Fusions Kontrolle im Gemeinsamen Markt zwischen
Wettbewerbspolitik und Industriepolitik (Merger Control in the Common Market Between
Compet), Europarecht, 349-377.
Mestmcker, Ernst-Joachim (ed.) (1993),Recht in der offenen Gesellschaft. Hamburger Beitrge zum
Deutschen, Europischen und Internationalen Wirtschafts- und Medienrecht Wirtschaftsrecht
und Wirtschaftspolitik 125 (Law in an Open Society), Baden-Baden, Nomos.
Meyer, Dirk (1989), Rent Seeking durch Rationalisierungsschutz oder die Wohlfahrtsverluste einer
Kostensenkungssteuer (Rent Seeking through Regulations Protecting Human Capital from
Devaluation Due to Technological Innovation), 35 Konjunkturpolitik, 188-1200.
Mohr, K. and Wehrt, Klaus (1995), Einbau der konomischen Analyse des Rechts in ein Juristisches
Fallgutachten (Implementing the Economic Analysis of Law into a Legal Opinion), 10 JURA,
536-542.
Mschel, Wernhard (1972), Das Wirtschaftsrecht der Banken. Die whrungs-, bankaufsichts-, kartell-
und EWG-rechtliche Sonderstellung der Kreditinstitute (Banking Law), in X. (ed.),Schriftenreihe
Wirtschaftsrecht und Wirtschaftspolitik, Band 29, Frankfurt. Reprinted by now Nomos
Verlagsgesellschaft Baden-Baden
Mschel, Wernhard (1975a), Kreditwirtschaft und Bereichsausnahme nach 102 GWB (Credit
Markets and Areas Exempt from Competition under 102 GWB [German Antitrust Law]), 139
Zeitschrift fr das gesamte Handels- und Wirtschaftsrecht, 347-361.
Mschel, Wernhard (1975b), Bankenrecht und Wirtschaftsordnung (Law of Banking and Economic
Order), BB, 1025-1030.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 195
Mschel, Wernhard (1975c), Rechtsordnung zwischen Plan und Markt. Am Beispiel von
Preiskontrollen nach 22 GWB. Heft 54 der Schriftenreihe Vortrge und Aufstze des Walter
Eucken Instituts (Law between Plan and Market), Tbingen.
Mschel, Wernhard (1978), Wettbewerb im Schnittfeld von Rechtswissenschaft und Nationalkonomie
(Competition at the Crossing of Legal Science and National Economy),
Wirtschaftwissenschaftliche Studien, 351-357.
Mschel, Wernhard (1981a), Neuere Entwicklungen der Wettbewerbstheorie. Kritische Bemerkungen
zu kritischen Bemerkungen (Recent Developments in Competition Theory), 145 Zeitschrift fr
das Gesamte Handels- und Wirtschaftsrecht, 590-598.
Mschel, Wernhard (1981b), Zur wettbewerbstheoretischen Begrndbarkeit von Ausnahmebereichen
(Areas Exempt from Competition and Competition Theory), 32 Ordo, 85-102.
Mschel, Wernhard (1983), Divergierende Entwicklungen im Amerikanischen und Europischen
Kartellrecht (Conflicting Developments in American and European Antitrust Law),
Wirtschaftwissenschaftliche Studien, 603-609.
Mschel, Wernhard (1986a), Effizienz und Wettbewerbspolitik (Efficiency and Policy of
Competition), Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Studium, 341-346.
Mschel, Wernhard (1986b), konomische Kriterien in der Anwendung des Kartellgesetzes (Views
of Economic Evidence in Antitrust Litigation), JA, 525-533.
Mschel, Wernhard (1988), Wettbewerbspolitik aus ordoliberaler Sicht, in Strafrecht,
Unternehmensrecht, Anwaltsrecht. Festschrift fr Gerd Pfeiffer zum Abschied aus dem Amt als
Prsident des Bundesgerichtshofes (Competition Policy from an Ordo-liberal Point of View),
Kln, Berlin, Bonn, Mnchen, Carl Heymanns Verlag.
Mschel, Wernhard (1990), Internationaler Freihandel in Bankdienstleistungen, in Festschrift fr
Ernst Steindorff (International Free Trade in Banking Services), Berlin.
Mschel, Wernhard (1992a), Wettbewerbspolitik vor neuen Herausforderungen, in Ordnung in
Freiheit (Competition Policy Faced by New Challenges), Symposium aus Anla des 100.
Jahrestages des Geburtstages von Walter Eucken am 17. Januar 1991, Tbingen.
Mschel, Wernhard (1992b), EG-Industriepolitik nach Maastricht, in Festschrift fr Rudolf Nirk (EC
Industrial Policy after Maastricht), Mnchen.
Mschel, Wernhard (1993a), Privatisierung als ordnungspolitische Aufgabe, in Festschrift fr
Joachim Gernhuber (Privatization as a Task of Policy), Tbingen.
Mschel, Wernhard (1993b), Privatisierung der Sparkassen. Zu den jngsten Vorschlgen der
Monopolkommission (The Privatization of Savings Banks), WM, 93-99.
Mschel, Wernhard (1993a), Zum Subsidiarittsprinzip im Vertrag von Maastricht (The Principle of
Subsidiarity in the Maastricht-Treaty), in Gerken, L. (ed.), Europa 2000 - Perspektive wohin?
Die europische Integration nach Maastricht, Freiburg, Max-Planck-Institut fr auslndisches
internationales Strafrecht, 93-105.
Mschel, Wernhard (1995), Den Staat an die Kette legen - Gegen die Aushhlung des Wettbewerbs
durch den Staat, Frankfurter Institut - Kleine Handbibliothek - Band 13 (Chaining up the State
- Against the Undermining of Competition by the State), Bad Homburg vdH, 94 p.
Mschel, Wernhard (1996a), Kartellrecht in der Reform, in Festschrift fr Ernst-Joachim
Mestmcker (The Reform of Antitrust Law), Baden-Baden.
Mschel, Wernhard (1996b), Ist die Tarifautonomie noch zeitgem? (Is the German System of
Autonomous Wage Bargaining Still up to Date?), 45 Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftspolitik, 39-48.
196 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Nagel, Bernhard (1988b), Mitbestimmung und Grundgesetz (Worker Participation and the German
Basic Law), Baden-Baden.
Nagel, Bernhard (1989), Wirtschaftsrecht II Eigentum, Delikt, Vertrag (Property, Tort, Contract),
Mnchen.
Nagel, Bernhard (1990), Erosion der Mitbestimmung und EG- Kommissionsentwrfe zur Europa-AG
(Erosion of Worker Participation), Arbeit und Recht, 205-213.
Nagel, Bernhard (1991a), Kommentar (Comment on Wehrt, Die Qualittshaftung des Verkuf), in
Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin,
Springer, 260-264.
Nagel, Bernhard (1991b), Schuldrechtliche Probleme bei Just-in-Time-Lieferbeziehungen - dargestellt
am Beispiel der Automobilindustrie (Problems with Law of Contract in Just-in-Time Delivery
Relations), DB, 319-326.
Nagel, Bernhard (1991c), Der EG-Richtlinienentwurf zum Europischen Betriebsrat (The
EG-Guideline on the European Workers Committee), Arbeit und Recht, 161-172.
Nagel, Bernhard (1992a), EG-Wettbewerbsrecht und Zulieferbeziehungen der Automobilindustrie,
Gutachten im Auftrag der EG-Kommission (EU Competition Law and the Delivery Relations in
the Automobile Industry), Verffentlichungen der Kommission, Luxemburg und Brssel, 1992.
Nagel, Bernhard (1992b), Von der Lex Mercatoria zur Lex Laboris, zur Rechtlichen Bewltigung der
Internationalen Arbeitsbeziehungen (Lex Mercatoria and Lex Laboris. On the Legal Analysis of
International Work Relations), in Dubler, Wolfgang, Bobke, Manfred and Kehrmann, Karl (ed.),
Festschrift fr Albert Gnade, Kln, Bund-Verlag.
Nagel, Bernhard (1992c), Zulieferbeziehungen der Automobilindustrie und Wettbewerbsrecht der EG
(Delivery Relations in the Automobile Industry and the Competition Law of the EG), Wirtschaft
und Wettbewerb, 818-829.
Nagel, Bernhard (1993a), Die Produkt und Umwelthaftung im Verhltnis von Herstellern und
Zulieferern (Product and Environment Liability in the Relation to Suppliers), DB, 2469-2474.
Nagel, Bernhard (1993b), Die Marken der Hersteller von Autoteilen und das Wettbewerbsrecht der
EG (Brands of Automobile Parts and the Competition Law of the EG), Zeitschrift fr
Wirtschaftsrecht, 987-993.
Nagel, Bernhard (1993c), Wirtschaftsrecht I, Grundrechte und Einfhrung in das Brgerliche Recht,
3. Ed. (Basic Rights and an Introduction into the Private Law), Mnchen.
Nagel, Bernhard (1994), Wirtschaftsrecht III (Unternehmens-und Konzernrecht) (Law of Firms and
Conglomerates), Mnchen, Lehrbuch.
Nagel, Bernhard (1995a), Gewhrleistung und Produkthaftung im internationalen Produktionsverbund
(Guarantee and Product Liability in International Cooperations), DB, 2581-2590.
Nagel, Bernhard (1995b), Autonomie, Abhngigkeit und Wettbewerb, rechtliche und konomische
Analyse (Law and Economics of Autonomy, Dependence and Competition), in X. (ed.),konomie
und Gesellschaft. Jahrbuch 11, Markt, Norm und Moral, Frankfurt/New York, 89-126.
Nagel, Bernhard (1996), Wie effizient sind Tarifvertrag und Mitbestimmung? (How Efficient are
Wage Agreements and Worker Participation?), 2 Gewerkschaftliche Monatshefte, 97-111.
Neumeyer, F. (1969), Patent und Beschrnkung des Wettbewerbs (Patent and Limitation of
Competition), 12 Wirtschaft und Recht, 240-251.
198 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (1996), Plea-Bargaining, der Deal im Strafproze
(Plea-Bargaining), in Schenk, Karl-Ernst, Schmidtchen, Dieter, Streit, Manfred E. (eds), Vom
Hoheitsstaat zum Konsensualstaat, Neue Formen der Kooperation zwischen Staat und Privaten
Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie 15, Tbingen, Mohr, 107-126.
Otto, Hans-Jochen (1982), Generalprvention und externe Verhaltenskontrolle, Wandel vom
Sociologischen zum konomischen Paradigma in der Nordamerikanischen Kriminologie?
(General Prevention and External Control of Behavior, Evolution from Sociological to Economic
Paradigm in the North American Criminology?), Freiburg, Max-Planck-Institut fr auslndisches
internationales Strafrecht, 323 p.
Panther, Stephan (1991), Zivilrecht und Umweltschutz (Civil Law and Environmental Protection),
in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin,
Springer, 267-289.
Picot, Arnold and Dietl, Helmut (1993), Neue Institutionenkonomie und Recht (New Institutional
Economics and Law), in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Analyse des
Unternehmensrechts, Beitrge zum 3. Travemnder Symposium zur konomischen Analyse des
Rechts, Heidelberg, Physica Verlag, 306-330.
Pies, Ingo and Leschke, Martin (eds) (1995), konomische Gesellschaftstheorie in der Diskussion,
John Rawls Politischer Liberalismus. Theoretische Grundlagen demokratischer Wirtschafts-
und Gesellschaftspolitik (Economic Theory of Society and John Rawls Political Liberalism),
Tbingen.
Pies, Ingo and Leschke, Martin (ed.) (1996), James Buchanans konstitutionelle konomik (Konzepte
der Gesellschaftstheorie, Bd. 2) (James Buchanans Constitutional Economics), Tbingen, Mohr,
281 p.
Priddat, Birger (1988), Das Geld und die Vernunft. ber John Lockes Versuch einer naturrechtlich
Economics), Frankfurt am Main, Peter D. Lang.
Priddat, Birger (1990), Hegel als konom (Hegel as an Economist), 403 Volkswirtschaftliche
Schriften.
Priddat, Birger (1993a), konomie und Macht. John Locke. Neue Aspekte (Economy and Power. John
Locke. New Aspects), in Gephardt, J. and Mnclker, H. (eds), Brgerschaft und Herrschaft. Zum
verhltnis von Demokratie und Macht im antiken und neuzeitlichen politischen Denken,
Baden-Baden, Nomos.
Priddat, Birger (1993b), Staat (The State), in Homann, K. and Enderle, G. (eds), Lexikon der
Wirtschaftsethik, Freiburg, 1020-1025.
Priddat, Birger (1997), Konstituanten deutscher Politischer konomie. Zur Geschichte der Parafiski
im 19. Jahrhundert (On the Sources of German Political Economics. The Genesis of Parafisci in
the 19th Century), in Tiepelmann, K. and van der Beek, G. (eds), Parafiski Vol. 2, Hamburg.
Prosi, G. (1971), konomische Theorie des Buches. Volkswirtschaftiche Aspekte des Urheber- und
Verlegerschutzes (The Economic Theory of Books, Copyright and Publishers Rights), Dsseldorf.
Rahmsdorf, Detlev W. (1986), Zur Renaissance der Sozialver tragstheorien in den
Wirtschaftswissenschaften und ihrer interdisziplinren Relevanz (The Renaissance of the Social
Contract in Political Economies and their Interdisciplinary Significance), Der Staat, 269-284.
Rahmsdorf, Detlev W. (1987), konomische Analyse des Rechts, Utilitarismus und die klassische
deutsche Philosophie (Economic Analysis of Law, Utilitarianism and the Classical German
Philosophy), 18 Rechtstheorie, 487-501.
200 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Rahmsdorf, Detlev W. and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds) (1988), Ethische Fragen der Wirtschaftspolitik
und des Rechts (Ethical Questions of Political Economics and Law), Berlin,
Dietrich-Reimer-Verlag, 219 p.
Ramb, B.T. and Tietzel, Manfred (eds) (1993), konomische Verhaltenstheorie (Economic Theory
of Behavior), Mnchen.
Ribhegge, Hermann (1994), konomische Theorie des effizienten Vertragsbruchs und die normativen
Grundlagen der konomischen Theorie des Rechts (The Economic Theory of Efficient Breach of
Contracts and the Normative Foundations of the Economic Analysis of Law), 11 Homo
Oeconomicus, 113-141.
Richter, Rudolf (1991a), Institutionenkonomische Aspekte der Theorie der Unternehmung
(Institutional Economics of the Theory of the Firm), in Ordelheide, D., Rudolph, B., Bsselmann,
E. (ed.), Betriebswirtschaftslehre und konomische Theorie, Stuttgart, Poeschel.
Richter, Rudolf (1991b), Bankenregulierung aus der Sicht der Neuen Institutionenkonomik
(Regulation of Banks from the Viewpoint of the New Institutional Economics), in Siebke, J. (ed.),
Finanzintermediation, Bankenregulierung und Finanzmarktintegration, Berlin, Duncker and
Humblot, 43-64.
Richter, Rudolf (1992), Institutionen konomisch analysiert. Zur jngsten Entwicklung auf dem
Gebiete der Wirtschaftstheorie (Economic Analysis of Institutions), in Landeszentralbank im
Saarland (ed.), Wissenschaftliche Hefte, Saarbrcken.
Richter, Rudolf (1993), konomische Theorie des Privateigentums, Thema und Variationen
(Economics of Property Rights), Jahrbuch fr Sozialwissenschaft.
Richter, Rudolf and Furubotn, Eirik G. (1996), Neue Institutionenoekonomik. Eine Einfuehrung und
kritische Wuerdigung (Institutions and Economic Theory - Contributions of the New Institutional
Economics), Tbingen, Mohr/Siebeck.
Rper, Bernd (1982), Die Mi brauchaufsicht vor dem Hintergrund der (The Abuse Aspect as
Background for the Development of a New Competition Theory), Berlin, Humboldt.
Roth, Gnter H. (1986), Zur economic analysis der beschrnk ten Haftung (On the Economic
Analysis of Limited Liability), 3 Zeitschrift fr Unternehmens- und Gesellschaftsrecht,
371-382.
Roth, Gnter H. (1991), Kommentar (Comment on Adams, Eigentum, Kontrolle und beschrn), in
Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin,
Springer, 226-233.
Rowe, Gerard C. (1992), Sachenrechtliche Ersitzungsregeln aus konomischer Sicht (An Economic
Perspective on Limitations of Actions in Property Law), 75 Kritische Vierteljahresschrift der
Gesetzgebung und Rechtswissenschaft, 390-415.
Ruppelt, Hans-Joachim (1989), Der Verordnungsentwurf fr eine europische Fusionskontrolle im
EG-Ministerrat (The Regulation Bill for a European Fusion Control in the EC-Cabinet Council),
39 Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 187-202.
Sadowski, Dieter (1988), Whrt ehrlich am lngsten? Personalpolitik zwischen Arbeitsrecht und
Unternehmenskultur (Is Honesty the Best Policy? Personal Management Between Labor Law and
Corporate Culture), in Budus, Dietrich, u.a. (ed.), Betriebswirtschaftslehre und Theorie der
Verfgungsrechte, Wiesbaden, Gabler, 219-238.
Sadowski, Dieter (1996), Programm und Stand der betriebswirtschaftlichen Rechtsanalyse (Economic
Analysis of Business Law), in Sadowski et al. (ed.), Regulierung und Unternehmenspolitik,
Wiesbaden, Gabler, 1-20.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 201
Schfer, Hans-Bernd and Ott, Claus (1991), konomische Auswirkungen der EG-Insider-Regulierung
in Deutschland (Economic Effects of the EU Insider Regulation), 3 Zeitschrift fr Bankrecht und
Bankwirtschaft, 226 ff.
Schfer, Hans-Bernd and Ott, Claus (1994), Entwicklung und Konstruktion effizienter Normen im
Rechtssystem des deutschen Zivilrechts (Development and Construction of Efficient Norms in the
Legal System of German Private Law), Homo Oeconomicus, 293 ff.
Schfer, Hans-Bernd and Ott, Claus (1995), Lehrbuch der konomischen Analyse des Zivilrechts,
2. Aufl. (Textbook on Economic Analysis of Private Law), Berlin.
Schfer, Hans-Bernd and Rlike, A. (1997), Kosten-Nutzen-Analyse der Rechtssprechung unter
besonderer Bercksichtigung der Vorschlge zur Kostenreduzierung in der Justiz, Handbuch
der auergerichtlichen Konfliktbeilegung (Cost-Benefit Analysis of Jurisdiction and Cost
Reduction),.
Schfer, Hans-Bernd and Struck, Gerhard (1983), Schlammbeseitigung auf der Bundesstrasse.
Geschftsfhrung ohne Auftrag, Deliktsrecht, negatorische Haftung. konomische Analyse des
Rechts (The Case of the Mud Removal at the Federal Highway), in Walz, W. Rainer and
Rascher-Friesenhausen, Hein (eds), Sozialwissenschaften im Zivilrecht: Flle und Lsungen in
Ausbildung und Prfung, Neuwied und Darmstadt, Luchterhand, 119-132.
Schfer, Hans-Bernd and Wehrt, Klaus (1989a), konomische Analyse des Schadensrechts. Ein
berblick (Economic Analysis of Tort Law. A Survey), 34 Hamburger Jahrbuch fr Wirtschaft
und Gesellschaftspolitik, 81-106.
Schfer, Hans-Bernd and Wehrt, Klaus (eds) (1989b),Die konomisierung der Sozialwissenschaften:
Sechs Wortmeldungen (Economics in Social Sciences: Six Contributions), Frankfurt am Main,
Campus Verlag, 182 p.
Schanze, Erich (1977), Anlegerschutz bei Aktienfonds, Das Indexfonds-Konzept (Shareholder
Protection), 22 Die Aktiengesellschaft, 102-107.
Schanze, Erich (1978a), konomische Analyse des Rechts in den U.S.A./Verbindungslinien zur
realistischen Tradition (Economic Analysis of Law in the U.S.A. - Origins a), in Assmann,
Heinz-Dieter, Kirchner, Christian and Schanze, Erich (eds), konomische Analyse des Rechts,
Kronberg, Athenum, 3-19.
Schanze, Erich (1978b), konomische Analyse des Rechts in den USA. Verbindungslinien zur
realistischen Tradition (Economic Analysis of Law in the US. Connections to the Realistic
Tradition), in Assmann, Heinz-Dieter, Kirchner, Christian and Schanze, Erich (eds),konomische
Analyse des Rechts, Kronberg, Athenum, 3-19.
Schanze, Erich (1981), Der Beitrag von Coase zu Rechte und konomie des Unternehmens (Coases
Contribution to Law and Economics of Business Organizations), 137 Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics, 694-701.
Schanze, Erich (1982), Rechtsnorm und konomisches Kalkl (Legal Norm and Economic
Calculus), 138 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 297-312.
Schanze, Erich (1983), Theorie des Unternehmens und konomische Analyse des Rechts (Theory of
the Firm and Economic Analysis of Law), in Boettcher, Erik, Herder-Dorneich, Philipp and
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (eds), Jahrbuch fr neue politische konomie, Tbingen, Mohr, 161-180.
Schanze, Erich (1986a), Investitionsvertrge im internationalen Wirtschaftsrecht (Investment
Contracts in International Economics), Frankfurt a.M., Metzner, 305 p.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 203
Schanze, Erich (1986b), Untemehmensrechtliche Koordination von Staat und Wirtschaft bei
internationalen Gro Projekten in Entwicklungslndern (Corporate Coordination of State and
Economy Concerning Project Investment in Developing Countries), 6 Jahrbuch fr Neue
Politische konomie, 269-287.
Schanze, Erich (1989), Langzeitvertrge im Spannungsfeld von Vertrags-, Gesellschafts-,
Wettbewerbs- und Arbeitsrecht, Symbiotische Bezugs- und Absatzsysteme, Vorlage fr die
Tagung fr Rechtsvergleichung Wrzburg 1989 (Long-Term Contracts between Contract,
Corporation, Competition, and Labor Law), Fachgruppe fr Grundlagenforschung, Arbeitssitzung,
14 Sept 1989.
Schanze, Erich (1991), Stellvertretung und konomische Agentur-Theorie - Probleme und
Wechselbezge (The Law of Agency and Agency Theory - Problems and Relations), in Ott, Claus
and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin, Springer, 60-75.
Schanze, Erich (1993), Rechtswissenschaft und Betriebswirtschaftslehre (Jurisprudence and Business
Administration), in Wittmann, W., Kern, W., Khler, R., Kpper, H.-U., Wysocki, K.v. (ed.),
Handwrterbuch der Betriebswirtschaft, 5. Aufl., Stuttgart, 3760-3774.
Schanze, Erich (1995a), Rechtsvorschriften fr die Produktion (Regulation of Production), in Kern,
W., Schrder, H.-H. And Weber, J. (eds), Handwrterbuch der Produktionswirtschaft, 2. Aufl.,
1779-1788.
Schanze, Erich (1995b), Franchising im ffentlichen Sektor (Franchising in the Public Sector), in
Naschold, F. u.a. (ed.), Leistungstiefe im ffentlichen Sektor, Kap. 7, Berlin.
Schatz, Klaus-Werner (1996), Reform von Planungs- und Genehmigungsverfahren (Reform of
Planning and Permission Procedures), in Schenk, Karl-Ernst, Schmidtchen, Dieter and Streit,
Manfred E. (eds), Vom Hoheitsstaat zum Konsensualstaat, Neue Formen der Kooperation
zwischen Staat und Privaten Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie 15, Tbingen, Mohr.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1970), Ein organisationstheoretisches Konzept der Regelungsvorgnge in
Wirtschaftssystemen und seine Anwendung (An Organization-Theoretical Concept of Control
Processes in Economic Systems and its Application), in Boettcher, E. (ed.), Beitrge zum
Vergleich von Wirtschaftssystemen, Schriften des Vereins fr Socialpolitik, N.F. Bd. 57, Berlin,
174-216.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1971a), Gedanken zur Untersuchung von Koordinationsmechenismen mit
sytemanalytischen Methoden (Thoughts on the Analysis of Coordination Mechanisms from the
Systems Approach), in Schenk, K.-E. (ed.), Systemanalyse in den Wirtschafts und
Sozialwissenschaften, ReiheWirtschaftskybernetik und Systemanalyse, Bd. 1, Berlin.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1971b), Wirtschaftsordnungen zwischen Konvergenz und Unvereinbarkeit
(Economic Constitutions between Convergence and Incompatibility), 17 Monatsbltter fr
freiheitliche Wirtschaftspolitik, 530-536.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1976a), Eine neue Variante des Marktsozialismus. Zu den Reformvorschlgen von
J. K. Galbraith (A New Variant of Market Socialism. About the Reform Ideas of J. K. Galbraith),
in Watrin Chr. (ed.), Studien zum Marktsozialismus, Schriften des Vereins fr Socialpolitik, N.F.,
Bd. 86, Berlin, 109-118.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1976b), Demokratie oder Brokratie? Dezentralisierung - Selbstverwaltung -
Entbrokratisierung (Democracy or Bureaucracy? Decentralization, Self-administration,
De-bureaucratisation)), in Geiler, H. (ed.), Verwaltete Brgergesellschaft in Fesseln.
204 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Brokratisierung und ihre Folgen fr den Staat, Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, Frankfurt (M),
Berlin Wien.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1978a), konomische Theorie der Brokratisch Organisierten Produktion
(Economic Theory of Bureaucratic Organized Production), in Helmstdter, E. (ed.), Neuere
Entwicklungen in den Wirtschaftswissenschaften, Schriften des Vereins fr Socialpolitik, N.F.,
Bd. 98, Berlin, 591-608.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1978b), Brokratie und Wirtschaftsordnung - Endogene Faktoren fr die
Vernderung (Bureaucracy and Economic Order. Endogenous Factors of Change),23 Hamburger
Jahrbuch fr Wirtschaft und Gesellschaftspolitik, 141-154.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1978c), Grenzberschreitende Unternehmensformen in den
Ost-West-Wirtschaftsbeziehungen (Transnational Forms of Enterprises in East-West Economic
Relations), mit A. Wass von Czege, in Schiller, Karl (ed.), Technolgietransfer durch
Ost-West-Kooperation, konomische Studien aus den Institut fr Auenhandel und
berseewirtschaft, Bd. 27, Stuttgart/New York, 1-12.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1980a), Marktversagen und Brokratieversagen (Market Failure and Bureaucracy
Failure), in Boettcher, E., Herder-Dorneich, Ph. and Schenk, K.-E. (ed.), Neue Politische
konomie als Ordnungstheorie, Tbingen, 192-199.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1980b), Rationale Ordnungspolitik (Rational Constitutional Policy), in Dettling,
W. (ed.), Die Zhmung des Leviathan. Neue Wege der Ordnungspolitik, Baden-Baden, Nomos
Verlagsgesellschaft, 207-225.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1981a), Das Spektrum der existierenden Wirtschaftsordnungen (The Spectrum
of Existing Economic Constitutions), in Issing, D. (ed.), Zukunftsprobleme der sozialen
Marktwirtschaft, Schriften des Vereins fr Socialpolitik, N.F. Bd. 116, Berlin, 412-419.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1981b), Mrkte und Hierarchien. Anreiz-und Kontrollmechanismen in der Theorie
der Wirtschaftssysteme (Markets and Hierarchies. Incentive and Control Mechanisms in the Theory
of Economic Systems), in Hedtkamp, G. (ed.), Anreiz-und Kontrollmechanismen in
Wirtschaftssystemen, Schriften des Vereins fr Socialpolitik, N.F., Bd. 117, Berlin, 11-27.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1981c), Mrkte, Hierarchien und Wettbewerb. Elemente einer Theorie der
Wirtschaftsordnung (Markets, Hierarchies and Competition. Elements of a theory of economic
constitution), Mnchen.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1982a), Institutional Choice und Transaktionskonomik. Perspektiven der
systemanalytischen und industriekonomischen Anwendung (Institutional Choice and Transaction
Economics, Perspectives of System-Analytic and Industrial-Economic Application), in Schiller,
K. (ed.), Studien zur Politischen konomie, konomische Studien aus dem Institut fr
Auenhandel und berseewirtschaft, Bd. 32, Stuttgart/New York.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1982b), Institutional Choice und Ordnungstheorie (Institutional Choice and
Theory of Order), Tbingen, Mohr, 39 p.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1983a), Second Economy und Wirtschaftsordnung - Ein systembergreifender,
transaktionskonomischer Erklrungsansatz (Second Economy and Economic Constitution. An
explanation approach encompassing different systems on the basis of transaction economics mit
A. Wass von Czege), in Hedtkamp, G. (ed.), Beitrge zum Problem der Schattenwirtschaft,
Schriften des Vereins fr Socialpolitik N.F., Bd. 132, Berlin, 33-51.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 205
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1983b), Vergleichende System und Industriestudien - Ein Institutional Choice-
Ansatz (Comparative Systems and Industrial Studies - An Institutional Choice approach), in
Schiller, K. (ed.), konomische Studien aus dem Institut fr Auenhandel und
berseewirtschaft, Bd. 34, Stuttgart-New York, 1-20.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1983c), Institutional Choice - Entwicklungen und Hauptanwendungen
(Institutional Choice - Developments and Main Applications), in Boettcher, E., Herder-Dorneich,
Ph. Schenk, K.-E. (eds), Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, Bd. 2, Tbingen, 70-85.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1985), Institutional Choice, Wirtschaftsordnung und Industrieorganisation, Ein
Beitrag zur Analyse komplexer arbeitsteiliger Systeme (Institutional Choice, Economic
Constitution and Industrial Organisation. A contribution to the analysis of complex economic
systems), in Schiller, K. (ed.), Industrieorganisation und Koordination - Theorien und
Lndervergleiche, konomische Studien aus den Institut fr Auenhandel und
berseewirtschaft, Bd. 36, Stuttgart-New York, 1-25.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1988a), Technologietransfer, Joint Ventures und Transaktionskosten.
Mglichkeiten und Grenzen strategischer Allianzen von Unternehmen in und zwischen Ost und
West (Transfer of Technologies, Joint Ventures and Transaction Costs. Opportunities and
boundaries of strategic alliances by enterprises of East and West), in Drr, E. Sieber, H. (eds),
Weltwirtschaft im Wandel, Festgabe fr E. Tuchtfeldt, Bern-Stuttgart, 595-606.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1988b), Die ordnungspolitische Funktion des Rechts in der modernen
Wirtschaftstheorie (Law and its Constitution-Political Functions in Modern Economic Theory),
in X. (ed.), Das Recht in einer freiheitlichen Industriegesellschaft, Verffentlichungen der
Walter-Raymond-Stiftung, Bd. 26, Kln, 179-202.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1988c), Property Rights und Theorie der Institutionen (Property Rights and
Theory of Institutions), Das Wirtschaftsstudium.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1991a), Bemerkungen zum Stand der Neuen Politischen konomie (Remarks
about the Achievements of the New Political Economics), 10 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische
konomie, 7-10.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1991b), Internationale Kooperationen und Joint Ventures. Theoretische und
strategische Grundlagen ((International cooperations and joint ventures. Theoretical and strategical
foundations), in Schoppe, S. G. (ed.),Kompendium der Internationalen Betriebswirtschaftslehre,
Mnchen-Wien, 153-184.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1992a), Ordnungstheorie auf Entscheidungstheoretischer Grundlage. Zum Buch
von Bruno Jeitziner unter diesem Titel (Theory of Economic Constitutions on Decision-Theoretical
Basis. About the book of Bruno Jeitziner), in X. (ed.), ORDO, Jahrbuch fr Ordnung von
Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, Bd, 43, Stuttgart, Franz Steiner, 515-517.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1992b), Die neue Institutionenkonomie - Ein berblick ber wichtige Elemente
und Probleme der Weiterentwicklung (New Institutional Economics - A Review of Important
Elements and Problems of further Developments), Zeitschrift fr Wirtschafts- und
Sozialwissenschaften, 339-378.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1996a), Genossenschaftsverbund und Netzwerk-Externalitten (Confederations
of Cooperatives and Network Externalities), in Bonus, H., Grossekettler, H., Grofeld, B. and
Wagner, H. (ed.), Humanitt und Genossenschaften. Festschrift fr Wilhelm Jger, Mnster,
157-167.
206 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1996b), Neue Politische konomie (NP) (New Political Economics), in X.
(ed.), Wirtschaftslexikon, 8. Aufl., Mnchen, 509-511.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst and Porschen, D. (1979), Anstze zu einer konomischen Theorie der
Einparteiensysteme Osteuropas (Approaches to an Economic Theory of Eastern Europes Political
Party Systems), in von Weizscker, C.C. (ed.), Staat und Wirtschaft, Schriften des Vereins fr
Socialpolitik, N.F., Bd. 102, Berlin.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst, Schmidtchen, Dieter and Streit, Manfred E. (eds) (1996), Vom Hoheitsstaat zum
Konsensualstaat, Neue Formen der Kooperation zwischen Staat und Privaten Jahrbuch fr
Neue Politische konomie 15 (From Sovereignity to Consensus, New Forms of Cooperation
Between State and Citizens), Tbingen, Mohr.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst, Schmidtchen, Dieter and Streit, Manfred E. (eds) (1997), Neue Politische
konomie der Integration und ffnung von Infrastrukturnetzen Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische
konomie 16 (Integration of and Access to Infrastructural Networks), Tbingen, Mohr.
Scherer, Frederic M. (1985), Stand und Perspektiven der Industriekonomik (S nd Perspectives of
Industrial Economics), in Bombach, G., Gahlen, B. and Ott, A.E. (eds), Industriekonomik:
Theorie und Empirie, Tbingen, Mohr, 3-19.
Schlicht, Ekkehart (1974), Die Theorie der kollektiven Entscheidung und der individualistische Ansatz
(Theory of Collective Choice and Individualism), 2 Leviathan, 265-280.
Schlicht, Ekkehart (1984), Bemerkungen zum Zusammenwirken konomischer und sozialer
Einflsse auf das Verhalten (On the Interaction of Social and Economic Influences), in Birg,
H., Wingen, M. and Zimmermann, K. (eds), Zusammenhnge zwischen Bevlkerungs- und
Wirtschaftsentwicklung in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland, Deutsche Gesellschaft fr
Bevlkerungswissenschaft e.V., Wiesbaden, Gabler, 119-124.
Schlicht, Ekkehart (1990), Individuelles Bestreben und kulturelles Gefge (Individual Striving in the
Cultural Context), in Weise, Peter (ed.), konomie und Gesellschaft Jahrbuch 8, Individuelles
Verhalten und kollektive Phnomene, Frankfurt am Main, Campus, 112-127.
Schlicht, Ekkehart (1993), Koordinationskosten und Social Capital (Co-ordination Costs and Social
Capital), in Schlieper, Ulrich and Schmidtchen, Dieter (eds), Makro, Geld and Institutionen,
Tbingen, 95-100.
Schlicht, Ekkehart (1994a), Die emotive und die kognitive Gerechtigkeitsauffassung (The Emotive
and the Cognitive View of Justice), 2 konomie und Gesellschaft, 141-154.
Schlicht, Ekkehart (1994b), Probleme mit dem konomischen Ansatz (Some Problems With the
Economic Approach), 5(2) Ethik und Sozialwissenschaften, 335-337.
Schlicht, Ekkehart and Kubon-Gilke, Gisela (1993), Gefordertheit und Institutionelle Analyse am
Beispiel des Eigentums (Requiredness and Institutional Analysis), 15 Gestalt Theory, 256-273.
Schmidt, Ingo (1963a), Die ffentliche Hand als Unternehmen im Sinne des GWB (The Government
as an Enterprise with Respect to Competition Law), 18 Der Betriebs-Berater, 1404 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1963b), Markttransparenz als Voraussetzung fr Wettbewerbsbeschrnkungen (Market
Transparency as a Prerogative for Competition Distortions), 13 Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 97
ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1964a), Preismeldestellen - Kartelle im Tarnanzug (Price Announcement Authorities
- Cartels in Disguise), 18 Der Volkswirt, 652 ff.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 207
Schmidt, Ingo (1964b), Zum Begriff des Preiswettbewerbs nach 16 GWB (Price Competition), 14
Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 120 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1965a), Preisbindung und Preiswettbewerb (Price Fixings and Price Competition), 27
Der Markenartikel, 435 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1965b), Das Verhltnis von Patent- und Kartellrecht - Folgerungen aus der
Konzentrationsenquete fr die Patentreform (The Relation of Patent Law and Competition Law),
Die Aussprache, 155 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1965c), Relevanter Markt, Marktbeherrschung und Mibrauch in 22 GWB und Art.
86 EWGV (Relevant Market, Domination, and Abuse according to German and European
Competition Law), 15 Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 453 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1966), Neuere Entwicklungen in der Wettbewerbstheorie unter Bercksichtigung
wachstumspolitischer Zielsetzungen (New Developments in the Competition Theory), 16
Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 699 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1967), Zum Nachweis des Mibrauchs einer Rechtlichen oder Faktischen
Wettbewerbsbeschrnkung, Eine Analyse der im amerikanischen Recht entwickelten Theorien und
Kriterien zur Schadenshhe in den civil damage suits und zur performance-Kontrolle in den
public (On Proving the Abuse of a Legal or Factual Restraints of Competition: An Analysis of the
American Theories), 17 Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 635 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1968), Zum Schutzzweck der Mibrauchsaufsicht ber marktbeherrschende
Unternehmen (The Goal of Abuse Control), 21 Der Betriebs-Berater, 1795 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1969), Reform des GWB - Aufgabe des nchsten Bundestages (Reform of the German
Anti-Trust Law), 49 Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftspolitik, 450 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1970), Erweiterter Schutz kleiner und mittlerer Unternehmen (Extended Protection for
Small and Medium Firms), Marktwirtschaft, 21 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1972), Entwicklung der Antitrustrechtsprechung gegenber Konglomeraten (The
Development of the Anti-Trust Judicature on Conglomerates), 18 Auenwirtschaftsdienst des
Betriebs-Beraters, 275 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1973a), US-amerikanische und Deutsche Wettbewerbspolitik Gegenber Marktmacht,
Eine vergleichende Untersuchung und kritische Analyse der Rechtsprechung gegenber
Tatbestnden des externen und internen Unternehmenswachstums sowie des
Behinderungswettbewerbs (Competition Policy and Market Power in the US and in Germany),
in Besters, Hans (ed.), Quaestiones Oeconomicae Band 6, Berlin.
Schmidt, Ingo (1973b), Wie kann Marktmacht kontrolliert werden? (How Can Market Power be
Controlled?), 23 Der Brger im Staat, 252 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1976a), Die Zusammenhnge von relevantem Markt, Marktbeherrschung und
Marktergebnis am Beispiel der Mibrauchsaufsicht des Bundeskartellamtes bei Arzneimitteln (The
Federal Anti-Trust Authoritys Abuse Control of the Pharmaceutical Market as an Example for the
Relation of Relevant Market, Market Dominance und Market Results), 190 Jahrbuch fr
Nationalkonomie und Statistik, 67 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1976b), Geplanter Verschlei (Intended Wear), in Arbeitsgemeinschaft der
Verbraucher and Deutscher Gewerkschaftsbund (ed.), Handbuch des Verbraucherrechts,
Neuwied/Rhine.
Schmidt, Ingo (1981a), Per se Rule oder Rule of Reason (Per-se rules or Rules of Reason), 10 WiSt,
282 ff.
208 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Schmidt, Ingo (1981b), Wettbewerbspolitik in den USA (Competition Policy in the US), in Cox, Jens
and Markert (eds), Handbuch des Wettbewerbs, Mnchen, 533-556.
Schmidt, Ingo (1981c), Preiskontrolle in Deutschland (Price Control in Germany), 50 Annalen der
Gemeinwirtschaft, 491 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1981d), Obsoleszenz als Mibrauch wirtschaftlicher Macht (Obsolescence as an Abuse
of Economic Power), 21 Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 868 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1986), Ist Gre an sich gefhrlich (Is Bigness Dangerous Per Se?), 36 Wirtschaft und
Wettbewerb, 193 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1990a), Wettbewerbspolitik und Kartellrecht: Eine Einfhrung, (3rd edn)
(Competition Policy and Antitrust Law: An Introduction), Stuttgart, Gustav Fischer, 330 p.
Schmidt, Ingo (1990b), Die Europische Fusionskontroll-Verordnung (The European Merger Control
Law), 70 Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftspolitik, 90 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1992a), EG-Integration, Industrie- versus Wettbewerbspolitik (European Integration,
Industrial Policy vs. Competition Policy), 72 Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftspolitik, 628 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1992b), Die Wettbewerbsordnung (The Competition Restraint), in Adams, W.P. et
al. (eds), Lnderbericht USA I, Geographie, Geschichte, Politische Kultur, Politisches System,
Wirtschaft, Schriftenreihe vol. 293/I der Bundeszentrale fr politische Bildung, 2nd ed., Bonn,
606 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1995), Europische Industriepolitik - ein Widerspruch zur Wettbewerbsordnung?
(European Industrial Policy - Contradiction to the Competition Law System?), 45 Wirtschaft und
Wettbewerb, 971 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1996a), Pro und Contra Konzentrationsprivileg, Die unterschiedlichen Wirkungen von
Kartellen und Fusionen auf Wettbewerb und Effizienz (Pro and Contra Privileged Concentration,
The Different Impacts of Cartels and Mergers on Competition and Efficiency), in Kruse, Jrn and
Mayer, Otto G. (eds), Aktuelle Probleme der Wettbewerbs- und Wirtschaftspolitik, Erhard
Kantzenbach zum 65. Geburtstag, Baden-Baden, 119 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo (1996b), Wettbewerbspolitik versus Industriepolitik in der EG, Korreferat zu Erhard
Kantzenbach (Industrial Policy vs. Competition Policy, Comment), 44 Applied Economics
Quarterly, 59 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo and Binder, Steffen (1996), Wettbewerbspolitik im internationalen Vergleich, Die
Erfassung wettbewerbsbeschrnkender Strategien in Deutschland, England, Frankreich, den
USA und der EG (An International Comparision of Competition Policy), Heidelberg.
Schmidt, Ingo and Eler, Stefan (1990), Innovationsoptimale Unternehmensgren und
Marktstrukturen (Innovation Optimal Firm Sizes and Market Structures), 19 WiSt, 556 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo and Eler, Stefan (1992), Die Rolle des Markenartikels im marktwirtschaftlichen
System (The Role of Brands in the Market Economy), in Dichtl, Erwin and Eggers, Walter (eds),
Marke und Markenartikel als Instrumente des Wettbewerbs, Mnchen, 47 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo and Engelke, Heinz (1989), Marktzutrittsschranken und Potentieller Wettbewerb
(Market Entry Barriers and Potential Competition), 18 WiSt, 399 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo and Kirschner, Ulrich (1985), Darstellung und wettbewerbspolitische Wrdigung der
U.S. Vertical Restraints Guidelines (Critical Evaluation of the US Vertical Restraint Guidelines),
35 Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 781 ff.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 209
Schmidt, Ingo and Kirschner, Ulrich (1987), Capture Theory, Ein Erklrungsansatz fr die mangelnde
Effizienz der Regulierung (Capture Theory as an Approach to Explain the Lack of Efficiency of
Regulation), 16 WiSt, 293 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo and Richard, Sabine (1989), Unternehmensgre, Ausdruck von Macht oder Effizienz?
(Size of Firms as an Indicator for Efficiency or Power?), gdi impuls, 26 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo and Richard, Sabine (1991), Zum Verhltnis von Dumpingrecht und Kartellrecht in der
EG (On the Relation of Anti-Dumping Law and Antitrust Law), 41 Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb,
665 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo and Ries, W. (1983), Der Hirschman-Herfindahl-Index (HHI) als
wettbewerbspolitisches Instrument in den US-Fusionsrichtlinien 1982 (The Hirschmann-Herfindah
Index as an Instrument of Competition Policy in the US Merger Guidelines), 33 Wirtschaft und
Wettbewerb, 525 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo and Rittaler, Jan B., Das wettbewerbstheoretische und -politische Credo der sog.
Chicago School (The Guidelines of the So-alled Chicago School on Competition Theory and
Competition Policy), Diskussionsbeitrge aus dem Institut fr VWL No. 23/85.
Schmidt, Ingo and Rittaler, Jan B. (1986a), Die Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis: Wett (The
Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis: Competition Theoretical and Political Analysis of a Credo),
Baden-Baden, Nomos, 119 p.
Schmidt, Ingo and Rittaler, Jan B. (1986b), Chicago School of Antitrust Law, konomische Analyse
des Wettbewerbsrechts (Chicago School of Antitrust Law, Economic Analysis of Competition
Law), 15 WiSt, 283 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo and Rittaler, Jan B. (1987), Marktphasen und Wettbewerb (Market phases and
Competition), 16 WiSt, 597 ff.
Schmidt, Ingo and Rhrich, Martina (1992), Kompetitive Marktstrukturen und externes
Unternehmenwachstum (Competitive Market structures and External Firm Growth),29 WiSt, 179
ff.
Schmidt, Ingo and Schmidt, Andr (1996), X-Ineffizienz, Lean Production und Wettbewerbsfhigkeit
(X-Inefficiency, Lean Production, and Ability to Compete), 25 WiSt, 65 ff.
Schmidt, Reinhard H. (1981a), Kreditsicherung und Konkursrecht (Credit Security and Insolvency
Law), in Gppl, Hermann and Henn, Rudolf (eds), Geld, Banken und Versicherungen,
Knigstein/Ts. 1981, Geld, Banken und Versicherungen, Knigstein/Ts., 569-573.
Schmidt, Reinhard H. (1981b), konomische Analyse des Insolvenzrechts (Economic Analysis of
Insolvency Law), Wiesbaden, Gabler, 155 p.
Schmidt, Reinhard H. (1981c), Die konomische Grundstruktur des Insolvenzrechts (The Economic
Struckture of the Insolvency Law), 26 Die Aktiengesellschaft, 35-44.
Schmidt, Reinhardt H. (1981d), Die konomische Grundstruktur der Insolvenz Recht (The Economic
Basic Structure of Bankruptcy Law), Die Aktiengesellschaft, 35-44.
Schmidt, Reinhard H. (1984), Asymmetrische Information und Glubigerverfgungsrechte in der
Insolvenz (Asymmetric Information and Creditors Rights during Insolvency), 54 Zeitschrift fr
Betriebswirtschaft, 717-742.
Schmidt, Reinhard H. (1996), Betriebswirtschaftslehre und Rechtspolitik (Business Administration and
Legal Policy), 41 Die Aktiengesellschaft, 250-260.
Schmidt, Reinhard H. and Koch, Hans-Dieter (1981), Ziele und Instrumente des Anlegerschutzes
(Goals and Means of Investor Protection), 33(3) Betriebswirtschaftliche Forschung und Praxis,
29-48.
210 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Schmidt, Reinhard H. and Kbler, Friedrich (1988), Gesellschaftsrecht und Konzentration (Company
Law and Concentration), Berlin, Duncker and Humblot, 225 p.
Schmidt, Reinhard H., Ballwieser, W., Bcking, H.-J. and Drukarczyk, Jochen (1994), Bilanzrecht
und Kapitalmarkt, Festschrift zum 65. Geburtstag von Adolf Moxter (Accounting Law and
Capital Markets), Dsseldorf.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1973a), Politische konomie staatlicher Preisinterventionen. Dargestellt am
Beispiel der politischen Preise im Nachrichtenverkehr (Political Prices in the News Business as
an Example for the Politcal Economics of Public Price Interventions), .
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1973b), Fr eine konsequente Wettbewerbspolitik und ber die Wege dorthin,
Bemerkungen zum Wettbewerbsverstndnis des Sachverstndigenrates (For a Consistent
Competition Policy and How to Achieve It), 129 Zeitschrift fr die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft,
102 ff.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1974a), Der politische Preis (The Political Price), 1
Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Studium, 17 ff.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1974b), Politische konomie (Political Economics), 24 Jahrbuch fr die
Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, 233 ff.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1978), Wettbewerbspolitik als Aufgabe: Methodologisch (Competition Policy
as Task: Methodological and System Theoretical Foundations for a Reorientatation), Baden-Baden,
Nomos.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1979), Ausbeutung aufgrund einer Wettbewerbsbeschrnkung durch Zustand?
Kritische Analyse der theoretischen Grundlagen einer freiheitsgefhrdenden Wettbewerbspolitik
(Expropriation through a Competition Restraint by State? A Critical Analysis of the Theoretical
Foundations of a Competition Policy that Threatens Freedom), 30 Ordo: Jahrbuch fr die
Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, 273 ff.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1981), Leitungspartizipation, Wettbewerb und Funktionsfhigkeit des
Marktsystems (Management Participation), in Issing, D. (ed.), Zukunftsprobleme der sozialen
Marktwirtschaft, Schriften des Vereins fr Socialpolitik, N.F. Bd. 116, Berlin, 191 ff.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1982a), Property Rights, Freiheitsschutz und die Logik staatlicher
Preisinterventionen: Kritische Analyse der theoretischen Grundlagen einer freiheits gefhrdenden
Wettbewerbspolitik (Property Rights, Protection of Liberty and the Logic of Governmental Price),
in Die Mi Brauchsaufsicht Vor Dem Hintergrund Der En (ed.), Schriften des Vereins fr
Socialpolitik, Vol. 124.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1982b), Theorie des politischen Preises (Theory of Political Prices), in Bcker,
F. (ed.), Preistheorie und Preisverhalten, Mnchen, 279 ff.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1985), Monopol und Institutional Choice (Monopoly and Institutional Choice),
in Schenk, K.-E. (ed.), Wirtschaftsordnung, Industrieorganisation und Koordination - Theorie
und Lndervergleiche, Stuttgart, 180-211.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1987a), Sunk Costs, Quasirenten und Mitbestimmung (Sunk Costs, Quasirents,
and Worker Participation), 6 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, 139 ff.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1987b), Unsichtbare-Hand-Erklrung und die Theorie der komparativen
Kosten (Invisible-Hand Explanations and the Theory of Comparative Costs), in Borchert, M.,
Fehl, U. und Oberender, P. (ed.), Markt und Wettbewerb, Festschrift fr Ernst Heu Bern,
Stuttgart, 287 ff.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 211
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1987c), Gebhrenpolitik der DBP und Ordnungspolitik (Pricing Policy of the
Deutsche Bundespost and Constitutional Policy), in Diederich, H., Hamm, W. and Zohlnhfer,
W. (eds), Die deutsche Bundespost im Spannungsfeld der Wirtschaftspolitik, Heidelberg,
221-281.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1988), Fehlurteile ber das Konzept der Wettbewerbsfreiheit (Wrong
Conclusions on the Concept of Competitive Freedom), 39 Ordo: Jahrbuch fr die Ordnung von
Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, 111-135.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1989), Evolutorische Ordnungstheorie oder: die Transaktionskosten und das
Unternehmertum (The Theory of Evolutionary Order, or: Transaction Costs and
Entrepreneurship), Ordo: Jahrbuch fr die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, 161-182.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1990), Die Produktion von Recht. Ein Literaturaufsatz (The Production of Law.
An Overview), 146(4) Journal for Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 749-757.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1991), Jenseits von Maximierung, Gleichgewicht und Effizienz: Neuland fr die
konomische Analyse des Rechts? (Beyond Maximization, Balance and Efficiency: New L), in
Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin,
Springer, 316-343.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1993), Neue Institutionenkonomik internationaler Transaktionen (New
Institutional Economics of International Transactions), in Schlieper, Ulrich and Schmidtchen,
Dieter (eds), Makro, Geld and Institutionen, Tbingen, 57-84.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1994a), Vom nichtmarginalen Charakter der Steuermoral (On the Non-marginal
Character of Tax Morals), in Chr. Smekal and Theurl, E. (eds), Stand und Entwicklung der
Finanzpsychologie, Baden-Baden, 185-211.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1994b), konomik des Vertrauens (Economics of Trust), in Hof, H. (ed.), Recht
und Verhalten, Verhaltensgrundlagen des Rechts - zum Beispiel Vertrauen. Interdisziplinre
Studien zu Recht und Staat, Bd. 1, Baden-Baden, 129-163.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1994c), Antitrust zwischen Marktmachtphobie und Effizienzeuphorie, Alte
Themen - neue Anstze (Antitrust between Fear of Market Power and Euphoria about Efficiency),
in Mschel, W., Streit M. and Witt, U. (eds), Marktwirtschaft und Rechtsordnung, Festschrift fr
Erich Hoppmann, Baden-Baden, 143-166.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1995a), Territorialitt des Rechts, Internationales Privatrecht und die
privatautonome Regelung internationaler Sachverhalte. Grundlagen eines interdisziplinren
Forschungsprogramms (Territoriality of Law, International Private Law, and Private Autonomous
Order of International Relations),59(1) Rabels Zeitschrift fr auslndisches und internationales
Privatrecht, 56-112.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1995b), Die Zwillingsideen der Evolution und der spontanen Bildung einer
Ordnung (The Twin Ideas of Evolution and Spontaneous Order), in Francke, H.-H. (ed.),
konomischer Individualismus und freiheitliche Verfassung, Freiburg, 239-271.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1997), Effizienz als Rechtsprinzip. Bemerkungen zu dem gleichnamigen Buch
von Horst Eidenmller (Center for the Study of Law and Economics), Discussion paper 9708,
1997. Jahrbcher fr Nationalkonomie und Statistik
Schmidtchen, Dieter and Fehl, E.U. (1986), Wettbewerbstheoretische Aspekte der Mibrauchsaufsicht
ber Autobahntankstellen (Competition Theoretical Approach of the Abuse Control Concerning
Highway Gas Stations), Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 572 ff.
212 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Schmidtchen, Dieter and Kirstein, Roland (1997), Abkoppelung der Prozekosten vom Streitwert?
Eine konomische Analyse von Reformvorschlgen (Separation of Litigation Costs and the Value
of the Case? An Economic Analysis of Reform Proposals), in Prtting, H. and Rssmann, H. (eds),
Verfahrensrecht am Ausgang des 20. Jahrhunderts. Festschrift fr Gerhard Lke zum 70.
Geburtstag, Mnchen 1997, Mnchen, 741-766.
Schmidtchen, Dieter and Koboldt, Christian (1991), Copyrights - A und O in Literatur und Musik?
(Copyrights in Literature and Music), 42 Ordo: Jahrbuch fr die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und
Gesellschaft.
Schmidtchen, Dieter, Koboldt, Christian and Kirstein, Roland (1997), Rechtsvereinheitlichung beim
droit de suite? konomische Analyse des Richtlinienentwurfs der Europischen Kommission
Center for the Study of Law and Economics (Harmonization of a Droit de Suite? An Economic
Analysis of a Proposal of the European Commission), .
Schmidtchen, Dieter, Schmidt Trenz, Hans Jorg and Utzig, S. (1988), Zwang oder nicht Zwang - das
ist hier die Frage. Der Verein fr Socialpolitik und seine Mitgliederzeitschrift (Coercion or not -
thats the Question. On the Member Journal of the Verein fr Socialpolitik), 204 Jahrbuch fr
Nationalkonomie und Statistik, 423-436.
Schmidt-Trenz, Hans-Joerg (1987), Der state of nature im Schatten von Erwartungen ber die
Bildung und Verteilung von Eigentumsrechten. Ergebnisse einer spieltheoretischen Analyse der
Vertragstheorie von J. M. Buchanan (The State of Nature in the Shadow of Expectations on
Creation and Distribution of Property Rights), Diskussionsbeitrge Fachbereich
Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Universitt des Saarlandes.
Schmidt-Trenz, Hans-Joerg (1990a), Auenhandel und Territorialitt des Rechts. Grundlegung einer
Neuen Institutionenkonomik des Auenhandels (Trade and Territoriality of Law), Baden-Baden,
Nomos.
Schmidt-Trenz, Hans-Joerg (1990b), Kammern und Verbnde als spontane Hilfssheriffs, (Anstze
zu einer Neuen Institutionenkonomik von Kammern und Verbnden, Teil I) (Chambers and
Non-profit Organizations as spontaneous Deputy Sheriffs), 15 Verbandsmanagement, 21-28.
Schmidt-Trenz, Hans-Joerg (1990c), Kammern und Verbnde als Organisatoren von
Whlerinteressen, (Anstze zu einer Neuen Institutionenkonomik von Kammern und Verbnden,
Teil II) (Chambers and Non-profit Organizations to Organize Voters Interests), 15/3
Verbandsmanagement, 52-59.
Schmidt-Trenz, Hans-Joerg (1991), Kammern und Verbnde als Nicht-Marktliche Institutionen
(Hierarchien), (Anstze zu einer Neuen Institutionenkonomik von Kammern und Verbnden, Teil
III) (Chambers and Non-profit Organizations as Non-market Institutions), 16
Verbandsmanagement, 19-24.
Schmidt-Trenz, Hans-Joerg (1992a), Systemwandel und vertrauensbildende Manahmen. Der
Transformationsproze der DDR-Wirtschaft im Lichte einer Neuen Institutionenkonomik von
Kammern und Verbnden (System Transition and Trustbuilding Means), 11 Jahrbuch fr Neue
Politische konomie, 145-163.
Schmidt-Trenz, Hans-Joerg (1992b), Systemwandel und vertrauensbildende Manahmen. Der
Transformationsproze der DDR-Wirtschaft im Lichte einer Neuen Institutionenkonomik von
Kammern und Verbnden (System Transition and Trustbuilding Means), Diskussionsbeitrge
Fachbereich Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Universitt des Saarlandes A 9203, Saarbrcken, No. A
9203.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 213
Schmidt-Trenz, Hans-Joerg (1995), konomische Analyse der Reform des Rechts der privaten
Schiedsgerichtsbarkeit. Was nutzt die Straffung des Vollstreckbarerklrungsverfahrens?
(Economic Analysis of the Reform of Private Arbitration Law), Diskussionsbeitrge der
Forschungsstelle zur konomischen Analyse des Rechts der Universitt des Saarlandes 9505,
Saarbrcken, 1995.
Schmidt-Trenz, Hans-Joerg (1996), Die Logik kollektiven Handelns bei Delegation. Das
Organisationsdilemma der Verbnde am Beispiel des Beitragszwangs bei den Industrie- und
Handelskammern (The Logic of Collective Action with Delegation), Tbingen, Mohr/Siebeck.
Schmidt-Trenz, Hans-Joerg and Schmidtchen, Dieter (1994), Theorie optimaler Rechtsrume. Die
Regulierung sozialer Beziehungen durch die Kontrolle von Territorium (Theory of Optimum Legal
Areas), 13 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, 7-29.
Schmitz-Herscheidt, Friedhelm, Anstze zu einer konomischen Theorie des Gesellschaftsrecht (Initial
Stages to an Economic Theory of Company Law), in Boettcher, Erik, Herder-Dorneich, Philipp
and Schenk, Karl-Ernst (eds), Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, Tbingen, Mohr.
Schneider, Jens-Peter (1996), Kooperative und Konsensuale Formen Administrativer
Entscheidungsprozesse (Cooperative and Consensual Forms of Administrative Decision Making),
15 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, 82-102.
Schneider, Jens-Peter (1997), Das Neue Steuerungsmodell als Innovationsimpuls fr
Verwaltungsorganisation und Verwaltungsrecht (New Public Management as an Innovative
Impulse for Administrative Organisation and Adminstrative Law), in Eberhard Schmidt-Amann
and Wolfgang Hoffmann-Riem (eds), Organisationsrecht als Steuerungsressource (Band 5 der
Schriften zur Reform des Verwaltungsrechts), Baden-Baden, Nomos.
Schneider, Jens-Peter and Hoffmann-Riem, Wolfganf (1995), Wettbewerbs- und umweltorientierte
Re-Regulierung im Grohandels-Strommarkt (Re-Regulation of wholesale electricity markets
towards competition and environmental protection), in Hoffmann-Riem/Schneider (eds),
Umweltpolitische Steuerung in einem liberalisierten Strommarkt, Baden-Baden, Nomos, 13-94.
Schch, Heinz (1985), Empirische Grundlagen der Generalprvention (Empirical Foundations of
General Prevention), in Vogler, T. (ed.), Festschrift fr Hans- Heinrich Jescheck zum 70. Ge,
Berlin, Duncker and Humblot, vol. II, 1081-1105.
Schffski, Oliver, Gedanken zur Deregulierung des deutschen Apothekenwesens (Ideas for the
Deregulation of the German Pharmacy System),45(2) Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftspolitik, 216-248.
Schffski, Oliver (1995), Die Regulierung des deutschen Apothekenwesens. Eine konomische
Analyse (Regulation of German Pharmacies. An Economic Analysis), Baden-Baden, Nomos.
Schffski, Oliver and Zhang, J. (1992), berlegungen zur Einfhrung einer Krankenversicherung in
der Volksrepublik China (Reflections about the Introduction of Health Insurance in the Peoples
Republic of China), 81 Versicherungswissenschaft, 249-260.
Schrder, Michael (1997), Betriebliche Vollzugskosten der Arbeits- und Sozialgesetzgebung. Ein
internationaler und intertemporaler Vergleich (Execution Costs of Labor and Social Laws),
Frankfurt, Campus.
Schrder, Roland (1996), Sind kleine Bundeslnder zu teuer? (Federal States in Germany, Are the
Small ones too Expensive?), Diskussionspapiere fr liberale Politik Nr. 1, 1996.
214 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der, Demographischer Wandel und Umverteilung via Gesetzliche
Krankenversicherung (Demographic Change and Redistribution via Statutory Health Insurance),
in Gfgen, G. and Oberender, P. (eds), Verteilungsziele und Verteilungswirkungen im
Gesundheitswesen, Gesundheitskonomische Beitrge Band 6, Baden-Baden, Nomos.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der (1982), Health Maintenance Organizations - Eine interessante
Alternative zur traditionellen Krankenversicherung? (Health Maintenance Organizations - An
Alternative for Traditional Health Insurance), 71 Zeitschrift fr die gesamte
Versicherungswissenschaft, 27-648.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der (1984), Wettbewerb und Regulierung im Gesundheitswesen
- Property Rights als Ziel und Restriktion rztlicher Honorarpolitik (Competition and Regulation
in the Health Care Sector), in Neumann, M. (ed.),Ansprache, Eigentums- und Verfgungsrechte,
Berlin, Duncker and Humblot, 435-456.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der (1985), Pro-Competitive-Strategy im Gesundheitswesen,
Eine kritische Stellungnahme aus deutscher Sicht (Pro-Competitive-Strategy in the Health Care
Sector, A Critical Statement from the German Point of View), in Hamm, W. and0 Neubauer, G.
(eds), Wettbewerb im Gesundheitswesen, Bd. 7 der Beitrge zur Gesundheitskonomie,
Gerlingen, Bleicher, 325-353.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der (1987), Marktstruktur und Wettbewerb in der ambulanten
Versorgung, Die rzteschwemme und ihre Auswirkungen auf die ambulante Versorgung (Market
Structure and Competition in Out-Patient Care, The Glut of Physicians and and Effects on
Ambulatory Care), in Brennecke, R. and Schach, E. (eds), Ambulante Versorgung, Nachfrage
und Steuerung, Berlin, Springer, 125-172.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der (1988), Mehr Markt im Gesundheitswesen (More Market in
the Health Care Sector), 144 Zeitschrift fr die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft, 396-402.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der (1989), Probleme der Gesundheitspolitik in Frankreich und
Deutschland (Problems of Health Politics in France and Germany), Frankfurt, Campus.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der (1990), Demographischer Wandel, intergenerationale
Gerechtigkeit und Stabilitt des Generationenvertrages (Demographic Change, Intergenerational
Justice and Stability of the Contact Between Generations), in Gahlen, B., Hesse, H. and Ramser
H.J. (eds), Theorie und Politik der Sozialversicherung, Schriftenreihe des
Wirtschaftswissenschaftlichen Seminars Ottobeuren Bd. 19, Tbingen, Mohr/Siebeck, 269-300.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der (1992), Wie souvern darf der Konsument auf
Versicherungmrkten sein? Nachfragerverhalten und Regulierung auf Versicherungsmrkten (How
Sovereign is a Consumer on Insurance Markets Allowed to be? Behaviour of Consumers and
Regulation on Insurance Markets), in Jacob, H., Adam, D., Hansmann, K.-H., Hilke, W., Mller,
W., Premar, D.B. and Scheer, A.-W. (eds), Schriften zur Unternehmensfhrung, Band 45,
Wiesbaden, Gabler, 3-18.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der (1993), Kann der moderne Wohlfahrtsstaat die Konflikte
zwischen medizinischen Mglichkeiten, sozialer Verantwortung und wirtschaftlicher Machbarkeit
lsen? (Is the Modern Welfare State Able to Solve the Conflicts Between Medical Possibilities,
Social Responsibility and Economic Possibilities?), 2 Staatwissenschaften und Staatspraxis,
256-269.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 215
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der and Breyer, F. (1989), Umlagefinanzierte Rentenversicherung
bei abnehmender Bevlkerung unter den Bedingungen eines demokratischen Wahlmechanismus
(Pension Insurance Financed by Contributions in Times of Decreasing Population Under the
Conditions of a Democratic Election Mechanism), in Boettcher, Erik, Herder-Dorneich, Philipp
and Schenk, Karl-Ernst (eds), Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, Tbingen, Mohr,
126-139.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der and Finsinger, Jorg (1989), Der Sonntagsverkauf (Selling on
Sunday), 109 Zeitschrift fr Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften, 119-228.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der and Hauser, Heinz (1988), Health Maintenance Organizations
- Eine Reformkonzeption fr die Gesetzliche Krankenversicherung in der Bundesrepublik
Deutschland (Health Maintenance Organizations - A New Concept for the Statutory Health
Insurance in Germany), 19 der von der Robert Bosch Stiftung herausgegebenen Beitrge zur
Gesundheitskonomie.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der and Kleindorfer, P. (1986), Wie stabil ist der
Generationenvertrag in der Krankenversicherung? Zum Problem der Gerechtigkeit und der
Akzeptanz intergenerativer Umverteilung (How Stable is the Contract Between Generations in the
German Statutory Health Insurance?), in Gfgen, G. (ed.), konomie des Gesundheitswesens,
Schriften des Vereins fr Socialpolitik, Berlin, Duncker and Humblot, 413-434.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der and Schffski, Oliver (1994a), berweisungs- und
Einweisungsverhalten von Primrrzten nach dem GSG (Referrals and Hospital Admissions of
Primary Care Physicians After the Health Care Reform Act of 1992), 136(14) Mnchener
Medizinische Wochenschrift, 202-205.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der and Schffski, Oliver (1994b), Transformation des
Gesundheitswesens im Spannungsfeld zwischen Kostendmpfung und Freiheit, Eine konomische
Analyse des vernderten berweisungs- und Einweisungsverhaltens nach den
Arzneimittelregulierungen des GSG (Transformation of the Health Care System, An Economic
Analysis of the Changes in Referrals and Hospital Admissions after the Drug Budget of the Health
Care Reform Act of 1992), in Oberender, P. (ed.), Probleme der Transformation im
Gesundheitswesen, Baden-Baden, Nomos, 45-81.
Schulenburg, J. Matthias Graf Von Der and Wagner, Michael J. (1990), Protektionismus,
Marktstruktur und Importkonkurrenz, Eine vergleichende konometrische Studie fr die
Bundesrepublik Deutschland und die USA (Protectionism, Market Structure and Import
Competition), 36(4) Ifo-Studien zur Industriewirtschaft, 267-291.
Schller, Alfred (1978), Property Rights, Unternehmerische Legitimation und Wirtschaftsordnung.
Zum vermgenstheoretischen Ansatz einer allgemeinen Theorie der Unternehmung (Property
Rights, Entrepreneurial Legitimation and Economic System. On the Property Rights Approach of
a General Theory of the Enterprise), in Schenk, K.E. (ed.), konomische Verfgungsrechte und
Allokationsmechanismen in Wirtschafsystemen, Berlin, Duncker and Humblot, 29-87.
Schller, Alfred (1979), Eigentumsrechte, Unternehmenskontrollen und Wettbewerbsordnung
(Property Rights, Corporate Control and Competition), 30 Ordo: Jahrbuch fr die Ordnung von
Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, 325-364.
Schller, Alfred (1983), Theorie der Firma und wettbewerbliches Marktsystem (Theory of the Firm
and Competitive Market System), in Schller, Alfred (ed.), Property Rights und konomische
Theorie, Mnchen, Vahlen, 145-183.
Schller, Alfred (1985), Zur konomik der Property Rights (On the Economics of Property Rights),
14(5) Das Wirtschaftsstudium, 259-265.
216 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Seidl, Christian (1988b), Welfarismus versus Liberalismus. Sind Demokratie und individuelle Rechte
unvereinbar? (Welfarism versus Liberalism. Are Democracy and Individual Rights
Contradictory?), in Rahmsdorf, Detlef and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), Ethische Grundfragen der
Wirtschafts- und Rechtsordnung, Bd. 4 der Hamburger Beitrge zur ffentlichen Wissenschaft,
Dietrich Reiner Verlag, Berlin-Hambug, 143-204.
Seidl, Christian (1989a), Kommentar (Comment on Ktz, Zur Effizienz von Haftungsausschl), in Ott,
Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds),Allekationseffizienz in der Rechtsordnung, Berlin, Springer,
201-207.
Seidl, Christian (1989b), Betriebssteuer und Neutralitt (On the Neutrality of a Business Tax), 66/4
Steuer und Wirtschaft, 350-357.
Seidl, Christian (1991a), Kommentar zur Arbeit von Helmut Kohl, Das Allgemeine
Persnlichkeitsrecht als Ausdruck oder Grenze des Effizienzdenkens im Zivilrecht? (A Comment
on the Paper by Helmut Kohl, Individual Rights as a Phenomenon or a Limit on Efficiency
Considerations in Private Law?), in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische
Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin, Springer, 52-57.
Seidl, Christian (1991b), Kommentar (Comment on Kohl, Das Allgemeine Persnlichkeitsrec), in Ott,
Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin, Springer,
52-57.
Seidl, Christian (1994), Marktgerechte versus kollektivistische Sozialpolitik (Libertarian versus
Collectivist Social Policy), in Hermann-Pillath, Carsten, Schlecht, Otto and Wnsche, Horst F.
(eds), Marktwirtschaft als Aufgabe, Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft im bergang vom Plan zum
Markt, Bd. III der Grundtexte zur Sozialen Marktwirtschaft der Ludwig-Erhard-Stiftung,
Stuttgart, Gustav Fischer, 363-376.
Seidl, Christian (1997), Das Wesen liberaler Rechte (On the Essence of Liberal Rights), in Ott, Claus
and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Analyse des Rechts, Fnftes Travemnder
Symposium zur Analyse des Rechts.
Seidl, Christian, Binder, Martin, Ruppe, Hans-Georg, Steinhfler, Karl and Tichy, Gunther (1981),
Sozialpolitik und Umverteilung. Eine kritische Analyse der konomischen und juristischen
Probleme aus sterreichischer Sicht (Social Policy and Redistribution. A Critical Analysis of the
Legal and Economic Conditions in Austria), Wien.
Siekmann, Hans (1996), Corporate Governance und ffentlich-rechtliche Unternehmen (Corporate
Governance and Public Enterprises), in Schenk, Karl-Ernst, Schmidtchen, Dieter and Streit,
Manfred E. (eds), Vom Hoheitsstaat zum Konsensualstaat, Neue Formen der Kooperation
zwischen Staat und Privaten Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie 15, Tbingen, Mohr.
Sinn, Hans-Werner (1989), Kommentar on Magoulas, Verbraucherschutz als Problem asymmetrischer
Informationskosten, in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), Allekationseffizienz in der
Rechtsordnung, Berlin, Springer, 81-90.
Spindler, Gerald (1988), Geschftsgrundlage und Steuerrechtsnderungen (Changes of Tax Law and
their Impact on Long Term Contracts - an Economic Analysis), in Finsinger and Simon (eds),
Recht und Risiko. Juristische und konomische Analysen, Mnchen, Florentz, 288-325.
Spindler, Gerald (1993), Recht und Konzern - Interdependenzen der Rechts- und
Unternehmensentwicklung in Deutschland und den USA zwischen 1870 und 1933 (The
Evolution of Corporate Law, Tax Law and Antitrust Law and their Impact on the Structures of
Corporations Comparing the History of the US to Germany), Tbingen, Mohr.
218 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Terberger, Eva (1994a), Kommentar zu Picot, Arnold/Dietl, Helmut, Informations (de-) regulierung
am Kapitalmarkt aus Institutionenkonomischer Sicht (New Institutional Economics and the
(De-)Regulation of Insider Trading), 13 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, 143-148.
Terberger, Eva (1994b), Neo-institutionalistische Anstze, Entstehung und Wandel - Anspruch und
Wirklichkeit (New Institutional Economics - Origin and Change, Scientific Claims and
Achievements), Wiesbaden, Gabler.
Terberger, Eva (1995), Bankenaufsicht (Regulation of Banks), in Gerke, Wolfgang and Steiner,
Manfred (eds), Handwrterbuch des Finanz- und Bankwesens, Band 6, 2. Aufl., Stuttgart,
151-163.
Terberger, Eva (1996), Kommentar zu Siekmann, Helmut, Corporate Governance und
ffentlich-rechtlich organisierte Unternehmen (Corporate Governance and Public Enterprises),
15 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie.
Terhart, Peter (1995), Chapter 11 Bankruptcy Code, Eine Alternative fr Deutschland? (Chapter 11
Bankruptcy Code, An alternative for Germany?), Frankfurt an Main, Lang Verlag.
Teutemann, Manfred (1992), Rationale Kompetenzverteilung im Rahmen der europischen
Integration. Ein Beitrag zur finanzwirtschaftlichen Ordnungspolitik (Rational Allocation of
Competency and the European Integration. A Contribution to the Constitutional Politics of Public
Economics), Berlin, Duncker and Humblot.
Tietzel, Manfred (1981a), Die Rationalittsannahme in den Wirtschaftswissenschaften oder Der homo
oeconomicus und seine Verwandten (The Rationality Assumption in Economics or the Homo
Oeconomicus and his Relatives), 32 Jahrbuch fr Sozialwissenschaft, 115-136.
Tietzel, Manfred (1981b), Die konomie der Property Rights, Ein berblick (Economics of Property
Rights), 30 Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftspolitik, 207-243.
Tietzel, Manfred (1981c), Die konomie Der Property Rights: Ein berblick (The Economics of
Property Rights: A Survey), 30 Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftspolitik, 207-243.
Tietzel, Manfred (1982), Was kann man von der Theorie rationaler Erwartungen rationalerweise
erwarten? (Rational Expectations about the Theory of Rational Expectations), 15(4) Kredit und
Kapital, 492-516.
Tietzel, Manfred (1983), Wirtschaftstheorie als allgemeine Theorie des menschlichen Verhaltens. Eine
Analyse der New Home Economics (Economic Theory as a General Theory of Human Behavior),
32(3) Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftspolitik, 225-242.
Tietzel, Manfred (1986), Zur Entstehung des Privateigentums (On the Evolution of Private Property),
37 Ordo, 105-127.
Tietzel, Manfred (1988), Zur konomischen Theorie des Betrgens und Flschens (On the Economic
Theory of Fraud and Counterfeiting), 204 Jahrbuch fr Nationalkonomie und Statistik, 17-34.
Tietzel, Manfred (1989), Probleme der asymmetrischen Informationsverteilung beim Gter- und
Leistungstausch (Problems of Asymmetric Information in the Trade of Goods and Services), in
Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), Allekationseffizienz in der Rechtsordnung, Berlin,
Springer, 52-63.
Tietzel, Manfred (1991a), Kommentar (on Schfer, konomische Analyse von Aufklrungspflichten
and Ott, Vorvertragliche Aufklrungspflichten) (Comment), in Ott, Claus and Schfer,
Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin, Springer, 163-166.
220 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Tietzel, Manfred (1991b), Der Neue Institutionalismus auf dem Hintergrund der alten
Ordnungsdebatte (The New Institutionalism and the Old Debate on Economic Order), 10
Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, 3-37.
Tietzel, Manfred (1994), Urheberrechte im Zeitalter der Fotokopie. Die konomik von
Verwertungsgesellschaften am Beispiel der VG Wort (Copyright Law in the Age of the Photocopy,
The Economics of Resale Royalty Organizations), in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds),
Okonomische Analyse der rechtlichen Organisation von Innovationen, Tbingen, Mohr,
128-147.
Tietzel, Manfred and Weber, M. (1991), Von Betrgern, Blendern und Opportunisten. Eine
konomische Analyse (Betrayers, Cheaters, and Opportunists), 40 Zeitschrift fr
Wirtschaftspolitik, 109-137.
Todt, Horst (1991), Freiheit und Utilitarismus (Freedom and Utilitarianism), in Ott, Claus and
Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin, Springer, 1-17.
Trimarchi, Pietro (1972), Die Regelung der Vertragshaftung aus konomischer Sicht (The Regulation
of Contractual Liability from an Economic Point of View), 136 Zeitschrift fr das gesamte
Handels- und Wirtschaftsrecht, 118-138.
Trimarchi, Pietro (1989), Der Wegfall der Geschftsgrundlage aus allokativer Sicht - Kommentar (The
Frustration of Contract from an Allocative Sig), in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds),
Allekationseffizienz in der Rechtsordnung, Berlin, Springer, 163-167.
Vanberg, Viktor J. (1982a), Verbrechen, Strafe und Abschreckung, die Theor (Crime, Sanction and
Deterrence: The Theory of), Tbingen, Mohr, 50 p.
Vanberg, Viktor J. (1982b), Markt und Organisation. Individualistische Sozialtheorie und das
Problem korporativen Handelns (Market and Organization. Individualist Social Theory and the
Problem of Corporate Action), Tbingen.
Vanberg, Viktor J. (1982c), Das Unternehmen als Sozialverband. Zur Sozialtheorie der Unternehmung
und zur juristsichen Diskussion um ein neues Unternehmensrecht (The Firm as a Social
Organization. The Social Theory of the Firm and the Legal Discussion on a New Law of Business
Corporations), 1 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, 276-307.
Vanberg, Viktor J. (1983a), Organisationsziele und individuelle Interessen (Organizational Goals and
Individual Interests), 34 Soziale Welt, 171-187.
Vanberg, Viktor J. (1983b), Der individualistische Ansatz zu einer Theorie der Entstehung und
Entwicklung von Institutionen (The Individualistic Approach to a Theory of the Emergence and
the Development of Institutions), 2 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische konomie, 50-69.
Vanberg, Viktor J. (1984), Unsichtbare Hand Erklrung und soziale Normen (Invisible Hand
Explanation and Social Norms), in Todt, H. (ed.), Normgeleitetes verhalten in den
Sozialwissenschaften Schriften des VEreins fr Socialpolitik, Berlin, 115-144.
Vanberg, Viktor J. (1995), Ordnungspolitik und die Unvermeidbarkeit des Wettbewerbs
(Constitutional Politics and the Unavoidability of Competition), in Francke, H.-H. (ed.),
konomischer Individualismus und freiheitliche Verfassung, Freiburg, 187-211.
Vth, Andreas (1987), Die Wettbewerbskonzeption des Europischen Ger (The Competition Concept
of the European Court), Bayreuth, P.C.O.-Verlag, 298 p.
Voigt, Stefan (1991), Die evolutionsorientierte Theorie der Verfassung - Bemerkungen zum Ansatz
von Hayeks (The Evolutionary Theory of Constitution. Remarks on Hayeks Approach), 40
Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftspolitik, 93-107.
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 221
Voigt, Stefan (1992a), Die Welthandelsordnung zwischen Konflikt und Stabilitt - Konfliktpotentiale
und Konfliktlsungsmechanismen (The World Trade System between Conflict and Stability),
Freiburg.
Voigt, Stefan (1992b), Das Lizenzauktionsverfahren, Ein zielkonformes Instrument zur Regulierung
lokaler Kabelfernsehstationen? Eine Analyse der anglo-amerikanischen Diskussion und Praxis
(The Licence Auctioning System as an Instrument to Regulate Local Cable Stations), 17 The
European Journal of Communications, 67-90.
Voigt, Stefan (1994a), Die kontraktorientierte Theorie der Verfassung - Anmerkungen zum Ansatz
Buchanans (A Contractarian Theory of Constitution. Remarks on Buchanans Approach), 11
Homo Oeconomicus, 173-209.
Voigt, Stefan (1994b), Der Weg zur Freiheit - Mgliche Implikationen Hayekscher Hypothesen fr
die Transformation der Wirtschaftssysteme Mittel- und Osteuropas (The Road to Freedom. Possible
Implications of Hayekian Hypothesises for the Transformation of the Economies in Middle- and
Eastern Europe), in Hlscher, J. et al (ed), Bedingungen konomischer Entwicklung in
Zentralosteuropa, Bd. 2, Marburg, Metropolis, 63-105.
Voigt, Stefan (1996), Die konstitutionelle konomik als Herausforderung fr die Theorie der
Wirtschaftspolitik - zugleich eine Skizze zur Weiterentwicklung einer konomischen Theorie der
Verfassung erscheint (Constitutional Economics as a Challenge for the Theory of Economic
Policy), in Pies, Ingo and Leschke, Martin (eds), James Buchanans konstitutionelle konomik,
Tbingen, Mohr/Siebeck.
Voigt, Stefan and Kiwit, Daniel (1995), berlegungen zum institutionellen Wandel unter
Bercksichtigung des Verhltnisses interner und externer Institutionen (Reflections on Institutional
Change with Respect to the Relation between Internal and External Institutions), 46 Ordo,
117-147.
Vollmer, Lothar (1997), Die Sondermrkte im Spannungsfeld von nationalen und europischen
Regulierungs- und Deregulierungsaktivitten (Tensions between national and European Regulation
and Deregulation), in Kruse, Jrn, Stockmann, Kurt and Vollmer, Lothar (eds),
Wettbewerbspolitik im Spannungsfeld nationaler und internationaler Kartellrechtsordnungen.
Festschrift fr Ingo Schmidt zum 65. Geburtstag, Baden-Baden, Nomos, 289 ff.
Von Randow, Philipp (1989), Kommentar (On Adams, Warum kein Ersatz von
Nichtvermgensschden), in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds),Allekationseffizienz in der
Rechtsordnung, Berlin, Springer, 218-225.
Von Weizscker, Carl-Christian (1984), Was leistet die Property Rights Theorie fr aktuelle
wirtschaftspolitische Fragen? (What Brings the Property Rights Theory for Economi), in
Neumann, M. (ed.), Ansprache, Eigentums- und Verfgungsrechte, Berlin, Duncker and
Humblot, 123-152.
Von Weizscker, Carl-Christian (1987), Der Markt fr unternehmensgebundene Ressourcen (The
Market for Enterprise Restricted Resources), 126 XXXStrukturwandel und Wirtschaftsord nung,
Referate des XX.FIW-Symposiums - FIW Schriftenreihe, 31-42.
Walwei, U., konomische Analyse arbeitsrechtlicher Regelungen am Beispiel des Kndigungsschutzes
(Economic Analysis of Protection Against Dismissal as an Example for Worker Protection Laws),
63(6) WSI-Mitteilungen, 392-400.
222 Law And Economics In Germany 0330
Willgerodt, Hans (eds), Germanys Social Market Economy, Origins and Evolution, London,
Macmillan, 106-123.
Watrin, Christian (1990a), Ordnungspolitische Defizite der DDR-Wirtschaft und Mglichkeiten zu
deren berwindung durch marktwirtschaftliche Reformen (Central Planning and the
Transformation to a Market Order), 37 Beihefte der Konjunkturpolitik, 9-22.
Watrin, Christian (1990b), Vom sozialistischen zum privaten Eigentum (From Socialist to Private
Property), 35 Hamburger Jahrbuch fr Wirtschaft und Gesellschaftspolitik, 119-128.
Watrin, Christian (1994), Die Gesellschaft freier Menschen - Bemerkungen zu Erich Hoppmanns
Arbeiten ber Freiheit und marktwirtschaftliche Ordnung (The Free Society - Erich Hoppmann on
Freedom and Economic Order), in Mschel, W., Streit, M. and Witt, U. (ed.), Marktwirtschaft
und Rechtsordnung, Festschrift fr Erich Hoppmann, Baden-Baden, 211-223.
Watrin, Christian (1995), Nutzen und Kosten des Rechts (Economics of Law), in Mantl, Wolfgang
(ed.), Effizienz der Gesetzesproduktion, Abbau der Regelungsdichte im internationalen
Vergleich Schriftenreihe des Zentrums fr angewandte Politikforschung Bd. 7, Wien, 239-244.
Watrin, Christian (1996), Der Wettbewerb der Ordnungen als Entdeckungsverfahren fr eine
nachhaltige Entwicklung (Korreferat) (Sustainable Development and Competition Among
Economic Systems as a Discovery Process), in Gerken, Lder (ed.), Ordnungspolitische
Grundfragen einer Politik der Nachhaltigkeit/Walter Eucken Institut, Baden-Baden, 103-113.
Weck-Hannemann, Hannelore (1991), Politische konomie des Protektionismus. Eine Institutionelle
Analyse (Political Economics of Protectionism. An Institutional Analysis), in Siebke, Jrgen (ed.),
Monetre Konfliktfelder der Weltwirtschaft. Schriftenreihe des Vereins fr Socialpolitik, NF
210, Berlin, Duncker and Humblot, 125-142.
Weck-Hannemann, Hannelore (1992), Politische konomie des Protektionismus. Eine Institutionelle
und Empirische Analyse (Political Economics of Protectionism. An Institutional and Empirical
Analysis), 17 Wirtschaftswissenschaft.
Weck-Hannemann, Hannelore (1996), Frauenerwerbsttigkeit und Familienbesteuerung (Female
Employment and Family Taxation), in Thni, Erich and Winner, Hannes (eds), Die Familie im
Sozialstaat. Familienbesteuerung aus konomischer und juristischer Sicht Verffentlichungen
der Universitt Innsbruck 216, Innsbruck, 191-207.
Weck-Hannemann, Hannelore and Pommerehne, Werner W. (1989), Einkommenssteuerhinterziehung
in der Schweiz. Eine empirische Analyse (An Empirical Analysis of Income Tax Evasion in
Switzerland), 125(4) Schweizerische Zeitschrift fr Volkswirtschaft und Statistik, 515-556.
Wegehenkel, Lothar (1980a), Transaktionskosten, Wirtschaftssystem und Unternehmertum
(Transaction Costs, Economic System and Entrepreneurship), Tbingen, Mohr, 77 p.
Wegehenkel, Lothar (1980b), Coase Theorem und Marktsystem (Coase Theorem and the Market
System), Tbingen, Mohr, 138 p.
Wegehenkel, Lothar (1989), Kommentar (on Kndgen and van Randow, Sanktionen bei
Vertragsverletzung), in Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), Allekationseffizienz in der
Rechtsordnung, Berlin, Springer, 141-145.
Wehrt, Klaus (1991a), Die Qualittshaftung des Verkufers aus konomischer Sicht (Economic
Analysis of the Sellers Liability for the Quality of his Good), in Ott, Claus and Schfer,
0330 Law and Economics in Germany 225
Abstract
1. Introduction
228
0335 Law and Economics in Greece 229
have used mostly German bibliography. This is largely the result of the heavy
influence of German law on Greek law (especially civil law). As a result, the
Greek scholars with a doctorate from a common law country (especially from
the United States) are very few in number. This is the basic reason for the
embryonic status of law and economics in Greece.
Many papers have been published from 1960 to the early 1980s studying the
relationship between law and economics and emphasizing the need for a
broader collaboration. These papers were often overly theoretical, without
potential application to actual legal problems and with no discussion of the
developments in the Anglo-Saxon legal world. The discussion revolved around
the work of Weber, Stammler and Marx, with some references to the
socialization of the economy after World War II (particularly the excellent
papers by Mantzoufas, 1960; Karakantas, 1973; Rokas, 1980, all three
professors of civil law in economic departments, Loukopoulos, 1962, as well
as Liakopoulos, 1982, for a typical Marxist, critical-legal approach). Another
extensively discussed problem was state intervention in the economy and the
ensuing constitutional issues from the antinomies created in a mixed economic
system (see Manitakis, 1975; Stathopoulos, 1981; Gemtos, 1990b). Finally,
a number of legal scholars have treated purely economic problems with the
intention of informing their colleagues of parallel developments in another
social science (see in particular the brief discussion of the Laffer curve by
Rodios, 1986, and the excellent survey by Gavrielidou,1990, of the economic
literature on taxation and the work of four scholars: Milton Friedman, Nicholas
Kaldor, Firmin Oules and Maurice Allais).
The scholar who first introduced EAL to the Greek legal world is the former
Rector of the University of Athens, Prof. Petros Gemtos. Gemtos (a specialist
in the philosophy and methodology of science and a holder of two doctorates,
one in law and another in economics from the University of Tbingen) is also
the central figure of Greek EAL. Prof. Gemtos was not only the first Greek
EAL scholar, but made original contributions, presented almost simultaneously
with the expansion of EAL in the USA in the early 1970s.
In his first and seminal EAL paper (Gemtos, 1976) on the legal problems
created by hyperinflation (in constitutional, tax and contract law), he not only
studied a legal problem using the tools of economics, but he extensively
discussed the usefulness of positive economics to the analysis and solution of
legal problems (see p. 833 for some insightful remarks and also pp. 836-846).
This paper was an exemplary application of his research program (formulated
and expounded as early as 1974, see Gemtos, 1974) for the association of legal
science with positive social science. In a second endeavor to treat legal
230 Law and Economics in Greece 0335
law scholar, Ioannis Rokas (1980), who completed his graduate studies in
Germany (Berlin) and now teaches at the Athens University of Economics and
Business. Rokas, like Gemtos, draws heavily upon German bibliography for the
relations between economy and law and briefly discusses the new field of
EAL. Although his intention was not to present EAL as a separate discipline
or school, his target was the lack of communication between law and
economics. These two disciplines are related internally to such an unusual
degree that it creates problems to both lawyers and economists who deal mainly
with the same object. Rokas calls for a standing interdisciplinary contact,
citing a number of examples where the convergence of law and economics is
inevitable. Rokas defends the old law and economics with clarity and zeal.
This lack of communication between lawyers and economists is bridged
temporarily by the first and only attempt in Greek legal scholarship (after
Gemtos, 1976, but also see Delivanes, 1954, for an early treatment of a legal
issue by an economist) of Phanes Christophorou (1986), a lawyer with the
European Commission (LL.M. from Harvard), to use economic analysis in
treating a legal issue, that is antitrust law (what else!). His interpretation of
Greek antitrust law is informed by an extensive critical discussion of the
economic literature (ibid., pp. 898-909) with the purpose of influencing the
implementation of the law (pp. 900, 906-907) (Similarly, see the brief
discussion of the economics of crime by Calliope Spinellis, 1992, a criminal
law professor with a doctorate from the University of Chicago).
Michalis Tsibris (1989) was the first to present an up-to-date introduction
to EAL. His paper consists of a fair presentation and discussion of the leading
theories and basic concepts and discusses various examples from torts and
property law (with an extensive reference to the Coase theorem). Tsibris has
many reservations concerning the use of efficiency as a criterion and the
compatibility of the two discourses, and although he is outright negative to the
normative EAL, he is decisively positive toward the use of economic analysis
by lawyers. Tsibris (a commercial law scholar) holds an LL.M. degree from
Harvard, where the influence of Frank Michelman on his thinking has proven
greater than that of Steven Shavell, as this article reveals.
A similar introductory paper has been written by another
American-educated scholar, Thanos Papaioannou (LL.M. and doctorate on
labor law from the University of Pennsylvania). This article is the most typical
of the attitude of Greek legal scholars (especially the ones specializing in
economic law), who are receptive to the use of economics by lawyers, but at
the same time quite suspicious of both the unintended and the intended effects
of the application of economic theories to what they perceive as the coherent
logical construct of Greek law. The title of the article is telling and, starting
from the first introductory paragraph, Papaioannou (1991) informs the reader
that EAL is a movement parallel and congenial to the wave of the reappraisal
232 Law and Economics in Greece 0335
3. Education
The discussion thus far has shown that Greek EAL is a newly-emergent field,
still taking hesitant infantile steps. There is a small number of scholars who
work in the field (or who at least have an interest in the field), largely due to
the nature of technical doctrinalism that characterizes Greek legal theory and
the absence of institutionalization. It is extremely difficult to expect a change
of attitude on the part of the great majority of Greek lawyers (even scholars)
who are both formalists and positivists. Nevertheless, some recent
developments, such as the founding of the School of Judges in Thessaloniki
(that emphasizes the study of social science), as well as the increasing
specialization and the tendency for the continuation of legal studies at the
graduate level displayed by Greek lawyers, are promising signs for the future.
Starting from the academic year 1995-1996, Nikolaos Intzessiloglou
(Professor of Sociology of Law at the University of Thessaloniki and the Greek
coordinator of the Erasmus Programme in Law and Economics) has dedicated
the second year of the graduate course of Sociology of Law to EAL. In
collaboration with Aristides Hatzis, he introduced the basic concepts of EAL
with a parallel discussion of philosophical, epistemological and methodological
issues. The readings consisted mainly of Cento Veljanovskis The Economics
of Law: An Introductory Text (London, IEA, 1990) and also included a number
of introductory articles in English, French and Greek, and notes prepared by
Hatzis (1997a). The first courses of EAL in Greece were very successful,
mainly because they were addressed to graduate students (all of them being
lawyers or judges) with a manifested interest in jurisprudence (most of them
had sociology of law as their major). After the completion of the course, many
graduate students showed a particular interest in continuing their studies in
EAL.
Prof. Intzessiloglou, as the founder and editor of Aissymnetes (an
interdisciplinary law journal) has promoted the discussion on EAL, dedicating
0335 Law and Economics in Greece 235
the sixth volume of the journal to this discussion (see Evangelopoulos, 1996;
Hatzis, 1996; Reynolds, 1996). This symposium includes an article by the
Professor of the University of Macedonia Vaios Lazos (1996) on the economics
of crime. Lazos, an economist who is not at all influenced by EAL or the work
of Gary Becker, comes to essentially similar conclusions.
4. Prospects
The prospects for EAL in Greece are more than favorable. In the following
years, the first special chairs for EAL are expected to be established by the
Universities of Athens and Thessaloniki. There is already a number of graduate
students with a great interest in the field and the number of publications is
steadily growing.
But the most significant development is the use of economic analysis by
mainstream legal scholars. In 1991, Prof. Panagiotis Papanikolaou, a contract
law scholar at the University of Athens, published a remarkable monograph on
freedom of contracts, using the findings of EAL in his discussion (Magoulas
and Jost, 1985, preceded him but they are professors in Germany). His book
(together with all the aforementioned work) managed to familiarize the Greek
legal world with EAL. As a result, in recent textbooks by some of the most
prominent civil and commercial law professors at the University of Athens,
there were many references to EAL (see for example Michales Stathopoulos,
General Law of Obligations, 2nd edn, Athens-Komotini, Ant. N. Sakkoulas,
1993, pp. 11-13, Leonidas Georgakopoulos, Handbook of Commercial Law,
vol. 1.1, 2nd edn, Athens, P. Sakkoulas, 1995 and Apostolos Georgiades,
General Principles of Civil Law, Athens-Komotini, Ant. N. Sakkoulas, 2nd
edn, 1997, pp. 67-68, all in Greek). This is more important than it appears.
Greek legal scholars are hostile to almost any interdisciplinary or philosophical
treatment of private law. These scholars present (particularly in textbooks, not
treatises) EAL, and EAL alone, as a very interesting (but also dangerous if
misused) theory of adjudication and interpretation.
The much-needed next step for economic analysis of law in Greece is its full
institutionalization and its extensive use for the analysis of legal problems.
However, such a prospect seems quite remote today.
Acknowledgments
Christoforou, Phanes (1986), Prostasia tou Antagonismou kai Oikonomike Analyse sta Plaisia tou
Nomou 703/77 (Protection of Market Competition and Economic Analysis under Law 703/77),
6 Ellenike Epitheorese Europaikou Dikaiou, 879-927.
Delivanes, D.I. (1954), Ai Oikonomikai Synepeiai tou Enoikiostasiou (The Economic Consequences
of Rent Control), 21 Ephemeris ton Hellenon Nomikon, 1106-1111.
Evangelopoulos, Panagiotis (1996), E Analyse ton Periousiakon Dikaiomaton kai e Ideologia tes
Eleutheres Agoras (Property Rights Analysis and Free-Market Ideology), 6 Aissymnetes.
Evangelopoulos, Panagiotis (1997), Oikonomike Analyse ton Periousiakon Dikaiomaton kai o
Mechanismos tes Agoras (Economic Analysis of Property Rights and the Market Mechanism),
PhD Thesis, University of Athens, Dept. of Economics. Reprinted as monograph: Athens, Libro,
1999.
Evangelopoulos, Panagiotis (1998), O Kanon tes Pleiopsefias kai o Prosdiorismos ton Dikaiomaton
(The Majority Rule and the Stipulation of Rights), 1 Episteme kai Koinonia, 69-81.
Gavrielidou, Alexandra A. (1990), Enallaktikes Protaseis sto Phoro Eisodematos (Alternative
Proposals to the Income Tax), 38 Nomiko Vema, 382-400.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1974), E Provlematike ton Axiologikon Kriseon stis Koinonikes Epistemes (The
Problem of Normative Judgments in the Social Sciences), 4 Philosophia, 120-136.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1976), Antimetopises tou Plethorismou os Oikonomikon kai Nomikon Provlema.
Sygchronos Symvole eis ten Diereunesin ton Themeliakon Scheseon ton Pragmatologikon kai ton
Kanonistikon Epistemon (The Treatment of Inflation as an Economic and Legal Problem.
Contemporary Contribution to the Examination of the Fundamental Relations between the Positive
and Normative Sciences), 30 Harmenopoulos, 830-846.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1988), Methodologika Programmata sten Oikonomike kai te Nomike Episteme kai
to Provlema tes Diepistemonikes tous Synergasias (Methodological Programs in Economics and
Legal Science and the Problem of their Interdisciplinary Collaboration), 36 Nomiko Vema,
1192-1202, reprinted in (1990), 39 Cyprus Law Review, 4627-4643.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1990a), Law and Economics: Methodological Problems in their Interdisciplinary
Cooperation, in Nicolacopoulos, Pantelis D. (ed.), Greek Studies in the Philosophy and History
of Science (Boston Studies in the Philosophy of Science, vol. 121), Dordrecht, Kluwer, 239-250.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1990b), Oikonomike Eleutheria kai Prostasia tou Katanalote se mia Sygxrone
Demokratike Koinonia (Economic Freedom and Consumer Protection in a Contemporary
Democratic Society), 16 Syntagma, 19-29.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1991), Thesmikes Analyseis sten Oikonomike: E Theoria ton Praxiakon
Dikaiomaton (Institutional Analyses in Economics: The Property Rights Theory), 4 Aissymnetes,
27-48.
0335 Law and Economics in Greece 237
Gemtos, Petros A. (1995), Oikonomika kai Dikaio: Oikonomika gia Nomikous, tomos A:
Methodologika kai Oikonomika Themelia (Law and Economics: Economics for Lawyers, vol. I:
Methodological and Economic Foundations), Athens-Komotini, Ant. N. Sakkoulas Publications.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1998), Oi Theoretikes Vaseis tes Oikonomikes Analyses tou Dikaiou (The
Theoretical Bases of Economic Analysis of Law), 46 Nomiko Vema.
Georgakopoulos, Nikos L. (1995), Peri Tmematikou Daneismou apo ten Amerikanike Nomike Skepse
(On the Partial Borrowing from the American Legal Thought), 43 Nomiko Vema, 799-807.
Georgakopoulos, Nikos L. (1997a), O Cardozo tou Posner san Eisagoge sten Amerikanike Nomike
Skepse (Posners Cardozo as an Introduction to American Legal Theory), in Posner (1997), i-xi.
Georgakopoulos, Nikos L. (1997b), Kritiko Semeioma: O Pragmatismos tou Posner (Critical Note:
Posners Pragmatism), in Posner (1997), 175-198.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1991), Ronald H. Coase: Nobel Oikonomikon 1991 (Ronald H. Coase: Nobel
Laureate in Economics, 1991), 68 Epikentra, 77-84.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1993), Comments on Bertrand Lemmeniciers paper Social Justice and its
Controversies, 4 Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines, 263-268.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1996), Neofileleutherismos, Dikaio kai Oikonomike Analyse ton Thesmon:
Eisagoge ste Melete ton Neon Oikonomikon Theorion gia to Dikaio, ten Koinonia kai ten Politike
(The so-called Neo-Liberalism, the Law and the Economic Analysis of Institutions: Introduction
to the Study of the New Economic Theories on Law, Society and Politics), 6 Aissymnetes.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1997a), Eisagoge sten Oikonomike Analyse tou Dikaiou (Introduction to the
Economic Analysis of Law), Aristotle University of Thessaloniki School of Law and Economics,
Department of History, Philosophy and Sociology of Law.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1997b), Krise tou Dikaiou e Krise tes Theorias tou? Prolegomena se mia
Oikonomike Theoria tou Dikaiou ton Symvaseon (A Crisis of Law or a Crisis of its Theory?
Prolegomena of an Economic Theory of Contract Law), working paper presented in a workshop
under the auspices of Panteios University.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1997c), The Absence of Theory: Common vs. Civil Contract Law, paper
presented at the XIVth Annual Conference of the European Association of Law and Economics,
held at Barcelona, September 4-6, 1997.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1998a), Mancur Olson, Jr. (1932-1998), 1 Episteme kai Koinonia, 195-202.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1998b), An Economic Theory of Greek Contract Law, PhD Thesis, University
of Chicago Law School.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1999a), Crime, in OHara, Phillip (ed.), Encyclopedia of Political Economy,
London, Routledge, Vol. I, 163-166.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1999b), Rent-Seeking and Vested Interests, in OHara, Phillip (ed.),
Encyclopedia of Political Economy, London, Routledge, Vol. II, 974-977.
Karakantas, Stylianos (1973), Oikonomia kai Dikaion (Law and Economics), 27 Harmenopoulos,
257-265.
Kozyris, Phaedon I. (1991), Treis Provlematismoi sten Amerikanike Theoria tou Dikaiou (Three
Deliberations in American Jurisprudence), 39 Nomiko Vema, 715-728.
238 Law and Economics in Greece 0335
Kozyris, Phaedon I. (1996), Protaseis Dianemetikes Dikaiosynes sto Telos tes Istorias: Ta Kyria
Erotemata me Apla Logia (Proposals of Distributive Justice in the End of History: Basic
Questions Made Easy), 3 Kritike Epitheorese, 23-81.
Lazos, Vaios (1996), E Kampyle Adiaforias enos Eglematos (The Indifference Curve of a Crime), 6
Aissymnetes.
Liakopoulos, Thanases (1982), Dikaio kai Oikonomia (Law and Economics), 2 Dikaio & Politike,
111-133.
Loukopoulos, Andreas D. (1962), Emporikon Dikaion kai oi Neoi Prosanatolismoi tes Oikonomias
(Commercial Law and the New Directions of Economy), 29 Ephemeris ton Hellenon Nomikon,
353-362.
Magoulas, Georgios and Fritz, Jost (1985), Oikonomike Analyse tou Dikaiou. - Provlemata ton
Katanalotikon Pistoseon se Allodapous Ergazomenous kai Symvole sten Ermeneia tes 138
GermAK (Problems of Consumer Credit to Foreign Employees and a Contribution to the
Interpretation of 138 of the German Civil Code), 6 Scientific Review of the Thessaloniki Bar
Association, 203-217.
Manitakis, Antonios (1975), Lantinomie entre la libert du commerce et de lindustrie et la
rgulation administrative de lconomie (en droit belge et en droit franais), Bruxelles, Centre
Interuniversitaire de Droit Public.
Mantzoufas, Georgios A. (1960), Oikonomikon Dikaion (Economic Law), in Oikomike kai Logistike
Egkyklopedeia (Encyclopedia of Economics and Accounting), Athens.
Papaioannou, Thanos (1991), E Oikonomike Analyse tou Dikaiou: Mia Endiaferousa alla kai
Epikindyne Theoria (Economic Analysis of Law: An Interesting but Dangerous Theory), 4
Aissymnetes, 51-65.
Papanikolaou, Panagiotis A. (1991), Peri ton Orion tes Prostateutikes Paremvaseos tou Dikaste ste
Symvase: Pros mia Genike Theoria Peri Katachreseos tes Symvatikes Eleutherias (On the
Boundaries of the Paternalistic Intervention of the Judge to a Contract: Towards a General Theory
on the Abuse of Freedom of Contracts), Athens-Komotini, Ant. N. Sakkoulas Publications.
Posner, Richard A. (1997), O Dikastes Cardozo: Mia Melete tes Physes tes Phemes (translation in
Greek of Richard Posners Cardozo, A Study in Reputation, Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1991, by Nikos L. Georgakopoulos), Athens-Komotini, Ant. N. Sakkoulas.
Provopoulos, George and Zambaras, Athanassios (1991), Testing for Causality Between Government
Spending and Taxation, 68 Public Choice, 277-282.
Reynolds, Noel B. (1996), Rule of Law in Legal and Economic Theory (Translated in Greek and
published in Aissymnetes, 6), in Kotsiris, L.E. (ed.), Law at the Turn of the 20th Century,
Thessaloniki, Sakkoulas Publications, 355-374.
Rodios, Nikos D. (1986), E Kampyle tou Laffer e Peri tes Phthinousas Apodoseos tes Phorologias (The
Laffer Curve or On the Diminishing Return of Taxation), 53 Ephemeris ton Hellenon Nomikon,
216-218.
Rokas, Ioannis (1980), Oikonomike kai Nomike Episteme: Eisagogikes Paratereseis epi ton Scheseon
Oikonomias kai Dikaiou (Economics and Legal Science: Introductory Remarks on the Relations
between Economy and Law), in Zepos, P., Rammos, G., Rokas, K. and Loukopoulos, A. (eds),
Afieroma eis Alexandron N. Tsirintanin (Volume in Honor of Alexandros N. Tsirintanis),
Athens-Komotini, Ant. N. Sakkoulas Publications, 317-347.
Spinellis, Calliope D. (1992), Victim-Oriented Crime Prevention through the Prism of the (New)
School of Social Defense and the School of Economic Analysis of Law, in X (ed.), Panegyrikos
0335 Law and Economics in Greece 239
Tomos gia ta Eikosachrona tou Hellenikou Tmematos tes Diethnous Etairias Koinonikes
Amynes (Commemorative Volume for the Twenty Years of the Greek Section of the International
Society of Social Defense), Thessaloniki.
Stathopoulos, Michales (1981), Oikonomike Eleutheria, Oikonomiko Systema kai Syntagma
(Economic Freedom, Economic System and the Constitution), 7 Syntagma, 517-532.
Symposium (1996), Oikonomike Analyse tou Dikaiou (Economic Analysis of Law), 6 Aissymnetes.
Tsaoussis-Hatzis, Aspasia (1999a), Changes in Greek Marriage and Divorce Law: The Impact of the
Family Law Reform of 1983', in Miller, Robin R. and Browning, Sandra Lee, Till Death Do Us
Part: A Multicultural Anthology on Marriage, Greenwich: JAI Press.
Tsaoussis-Hatzis, Aspasia (1999b), The Social and Economic Consequences of the Greek Divorce
Law Reform of 1983, PhD Thesis, University of Chicago Law School.
Tsibris, Michalis R. (1989), Oikonomike Analyse tou Dikaiou: To Epomeno Vema (Economic
Analysis of Law: The Next Step), 37 Nomiko Vema, 574-586.
0340
LAW AND ECONOMICS IN HUNGARY
Andrs Saj and Kinga Ptervri
Central European University (Budapest) - Legal Studies
Copyright 1999 Andrs Saj and Kinga Ptervri
Abstract
This chapter describes the state of law and economics in Hungary in 1996.
Its main conclusion is that little work has been done in this field. Earlier it
was the socialist economic system which hindered the introduction of this
sort of analysis. But - contrary to our expectations expressed in the 1992
precursor of this article - the creation of a market economy did not lead to
the establishment of law and economics in Hungary as a side-effect. The
main factors which prevented this were the nature of the Hungarian legal
system and legal thinking and the rigid divisions within the academic
system.
JEL classification: K00
Keywords: Hungarian Legal System, Research, Teaching, Hungarian
Academic System
1. Introduction
As you will see below the numbers of items in the bibliography of this
chapter is smaller than that of the 1992 list. The main reason for this is that
we have decided to change the principle upon which the selection is based.
When compiling the 1992 bibliography we construed law and economics in
a very broad sense, which now seems to be far too broad. The reason why
this broad construction seemed justified to us back then had to do with some
promising starts at the ELTE Law School, for example the extra-curriculum
seminars on law and economics in 1987 held by Andrs Saj, which are no
longer available.
In the 1970s and very early 1980s the non-conceptual, case-by-case oriented
command market system was often referred to. This term implies a softened
planned economy, in which state enterprises have some degree of legally
guaranteed autonomy in executing the central plans, as opposed to the strict
command economy characteristic of the 1950s and early 1960s, in which the
240
0340 Law and Economics in Hungary 241
state exercises discretionary and direct control. However mild the system
had gradually become, it was still in control of the economic regulations,
thus leaving no room for considerations of efficiency analysis. Even though
students of law had to study economics, the kind of economics they were
exposed to was Marxist economic theory, the spirit of which is quite alien to
that of law and economics.
After the fall of the communist regime, economic legislation got from the
ground and an enormous number of new laws were introduced (for example
the Company Act of 1988, the Income Tax Act, the VAT Act, and so on in
1989, and so on). This frenzy of economic legislation has of course given
rise to serious theoretical reflections and the 1992 bibliography is the record
of that. Certainly, some of that literature does not belong to law and
economics proper, but it dealt with related topics and had the promise of
developing into law and economics in a narrow sense. To put it briefly, it
seemed to us then that the economic analysis-related legal literature of the
late 1980s and early 1990s constituted the rudiments of a session study of
law and economics. This expectation proved to be wrong.
The more recent literature, voluminous as it still is, shows little signs of
the assimilation of the theoretical principles, explanatory models,
argumentative strategies, methodological approaches, and so on
characteristic of law and economics in its narrow sense. The most significant
common feature of the Hungarian articles, comments and textbooks is that
they focus on the mere interpretation of the new laws, the explanation of
new legal institutions and the description of enforcing specific provisions.
Because of that, new legal periodicals have been established in the past few
years (for example Gazdasg s Jog, Economy and Law), which despite their
inspiring titles show no inclination to apply the method of analysis of law
and economics. We might have continued to construe law and economics
broadly and put together a bibliography as long as (or even longer than) that
of 1992, but this would have been thoroughly misleading.
Clearly, the application of the same principles of selection, which may have
been charitable in 1992, would now be straightforwardly deceptive. At this
juncture one may naturally inquire into the reasons of why the
economics-related legal literature has failed to develop into an economic
analysis of law. It seems that the main factors include the following:
(a) The predominance of traditional German legal thought in Hungarian
legal thinking. It must be emphasised that this involves traditional German
242 Law and Economics in Hungary 0340
4. Prospects
Even so it does not seem justified to conclude from all this that the chances
of law and economics are meagre. Integration into the international
community of legal scholars has increased and the Hungarian students of
law are aware of the issues which have the focus of attention of the
international community. A good example to that may be that there are more
articles in English on law and economics now than in Hungarian. So,
whereas five years ago the great majority of Hungarian scholars had not yet
heard of law and economics, this is not the case any longer. The community
of Hungarian legal scholars has a fairly good basic understanding of the
basic issues and approaches associated with law and economics, which
seems to provide a strong enough basis for the future development of law
and economics research.
0340 Law and Economics in Hungary 243
bel, Istvn and Szakadt, Lszl (1995), Csd a Piacgazdasgi tmenetben (Insolvency in the
Transitional Economy), 10 Kzgazdasgi Szemle, 942-954.
Berde va (1994), Kzjavak s Potyautasok (Public Goods and Free Riders), 5 Kzgazdasgi
Szemle, 431-443.
Lendvai, Balzs and Nyri, Viktor (1994), Az zlethelyisgek Brleti Jognak Egyes Krdsei
(Some Questions on Lease Rights of Retail Premises), 12 Jogtudomnyi Kzlny, 498 ff.
Major, va (1994), Iparjogvdelem Gazdasgtana (Economics of Intellectual Property), in X
(ed.), Iparjogvdelmi Kziknyv (Handbook of Intellectual Property), Budapest, Kzgazdasgi
s Jogi Knyvkiad, 188-197.
Mtys, Antal (1996), A Modern Kzgazdasgtan Trtnete (History of Modern Economics),
Budapest, Aula.
Mtys, Antal (1996), A Hagyomnyos Kzgazdasgtan Brlata s Kutatsi Krnek
Kiszlestse az j Intzmnyi Iskola Kpviseli Rszrl (Criticism and Extension of the Scope of
Research of Traditional Economics as Carried out by the Neoinstitutionalists), 7-8
Kzgazdasgi Szemle, 614-628.
Szakadt, Lszl (1991), A Tulajdonjogok Problmja a Bankrendszerben (Problems of Property
Rights in the Banking System), in X (ed.), Ki Fizet a Vgn?, Budapest, MTA
Kzgazdasgtudomnyi Intzet.
Szakadt, Lszl (1995), Ronald Coase s a Kzgazdasgtan Mdszertana (Ronald Coase and the
Methodology of Economics), 11 Kzgazdasgi Szemle, 1044-1051.
Urbn, Lszl (1995), Kzcl Szablyozs Hatselemzse Public Policy Elemzs (Efficiency
Analysis of Public Policy (Public Policy Analysis)), 3 Kzgazdasgi Szemle, 270-278.
0345
LAW AND ECONOMICS IN ITALY
Roberto Pardolesi
University of Roma (Luiss)
Giuseppe Bellantuono
University of Trento
Copyright 1999 Roberto Pardolesi and Guiseppe Bellantuono
Abstract
Law and economics in Italy is still an underdeveloped subject. Despite the early
contributions of the 1960s and 1970s, most Italian lawyers and economists have
displayed a marked indifference towards the economic approach to law. After
reviewing some initiatives which promise to foster the spread of law &
economics, we show that the hindrances encountered by the economic analysis
of law stem from a misconception of both the economic and the comparative
method.
JEL classification: K0
Keywords: Law and economics, Italy, Comparative Law, Interdisciplinary
Education.
1. Introduction
The origins and subsequent development of law and economics in Italy can be
described as a history with some lights and many shadows. In the following
sections we shall see that since the 1960s the economic approach to law has
attracted increasing attention, but it has not succeeded becoming a prominent
part of Italian legal doctrine. The second section briefly reviews the earliest
Italian contributions to EAL and summarizes the debate on its transplantation
to a civil law country. Sections 3 and 4 discuss the reasons why large sectors
of the legal and economic profession have chosen not to follow the path that
has proved so fruitful in the United States.
2. Italian Law and Economics Between the Past and the Future
At the same time as Ronald Coase and Guido Calabresi were working on their
seminal articles, an Italian scholar, Pietro Trimarchi, published a pathbreaking
244
0345 Law and Economics in Italy 245
book on strict liability (Trimarchi, 1961) entirely based on concepts such as the
allocation of risks to the least cost insurer or recourse to strict liability to induce
potential wrongdoers to adopt optimal precautions. A later article, also
translated into German, applied the tools already employed in the field of tort
law to breach of contract cases ( Trimarchi, 1970).
These contributions marked the first appearance of EAL in Italy. However,
they did not prompt an immediate reaction. It was not until the late 1970s that
systematic EAL research and teaching began in Italy. Even at this late stage,
moreover, the economic approach to law was largely confined to the margins
of the legal profession.
Some years ago the spread of the economic approach to law in Italy was the
subject of a detailed analysis by Ugo Mattei and Roberto Pardolesi (1991). The
authors remarked that the hindrances encountered by the economic analysis of
law stemmed, above all, from a misconception of both the economic and the
comparative method.
With regard to the former, Mattei and Pardolesi stressed that Italian
economists had devoted their energies mostly to the study of post-Keynesian
economics. Yet, it is well known that the law and economics movement sprang
from the development and revision of the neoclassical paradigm during the
decades following the end of the Second World War. The choice of a different
line of research was probably one of the factors that most seriously hampered
the dialogue between lawyers and economists.
As far as the comparative method is concerned, Mattei and Pardolesi
dismissed the claim that EAL is useless in civil law systems because of its
American origin. To be sure, the great dichotomy between civil law and
common law is still a distinctive feature of the Western legal tradition. Today,
however, few scholars (if any) would be willing to reject the doctrines
developed on the other side of the Atlantic because of fundamental differences
in the American legal system. The phenomenon of legal transplants, which
modern comparative studies have emphasised and explored (see for example,
Watson, 1974; Sacco, 1991; Ewald, 1995) is the best evidence that each
tradition borrows from the other when confronted with the same problems.
If common and civil lawyers are able to communicate in many fields,
explanation is still required as to why, in the late 1990s, the economic analysis
of law has still not gained widespread acceptance in Italian legal culture. In the
following two sections we shall see that the answer probably differs between
lawyers and economists. Both groups of social scientists may have been heavily
influenced by EAL, but each chose not to cultivate the interaction between
algebra and pandects. The reasons why lawyers and economists have been deaf
to the lessons of Coase et al. shed light on the evolution of these two branches
in Italy.
246 Law and Economics in Italy 0345
pollute (Pardolesi, 1977 and, more recently, Mattei 1995; Gambaro, 1995). In
tort law the age-old debate on the content of fault gains a new and stimulating
meaning when analysed through the lens of economics (Cafaggi, 1996).
Needless to say, the new Italian antitrust law of October 1990 would be
impossible to understand without the support of an economic apparatus (see
Pardolesi, 1993).
Although its results are hardly original law and economics exerts a powerful
influence on the style of legal reasoning. The new rhetoric of EAL is best seen
as a device which shows the lawyers which elements of a legal controversy are
relevant and which are not (see Ackerman, 1984; McCloskey, 1988). This
feature, however, can be regarded as a primary reason for its appeal as well as
for its uneasy reception in Italy. Indeed, the economic argument compels
lawyers to look at legal disputes from an unprecedented point of view, one
almost at odds with the supposedly orthodox attitude. Instead of talking about
rights and entitlements, lawyers are forced to assess the consequences of each
rule on the allocation of resources. Apart from the complexity of the analysis,
it is clear how far it diverges from the traditional reasoning of the Western
legal tradition. The clash between the Western legal tradition and the Posnerian
version of law and economics has recently been highlighted by Monateri
(1995). By contrast, the usefulness of instrumental reasoning in the Italian legal
system has been reaffirmed by the constitutional judge Mengoni (1994).
In short, Italian legal culture finds itself caught in a paradox. Law and
economics promises valuable insights into legal problems, but at the same time
it requires in-depth understanding of its techniques. Lawyers can take
advantage of the economic approach to law only if they choose to invest in this
field. Unfortunately, though, they lack the data with which to gauge the benefits
available until that investment is made. This paradox is largely due to the scant
attention paid to economics in lawyers training. The Italian law faculties
normally include only one course of economics on their programs, which is
clearly inadequate to tackle the complexity of modern mathematical economics.
Of course, Italian lawyers have occasionally displayed deep understanding
of the economic issues underlying legal matters. For their part, many Italian
economists have been keenly aware of the interaction between law and
economics (for references to the works of nineteenth-century Italian lawyers
and economists see Cosentino, 1990). It is clear, however, that this tradition
has been unable to lay the basis for more systematic study. It may be that one
of the reasons for this lack of communication has been the role played by social
scientists in Italian society and culture, but we believe that the present situation
can be explained mainly by the shortcomings of academic training.
In short, the lack of a formal training is a problem that cannot be postponed
any longer. It is at this point that Italian economists should enter the scene.
Unfortunately, they have listened no more than Italian lawyers have done.
0345 Law and Economics in Italy 249
About two decades ago Ronald Coase suggested that the expansion of
economics into contiguous fields would come to an end when social scientists
in those fields were able to master its techniques. The number of American
lawyers who now have a PhD in economics seems to confirm his forecast
(Coase, 1978, 1996). Nevertheless, it is clear that law and economics in the
United States would have had less impact if economists had not involved
themselves in the enterprise. It is hardly an exaggeration to state that the
cooperation between lawyers and economists has been a fundamental factor in
the development of the economic approach to law (for information on the
involvement of economists in law and economics see Ellickson, 1989; Landes
and Posner, 1993; Stigler, 1992).
What about Italy? The indifference of economists towards legal institutions
is so manifest that it is not worth dwelling upon. Suffice it to say that a recent
introduction to a collection of papers by Ronald Coase does not include the
slightest reference to his influence on the economic analysis of law or to Italian
contributions in that field (Grillo, 1995, pp. 7ff.). Judging from these writings,
it seems that economics and law in Italy do not communicate at all.
This situation is even more surprising if we look at the training provided by
Italian schools of economics. Their programs include a wide range of law
courses, and economics students have ample opportunity to become fully
conversant in both disciplines. Why this does not happen is not clear. One
might suggest that the jobs market is highly specialized and young graduates
with hybrid skills do not find employment easily. Whatever the case may be, on
the eve of the twenty-first century the Italian Bibliography of Law and
Economics lists only a few contributions by Italian economists.
It is difficult to say whether the present situation will to change in the near
future. Since the last century, political debate on the reform of administrative
agencies and governmental regulation has been the main concern of economic
thinkers in Italy (see, for example, the essays on market and democracy
collected in Bocciarelli and Ciocca, 1994). In accordance with this tradition,
current analysis appears to be dominated by macroeconomics issues (for a
recent survey of the Italian situation by a French economist see Bartoli, 1996).
This is not to say, however, that hopeful signs of a renewed interest in legal
institutions are entirely lacking. The presence of economists in the law faculties
has recently begun to yield fruitful interdisciplinary studies. Some courses in
economics, for example, have applied insights from law and economics to
Italian laws and institutions (see Chiancone and Porrini, 1996; Galeotti 1995),
and there are encouraging signals from the already mentioned Italian
economists working in the field of the New Institutional Economics. Even more
importantly, modern economics textbooks are now devoting more space to such
250 Law and Economics in Italy 0345
Competizione e Circolazione dei Modelli Giuridici (The Institutional Structure of the new
European Common Law: Competion and Transplants of Legal Models), Trento, Dipartimento di
Scienze guiridiche.
Aprile, Ercole (1989), Regolamentazione dei Fenomeni Economici e Analisi Economica degli
Strumenti Giuridici: Spunti per una Riflessione (Regulation of Economic Phenomena and
Economic Analysis of Legal Instruments: Hints for a Reflection), Nuovo Diritto, 505-521.
Bellantuono, Giuseppe (1995), Polizza Fideiussoria, Reticenza e Obblighi di Informazione
(Performance Bond, Non-Disclosure and Duties of Information), Il Foro Italiano, 1905-1909.
Bessone, Mario (1984), Gli standards dei contratti di impresa e lanalisi economica del diritto (The
Standards in Contracts and Economic Analysis), Giurisprudenza di merito, 982-987.
Cafaggi, Fabrizio (1995), La nozione di difetto ed il ruolo dellinformazione. Per ladozione di un
modello dinamico-relazionale di difetto in una prospettiva di riforma (The notion of defect and the
role of information. For the adoption of a dynamic-relational model of defect in a perspective of
reform), Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato, 447-480.
Cafaggi, Fabrizio (1995b), Pubblicit commerciale (Commercial Advertising), XI Digesto
commerciale, 433-500.
Cafaggi, Fabrizio (1996), Profili della Colpa Relazionale (Outlines of Relational Fault), Padova,
CEDAM.
Cafaggi, Fabrizio, Cuffaro, Vincenzo and Di Via Luciano (1993), Attuazione della Direttiva n.
450/84/Cee in Materia di Pubblicit ingannevole (decreto legislativo 25 gennaio 1992 n. 74)
(Implementation of EC Directive no. 450/84 on Misleading Advertising), Le Nuove Leggi Civili
Commentate, 671-761.
Carbone, Paolo (1991), Nuovi Illeciti Attinenti alla Negoziazione di Valori Mobiliari. Profili della
disciplina. Spunti critici (New Torts concerning Securities Exchange. Outlines of the rules. Critical
hints), V Il Foro Italiano, 466-490.
Carbone, Paolo (1993), Tutela Civile del Mercato e Insider Trading (Private Law Protection of the
Market and Insider Trading), Padova, CEDAM.
Carriero, Giuseppe (1992), Informazione, Mercato, Buona Fede: il Cosiddetto Insider Trading
(Information, Market, Good Faith: the socalled Insider Trading ), Milano, Giuffr.
Carriero, Giuseppe (1997), Norme di Protezione dellUtente dei Servizi Bancari e Finanziari: Taluni
Effetti Economici (Legal Protection of the Consumer of Bank and Financial Services: Some
Economic Effects), Rivista di diritto dellimpresa, 79 ff.
Caruso, Daniela (1991), Relazioni Precontrattuali e Teoria dei Giochi (Precontractual Relations and
Game Theory), Quadrimestre, 810-832.
Caruso, Daniela (1991b), Note in Tema di Danni Precontrattuali (Nota a Cass., 11 maggio 1990, n.
4051, Bellucci c. Min. difesa) (Notes about Precontractual Damages), 1 Il Foro Italiano,
188-200.
Caruso, Daniela (1993), La Culpa in Contrahendo - LEsperienza Statunitense e Quella Italiana
(Culpa in Contrahendo - The American and Italian Experience), Milano, Giuffr.
Castronovo, Carlo (1981), Inattuazione Della Prestazione di Lavoro e Responsabilit Del
Danneggiante (Employees Non-Performance and Tortfeasors Liability), Massimario di
Giurisprudenza del Lavoro, 370-377.
252 Law and Economics in Italy 0345
Chianale, Angelo (1992), LAtto Pubblico: Contributo allo Studio dei Costi Transattivi (The
Document under the Seal of a Public Officer: Contribution to the Study of Transaction Costs),
Torino, Giappichelli.
Chianale, Angelo (1993), Diritto Soggettivo e Tutela in Forma Specifica. Indagine in Tema di
Responsabilit Extracontrattuale (Subjective Right and Specific Performance. An Inquiry in Tort
Law), Milano, Giuffr.
Chiancone, Aldo and Porrini, Donatella (1996), Lezioni di Analisi Economica del Diritto (Lessons of
Economic Analysis of Law), Torino, Giappichelli.
Chiassoni Pierluigi (1991), LAnalisi Economica del Diritto negli Stati Uniti: Formalismo o Realismo?
(Economic Analysis of Law in the United States: Formalism or Realism?), Quadrimestre,
473-525.
Chiassoni, Pierluigi (1992), Economic Analysis of Law. Lanalisi economica del diritto negli Stati
Uniti (The Economic Analysis of Law in the United States), Torino, Giappichelli.
Clerico, Giuseppe (1992), Inadempienza Contrattuale e Determinazione del Risarcimento Monetario
(Breach of Contract and Quantification of Monetary Damages), Economia Pubblica, 267-276.
Clerico, Giuseppe (1994), Raccolta e Allocazione diSsangue: Donazione, Mercato e Intervento
Pubblico (Gathering and Allocation of Blood: Gift, Market and Public Intervention), 4 Rassegna
Giuridica della Sanit, 140-152.
Clerico, Giuseppe (1995), Prodotto Difettoso e Responsabilit delDanno: i Dilemmi della Scelta
Pubblica (Defective Product and Liability for Damages: the Dilemma of the Public Choice),
Economia Pubblica, 25-70.
Clerico, Giuseppe (1996), Produzione e Rischio di Danni: regolamentazione Pubblica versus Regole
di Responsabilit (Production and Risk of Damages: Public Regulation vs. Liability Rules),
Economia e Diritto del Terziario, 491-518.
Cosentino, Fabrizio (1988), Autonomia Privata e Paternalismo del Legislatore Nella Prospettiva
dellAnalisi Economica del Diritto (Individual Autonomy and the Paternalism of the Legislator:
An EAL Perspective), Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato, 473-511.
Cosentino, Fabrizio (1989), Responsabilit da Prodotto Difettoso: Appunti di Analisi Economica del
Diritto (nota a U.S. Supreme Court California, 31 marzo 1988, Brown c. Abbott Laboratories)
(Liability for Defective Products: An Economic Analysis of Law), 4 Foro Italiano, 137-143.
Cosentino, Fabrizio (1990a), Analisi Economica del Diritto: Ritorno al Futuro? (Economic Analysis
of Law: Back to the Future?), 5 Foro Italiano, 153-156.
Cosentino, Fabrizio (1990b), Il Contratto di Servizio delle Cassette di Sicurezza: Clausole di
Limitazione della Responsabilit della Banca e Dichiarazione di Valore (The Contract for Services
Related to Safety Deposit Boxes: Exemption Clauses for the Bank and Statement of Value), 1
Foro Italiano, 1292-1298.
Cosentino, Fabrizio (1990c), LInadempimento Efficiente Nuovamente al Vaglio della Cassazione
(Nota a Cass., 21 marzo 1989, n. 1403, Allione c. Greco) (The Efficient Breach again Under
Scrutiny Before the Court of Cassation), I Il Foro Italiano, 223-227.
Cosentino, Fabrizio (1992), Trasporto di Merci su Strada e Limitazione della Responsabilit:
Osservazioni in Chiave di Analisi Economica del Diritto, (Nota a Corte costit., 22 novembre 1991,
n. 420, Soc. Dafne et Cloe c. Autotrasp. bestiame Melano) (Carriage of Goods by Road and
Limitation of Liability: Remarks from the Point of View of the Economic Analysis of Law), 1 Il
0345 Law and Economics in Italy 253
Gallo, Paolo (1992), Errore sul Valore, Giustizia Contrattuale e Trasferimenti Ingiustificati di
Ricchezza alla Luce dellAnalisi Economica del Diritto (Mistake on Value, Contractual Justice and
Unjust Enrichment), Quadrimestre, 656-703.
Gallo, Paolo (1993), Appunti in Tema di Colpevolezza, Colpa Soggettiva ed Efficienza Economica
(in occasione di alcune recenti pubblicazioni) (Notes about Liability, Subjective Fault and
Economic Efficiency on the Occasion of Some Recent Publications), Quadrimestre, 712-732.
Gallo, Paolo (1995), Immissioni, usi Incompatibili e Problemi di Allocazione di Risorse Scarse
(Nuisance, Incompatible Uses and Problems of Allocation of Scarce Resources), 1 Rivista di
Diritto Civile, 657-693.
Gallo, Paolo (1998), Analisi Economica del Diritto (Economic Analysis of Law), Torino, Giappichelli.
Gambaro, Antonio (1979), La Legittimazione Passiva alle Azioni Possessorie (Standing to Be Sued
in Ownership Litigation), Milano, Giuffr, 163 p.
Gambaro, Antonio (1995), Il Diritto di Propriet (Property Law), Milano, Giuffr.
Gambaro, Antonio (1996), LAnalisi Economica e la Ricerca della Logica Proprietaria (Economic
Analysis and the Search for the Rationale of Ownership), Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato,
235-244.
Grillo, Michele (1995), Introduzione to Coase, Impresa Mercato e Diritto (Introduction to Coase, Law
and Economics), il Mulino, Bologna, 7-38.
Grillo, Michele (1996), Lo Snobismo degli Economisti e il Rifiuto del Dialogo con i Giuristi. Una
Risposta a Guido Alpa (The Economists Snobbery and the Refusal of Dialogue with Lawyers. A
reply to Guido Alpa), Economia e Diritto del Terziario, 751-754.
Guatri, Luigi (1986), Crisi e Risanamento delle Imprese (Crisis and Reorganization of the Firms),
Milano, Giuffr, 339 p.
Ichino, Pietro (1998), Il Diritto del Lavoro e i Modelli Economici (Labour law and economic models),
Lavoro e Diritto, 309-322.
Macario, Francesco (1996), Adempimento e Rinegoziazione nei Contratti a Lungo Termine
(Performance and Renegotiation in Long-Term Contracts), Napoli, Jovene.
Maccabruni, Franco (1995), Insider Ttrading e Analisi Economica del Diritto (Insider Trading and
Economic Analysis of Law), 1 Giurisprudenza Commerciale, 598-622.
Marella, Maria Rosaria (1994), Onerosit del Risarcimento in Forma Specifica (Onerousness of
Specific Performance), I,2 Giurisprudenza Italiana, 1067-1074.
Marini, Giovanni (1986), Ingiustizia dello Scambio e Lesione Contrattuale (Unfairness of the
Exchange and Contractual Lesion), Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato, 257-315.
Marini, Giovanni (1990), Promessa ed Affidamento nel Diritto dei Contratti (Promise and Reliance
in Contract Law), Napoli, Jovene, 317 p.
Marini, Giovanni (1995), Promessa e Affidamento nel Diritto dei Contratti (Promise and Reliance in
Contract Law), Napoli, Jovene.
Mastrorilli, Annachiara (1994), Originalit nelle opere compilative e informazione (Nota a Cass. 10
marzo 1994, n. 2345 e 2 dicembre 1993, n. 11953) (Originality in Compiled Works and
Information), I Il Foro Italiano, 2417-2422.
Mattei, Ugo (1985),I Modelli nella Tutela dellAmbiente (The Models for the Protection of the
Environment), 2 Rivista di Diritto Civile, 389-427.
Mattei, Ugo (1987),Diritto e Rimedio nellEsperienza Italiana ed in quella Statunitense: un Primo
Approccio (Law and Remedies Related to Italian and American Experiences: A First Approach),
Quadrimestre, 341-359.
0345 Law and Economics in Italy 255
Mattei, Ugo (1987b), Tutela Inibitoria e Tutela Risarcitoria (Injunctive Relief and Damages), Milano,
Giuffr, 419 p.
Mattei, Ugo (1995), La Propriet Immobiliare (Real Property), Torino, Giappichelli.
Mattei, Ugo (1996), Analisi Economica e Comparata delle Clausole Penali nel Diritto dei Contratti
(Comparative Law and Rconomics of Penalty Clauses in Contracts), Rivista Critica del Diritto
Privato, 603-627.
Mattei, Ugo and Pulitini, Francesco (1990), Modelli Competitivi, Regole Giuridiche ed Analisi
Economica (Competitive Models, Legal Norms and Economic Analysis), Quadrimestre, 77-102.
Mattei, Ugo and Pulitini, Francesco (eds) (1994), Consumatore, Ambiente, Concorrenza -
AnalisiEeconomica del Diritto (Consumer, Environment, Competition - Economic Analysis of
Law), Milano, Giuffr.
Mengaroni, F. (1988), Analisi Economica del Diritto (Economic Analysis of Law), 1 Enciclopedia
giuridica, 1-9.
Mengoni, Luigi (1994), Largomentazione Orientata alle Conseguenze (The argumentation Oriented
to the Consequences), Rivista Trimestrale di Diritto e Procedura Civile, 1-18.
Monateri, Pier Giuseppe (1989), Cumulo di Responsabilit Contrattuale ed extra Contrattuale
(Overlap of Contractual and Extracontractual Liability), Padova, CEDAM, 315 p.
Monateri, Pier Giuseppe (1995), Risultati e Regole. (UnAnalisi Giuridica dellAnalisi Economica del
Diritto) (Rules and Outcomes. A Legal Analysis of the Economic Analysis of Law), Rivista
Critica del Diritto Privato, 605-619.
Monateri, Pier Giuseppe (1998), La responsabilit Civile (Tort Law), Torino, Utet.
Monateri, Pier Giuseppe (1998), Responsabilit Civile (Tort Law), 17 Digesto Civile, 1-12.
Monti, Andrea (1998), Learned Hand Formula e Buona Fede nellEsecuzione del Contratto. Analisi
economica e comparata (Learned Hand Formula and Good Faith in Contract. Comparative and
Economic Analysis, Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato, 125-147 (4400).
Nogler, Luca (1992), Una Ventata di Analisi Economica del Diritto in Tema di Contratto di Lavoro
a Termine (Nota a Cass., sez. lav., 21 febbraio 1992, n. 2153, Matteucci c. Cassa risp. Citt di
Castello) (A Wave of Economic Analysis of Law on Forward Employment Contract), I Giustizia
Civile, 2104-2105.
Osti, Cristoforo (1995), Antitrust e Oligopolio: Concorrenza, Cooperazione e Concentrazione
(Antitrust and Oligopoly: Competition, Cooperation and Merger), Bologna, Il Mulino.
Pacces, Alessio and Pardolesi, Roberto (1997), Clausole Vessatorie in Crisi d Identit. Appunti di
Analisi Economica del Diritto (The Identity Crisis of Unfair Terms. Remarks of Economic
Analysis of Law), in Furgiuele (ed.), Diritto Privato, II1996, Padova.
Paganelli, Maurizio (1989), Alla Volta di Frankenstein: Biotecnologie e propriet (di parti) del corpo
(Toward Frankenstein: Biotechnology and Property Rights in Body Parts), 4 Foro Italiano,
417-441.
Panella, Giorgio (1994), Responsabilit Civile ed Effetti Esterni: unApplicazione ai Problemi
dellInquinamento (Tortious Liability and External Effects: an Application to the Problems of
Pollution), Economia e Diritto del Terziario, 631-653.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1977), Azione Reale e Azione di Danni nell Art. 844 C.C. Logica Economica e
Logica Giuridica Nella Composizione Del Conflitto Tra Usi Incompatibili Delle Propriet Vicine
(Property Rule and Liability Rule in Article 844 Codice Civile: Economic Arguments, Legal
256 Law and Economics in Italy 0345
Arguments and Litigation for Inconsistent Uses of Neighbours Lands), 1 Foro Italiano,
1144-1154.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1982), Luci ed Ombre nell analisi economica del diritto (Appunti in Margine Ad
Un Libro Recente) (Lights and Shadows in Law and Economics - Notes about a Recent Book),
2 Rivista di Diritto Civile, 718-728.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1985), Invalidit Temporanea del Dipendente, Illecito del Terzo Rivalsa del
Datore di Lavoro (ovvero: lanalisi economica del diritto in cassazione) (Temporary Disability of
Employees, Tortuous Conduct by Third Party Employers Remedies), 1 Foro Italiano,
2286-2291.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1986), Una Introduzione allAnalisi Economica del Diritto con Postfazione
(Translation of A. Mitchell Polinskys Introduction), Bologna, Zanichelli, 149 p.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1987), Analisi Economica del Diritto (Economic Analysis of Law), 1 Digesto
Civile, 309-320.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1988), Tutela Specifica e Tutela per Equivalente nella Prospettiva dellAnalisi
Economica del Diritto (Specific Performance and Damages: An EAL Perspective), Quadrimestre,
76-97.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1989), Un Moderno Minotauro: Law and Economics (A Modern Minotaur: Law
and Economics), Economia, Societ e Istituzioni, 519-534.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1991), Energia (Energy), VII Digesto Civile, 444-448.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1992), Postfazione a Polinsky, Mitchell A., Una Introduzione allAnalisi
Economica del Diritto, (Afterword to Polinsky, Mitchell A., An Introduction to Economic Analysis
of Law), Il Foro Italiano, 179-199.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1993), Analisi Economica della Legislazione Antitrust Italiana (Economic
Analysis of Italian Antitrust Law), V Il Foro Italiano, 1-18.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1994), Parallelismo e Collusione Oligopolistica: il Lato Oscuro dell Antitrust
(Parallelism and Oligopolistic Collusion: the Dark Side of Antitrust), IV Il Foro Italiano, 65-76.
Pardolesi, Roberto (1996), Regole di Default eRazionalit.. Limitata: per un (diverso) Approccio
diAnalisiEconomicaa l Diritto dei Contratti (Default Rules and Bounded Rationality: for a
Different Economic Approach to Contract Law), Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato,451-466.
Pardolesi, Roberto and Motti, Cinzia (1990), LIdea Mia!: Lusinghe e Misfatti dellEconomics of
Information (The Idea is Mine!: Enticements and Misdeeds of the Economics of Information),
Diritto dellInformazione e dellInformatica, 345-359.
Pardolesi, Roberto and Osti, Cristoforo (1996), Avvisi di Burrasca: Antitrust e Diritti Tv
suManifestazioni Sportive (Storm Warnings: Antitrust and Television Rights on Sport Events),
Rivista di Diritto Sportivo, 1-31.
Parisi, Francesco, and (1990), Sviluppi nell'Elemento Soggettivo del Tort of Negligence, 36 Rivista
di diritto civile, 545-599.
Parisi, Francesco (1991), Interpretazione Giuridica ed Analisi Economica - IlTeorema di Coase Trenta
Anni Dopo (Legal Interpretation and Economic Analysis - The Coase Theorem Thirty Years
Later), Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato, 643-676.
Parisi, Francesco (1993), Learned Hand Formula of Negligence, X Digesto Civile, 4th ed., 436-443;
reprinted in Materiali di Economia e Diritto, 1997, Universit di Roma La Sapienza, 285-292.
Parisi, Francesco (1998), The Market for Votes: Coasian Bargaining in an Arrovian Setting, 6
0345 Law and Economics in Italy 257
Efficienza (Avoidable Damage: The Measure of Liability Between Due Care and Efficiency),
Padova, CEDAM, 320 p.
Russo, Enzo (1992), LImpatto Amministrativo della Riforma del Contenzioso: Spunti di Analisi
Economica del Diritto (The Administrative Impact of the Reform of the Contentious Procedure:
Hints of Economic Analysis of Law), Il Fisco, 10471-10479.
Santagata, Walter (1995), Istituzioni per il Mercato dellArte: Artisti e Mercanti tra Regole,
Convenzioni e Allocazioni dei Diritti (Institutions for the Market of Works of Art: Artists and
Merchants among Rules, Conventions and Allocation of Rights), Economia Pubblica, 87-115.
Santini, Gerardo (1979), Il Commercio (Trading), Bologna, Il Mulino, 364 p.
Santini, Gerardo (1987), I Servizi. Saggio di Economia del Diritto (The Services. An Example of an
Economic Approach to Law), Bologna, Il Mulino, 562 p.
Savona, Ernesto (1990), Un Settore Trascurato: lAnalisi Economica della Criminalit .., del Diritto
Penale e del Sistema di Giustizia Penale (A Neglected Sector: Economic Analysis of Crime,
Criminal Law and the System of Criminal Justice), Sociologia del Diritto, 255-277.
Tarzia, Giuseppe (1983), Credito Bancario e Risanamento dellImpresa nella Procedura di
Amministrazione Straordinaria (Credit and the Reorganization of the Firm), Giurisprudenza
Commerciale, 340-352.
Toffoletto, Alberto (1996), Il Risarcimento del Danno nel Sistema delleSanzioni per La violazione
della Normativa Antitrust (The Compensation for Damages in the Liability System for the
Infringment of Antitrust Law), Milano, Giuffr.
Tricoli, Clara (1981), Per una Teoria Economica dell Espropriazione e dell Indennizzo (An Economic
Theory of Takings and Compensation), Rivista di Diritto Commerciale, 335-357.
Trimarchi, Pietro (1961), Rischio e responsabilit oggettiva Risk and Strict Liability), Milano,
Giuffr, 383 p.
Trimarchi, Pietro (1970), Sul Significato Economico dei Criteri di Responsabilit Contrattuale
(Economic Meaning of Contract-Liability Criteria), Rivista Trimestrale di Diritto e Procedura
Civile, 512-531.
Trimarchi, Pietro (1987), LAnalisi Economica del Diritto: Tendenze e Prospettive (Economic
Analysis of Law: Tendencies and Perspectives), Quadrimestre, 563-582.
Trimarchi, Pietro (ed.) (1994), Per una Riforma della Responsabilit.. Civile per Danno allAmbiente
(The Reform of Tort Law for Environmental Damage), Milano, Giuffr.
Troiano, Onofrio (1996), I Servizi Elettronici di Pagamento. Addebiti in Conto non Autorizzati:
unAnalisi Comparata (Electronic Payment Systems: A Comparative Analysis), Milano, Giuffr
(5850).
Ventura, Andrea (1990), Il Ruolo del Teorema di Coase nellAnalisi Economica del Diritto di G.
Calabresi (The Role of the Coase Theorem in G. Calabresis Economic Analysis of Law),
Economia Pubblica, 27-34.
Villa, Gianroberto (1988), Errore Riconosciuto, Annullamento del Contratto ed Incentivi alla Ricerca
di Informazioni (Known Mistake, Contract Avoidance and Incentives towards Information
Acquisition), Quadrimestre, 286-300.
Villa, Gianroberto (1992), Contratto Illecito ed Irripetibilit della Prestazione - Una Analisi
Economica (Unlawful Contract and Non Repayable Performance - An Economic Analysis),
Quadrimestre, 19-64.
Zaccaria, Giuseppe (1995), Una Teoria del Pragmatismo Prescrittivo. Sulla Jurisprudence di Richard
260 Law and Economics in Italy 0345
Other References
Ackerman, Bruce (1984), Reconstructing American Law, Harvard University Press. Cambridge, Mass.
Ayres, Ian (1990), Playing Games with the Law, 42 Stanford Law Review, 1291-1317.
Bartoli (1996), Chronique de la Pense conomique en Italie (Chonicle of Economic Thinking in
Italy, 47 Revue conomique, 1013 ff.
Blaug, Mark (1992), The Methodology of Economics, or, How Economics Explain, Second Edition,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Bocciarelli, Rossella and Ciocca, Pierluigi (1994), Scrittori Italiani di Economia (Italian Writing in
Economics), Laterza, Roma-Bari.
Coase, Ronald H. (1978), Economics and Contiguous Disciplines, 7 Journal of Legal Studies, 201
ff.
Coase, Ronald H. (1996), Law and Economics and A.W. Brian Simpson, 25 Journal of Legal
Studies, 103-119.
Costa, Giacomo and Mori, Pier Angelo (1994), Introduzione alla Teoria dei Giochi (Introduction to
the Theory of Giochi), Bologna, Il Mulino.
Delbono, Flavio and Zamagni, Stefano (1996), Lezione di Microeconomia (Lessons in
Microeconomics), Bologna, Il Mulino.
Dworkin, Ronald (1986), Laws Empire, Cambridge (MA), Harvard University Press.
Ellickson, Robert (1989), Bringing Culture and Human Frailty to Rational Actors: A Critique of
Classical Law and Economics, 65 Chicago-Kent Law Review, 23-55.
Ewald (1995), Comparative Jurisprudence: The Logic of Legal Tranplants, 43 American Journal of
Comparative Law, 489 ff.
Hovenkamp, Herbert (1990), Positivism in Law and Economics, 78 California Law Review, 815.
Hovenkamp, Herbert (1995), Law and Economics in the United States: A Brief Historical Survey, 19
Cambridge Journal of Economics, 331-352.
Huang, Peter H. (1995), Strategic Behavior and the Law: A Guide for Legal Scholars to Game Theory
and the Law and Other Game Theory Texts, 36 Jurimetrics Journal, 99-114.
Landes, William and Posner, Richard (1993), The Influence of Economics on Law: A Quantitative
Study, 36 Journal of Law and Economics, 385 ff.
Mattei, Ugo and Pardolesi, Roberto (1991), Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries: A
Comparative Approach, 11 International Review of Law and Economics, 265-275.
McCloskey, Donald (1988), The Rhetoric of Law and Economics, 86 Michigan Law Review, 752 ff.
Rizzello, Salvatore (1996), Mente Organizzazioni Istituzioni. I Fondamenti Microeconomici del
Neoistituzionalismo, Economia Politica, 225-263.
Rubin, Edward L. (1996), The New Legal Process, the Synthesis of Discourse, and the Microanalysis
of Institutions, 109 Harvard Law Review, 1393-1438.
Sacco, Rodolfo (1991), Legal Formants, A Dynamic Approach to Comparative Law, 39 American
0345 Law and Economics in Italy 261
Abstract
1. Introduction
262
0350 Law and Economics in Mexico 263
In the academic community there are few Mexican universities that show
any interest in economic analysis of law. Among them we can mention the
Autonomous Technological Institute of Mexico (ITAM), Center for
Economic Research and Teaching (CIDE). Likewise, a certain interest has
been detected in the Law School of the National Autonomous University of
Mexico (UNAM) (since the new curriculum of 1993, there exists a course
related to economic matters in each of the 10 semesters), the National
Institute of Public Administration (INAP), and the University of the
Americas in Puebla (UDLA).
This disciplines main achievement in the academic community has been
its contribution to forming a different juridical mentality, whether of
research, policy or analysis. Students often see the emphasis on the real or
potential effects of law and economics through the incentives it produces and
the importance of the costs of the legal system as the main contribution of
the economic approach to law.
In law schools, most teaching related to economics is given in courses
that concern economic theory, history of economic thought and economic
law (part of Mexican social law). These courses are part of the law schools
curriculum (first, second and seventh semesters respectively). This teaching
lasts approximately four months per term.
May of 1997) (AMDE) was founded on April 6, 1995 with the important
support of professors Robert Cooter and Albert Fishlow, as well as of the
former President of Mexico, Miguel de la Madrid Hurtado, the former
Federal Attorney of Mexico, Pedro Ojeda Paullada, the President of the
ITAM, Dr Arturo Fernndez, and Andrs Roemer. Being part of the Latin
American and Caribbean Association of Law and Economics, the AMDE
has more than 30 founding members, 27 numerary members (who have
presented academic papers and are current with their fees), as well as 25
supernumerary members (who are current with payments but have not
presented any related academic paper) and another 400 people interested in
the Academy (who attend congresses and seminars).
Since its establishment on April 6, 1995, the Mexican Academy of Law
and Economics has carried out academic, teaching and research activities
among which the following should be mentioned:
To date more than 137 research papers have been compiled that address
Economic Analysis of Sexual Commingling and Regulation,
Microeconomics of Civil Liability and the Marriage Contract, to Analysis
of the Free Trade Agreement.
- A data base in the subject has been formed with 9000 academic
essays from more than fourteen countries, indexed by place, topic
and author.
- Two National Congresses have been held with more than 200
participants in each one.
- Economic Analysis of Law courses have been implemented in the
Autonomous Technological Institute of Mexico (ITAM), in the
Center for Economic Research and Teaching (CIDE) and in the
Autonomous Metropolitan University (UAM), as well as seminars in
the National Institute of Public Administration (INAP), the
University of the Americas, Puebla Campus and in the Law School
of the National Autonomous University of Mexico (UNAM).
- The Annual National Law and Economy award was established for
the best research paper in the area, as well as the Robert Cooter
Award for the best academic paper in Law and Economics from the
ITAM.
- The respective Academies were likewise formed in the States of
Puebla, Coahuila, Chiapas, Jalisco, Oaxaca and Veracruz.
0350 Law and Economics in Mexico 265
4. Perspectives
Alcudia Goya, Hector, The Social Convenience of a Disincorporation from Federal Government of
the Almacenes Generales De Deposito, Mexican Association of Law and Economics
Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 14.
Acosta Rivera, Jose De Jesus, Culebro Moreno, Jorge and Rosillo Iglesias, Jose Gabriel, Economic
Analysis on Voting, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of
Law and Economics, no. 64.
Acosta, Francisco Antonio, Market Power and Institutional Assignation of a Transferable
Permissions System For Polluting Emissions, Mexican Association of Law and Economics
Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 06.
Agiss Bitar, Fernando, The Law of Economic Competence: A Judicial and Economic
Approximation on the Competence Law in Mexico, Mexican Association of Law and
Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 84.
Aguirre Pablo, Karla, Economic Analysis on Tributary Law on Trade Taxes and its Relation with
Nafta, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and
Economics, no. 40.
Alba, Pilar, Ocaa, Alan and Suarez, Diana, Analysis on the New Fishing Law, Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 88.
Arias De La Mora, Roberto, The Participation of the Citizenship in Mexico City, Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 49.
Barraza Llorenz, Mariana, The New Law on Agriculture In Mexico, Mexican Association of Law
and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 86.
Barrera Flores, Raymundo, Economic Analysis of the Regulation of Lethal Weapons, Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 25.
Barria Macera, Rodrigo, Economic Analysis on Article 27 of the Constitution of Mexico, Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 87.
Bravo Ruiz, Maria Lilia and Presser Valdes, Soren, Economic Analysis on Institutional Aspects of
Mexico Citys Water Supply, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series
Papers of Law and Economics, no. 55.
Caceres Nieto, Enrique, Economic Analysis on Law: An Integral Theory, Mexican Association of
Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 88.
Cambero Garcia, Gerardo and Covil Princivil, Donald, Economic Analysis on Intellectual Property
Rights, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and
Economics, no. 56.
Carrera Paniso, Sofia and Peralta Sanchez, J. Ignacio, Analysis of the Education System in Mexico
and its Legal Perspective, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers
of Law and Economics, no. 89.
Castro, Mariana and Rodriguez, Manuel, Economic Analysis on Voting, Mexican Association of
Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 67.
0350 Law and Economics in Mexico 267
Chavez Mondragon, Rafael, The Problem of Milk Production, Mexican Association of Law and
Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 03.
Cuellar Trewartha, Ana Leticia, The Mexican Federalism Case: Public Choice vs Republicanism,
Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics,
no. 90.
Diarte Martinez, Heriberto, The Mexican Federalism From an Economic and Legal Perspective,
Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics,
no. 91.
Dominguez Diaz, Deisy Gabriela, Intellectual Property Rights in Mexico, Mexican Association of
Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 92.
Dudet Bellanger, Federico and Rios Piter, Armando, Economic Analysis of Law: Possibilities of An
Alternative Banking System In Mexico, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working
Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 58.
Elenes, Vanessa, Economic Analysis on Prostitution, Mexican Association of Law and Economics
Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 66.
Fragoso, Edna, Consequenses of Nafta, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working
Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 93.
Galindo Suarez, Rosa Maria, Economic Analysis on Law, Mexican Association of Law and
Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 84.
Garcia Salgo, Claudio, Law and Development, Mexican Association of Law and Economics
Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 25.
Garcia Verdu, Rodrigo, The Irreversible Investment Under Uncertainty Theory: An Economic
Analysis on Law Application, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series
Papers of Law and Economics, no. 95.
Garcia Villegas Sanchez Cordero, Olga Economic Analysis on Judges on Creation of Efficient
Juridical Rules, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law
and Economics, no. 13.
Garcia Villegas Sanchez Cordero, Paula Maria, Economic Analysis on Article 28 of the
Constitution of Mexico, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers
of Law and Economics, no. 96.
Gomez Martinez, Juan Carlos, The Public Policies Elaboration on the Federal Public
Administration, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law
and Economics, no. 97.
Gonzalez Burelo, Juan Alejandro, The Problem of a Getting Degree, Mexican Association of Law
and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 27.
Gonzalez De Alba, Ivan Guillermo, Economic Analysis of Environmental Policy, Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 60.
Gutierrrez Fernandez, Geronimo and Islas Torres, Alberto, The Federal Taxes, Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 98.
Hernadez Pintado, Fausto Jose, An Independent Central Bank: An Economic Analysis of the Law
of the Bank of Mexico, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of
Law and Economics, no. 83.
Hernandez Murillo, Ruben, Civil Contracts Regime: the Unfulfilment, Mexican Association of
268 Law and Economics in Mexico 0350
Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 99.
Karam, Daniel, Economic Analysis on the Relation between Federal Government And the Press,
Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics,
no. 44.
Leipen Linares, Elizabeth and Garcia Franco, Jose Carlos, Analysis on Mining Regulation in
Mexico, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and
Economics, no. 100.
Leon Oviedo, Fernando, Economic Analysis on the Bankruptcy Law, Mexican Association of Law
and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 28.
Levy, Gabriel, Selected Topics on Soller, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working
Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 30.
Lobeira, Santiago, Economic Analysis of Environmental Legislation in the Matter of Pollution,
Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics,
no. 31.
Lopez G., Cesar Miguel, Economic Analysis of Aids, Mexican Association of Law and Economics
Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 46.
Lopez Hoyo, Jose Gerardo, The Collective Contract System in Mexico, Mexican Association of
Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 101.
Madero, Samantha, Law and Economics of the Regulation of Illegal Drugs, Mexican Association
of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 36.
Marin Suarez, Anouk, Analysis of the Regime of Rental Apartments in Mexico City, Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 102.
Marquez Heine, Luis Antonio, Economic Analysis of Antitrust Laws, Mexican Association of Law
and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 103.
Martin Del Campo Flores and David, Erik, The Lords of War, Mexican Association of Law and
Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 104.
Martinez Lopez, Andres and Quintero Ramirez Horacio, Economic Analysis on the
Jewish-Christian Divine Pact, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series
Papers of Law and Economics, no. 61.
Martinez, Luis Danton, The Creation of a Mortgage Backed Securities Market on Mexico,
Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics,
no. 82.
Mejica Rosales, Ricardo, El Chopo Economic Analysis on a Non-regulated Market, Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 20.
Mendoza Justo, Gustavo Hernandez O., Ma. Eugenia, Economic Analysis on Guerrillas, Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 62.
Meneses Cazares, Julio, Who Should I Vote For?, Mexican Association of Law and Economics
Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 38.
Meritano Corrales, Sergio, Economic Analysis on a New Federalism, Mexican Association of
0350 Law and Economics in Mexico 269
Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 17.
Messmacher Linatas, Miguel and Yaez Sandoval, Armando, Economic Analysis on the Federal
Hunting Law, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and
Economics, no. 105.
Meza Parra, Isaac Omar, The Limit of the Autonomy of the Central Bank in Mexico, Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 63.
Milo Caraza, Alexis and Valencia Alvarez Donaji, Economic Analysis of Art, Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 64.
Mir, Claudia, Zarate, Graciela and Ripol, Alex, Economic Analysis of the Federalization of the
Health Services in Mexico City, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series
Papers of Law and Economics, no. 65.
Montao Fernandez, Carlos, Analysis on the Regulation of the Federal Law of Environmental
Balance And Environment Protection in the Matter of Prevention and Control of Air Pollution,
Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics,
no. 106.
Montesinos Cordoba, Jorge Luis and Araujo Papilla, Agustin, Economic Analysis on Divorce,
Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics,
no. 66.
Obregon Roa, Hector Manuel, Economic Analysis of Internet, Mexican Association of Law and
Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 01.
Ordoes Bustos, Dora Irene, Economic Analysis of Theft, Mexican Association of Law and
Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 67.
Orejas R., Miguel A. Economic Analysis of the Mexican Legislation, Mexican Association of Law
and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 43.
Ortega Gilly, Federico, Management of Prisons in Mexico From Governmental To Private Sector,
Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics,
no. 52.
Ortega Ortiz, Hiquingari, Economic Analysis on Artificial Insemination in Humans, Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 23.
Ortiz Alonso, Maria Guadalupe, Efficiency on Family Law, Mexican Association of Law and
Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 35.
Perez Gavila, Fernando, An Economic Analysis of the Mexican System of Public Education,
Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics,
no. 11.
Perez Lara, Delfino, The Reform on House-living Funds: the Infonavit Case, Mexican Association
of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 41.
Pinto, Jesus, Economic Analysis of the Cocaine Market, Mexican Association of Law and
Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 68.
Pizaa Trevio, Karla, Economic Analysis on the Law of Investment Societies, Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 107.
270 Law and Economics in Mexico 0350
Pliega Zapata, Alejandra, Economic Analysis on Basic Education: Economic and Social
Development, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and
Economics, no. 69.
Pulido Rincon, Rodrigo, Economic Analysis on the Living-houses Renting Problem of Mexico
City: A Comparison Between the Former and the Actual Renting Law, Mexican Association of
Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 10.
Quiyond Jimenez, Alejandro, Be Ware!, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working
Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 26.
Ramirez Rodales, Alejandro, Economic Analysis on the Federal Fishing Law, Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 34.
Ramirez Salazar, Eduardo, Comparison Between Two Proposals To Solve the Intermediatism,
Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics,
no. 70.
Remes Tello De Meneses, Roberto, Economics, Law an Urban Transportation From Individual To
Collective Transportation, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers
of Law and Economics, no. 09.
Rendon Ojeda, Victor Armando, Analysis on the Efficiency of Corruption Against Inefficient
Laws, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and
Economics, no. 16.
Rios Gonzalez, Rogelio, Personal Economic Analysis on Public Policy: Make a Decision,
Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics,
no. 71.
Rivera, Miguel Angel, The Gossip Market, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working
Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 37.
Rocha, Carolina, Economic Analysis on Abortion, Mexican Association of Law and Economics
Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 19.
Roemer, Andrs (1989), Anlisis Econmico-Jurdico de le Acuacultura de Camern, el Caso
Mexicano (Economic Analysis of the Shrimp Market in Mexico), Mexico, UNAM.
Roemer, Andrs (1989), Evaluacion Juridica, Finmanciera, y Economicade la Camaronicultura
en Mexico, Instituto Tecnologico Autonomo de Mexico.
Roemer, Andrs (1992), Importancia del Anlisis Econmico del Derecho, Mexico, SUMMA de
la Sociedad Mexicana de Geografa en Mxico y Estadstica.
Roemer, Andrs (1993), Introduccion al Analisis Economico del Derecho, Mexico City, Fondo de
Cultura Economica.
Roemer, Andrs (1994), Introducin al Anlisis Econmico del Derecho (Introduction to Law and
Economics), Mexico, Fondo de Cultura Econmica, Sociedad Mexicana de geografa y
Estadstica, e Instituto Technolgico Autnome de Mxico.
Roemer, Andrs (1996), Economa y Derecho: Polticas Pblicas del Agua (Economics and Law:
Public Policy of Water), Centro de Investigacin y Docencia Econmica, la Sociedad Mexicana
de Geografa y Estadstica and Porra.
Roemer, Andrs, An Eclectic Approach To Property Rights, Mexican Association of Law and
Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics.
Roemer, Andrs, Economic Analysis of Law: Markets For Water In Mexico, Porrua, Cide.
Roemer, Andrs, Introduction To Law and Economics, Fce, Smge, Itam (1994).
0350 Law and Economics in Mexico 271
Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 77.
Torres Rivera, Alma Delia and Ponce Lazaro, Reyna, Economic Analysis of the Criminal Code An
the Criminal Procedure Code: the State of Morelos Proposal, Mexican Association of Law and
Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 78.
Trevio Goirgulli, Alfonso, Economic Analysis on Civil Law Regulation, Mexican Association of
Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 42.
Urritia, Luis, Economic Reasons for a Financial Regulation in Mexico, Mexican Association of
Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 02.
Valades, Jose Diego, Economic Analysis on Flirting, Mexican Association of Law and Economics
Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 79.
Valderrama Lopez, Juan Carlos and Diaz Tapia, Juan, A Negotiation Project To Accomplish An
Agreement of Economic Partnership And Political Arrangement Between Mexico And the
European Community, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of
Law and Economics, no. 41.
Valdes Palacio, Yailen and Romo Morales, Gerardo, Abortion in Mexico: An Economic Analysis,
Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics,
no. 109.
Varela Pineda, Flavio, Institutional Change And Internal Reform In the P.r.i., Mexican
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 63.
Vargas Diaz, Jaime Fernando, The Deregulation in the Electrical Industry in Mexico: Causes and
Consequenses, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law
and Economics, no. 04.
Vazquez Ochoa, David, Economic Effects on the Rural Production System Under the Law of
January 15th of 1915, and Under the Reform of Article 27 of the Constitution of Mexico,
Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics,
no. 33.
Vega Godines, Alejandro, Law and Neo-instututional Economics of the Budgetary System of
Education, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and
Economics, no. 80.
Vernon, Andres, The Last Chance: Reforms on Article 27 of the Mexican Constitution and a New
Law on Forests, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law
and Economics, no. 110.
Villa Rodriguez, Jose Manuel, Games, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working
Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 18.
Willie, Thomas, An Economic Analysis of the Market For Diamonds, Mexican Association of
Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 81.
Yunes Zorrilla, Jeso, The Human Capital: Municipalities, Mexican Association of Law and
Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 08.
Zavala Pavila, Adolfo, Economic Analysis on Crime, Mexican Association of Law and Economics
Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 32.
Zepeda Lecuona, Guillermo Raul, Law on Environmental and Protection Policies, Mexican
0350 Law and Economics in Mexico 273
Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 111.
Zepeda Leucona, Guillermo Raul, Analysis on the Reform of the Legal Regime of the Ministerio
Publico (Public Ministry) on Justice Prosecution, Mexican Association of Law and
Economics Working Series Papers of Law and Economics, no. 50.
Zepeda Leucona, Guillermo Raul, Economic Analysis of the Judiciary System in the State of
Jalisco, Mexican Association of Law and Economics Working Series Papers of Law and
Economics, no. 01.
0355
LAW AND ECONOMICS IN THE NETHERLANDS
Rudi W. Holzhauer
Erasmus University of Rotterdam
Rob Teijl
Dutch Ministry of Justice
Copyright 1999 Rudi W. Holzhauer en Rob Teijl
Abstract
The rise of law and economics in the Netherlands has been a mixed lawyers
and economists effort. Budget cuts during recent years put pressure on
economics departments in law faculties to focus more on the law and hence
law and economics became an interesting issue for these departments.
Adoption by the regular law professors is fairly slow and fairly reluctant.
The cautious positioning of law and economics by its early (and later)
proponents avoided any major confrontative philosophical or political
debates.
JEL classification: K00.
Keywords: Research, Education, Teaching.
1. Introduction - Overview
The proper activities in new law and economics started in the Netherlands in
1987. Leiden University (Franken, Hol) then organised a nationwide
meeting, with the aims to make an inventory of all law and economics
activities in the Netherlands, and to see what options were open to cooperate
with and coordinate research and teaching. Approximately 40 academics
attended that meeting.
One of the results was the plan to cooperate in writing a student text
book. Representatives of three faculties (Franken and Hol from Leiden,
Backhaus from Maastricht and Holzhauer and Teijl from Rotterdam) agreed
to write a text that was embedded in Dutch law and that used examples from
the Dutch legal system. A first student textbook by Holzhauer and Teijl was
published in June 1989; a second edition appeared in 1995. Other textbooks
followed: Theeuwes et al. (1989), Hondius (1991), Nentjes (1993b) and Van
Velthoven and Van Wijck (1997).
274
0355 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 275
The Dutch judiciary has a centre for permanent education. In 1992 a first
two day seminar was organised, which basically is repeated bi-annually.
There is some - be it limited - interest (15 to 20 participants).
The major general Dutch law review (Nederlands Juristen Blad) has had
a special editor for law and economics since the 1980s (Ejan Mackaay). The
main student law journal (Ars Aequi) has had a one page column twice a
year since 1992 (Holzhauer, Teijl). The major general Dutch economists
journal (Economisch Statistische Berichten) intends to accommodate a
regular column from 1998 onwards.
So far the Society for Civil Law (Van den Bergh and Faure, 1990) and
the Society for Procedural Law (Holzhauer, 1993) have explicitly put the law
and economics approach at the centre of an annual meeting.
2. Research - General
The first PhD thesis in the field of law and economics in the Netherlands is
Mackaay (1982). Mackaay has also published several overview articles of
(1985, 1988, 1989, 1991). Kaufmann wrote his PhD thesis in 1985 on
Passing off and misappropriation in the law of unfair competition (thesis
Utrecht); Kneppers-Heynert in 1988 on An economic and legal analysis of
franchising (thesis Groningen); Kerkmeester in 1989 on Law and game
theory: an economic model for the emergence of state organization and law
(thesis Rotterdam); Hol on Law in balance (1993; thesis Leiden) and Teijl
and Holzhauer in 1997 on Changing Perspectives in Law and Economics
(thesis Rotterdam). By now several law and economics oriented research
projects have been started.
In 1988 it was decided to found the Centre for Law and Economics. Its
goal is to promote research and teaching in law and economics. Its
information adress is Erasmus University Rotterdam - law faculty, PO box
1738, 3000 DR Rotterdam, Netherlands.
In 1988 the first workshop on law and economics was held in Maastricht
(Backhaus). The workshop had five lectures. And Gordon Tullock was as a
guest-speaker invited. His keynote lecture was on Economic analysis of
legal procedure. By now there is a firm tradition: in April 1998 the eleventh
Workshop was held in Maastricht.
All law faculties now regularly focus on the economic implications of
(changes in) legal rules.
In 1991 a Dutch language law and economics series was started by
Franken, Holzhauer and Teijl (Series Rechtseconomische Verkenningen,
published by Gouda Quint, Arnhem). The purpose is to offer a forum for
publishing contributions of 75-150 pages. On average one volume a year has
276 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 0355
3. Research - Topics
Property Law
Limited attention is paid to institutional property arrangements. Bouckaert
(1990) gives a summary outline. Meijs and Jansen (1989) relate ownership
to politics and economics. De Geest (1994) discusses private versus common
ownership. Economic ownership and legal ownership are confronted by
Slagter (1968), Colijn et al. (1981) and Huijgen (1995). For a more
sociological setting see von Benda-Beckman (1992).
Hol (1993) touches nuisance issues. Environmental topics are discussed
by Faure (1990b, 1993, 1994). Wiersma (1989) and Peeters (1992) focus on
tradeable (pollution) permits. Ownership of the company is analysed by
Moerland (1995c) and Timmerman (1996). See Company Law below.
Teijl and Holzhauer (1991b) provide an overview of the economic
analysis of intellectual property. An economic perspective on intellectual
property can also be found in Koopmans (1983, 1994) and Strowel (1994).
Van Dijk (1994) concentrates on the economics of patent protection, and
Kaufmann (1986) on the economics of trademarks. For an economic
approach on copyright on the Internet see Richard (1996).
Contracts
There is no literature on the economics of contracts in general. Du Perron
(1990) and Theeuwes (1996) are summary attempts. Franchising is dealt
with in depth by Kneppers-Heynert (1988). Aelen (1990) examines the EC
block exemption for franchise agreements. Castermans and Notermans
(1985) look at disclosure rules in contract formation.
Tort
Basic outlines are Mackaay (1990) and Van Schilfgaarde (1990). Hol (1993)
offers a fairly thorough economic analysis of general tort principles,
including a philosophical perspective. Van Dam (1989) touches on law and
economics. Causation issues are discussed in Faure (1993), Ietswaart (1995)
and Kerkmeester (1993b, 1994b). Law professor and Supreme Court Judge
Nieuwenhuis (1991) has always been rather sceptical. More opposition can
be found in Hol (1991) and Bloembergen (1996). Raes (1988b) criticizes the
economic approach to personal harm on humanistic/philosophical grounds.
Traffic liability is the topic in two early reports by the Justice Department
Ministerie van Justitie (1978, 1980). Nentjes and Dijkstra (1993) and Van
0355 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 277
Company Law
By way of introduction read De Kluiver (1994, 1996). The ownership of
the firm and the relationship between shareholders, management and
supervisors are discussed in Boot (1995), Brink (1994), Rietkerk (1992),
Slagter (1988, 1989, 1993), Van der Grinten (1994), Wildenberg and
Zwetsloot (1994).
Different systems of remuneration are analysed by Eigenhuizen et al.
(1987) and Bruining et al. (1989).
In 1995 and 1996 there was a fairly extensive discussion of Corporate
Governance issues: see Boot (1994), Crist (1995), Frentrop (1995), Frijns et
al. (1995), Mendel (1995), Moerland (1995b and 1995e), Slagter (1994),
Tabaksblatt (1995), Wallage (1995), Wiggers (1995), Commissie Corporate
Governance (1996) and Raaijmakers et al. (1996). This discussion is likely
to continue. Moerland (1995a) analyses alternative disciplinary mechanisms
in different corporate systems.
Insider dealing is discussed in Doorenbos and Roording (1990). More
law than economics (on insider dealing) are Beckman and Herst (1988),
Corstens (1989), Doorenbos (1989), Dreese (1984), Groenhuijsen (1995),
Slagter (1996) and Vote (1989).
Economic analyses of takeovers can be found in Rietkerk (1988) and
Moerland (1988), facts on the Netherlands in Vogelzang and Dotsch (1988).
See Braakman (1988) for the role of European competition law. Bruining
(1992) shows the effects of takeovers on share prices. De Jong (1988) relates
protective measures to takeovers.
Theoretical and empirical concentration issues in De Jong (1992),
Dorsman (1992) and Langendijk (1992).
Tax Law
Contributions on the economics of tax law are Caanen and Essers (1990),
Hessing and Elffers (1994) and Zwemmer (1995).
Criminal Law
Basic analyses in line with Gary Beckers approach: Meester and Wesemann
(1976), Franken (1983, 1991) and Nentjes (1988).
The economic and non-economic factors of crime are analysed in
Theeuwes and Van Velthoven (1994a). Their conclusion is that economic
determinants like unemployment, probability of apprehension and
punishment significantly explain the decrease in criminality, but that social
norm variables at the same time have a relatively more substantial effect. An
economic model of the criminal law system is developed by Van Tulder
(1994). In a non-model way see Steenhuis (1984). Of special interest is Van
Tulders finding that extra expenditures later on in the system (for example
on prisons) are more effective. Kleemans (1996) focusses on the possibilities
to describe urban crime patterns using choice behaviour of those who
commit the specific crime. Economic offences are discussed in Van Altena
et al. (1990).
Critique on the rational choice model with respect to criminal law can be
found in Franken (1983), Wladimiroff (1991), Baerveldt (1993), Bruinsma
and Van de Bunt (1993), Van Dijk (1993), Hesseling (1993), Kleemans
(1993) and Moerland (1993). The latter six references are in a special issue
of the Tijdschrift voor Criminologie (Journal of Criminology 1993/2)
rational choice and criminal behaviour.
Administrative/Constitutional Law
An economic model for the emergence of state organization and law in a
game theoretical approach is offered by Kerkmeester (1989). The same
author presents an introduction into constitutional economics in
Kerkmeester (1993a). For an economic analysis of constitutional law see
also Backhaus (1991) and Ten Berge (1991). Van Ommeren (1990) looks at
administrative compensation and financial capacity from a law and
economics angle. Jansen (1996) discusses administrative fines in the new
Dutch Competition Act.
Regulation
Early notes on deregulation are De Kraan (1982a, 1982b) (general), Mok
(1983), Slot (1983) and Bolkestein (1985) (competition law). Deregulation
in working conditions legislation is discussed in Faure (1995a). In 1994 the
Minister of Economic Affairs initiated a research project on the functioning
of the market in the Netherlands. It has boosted the writings on regulation in
0355 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 279
Public Choice
The economic theory of political decisionmaking is presented by
Groenewegen et al. (1988), De Geest (1990), Van Winden (1990) and
Schreuders (1990).
Environmental Law
In a very general way Nentjes (1993a) discusses who owns the environment.
The efficiency of an environmental policy in accordance with market
principles is discussed in Wiersma (1989).
Faure (1990b) takes up the Shavell model for the choice of protecting the
environment through liability law or through regulation. The first use rule is
analysed in Faure (1994), and reflections on probabilistic causal evidence for
environmental health damage are made in Faure (1993). Nieuwenhuis
(1991) offers three ways of balancing interests in environmental law,
including a critique on the economic approach (see also Nieuwenhuis,
1997).
A comparative study regarding the transferability of pollution rights is to
be found in Peeters (1992). Nentjes (1996) compares tradeable permits to
covenants.
Legal Procedure
Van Velthoven and Van Wijck (1996, 1997) apply the Shavell model on
suits and settlements. Authors that should be mentioned here in a more
general way are Van Tulder, Van Koppen, Ten Kate and Malsch. All their
work is more or less on efficiency and effectiveness in the area of
adjudication. Their empirical approach partly stems from a sociological
background. More purely sociological in nature are the contributions of
Blankenburg (1984, 1990). Klijn (1988, 1996) are somewhere in between.
Contributions from lawyers are Van Dijk (1987) and Snijders (1987).
4. Teaching
The rise of law and economics in the Netherlands has been a mixed effort by
lawyers and economists. Most law faculties (there are eight in the
Netherlands) have their own chair in economics (as well as in sociology and
- often - psychology). Budget cuts during recent years put pressure on
economics departments in law faculties to focus more on the law and hence
law and economics became an interesting issue for these departments.
Adoption by the regular law professors is - as one could expect - fairly slow
and fairly reluctant. The cautious positioning of law and economics by its
early (and later) proponents avoided any major confrontative philosophical
or political debates.
So far, faculties of economics hardly seem to take an interest in law and
economics. Most contributions came and come from (economists and
lawyers in) law faculties.
For a moment, in the mid 1990s, the already mentioned budget cuts
threatened the existence of economics (and all other non-law disciplines) in
those faculties. However, there are now (1997/98) signs for a renewed
interest in interdisciplinary research and teaching. Thus, we may see regular
economics chairs being transformed into law and economics. On the whole
0355 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 281
ABN (1989), Octrooien en Licenties (Patents and Licences), Algemene Bank Nederland, 35 p.
ABN (1989), Kwekersrecht (Plant Breeders Right), Algemene Bank Nederland, 12 p.
ABN (1990), Octrooien in het Midden- en Kleinbedrijf (Patents in Middle-sized and Small
Companies), Algemene Bank Nederland, 11 p.
Aelen, L.O.M. (1990), De EEG-Groepsvrijstelling voor Franchise-Overeenkomsten (The EX
Block Exemption for Franchise Agreements), 38 Sociaal-Economische Wetgeving:
Tijdschrift voor Europees en Economisch Recht, 3-16.
Akkermans, A. (1995), Statistisch Causaliteitsbewijs bij Toxische Schadeveroorzaking (Statistical
Causation and Toxic Damage), Verzekeringsarchief, 44-53.
Algra, N.E. (1991), The Relations Between Law and Economics, Cahiers Rechtstheorie en
Encyclopedie van het Recht, Nr. 2.
Aretz, Edward M. (1993), Efficient Law, Limburg, Rijksuniversiteit, 181 p.
Baarslag, A.D. (1990), Octrooibeleid van de Onderneming (Patent Policy of the Firm), in X (ed.),
Octrooien in Nederland en Europa, Kamer van Koophandel en Fabrieken voor Rotterdam en
de Beneden-Maas, 22 mei.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (1990), De Eis tot Correctie van Ondoelmatig Recht (The Need to Correct
Inefficient Law), 39(10) Ars Aequi, 660-665.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (1991), Een Economische Analyse van het Constitutionele Recht (An
Economic Analysis of Constitutional Law), in Hondius, E.H., Schippers, J.J. and Siegers, J.J.
(eds), Rechtseconomie en Recht, Zwolle, Tjeenk Willink, 107-148.
Baerveldt, Chris (1993), Het Gebruik van Rationele Keuzereconstructies bij de Effect-evaluatie
van Interventies (The Use of Rational Choice Constructs in Evaluating the Consequences of
Interventions), 35(2) Tijdschrift voor Criminologie, 158-176.
Bakker, Luit M. et al. (1996), Economie en Recht: van Confrontatie naar Integratie (Economics
and Law: From Confrontation to Integration), in Van de Hoek, M.P. (ed.),
282 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 0355
Booij, J.T. (1993), De Economische Betekenis van het Auteursrecht in 1989: Rapportage 1993
(The Economic Role of Copyright Law in 1989: Report 1993), Amsterdam, Stichting voor
Economisch Onderzoek, 61 p.
Boot, Arnoud, W.A. (1994), Corporate Governance, Structuurregime en de Financiering van het
Bedrijfsleven (Corporate Governance, Supervisory Boards and Corporate Finance), 68
Maandblad voor Accountancy en Bedrijfseconomie, 724-736.
Boot, Arnoud, W.A. (1995), Naar een Dynamischer Structuurregime (Towards More Dynamic
Supervisory Boards), 73 De Naamloze Vennootschap, 280-284.
Bos, P.V.F. (1994), Van Ontvoogding naar Ontgoocheling of van Interstatelijkheid naar
Communautaire Dimensie? (From Guardianship to Illusion or From a State to a Community
Perspective), 69 Nederlands Juristen Blad, 906-911.
Bos, D.I. (1995), Marktwerking en Regulering: Theoretische Aspecten en Ervaringen in
Nederland en het Buitenland (Market Forces and Regulation: Theoretical Aspects and
Experiences in the Netherlands and Abroad), Den Haag, Ministerie van Economische Zaken,
130 p.
Bos, P.V.F. (1996), Het Voorstel voor een Nieuwe Mededingingswet: De Sprong van Us Men naar
het Paard van Troje (The New Competion Bill: From Like Knows Like to the Trojan Horse),
71 Nederlands Juristen Blad, 1237-1243.
Bos, P.V.F. and Fierstra, Marc A. (1989), Europees Mededingingsrecht (European Competition
Law), Deventer, Kluwer, 274 p.
Bos, P.V.F. and Stuyck, J.H.V. (1989), Concentratiecontrole naar EEG-recht (Concentration
Control in EC-Law), 37 Sociaal-Economische Wetgeving: Tijdschrift voor Europees en
Economisch Recht, 300-404.
Bouckaert, Boudewijn (1990), Eigendomsrechten vanuit Rechtseconomisch Perspectief (Property
Rights from an Economic Perspective), 39 Ars Aequi in Bock, Ruth de, et al. (ed),
Themanummer Rechtseconomie, 777-789.
Boukema, C.A. (1991), Economische en Juridische Aspecten van Hoofdstuk I Fusiecode
(Economic and Legal Aspects of Chapter I Dutch Merger Rules), in Coljee, P.D., Franken, H.,
Heertje, A. and Kanning, W. (eds), Law and Welfare Economics, Amsterdam, VU Amsterdam.
Bouckaert, Boudewijn (1994), Misschien Geen Vrienden, Waarschijnlijk Wel Bondgenoten:
Bedenkingen over de Nauwe Kloof tussen de Rechtssociologie van het Handelen en de
Rechtseconomie van de Sociale Coperatie (Perhaps not Friends but Probably Allies:
Considerations Regarding the Narrow Gap Between Legal Sociology of Action and Legal
Analysis of Social Cooperation), in Raes, Koen and Willekens, H. (eds), Economische
Verklaringen van het Recht, Den Haag, VUGA, 44-74.
Bovens, M.A.P. and Witteveen, W.J. (1987), Bruce Ackerman over Sociale Rechtvaardigheid, de
Rol van de Rechter en Law and Economics (Bruce Ackerman on Social Justice, the Role of
the Judiciary and Law and Economics), Staatkundig Jaarboek, Ars Aequi Libri, 255-278.
Braakman, A.J. (1988), Europees Kartelrecht als Strijdmiddel bij Overnames (European Anti-trust
Law as Takeover Combat Mechanism), 73 Economisch-Statistische Berichten, 854-858.
Brink, M. (1994), De Discussie over de Structuurwet Anders Bezien (A Different View on the
Supervisory Boards Act), 72 De Naamloze Vennootschap, 240-246.
Brinkhof, Jan J. (1990), Over Octrooirecht en Economie (On Patent Law and the Economy),
39(10) Ars Aequi, 794-802.
284 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 0355
Bruin, A.C.N. (1995), Fusietoezicht: Derde Pijler van het Mededingingsbeleid (Merger Control:
Third Leg of Competition Policy), 80 Economisch-Statistische Berichten, 489-492.
Bruining, J. (1992), De Effecten van Overnames op Aandelenrendementen in Fusies en Overnames
(The Effects of Take-Overs on Share Prices in Mergers and Take-Overs), in X (ed.), Fusies en
Overnames: Liber Amicorum aangeboden aan Prof. dr. L.A. Ankum, Schoonhoven,
Academic Service, 35-50.
Bruining, J. et al. (1989), Prestatieverbetering na Management Buy-out in het Licht van de Agency
Theorie (Improvement of Performance After Management Buy-Out in View of the Agency
Theory), 67 De Naamloze Vennootschap, 229-234.
Bruinsma, G.J.N. and Van de Bunt, H.G. (1993), Misdrijven uit Berekening (Calculated Crimes),
35(2) Tijdschrift voor Criminologie, 99-109.
Bruinsma, J.F. and Huls, N.J.H. (1995), Recht in de Broze Vernislaag van een Booming Industry
(Law as the Fragile Coat of Varnish of a Booming Industry), 70 Nederlands Juristen Blad,
1625-1631.
Caanen, Ch. and Essers, P.H.J. (1990), Rechtseconomie en Belastingrecht (Law and Economics
and Taxation Law), 39(10) Ars Aequi, 677-681.
Cantrijn, A., Jeunink, A. and Kabir, R. (1993), Beschermingsconstructies en de Rol van de
Aandeelhouder (Protection Schemes and the Role of the Shareholder), Nederlands Instituut
voor het Bank-en Effectenbedrijf.
Castermans, A.G. (1989), Schadevergoeding bij Dwaling (Damages for Misrepresentation),
Rechtsgeleerd Magazijn Themis, 136-146.
Castermans, A.G. and Notermans, R. (1985), Naar een economische analyse van de
mededelingsplicht bij dwaling (Towards an Economic Analysis of the Duty to Inform in
Misrepresentation Law), 141-155.
Chao-Duyvis, M.A.B. (1990), Vergelding als Schadevergoeding (Retribution as Damages),
Nederlands Juristen Blad, 513-520.
Cohen Jehoram, Herman (1979), Industrile Eigendom en Innovatie (Industrial Property and
Innovation), Nederlands Juristen Blad, 609-612.
Cohen Jehoram, Herman (1989), Het Economisch Belang van het Auteursrecht en de Gevaren
Daarvan (The Economic Importance of Copyright and its Dangers), 13 Informatierecht AMI,
91-95.
Colijn, P.J. et al. (eds) (1981), Economische Eigendom (Economic Ownership), Deventer, Kluwer,
92 p.
Coljee, P.D. (1991), Het Economisch Adviesrecht van de Ondernemingsraad, Quo Vadis? Artikel
25 WOR nader beschouwd (The Workers Council Economic Right of Advice, Quo Vadis), in
Coljee, P.D., Franken, H., Heertje, A. and Kanning, W. (eds), Law and Welfare Economics,
Amsterdam, VU Amsterdam, 77-99.
Commissie Corporate Governance (1996), Corporate Governance in Nederland (Corporate
Governance in the Netherlands), Amsterdam, Secretariaat Corporate Governance, 40 p.
Corstens, G.J.M. (1989), De Strafbaarstelling van Misbruik van Voorwetenschap (Penalization of
Insider Dealing), in X (ed.), Misbruik van Voorwetenschap, serie Monografien Van der
Heijden Instituut, Deventer, Kluwer, 19-38.
Cortenraad, Wouter H.F.M. (1996), Rechtseconomie Bestaat Niet (Theres no Such Thing as Law
and Economics), 71 Nederlands Juristen Blad, 963-967.
0355 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 285
Cramer, Meijering, Nijssen (1986), De Economische Betekenis van het Auteursrecht 1 (The
Economic Importance of Copyright 1), Amsterdam, Stichting voor Economisch Onderzoek
Universiteit van Amsterdam.
Crist, William D. (1995), The Corporate Governance Impact of US Pension Funds as Large Global
Investors, 73 De Naamloze Vennootschap, 257-264.
Crol, Conrad-Jan E. (1988), Beschermingsconstructies: Overbodig (Protective Measures:
Superfluous), 73 Economisch-Statistische Berichten, 862-864.
Crombag, H.F.M. and Van Dun, Frank (1990), Recht en Economie in Utopia: een
Rechtsfilosofisch Gedachtenexperiment (Law and Economics in Utopia: a Mental Experiment
in Legal Philosophy), 4 Rechtsgeleerd Magazijn Themis, 167-176.
Cuelenaere, L.M. and Leen, A.R. (1989), Een Rechtseconomisch Aspect van de Positie van de
Crediteur in een Faillissement. Is Afschaffing van de Maximum Rente een Oplossing? (A Law
and Economics Aspect of the Creditors Position), 38(10) Ars Aequi, 834-836.
De Beus, J.W. (1989), Markt, Democratie en Vrijheid (Market, Democracy and Liberty), Zwolle,
Tjeenk Willink, 682 p.
De Bock, Ruth (1990), Inleiding (Introduction), 39(10) Ars Aequi in Bock, Ruth de, et al. (eds),
Themanummer Rechtseconomie, 607-613.
De Bock, Ruth et al. (1990), Themanummer Rechtseconomie (Special Issue Law and Economics),
39(10) Ars Aequi, 607-804.
De Geest, Gerrit (1990), Public Choice en Rechtseconomie (Public Choice and Law and
Economics), 39(10) Ars Aequi in Bock, Ruth de et al. (eds), Themanummer Rechtseconomie,
666-673.
De Geest, Gerrit (1994), Private Versus Gemene Eigendom: de Strategy of the Commons
Herbekeken (Private versus Common Ownership: the Strategy of the Commons revisited), in
Raes, Koen and Willekens, H. (eds), Economische Verklaringen van het Recht, Den Haag,
VUGA, 132-146.
De Jong, Hendrik W. (1981), Marktorganisatie, Mededinging en Prijsvorming (Market
Organisation, Competition and Price-Making), 66 Economisch-Statistische Berichten,
1268-1280.
De Jong, Hendrik W. (1982), De Europese Mededingingspolitiek: Overzicht en Beoordeling
(European Competition Policy: Overview and Assessme), Beleid en Maatschappij, 230-240.
De Jong, Hendrik W. (1988), Fusies, Overnames en Beschermingsconstructies (Mergers,
Take-overs and Protective Devices), 73 Economisch-Statistische Berichten, 842-847.
De Jong, Hendrik W. (1989a), Concurrentie, Concentratie en het Europese Mededingingsbeleid
(Competition, Concentration and European Competition Policy), 74 Economisch-Statistische
Berichten, 1182-1187.
De Jong, Hendrik W. (1989b), Concurrentie en Concentratie in de Markteconomie (Competition
and Concentration in the Market Economy), 37 Sociaal-Economische Wetgeving: Tijdschrift
voor Europees en Economisch Recht, 664-688.
De Jong, Hendrik W. (1989c), Dynamische Markttheorie (Dynamic Market Theory), Leiden,
Stenfert Kroese, 334 p.
286 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 0355
De Jong, Hendrik W. (1990), Nederland: Het Kartelparadijs van Europa (The Netherlands:
European Anti-trust Paradise), 75 Economisch-Statistische Berichten, 244-248.
De Jong, Hendrik W. (1992), Theorie en Empirie van het Concentratieproces (Theorie and
Empiricism of the Process of Concentration), in X (ed.), Fusies en Overnames: Liber
Amicorum aangeboden aan Prof. dr. L.A. Ankum, Schoonhoven, Academic Service, 119-135.
De Jong, Hendrik W. (1997), Monopoliseren of Rivaliseren: Opstellen over Concurrentie,
Kartelvorming en Economische Machtsposities (Monopolizing or Competing: Essays on
Competition, Cartelization and Dominant Positions), Weteringbrug, Edclusa, 115 p.
De Kluiver, H.J. (1996), Mag het nog Ietsje Meer Zijn? Over Tekort, Overvloed en Onbehagen in
het Ondernemingsrecht (Could We Have Some More? On Shortage, Abundance and
Dissatisfaction in Company Law), 71 Nederlands Juristen Blad, 1439-1451.
De Kluiver, H.J. (1994), Het Vennootschapsrecht Dient te Worden Versoepeld ... en Verscherpt
(Company Law Should Be Relaxed ... and Tightened), 37 TVVS Maandblad voor
Ondernemingsrecht en Rechtspersonen, 174-180.
De Kraan, D.J. (1982a), Deregulering: een Begripsbepaling (Deregulation: A Definition), 9
Beleid en Maatschappij, 177-181.
De Kraan, D.J. (1982b), Deregulation, 62 Economisch-Statistische Berichten, 692-696.
De Laat, Eric (1997), Essays on Patent Policy. The Multi-dimensionality of Patents and
Asymmetric Information, Tinbergen Institute Research Series Nr. 137.
De Vreugd, Kees (1993), Overheidsingrijpen ter Bevordering van Marktwerking? De
Kartelwetgeving in Nederland met Behulp van de Rechtseconomie nader Bekeken
(Government Intervention in Furtherance of the Market? Dutch Anti Trust Legislation
Analysed from a Law and Economics Perspective), Rotterdam, Erasmus University, 127 p.
Degenkamp, J.Th. and Heynen, H.M. (1980a), Juridische en Economische Eigendom. Een Formele
Analyse (Legal and Economic Ownership. A Formal Analysis), in X (ed.), Tolvrije gedachten,
Deventer, Kluwer, 117-129.
Degenkamp, J.Th. and Heynen, H.M. (1980b), Tolvrije Gedachten (Free Thoughts), Deventer,
Kluwer, 304 p.
Doel, J. v.d. and Van Velthoven, Ben C.J. (1990), Democratie en Welvaartstheorie (3rd edn)
(Democracy and Welfare Economics), Alphen a.d. Rijn, Samsom H.D. Tjeenk Willink, 232 p.
Doel, J. v.d. and Van Velthoven, Ben C.J. (1993), Democracy and Welfare Economics: an
Introduction into New Political Economy, 2nd edn, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press,
212 p.
Doorenbos, D.R. (1989), Misbruik van Voorwetenschap: Schade en Schande (Insider Dealing:
Once Bitten, Twice Shy), 67 De Naamloze Vennootschap, 164-166.
Doorenbos, D.R. and Roording, J.F.L. (1990), Rechtseconomie en Strafrecht: een
Rechtseconomische Analyse van de Bestrijding van Misbruik van Voorwetenschap bij de
Handel in Rffecten (Law and Economics and Criminal Law: A Law and Economics Analysis of
Insider Trading in Securities), 39 Ars Aequi, 733-742.
Dooyeweerd, H. (1949a), De Sociologische Verhouding tussen Recht en Economie en het
Probleem van het Zogeheten Economisch Recht (The Sociological Relationship Between
0355 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 287
Law and Economics and the Problem of So-called Economic Law), in Dooyeweerd, H. (ed.),
Opstellen op het gebied van Recht, Staat en Maatschappij, Amsterdam, Bakker, 221-264.
Dooyeweerd, H. (ed.) (1949b), Opstellen op het Gebied van Recht, Staat en Maatschappij
(Essays on Law, State and Society), Amsterdam, Bakker, 471 p.
Dorsman, A.B. (1992), Concentratietendensen in de Financile Sector (Concentration Tendencies
in the Financial Sector), in X (ed.), Fusies en Overnames: Liber Amicorum aangeboden aan
Prof. dr. L.A. Ankum, Schoonhoven, Academic Service, 161-177.
Dreese, A. (1984), Misbruik van Voorwetenschap bij Effectenbeurstransacties. An Outsiders
View on Insider Trading (Insider Dealing on the Stock Exchange. An Outsiders View),
s-Gravenhage, Vereniging voor Effectenbescherming, 127 p.
Drijber, B.J. (1989), Groepsvrijstelling Know-How Licenties: Rechtszekerheid of Onduidelijkheid
(Block Exemption Know-How Licences: Legal Certainty or Vagueness), 37
Sociaal-Economische Wetgeving: Tijdschrift voor Europees en Economisch Recht, 200-216.
Eigenhuizen, H.G. et al. (1987), Aandelenopties voor Management en Personeel Sterk in Opkomst
(The Increasing Use of Stock Options for Management and Staff), 65(1) De Naamloze
Vennootschap, 1-16.
Eijlander, Ph. (1996), Regulering van de Kwaliteit van Zorginstellingen (Regulating the Quality of
Care Organizations), in Van Gestel, R.A.J. et al. (eds), Markt en Wet, Deventer, W.E.J. Tjeenk
Willink, 209-219.
Faure, Michael G. (1990a), De Verzekering van Geldboeten bij Zeewaterverontreiniging door Olie
(The Insurance of Fines with Respect to the Oil-Pollution in Sea Waters), in X (ed.),
Grensoverschrijdend Strafrecht. Opstellen, Arnhem, Gouda Quint, 203-221.
Faure, Michael G. (1990b), Milieubescherming door Aansprakelijkheidsrecht of Regulering
(Protecting the Environment through Liability Law or Regulation), 39(10) Ars Aequi,
759-769.
Faure, Michael G. (1991), Rechtseconomie en Privaatrecht: Kunnen Rechtsregels Bijdragen tot de
Reductie van Ongevalskosten (Law and Economics and Private Law: Can Legal Rules), in
Hondius, E.H., Schippers, J.J. and Siegers, J.J. (eds), Rechtseconomie en Recht, Zwolle,
Tjeenk Willink, 51-93.
Faure, Michael G. (1993), (G)een Schijn van Kans ((Not) A Shadow of a Chance), Antwerpen,
Maklu, 68 p.
Faure, Michael G. (1994), Eerstingebruikneming in het Milieurecht: een Rechtseconomische
Analyse (First Use in Environmental Law: a Law and Economics Analysis), in Raes, Koen and
Willekens, H. (eds), Economische Verklaringen van het Recht, Den Haag, VUGA, 147-178.
Faure, Michael G. (1995a), Rechtseconomische Kanttekeningen bij de Deregulering van de
Arbeidsomstandighedenwetgeving (A Law and Economics Note on Deregulation in Working
Conditions Legislation), 10(5) Sociaal Recht, 140-149.
Faure, Michael G. (1995b), Over Beschermde Slachtoffers, Vrijgevige Rechters en Zuchtende
Verzekeraars (On Protected Victims, Generous Judges and Yearning Insurers), 70(33)
Nederlands Juristen Blad, 1227-11235.
288 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 0355
Holzhauer, Rudi W., Teijl, Rob et al. (1995), Inleiding Rechtseconomie (Introduction to Law and
Economics), Arnhem, Gouda Quint.
Hondius, E.H. (1991), Rechtseconomie en Privaatrecht: Enige Kanttekeningen (Law and
Economics and Private Law: Some Remarks), in Hondius, E.H., Schippers, J.J. and Siegers,
J.J. (eds), Rechtseconomie en Recht, Zwolle, Tjeenk Willink, 95-105.
Hondius, E.H., Schippers, J.J. and Siegers, Jacques J. (eds) (1991), Rechtseconomie: Brug tussen
twee disciplines (Law and Economics: Bridge between two Disciplines), in Hondius, E.H.,
Schippers, J.J. and Siegers, J.J. (eds), Rechtseconomie en Recht, Zwolle, Tjeenk Willink, 1-7.
Hondius, E.H. et al. (1991), Rechtseconomie en Recht: Kennismaking met een Vakgebied in
Opkomst (Law and Economics and Law: Getting to Know an Emerging Discipline), Zwolle,
Tjeenk Willink, 201 p.
Hoogenboom, B. (1990), Rechtseconomie en Particuliere Beveiliging: Policing for profits als
Voorloper van Strafrechtelijke Hervormingen (Law and Economics and Private Security:
Policing for Profit as Precursor of Criminal Reform), 39(10) Ars Aequi, 721-732.
Hoogendoorn, Ms.N. (1995), De Accountant in het Spanningsveld tussen Rechtsregels en
Economische Werkelijkheid (The Accountant in the Area of Tension between Legal Rules and
Economic Reality), in X (ed.), Ondernemen tussen Macht en Ordening: Opstellen op het
Grensvlak van Economie en Recht, Amsterdam, Thesis Publishers, 57-72.
Huijgen, W.G. (1995), Economische Eigendom (Economic Ownership), Deventer, W.E.J. Tjeenk
Willink, 120 p.
Huls, N.J.H. (1988), Van Liquidatie tot Rehabilitatie (From Liquidation to Rehabilitation),
s-Gravenhage, Ministerie van Economische Zaken, 106 p.
Hulst, W.G.J. Van and Willems, J.G.L.M. (1989), Externe Organisatie: Een Kennismaking met
het Ondernemingsgedrag in Markteconomische Stelsels (External Organisation: An
Introduction to Firm Behaviour in Market Systems), Leiden, Stenfert Kroese, 284 p.
Huyghen, Annelies and Theeuwes, Jules (1997), Electriciteit wordt duur betaald (Electricity
doesnt come Cheap), Economisch-Statistische Berichten, 84-86.
Ietswaart, Heleen F.P. (1995), Boekbespreking: Michael Faure, (G)een Schijn van Kans,
Beschouwingen over het Statistisch Causaliteitsbewijs bij Milieugezondheidsschade (Book
Review: Michael Faure, (Not) A Shadow of a Chance), Reflections on Probabilistic Causal
Evidence for Environmental Health Damage), 156 Rechtsgeleerd Magazijn Themis, 35-38.
Jacobs, A.T.J.M. (1996), Deregulering, Economische Flexibiliteit en het Arbeidsrecht
(Deregulation, Economic Flexibility and Labour Law), in Gestel, R.A.J. van et al. (eds), Markt
en Wet, Deventer, W.E.J. Tjeenk Willink, 195-207.
Jansen, O.J.D.M.L. (1996), De Bestuurlijke Boete in het Wetsvoorstel Mededingingswet
(Administrative Fines in the Competition Bill), 71(31) Nederlands Juristen Blad, 1250-1254.
Jeunink, A. and Kabir, R. (1993), De Relatie tussen Aandeelhoudersstructuur en
Beschermingsconstructies (The Relation between the Shareholders Structure and Protection
Schemes), 71 De Naamloze Vennootschap, 90-95.
Jongbloed, A.W. (1993), Recht, Economie en Rechtseconomie (Law, Economics and Law and
Economics), 85(10) Rechtsstrijd, 204-210.
292 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 0355
al. (eds), Bijdragen tot de Rechtsgeschiedenis van de Negentiende Eeuw, Arnhem, Gouda
Quint, 235-254.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1994c), Economie als Integratieve Wetenschap (Economics as a Science of
Integration), in Foqu, R. et al. (eds), Gentegreerde Rechtswetenschap, Arnhem, Gouda
Quint, 379-402.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1996a), Boekbespreking: Baird, D.C., Gertner, R.H. and Picker, R.C., (Book
review) Game Theory and the Law, 25 Tijdschrift voor Rechtsfilosofie en Rechtstheorie,
72-75.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1996b), Evolutionaire Rechtseconomie: naar een Herwaardering van
Gewoonterecht? (Evolutionary Law and Economics: Towards a Reassessment of Customary
Law), 22 Recht en Kritiek, 335-355.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1996c), Bespreking van R.P. Malloy en J. Evensky (red.), Adam Smith and
the Philosophy of Law and Economics and van R.H. Coase, Essays on Economics and
Economists (Book Reviews), 22 Recht en Kritiek, 290-296.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1996d), Bespreking van G. De Geest, Economische Analyse van het
Contracten- en Quasi-contractenrecht: Een Onderzoek naar de Wetenschappelijke Waarde van
de Rechtseconomie (Book Review), 25 Tijdschrift voor Rechtsfilosofie en Rechtstheorie,
216-219.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1996e), Bespreking van F.P. van Tulder, Van Misdaad tot Straf: een
Economische Benadering van de Strafrechtelijke Keten (Book Review), 26 Delikt en
Delinkwent, 892-903.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1997), De Retoriek van de Rechtseconomie (The Rhetorics of Law and
Economics), in Feteris, E.T. et al. (eds), Op Goede Gronden, Nijmegen, Ars Aequi Libri,
207-213.
Kerkmeester, Heico and De Mulder, R.V. (1987), Statistiek en Bewijsrecht (Statistics and the Law
of Evidence), 62 Nederlands Juristen Blad, 73-81.
Kerkmeester, Heico and Holzhauer, Rudi W. (1998), Rechtseconomische Annotaties (Law and
Economics Case Comments), Rechtseconomische Verkenningen, Arnhem, Gouda Quint.
Kerkmeester, Heico O. and Mulder, R.V. De (1988), Beslissingstheoretische Criteria voor de
Beslechting van een Juridisch Geschil door een Onafhankelijke Derde (Theoretical
Decisionmaking Criteria in Settling a Legal Dispute by a Third Party), in Snijders, H.J. (ed.),
Overheidsrechter Gepasseerd, Arnhem, Gouda Quint, 501-511.
Kernkamp, F.H. (1985), Risk Appraisal, in Van Dunn, Jan M. et al. (eds), Iustitia et Amicitia,
Arnhem, Gouda Quint, 61-74.
Kleemans, Edward R. (1993), Misdaadanalyse en de Rationele Keuzebenadering (Crime Analysis
and the Rational Choice Perspective), 35(2) Tijdschrift voor Criminologie, 127-142.
Kleemans, Edward R. (1996), Strategische Misdaadanalyse en Stedelijke Criminaliteit
(Strategical Crime Analysis and City Crime), Enschede, Internationaal Politie Instituut Twente,
291 p.
Klijn, A. (1988), Duurder Recht, Minder Vraag: De Prijsverhoging van Rechtsverzorging en de
Gevolgen daarvan voor Lagere Inkomens (More Costly Law, Lesser Demand: The Increased
Price of Legal Assistance and its Consequences for Lower Incomes), s-Gravenhage, SDU, 96
p.
Klijn, A. et al. (1996), Rechtsbijstand: Krimpende Markten (Legal Assistence: Shrinking Markets),
s-Gravenhage, SDU.
294 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 0355
Kneppers-Heynert, E.M. (1988), Een Economische en Juridische Analyse van Franchising tegen
de Achtergrond van een Property Rrights- en Transactiekosten Benadering (An Economic
and Legal Analysis of Franchising in the Light of a Property and Transaction Costs Approach),
Groningen, Van Denderen, 268 p.
Kneppers-Heynert, E.M. (1995), Juridische en Economische Aspecten van Partnerships (Legal and
Economic Aspects of Partnerships), in X (ed.), Ondernemen tussen Macht en Ordening:
Opstellen op het Grensvlak van Economie en Recht, Amsterdam, Thesis Publishers, 15-35.
Koedijk, C.G. (1994), Nooit meer Slapen: Over Deregulering en Verantwoordelijkheid (No More
Sleeping: About Deregulation and Responsibility), Maastricht, Universitaire Pers, 34 p.
Koopmans, T. (1983), Mini-monopolies (Mini-monopolies), Rechtsgeleerd Magazijn Themis,
342-344.
Koopmans, T. (1994), Intellectuele Eigendom, Economie en Politiek (Intellectual Property,
Economics and Politics), 18 Informatierecht, 107-111.
Lambers, H.W. (1962), Mededingingspolitiek (Competition Policy), in Andriessen, J.E. and Van
Meerhaeghe, M.A.G. (eds), Theorie van de Economische Politiek, Leiden, Stenfert Kroese,
307-338.
Langendijk, H.P.A.J. (1992), Concentratie op de Markt voor Zakelijke Dienstverlening
(Concentration on the Market for Commercial Services), in X (ed.), Fusies en Overnames:
Liber Amicorum aangeboden aan Prof. dr. L.A. Ankum, Schoonhoven, Academic Service,
137-159.
Le Blanc, L.J.C.M. (1990), Bismarck als Benchmark. Enkele Rechtseconomische Beschouwingen
over Publieke Sector en Sociale Zekerheid in Nederland (Bismarck as Benchmark. Some Law
and Economics Considerations on the Public Sector and Social Welfare in the Netherlands),
39(10) Ars Aequi, 654-659.
Le Blanc, L.J.C.M. (1990), Bismarck als Benchmark: enkele Rechtseconomische Beschouwingen
over Publieke Sector en Sociale Zekerheid in Nederland (Bismarck as Benchmark: Some Law
and Economics Considerations on the Public Sector and Social Welfare in the Netherlands),
39(10) Ars Aequi, 654-6100.
Lindner, G.L. (1985), Arreststraf of Geldboete (Detention or Fine), Dissertatie Rijks Universiteit
Leiden.
Linneman, M.J.T. (1990), Sportrechten, artikel 15 en Marktopdeling (Sports Rights, Section 15
and Splitting up the Market), 14 Informatierecht AMI, 63-66.
Linssen, G.J. (1973), De Rol van de Commissie bij de toepassing van het Europese
mededingingsrecht (The Role of the Commission in Applying European Competition Law), in
Verloren Van Themaat, Pieter (ed.), Europees Kartelrecht anno 1973, Deventer, Kluwer,
23-45.
Linssen, G.J. (1981), De Verhouding Tussen het Formele en het Informele Kartelbeleid in
Nederland en de Plaats van de Commissie Economische Mededinging (The Interrelationship
between the Formal and Informal Dutch Anti-trust Policy and the Position of the Economic
Competition Commission), 24 TVVS Maandblad voor Ondernemingsrecht en
Rechtspersonen, 255-259.
Mackaay, Ejan (1980), Veranderingen in het Stelsel van Vergoeding en Verhaal van Schade
(Changes in the System of Compensation and Recoupment of Damages), 55 Nederlands
Juristen Blad, 813-825. Reprinted in Schade lijden en schade dragen, Zwolle, Tjeenk
Willink, Nederlands Juristenblad Boekenreeks No. 6, 1981.
0355 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 295
Mackaay, Ejan (1982), Economics of Information and Law, Boston, Kluwer-Nijhoff, 293 p.
Mackaay, Ejan (1985), Rechtseconomie - Hora Est (Law and Economics - The Time Has Come),
Nederlands Juristenblad, 1347 ff.
Mackaay, Ejan (1988), Het Recht Bezien door de Bril van de Economist - Een gestyleerd overzicht
van de rechtseconomie (Law Seen Through Economists Glasses: An Overview),
Rechtsgeleerd Magazijn Themis, 411-452.
Mackaay, Ejan (1989), Rechtseconomie Behind the Dikes (Law and Economics Behind the
Dikes), Nederlands Juristenblad, 921-922.
Mackaay, Ejan (1990), Het Aansprakelijkheidsrecht (Liability Law), 39(10) Ars Aequi, 743-749.
Mackaay, Ejan (1991), Verschuivingen in De Rechtseconomie (Shifts in Law and Economics), 66
Nederlands Juristenblad, 1505-1521.
Maijoor, Steven J. (1991), The Economics of Accounting Regulation, Maastricht, Datawyse, 213
p.
Maijoor, Steven J. (1994), Economische Analyses van de Regelgeving van de Externe
Verslaggeving: een Beschrijving van Onderzoeksresultaten (Economic Analyses of External
Accounting Rules: a Description of Research Results), 68 Maandblad voor Accountancy en
Bedrijfseconomie, 112-118.
Maijoor, Steven J. (1995), Dominees op de Markt: een Economische Analyse van de Markt, het
Kantoor en het Controleproces van Accountants (Preachers on the Market: an Economic
Analysis of the Market, the Office and the Monitoring by Accountants), Maastricht,
Universitaire Pers, 39 p.
Malsch, Marijke (1990), Advocaten Voorspellen de Uitkomst van hun Zaken (Lawyers
Predictions of Judicial Decisions: A Study on Calibration of Experts), Lisse, Swets &
Zeitlinger, 109 p.
Malsch, Marijke (1997), De Uitkomst van de Zaak Voorspellen (Predicting the Outcome of
Judicial Decisions), in Van Koppen, Peter J. et al. (eds), Het Hart van de Zaak, Deventer,
Gouda Quint, 532 ff.
Meester, G. and Wesemann, P. (1976), Kosten-baten Analyse en Strafrecht (Cost Benefit Analysis
and Criminal Law), in X (ed.), Portret van de Juridische Faculteit Rotterdam 12 1/2,
Deventer, Kluwer, 217-228.
Meijs, Paul and Jansen, Wim (1989), Eigendom tussen Politiek en Economie (Ownership between
Politics and Economy), Groningen, Wolters-Noordhoff, 195 p.
Melai, A.L. (1973), De Straf en het Gezichtspunt van de Econometristen (Punishment and the
Econometrist Perspective), in X (ed.), Speculum Langemeyer, Zwolle, Tjeenk Willink,
315-331.
Mendel, M.M. (1995), Wetsontwerp Beschermingsmaatregelen VEUO-beurs uit Oogpunt van
Rechtsbedeling en Corporate Governance (Protective Measures Bill from a Justice and from a
Corporate Governance Perspective), 73 De Naamloze Vennootschap, 271-273.
Ministerie Van Justitie (1978), Rapport van de Studiegroep Verkeersaansprakelijkheid, Deel I,
Vergoeding van Schade door Dood en Letsel (Report of the Commission Traffic Liability,
Part I, Compensation of Damages through Death and Injury), s-Gravenhage, Staatsuitgeverij,
1978 p.
Ministerie Van Justitie (1980), Rapport van de Studiegroep Verkeersaansprakelijkheid, Deel II,
Vergoeding van Zaakschade (Report of the Commission Traffic Liability, Part I,
296 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 0355
Nagelkerke, J.J. (1979), Beschouwingen over Economische Wetenschap en haar Betekenis voor de
Rechtsvorming (Considerations about Economic Science and its Use), RMThemis, 356-385.
Nederlands Economisch Instituut (1989), Naar een Economische Benadering van Criminaliteit en
Veiligheidszorg (Towards an Economic Approach of Delinquency and Security Provision),
Rotterdam, Nederlands Economisch Instituut.
Nederlands Economisch Instituut (1991), Verhuur- en leenrecht EG. Commentaar op het
SEO-rapport Naar een Verhuur- en Leenrecht in de Europese Gemeenschap (EC Rental
and Lending Rights. Commentary on the SEO-report Towards a Rental and Lending Right in
the European Community), Rotterdam, Nederlands Economisch Instituut, 24 p.
Nederlof, H.P. (1994), Gevolgen van de Toepassingsdrempel van Vijf Miljard Ecu voor de
Beleidsconsistentie bij Concentratiecontrole (Consequences of the Five Billion Ecu Threshold
for Policy-consistency in Concentration Controle), 42 Sociaal-Economische Wetgeving:
Tijdschrift voor Europees en Economisch Recht, 83-96.
Nentjes, Andries (1987), De Economie van het Recht (The Economy of the Law), oratie
Groningen, s.l., 18 p.
Nentjes, Andries (1988), De Welvaartseffecten van het Strafrecht (Welfare Effects of Criminal
Law), 2 Justitile Verkenningen, 34-52.
Nentjes, Andries (1993a), Van Wie is het Milieu? (Who Owns the Environment?), 39(10) Ars
Aequi in Bock, Ruth de et al. (eds), Themanummer Rechtseconomie, 706-713.
Nentjes, Andries (1993b), Elementaire Rechtseconomie (Basic Law and Economics), Groningen,
Wolters-Noordhoff, 139 p.
Nentjes, Andries (1996), Meer Markt in het Milieubeleid: Convenanten Versus Verhandelbare
Vergunningen (More Market in Environmental Policy: Covenants Versus Tradeable Permits),
in Van de Hoek, M.P. (ed.), Opstellen aangeboden aan prof. dr. C. Rijnvos, Groningen,
Wolters-Noordhoff, 112-126.
Nentjes, Andries and Dijkstra, J. (1993), Verkeersaansprakelijkheid: Slachtoffercompensatie of
Ongevallenpreventie (Traffic Liability: Compensating Victims or Preventing Accidents), 68
Nederlands Juristen Blad, 951-954.
Nieuwenhuis, J.H. (1984), Recht en Belang (Law and Interests), Flores Debitorem, 65-74.
Nieuwenhuis, J.H. (1988), Ieder het Zijne (Each His Own), 2 RMThemis, 73-84.
Nieuwenhuis, J.H. (1991), Blinddoek En Balans in Het Milieurecht. Drie Manieren Om Belangen
af te Wegen (Blindfold and Balance in Environmental Law. Three Ways of Balacing
Interests), in X (ed.), Dilemmas van Aansprakelijkheid, Zwolle, Tjeenk Willink, 37-51.
Nieuwenhuis, J.H. (1997), De Ramp op het Pikmeer (The Pikmeer Disaster), Deventer, Kluwer, 22
p.
Ommeren, F.J. Van (1990), Bestuurscompensatie, Draagkracht en Rechtseconomie
(Administrative Compensation, Financial Capacity and Economic Analysis of Law), 39(10)
Ars Aequi, 682-691.
Ottervanger, T.R. (1996), Concentratietoezicht (Monitoring Concentrations), 71 Nederlands
Juristen Blad, 1245-1249.
298 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 0355
Pagie, Katja (1993), Wel of Niet Fuseren? Een Onderzoek vanuit Rechtseconomisch Perspectief
(To Merge or Not To Merge? A Law and Economics Perspective), thesis.
Peeperkorn, Luc (1987), Mededingingsbeleid op klompen (Competition Policy on Wooden
Shoes), 10 Tijdschrift voor politieke economie, 57-75.
Peeperkorn, Luc (1988), Openbaarheid van Kartels (The Public Nature of Cartels), 73
Economisch-Statistische Berichten, 212-214.
Peeperkorn, Luc (1989a), Het EG-mededingingsbeleid (EC Competition Policy), 74
Economisch-Statistische Berichten, 1139-1142.
Peeperkorn, Luc (1989b), Fusiecontrole in de EG (EC Merger Control), 74
Economisch-Statistische Berichten, 1163-1165.
Peeters, Marjan G.W.M. (1992), Marktconform Milieurecht. Een Rechtsvergelijkende Studie naar
de Verhandelbaarheid van Vervuilingsrechten (Market Conform Environmental Law. A
Comparative Study Regarding the Transferability of Pollution Rights), Zwolle, Tjeenk Willink,
438 p.
Peeters, Marjan G.W.M. (1994), Marktconforme Regulering (Market Conform Regulation), in
Eijlander, Ph. et al. (eds), Wetgeven en de Maat van de Tijd, Deventer, W.E.J. Tjeenk Willink,
125-135.
Perron, Edgar Du (1990), De rechtseconomische Analyse van het Verbintenissenrecht (A Law and
Economics Analysis of the Law of Obligations), 39(10) Ars Aequi, 770-776.
Pijnacker Hordijk, E.P.H. and Snoep, T.M. (1996), De Overheid als Ondernemer: Kanttekeningen
vanuit Mededingingsrechtelijk Perspectief (The Government as Entrepreneur: Notes From a
Competion Law Perspective), 71 Nederlands Juristen Blad, 923-929.
Praet, Patrick (1992), De List van de Economische Rede: de Ethische Constructie in Law and
Economics (The Lure of Economic Reasoning: the Ethical Construction in
Law-and-Economics), 18 Recht en Kritiek, 343-359.
Quaedvlieg, Antoon A. (1992), The Economic Analysis of Intelletual Property Law, in Korthals
Altes, Willem F., Dommering, Egbert J., Hugenholtz, P. Bernt and Kabel, Jan J.C. (eds),
Information Law Towards the 21st Century, Deventer, Kluwer, 379-393.
Raaijmakers, M.J.G.C. et al. (1996), Corporate Governance in Nederland: Besluitvorming en
Verantwoording in Beursondernemingen (Corporate Governance in the Netherlands:
Decisionmaking and Answerability in Quoted Companies), Den Haag, Stichting Maatschappij
en Onderneming, 117 p.
Raes, Koen (1988a), Rechtstheorie als Ideologiekritiek (Law and Economics as Ideological
Criticism), in Kamstra, O.W.M. et al. (eds), Nederlandsche Rechtswetenschap, Zwolle,
Tjeenk Willink, 283-298.
Raes, Koen (1988b), Onrechtmatige Daad en de Markt van Pijn en Smart (Torts and the Market
for Pain and Suffering), 14 Recht en Kritiek, 102-125.
Raes, Koen (1990), Het Recht van de Schaarste (The Law of Scarcety), 16 Recht en Kritiek,
380-394.
Raes, Koen and Willekens, Harry (1994a), Grondproblemen en -Mogelijkheden (Basic Problems
and Options), in Raes, Koen and Willekens, H. (eds), Economische Verklaringen van het
Recht, Den Haag, VUGA, 9-43.
Raes, Koen (1994), 'Economische verklaringen van het recht: grondproblemen en -mogelijkheden'
(Economic Explanations of Law: Fundamental Problems and Potential)', 2 Recht der
0355 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 299
Werkelijkheid, 9-44. Reprinted in Raes, Koen and Willekens, Harry (eds.), Economische
verklaringen van het recht, 's-Gravenhage, Vuga, 1994
Resius, F.J. (1990), Uitgeversbescherming (The Protection of Publishers), 14 Informatierecht,
67-69.
Richard, Th.A.M. (1996), Naar een Economische Benadering van het Auteursrecht op Internet
(Towards an Economic Approach of Copyright on Internet), 71 Nederlands Juristen Blad,
957-962.
Richters, H.W. (1991), Schikkingen en Proceskansen (Settlements and Expected Proceedings
Outcome), diss. Rotterdam, 171 p.
Rietkerk, G. (1988), Bestuursonvriendelijke Onderneming: een Countervailing Power. Een
Economische Analyse (Management Unfriendly Take-over: A Countervailing Power. An
Economic Analysis), 66 De Naamloze Vennootschap, 45-54.
Rietkerk, G. (1992), Structuurregeling aan Heroverweging Toe (Supervisory Rules to be
Reconsidered), 77 Economisch-Statistische Berichten.
Rovens, R. and Prinsen, P.J. (1984), Extra Politie-inzet en Rijden onder Invloed (More Police and
Drunken Driving), 52 WODC.
Ru, H.J. De (1987), Staat, Markt en Recht (The State, the Market and the Law), Zwolle, Tjeenk
Willink, 93 p.
Ru, H.J. De (1988), Prijst de Wet zich uit de Markt? (Does the Law Price Itself Out of the
Market?), Zwolle, Tjeenk Willink.
Ryan, Bernard (1994), Law and Economics and Employment Law, in Raes, Koen and Willekens,
H. (eds), Economische Verklaringen van het Recht, Den Haag, VUGA, 109-131.
Scheiwe, Kirsten (1991), Costs and Benefits of Housework: Winners and Losers, 17(2) Recht en
Kritiek, 283-297.
Schenk, Hans (1997), Fusies, Efficintie en Mededingingsbeleid: Mogelijkheden en Beperkingen
van het Nieuwe Concentratietoezicht (Mergers, Efficiency and Competition Policy: Options and
Limitations of the New Concentration Monitoring), in Dankbaar, Ben and Becker, F. (eds),
Economisch Beleid in een Ondernemende Samenleving, Houtem/Diegem, Bohn Stafleu/Van
Loghum, 111-148.
Schippers, J.J. (1988), Rechtseconomie: het Recht van de Economie en de Plicht van het Recht
(Law and Economics: Laws of Economics and the Duty of the Law), 5 Lust: Onafhankelijk
Juridisch Opinieblad, 104-109.
Schreuders, Wicher (1990), Het Formatie Dillemma: Nieuwe Variant op het Prisoners Dilemma
(The Formation Dilemma, A New Variant on the Prisoners Dilemma), 5 Namens, 13-17.
Schreuders, Wicher (1994), Globale Grenzen (Global Frontiers), in Department of Economic
Affairs (ed.), Internationaal Platform Globalisering, Den Haag, Ministerie van Economische
Zaken, 105-110.
Schreuders, Wicher and Holzhauer, Rudi W. (eds) (1993), Teksten Rechtseconomie (Readings in
Law-and-Economics), Arnhem, Gouda Quint, 461 p.
SEO (1982), De Economische Betekenis van het Auteursrecht in Nederland (The Economic
Importance of Copyright in the Netherlands), Amsterdam, Stichting voor Economisch
Onderzoek, 241 p.
SEO (1989), Naar een Verhuur- en Leenrecht in de Europese Gemeenschap (Towards a Rental
and Lending Rights in the European Community), Amsterdam, Stichting voor Economisch
Onderzoek, 203 p.
300 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 0355
Teijl, Rob and Holzhauer, Rudi W. (1995), The Impact of the Austrian School on Law and
Economics, in Bouckaert, Boudewijn and De Geest, Gerrit (eds), Essays in Law and
Economics II: Contract Law, Regulation, and Reflections on Law and Economics,
Antwerpen, Maklu, 247-266.
Teijl, Rob and Holzhauer, Rudi W. (1997), Wisselende Perspectieven in de Rechtseconomie
(Changing Perspectives in Law and Economics), Arnhem, Gouda Quint, 431 p.
Ten Berge, J.B.J.M. (1991), Rechtseconomie en Staatsrecht/bestuursrecht (Law and Economics
and Constitutional/Administrative Law), in Hondius, E.H., Schippers, J.J. and Siegers, J.J.
(eds), Rechtseconomie en Recht, Zwolle, Tjeenk Willink, 149-162.
Ten Kate, J. (1989), Schikkingen tijdens Civielrechtelijke Geschillen (Settlements in Private Law
Disputes), 10(1) Recht der Werkelijkheid, 63-79.
Ten Kate, J. and Koppen, P.J. Van (1984), Determinanten van Privaatrechtelijke Beslissingen
(Determinants of Civil Decisions), Arnhem, Gouda Quint, 123 p.
Ten Kate, J. and Koppen, P.J. Van (1997), Schikken of Niet (To Settle or Not To Settle), in Van
Koppen, Peter J. et al. (eds), Het Hart van de Zaak, Deventer, Gouda Quint, 44-62.
T Gilde, A.P.J. and Haank, D.J. (1985), De Praktijk van de Wet Economische Mededinging (The
Competition Act in Practice), s-Gravenhage, SWOKA, Onderzoeksrapport, 38 p.
Theeuwes, Jules J.M. (1996), Economische Analyse van het Overeenkomstenrecht (Economic
Analysis of Contract Law), in Van de Hoek, M.P. (ed.), Opstellen aangeboden aan prof. dr.
C. Rijnvos, Groningen, Wolters-Noordhoff, 127-152.
Theeuwes, Jules J.M. and Van Velthoven, Ben C.J. (1994a), Een Economische Visie op de
Ontwikkeling van de Criminaliteit (An Economic Look at the Development of Criminality),
20 Justitile Verkenningen, 42-65.
Theeuwes, Jules J.M. and Van Velthoven, Ben C.J. (1994b), De Ontwikkeling van de Criminaliteit
in Nederland, 1950-1990: een Economische Analyse (The Development of Criminality in the
Netherlands, 1950-1990: an Economic Analysis), Research Memorandum 94-07, Faculty of
Law, Department of Economics.
Theeuwes, Jules J.M., Van Velthoven, Ben C.J. and Winters, J.K. E.A. (1989), Recht en Economie
(Law and Economics), Amsterdam, Addison-Wesley, 294 p.
Theeuwes, Jules J.M. et al. (1992), Recht en Economie (Law and Economics), Amsterdam,
Addison-Wesley, 301 p.
Timmerman, L. (1990), Onderneming en Vennootschap (Enterprise and Firm), in X (ed.),
Piercing Van Schilfgaarde, Deventer, Kluwer, 3-11.
Timmerman, L. (1993), Enkele Opmerkingen over Vennootschapsrecht in EG-Perspectief (Some
Remarks on Company Law in an EC-Perspective), 6094 Weekblad voor Privaatrecht,
Notarisambt en Registratie, 436-438.
Timmerman, L. (1996), Doorbraak van Aansprakelijkheid, de Kern van Enige Recente
Ontwikkelingen (Lifting the Veil: the Core of Some Recent Developments), 39 TVVS
Maandblad voor Ondernemingsrecht en Rechtspersonen, 134-137.
Tinbergen, J. (1982), Kan de Economische Wetenschap Bijdragen tot de Ontwikkeling van het
Recht? (Can the Economic Science Contribute to Legal Development?), in X (ed.), In Orde:
Liber Amicorum Pieter Verloren van Themaat, Deventer, Kluwer, 295-300.
0355 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 303
Van den Bergh, Roger (1993), Economische Analyse van het Mededingingsrecht: een
Terreinverkenning (Economic Analysis of Competition Law: an Exploration),
Rechtseconomische Verkenningen, Arnhem, Gouda Quint, 120 p.
Van den Bergh, Roger (1994), Subsidiariteit Rechtseconomisch Bekeken: Adieu Bruxelles?
(Subsidiarity from an Economic Perspective: Adieu Bruxelles), Rechtseconomische
Verkenningen, Arnhem, Gouda Quint, 105 p.
Van den Bergh, Roger (1997a), Automatische Vergoeding van Schade Geleden door Zwakke
Verkeersdeelnemers: een Rechtseconomische Kritiek (Automatic Compensation of Damages
Suffered by Weak Parties in Traffic Accidents), Paper gepresenteerd op de studiedag
Verkeersaansprakelijkheid in Belgi en Nederland.
Van den Bergh, Roger (1997b), Van Nederlands Kartelparadijs naar Europees Kartelparadijs: een
Kritische Rechtseconomische Kijk op het Wetsvoorstel voor een Nieuwe Mededingingswet
(From a Dutch Cartel Paradise to an European Cartel Paradise), 72(4) Nederlands Juristen
Blad, 149-153.
Van den Bergh, Roger (1997c), Economische Analyse van het Mededingingsrecht: een
Terreinverkenning (Economic Analysis of Competition Law: an Exploration),
Rechtseconomische Verkenningen, Arnhem, Gouda Quint, 164 p.
Van den Bergh, Roger (1998), Automatische vergoeding van schade geleden door zwakke
verkeersdeelnemers: een rechtseconomische kritiek (Automatical Compensation to Weak
Parties in Traffic Accidents: An Economic Critique, in Faure, Michael and Hartlief, T. (eds),
Verkeersaansprakelijkheid in Belgi en Nederland, Antwerp, Intersentia, 27-74.
Van den Broek, Jan H.G. (1991), Nieuwe Instrumenten voor Energiebesparing (New Instruments
for Energy Savings), in Coljee, P.D., Franken, H., Heertje, A. and Kanning, W. (eds), Law and
Welfare Economics, Amsterdam, VU Amsterdam, 59-76.
Van den Hof, Danille (1994), Instrumenten van Milieubeheer. Een onderzoek vanuit
Rechtseconomisch Perspectief (Instruments of Environmental Policy. A Law and Economics
Perspective), thesis.
Van der Grinten, W.C.J. (1994), De Structuurvennootschap in Discussie (The Supervised
Company under Discussion), 69(3) Nederlands Juristen Blad, 85-89.
Van der Ploeg, Frederick (1994), Regulering: Zegen of Vloek? Van Deelbelang naar Algemeen
Belang (Regulation: Blessing or Curse? From Private to General Interest), in Bos, D.I. (ed.),
Deregulering in Nederland: Economische Uitdagingen voor de Nieuwe Regering,
Rotterdam, Erasmus University, 9-38.
Van der Ploeg, Frederick (1996), Vijf Kanttekeningen bij de Nieuwe Mededingingswet (Five
Comments on the New Competition Act), 81 Economisch-Statistische Berichten, 652-653.
Van der Weijden, Carel J. (1987), Over toetreding, uittreding en effectieve mededinging (Entry,
Exit and Effective Competition), in Van alle markten thuis, Rotterdam, Universitaire Pers, 97-
106.
Van der Weijden, Carel J. (1995), Te Laag Geprijsd (At What Price), Rotterdam, Erasmus
University, 22 p.
Van der Woude, M.H. (1995), Nederlands en Europees Kartelrecht (Dutch and European
Anti-trust Law), 5 Rechtsgeleerd Magazijn Themis, 198-204.
Van der Woude, M.H. (1996), Decentralisatie en Mededinging (Decentralization and
Competition), 2 Nederlands Tijdschrift voor Europees Recht, 255-259.
0355 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 305
Van Tulder, Frank (1990), Rechtshulp in Economisch Perspectief (Legal Aid from an Economic
Perspective), 39(10) Ars Aequi, 692-705.
Van Tulder, Frank (1991), Over Fietsen en Recht (On Bicycles and Law), 66 Nederlands
Juristenblad, 444-445.
Van Tulder, Frank (1994), Van Misdaad tot Straf (From Crime to Penalty), Serie Sociale en
Culturele Studies, s-Gravenhage, Vuga, 319 p.
Van Tulder, Frank and Janssen, S. (1988b), De Prijselasticiteit van het Recht (The Price Elasticity
of Law), 73 Economisch-Statistische Berichten, 19-22.
Van Tulder, Frank and Janssen, S. (1988a), De Prijs van de Weg naar het Recht (The Price of the
Road to the Law), Sociaal Cultureel Planbureau Stukwerk, No. 45.
Van Tulder, Frank P. and Spapens, A.C. (1990), Doelmatig Rechtspreken (Efficient
Administration of Justice), s-Gravenhage, Vuga, 74 p.
Van Veen, P. (1995), Naar een Nieuwe Mededingingswet (Towards a New Competition Act),
Rotterdam, Erasmus University, 31 p.
Van Velthoven, Ben C.J. (1994), De Economie van Misdaad en Straf: een Overzicht van de
Literatuur (The Economics of Crime and Punishment: a Literature Review), Research
Memorandum 94-08, Faculty of Law, Department of Economics.
Van Velthoven, Ben C.J. and Van Wijck, Peter W. (1996), De Economie van Civiele Geschillen:
Rechtsbijstand Versus No Cure No Pay (The Economics of Civil Suits: Legal Aid versus No
Cure No Pay), Research Memorandum 96-02, Faculty of Law, Department of Economics.
Van Velthoven, Ben C.J. and Van Wijck, Peter W. (1997), De Economie van Civiele Geschillen
(The Economics of Civil Suits), 18 Recht der Werkelijkheid, 18-52.
Van Velthoven, Ben C.J., Van Wijck, Peter W. et al. (1997), Recht en Efficintie (Law and
Efficiency), Deventer, Kluwer, 337 p.
Van Waarden, F. and Unger, B. (1992), Marktfalen, Kartellering en Economische Efficintie
(Market Failure, Cartelization and Economic Efficiency), 77 Economisch-Statistische
Berichten, 916-920.
Van Welderen Rengers, W.J. (1861), Beschouwingen over het Verband tusschen het Burgerlijk
Recht en de Staatshuishoudkunde (Reflections on the Relationship Between Civil Law and
Economics), Utrecht, P.W. v.d. Weijer, 120 p.
Van Wijck, Peter W. and Van Velthoven, Ben C.J. (1996), Een Economische Analyse van het
Amerikaanse en het Continentale Systeem van Proceskostentoerekening (An Economic
Analysis of American and Continental Systems of Cost Allocation Rules), Research
Memorandum, Faculty of Law, Department of Economics, 96-04.
Van Winden, Frans A.A.M. (1990), De Economische Theorie van de Politieke Besluitvorming
(The Economic Theory of Political Decisionmaking), in Van der Geest, L. (ed.), Economische
Theorie: de Stand van Zaken, Schoonhoven, Academic Service, 125-148.
Van Winden, Frans A.A.M. (1997), On The Economic Theory of Interest Groups, Discussion
paper, 97-117/1.
Verhaegen, P.H.A.M. and Volkers, A.B. (1996), Kosten en Baten van Regelgeving (Costs and
Benefits of Rulemaking), in Gestel, R.A.J. van et al. (eds), Markt en Wet, Deventer, W.E.J.
Tjeenk Willink, 45-57.
Verhoef, B.M., Verster, A.C.P. and Klaassen, L.H. (1989), Naar een Economische Benadering
van Criminaliteit en Veiligheidszorg (Towards an Economic Approach of Delinquency and
0355 Law and Economics in the Netherlands 307
Abstract
1. Research
309
310 Law and Economics in Norway 0360
2. Education
Allingham, M. and A. Sandmo (1972), Income Tax Evasion: A Theoretical Analysis, 1 Journal of
Public Economics, 323-338.
Andvig, Jens C. (1989), Korrupsjon i Utviklingsland (Corruption in Developing Countries), 23
Nordisk Tidsskrift for Politisk Ekonomi, 51-70.
Andvig, Jens C. (1995), Corruption in the North Sea Oil Industry: Issues and Assessment, 23 Crime,
Law and Social Change, 289-313.
Andvig, Jens C. and Karl Ove Moene (1990), How Corruption may Corrupt, 13 Journal of Economic
Behavior and Organization, 63-76.
0360 Law and Economics in Norway 311
Ryssdal, Stray A.C. (1993), Antitrust Enforcement - An Inquiry into Policy Analysis of Competition
Law, Working Paper, 89 Centre for Research in Economics & Business Administration, Bergen.
Ryssdal, Anders C. Stray (1995a), Legal Realism and Economics as Behaviour: A Scandinavian
Look at Economic Analysis of Law, Oslo, Juridisk Forlag.
Ryssdal, Anders C. Stray (1995b), An Economic Analysis of Civil Suits and Appeals, Oslo, Juridisk
Forlag.
Ryssdal, Stray A.C. (1996), Towards a Nordic Competition Law?, 109 Tidsskrift for Rettsvitenskap,
332-357.
Sandmo, Agnar (1981), Income Tax Evasion. Labour Supply, and the Equity-efficiency Tradeoff,
16 Journal of Public Economics.
Stavang, Endre (1992), Verdiskapningshensyn og juridisk argumentasjon: Srlig om kompensasjon
for lokale miljskader (The Relation between Efficiency Analysis and Legal Reasoning, with
Special Reference to Local Pollution Damage), Stensilserie Nr. 139, Institutt for privatrett,
Universitetet i Oslo.
Stavang, Endre (1996), Legal Economics: How Cautious Should Lawyers Be?, Working Paper, 3
Law and Economics, Institutt for privatrett, Universitetet i Oslo.
Stavang, Endre (1997), Tolerance Limits and Temporal Priority in Environmental Civil Liability,
Working Paper, 4 Law and Economics, Institutt for privatrett, Universitetet i Oslo.
Van den Bergh, Roger and Erling, Eide (1994), Law and Economics of the Environment, Oslo,
Juridisk Forlag.
Wilhelmsen, Trine-Lise (1989), Egenrisiko i Skadeforsikring (Retained Risk in Casualty Insurance),
Sjrettsfondet, Grafisk Hus, Bergen.
Wilhelmsen, Trine-Lise (1995), Avtalelovens 36 og konomisk effektivitet (Section 36 of the Nordic
Contract Acts and Economic Efficieny), 108 Tidsskrift for Rettsvitenskap, 1-246.
0365
LAW AND ECONOMICS IN PORTUGAL
Miguel Moura e Silva
Assistente, Faculdade de Direito da Universidade de Lisboa
Copyright 1999 Miguel Moura e Silva
Abstract
This short chapter presents an overview of the current state of law and
economics in Portugal. Whereas no specific courses are taught on this subject,
researchers in the field have been relatively active. An account is given of some
of the research done so far in Portugal.
JEL classification: K00
Keywords: Portugal, Law and Economics, Teaching, Research
1. Introduction
At present, law and economics seems to remain the province of a few scholars,
mainly teaching at the University of Coimbra and University of Lisbon Law
Schools and the Economics departments of the University of Coimbra,
Universidade Nova and Universidade Catlica, as well as the ISEG -
Economics and Business School. With a few exceptions, such as a special issue
by a law review, Sub Iudice, dedicated to Law and Economics, published in
1992, there seems to be a lack of institutionalized communication channels
between scholars, particularly between lawyers and economists.
313
314 Law and Economics in Portugal 0365
3. Research
Professor Sousa Franco, of the University of Lisbon Law School and the
Portuguese Catholic University Law School, emphasizes the role of economic
analysis of law in overcoming legal positivism by providing a framework for
the analysis of the content and purpose of legal rules (Sousa Franco, 1992).
Nevertheless, he cautions against an excessive enthusiasm for economic
analysis of law due to what he terms its materialistic and individualistic bias.
The preservation of the particular values established by the legal system is
necessary to prevent an instrumentalization of law and the replacement of
non-economic or supra-economic values. Despite these methodological issues,
the author argues cogently for the role of economic analysis in overcoming a
certain narrow-mindedness of legal studies and in bringing together law and
its practice.
3.3 Antitrust
Moura e Silva (1993) attempts to show the tension and the interplay between
intellectual property law with its concern for the protection of incentives to
innovate and antitrust with its goal of maintaining competitive markets. The
1991 EC software directive incorporated this concern in the form of a
decompilation exception which allows access to the elements of a computer
program which are necessary to achieve interoperability. However, this delicate
balance may be upset by the use of EC competition law in order to prevent the
exercise of such intellectual property rights as a mean to foreclose competitors,
as evidenced by the Magill case. Using the tools of economic analysis of
intellectual property, he argues for moderation in the use of antitrust when
316 Law and Economics in Portugal 0365
4. Conclusion
Abstract
Although law and economics has had a definitive impact on legal studies in the
United States and English-speaking Canada, and continues to make inroads
in Europe, the Province of Quebec remains insulated. Not only is institutional
recognition of the discipline absent, its practitioners are also few and isolated.
In this short chapter, I try to offer an up-to-date picture of the field within
Quebecs law schools as well as some hypotheses that could explain the current
state of affairs.
JEL classification: K00
Keywords: Canada, Quebec, Research, Education, Teaching, French
1. Introduction
In the introduction to the second edition of their Law and Economics, Cooter
and Ulen (1996, p. 2) list ten criteria by which one can measure the impact of
318
0370 Law and Economics in Quebec 319
economics on law. None of the six Quebec law schools (Laval, McGill,
Montreal, Sherbrooke, UQAM, to which I add the civil law section of the
University of Ottawa) pass all these tests. There are no Economics PhD
programmes in the faculty of any law school. There is no joint degree program
(PhD econ./LL.B.). There are evidently no journals devoted to the field and
Quebec law journals only exceptionally publish law and economics articles. The
few articles that were published, are cited only rarely by other Quebec legal
scholars, despite their quality. Not only is the field often ignored, but only four
law schools out of six have an Economic Analysis of Law course on their
curriculum (McGill and UQAM being the exceptions), and only two of them
(Montreal and Laval) have been offering the course on a yearly basis since it
was added to the curriculum. Finally, there is no professional organization in
Quebec equivalent to the Canadian Law and Economics Association (CLEA),
in spite of the fact that in most fields there are French-speaking organizations
in Quebec duplicating the corresponding Canadian organizations.
Contrary to lawyers, Quebec economists fully consider themselves to be part
of an international profession. Economics has developed into a truly
international field, with a common language and a shared hierarchy of schools
and departments. Quebec economists are not, contrary to civil lawyers,
insulated from foreign influences: they study abroad, candidates for teaching
positions come from all over the world and faculty members engage actively in
economic research whose quality they expect to be measured by world
standards. Hence, economics departments should provide more opportunities
for studies in law and economics. However, the fact remains that, as is the case
with legal scholars, most economists do not seem to have expressed any special
interest in studying Quebec law, except perhaps with regard to some special
legislation such as the introduction of the provincial no-fault automobile
insurance bill.
Two notable exceptions must be mentioned here. Reuven Brenner, who
holds the Repap Chair at McGills Faculty of Management, and Jean-Luc
Migu of the Ecole Nationale dAdministration Publique (ENAP) are two
scholars of international stature whose involvement in law and economics must
be pointed out. Although not strictly associated with the law and economics
movement, Prof. Brenner has made a distinctive use of law and economics tools
throughout his oeuvre to explain why people innovate or gamble on new ideas.
Prof. Migus involvement with law and economics has been more explicit and
more accessible, as he has written in both French and English. His most
important contribution must be his studies on the economics of language and
the economics of federalism.
Reasons as to why so few scholars have made distinctive contributions to the
field are not readily forthcoming. As is the case with Prof. Brenner, it might be
that the economic papers discussing legal issues are not written in French but
in English, and that they could be found in the appropriate section of the
320 Law and Economics in Quebec 0370
encyclopedia. Even with that caveat in mind, one would be hard pressed to find
more than twenty articles published by Quebec scholars in economics reviews.
So there is a real puzzle with regard to the lack of involvement in law and
economics by Quebec scholars, be they legal scholars or economists.
Common prejudiced views advanced as explanations for this puzzle simply
do not resist a comparative perspective. For example, the language differential
or the presence of a civil code cannot be part of the explanation: most Quebec
economists publish in English, and the language barrier has not prevented
German and Dutch jurists from applying the economic model to their own civil
code.
A more plausible hypothesis would focus on the lack of competition between
Quebec universities. Not only is the system completely public with no private
university in operation, but studies are heavily subsidized, with the lowest
tuition fees in all of North America, and teachers fully unionized. Because civil
law schools are so few in number, and because full employment security is
provided after a five year probation period, there is very little movement
between the faculties and hence an utter lack of competition. Professors
appointment fees are exclusively based on experience rather than on
performance and there is consequently a relative uniformity of treatment among
faculty members. Chairs are exceedingly rare. Incentives to innovate by
researching new fields of study are mostly indirect.
As in any other field, publications remain paramount for prestige and
promotions. However, in law schools, the criteria of international publications
is not retained, perhaps because of the civil character of the profession. The
pressure to perform at the international level remains low. As long as this will
be the case, incentives to innovate and excel will be likely to be lower in
Quebec than elsewhere. Because competition leads to a discovery process, its
absence often explains a lack of entrepreneurship. For the moment, the few
steps on the academic ladder can be easily climbed by producing commentaries
on case law or legislative notes affecting ones field; there is nothing to gain
from ventures in new studies far from the comforts of ones home turf.
3. Future Prospects
Nevertheless, there may be some hope. The expansion of law and economics
into public law and international law, and especially the economics of
federalism, is bound to influence Quebec jurists working in those fields.
Contrary to private law, and despite the language barrier, public law in Quebec
is traversed by Canadian and American influences. Moreover, funding cuts,
declining admission prospects and a relatively high unemployment rate have
forced law schools to require a doctoral degree as a condition of employment.
Aspiring professors are now more likely to have received training in the US and
0370 Law and Economics in Quebec 321
hence to have been exposed to law and economics. Finally, since there will be
growing uncertainty regarding employment security, it is likely that those new
and highly mobile professors will have to distinguish themselves in order to
keep a high profile; the law and economics field continues to offer enormous
possibilities in this regard.
Much as law and economics might catch on and attract new practitioners
in Quebec, this is still a far cry from becoming a standard part of the
curriculum in law schools. One essential step in that direction is the first
general introduction to law and economics in French (in addition to the brief
survey of core private law subjects by Bertrand Lemennicier in his conomie
du Droit, Paris, Cujas, 1991), currently being written by Prof. Ejan Mackaay
and the undersigned. Prof. Mackaay, who teaches at the Facult de Droit de
lUniversit de Montral, must be considered as one of the pioneers of the field
and the leading figure of law and economics in Quebec. His writings in
French, English and Dutch can all be praised for their clarity and soundness.
The book is aimed at the civilian legal community, both in Quebec and
elsewhere in the French-speaking world. The publication of this book should
help to establish law and economics as an integral part of the legal curriculum
in those countries. Beyond this upcoming introductory work, however, the
prospects for the development of French language literature on the subject are
dim. Economists already publish in English, and new professors at law schools
are more likely than their seniors to write in English, not only because they
have often been trained in that language, but especially because they want to
keep their job options open beyond provincial and national boundaries.
This does not mean that there is no hope for the study of Quebec private law
institutions. The recent growth of a distinct comparative law and economics
field could spur interest in the unique civil law system of Quebec, and with
good reason. First of all, there is an official English version of all legislative
texts, as well as of some court decisions and textbooks. Moreover, and contrary
to the French system, Quebecs private law has borrowed its civil procedure
styles of judicial reasoning from British common law and has developed a large
body of case law. Finally, Quebec having been more influenced by the
European model of the welfare state than by the American one, it provides a
stark contrast to the latter, a useful beginning for any comparative study.
4. Conclusion
All is not gloomy about the state of the field in Quebec. As the following
bibliography will show, there are scholars of great quality in Quebec, and the
new generation of professors will be better trained and more outward looking
than their predecessors. The development of a body of convincing comparative
322 Law and Economics in Quebec 0370
and constitutional law and economics studies may be just what is needed to
help Quebec jurists overcome their initial reservations about the field. We may
yet be heading for a new quiet revolution.
Brenner, Reuven and Brenner, Gabrielle A. (1988), Entrepreneurship - Le Nouveau Nom dun Vieux
Phnomne (Entrepreneurship - A New Name for an Old Phenomenon), Revue Internationale de
Gestion.
Breton, Albert (1978), Le Bilinguisme: une Approche conomique (Bilingualism: An Economic
Approach), Montral, Institut de recherche C.D. Howe.
Charette, Frdrick (1992a), Lillusion du Droit Moral, telle que Rvle par le Droit de
lInformatique (The Illusion of a Moral Right, as Revealed by a Study of Computer Law), 4
Cahiers de Proprit Intellectuelle, 161-185.
Charette, Frdrick (1992b), Libraliser la Publicit des Avocats: Fondements et Consquences
(Liberalizing Lawyers Advertising: Foundations and Consequences), 71 Canadian Bar Review,
508-551.
Courchene, Thomas J. (1986), La Gestion conomique et le Partage des Pouvoirs (Management and
the Separation of Powers), Ottawa, Commission royale sur lunion conomique et les perspectives
de dveloppement du Canada.
Courchene, Thomas J. (1987), Les Offrandes des Rois Mages : Etat-providence ou Etat Providentiel?
(The Magis Offerings: Welfare State or Providential State?), Toronto, C.D. Howe Institute.
Courchene, Thomas J. (1991), Eloge du Fdralisme Renouvel (Praise for a Renewed Federalism),
Toronto, C.D. Howe Institute.
Cousineau, Jean-Michel (1991), LEffet du Salaire Minimum sur le Chmage des Jeunes et des
Femmes au Qubec: une Restimation et un Rexamen de la Question (The Impact of a Minimum
Wage on Unemployment of Young People and Women in Quebec: A New Look at the Question),
67 Actualite Economique, 144-165.
Dion, Michel (1992a), Le Raisonnement thique en Affaires (Ethics Reasoning in Business), in Dion,
Michel (ed.), Lthique ou le Profit, Montral, Fides, 13-98.
Dion, Michel (ed.) (1992b), LEthique ou le Profit (Ethics or Profit), Montral, Fides.
Fluet, Claude (1990), LAnalyse Economique du Droit (Economic Analysis of Law), 43(3) Economie
Applique, 53-66.
Fortin, Bernard, Garneau, Gatan, Lacroix, Guy, Lemieux, Thomas and Montmarquette, Claude
(1996), Lconomie Souterraine au Qubec - Mythes et Ralits (The Underground Economy
in Quebec - Myths and Realities), Sainte-Foy, Presses de lUniversit Laval.
Fortin, Pierre (1980), Les Conditions Minimales de Travail: Leurs Consquences conomiques (The
Fixation of Minimum Working Conditions: Their Economic Consequences), 35e congrs des
relations industrielles, La dtermination des conditions minimales de travail par lEtat: une loi: son
conomie et sa porte.
Gaudry, Marc (1977), Quelques Problmes de Tarification du Transport des Voyageurs Montral
(Some Tarification Problems Regarding Public Transit in Montreal),III Canadian Public Policy,
307-314.
Gaudry, Marc (1986), Un Abrg de DRAG, un Modle de la Demande Routire, des Accidents et
de leur Gravit, appliqu au Qubec de 1956 1982 (A Summary of DRAG, a model of Road
Demand and of Accidents and their Seriousness, Applied to Quebec from 1956 to 1982), Montral,
Centre de recherche sur les transports.
Gaudry, Marc (1995), Sur une Application la Rgion Mtropolitaine de Montral des
Recommandations de la Commission Royale sur le Transport des Voyageurs au Canada (Of
an Application to the Montreal Metropolitan Area of the Recommendations of the Royal
Commission on Public Transit in Canada), Montral, Centre de recherche sur les transports.
324 Law and Economics in Quebec 0370
Gaudry, Marc, Fournier, Franois and Simard, Robert (1995), DRAG-2, un Modle conomtrique
Appliqu au Kilomtrage, aux Accidents et leur Gravit au Qubec - Synthse des rsultats
(DRAG-2, An Econometric Model Applied to Mileage and to Accidents and their Seriousness in
Quebec - Summary of Results), Qubec, Socit de lassurance automobile du Qubec.
Hbert, Grard (1986), Les Normes du Travail Caractre conomique au Canada et au Qubec
(Labor Rules of an Economic Nature in Canada and Quebec), 17 Revue Gnrale de Droit,
45-84.
Krauss, Michael I. (1986), Laffaire Lapierre: vers une Thorie conomique de lObligation
Quasi-contractuelle (The Lapierre Case: Toward an Economic Theory of the Quasi-Contractual
Obligation), 31 McGill Law Journal, 683-721.
Krauss, Michael I. (ed.) (1989), Action Positive - Thorie et Consquences (Affirmative Action -
Theory and Consequences), Cowansville (QC), Yvon Blais.
Krauss, Michael I. (1994), La Rglementation contre le March dans le Dveloppement de Normes
(Regulation against the Market in Norms Formation), 5 Journal des conomistes et des tudes
Humaines, 573-599.
Landry, Raymond A. (1991), La Priorit Fiscale sur les Meubles et le Projet de Code Civil du Qubec
(Fiscal Priority on Movables and the Quebec Civil Code Bill), 22 Revue gnrale de droit,
649-658.
Lemieux, Pierre (1983), Du Libralisme lAnarcho-capitalisme (From Liberalism to
Anarcho-Capitalism), Paris, Presses Universitaires de France (PUF).
Lemieux, Pierre (1987), La Souverainet de lIndividu (The Sovereignty of the Individual), Paris,
Presses Universitaires de France (PUF).
Lemieux, Pierre (1988), LAnarcho-capitalisme (What is Anarcho-Capitalism?), Paris, Presses
Universitaires de France (PUF).
Lemieux, Pierre (1991), Apologie des Sorcires Modernes (An Apology of Modern Witches), Paris,
Belles Lettres.
Lemieux, Pierre (1993), Le Droit de Porter des Armes (The Right to Bear Arms), Paris, Belles Lettres.
Lemieux, Vincent (1991), Les Relations de Pouvoir dans les Lois - Comparaison entre les
Gouvernements du Qubec de 1944 1985 (Power Relations in Laws - Comparison Between
Quebec Governments from 1944 to 1985), Sainte-Foy, Presses de lUniversit Laval.
Mackaay, Ejan (1979), Les Notions Floues ou lconomie de lmprcision (Fuzzy Concepts or the
Economics of Imprecision), 12 Langages, 33-50.
Mackaay, Ejan (1980), Le Droit Relatif aux Accidents - une Interprtation conomique (The Law of
Accidents - An Economic Approach), 15 Revue Juridique Themis, 383-415.
Mackaay, Ejan (1986a), Les Biens Informationnels ou le Droit de Suite dans les Ides (Information
Goods or the Sequel Right in Ideas), 12 Informatica e Diritto, 45-65.
Mackaay, Ejan (1986b), La Rgle Juridique Observe par le Prisme de lconomiste - une Histoire
Stylise du Mouvement dAnalyse conomique du Droit (The Legal Rule Viewed from the
Perspective of the Economist - A Stylized History of the Law and Economics Movement), 1 Revue
Internationale de Droit conomique, 43-88.
0370 Law and Economics in Quebec 325
Mackaay, Ejan (1987a), Tableau Synoptique de lAnalyse conomique du Droit (Synoptic Table of
the Economic Analysis of Law), 1987 Revue de la Recherche Juridique Droit Perspectif, 637
ff.
Mackaay, Ejan (1987b), Courants de Pense Juridique lOrigine de lAnalyse conomique du Droit
(tableaux) (Legal Currents at the Origin of the Economic Analysis of Law (Tables), 1987 Revue
de la Recherche Juridique Droit Perspectif, 635-636.
Mackaay, Ejan (1987c), Le Paradoxe des Droits Acquis. De lAncienne la Nouvelle conomie -
Essais lOccasion de la Dixime Universit dt de la Nouvelle conomie, Aix-en-Provence
1978-1987 (The Paradox of Vested Rights), Aix-en-Provence, Librairie de lUniversit.
Mackaay, Ejan (1987d), Le Juriste a-t-il le Droit dIgnorer lEconomiste? (May Lawyers Ignore
Economists?), Revue de la Recherche Juridique, 419-427.
Mackaay, Ejan (1988), Lordre Spontan comme Fondement du Droit - un Survol des Modles de
lmergence des Rgles dans une Socit Civile (Spontaneous Order as Foundation of Law - A
Survey of Models of the Emergence of Rules in Civil Society), 22 Revue Juridique Themis,
347-383.
Mackaay, Ejan (1989), Lordre Spontan comme Fondement du Droit - un Survol des Modles de
lmergence des Rgles dans la Socit Civile (Spontaneous Order as the Foundation of Law - A
Survey of Models of the Emergence of Rules in Civil Society), 3 Revue Internationale de Droit
Economique, 247-287.
Mackaay, Ejan (1990), Les Droits Intellectuels - entre Proprit et Monopole (Intellectual Property
Rights - Between Property and Monopoly), 1 Revue des conomistes et des tudes Humaines,
61-358.
Mackaay, Ejan (1991a), La Proprit Est-elle en Voie dExtinction? (Is Property about to Become
Extinct?), in Mackaay, Ejan (ed.), Nouvelles Technologies et Proprit, Montral, Ed. Thmis,
Paris, LITEC, 217-247.
Mackaay, Ejan (1991b), Le Droit Saisi par le Jeu (Game-Theory Applied to Law), Droit et Socit,
57-81.
Mackaay, Ejan (ed.) (1991c),Nouvelles Technologies et Proprits (New Technologies and Property),
Montral, Ed. Thmis, Paris, LITEC.
Mackaay, Ejan (1992a), Penser lInformatique Gntique en Droit Qubcois (Thinking about Genetic
Computing in Quebec Law), in Knoppers, Bartha Maria; Cadiet, Loc and Laberge, Claude M.
(eds), La Gntique Humaine: de lInformation lInformatisation (Human Genetics: From
Information to Computerization), Montral et Paris, Thmis et LITEC, 25-38.
Mackaay, Ejan (1992b), Le Droit Saisi par le Jeu (Game-Theory Applied to Law), in Ost, Franois
and Van De Kerkhove, Michel (eds), Le Jeu: un Paradigme pour le Droit, Paris, Librairie
Gnrale de Droit et de Jurisprudence, 81-110.
Mackaay, Ejan (1992c), Rgle et Dcision en Droit (Rule and Decision in Law), in Bourcier, Danile
and Mackay, Pierre (eds), Lire le Droit - Langue, Texte, Cognition, Paris, Librairie Gnrale de
Droit et de Jurisprudence, 41-69.
Mackaay, Ejan (1993), Assurances Sociales et Responsabilit (Social Welfare and Responsibility),
4 Journal des conomistes et des tudes Humaines, 135-157.
Mackaay, Ejan and Trudeau, Hlne (eds) (1995), Lenvironnement - Quel Prix? (Protecting the
Environment - At What Price?), Montral, Editions Thmis.
Migu, Jean-Luc (1956), Histoire des Finances Canadiennes, 1866-1939 (History of Canadian Public
Finances), Universit de Montral.
326 Law and Economics in Quebec 0370
Sosoe, Lukas (1992), Le Contractualisme et la Question des Nationalits (Contractualism and the
Question of Nationalities), 19 Philosophiques, 29-40.
Vaillancourt, Franois (ed.) (1985), Economie et Langue (Economy and Language), Qubec, Editeur
officiel du Quebec.
Vaillancourt, Franois (1988), Langue et Disparits de Statut conomique au Qubec, 1970 et 1980
(Language and Disparities of Economic Status in Quebec, 1970 and 1980), Montral, Office de
la langue franaise.
Vaillancourt, Franois (1991), Rponses aux Questions Poses par la Commission sur lAvenir
Politique et Constitutionnel du Qubec (Answers to the Questions Asked by the Commission on
the Political and Constitutional Future of Quebec), in Commission sur lavenir politique et
constitutionnel du Qubec (Commission Blanger-Campeau), Les avis des spcialistes invits
rpondre aux huit questions par la Commission (Commission Blanger-Campeau), Qubec,
Editeur officiel du Quebec, 1117-1133.
Vaillancourt, Franois and Carpentier, Jose (1989), Le Contrle de lconomie du Qubec: la Place
des Francophones en 1987 et son volution depuis 1961 (The Control of the Economy of
Quebec: The Status of Francophones in 1987 and its Evolution since 1961), Montral, Office de
la langue franaise.
Other References
Cooter, Robert and Ulen, Thomas S. (1996), Law and Economics, 2nd edition, Addison-Wesley.
0375
LAW AND ECONOMICS IN TAIWAN
Steven S. Kan
Professor at the Department of Economics
National Tsing Hua University, Hsin Chu, Taiwan
Copyright 1999 Steven S. Kan
Abstract
The purpose of this chapter is to show how law and economics has taken roots
in Taiwan, which authors have played primary roles in teaching and research,
and what have been the recent research topics. The chapter first presents a brief
description of Taiwans economic-social-political background. This is then
followed by an introduction to Taiwans education and research in law and
economics.
JEL classification: K00
Keywords: Economics, Law, Taiwan
1. Economic-Social-Political Background
2. Education
328
0375 Law and Economics in Taiwan 329
proportions from the US, Germany and Japan. In the past, economics students
were required to take an introductory law course, but law students were not
required to take any economics courses. Laws and regulations enacted since the
early 1980s have helped to bring about a change. They were promulgated to
meet new economic and social problems in employment, fair trade, finance,
environmental protection, and so on. Responding to the development, law
departments soon initiated specialized programs in financial and economic law.
To prepare students to deal with such legal matters, these programs require
first-year students to take four credit hours in economics principles, which are
taught by the economics faculty. For the same reason, more economics students
would like to start taking elective law courses to help their career development.
Both the economics and the law students know that there are substantial
differences not only between economics and law but also between the
English-American and Continental systems of law. However, not until recently
were they able to find a connection between economics and law, because few
scholars were familiar with Ronald H. Coases insights in the firm, the market,
and the law.
It was only ten years ago that the modern law and economics field became
known in Taiwan. Yu-Min Tang (1987) deserves special credit for translating
the first edition of Posners Economic Analysis of Law. The translated work
was well-received and reprinted after two years. Another special credit should
go to Steven Cheung (1987). His popular writings on private property rights
and contracts were published when privatization and economic liberalization
were hot issues in Taiwan. They soon became best-sellers and they helped
popularize the names of Coase, Alchian and Demsetz with Taiwans college
students.
Taiwans first undergraduate law and economics course was offered in
September 1987 to juniors by the economics department of National Tsing Hua
University. A graduate sequel, the economic analysis of law, debuted in 1990.
Coases winning of the Nobel Prize in 1991 further boosted students interests.
A course on economic organization along Oliver E. Williamsons line was
started up as a response to graduate students requests in 1992. However, the
demands of freshmen and sophomores could not be met because of a lack of
adequate teaching materials and teachers. Hwang and Kan (1994) published a
principles textbook emphasizing new institutional economics in the summer of
1994. With the arrival of a new faculty member, the department started to offer
courses on new economic history and new institutional economics. In addition
to fulfilling these teaching responsibilities, Liu (1994, 1995) translated
Douglass C. Norths two major books. Finally, with Chen and Li (1995)
translation of Coases book, there are now basic Chinese materials for students
of all departments that can open the door to law and economics.
In the meantime several scholars have also contributed to promoting the
central message of law and economics. Bing-Yuang Hsiung of National Taiwan
330 Law and Economics in Taiwan 0375
A few institutions and foundations have in recent years sponsored the visits of
distinguished foreign scholars to promote academic research in economics. For
example, the visitors included Gary Becker, James Buchanan, Issac Ehrlich,
Douglass North and Gordon Tullock. Their visits have helped stimulate
research in law and economics. A special day was marked on January 19, 1991
when Cyrus C. Chu successfully organized Taiwans first academic conference
on the economic analysis of law. The conference not only brought together
various researchers in law and economics but also opened up a dialogue
between legal scholars and economists. The effect of these activities is clear in
that legal scholars and professional lawyers are now invited to help with an
economics students thesis. Likewise, economists are invited to be members of
a law students thesis committee. As a result, there is more vigorous research
in law and economics and more research results are appearing in professional
journals.
The law and economics research community in Taiwan is small. There are
two types of research related to law and economics. The first type deals with
financial and economic laws and is mainly conducted by legal scholars. It is
related to law and economics because more of the substance is involved but less
of the methodology is used. The second type of research involves rigorous
economic analysis and belongs to the narrowly defined field of law and
economics. It is conducted by economists and several areas of law have been
taken up. To illustrate Taiwans recent interest in law and economics a select
bibliography is appended at the end of this overview. The bibliography shows
that recent research topics can be classified into four groups: financial and
economic law, criminal law, environmental law and others. While the volume
cannot warrant a full survey, I will try in the following to give a brief guide and
0375 Law and Economics in Taiwan 331
show that Taiwanese scholars can actively contribute to law and economics
research.
In the area of financial and economic law, research topics are concerned with
current economic conflicts. Li and Chen (1995), Hwang (1995, 1996) and Chen
(1997) focus on antitrust issues of intra-industry alliance in product designs,
intra-industry mutual holdings of stocks, vertical mergers, and collusive
pricing. The issues of foreign competition and financial disclosure have been
investigated by Juang (1997) and Tseng (1996). Fong (1997) and Tan (1991)
discuss issues related to intellectual property rights such as the corporate name,
the trademark, and counterfeits. Aoki and Hu (1997) have also investigated the
effect of a legal system on incentives to innovate. They are mostly written in
Chinese and some of their research results have wider implications that are not
limited to Taiwanese cases. However, no law and economics research related
to employment laws is being published, perhaps reflecting the fact that Taiwan
has been able to maintain full employment.
The most active law and economics research is on criminal law and purely
conducted by economists. The results of this line of research are especially
interesting and some of them have been published in international journals.
They are interesting because the researchers have utilized Chinese cases to shed
light on some less attended topics in Western literature. For examples, two
articles by Chu (1990a, 1990b) explicitly consider venal tax officials and plea
bargaining with respect to the problem of tax evasion. As law enforcement
efforts in Taiwan have been oscillatory, Chu (1991) makes a case that
oscillatory enforcement is optimal under some conditions. On the proposition
that fines are more efficient than imprisonment, Chu and Jiang (1993) present
an opposite case by considering wealth. Imprisonment serves the dual functions
of deterrence and incapacitation; yet little work has been done to address the
latter function. For criminal offenses involving bodily parts that cannot be
deterred, Kan (1996) finds that imprisonment is less efficient than corporal
punishment because it incapacitates other productive parts as well. As a life
sentence involves a permanent incapacitation of the whole body, he also finds
that its abolition would hinge on whether a society accepts temporary
incapacitation as a substitute punishment. Chu (1991), Chu et. al. (1997), Chen
et al. (1997), Koo (1991) and Shea and Wu (1994) have embarked on other
important topics such as criminal proceedings, litigation procedure, repeat
offenses, the allocation of legal costs and anti-monitoring activities. There are
also empirical studies written in Chinese. Adopting a Bayesian approach, Yang
and Chen (1996) find that a life sentence had no deterrence effect.
332 Law and Economics in Taiwan 0375
relates the common use and abuse of a condominiums top space to transaction
costs and property rights.
Finally, Taiwans ongoing democratization process has spurred Hwang and
Kans (1995) and Kan and Hwangs (1996, 1997) significant contributions to
constitutional law. They adopt a super-firm approach to focus on the
organization of a democratic government. As there are transaction costs
between representatives and officials and between them and the people, they
think that checks and balances are mechanisms to prevent the collusion of
officials and representatives. However, the costs associated with checks and
balances have been neglected. Applying Fama and Jensens distinction of
decision control and decision management powers in the firm, they elucidate
that different concerns over the two types of transaction costs can lead to
various forms of presidential, parliamentary and hybrid governments. A
testable implication of their transaction cost analysis is that the number of
check-and-balance mechanisms decreases with the development of competitive
mass media and the technological advances in transportation as well as
telecommunication. The research not only breaks away from current models in
political science, but also shows that transaction cost economics can shed
significant insights into the organization of a democratic government.
Acknowledgments
The author would like to thank Sheng C. Hu, Ruey-Hua Liu and Daigee Shaw
for their comments and suggestions.
Aoki, Reiko and Hu, Jin-Li (1997), Licensing vs. Litigation: Effect of the Legal System on Incentives
to Innovate, unpublished manuscript.
Chen, C.M. (1997), Basing-Point Pricing, Parallel Behavior, and Colluding Behavior: From American
Anti-Trust Law (in Chinese), 5(1) Fair Trade Quarterly, 65-96.
Chen, K.M. and Li, H.H. (1995), Chinese Translation of Ronald H. Coases The Firm, the Market, and
the Law, Taipei, Yuan-Liou Publishing Company, Ltd.
Chen, Kong-pin, Chien Hung-ken and Chu, Cyrus C.Y. (1997), Sequential versus Unitary Trials with
Asymmetric Information, 26(1) Journal of Legal Studies, 239-258.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1987), The Words of An Orange Seller (in Chinese) Taipei, Yuan-Liou
Publishing Company, Ltd.
Chien, Tze-shiou (1995), A Study on the Property Right of a Condominiums Top Space (in Chinese),
41(10) Military Law Journal, 8-15.
Chien, Tze-shiou (1997), Coases The Market, the Firm, and the Law: A Legal Perspective (in
Chinese), 26(2) National Taiwan University Law Journal, 229-246.
334 Law and Economics in Taiwan 0375
Chu, Cyrus C.Y. (1990a), A Model of Income Tax Evasion with Venal Tax Officials: The Case of
Taiwan, 45(3) Public Finance, 392-408.
Chu, Cyrus C.Y. (1990b), Plea Bargaining with the IRS, 41(3) Journal of Public Economics,
1319-1333.
Chu, Cyrus C.Y. (1991), An Economic Analysis of the Criminal Proceedings in Civil Law Countries,
11(1) International Review of Law and Economics, 111-116.
Chu, Cyrus C.Y. (1993), Oscillatory vs. Stationary Enforcement of Law, 13(3) International Review
of Law and Economics, 303-315.
Chu, Cyrus C.Y. and Jiang, Neville (1993), Are Fines More efficient Than Imprisonment?, 51
Journal of Public Economics, 391-413.
Chu, Cyrus C.Y. and Qian, Yingyi (1995), Vicarious Liability under a Negligence Rule, 15(3)
International Review of Law and Economics, 305-322.
Chu, Cyrus C.Y., Sheng-Cheng Hu and Ting-Yuan Huang (1997), Punishing Repeat Offenders More
Severely!, IEAS Working paper No. 9703, Academia Sinica.
Fong, Jerry G. (1997), Corporate Name, Trade Name, Trade Mark, and Domain Name (in Chinese),
5(2) Fair Trade Quarterly, 65-96.
Fu, Tsu-tan, Shaw, Daigee and Yu, B.T. (1993), A Property Rights and Contractual Approach to
Sustainable Development, Discussion Paper No. 9334, The Institute of Economics, Academia
Sinica.
Hsieh, Chee-Ruey (1991), Medical Liability, Dispute, and Litigation: Theory and Evidence of Taiwan
(in Chinese), 19(1) Taiwan Economic Review, 87-114.
Hsiung, Bing Yuang (1993), The Scale of the Market and the Scale of the Heart: Reconciling Coase
and Buchanan on the Coase Theorem (in Chinese), 21(2) Academia Economic Papers, 331-356.
Huang, Chung-Huang (1996a), Hierarchical Government, Environmental Regulations, Transfer
Payments, and Incomplete Enforcement, in Mendelsohn, Robert and Shaw, Daigee (eds), The
Economics of Pollution Control in the Asia Pacific, 253-272. Vermont, Edward Elgar Publishing
Company.
Huang, Chung-Huang (1996b), Effectiveness of Environmental Regulations under Incomplete
Enforcement and the Firms Avoidance Behavior, 8 Environmental and Resource Economics,
182-204.
Hwang, Chun-Sin and Kan, Steven S. (1994), Principles of Economics-Cooperating for Mutual
Prosperity and Progress, Vol. 1 (in Chinese), published by the authors and distributed by Shin
Lu Bookstore, Taipei.
Hwang, Chun-Sin and Kan, Steven S. (1995), Democracy and the Principle for the Division of Labor
in Government Organization (in Chinese), in Chien, Sechin Y.S. and Tai, Terence H. (eds),
Philosophy and Public Norms, Book Series 34, Sun Yat-sen Institute for Social Sciences and
Philosophy,163-200. Taipei, Academia Sinica.
Hwang, L.T. (1996), The Anti-Competitive Effect of Intra-Industry Mutual Holdings of Stocks: A
Discussion on Fair Trade Law (in Chinese), 4(2) Fair Trade Quarterly, 1-14.
Hwang, L.T. (1995), The Paradoxical Regulation of Fair Trade Law on Vertical Merger: An
Economic Analysis (in Chinese), 3(3) Fair Trade Quarterly, 19-31.
Juang, C.F. (1997), Foreign Competition and the Demarcation of Geographical Market (in Chinese),
5(1) Fair Trade Quarterly, 1-47.
Kan, Steven S. (1993), Entrepreneurship, Transaction Costs, and Subjectivist Economics, 1(2)
Journal of Enterprising Culture, 159-182
0375 Law and Economics in Taiwan 335
Kan, Steven S. (1996), Corporal Punishments and Optimal Incapacitation, 25(1) Journal of Legal
Studies, 121-130.
Kan, Steven S. and Hsiao, Ding-Way (1996), Contracts in Tsing Dynasty to Build Irrigation System
at Lan-Yang Plain: A Transaction Cost Analysis (in Chinese), 59 Journal of Agricultural
Economics, 111-157, National Chung Hsing University.
Kan, Steven S. and Hwang, Chun-Sin (1991a), Hsun-Tzus Theory of Justice (in Chinese), in Tai,
Hua T. and Cheng, Hsiao-Shih (eds), Justice and Related Concepts, Monograph Series 28, Sun
Yat-sen Institute for Social Sciences and Philosophy, 93-130. Taipei, Academia Sinica.
Kan, Steven S. and Hwang, Chun-Sin (1991b), Economic Thoughts of Law in Ancient China,
unpublished manuscript.
Kan, Steven S. and Hwang, Chun-Sin (1994), Principles of Economics-Cooperating for Mutual
Prosperity and Progress, Vol. 2 (in Chinese), published by the authors and distributed by Shin Lu
Bookstore, Taipei.
Kan, Steven S. and Hwang, Chun-Sin (1995), The Break and the Link between Cofucius and
Mo-Tzus Public Norms (in Chinese), in Chien, Sechin Y.S. and Tai, Terence H. (eds),
Philosophy and Public Norms, Monograph Series 34, Sun Yat-sen Institute for Social Sciences
and Philosophy, 135-162. Taipei, Academia Sinica.
Kan, Steven S. and Hwang, Chun-Sin (1996), A Form of Government from the Perspective of
Transaction Cost Economics, 7(3) Constitutional Political Economy, 197-220.
Kan, Steven S. and Hwang, Chun-Sin (1997), Check-and-Balance or the Separation of Decision
Control and Decision Management Powers (in Chinese), 25(3) Economic Essays, 375-406.
Taipei, Academia Sinica.
Koo, Hui-Wen (1991), Allocation of Legal Costs: American Rule vs. British Rule, 19(2) Taiwan
Economic Review, 197-218.
Koo, Hui-Wen and Png, I.P.L. (1994), Private Security: Deterrent or Diversion?, 14 International
Review of Law and Economics, 87-101.
Koo, Hui-Wen and Sung, Yusen D. (1993), The Public Financing of Private Election Expenditures:
An Economic Analysis of the Taiwanese Election and Recall Law (in Chinese), 21(1) Taiwan
Economic Review, 25-44.
Li, Y.M. and Chen, H.M. (1995), An Economic Analysis of Intra-Industry Alliance in Product
Designs (in Chinese), 3(4) Fair Trade Quarterly, 109-125.
Liu, Ruey-Hua (1994), Translation of Douglass C. Norths Institution, Institutional Change, and
Economic Performance, Taipei, China Times Publishing Company.
Liu, Ruey-Hua (1995), Translation of Douglass C. Norths Structure and Change in Economic
History, Taipei, China Times Publishing Company.
Shaw, Daigee (1992), Controlling Environmental Externalities: Pigouvian Tax vs. Strict Liability (in
Chinese), 2(1) Humanities and Social Sciences, 35-44.
Shaw, Daigee (1995), Translation of T.L. Anderson and R. Leals Free Market Environmentalism,
Taipei, Chu Liu Book Company.
Shea, Jia-Dong and Wu, Jy-Wen (1994), Tax Evasion, Anti-Monitoring Activities, and the Imapcts
of Government Policies (in Chinese), 22(1) Academia Economic Papers, 81-100.
Su, Yeong-Chin (1991), Rethinking of the Principle of Numerus Clausus-in the light of Development
of Civil Law and Economic Theory of Property Right (in Chinese), 19(2) Taiwan Economic
Review, 219-257.
336 Law and Economics in Taiwan 0375
Tan, Leslie L.T. (1991), Informative Advertising with Counterfeits (in Chinese), 19(2) Academia
Economic Papers, 217-231.
Tang, Yu-Min (1987), Translation of Richard A. Posners Economic Analysis of Law, Taipei,
Commercial Press.
Tseng, Wang-Run (1996), Capital Structure and the Regulation of Disclosure, 25(4) National
Taiwan University Law Journal, 279-317.
Yang, Hao-Yen and Chen, Jong-Rong (1996), A Bayesian Approach of the Deterrent Effect of Life
Sentence (in Chinese), 24(1) Academia Economic Papers, 115-133.
Yeh Jiunn-rong (1992), Selling Environmental Rights: From the Fifth Cracking Project to the
Compensation Fund (in Chinese), 2(1) Humanities and Social Sciences, 17-34.
Wu, Ho-Mou and Huang, Peter (1994), More Order without More Law: A Theory of Social Norms
and Organizational Cultures, 10 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 390-406.
0380
LAW AND ECONOMICS IN SERBIA
Zeljko Sevic
Senior Lecturer
Business School - University of Greenwich
Copyright 1999 Zeljko Sevic
Abstract
1. Introduction
From the early 1990s onwards Yugoslav scholars have increasingly begun to
recognise the importance of the economic analysis of legal institutions and
practice.
In the former Republic of Yugoslavia, the development of legal and social
science disciplines was strictly influenced and monitored by political bodies,
but probably less so than in other socialist countries; hence the need to analyze
this legal and economic development within the political and cultural
frameworks of these countries. Given the traditional influence of universities
on social life in Serbia, the teaching of these disciplines will be analyzed as
well.
First, a brief chronicle of the developments in law and economics against
the background of the changes in social and political structures in Serbia will
be given. Second, the major works in law and economics in Serbia will be
presented, and finally a conclusion will be provided (Section 4).
337
338 Law and Economics in Serbia 0380
2. Historical Developments
Legal sciences have been taught in Serbia since the establishment of the Faculty
of Law in 1841 (more correctly it concerned the legal division of the Great
School). A number of economic subjects also were taught in courses from the
mid-1850s onwards, to provide students with the broad educational background
necessary for future employment, mainly in the civil service. With the
reorganisation of higher education and the establishment of the University of
Belgrade in 1905, a separate Department of National Economy and Finance
was established within the Faculty of Law. The Faculty of Law educated
aspiring lawyers, some of whom were specialising in economics and finance.
Until 1937, the Faculty of Law was the only institution offering training in
economics, but only as a supplementary subject. The main degree (which was)
granted to successful students was a classical LLB degree. A number of the best
performing students continued their studies abroad, at the faculties of
economics, and gained doctoral degrees in economics (political economy). In
1937, the Higher Economics and Commerce School (analogous to a
polytechnic) was established. Although after World War II this school became
the University of Belgrades Faculty of Economics, the Faculty of Law retained
its economics department.
After the socialist revolution during World War II, both institutions suffered
great changes in their educational programmes and lost a number of
unsuitable staff (that is, despite their academic merit, a number of academics
were arrested or expelled from the university). The syllabi were changed to be
in line with mainstream socialist doctrine. Immediately after World War II the
Soviet textbooks were simply translated and used for teaching. Even after the
break with the Soviet Union in 1948, a few authors were still largely influenced
by Stuchka-Pashukanis legal, and Kondratyevs economic doctrine.
With the introduction of market reforms in 1965, changes in the
universities educational programmes were introduced. Some Western theories
were slowly integrated into both legal and economic theory, and scholars
gradually reestablished links with research institutions in Western countries.
This resulted in a huge increase in the number of publications. Although these
reforms lasted a year or so, it did not improve the openness of the research
institutions. However, some academics, particularly lawyers, passed the
Rubicon of socially allowed political dissidence determined by the political
censors, with their strong criticism of a final draft of the Federal constitution
drawn up in 1973. Some of the scholars, for the first time, began to analyze the
welfare effects of proposed legal acts from the point of view of comparative
constitutional law, the legal system, social logic, social justice, and so on. But,
it turned out that Titos regime did not support academic freedom fully, and
some academics were either imprisoned or isolated from the academic
0380 Law and Economics in Serbia 339
community. Others simply fled the country. Fifteen years later the predictions
of these academics proved to be correct, when the constitutional crisis caused
the former Republic of Yugoslavia to disintegrate. The introduction of a
concept of self-management, in connection with the institutions of associated
labour and social ownership without owners (non-ownership concept of
social property) severely affected the universities educational programmes.
3. Current Situation
The fall of the communist regimes in Eastern Europe has shown that the
Yugoslav concept of socialism with a human face was not socially
sustainable either. The transition requires change, new proposals and social
solutions. This implies both the return to the positive pre-socialist traditions
and a critical adoption of advanced Western theory. In this respect, the 1990s
marked the birth of law and economics literature in Serbia. A number of
authors adopted a more or less economically-based approach to legal and
economic phenomena. Generally, these works were devoted to the problems of
property rights and their (social) efficiency. Some of the authors apply
simultaneously both law and economics and the public choice approaches
(Sevic).
Professor Vodinelic of Belgrade Universitys Faculty of Law first mentioned
law and economics in his textbook Civil Law - Introductory Themes, in 1991.
With simple and generalistic explanations of law and economics concepts, he
introduced them to the first-year law students. The second and more significant
move was made by Professor Labus, also from Belgrades Faculty of Law, in his
recent textbook: Foundation Economics: Contemporary Theory and
Application, published in 1995. This book was aimed at second-year law
students, and presented in an exhaustive fashion the Coase theorem and its
possible application in legal practice with reference to the Yugoslav legal order.
It also stressed, as had been done many times before, that the judge is more
constrained by law in a continental legal system than in the Anglo-Saxon
(Common Law) system. The author provided his students with many splendid
examples referring to Yugoslav positive law and practice, especially in the field
of torts. Until this work the economic aspects of damage had not been
considered from the point of view of the classic restitution rules. Currently, law
students are informed about the basics of the economic analysis of law (in
Professor Labus words: Legal School in Economics). In contrast, at the
Faculty of Economics there is no mention of law and economics. Even the
course in Contemporary Economic Thought does not consider this discipline,
and only one page is devoted to public choice. Economics students are taught
positive commercial (or international commercial) law but they do not have an
opportunity to learn about law and economics.
340 Law and Economics in Serbia 0380
fills a gap in Serbian/Yugoslav legal and economic literature. As the first book
of its kind, it really reaches its aims, and provides a basis to build upon. The
main objection beside its over-simplicity may be the lack of use of up-to-date
literature, and support of only some streams in modern law and economics,
equalising Law and Economics with New Institutional Economics, which the
author refers to as Economics of Property Rights.
The application of principles of law and economics is still not accepted in
court procedures, even though an improvement in the field may be expected.
At present a number of economists are sworn court experts (appointed by the
Minister of Justice). They are supposed to formulate opinions on different
economic, financial and accountancy issues, but in most cases they just estimate
the losses. The sworn experts opinion is not obligatory but (optional
demonstrative) as the final decision is always in the hands of the court council,
usually consisting of the presiding professional judge and two so-called jury
judges. Although experts only apply a classical utilitarian cost-benefit analysis,
the judges usually base their sentence on the experts opinion. Practice is not
a formal source of law in Serbia, but lower courts take into account previous
acknowledged decisions in order to avoid cancellation of the sentence in the
appeal procedure later on. Although it is widely believed that judges in
continental legal systems firmly stick to the legal norms stipulated in the law
(Statute, Act), practice has recently shown a wide variety in sentencing, at least
in Serbia.
What are the possible reasons for the present state of law and economics in
Serbia? Besides the previously noted influence of a dominant socialist model
in the past, a divergence of academic lawyers and economists can be observed.
Both professions seem to try to keep their respective disciplines clearly
separated from one another. For a while, there was open reluctance towards
authors who tried to connect the two disciplines in their research. Historically,
there has also been rivalry between the Faculty of Law and Faculty of
Economics. The Faculty of Law kept its own department of economics, which
is usually staffed very well. Even a well-known American property rights
economist, Professor Svetozar (Steve) Pejovich, graduated from Belgrades
Faculty of Law in 1955.
4. Conclusion
It seems that Serbian law and economics is on its way to developing its own
distinctive identity, rather than merely following the dominant American path.
It is more European, and as a result more conservative with respect to certain
typically Anglo-Saxon applications. The introduction of efficiency in the
analysis of law, which comprises all three analyses (predictive, explanatory
342 Law and Economics in Serbia 0380
and normative) can undoubtedly influence the further development not only of
legislative activities, but also of legal and economic thought as a whole in the
country. However, it is not clear whether legislators in Serbia understand that
law enforcement is not free and whether they know how to deal with the
existence of externalities. At present, it seems that the Serbian/Yugoslav
legislators strongly believe that the implementation of law and law enforcement
does not bring about any costs. This can, consequently, influence the path of
administrative and legal reforms. More particularly, the size of the state
apparatus may be more important for the legislator than its actual efficiency
level. However, some authors have recently pointed out this problem, and the
legislation policy stance will hopefully change in the future.
The mid-1990s appeared to be a turning point in the development of law
and economics in Serbia. Up to this moment the main subjects of interest in
terms of research have been property rights and privatisation, given that these
issues are crucial for the transition process. Papers dealing with the efficiency
of (commercial) law and its influence on the dynamics of economic change can
be found as well. Authors who started to show an interest in law and economics
at the beginning of the 1990s are currently very research-productive. They have
also obtained senior positions in academia, and it can be expected that law and
economics as an academic discipline will have a prominent future in Serbia in
the years to come.
Begovic, Boris (1996), Smece u Ekonomskoj Teoriji: Slucaj Prirodnog Monopola (Garbage in the
Economic Theory: The Case of Natural Monopoly), 29 Ekonomska Misao, 35-47.
Begovic, Boris and Mijatovic Bosko (1991), Predlog Reforme Sistema Koricenja Gradskog Zemljita
(A Proposal for a Reform of the Use of Urban Building Sites), 24(2) Ekonomska Misao, 175-186.
Begovic, Boris and Mijatovic Bosko (1991), Predlog Strategije Privatizacije Gradskog Zemljita (A
Proposal for the Privatisation Strategy of Urban Building Sites), 24(3) Ekonomska Misao,
289-300.
Bozovic Radoman (1988), Svojinski Odnosi i Ustavne Promene (Ownership Relations and the
Constitutional Changes), 21(2) Ekonomska Misao, 11-20.
Cok, Vida (1989), Svojina kao Pravo Coveka (Property as a Human Right), 35 Jugoslovenska Revija
za Medjunarodno Pravo, 38-49.
Djuricin, Dragan (1994), Privrede u Tranziciji: Privatizacija i Povezane Teme (Economies in
Transition: Privatization and Related Issues), Decije novine, Gornji Milanovac.
Gligorov, Vladimir (1990), Zavisnost i Reforme (Dependency and Reforms), in Vladimir Gligorov
and Jovan Teokarevic (eds), Napustanje Socijalizma, Belgrade, Institut za medjunarodni radnicki
pokret i Strucna knjiga, 257-274.
Gligorov, Vladimir (1990), Nejednakost i Efikasnost: Modernizacija sa Socioloskog i Ekonomskog
Stanovista (Inequality and Efficiency: Modernisation from Sociological and Economic
Perspectives), in Teokarevic Jovan (ed.), Modernizacija i drustveni razvoj, Belgrade, Institut za
medjunarodni radnicki pokret, 29-38.
Hiber, Dragor (1993), Privatizacija - moc Drzave i Vladavina Prava (Privatization - Power of the State
and Rule of Law), 35(1) Sociologija, 39-52.
Hiber, Dragor (1998), Svojina u Tranziciji (Property in Transition), Belgrade, Pravni fakultet.
Ilic Bogdan (1992), Primat Preduzetnistva ili Svojine u Savremenoj Trzisnoj Privredi (Superiority of
Entrepreneurship or Property in a Contemporary Market Economy), 45 Ekonomist, 47-58.
Ivic, Aleksandar and Maksimovic, Ivan (1984), Drustvena Svojina i Samoupravljanje I (Social
Property and Self-Management I), Belgrade, Pravni fakultet.
Jelic, Ranko (1995), Drustvena i Drzavna Svojina (Social and State Property), Belgrade, Nomos.
Jovanovic, Aleksandra (1993), Participativna Ekonomija: Uticaj Tipa Svojine na Ponasanje
(Efikasnost) Preduzeca (Participatory Economics: Influence of a Property Form on Behaviour
(Efficacy) of a Firm), Belgrade, Pravni fakultet.
Jovanovic, Aleksandra (1994), Transakcioni Troskovi Privatizacije (Transaction Costs of
Privatisation), 43 Pravni Zivot, 895-905.
Jovanovic, Aleksandra (1996), Ekonomski Efekti Nekih Ekonomskih Prava, in Svetislav, Taborosi
(ed.), Srbija u Tranziciji, Belgrade, Pravni fakultet, 113-125.
Jovanovic, Aleksandra (1998), Uvod u Ekonomsku Analizu Prava (Introduction to Economic Analysis
of Law), Belgrade, Pravni fakultet.
Jovanovic, Aleksandra and Hiber, Dragor (1996), Postupak Izvrsenja na Imovini Drustvenog Preduzec
a i Moralni Hazard (Execution Procedure on the Property of a Social Enterprise and Moral
Hazard), in Svojina i Slobode - Aspekti Tranzicije, Belgrade, Institut ekonomskih nauka,
202-208.
344 Law and Economics in Serbia 0380
Jovanovic, Aleksandra and Mijatovic, Bosko (1996), Preduzece i Moralni Hazard (Firm and Moral
Hazard), 45 Pravni Zivot, 404-415.
Labus, Miroljub (1988), Drustvena ili Grupna Svojina (Social or Group Property), Belgrade, Naucna
knjiga.
Labus, Miroljub (1990), Devalvacija i Administrativna Kontrola Cena (Devaluation and
Administrative Control of Prices), 23(1) Ekonomska Misao, 1-24.
Labus, Miroljub (1995), Osnovi Ekonomije: Savremene Teorije i Primena (Foundation Economics:
Contemporary Theories and Application), Jugoslovenska knjiga, Belgrade.
Madzar, Ljubomir (1972), Osnovi Teorije Proizvodnje (Basics of the Theory of Production), Belgrade,
Institut ekonomskih nauka.
Madzar, Ljubomir (1995), Svojina i Reforma (Property and Reform), Belgrade, Institut ekonomskih
nauka.
Maksimovic, Ivan (ed.) (1992), Transformacija Svojinskih Odnosa - Teorijski i Empirijski Aspekti
(Transformation of Property Rights - Theoretical and Empirical Issues), Belgrade, Srpska
akademija nauka i umetnosti (SANU).
Mihajlovic, Kosta (1991), Svojina i Efikasnost (Property and Efficiency), 39 Pravni Zivot, 561-575.
Mijatovic, Bosko (1993a), Mogucnosti Privatizacije (Possibilities for Privatization), 35(1)
Sociologija, 23-38.
Mijatovic, Bosko (1993b), Privatizacija (Privatization), Belgrade, Ekonomski institut.
Mijatovic, Bosko (1994), Privatizacija Gradskog Gradjevinskog Zemljista (Privatisation of Urban
Building Sites), 43(9-10) Pravni zivot, 875-893.
Milovanovic, Milic (1993), Teorijski Izvori i Metodi Privatizacije (Theoretical Sources and Methods
of Privatisation), 35(1) Sociologija, 5-22.
Milovanovic, Milic (1994), Privatizacija i Ekonomska Efikasnost (Privatization and Economic
Efficiency), 27(1-2) Ekonomska Misao, 1-20.
Orlic, V. Miodrag (1993), Zakljucivanje Ugovora (Conclusion of Contracts), Institut za uporedno
pravo, Beograd.
Orlic, V. Miodrag and Rajovic, Veroljub (1984), Drustvena Svojina i Samoupravljanje II (Social
Property and Self-Management II), Belgrade, Pravni fakultet.
Petrovic, Milenko (1995), Funkcije Drzave u Savremenoj Trzisnoj Privredi (State Functions in a
Contemporary Market Economy), 28(3-4) Ekonomska Misao, 207-224.
Popovic, Dejan (1997), Nauka o Porezima i Poresko Pravo (Tax Science and Tax Law), Savramena
administracija and Open Society Institute/COLPI, Belgrade and Budapest.
Sevic, Zeljko (1994a), Socijalisti i Svojina: Prilog Pravnoj i Ekonomskoj Teoriji (Prava) Svojine
(Socialists and Property: Contribution to the Legal and Economic Theory of Property Rights), in
Suvakovic, Uros (ed.), Evropska Levica Danas (European Left Today), Belgrade, SPS.
Sevic, Zeljko (1994b), Komisioni Posao u Bankarskom Pravu (Undisclosed Agency Operations
Commission Transactions in the Banking Law), Belgrade, CiP-stampa.
Sevic, Zeljko (1994c), Pravni Status Centralne Banke u Savremenoj Trzisnoj Privredi (Status of the
Central Bank in a Contemporary Market Economy), Belgrade, Faculty of Law, University of
Belgrade.
Sevic, Zeljko (1995), Svojinski Oblici i Efikasnost Funkcionisanja Bankarskog Sistema (Property
Forms and the Banking System Efficiency), 44(9) Pravni Zivot, 647-660.
Sevic, Zeljko (1996a), Ekonomska Analiza Prava Svojine u Tranziciji (Economic Analysis of the
Property Rights in Transition), 45(10) Pravni Zivot, 964-977.
0380 Law and Economics in Serbia 345
Sevic, Zeljko (1996b), Centralna Banka: Polozaj - Organizacija - Funkcije (Central Bank: Position
- Organization - Functions), Belgrade, Cigoja-stampa.
Sevic, Zeljko (1996c), Odnos Centralne Banke i Izvrsne Vlasti (Relationship between the Central
Bank and Executive Power), 26(1-2) Jugoslovensko Bankarstvo, 29-36.
Sevic, Zeljko (1996d), Bankarstvo i Bankarsko Pravo: Neka Otvorena Pitanja Samostalnosti
Bankarskog Prava (Banking and Banking Law: Some Open Questions on Banking Law
Independence), 51(11-12) Finansije, 964-977.
Sevic, Zeljko (1997), Svetska Trgovinska Organizacija: Pravni i Institucionalni Aspekti (World Trade
Organization: Legal and Institutional Aspects), 52 Finansije, 139-146.
Sevic, Zeljko and Sevic, Aleksandar (1997), Centralna Banka i Finansijska Trzista (Central Bank and
Financial Markets), 27 Jugoslovensko Bankarstvo, 28-34.
Sevic, Zeljko and Zorica, Vukasinovic (1997), Reforma Drzavne Uprave: Pravno-Ekonomska i
Finansijska Analiza (Civil Service Reform: Law and Economics and Financial Management
Analyses), 46(9) Pravni Zivot, 815-831.
Soskic, Dragutin (1983), Kriticki Osvrt na Sustinu Samoupravno Dogovorene cene Obrazovanja
(Critical Notices on the Core on Self-Management Agreed Price of Education), 31 Anali Pravnog
fakulteta u Beogradu, 756-771.
Stankovic, Vladeta (1985), Privredni Sistem (Economic System), Belgrade, Pravni fakultet.
Stankovic, Vladeta (1991), Pravo Privrednog Sistema (Law of the Economic System), 39 Anali
Pravnog Fakulteta u Beogradu, 277-288.
Stankovic, Vladeta (1995), Pravo Privrednog Sistema (Law of the Economic System), Belgrade,
Pravni fakultet.
Vasic, B. Vukasin (1986), Makroekonomska Politika kao Javno Dobro (Macroeconomic Policy as a
Public Good), 39(3) Ekonomist, 429-430.
Vodinelic, V. Vladimir (1991), Gradjansko Pravo - uvodne Teme (Civil Law - Introductory Themes),
Belgrade, Nomos.
Vracar, K. Stevan (1994), Preispitivanja Pravne Metodologije: Nagovestaji Drzavno-Pravnog
Integralizma (Reexamination of the Legal Methodology: Indications of State-Legal Integralism),
Naucna knjiga, Belgrade.
Vukadin, Emilija (1988), Instrument Kompenzacije u Jugoslovenskom Privrednom Sistemu: Karakter
Uslova i Mogucnost Primene (Compensation as an Instrument in Yugoslav Economic System:
Character of Conditions and its Feasibility), 36(4) Anali Pravnog Fakulteta u Beogradu,
386-398.
Vukotic, Veselin (1993a), Privatizacija i Razvoj Trzisne Privrede (Privatisation and Development of
a Market Economy), Belgrade, Institut ekonomskih nauka.
Vukotic, Veselin (1993b), Privatizacija, Pravicnost i Efikasnost (Privatization, Justice, and
Efficiency), 46(1-2) Ekonomist, 81-88.
Vukovic, S. (1996), Cemu privatizacija (Why Privatization), Belgrade, SDS-IKSI.
Zec, Miodrag, Mijatovic Bosko and Nebojsa Savic (eds) (1994), Privatizacija Nuznost ili Sloboda
Izbora (Privatization Necessity or Freedom of Choice), Belgrade, Ekonomski institut and
Jugoslovenska knjiga.
0385
LAW AND ECONOMICS IN SPAIN
Santos Pastor
Universidad Complutense de Madrid y Centro de Investigaciones en
Derecho, Economi y Administracin de Empresas
Jess Pintos
Instituto de la Rioja et Instituto de Derecho y Economi
Copyright 1999 Santos Pastor and Jess Pintos
Abstract
This chapter addresses the evolution and current situation of law and
economics in Spain along four major dimensions: teaching, academic research,
legal policy and judicial practice. A glance at trends and likely extensions is
also included. Furthermore, an accompanying Spanish bibliography in law and
economics provides detailed information on a wide variety of research fields
and authors, following the guidelines provided by the editors.
JEL classification: K00, H0, L5
Keywords: Law and Economics in Spain, Public Choice, Economics of
Regulation, Public Economics.
1. Introduction
Although, as usual, one can trace the roots further back, in Spain what can be
narrowly defined as new Law and Economics started in the 1980s. At that time,
some academics started to introduce basic ideas of the movement as they were
evolving (mainly in the United States), and tried to apply them to Spanish legal
institutions. As time went by, the emphasis tended to be placed more on the
applications and less on the review or importing of existing developments from
abroad. At the present time, one may well conclude that at least one third of
legal scholars have heard about this business, and at least one tenth are well
acquainted with the approach. On the other hand, about half of the academic
economists know the approach well and more than 10 percent are familiar with
it and use it on a more regular basis.
This short report concerns law and economics in a broader sense, that is, it
reflects not only (although mainly) works pertaining to what has been named
new Law and Economics, but also publications related to Public Choice and
Constitutional Economics, Economic Regulation and (only a few) General
346
0385 Law and Economics in Spain 347
already being taught in the law schools at the University Carlos III and
Universidad Autnoma, both in Madrid. It is also contemplated at the
University of Santiago de Compostela (including public choice), at the
University of Extremadura, and may soon be adopted as part of the curriculum
at the Universidad Complutense in Madrid.
In addition, law and economics topics are being taught as part of the
course on principles of economics in several universities: for instance, at the
University of La Corua, and Complutense (Madrid). Topics in Public Choice
and Constitutional Economics are also taugth at the Universities of Valladolid,
Valencia and Santiago de Compostela Law Schools.
3. Scholarly Work
also be applied to a great deal of commercial law, torts and contract law. We
can expect this direction to be further developed most rapidly in the next years.
The setting up of the specialized Center of Law and Economics, Instituto
de Derecho y Economa at the University Carlos III and the newest Centro de
Investigaciones en Derecho, Economi y Administracin de Empresas (Cinde)
at University Complutense, may be an important achievement for the scholarly
work as well as for the policy implementation of this approach.
6. Final Remarks
Language barriers are dropping, and this will open up the market for ideas. It
is also an advantage that the law and economics practitioners, at least in
Europe, are nowadays more realistic and practice-oriented than before.
We still believe that the expansion of the approach greatly depends on its
involvement and application to specific areas (sometimes called disciplines) of
law. Economics will be more fruitful as Economics of Corporate Law, Criminal
Law, Contract Law and the like. When some sound economics is placed in the
hands of a good legal scholar, the productivity is more that duplicated in any
respect, that is, for the law itself, for the law and economics approach and
sometimes even for economics as well. We need to know more about the legal
350 Law and Economics in Spain 0385
Alfaro Aguila-Real, Jess (1995b), Inters Social y Derecho de Suscripcin Preferente. Una
Aproximacin Econmica (Economic Efficiency of a Strict Construction of the Interest of the
Corporation Clause in Corporate Law), Madrid, Ed. Cvitas, 160 p.
Alfaro Aguila-Real, Jess (1996a), Los Costes de Transaccin (Transaction Costs), in Iglesias, Prada
(ed.), Estudios Jurdicos en Homenaje al Profesor Aurelio Menndez, Madrid, Ed. Civitas,
Tomo-I, 131-162.
Alfaro Aguila-Real, Jess (1996b), Los Justos Motivos Como Causa Legal no Escrita de Exclusin
y Separacin de Socios en la Sociedad de Responsabilidad Limitada. Cmo Deshacerse de un Socio
Molesto (How to exclude an annoying shareholder), 222 Revista de Derecho Mercantil, 1079-
1142.
Alonso Gonzalez, Luis Alberto (1995), Ideas para una Teora de la Corrupcin (Some Ideas for a
Theory of Corruption), 741 Informacin Comercial Espaola, 71-83.
Arruada, Benito (1991), Market vs. Regulation in the Market for Corporate Control: Interactions
Between Takeovers and Industrial Policiy in Spain, in Pardolesi, Roberto and Van Den Bergh,
Roger (eds), Law and Economics: Some Further Insights, Milano, Giuffr, 71-106.
Arruada, Benito (1988a), Tiburones y Sanguijuelas en la Plaza de la Lealtad (Sharks and Spongers
in the Stockmarket), 2123 Boletn del ICE, 771-772.
Arruada, Benito (1988b), Un Anlisis Econmico de la Regulacin de la Sociedad Annima en
Espaa (An Economic Analysis of the Regulation of the Joint-Stock Society in Spain), 3 Anales
de Estudios Econmicos y Empresariales, 191-224.
Arruada, Benito (1990a), Control y Regulacin de la Sociedad Annima (Control and Regulation
of Joint-Stock Companies), Madrid, Alianza Editorial, 390 p.
Arruada, Benito (1990b), Economa de la empresa: un Enfoque Contractual (The Economics of the
Firm: A Contractual Approach) ,Barcelona, Ed. Ariel, 398 p.
Arruada, Benito (1990c), La Regulacin de la Informacin Empresarial (Regulation of Corporate
Information), 51 Boletn del Crculo de Empresarios, 11-42.
Arruada, Benito (1990d), Control y Propiedad: Lmites al Desarrollo de la Empresa Espaola
(Corporate Control and Ownership: Limits to its Growth in Spain), 687 Informacin Comercial
Espaola, 67-88.
Arruada, Benito (1991), Nobel al Giro Coasiano (Nobel to the Coasian Turn), 41 Revista de
Economa, 122-126.
Arruada, Benito (1992a), La Conversin Coactiva de Acciones Comunes en Acciones sin Voto para
Lograr el Control de las Sociedades Annimas: De cmo la ingenuidad legal prefigura el fraude
(Mandatory Conversion of Common Shares into Non-Voting Shares to Reach Corporate Control
over Joint-Stock Companies: How legal Simplicity Leads to Fraud), 71 Revista Espaola de
Financiacin y Contabilidad, 283-314.
Arruada, Benito (1992b), Hacia un Mercado Unico de Control Societario? (Towards a Common
Market of Corporate Control), 703 Informacin Comercial Espaola, 144-170.
Arruada, Benito (1992c), Tiburones Slo en el Diccionario (Sharks only in the Dictionary), 56
Boletn del Crculo de Empresarios, 15-30.
Arruada, Benito (1992d), Crtica a la Regulacin de las Opas (A Critique on the Regulation of
Takeovers), 203-4 Revista de Derecho Mercantil, 29-67.
Arruada, Benito (1992e), Profesionales del Monopolio (Professionals of Monopoly), 14 Revista de
Economa, 95-101.
352 Law and Economics in Spain 0385
Arruada, Benito (1993), Pintando la Caja Negra: Notas a La Empresa en el Anlisis Econmico
de V. Salas (Painting the Black Box: A Note on The Firm in V. Salas Economic Analysis), 57
Papeles de Economa Espaola, 156-169.
Arruada, Benito (1994a), Competencia y Privatizacin en el Mercado Educativo (Competition and
Privatization in the Education Market), 59(2) Boletn del Crculo de Empresarios, 265-275.
Arruada, Benito (1994b), El Reparto del Monopolio: Obreros y Empresarios en la Historia de
Asturias (Sharing the Monopoly: Workers and Managers in the History of Asturias), in Garca
Delgado, J.L. and Fernndez de la Buelga, L. (eds), Economa y Empresa en Asturias: Homenaje
al Marqus de Aledo, Madrid, Editioral Cvitas, 690-720.
Arruada, Benito (1995a), Diseo Organizativo y Gestin de Personal en la Sanidad Pblica
(Organization and Management of Human Resources in the Public Healthcare System), in A.E.S.
(ed.), Cambios en la Regulacin Sanitaria, Barcelona, SG Editores, 64-119.
Arruada, Benito (1995b), Colegios Profesionales y Diseo Institucional (Professional Corporation
and Institutional Design), 63 Economistas, 86-90. Reproduced in Velarde J. et al. (dirs.)
Regulacin y competencia en la economa espaola, Cvitas, Madrid, 1995, 65-75.
Arruada, Benito (1995c), The Search for Efficiency in the Spanish Healthcare System, in X (ed.),
A Mixed Market in Healthcare, A New European Convergence, Londres, European Policy
Forum, 52-64.
Arruada, Benito (1995d), Anlisis Econmico del Notariado (Economic Analisis of the Notary),
Madrid, Consejo General del Notariado, 166 p.
Arruada, Benito (1996a), Liberalizacin de Servicios y Colegios Profesionales (Liberalization of
Professional Services and Associations), in Arruada, B. et al. (eds), Reforma de estructura,
Barcelona, Sociedad de Estudios Econmicos, 49-71.
Arruada, Benito (1996b), The Economics of Notaries, 3(1) European Journal of Law and
Economics, 5-37.
Arruada, Benito and Paz Ares, Cndido (1995), Conversion of Ordinary Shares into Non-Voting
Shares, 15(4) International Review of Law and Economics.
Arruada, B. and Paz-Ares, Cndido (1996), Mandatory Rotation of Company Auditors - A Critical
Examination, 16 International Review of Law and Economics, 31-61.
Barbera, Salvador (1989), Los Derechos Individuales en el Anlisis Econmico (Individual Rights and
Economic Analysis), 38 Economistas, 6-9.
Bisbal Mndez, Joaquim (1970), Prlogo Tcnico de: Guido Calabresi, The Costs of Accidents
(Technical Foreword to Guido Calabresis The Cost of Accidents), New Haven, Yale University
Press. Reprinted in El Coste de los accidentes, Ed., Ariel, Barcelona, 1984.
Bisbal Mndez, Joaquim (1983), La Responsabilidad Extracontractual y la Distribucin de los Costes
del Progreso (Tort Law and the Allocation of the Costs of Progress), 167-168 Revista de Derecho
Mercantil, 76-125.
Bisbal Mndez, Joaqum (1986), La Empresa en Crisis y el Derecho de Quiebras (The Crisis of the
Firm and Bankruptcy Law), Bolonia, Real Colegio de Espaa, 383 p.
Bisbal Mndez, Joaquim (1994), La Insoportable Levedad del Derecho Concursal (The Unbearable
Lightness of Bankruptcy Law), 214 Revista de Derecho Mercantil, 843-872.
Bustos Gisbert, Antonio (1995), El Debate Sobre la Legalizacin de las Drogas Blandas: un Anlisis
Formalizado (Making Drugs Legal: A Formal Analysis), 155 p.
Cabrillo, Francisco (1986), Adam Smith on Bankruptcy Law? New Law and Economics in the
0385 Law and Economics in Spain 353
Contractualism?, in Casas Pardo, J. and Schneider, F. (eds), Current Issues in Public Choice,
Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
Casas Pardo, Jos (1995b), Introduccin (Introduction), in Casas Pardo, J. and Schneider, F. (eds),
Current Issues in Public Choice, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
Casas Pardo, Jos (1995c), Las Estructuras Federal y Fiscal de las Democracias Representativa y
Directa como Modelos para una Unin Europea Federal (Federal and Fiscal Structures in
Representative and Direct Democracies as Models for a Federal European Union), in X (ed.),
Actas de las Jornadas de Estudio sobre La Constitucin espaola y el ordenamiento
comunitario europeo (II), Direccin General del Servicio Jurdico del Estado, Ministerio de
Justicia.
Casas Pardo, Jos (1998), The Spanish Transition to Democracy: a Public Choice Approach, in
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (ed.), The Political Economy of Structural Change, Cheltenham, Edward
Elgar.
Casas Pardo, Jos (1998), El Contractualismo-Constitucionalismo Liberal de James M. Buchanan
(James M. Buchanans Liberal Contractualism-Constitutionalism), in Cortina, A. (ed.), tica de
los Negocios, Bancaja, Valencia, Fundacin Etnor, forthcoming.
Casas Pardo, Jos and Brennan, Geoffrey (1990a), A Reading of the Spanish Constitution (1978), 1
Constitutional Political Economy.
Casas Pardo, Jos and Brennan, Geoffrey (1990b), La Constitucin Espaola a la luz de la Economa
Poltica de las Constituciones (The Spanish Constitution from the Political Economy of
Constitutions Approach), 116 Hacienda Pblica Espaola, 53-67.
Casas Pardo, Jos and Fernndez Cainzos, J. (1989), Las Contituciones Econmica y Fiscal en la
Constitucin Espaola de 1978 (The Economic and Fiscal Constitutions into the Spanish
Constitution of 1978), in Alvarez Conde, E. (ed.), La Constitucin Espaola de 1978 diez Aos
Despus, Madrid, Tecnos.
Casas Pardo, Jos and Fernndez Cainzos, J. (1995), La Imposicin a Traves de la Regulacin en
Espaa: Un Intento de Medir la Imposicin Implicita en el Sistema Financiero Espaol en la
Dcada 1977-1987 (Taxation Through Regulation in Spain: An Effort to Measure Implicit
Taxation in the Spanish Financial System between 1977-1987), in X (ed.), Estudios de Derecho
Mercantil en Homenaje al Prof. Manuel Broseta Pont, Tirant lo Blanch, Valencia.
Casas Pardo, Jos and Navarro, Puchades M. (1996), La perspectiva de la Public Choice en el
Anlisis de la Actuacin de los Entes Pblicos (Public Choice Approach and the Behaviour of
Public Enterprises), in X (ed.), Actas del II Congreso Espaol de Ciencia Politica y de la
Administracin (forthcoming).
Casas Pardo, Jos and Sainz Snchez, E. (1995), La coaccin de las instituciones colectivas
(Compelling Collective Institutions), in Sainz Snchez, E. (ed.), Las Organizaciones como
Sistemas Constitucionales, Ensayos Sobre el Modelo de Gestin Burocrtica de la Universidad
Pblica, Granada, Ed. Mtodo.
Chiappori, P.A. and Macho-Stadler, I. (1990), Contrats de Travail Repetes: la Memoire (Repeated
Labour Contracts:The Memory), 17 Annales dEconomie et de Statistique, 47-70.
Chiappori, P.A., Macho-Stadler, I., Rey, P. and Salanie, B. (1994), Repeated Moral Hazard: the Role
of Memory, Commitment, and the Access to Credit Markets, 38 European Economic Review,
1527-1553.
Chiappori, P.A., Prez-Castillo, J. David and Verdier, T. (1995), Spatial Competition in the Banking
System: Localization, Cross Subsidies and the Regulation of Interest Rates, 39 European
0385 Law and Economics in Spain 355
WP-EC95-03, 22 p.
Garci Gallego, Aurora and Georgantzis, Nikolaos (1996a), Competition Intensity vs. Service Quality:
On the Distribution of Para-Pharmaceutical Products in Spain, in Martin, Stephen (ed.),
Interaction of Member State and EU Competition Policy, Amsterdam, forthcoming.
Garci Gallego, Aurora and Georgantzis, Nikolaos (1996b), Multiproduct Activity and Competition
Policy: The Tetra Pak Case, 31 European Journal of Law and Economics, 83-95.
Garci Sanz, Angel (1994), El siglo XVIII: entre la Prosperidad de la Trashumancia y la Crtica
Antimestaa de la Ilustracin (The Mesta in Spain, XVIIIth Century), in Gonzalo Anes y Angel
Garca Sanz (eds), Mesta, Trashumancia y vida Pastoril, Madrid, Sociedad V Centenario del
Tratado de Tordesillas, 137-158.
Garcia Viuela, Enrique (1992), La Distribucin de la Renta y el Criterio de Justicia de Rawls
(Income Distribution and Rawls Justice), 123 Hacienda Pblica Espaola, 77-83.
Garci Viuela, Enrique (1995), Bsqueda de Rentas a Travs del Sector Pblico (Rent Seeking
Through the Public Sector), 133 Hacienda Pblica Espaola, 107-114.
Garcia Viuela, Enrique (1996a), La Financiacin de los Partidos Polticos: un Enfoque de Eleccin
Pblica (Financing Political Parties: A Public Choice Approach), 92 Revista de Estudios
Polticos, 281-297
Garcia Viuela, Enrique (1996b), Una Nota Sobre la Teora del Estado de Anthony de Jasay (A Note
on Anthony de Jasays Theory of the State), 136 Hacienda Pblica Espaola.
Garci Viuela, Enrique (1996c), Una Estimacin de la Bsqueda de Rentas en los Presupuestos de
Gastos de Algunos Paises de la Unin Europea durante los aos 80 (An Estimation of Rent Seeking
in Some E.E.C. Countries Budgets during the 80s), Hacienda Pblica Espaola, 49-54.
Garci Viuela, Enrique and Vzquez Vega, Pablo (1996), Financing the Political Parties: A Public
Choice Approach, 2-3 Ecomonia delle Scette Pubbliche, 139-153
Garci Villarejo, Avelino and Salinas Snchez, Janvier (1993), Manual de Hacienda Pblica general
y de Espaa (Public Treasury Manual), Madrid, Tecnos, 671 p.
Garcimartin Alfrez, Francisco Javier (1995), El Rgimen Normativo de las Transacciones Privadas
Internacionales: una Aproximacin Econmica (The Regulation of International Private
Transactions: an Economic Approach), 47 Revista Espaola de Derecho Internacional, 11-39.
Garcimartin Alfrez, Francisco Javier (1996), El Coste de la ley Helms-Burton para las Empresas
Espaolas (The Costs of Helms-Burton Rule for Spanish Companies), 306 Derecho de los
Negocios, 13-27 .
Georgantzis, Nikolaos (1992a), The Social Aspects of Telecommunications: Targeted Subsidies as
a Means to Achieve Universal Basic Services, Report for the A-3 Unit (Economic Questions and
Studies) of DG IV (Competition) of the European Comission.
Georgantzis, Nikolaos (1992b), The Effect of Mergers on Potential Competition under Economies
or Diseconomies of Joint Production, Istituto Universitario Europeo, EUI Working Paper ECO,
Florence, Italy, No. 92/67.
Georgantzis, Nikolaos and Garci Gallego, Aurora (1995), La Actividad Multiproducto y sus
Implicaciones para la Politica de la Competencia (Multiproduct Activity and Competiton Policy
Implications), Instituto Valenciano de Investigaciones Economicas, WP EC 95-04, 40 p.
Gimeno Ullastres, Juan A. (1975), Las Causas del Dficit Pblico (Trying to Explain Public Deficit),
0385 Law and Economics in Spain 357
Statistique, 189-208.
Macho-Stadler, I. and Prez-Castrillo, J. David (1991c), Double Risque Moral et Delegation (Double
Moral Hazard and Delegation), 57 Recherches conomiques de Louvain, 277-296.
Macho-Stadler, I. and Prez-Castrillo, J. David (1992), Le Regle de la Derogation dans une Relation
dAgence (Derogation Rule in an Agent-Principal Relationship),102-103 Economie et Prvision,
67-77.
Macho-Stadler, I. and Prez-Castrillo, J. David (1993a), Delegar o Centralizar? Qu dice la
Economa de la Informacin? (What Economics of Information Say about Delegation and
Decentralization?), 52 Cuadernos Econmicos de ICE, 25-46.
Macho-Stadler, I. and Prez-Castrillo, J. David (1993b), Moral Hazard with Several Agents: the Gains
from Cooperation, 11(1) International Journal of Industrial Organization, 73-100.
Macho-Stadler, I. and Prez-Castrillo, J. David (1994), Random Audits in Tax Evasion Models, W.P.
UAB-IAE, No. 287.94.
Macho-Stadler, I. and Prez-Castrillo, J. David (1996), Optimal Tax Auditing when Some Individuals
Need Not File, Economic Design.
Macho-Stadler, I. and Prez-Castrillo, J. David (1997a), An Introduction to the Economics of
Information: Incentives and Contracts, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 277 p.
Macho-Stadler, I. and Prez-Castrillo, J. David (1997b), Optimal Auditing Policy with Heterogeneous
Income Sources, 38 International Economic Review, 951-968.
Macho-Stadler, I. and Verdier, T. (1989), Aspectos Estrategicos de la Separacin Accionista-Gestor
(Strategic Aspects between Corporate Ownership and Control), 2(3) De Economa Pblica,
25-44.
Macho-Stadler, I., Martinez-Giralt, X. and Prez-Castillo, J. David (1996), The Role of Information
in Licensing Contract Design, 25 Research Policy, 25-40.
Macho-Stadler, I., Olivella-Cunill, P. and Prez-Castillo, J. David (1993),Tax Amnesties in a Dynamic
Model of Tax Evasion, W.P. UAB-IAE, No. 247.94.
Macho-Stadler, I., Prez-Castillo, J. David and Ponsati, C. (1994), Stable Multilateral Trade
Agreements, W.P. UAB-IAE, No. 281.94.
Mas-Colell, Andreu (1994), LAnlisi Econmica i el Dret (The Economic Analysis and the Law),
3 Iuris, 73-84.
Massaguer, Josep Mara (1994), La Regulacin de Servisios Profesionales, (un Anlisis de
Racionalidad Econmica y Legitimidad Antitrust) (The Regulation of the Professions Economic
Rationality and Antitrust Legitimacy), 3 Iuris, 85-120.
Mercado Pacheco, Pedro (1994), El Anlisis Econmico del Derecho. Una Reconstruccin Terica
(Law and Economics. A Theoretical Reconstruction), Madrid, Centro de Estudios Constitucionales,
292 p.
Naharro Quirs, Elena (1987), La Regulacin Jurdica de las Comarcas de alta Montaa y la
Definicin de los Derechos de Propiedad (The Law of the Highlands and the Definition of Property
Rights), 647 Informacin Comercial Espaola, 93-109.
Nugent, Jeffrey B. and Sanchez, Nicols (1989), The Efficiency of the Mesta: A Parable, 26(3)
Explorations in Economic History, 261-284.
Ocaa, Carlos (1995), Mergers and Takeovers in Spain: Empirical Evidence on Abnormal Returns and
Insider Trading, (forthcoming) Journal of Business Accounting and Finance.
Olivella, P. (1990), Una Introduccin a la Delegacin como Mecanismo de Compromiso (An
362 Law and Economics in Spain 0385
Pastore, Mario H. (1990), La Hipotesis de Domar sobre las Causas de la Sevidumbre o la Esclavitud
en una Colonia Hispanoamericana: Contraste y Reformulacin (Domars Hypothesis on the
Origins of Slavery in a Spanish Colony in America), 8 Revista de Historia Econmica, 575-589.
Paz-Ares, Cndido (1981), La Economa Poltica Como Jurisprudencia Racional (Political Economy
as Rational Jurisprudence), 34 Anuario de Derecho Civil, 601-707.
Paz-Ares, Cndido (1983a), Sobre la Infracapitalizacin de las Sociedades (On Infra-Capitalization
of Corporations), 36 Anuario de Derecho Civil, 1587-1369.
Paz-Ares, Cndido (1983b), Una Teora Econmica Sobre la Mercantilidad de la Compraventa (An
Economic Theory for Sale Being Contract Law), 36 Anuario de Derecho Civil, 943-996.
Paz-Ares, Cndido (1985a), Seguridad Jurdica y Seguridad del Trfico (Legal Certainty and Exhange
Certainty), 175-176 Revista de Derecho Mercantil, 7-41.
Paz-Ares, Cndido (1985b), Seguridad Jurdica y Seguridad del Trfico (Certainty in the Law and
Secure Trade), RDM, 7-41.
Paz-Ares, Cndido (1993), Principio de Eficiencia y Derecho Privado (Efficiency and Private Law),
in AA.VV., Derecho, Moral y Eficiencia, III, Jornadas de Filosofa del Derecho, Palma de
Mallorca. Revisado en Estudios en homenaje a M. Brocheta Pont, Valencia 1995, III pp.
Paz-Ares, Cndido (1994a), Seguridad Jurdica y Sistema Notarial (Certainty in the Law and the
Notarial System), in X (ed.), El Libro Colectivo de la F Pblica, Madrid, 73-134. Igualmente
publicado el Iuris 1, 1994, pp. 351-372.
Paz-Ares, Cndido (1994b), La Infracapitalizacin. Una Aproximacin Contractual (A Contractual
Approach to Infracapitalization), Revista de Derecho de Sociedades, Nmero Extraordinario,
253-269.
Paz-Ares, Cndido (1995a), El Sistema Notarial. Una Aproximacin Econmica (An Economic
Approach to The Notarial System), Madrid, Consejo General del Notariado, 153 p.
Paz-Ares, Cndido (1995b), The Conversin of Ordinary Shares into Non Voting Shares, 15
International Review of Law and Economics, 351-372.
Paz-Ares, Cndido (1996a), La Ley, el Mercado y la Indepencia del Auditor (The Law, the Market
and Auditors Independence), Madrid, Ed. Cvitas, 120 p.
Paz-Ares, Cndido (1996b), Dividendos a Cambio de Votos? (Assessments for Votes), Madrid,
McGraw-Hill, 180 p.
Pedraja, Francisco and Salinas, Javier (1995), La Eficiencia de la Justicia (The Efficiency of the
Contentious-Administrative Courts), 8 Revista de Economa Aplicada, 163-196.
Prez-Castrillo, J. David (1990), Procesos de I+D y Estructura Industrial: un Panorama de Modelos
Tericos (Theoretical Models for R&D Procedures and Industrial Structure), 6 Economa
Pblica, 171-214.
Prez-Castrillo, J. David (1993), Una Panormica de la Literatura de Contratos de Licencia (Survey
on Licensing Contracts), Revista Espaola de Economa (Nmero Monogrfico sobre
Investigacin y Desarrollo), 109-126.
Prez-Castrillo, J. David and Verdier, T. (1992), A General Analysis of Rent Seeking Games, 73(3)
Public Choice, 335-350.
Prez-Castrillo, J. David and Verdier, T. (1993), On Subsidizing R&D, Revista Espaola de
Economa (Nmero Monogrfico sobre Investigacin y Desarrollo), 9-20.
Prez-Castrillo, J. David. and Sandons, J. (1996), Disclosure of Know-How in Research Joint
Ventures, 4 International Journal of Industrial Organization.
0385 Law and Economics in Spain 365
Pintos Ager, Jess (1998a), Responsabilidad Civil y Reparacin sin Culpa. Un Anlisis Jurdico y
Econmico de las Alternativas Globales y las Reformas Parciales Mediante Baremos, Tesis
Doctora indita en el departamento de derecho privado y de la empresa de la universidad Carlos
III de Madrid.
Pintos Ager, Jess (1998b), Sobre la Convenienca y la Constitucionalidad del Sistema de Valoracin
del Dao Personal de la Ley 30/1995', 4458 La Ley.
Portellano, Pedro (1995a), La imitacin en el Derecho de la Competencia Desleal (Mimic in
Competition Law), Madrid, Editorial Cvitas, 645 p.
Portellano, Pedro (1995b), La Valoracin del Sistema de Patentes: una Enseanza para el Derecho de
la Competencia Desleal (Valuing the Patent System: a Lesson for Competition Law), 604-605
Revista General de Derecho, 625-637.
Portellano, Pedro (1996), Deber de Fidelidad de los Administradores de Sociedades Mercantiles y
Oportunidades de Negocio (Fidelity Commitment of Corporation Managers and Bussiness
Oportunities), Madrid, Editorial Cvitas, 143 p.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1987), El Programa de la Economa Constitucional: Una Sntesis (The
Constitutional Economics Program: an Abstract), 192 Revista de Derecho Financiero y
Hacienda Pblica, 1181-1194.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1988), A Framework for a Public Choice Analysis of the European Community,
in Faia Medn, J. Andrs, Economa delle Scelte Pubbliche, 141-158.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1991a), Contractualismo y Justicia (Contractualism and Justice), in Otero, M.,
Rovira, C. and Segura, M. (eds), Problemas de la Ciencia Jurdica. Homenaje a Francisco Puy
Muoz, Santiago, Servicio de Publicacins da Universidade de Santiago de Compostela, 269-289.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1991b), La Influencia de la Economa en el Derecho, Veinticinco Aos Despus
(The Influence of Economics on the Law), in Puy Fraga, P. (ed.), Estudios en Homenaje al
Profesor Carlos Otero Daz, Santiago, Servicio de Publicaciones de la Universidad de Santiago,
541-575.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1992a), La Economa Poltica del Servicio Militar (Political Economy of
Recruiting), 219 Revista de Derecho Financiero y Hacienda Pblica, 471-500. edicin, Boletn
de Informacin del Ministerio de Defensa, n 227, 1992, p. 9-29. 2nd edn, Monografas del
Ceseden: Cuatro aspectos de la defensa nacional, Ministerio de Defensa, Madrid, 1993, pxs.
137-165.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1992b), Comment on the Political Economy of Current European Integration, in
Vosgerau, H.J., European Integration in the World Economy, Heildelberg, Springer, 707-716.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1992c), Presentacin a El Modelo Econmico del Comportamiento Humano
(Presentation to the Economic Model of Human Behaviour), in Frey, B.S. and A. Serna, Dereito,
Revista Xurdica da Universidade de Santiago de Compostela, vol. I, 197-200.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1993a), Anlisis Econmico del Derecho y la Poltica (Economic Analysis of Law
and Politics), Santiago de Compostela, Fundacin Alfredo Braas, 224 p.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1993b), Busqueda de Rentas en el Sector Pblico, o una Teora Econmica de la
Corrupcin Poltica (Rent Seekers in the Public Sector: An Economic Theory for Corruption), in
Puy Fraga, P. (ed.), Anlisis Econmico del Derecho y de la Poltica, Santiago de Compostela,
Fundacin Alfredo Braas, 149-172.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1993c), O Procedemento Administrativo como Factor na toma de Decisins
Pblicas, (Comentarios desde a economa poltica Lei 30/1992 do 26 de Novembro, de rxime
366 Law and Economics in Spain 0385
743-761.
Salinas, Javier (1996a), Economa Constitucional de la Poltica Fiscal Espaola y la Convergencia
Europea (Constitutional Economy of Spanish Tax Policy and European Covergence), in X (ed.),
Proceedings, XVIII Jornadas de la Direccin General del Servicio Juridico del Estado sobre
la Constitucin Espaola y el Ordenamiento Comunitario Europeo, Madrid, Ministerio de
Justicia.
Salinas, Javier (1996b), Elementos Institucionales de la Organizacin Territorial del Sector Pblico
en Castilla y Len (Institutional Elements of the Public Sectors Territorial Organization in
Castilla and Leon), Valladolid, Consejera de Economa, Junta de Castilla y Len.
Salvador Coderch, Pablo (1987), Qu es Difamar?. Libelo Contra la ley del Llibelo (Defamation.
The Law on Libel), Madrid, Editioral Cvitas, 114 p.
Salvador Coderch, Pablo (1990), El Mercado de las Ideas (The Market for Ideas), Madrid, Centro de
Estudios Constitucionales, 549 p.
Salvador Coderch, Pablo (1993), El Derecho de la Libertad (Liberty Rights), Madrid, Centro de
Estudios Constitucionales, 64 p.
Salvador Coderch, Pablo, Lloveras, Ferrer et al. (1995), Del Servicio Pblico al Servicio a la
Comunidad (From Public Service to Service for the Community), 136 Revista de Administracin
Pblica, 69-117.
Snchez, Isabel (1990), Evasin Fiscal, Regulacin y Mecanismos Optimos de Inspeccin (Tax
Evasion, Regulation, and Optimal Auditing Mechanisms), 45 Cuadernos Econmicos de ICE,
121-143.
Snchez, Isabel (1991), Provisin Voluntaria de Bienes Pblicos: Resultados Experimentales
(Volutantary Contributions to Public Goods: Experimental Results), 11 Economa Pblica, 191-
218.
Snchez, Isabel (1993), Hierarchical Design and Enforcement of Income Tax Policies, 50 Journal
of Public Economics, 345-369.
Snchez, Isabel (1994), Determinantes Individuales de la Evasin Fiscal: un Enfoque Experimental
(Individual determinants of Tax Evasion: an Experimental Approach), monografa, Instituto de
Estudios Fiscales.
Snchez, Isabel (1995a), Experimental Analysis of Individuals Tax Compliance Rate, in de Juan, A.
(ed.), Frontiers in Economic Psychology, proceedings of the IAREP Conference, Agosto.
Sanchez, Isabel (1995b), Unravelling the Puzzle of Tax Compliance Using Experimental Methods,
48 Kyklos, 3-18.
Snchez, Isabel and Zapater, I. (1986), Diseo Dinmico de Contratos (Dynamic Contract Design),
Investigaciones Econmicas, 117-142.
Sanjiao Otero, Francisco Javier (1991), Una Aproximacin al Estudio de los Ciclos Poltico
Econmicos (Political-Economic Cycles), in Puy Fraga, P. (ed.), Estudios en Homenaje al Prof.
Carlos G. Otero Diaz, Universidade de Santiago de Compostela, 657-673.
Sanjiao Otero, Francisco Javier (1993), Decisins Polticas e Ciclos Econmicos (Political Decisions
and Economic Cycles), in X (ed.), Anlisis Econmico del Derecho y de la Poltica, Fundacin
Alfredo Braas, 173-190.
Sanjiao Otero, Francisco Javier (1994), Economa de las Instituciones: Anlisis de la Poltica
Musestica en Galicia (Economics of Institutions: Policy on Museums in Galicia), 3 Dereito,
Revista Xurdica da Universidade de Santiago de Compostela, 127-158.
Sanjiao Otero, Francisco Javier (1995a), El Dinero de Tala y Melpmene: un Anlisis Econmico del
0385 Law and Economics in Spain 369
Mundo Teatral (Talia and Melpomenes Money: Economic Analysis of the Theatre), in Corona,
Ramn and Puy, Fraga (eds), Economa en Broma y en Serio, Madrid, Minerva - Fundacin
Alfredo Braas, 107-132.
Sanjiao, Otero and Francisco, Javier (1995b), Anlise Econmico das Medidas Pblicas para o
Fomento do Teatro Privado Galego (Economic Analysis of Public Policy to Promote Private
Galician Theatre), in Leiceaga, Fernndez, Jordn, Rodrguez, Lpez, Iglesias and Vence, Deza
(eds), Estudos en homenaxe profesor Xose Manuel Beiras Torrado, Universidade de Santiago
de Compostela, 439-460.
Torres Lpez, Juan (1983a), Recensin del Libro (A Review of) Law and Economics, de R. Hirsh,
2 Revista de la Facultad de Derecho de la Universidad de Granada.
Torres Lpez, Juan (1983b), Recensin de la (A Review of) International Review of Law and
Economics, 3 Revista de la Facultad de Derecho de la Universidad de Granada.
Torres Lpez, Juan (1984a), Recensin del Libro, El Coste de los Accidentes (A Review of, The Cost
of Accidents), 4 Revista de la Facultad de Derecho de la Universidad de Granada, 175-179.
Torres Lpez, Juan (1984b), Tradicin y Resultados de una Disciplina Novedosa: La Economa del
Derecho (Tradition and Outcomes of Law and Economics), 5 Revista de la Facultad de Derecho
de la Universidad de Granada, 27-40.
Torres Lpez, Juan (1985), Las Crticas a la Corriente Mayoritaria en el Anlisis Econmico del
Derecho (Critizisms Against the Mainstream in Law and Economics), Valladolid.
Torres Lpez, Juan (1987a), Anlisis Econmico del Derecho. Panorama doctrinal (Survey on Law
and Economics), Madrid, Editorial Tecnos, 108 p.
Torres Lpez, Juan (1987b), Tradicin y Resultados de una Disciplina Novedosa: la Economa del
Derecho. Una Orientacin Bibliogrfica (Tradition and Outcome of a New Discipline: The
Economics of Law. A Guide to the Literature), 5 Revista de la Facultad de Derecho de la
Universidad de Granada.
Torres Lpez, Juan (1989), Derechos de Propiedad, Poder y Mercado (Property Rights, Power and
Market), 38 Economistas, 22-26.
Torres Lpez, Juan (1992), Regular la Informacin, Problemas Econmicos, Perspectivas Jurdicas
(Economic and Legal Issues in the Regulation of Information), 14 Revista de Economa, 89-94.
Valden Buruque, Julio (1994), La Mesta y el Pastoreo en Castilla en la Baja Edad Media, 1273-1473
(The Mesta in the Low Medieval Age 1273-1473), in Gonzalo Anes y Angel Garca Sanz (eds),
Mesta, Trashumancia y vida Pastoril, Madrid, Sociedad V Centenario del Tratado de Tordesillas,
49-64.
Vzquez Vega, Pablo (1990), Grupos de Inters en la Comunidad Econmica Europea. Apuntes Sobre
un Regulacin Actual (The Regulation of Interest Groups in the European Community), 687
Informacin Comercial Espaola, 89-102.
Vzquez Vega, Pablo (1992), Anlisis Econmico de las Organizaciones Internacionales (Economic
Analysis of International Organizations), Universidad Complutense.
Vzquez Vega, Pablo (1995), Institutions and Postwar Economic Growth in Europe, Working Paper,
Departamento de Economa Universidad de Cantabria, n.95.06.
Vzquez Vega, Pablo (1996), Discriminacin Positiva? La Reforma del Impuesto de Sociedades en
el Pais Vasco (Positive Discrimination? Corporate Tax Reform in Euskadi), Revista de la
Camara de Comercio, Industria y Navegacin.
0390
LAW AND ECONOMICS IN SWEDEN
Gran Skogh
Professor of Economics, Department of Managment and Economics,
Linkping University
Copyright 1999 Gran Skogh
Abstract
The European law and economics movement started early in Sweden. However,
the dialogue between economists and lawyers has developed slowly, if at all.
The reluctance toward economics in the law schools can be explained by the
strong influence emanating from legal realism and positivism. Moreover,
scholars with a law degree have most limited training in social sciences.
Although law and economics has only exerted a marginal impact on legal
education, it has nonetheless influenced the Swedish political debate.
JEL classification: K00
Keywords: Law and Economics, Scandinavian Realism, Education, Research.
1. Introduction
During 1974-77, a Law and Economics seminar took place at the Department
of Economics and at the Faculty of Law at the University of Lund. The first
international conference in Law and Economics in northern Europe was held
in 1977, and a conference volume ensued, Acta Societatis Juridicae Lundensis
(1977). Thus, the European law and economics movement started early in
Sweden.
The first doctoral dissertation in law and economics in Sweden was
defended at the University of Lund (see Skogh, 1973). Thereafter, several
dissertations have been presented by economists, for example Soeria-Atmadja
(1983), Bjuggren (1985), Schuller (1986), Fahlbeck (1996), Bolin (1996),
Berggren (1997), Hgg (1998) and by lawyers, for example Samuelsson (1991),
Runesson (1996) and Domeij (1998).
Nevertheless, the dialogue between academic economists and lawyers has
developed slowly, if at all. Nowadays, there are no regular law and economics
seminars at any Swedish university. Nonetheless, there are three fully
accredited law schools in Sweden: at the universities of Lund, Stockholm and
Uppsala. Other universities and colleges offer partial programs in law. There
is one chair in Economics (shared with the economics department) at the
Faculty of Law at the University of Stockholm. There used to be a similar chair
370
0390 Law and Economics in Sweden 371
in Economics at the law faculties of the Universities of Lund and Uppsala, but
the chairs have been withdrawn.
Law students traditionally take an obligatory introductory course in
economics. This course was reduced in the 1970s from around ten weeks to four
weeks of full-time study. Swedish textbooks in economics for law students are
Skogh (1977), Werin (1982, 1997), Hglund (1984), Bjuggren and Skogh
(1990), Skogh and Lane (1993), and Bergstrm and Samuelsson (1997). Also
international textbooks are used. Law students are, thus, to some extent
acquainted with the economics of property rights, risk-sharing, and so on. The
normal period of study for a law degree is four-and-a-half years. Swedish law
students have no previous university training (such as the bachelors degree in
the USA). Hence, the Swedish lawyer gains very little training in the social
sciences.
2. Scandinavian Realism
economic analysis of law. Exceptions, however, are Hellner (1988) and Roos
(1981, 1990) that notes the relevance of economic analysis of law. One reason
for the reluctance may be that Swedish academic lawyers lack understanding
of economic methods, and another may be that the contributions Swedish
economists have made to law have been limited.
The mutual distrust has to some extent been transmitted to law and
economics research. Economic analysis of law is not regarded as mainstream
economics. Nevertheless, there is an interest in institutional economics, and as
long as the analysis of institutions is based on generally accepted methods,
economic analysis of law is accepted within the profession.
Applied economics, in cooperation with lawyers or adapted for them, has
little professional status among academic economists. Similarly, cooperation
with economists is of low professional value in the legal profession.
Nevertheless, a number of scholars are working on law and economics
problems at various institutions. In addition to what has been mentioned above,
work by Holmn (1993), Eklund (1995) and Bjuggren (1992, 1995) should be
noted. Moreover, the Stockholm School of Economics has an Economics
Department and a Law Department interested in the field. Some smaller
business schools and universities have also shown an interest in law and
economics, especially Linkping University and Jnkping International
Business School. Finally, the private Center for Business and Policy Studies
(SNS) has conducted a number of law and economics projects: see, for
instance, Bergstrm and Rydqvist (1992) and Macey (1994).
Criminal Law
Economic reasoning has also influenced specific legal fields. Until the early
1970s, the criminological debate was dominated by sociological and medical
schools, which held that the purpose of sanctions was to treat the individual and
to make the criminal less inclined to commit crimes. Punishment did not
appear to deter, and general deterrence was not analysed in detail. In the mid
1970s, the classical school experienced a renaissance: punishment was to be
proportional to the harm of the crime and not only related to the criminals
need for treatment. General deterrence was again regarded as important (see
Brottsfrebyggande Rdet, 1975), and the criminal code was adjusted,
accordingly.
Although it is not possible to identify clearly the connection between
changes in criminal policy and the economics of crimes, it can be argued that
the connection existed. The first publications in law and economics in Swedish
were on the economics of crime (see Skogh, 1973; Skogh and Stuart, 1982a,
1982b). Swedish criminologists and criminal lawyers in the Ministry of Justice
were familiar with Gary Beckers (1968) work and the subsequent empirical
literature on deterrence. The Swedish debate was also influenced indirectly
through international changes in favour of the classical schools belief that
punishment should parallel harm.
National factors also had an impact on the rapid change in Swedish
attitudes toward general prevention. One such factor was that criminals formed
an association, KRUM, which claimed to represent prisoners. KRUM rejected
the idea that criminals were mentally ill or incapable of rational decisions. It
wanted prisoners to be regarded as rational and argued in favour of
time-limited sentences instead of time-unlimited treatment. In the 1970s, there
was also an increased interest in white-collar crimes, drug-related crimes, tax
evasion, and other calculated crimes. For such crimes, deterrence may be the
most obvious reason for punishment.
Tort law
One of the major goals of the Social Democratic party has been to build up an
extensive public insurance system. Health insurance, disability insurance,
unemployment insurance, and pension schemes today cover most personal
economic losses. Such insurance is mainly financed through taxes and is
0390 Law and Economics in Sweden 375
independent of negligence.
Opponents have argued that damages are an important tool for preventing
accidents. The counter-argument from Social Democratic politicians and some
influential lawyers has been that the tort system is slow, unsophisticated, and
expensive. It has also been argued that the preventive effect of damages is
unproved, (see Hellner, 1985).
Economic analysis of accident law was introduced in Sweden two decades
ago, (see Skogh, 1977, 1998a, 1998b). In general, there has been a political
reluctance to change the public system of undifferentiated, no-fault insurance
schemes. However, attitudes have changed among lawyers, (see Roos, 1990).
One reason for the change in political attitudes is that costs of compensating
people for losses of earnings due to sickness have increased sharply. A reform
instituting deductibles for employees and employers has been introduced and
extended. An immediate effect was a significant reduction in the absence at the
workplace. The traffic and disability insurance systems are now under debate
(see Bladini, 1994).
5. Concluding Remarks
Although law and economics came to Sweden more than two decades ago, it
has not yet become an integral part of legal research. The Scandinavian
doctrine of legal realism, together with various institutional obstacles, may
explain why. There is no reason, however, to be overly pessimistic about the
future of law and economics in Sweden. Several positive factors ought not be
overlooked. First, especially young academic lawyers are interested in applying
economics to law. In the law schools, there appears to be dissatisfaction with
traditional legal realism and formalistic positivism. Second, membership in the
EU and the presence of international common law trends influence the legal
scholars. Third, the application of economic analysis to ongoing legislation is
fruitful, which is likely to have an impact on legal education and research in
the long run.
Acta Sociatatis Juridicae Lundensis (1977), Law and Economics. Report from a Symposium in
Sweden, 28 Juridiska Freningen i Lund.
Berggren, Niclas (1997), Essays in Constitutional Economics. Dissertation, Stockholm School of
Economics.
Bergstrm, Clas and Rydquist, Kristian (1992), Marknaden fr Fretagskontroll (The Market for
Corporate Control), Stockholm, SNS frlag.
Bergstrm, Clas and Samuelsson, Per (1997), Aktiebolagets Grundproblem (Basic Problems of the
376 Law and Economics in Sweden 0390
Skogh, Gran (1988), ganderttens Ekonomi och Politik (The Economics and Politics of Property
Rights), Politiskt-Filosofiska Sllskapets rsskrift.
Skogh, Gran (1991), Law and Economics in Sweden, 11 International Review of Law and
Economics, 319-324.
Skogh, Gran (1995), Ekonomiskt Ansvar vid Krnkraftsolyckor (Liability at Nuclear Accidents),
Rapport till Energikommissionen, SOU 1995:140, bil. 25.
Skogh, Gran (1998a), Development Risks and the Insurability of Industrial Hazards, a Geneva
Papers on Risk and Insurance, 247-265.
Skogh, Gran (1998b), Insurance and Liability, in X., Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, Edward
Elgar and University of Gent.
Skogh, Gran and Lane, Jan Erik (1993), gandertten i Sverige. En Lrobok i Rttsekonomi
(Property Rights in Sweden), SNS Frlag.
Skogh, Gran and Samuelsson, Per (1985a), Konsumentpolitik (Consumer Policy), Stiftelsen
Marknadsekonomiskt Alternativ fr Sverige.
Skogh, Gran and Samuelsson, Per (1985b), Splittring eller Sammanhllning i Svensk Frs-kring
(Disruption or Unity in Swedish Insurance? An Economic and Legal Analysis of the Marketing
Agreements etc.), Lund, Dialogos.
Skogh, Gran and Stuart, Charles (1982a), A Contractarian Theory of Property Rights and Crime,
1 Scandinavian Journal of Economics.
Skogh, Gran and Stuart, Charles (1982b), An Economic Analysis of Crime Rates, Punishments and
the Consequences of Crime, 39 Public Choice.
Skogh, Gran, P.O. Bjuggren et al. (1989), Fretaget. En Kontraktsekonomisk Analys (The Firm. A
Contractual Analysis), SNS Frlag.
Soeria-Atmadja, S. (1982), Handlar Konsumentombudsmannen Alltid i Konsumenternas Intresse?
(Do the Consumers Representatives Always Protect the Consumers Interests?), 4 Ekonomisk
Debatt.
Soeria-Atmadja, S. (1983), Product Guarantees and Liability Rules: an Economic Analysis.
Disseration, Department of Economics. University of Stockholm.
Sthl, Ingemar (1976), gande och Makt i Fretagen - en Debattinledning, Nationalekonomiska
Freningens Frhandlingar (Ownership and Power in the Firms - An Introduction to Debate, the
Economics Associations Negotiations), 1 Ekonomisk Debatt.
Sthl, Ingemar (1989), Ngra Data om Forskning och Utbildning vid Juridiska Fakulteter (Some
Data on Research and Education at Law Faculties), Unpublished, Department of Economics, Lund
University.
Werin, Lars (1978), Expropriation - en Studie i Lagstiftningsmotiv och Ersttningsrttsliga
Grundprinciper (Expropriation - A Study in Legislative Motives and Compensatory Basic
Principles), Svensk Juristtidning, 81-120.
Werin, Lars (1982), Ekonomi och Rttssystem (Economy and Legal System), Malm, Liber.
Werin, Lars (1997), Economic Incentives and the Legal Order, Unpublished manuscript.
Wicksell, Knut (1958), A New Principle of Just Taxation, Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen.
Musgrave and Peacock, 1958, 72-118
Wijkman, P.M. (1974), Kampen om Jordens Allmnningar (The Struggle for the Common Land on
Earth), Ekonomisk Debatt.
0390 Law and Economics in Sweden 379
Other References
Becker, Gary (1968), Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach, Journal of Political
Economy, 169-217.
Lloyd, Lord of Hampstead (1972), Introduction to Jurisprudence, 3th Edition, London, Steams and
Son.
Macey, Jonathan (1993), Corporate Law and Corporate Governance in Sweden, SNS frlag,
Stockholm.
Malmstrm, ke (1986), Civilrtt (Civil Law), Malm, Liber.
Olivecrona, Karl (1939), Law as Facts, 2nd edn, 1971, Copenhagen and London.
Ross, Alf (1968), Directive and Norms, in Honderick, T. (ed.), International Library of Philosophy
and Scientific Method.
Ross, Alf (1971), Om Ret og Retfaerdighet. En infrelse i den analytiske retsfilosofi (On rights and
Justice. An introduction to the Analytical Legal Philosophy), 3rd edn, Nyt Nordisk Forlag,
Copenhagen.
Ryssdal, Stray A.C. (1995), Legal Realism and Economic Behaviour. A Scandinavian Look at
Economic Analysis of Law, Oslo, Juridisk Forlag.
0395
LAW AND ECONOMICS IN SWITZERLAND
Copyright 1999 Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest
380
0395 Law and Economics in Switzerland 381
Hotz, Beat (1982), konomische Analyse des Rechts - eine skeptische Betrachtung (Economic
Analysis of Law - A Sceptical Reflection), 34 Wirtschaft und Recht, 293-314.
Iten, R., Maggi, R., Schelbert-Syfrig, Heidi and Zimmerman, Andreas J. (1989), There is no Such
Thing as a Free Lunch, 125 Schweizerische Zeitschrift fr Volkswirtschaft und Statistik.
Janssen, Martin and Hummler, Konrad (1979), Bundesverfassung und Verfassungsentwurf, Eine
konomisch-rechtliche Analyse (Constitution and Revision of the Constitition, An Economic
and Legal Analysis), Schriften des Schweizerischen Aufklrungs-Dienstes.
Junod, Charles-Andr (1988), LIndexation des Crdits Hypothcaires Pourrait-elle la Fois
Amliorer le Fonctionnement du March du Logement et Servir de Correctif lInflation?
(Could the Indexation of Mortgage debt Improve the Functioning of the Housing Market and
Serve to Correct the Inflation), 40 Wirtschaft und Recht, 88-123.
Kleinewefers, Henner (1987), konomische Theorie des Rechts, ber Unterschiede Zwischen dem
Okonomischen und dem Juristischen Denken (Economic Theory of Law, On the Differences
between), in X (ed.), Staat und Gesellschaft, Festschrift fr Leo Schrm, Fribourg,
Universittsverlag, 83-116.
Kramer, Ernst A. (1979), Konsumentenschutz als neue Dimension des Privat- und Wirtschaftsrecht
(Consumer Protection as a New Dimension of Private and Economic Law), 98 Zeitschrift fr
Schweizerisches Recht, 49-92.
Meier-Schatz, Christian (1987), Unternehmenszusammenschlsse mittels bernahmeangebot
(Mergers by Takeover Bid), 39 Wirtschaft und Recht, 16-39.
Meier-Schatz, Christian (1988), ber die Notwendigkeit Gesellschaftsrechtlicher Aufsichtsregeln,
Ein Beitrag zur konomischen Analyse des Gesellschaftsrechts (On the Necessity of Rules for
the Supervision of Corporations, A Contribution to the Economic Analysis of Company Law),
1 Zeitschrift fr Schweizerisches Recht, 1-241.
Meier-Schatz, Christian (1989a), Wirtschaftsrecht und Unternehmenspublizitt (Economic
Legislation and Enterprise Publicity), Zurich, Schulthess.
Meier-Schatz, Christian (1989b), Europische Harmonisierung des Gesellschafts- und
Kapitalmarktrechts (European Harmonization of Company and Capital Market Law), 41
Wirtschaft und Recht, 84-110.
Pommerehne, Werner W. (1983), Steuerhinterziehung und Schwarzarbeit als Grenzen der
Staatstatigkeit (Tax Evasion and Underground Activities as Limits of Governments Growth),
119 Schweizerische Zeitschrift fr Volkswirtschaft und Statistik, 261-284.
Richli, Paul (1985), Handels- und Gewerbefreiheit contra Energiepolitik (Freedom of Trade and
Industry versus Energy Policy), 86 Schweizerisches Zentralblatt fr Staats- und
Verwaltungsrecht, 1-14.
Robert, Philippe and Godefroy, Thierry (1977), Le Cot du Crime ou lEconomie Poursuivant le
Crime (The Cost of Crime or Economics Prosecuting Crime), Genve, Masson, 225 p.
Ruffner, Markus (1990), Neue Wettbewerbstheorie und schweizerisches Ka (New Competition
Theory and Swiss Antitrust Law, Possibilities and Limitations of a Market and Institutionalist
Foundation of Competition Policy), Zurich, Schulthess.
Schelbert-Syfrig, Heidi and Zimmermann, Andreas J. (1988), Konkurrenz und Umweltschutz.
Wald und Holzwirtschaft zwischen Okonomie und Okologie (Competition and Environment
Protection. Forest and Forestry Between Economics
and Ecology), 124 Schweizerische Zeitschrift fr Volkswirtschaft und Statistik, 289-302.
382 Law and Economics in Switzerland 0395
Schelbert-Syfrig, Heidi, Lang, Th., Buse, I., Henzman, J., Maggi, R. and Iten, R. (1988), Wertvolle
Umwelt (Valuable Environment), Zurich, Schriftenreihe Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft der
Zrcher Kantonalbank, September.
Schrmann, Leo (1976), Konjunkturpolitik und freie Wechselkur se (Conjuncture Policy and Free
Exchange Rate), in X (ed.), Schweizerische Wirtschaftspolitik zwischen gestern, Bern, Haupt,
265-277.
Schrmann, Leo (1990), Der Wettbewerb im Urteil der Staatswissenschaft (The Competition in the
Judgment of Economics), 42 Wirtschaft und Recht, 35-41.
Sieber, Hugo (1981), Wirtschaftsfreiheit und Wirtschaftspolitik (Festschrift fr Hans Huber zum
80. Geburtstag) (Economic Freedom and Economic Policy), in X (ed.), Recht als Prozess und
Gefge, Bern, Haupt, 447-465.
Stolz, Peter (1983), Das Wiedererwachte Interesse der konomie an Rechtlichen und Politischen
Institutionen (The Renewed Interest of Economics in Legal and Political Institutions), 119
Schweizerische Zeitschrift fr Volkswirtschaft und Statistik, 49-67.
Vuaridel, Roger (1986), LObjet et le Niveau de la Concurrence dans la Thorie Economique et
dans la Jurisprudence (The Object and Level of Competition in Economic Theory and in
Jurisprudence), 20 Wirtschaft und Recht, 111-128.
Weck-Hannemann, Hannelore and Pommerehne, Werner W. (1989),
Einkommenssteuerhinterziehung in der Schweiz. Eine empirische Analyse (An Empirical
Analysis of Income Tax Evasion in Switzerland), 125(4) Schweizerische Zeitschrift fr
Volkswirtschaft und Statistik, 515-556.
Wiegang, Wolfgang (1988), Die Rezeption Amerikanischen Rechts (The Reception of American
Law), in X (ed.), Die Schweizerische Rechtsordung in ihren Internationalen Bezgen, Bern,
Haupt, 229-262.
0400
METHODOLOGY: GENERAL
Heico Kerkmeester
Associate Professor
Erasmus University of Rotterdam
Copyright 1999 Heico Kerkmeester
Abstract
Most disputes on the methodology of law and economics have been initiated
by critical scholars from disciplines outside the field itself, such as
practitioners of law and literature and critical legal studies. This chapter
reviews the literature on the methododology of law and economics.
It discusses, among others, the following issues: the object of law and
economics, the measuring rod (money versus utility), positive and normative
law and economics, and the scientific value of law and economics
JEL classification: K00.
Keywords: Positive and Normative Law and Economics, Scientific Value,
Method and Object.
Law and economics does not differ from other fields of study in the respect
that over time different schools of thought have come into existence. Such
schools include Chicago Law and Economics, Public Choice Theory,
Institutional Law and Economics and Neoinstitutional Law and Economics
(Mercuro and Medema, 1997). It has been argued, however, that most legal
economists follow a pragmatic, eclectic, approach and that with a few
exceptions, it is hard to fit them in a particular school of which they
faithfully follow the rules. The economic approach to law is based on a
limited number of assumptions that themselves may be amended if an
alternative set of assumptions would fit the particular object of study better
(De Geest, 1994). Therefore, a review of the methodology of law and
economics must concentrate on the ideas that are shared by the vast majority
of the people working in this field, although attention will be paid to the
cases in which alternative viewpoints have been defended by major scholars.
Remarkably, most disputes on the methodology of law and economics have
been initiated by critical scholars from disciplines outside the field itself,
such as practitioners of law and literature and critical legal studies.
383
384 Methodology: General 0400
the method and thereby improve on the study of the particular object. Over
time this will be required in order to advance law and economics.
The people who are assumed to maximize are individual people. This is
to say that the individual action is the basic unit of analysis, so that the
action of collective actors like firms or states should be analyzed in
individual terms. This principle, known as methodological individualism, is
just an analytical tool and in itself does not have ethical implications in the
sense that the interests of individuals ought to be maximized.
Moreover, methodological individualism does not require that
individuals are nontuistic in the sense that they only take their own
wellbeing into account when they make decisions. It is true that in most
economic analysis of law the assumption of rationality implies nontuism, but
this is clearly an example of an assumption that may be amended without
violating the essence of an economic analysis. In the context of family law,
for example, it is usually assumed that parents are altruistic towards their
children (Becker, 1991). Neither does methodological individualism imply
that individuals are assumed to make their decisions in isolation from
others. The idea that individuals choose in the context of social interactions
is made explicit when game theory is used as a method of economic analysis,
as nowadays is often the case (Kerkmeester, 1995).
It has been argued that human rationality is bounded in the sense that it
is limited by a lack of information or of abilities to process information. An
alleged consequence is that people do not maximize but are satisfied with
reaching a certain aspiration level of utility. However, in mainstream law
and economics issues of information may be taken into account by
acknowledging that acquiring and processing information is costly and that,
therefore, a rational individual deliberately will limit the collection of
information (Posner, 1993a).
Recent developments in law and economics extend its realm beyond the
context of markets by analyzing the consequences of social norms. The
existence of social norms can be the basis for an explanation of human
behavior, alternative to the rational choice approach. In some cases the best
predictions may be yielded by the assumption that individuals choose
certain acts because it is the norm to do so, rather than that they would base
their actions on an outcome-oriented evaluation of costs and benefits (Elster,
1989). Within law and economics, social norms have particularly attracted
attention since Ellickson (1991) showed that, different from what the Coase
theorem predicts, individuals do not bargain towards an efficient solution on
the basis of clearly defined rights that function as starting point for
negotiations. Rather they simply follow social norms that often, although not
always, help to obtain efficient outcomes.
386 Methodology: General 0400
Many attempts have been made to show that social norms themselves
may be the results of rational choices (Becker, 1996; Cooter, 1998).
Ronald Coase (1994) compares the use of the term utility in economic
models with the use of the term aether in classical physics. It is not
observable, but only called in because it is required to make the traditional
model work.
The fact that all behaviors can be explained in terms of utility is an
advantage, but at the same time another drawback of its use. The only way to
determine someones utility function is to observe his behavior. If, however,
the utility function thus derived will be used to predict the behavior of the
same individual, circularities are bound to occur. No matter how unusual
ones behavior, it always can be explained by assuming that it maximizes
utility. This helps to understand the importance of rational choice theorys
assumption that preferences are stable during the period under
consideration.
The most obvious alternative for the use of utility is money, as is
preferred by both Coase and Posner, and this use has clearly some
advantages. In the first place the assumption that, other things being
constant, people prefer more money over less and always like to have more,
is among the most realistic assumptions that can be made. Because,
however, some individuals may form an exception to this rule, the circularity
inherent in the statement that individuals maximize utility is avoided.
Interpersonal comparisons are easier to make with money than with utility.
Although a dollar may not mean the same to person A as to person B, at
least it is the same dollar. This possibility is particularly important in
normative law and economics. In order to avoid the restrictions of the Pareto
criterion that as was noted above, only allows for a change if nobody is
worse off as a result, Richard Posner (1992) defends the use of the principle
of wealth maximization. The measure is the willingness to pay: if goods and
other resources are in the hands of the persons who were willing and able to
pay the highest amount for this, wealth is maximized. Willingness to pay is
not a pure expression of the preferences that an individual has towards a
particular item. It may be the case that although A has more intense
preferences with regard to an item than B has, still B may be willing to pay
more for it, for the simple reason that he has more money available. There is
a speculative element in it since the offering prices one needs to know to
determine willingness to pay are not always observable.
Alternatives
There has not been much attention for the use of alternatives to money or
utility in law and economics. This neglect contrasts with the extensive
discussions in economics and in ethical discourses. A source of alternatives
for money is fed by some authors argument against welfarism, that is the
idea that the social ordering of different situations should depend on the
utility that individuals derive in those different states of the world (Roemer,
1996). An important problem is that individuals may have perverse
388 Methodology: General 0400
Criticisms
The economic assumptions regarding utility or wealth maximization have
been the main objects of attacks by critics of law and economics. The
criticisms have focused on the positive as well as the normative use of the
assumptions.
The mainstream ideas about maximizing behavior are based on the
assumption that desires and opportunities are independently given
(Kerkmeester, 1992). It may, however, be the case that desires are
influenced by opportunities. Dworkin (1980) points at the possibility that
because of the familiar grass is greener phenomenon, social wealth may be
increased by a transfer from A to B, but because of the resulting change in
preferences then again may be increased by transferring the item back from
B to A. Even more common is the situation in which on the contrary
someone will ask more for something he owns than he would pay to acquire
it. This has become known as the endowment effect and as such it has
received its place in the economic analysis of law (Sunstein 1997a).
Particularly vexing for economists is the sour grapes effect, named after
the fable of the fox who, when he discovered that he could not reach certain
grapes, did not want them because they were sour anyway (Elster, 1979).
The effect is important for a judgement of the assumption of wealth
maximization but it conflicts with the equally important assumption that
preferences are stable.
Some authors have argued that the unidimensionality of measuring in
terms of utility or money fails to take the complexity of human motivation
into account. Martha Nussbaum (1997) argues that in law and economics too
much attention is paid to variables that are measurable, at the expense of
0400 Methodology: General 389
other factors that may play no lesser role in determining human action.
According to Robin West (1988) legal economists fail to reckon with the
warmth and empathy that characterizes human relations. The use of
Kaldor-Hicks efficiency in law and economics, however, implies the
assumption that it is possible to obtain sufficient insight in the preferences of
others to determine what one needs to get in order to be compensated for a
loss (De Geest 1994). Therefore, it is doubtful whether Wests criticism
holds against mainstream law and economics.
All the previous remarks are based on the idea that the assumptions
regarding utility or wealth maximization do not provide for a realistic
description of the complexities of human behavior in the real world. One
response from law and economics could be that its assumptions can be - and
often are - made to be more in accordance with reality. In particular, Gary
Beckers (1996) recent work on tastes shows willingness to incorporate the
possibility of changes in preferences into the economic model. A different
response, however, could be that unrealism of assumptions is not necessarily
a bad thing. The latter point will be returned to in Section 4.
Most reactions have been provoked by Richard Posners principle of
wealth maximization. The most influential of these reactions is Ronald
Dworkins (1980) comment.
In the first place Dworkin notes that willingness to pay for an item is not
only determined by preferences for the item, but also by ability to pay.
Therefore, a scarce item may end up in the hands of a rich man who barely
needs it, rather than with a poor soul who desperately needs it, but simply
cannot afford to pay the same amount. This situation is in accordance with
the principle of wealth maximization, while total utility is not maximized.
In the second place, wealth maximization may lead to outcomes that can
be regarded as unfair. This is the case in the example mentioned above, but
outcomes can also be unfair in cases in which total utility is maximized but
unequally divided.
In the third place, Dworkin argues that the principle of wealth
maximization interferes with individual autonomy as would be guaranteed
by individual rights. He mentions a case in which A attaches a higher value
to an item than owner B does. A benevolent dictator then would maximize
wealth by taking the item from B and giving it to A.
The allegation that law and economics does not recognize rights that is
implicit in the last remark is clearly unjustified, and Dworkin himself
mitigated his criticism in this respect. As the importance of the notion of
property rights within law and economics shows, rights do play an important
role. Dworkins remarks certainly have their merits, but it should be noted
that a normative law and economics does not stand or fall with Posners
390 Methodology: General 0400
Due to the discussion above it has become obvious that it is important to try
to distinguish between positive and normative law and economics. This issue
is particularly important for an evaluation of the position of law and
economics as a scientific discipline. In other words: it should be clear
whether law and economics regards statements about how the law and its
effects are, or about how they ought to be.
A possible point of view is that both are possible (Friedman, 1987). A
positive analysis explains the law, predicts its effects and thereby indicates
which legal rule as a matter of fact will be efficient. These results of a
positive analysis can then be used for normative purposes, such as the
prescription of the efficient rule.
The approach leading to normative statements has been aptly
characterized by James Buchanans (1990) words the ought is derived from
the presumed is. A legal economists starts with assumptions about human
behavior. Correct predictions of human behavior and the way it is influenced
by the law are required for decisions on how the law should be. Therefore,
the discussion about the realism of assumptions that will follow in the next
paragraph will be relevant for both positive and normative law and
economics.
However, not everyone is satisfied with the idea of a co-existence of
positive and normative law and economics. Some argue that only a positive
economic analysis of law is possible (De Geest 1994). The efficiency of a
legal rule is regarded to be a factual issue, and that it thus can be determined
objectively. To argue that therefore this rule is desirable is to add a value
judgement that is not a part of an economic analysis.
A point of view that is even more radical is that economics is a strictly
positive science, while law is a strictly normative undertaking, and that
therefore law and economics cannot go together (Couwenberg et al. 1980).
The opinions just cited lose ground, however, as soon as it is
acknowledged that a science is not necessarily positive and that this is
particularly true for the economic science. Coase gives the example of an
economist predicting that a certain measure, namely collectivization of
agriculture, will lead to mass starvation. In Coases opinion it is absurd to
state that the economist is not able to make a statement about whether this
particular measure is desirable or not. The idea that the making of value
judgements is better left to others is rejected by Coase (1994), since he
0400 Methodology: General 391
believes that economists and others share many values and economists thus
are able to make acceptable value judgements on their own.
Coases opinion is supported by the fact that nowadays many economists
are no longer reluctant to acknowledge that they are engaged in a normative
undertaking. In particular, the relation between economics and ethical issues
as the just distribution of welfare has been the subject of study (Roemer,
1996). It could well be argued that if economics could be normative
anywhere it is in the context of the economic analysis of law.
Several authors (for example Raes 1990) even argue that an economic
analysis always is normative, at least implicitly. Their argument is that if
legal economists focus so much on efficiency, this shows that they believe
laws should be efficient or that at least efficiency is an important and
desirable characteristic. An even more critical approach to the allegedly
normative contents of law and economics is put forward from critical legal
studies and law and literature. Both are currents in American legal theory
that have been particularly aimed at unmasking law and economics as a
biased - inherently conservative, right-wing - movement (Kelman, 1987;
Duxbury, 1995; Mercuro and Medema, 1997).
less interested in positive studies than in normative arguments that state how
a case should be decided or how a law should be written.
Another alternative that attracted attention in law and economics is
Lakatoss Methodology of Scientific Research Programmes (De Geest 1994;
Teijl and Holzhauer 1997). According to Lakatos, theories have a hard core
that is maintained, even if some elements have been falsified. A layer of
additional hypotheses, ceteris paribus clauses and empirical observations
protects this hard core. In practice, several research programs compete with
each other. A research program is regarded as progressive if it yields new
and correct predictions. A theory is only regarded to be falsified when it is
replaced by a new and better theory.
De Geest (1994) has developed a theory that does not stress the
importance of the truth of a theory but its plausibility, defined as the
probability that its statements about the reality are true. For the plausibility
of a theory not only empirical confirmations are relevant, but also the
accordance of its statements with self-observation and life experience of the
specialists that give a judgement of the theory. The latter is important for
law and economics because empirical confirmations in the form of
observable data are still limited in number. The same line of reasoning is
followed by Coase (1994) in his effort to reconcile the main works of Adam
Smith, namely The Theory of Moral Sentiments and The Wealth of Nations.
If the complicated theory of motivation as developed in The Theory of Moral
Sentiments is used as the starting point of an economic analysis the
conclusions from The Wealth of Nations still hold, but are made more
plausible. In this respect the problem with the use of unrealistic assumptions
as defended by Friedman is that they do not contribute to the plausibility of a
theory.
Ronald Coase (1994) further argues that even if predictions on the basis
of unrealistic assumptions are correct, a theory based upon them may fail in
providing insight in the working of the economic (or legal) system. An
important factor in judging the importance of realism of assumptions is the
goal one is aiming for. If it is only prediction and control, the use of
unrealistic assumptions is fine, as long as they indeed predict well. If,
however, the goal is explanation, an approach based on unrealistic
assumptions is not really helpful in providing insight in what really moves a
person and in how legal rules really have effects. There is an additional need
for a mechanism that shows how something could have happened. Not
only the predictions, but also the beauty, elegance and internal consistency
of an economic model determine its value for the analysis of law. Therefore,
the life of law and economics is not just experience; it is logic as well.
0400 Methodology: General 395
Adams, Michael (1984), Ist die konomie eine imperialistische Wissenschaft? - ber Nutz und
Frommen der konomischen Analyse des Rechts (Is Economics an Imperialist Science? On the
Usefulness and Forms of Economic Analysis of Law), 7 JURA, 337-349.
Adelstein, Richard P. (1981a), The Plea Bargain in England and America: A Comparative
Institutional View, in Burrows, Paul and Veljanovski, Cento G. (eds), The Economic
Approach to Law, London, Butterworths, 226-252.
Adelstein, Richard P. (1981b), Institutional Function and Evolution in the Criminal Process, 76
Northwestern University Law Review, 1-99.
Adelstein, Richard P. and Peretz, Steven I. (1985), The Competition of Technologies in Markets
for Ideas: Copyright and Fair Use in Evolutionary Perspective, 5 International Review of Law
and Economics, 209-238.
Alpa, Guido (1996), Lo Snobismo degli Economisti e il Rifiuto del Dialogo con i Giuristi (a
Proposito dellIntroduzione alla Versione Italiana di Impresa, Mercato e Diritto di R.H.
Coase) (The Economists Snobbery and the Refusal of Dialogue with Lawyers), Economia e
Diritto del Terziario, 745-749.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (1996), Good Economics, Bad Economics, and European Economics,
Meteor Research Memorandum, Maastricht, No. RM/96/007.
Baird, Douglas G. (1997), The Future of Law and Economics: Looking Forward, 64 University of
Chicago Law Review, 1129-1165.
Becker, Gary S. (1976), The Economic Approach to Human Behavior, Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Becker, Gary S. (1991), A Treatise on the Family, Enlarged edition, Cambridge, MA, Harvard
University Press.
Becker, Gary S. (1996), Accounting for Tastes, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Brenner, Reuven (1980), Economics: An Imperialistic Science?, 9 Journal of Legal Studies, 184
ff.
Brietzke, Paul H. and Whitton, Linda S. (1996), An Old(er) Master Stands on the Shoulders of
Ageism to Stake Another Claim for Law and Economics (Book Review of Richard A. Posner,
Aging and Old Age), 31 Valparaiso University Law Review, 89-109.
Bruce, Christopher J. (1989), A Positive Analysis of Methodology in the Law and Economics
Literature, Hamline Law Review, 197-228.
Buchanan, James M. (1990), The Domain of Constitutional Economics, 1 Constitutional Political
Economy, 1-18.
Campbell, David (1994), Ayres versus Coase: An Attempt to Recover the Issue of Equality in Law
and Economics, 21 British Journal of Law and Society, 434-463.
Campbell, David (1996), On What is Valuable in Law and Economics, 8 Otago Law Review,
489-514.
Campbell, David (1997), The Relational Constitution of Contract and the Limits of Economics:
Kenneth Arrow on the Social Background of Markets, in Deakin, Simon and Michie, Jonathan
(eds), Contracts, Co-operation and Competition: Studies in Economics, Management and
Law, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 529-596.
396 Methodology: General 0400
Coase, Ronald H. (1988), The Firm, the Market, and the Law, Chicago, University of Chicago
Press.
Coase, Ronald H. (1994), Essays on Economics and Economists, Chicago, University of Chicago
Press.
Cooter, Robert (1998), Expressive Law and Economics, 27 Journal of Legal Studies, 585-608.
Cosentino, Fabrizio (1988), Autonomia Privata e Paternalismo del Legislatore nella Prospettiva
dellAnalisi Economica del Diritto (Individual Autonomy and the Paternalism of the Legislator:
An EAL Perspective), Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato, 473-511.
Cotter, Thomas F. (1996), Legal Pragmatism and the Law and Economics Movement, 84
Georgetown Law Journal, 2071-2141.
Couwenberg, S.W., Nagelkerke, J.J. and Slagter, Wiek J. (1980), Recht en Economie (Law and
Economics), Rotterdam.
De Geest, Gerrit (1994), Economische Analyse van het Contracten- en Quasi-Contractenrecht:
een Onderzoek naar de Wetenschappelijke Waarde van de Rechtseconomie (Economic
Analysis of Contract Law and Quasi Contract Law: A Study on the Scientic Value of Law and
Economics), Antwerpen, Maklu, 568 p.
De Geest, Gerrit (1996), The Debate on the Scientific Status on Law and Economics, 40
European Economic Review, 999-1006.
Duxbury, Neil (1995), Patterns of American Jurisprudence, Oxford, Clarendon.
Dworkin, Ronald M. (1980), Is Wealth a Value?, 9 Journal of Legal Studies, 191-226.
Ellickson, R.C. (1991), Order Without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes, Cambridge, MA,
Harvard University Press.
Elster, Jon (1979), Sour Grapes, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Elster, Jon (1989), The Cement of Society. A Study of Social Order, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press.
Elster, Jon (1997), More Than Enough. Review of G.S. Becker, Accounting for Tastes, 64
University of Chicago Law Review, 749-764.
Epstein, Richard A. (1997), Law and Economics: Its Glorious Past and Cloudy Future, 64
University of Chicago Law Review, 1167-1174.
Feichtinger, Gustav (1995), Crime and Punishment: A Dynamic Approach, 195
Forschungsbericht/Research Memorandum.
Feichtinger, G., Forst, Ch.V. and Piccardi, C. (1993), A Nonlinear Dynamic Model for the
Dynastic Cycle, 165 Forschungsbericht/Research Memorandum.
Ferrarese, Maria Rosaria (1992), Diritto e Mercato: il Caso degli Stati Uniti (Law and Market: the
Case of the United States), Torino, Giappichelli.
Fezer, Karl-Heinz (1986), Aspekte einer Rechtskritik an der Economic Analysis of Law und am
Property Rights Approach (Critical Aspects of the Economic Analysis of Law and the Property
Rights Approach from a Lawyers Viewpoint), 41 Juristenzeitung, 817-824.
Fezer, Karl-Heinz (1988), Nochmals, Kritik an der konomischen Analyse des Rechts (More
Critics on Law and Economics), 43 Juristenzeitung, 223 ff.
Frech, H. Edward III (1995), European versus American Economics, Artificial Intellegence and
Scientific Content, 48 Kyklos, 219-226.
Friedman, David D. (1987), Law and Economics, in X (ed.), The New Palgrave: Invisible Hand,
London, Macmillan, 173-182.
0400 Methodology: General 397
Friedman, Milton (1953), The Methodology of Positive Economics, in X (ed.), Essays in Positive
Economics, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Gaakeer, Jeanne and Kerkmeester, Heico (1997), De Toenadering tussen Law and Economics en
Law and Literature. Liaisons Dangereuses of De Werking van Adam Smiths Onzichtbare
Hand? (The Rapproachement between Law and Economics and Law and Literature. Laisons
Dangereuses or Adam Smiths Invisible Hand), Deventer, Gouda Quint.
Gay, David E.R. (1981), Book Review of Moral Revolution and Economic Science: The Demise
of Laissez-Faire in Ninteenth Century British Political Economy, Ellen Frankel Paul, 48
Southern Economic Journal, 530-531.
Gay, David E.R. (1982), Book Review of The Role of Government in a Free Society, Phil
Gramm, 50 Southern Economic Journal, 916-917.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1974), E Provlematike ton Axiologikon Kriseon stis Koinonikes Epistemes
(The Problem of Normative Judgments in the Social Sciences), 4 Philosophica, 120-136.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1988), Methodologika Programmata sten Oikonomike kai te Nomike Episteme
kai to Provlema tes Diepistemonikes tous Synergasias (Methodological Programs in Economics
and Legal Science and the Problem of their Interdisciplinary Collaboration), 36 Nomiko Vema,
1192-1202, reprinted in Cyprus Law Review, 39, 4627-4643 (1990)
Gemtos, Petros A. (1990), Law and Economics: Methodological Problems in their Interdisciplinary
Cooperation, in Nicolacopoulos, Pantelis D. (ed.), Greek Studies in the Philosophy and
History of Science (Boston Studies in the Philosophy of Science, vol. 121), Dordrecht, Kluwer,
239-250.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1995), Oikonomika kai Dikaio: Oikonomika gia Nomikous, tomos:
Methodologika kai Oikonomika Themelia (Law and Economics: Economics for Lawyers, vol.
I: Methodological and Economic Foundations), Athens-Komotini, Ant. N. Sakkoulas
Publications.
Gragnani, A., Feichtinger, G. and Rinaldi, S. (1994), Dynamics of Drug Consumption: A
Theoretical Model, 94-77 Working Paper.
Gragnani, A., Rinaldi, S. and Feichtinger, G. (1995), Slow-Fast Limit Cycles in Controlled Drug
Markets, 185 Forschungsbericht/Research Memorandum.
Gridel, J.-P. (1994), Introduction au droit et au droit franais. Notions fondamentales.
Mthodologie. Synthses. (Introduction to the Law and the French Law. Fundamentals notions.
Methodology. Synthesis), Dalloz.
Grillo, Michele (1996), Lo Snobismo degli Economisti e il Rifiuto del Dialogo con i Giuristi. Una
Risposta a Guido Alpa (The Economists Snobbery and the Refusal of Dialogue with Lawyers.
A Reply to Guido Alpa), Economia e Diritto del Terziario, 751-754.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1997), Eisagoge sten Oikonomike Analyse tou Dikaiou (Introduction to the
Economic Analysis of Law), Aristotle University of Thessaloniki School of Law and
Economics, Department of History, Philosophy and Sociology of Law.
Hol, A.M. (1991), Rechten En Doeleinden. Enkele Morele Aspecten Van Juridische
Aansprakelijkheid (Rights and Goals. Some Moral Aspects of Legal Liability), in X (ed.),
Dilemmas van Aansprakelijkheid, Zwolle, Tjeenk Willink, 127-142.
398 Methodology: General 0400
Huerta De Soto, Jess (1982), Mtodo y Crisis en la Ciencia Econmica (Method and Crisis in
Economics), 74 Hacienda Pblica Espaola, 33-48.
Johnsen, D. Bruce (1986), Wealth is Value, 15 Journal of Legal Studies, 263-288.
Katz, Avery (1996a), Taking Private Ordering Seriously, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law
Review.
Katz, Avery (1996b), Positivism and the Separation of Law and Economics, 94 Michigan Law
Review.
Kelman, Mark G. (1987), A Guide to Critical Legal Studies, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1992), De Veronderstellingen in de Rechtseconomie: Wanneer Zij Bruikbaar
Zijn en Wanneer Niet, 21 Nederlands Tijdschrift voor Rechtsfilosofie en Rechtsrtheorie,
126-143.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1995), Game Theory as a Method in Law and Economics, in Bouckaert,
Boudewijn and De Geest, Gerrit (eds), Essays in Law and Economics II: Contract Law,
Regulation, and Reflections on Law and Economics, Antwerpen, Maklu, 267-285.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1996), Bespreking van R.P. Malloy en J. Evensky (red.), Adam Smith and the
Philosophy of Law and Economics en van R.H. Coase, Essays on Economics and Economists
(Book Reviews), 22 Recht en Kritiek, 290-296.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1997), De Retoriek van de Rechtseconomie (The Rhetorics of Law and
Economics), in Feteris, E.T. et al. (eds), Op Goede Gronden, Nijmegen, Ars Aequi Libri,
207-213.
Kitch, Edmund W. (1983), Intellectual Foundations of Law and Economics, 33(2) Journal of
Legal Education, 183-209.
Kitch, Edmund W. (1992), The Framing Hypothesis, in Newman, Peter, Milgate, Murray and
Eatwell, John (eds), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance, London,
MacMillan.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1984), The Great Image of Authority, 36 Stanford Law Review, 349 ff.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1986), Economic Analysis of Law, 16 Materiali per una Storia della
Cultura Giuridica, 233 ff.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1988), Economique (Analyse - du droit), in Arnaud, Andr-Jean (ed.),
Dictionnaire Encyclopedique de Theorie et de Sociologie du Droit, Librairie General de
Droit et de Jurisprudence.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1989), The New Economic Analysis of Law: Legal Rules as Incentives, in
Mercuro, Nicholas (ed.), Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1992), Analise Economica do Direito, 43(2) Sub Judica: Justica e
Sociedade.
Kronman, Anthony T. (1980), Wealth Maximization as a Normative Principle, 9 Journal of Legal
Studies, 227-242.
Lande, Robert H. (1989), Commentary: Implications of Professor Scherers Research for the Future
of Antitrust, 29 Washburn Law Journal, 256 ff.
Leff, Arthur A. (1974), Economic Analysis of Law: Some Realism About Nominalism, 60
Virginia Law Review, 78 ff.
Malloy, Robin Paul and Evensky, Jerry (eds) (1995), Adam Smith and the Philosophy of Law and
Economics, Dordrecht, Kluwer Academic Publishers.
0400 Methodology: General 399
Mercuro, Nicholas and Medema, Steven G. (1997), Economics and the Law. From Posner to
Post-Modernism, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Mercuro, Nicholas and Ryan, Timothy P. (1984), Law, Economics, and Public Policy, Greenwood,
JAI Press.
Migu, Jean-Luc (1977), Mthodologie conomique et conomie Non Marchande (Economic
Methodology and Non-Trading Economics), Revue dconomique Politique, 506 ff.
Monateri, Pier Giuseppe (1995), Risultati e Regole. (UnAnalisi Giuridica dellAnalisi Economica
del Diritto) (Rules and Outcomes. A Legal Analysis of the Economic Analysis of Law),
Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato, 605-619.
Nussbaum, Martha C. (1997), Flawed Foundations. The Philosophical Critique of (a Particular
Type of) Economics, 64 University of Chicago Law Review, 1197-1214.
Parisi, Francesco (1998), The Economic Structure of the Law (The Collected Papers of Richard A.
Posner: Volume I), Cheltenham and Lyme, Edward Elgar, 354 p.
Parisi, Francesco and Posner Richard A. (1997a), Law and Economics: An Introduction, in
Posner, Richard A. and Parisi, Francesco (ed.), Law and Economics, Cheltenham and Lyme,
Edward Elgar, Ashgate, 3-57.
Parisi, Francesco and Posner Richard A. (1997b), Scuole e Tendenze nella Analisi Economica del
Diritto, 15 Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato.
Parisi, Francesco and Posner Richard A. (1997c), International Library of Critical Writings in
Economics, Volume I: Theoretical and Methodological Foundations, Cheltenham and Lyme,
Edward Elgar.
Pastor, Santos (1984), Una Introduccin al Anlisis Econmico del Derecho (An Introduction to
Law and Economics), 89 Hacienda Pblica Espaola.
Pastor, Santos (1989), Derechos de Propiedad y Anlisis Econmico: Nuevas Luces a Viejas
Sombras? (Economics of Property Rights: Shading Lights?), 38 Economistas, 28-35.
Polinsky, A. Mitchell (1974), Economic Analysis as a Potentially Defective Product: A Buyers
Guide to Posners Economic Analysis of Law, 87 Harvard Law Review, 1655-1681.
Posner, Richard A. (1979), Utilitarianism, Economics, and Legal Theory, 8 Journal of Legal
Studies, 103-140.
Posner, Richard A. (1980), The Value of Wealth: A Comment on Dworkin and Kronman, 9
Journal of Legal Studies, 243-252.
Posner, Richard A. (1992), Economic Analysis of Law, 4th edn, Boston, Little Brown.
Posner, Richard A. (1993a), The New Institutional Economics Meets Law and Economics, 149
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 73-87.
Posner, Richard A. (1993b), Ronald Coase and Methodology, Journal of Economic Perspectives,
195-210.
Raes, Koen (1990), Het Recht van de Schaarste (The Law of Scarcity), 16 Recht en Kritiek,
380-394.
Reumer, Andrs (1996), Anlisis Econmico del Derecho (Economic Analysis of Law), Mexico,
Fondo de Cultura Econmica, Sociedad Mexicana de geografa y Estadstica, e Instituto
Technolgico Autnome de Mxico.
Rinaldi, S., Feichtinger, G. and Wirl, F. (1994), Corruption Dynamics in Democratic Systems,
168 Forschungsbericht/Research Memorandum.
400 Methodology: General 0400
Roemer, Andrs (1992), Importancia del Anlisis Econmico del Derecho, Mexico, SUMMA de
la Sociedad Mexicana de Geografa en Mxico y Estadstica.
Roemer, John E. (1996), Theories of Distributive Justice, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press.
Romani, Franco (1990), Diritto ed Economia: la Prospettiva di un Economista (Law and
Economics: the Perspective of an Economist), Sociologia del Diritto, 245-254.
Rowley, Charles K. (1981), Social Sciences and the Law: The Relevance of Economic Theories, 1
Oxford Journal of Legal Studies, 391-405.
Slagter, Wiek J. (1995), Grensoverschrijdingen en Grensgeschillen tussen de Economische en
Rechtswetenschap (Border-crossings and Border-differences Between Economic and Legal
Science), in Slagter, Wiek J. et al. (eds), Ondernemen Tussen Macht en Ordening: Opstellen
op het Grensvlak van Economie en Recht, Amsterdam, Thesis Publishers, 1-14.
Sousa Franco, Atnio (1992), Anlise Econmica do Direito: Exerccio Intelectual ou Fonte de
Ensinamento?, 2 Sub Judice, 63-70.
Stake, Jeffrey E. (1991), Status and Incentive Aspects of Judicial Decisions, 79 Georgetown Law
Journal, 1447-1497.
Stout, Lynn A. (1997), Irrational Expectations, (forthcoming) Journal of Legal Theory.
Sunstein, Cass R. (1997a), Free Markets and Social Justice, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Sunstein, Cass R. (1997b), Behavioral Analysis of Law, 64 University of Chicago Law Review,
1175-1195.
Teijl, Rob and Holzhauer, Rudi W. (1997), Wisselende Perspectieven in de Rechtseconomie
(Changing Perspectives in Law and Economics), Deventer, Gouda Quint.
Trebilcock, Michael J. (1983), The Prospects of Law and Economics: A Canadian Perspective,
33 Journal of Legal Education, 288-290.
Turnbull, Shann (1977), Impact of Mining Royalties on Aboriginal Communities in the Northern
Territory, First Report, Parliamentary Paper, Canberra, Australian Government Publishing
Service, No. 135/1978.
Turnbull, Shann (1978), Economic Development of Aboriginal Communities in the Northern
Territory Second Report, Self-sufficiency (with Land Rights), Parliamentary Paper, Canberra,
Australian Government Publishing Service, No. 438/1978.
Turnbull, Shann (1980), Economic Development of Aboriginal Communities in the Northern
Territory: A Study in two parts, Department of Aboriginal Affairs, Canberra, Australian
Government Publishing Service.
Turnbull, Shann (1992), Economics and the Laws of Nature, in Marston, Alan (ed.), The Other
Economy: Economics Nature Can Live With, LBD Publishers, Auckland, 81-138.
Turnbull, Shann (1994), Stakeholder Democracy: Redesigning the Governance of Firms and
Bureaucracies, 23(3) Journal of Socio-Economics, 321-360.
Turnbull, Shann (1997), Stakeholder Governance: A Cybernetic and Property Rights Analysis,
5(1) Corporate Governance: An International Review, 11-23.
Weise, Peter (1991), Effizienz und Menschenwrde - Ein Gegensatz? Anmerkungen zu einer
Kontroverse zwischen Ott/Schfer und Fezer (Efficiency and Human Dignity - a Contradiction?
Remarks on a Controversy between Ott/Schfer and Fezer), in Ott, C. and Schfer, H.-B. (eds),
0400 Methodology: General 401
konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Beitrge zur konomischen Analyse des Rechts,
Heidelberg/New York, Springer, 18-34.
West, Robin (1988), Economic Man and Literary Woman: One Contrast, 39 Mercer Law Review,
867-878.
White, James Boyd (1987), The Language and Culture of Economics, 54 Tennessee Law Review,
161-202.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1991), Intellectual Foundations: The Need for a Broader View, 33
Journal of Legal Education, 210-216.
0500
SCHOOLS: GENERAL
Ejan Mackaay
Professor of Law
University of Montreal
Copyright 1999 Ejan Mackaay
Abstract
The concept of schools is used to summarise the ideas of thinkers who share
common premises on how and what to research, and to contrast them with
those of other schools. It is an expositional convenience and should be used
only when the differences touch fundamental matters of the field of research.
The differences between schools focus attention on questions to be resolved by
further research.
Within the current law and economics movement, besides the mainstream,
the institutionalists, the neoinstitutionalists and the Austrians constitute distinct
schools. Whether the New Haven School constitutes a distinct school is
debatable.
JEL classification: K00
Keywords: Law and Economics in General, Schools
1.1 Schools
A school of thought in scientific endeavour is a group of thinkers who adopt a
common approach, including shared theoretical premises, on how and what to
research in a particular field. The term is also used as shorthand for the ideas
those thinkers defend.
Originally the term school may have designated a major thinker, founder
of the school, and his or her disciples. In current usage the link to a common
intellectual leader is no longer essential. The members of a school of thought
may, but need not, themselves claim allegiance to the school. Members of a
school may consider that the adherence to a set of common precepts allows
them to build on each others work and so to attain economies of scale in
research not available if they worked in isolation.
402
0500 Schools: General 403
1.2 Movements
It is useful to consider a few related terms. Movement is a broader term than
school of thought. It designates a large grouping of people loosely sharing
404 Schools: General 0500
scientific or practical and, in particular, political aims. One could speak of the
law and economics movement, but scarcely of the law and economics school.
1.3 Paradigms
Since the 1960s, two new terms, paradigm and research programme, are used
to describe aspects of the evolution of scientific thinking (De Geest, 1995, p.
389 f.). Paradigm in normal usage is a very clear or typical example of
something. With respect to the evolution of the sciences, it acquired a different
meaning as a result of Thomas Kuhns book (Kuhn, 1970). The term research
programme is due to Lakatos, writing in reaction to Kuhn (Lakatos, 1970).
The puzzle Kuhn sought to explain is how science grows. The collapse of
the best-corroborated scientific theory of all times, Newtons mechanics and
gravitation theory, in favour of Einsteins ideas, had scattered the view of
scientific growth by accumulation of eternal truths (Lakatos, 1970, p. 92).
Popper had used this and like episodes to argue that the best way forward in
science is not so much by seeking confirmation of ones ideas through
observation, but by seeking ruthlessly to disprove them. The force of scientific
theories lies in the attempted refutations they have so far withstood.
Do scientists effectively proceed in this manner? Kuhns reading of the
history of science leads him to argue that they do not. During periods of what
Kuhn terms normal science, the practitioners of a scientific discipline let
themselves be guided by a shared fundamental theory and view of methods,
problem-field, and standard of solution (Kuhn, 1970, p. 103). These shared
ideas Kuhn termed the paradigm (Kuhn, 1970, p. 10). To attract a following
amongst scientists, the paradigm must account for observations and regularities
considered certain within the discipline, and for some new ones; it must also
be open-ended enough to set a range of new puzzles to be solved. During this
period of normal science, scientists are engaged in puzzle-solving and the
discipline advances without the paradigm being questioned (Kuhn, 1970, p.
10).
As research proceeds and empirical results accumulate, one finds
observations tending to support the theory, but also some which tend to
disconfirm it. If the latter concern puzzles at the periphery of the theory, one
attempts to refine it to yield predictions that better accord with observation. But
the contrary evidence may also concern more fundamental aspects of the theory.
Such observations do not immediately lead one to consider the current theory
refuted. Rather such instances are provisionally set aside as anomalies.
As the number of known anomalies grows, there comes a point when some
practitioners of the discipline no longer consider the current paradigm tenable
and start looking for a modified or improved one. As this sentiment spreads,
the discipline enters into a crisis: practitioners are no longer convinced that
their theory and associated research procedures are well-founded. An outsider
0500 Schools: General 405
may have the impression that research stagnates and that there are interminable
discussions about foundations and methodology.
As the crisis deepens the stage is set for a new paradigm to be proposed.
The acceptance of the new paradigm bring about what Kuhn calls a scientific
revolution. The fundamental advances in science are in his view the result of
such revolutions.
transition to maturity is not the presence of a paradigm but rather its nature.
Only after the change is normal puzzle-solving research possible. Many of the
attributes of a developed science which I have above associated with the
acquisition of a paradigm I would therefore now discuss as consequences of the
acquisition of the sort of paradigm that identifies challenging puzzles, supplies
clues to their solution, and guarantees that the truly clever practitioner will
succeed. (Kuhn, 1970, p. 179).
Blaug (1980) considers paradigms and research programmes for economics
at large. He concludes that a presentation in terms of competing and partly
overlapping research programmes is apposite and to be preferred to one in
terms of revolutions. He speaks nonetheless of the marginalist revolution in the
latter part of the nineteenth century and of the Keynesian Revolution in the
1930s. Wolin (1980) applies Kuhns ideas to political science, but adopts as the
criterion for the merit of a theory the extent to which it is acceptable to various
political actors. The approach allows him to demonstrate what he considers to
be a paradigm shift in his discipline. But it leaves the reader with the
uncomfortable question of what distinguishes a scientific paradigm from a
shared social or religious outlook, or even a mere fashion. Surely the distinction
must ultimately rest on the possibility to account for observations and to make
testable predictions.
Can these concepts of paradigms and research programmes be usefully
applied to law and economics? Several writers have recently considered this
question (Rubin, 1985; Veljanovski, 1985; De Geest, 1995, p. 389 f.; van den
Hauwe, 1996; Teijl and Holzhauer, 1997, p. 7 f.; Ellickson, 1998; Posner,
1998). If the answer is affirmative, further questions concern the scope of the
paradigm or research programme and the grounds for preferring one paradigm
or research programme to another.
In the piece on the History of Law and Economics (0200) the term
paradigm was loosely used in describing different periods of the latest wave
of law and economics. The 1950s, 1960s and 1970s might be described, loosely
again, as periods of normal science: the research agenda seemed clear and
researchers spent their time solving puzzles indicated by the paradigm. The
1980s brought debates about various foundational questions. Since then several
competing schools present themselves in the law and economics literature. In
Kuhns terms, that could indicate attempts to establish a first scientific
paradigm or a crisis in the existing paradigm.
To accept the latter hypothesis, one would have to be able to point to a set
of unquestionable scientific accomplishments and to anomalies giving rise to
the crisis. Ellickson (1998, p. 551) professes to see the latter in the blindness
of the classical law and economics to social norms (which, in his view,
would give an entirely different twist to the problem situations envisaged in the
Coase theorem). Posner (1998, p. 565) sees no crisis but merely new puzzles
to be solved within the existing research programme, the core of which, in his
0500 Schools: General 407
view, is the rational choice theory. A paradigm shift occurs when a theory no
longer furnishes acceptable answers to the questions that trouble current
researchers, not when it is modified or enriched to cope with new questions or
questions previously beyond the grasp of the theory (Posner, 1998, p. 564).
The question of the criteria to be used for choosing amongst competing
theories or research programmes is debated in Rubin (1985); Veljanovski
(1985); De Geest (1995, pp. 389 f.); van den Hauwe (1996); Teijl and
Holzhauer (1997, pp. 7 f.); Posner (1998). Posner (1998, p. 555) recalls
Friedmans prediction test in writing that a theory that does not generate
predictions is difficult to feel comfortable with. De Geest, after a lengthy
discussion of the issue, proposes what he terms a plausibility theory (1995, pp.
407 f.), which is criticised by van den Hauwe (1996). In De Geests view, the
mainstream approach to law and economics is sufficiently open-ended to
absorb, by way of puzzles to be solved, the ideas which are now put forward by
competing schools. This view appears close to Posners (1998).
Teijl and Holzhauer (1997) undertake a comparison of what the Chicago
school and the Austrian School have to contribute to law and economics. The
Austrian School considers that the optima on which much Chicago law and
economics relies are indeterminable. The approaches appear to be radically
incompatible and this obliges the authors squarely to face the question of the
criteria for choosing between rival approaches. The difficulty is to avoid
judging the performance of one approach in terms set by the other. Teijl and
Holzhauer opt for the framework of research programmes put forth by Lakatos
and propose to examine what each approach has to say on a range of practical
legal puzzles within the fields of contracts, tort liability and litigation. In each
case, they seek answers to three questions: what are the effects of legal rules
can be explained? To what extent do they contribute to societys welfare? How
can the emergence and contents of legal rules be explained? (Teijl and
Holzhauer, 1997, p. 35). At the end of their study, Austrian economics is
presented as perhaps more like the armchair economics than its practitioners
would like to admit. Nonetheless the authors profess, in conclusion, to be
unable to state a preference between these theories on objective grounds.
Ultimately the choice is a matter of acceptance within the scientific community
(Teijl and Holzhauer, 1997, p. 365).
Before examining the different schools within law and economics, it may
be helpful to summarise the common principles which set law and economics
approaches off against other intellectual currents such as Critical Legal Studies,
and feminism. As for the sociology of law, popular in Europe in particular as
a link between the social sciences and the law, there is debate about the extent
to which its practitioners share the premises set out below, in particular the
postulate of methodological individualism.
408 Schools: General 0500
All law and economics research is aimed at gaining new insights in the law by
applying economic concepts and theories. The underlying premises are those
of economics proper.
2.4 Equilibrium
A fourth premise concerns what happens in human interaction. Barring
disturbance, interactions are presumed to tend towards an equilibrium,
described in bare form by game theory and more elaborately by economic
theory dealing with markets, in which (implicit) price adjustments in the
process of competition tend to equalise supply and demand for a good or
service. Becker (1976, p. 5f.) considers the premise of market equilibrium to be
applicable to implicit markets in politics, marriage and other areas as much as
to markets in which transactions involving money take place.
Within a community as large as the law and economics movement, one must
expect differences of opinion about research matters. They may concern such
questions as whether particular anomalies should count as tolerable within the
existing theoretical framework, rather than as refutations calling for rejection
or revision of the theory, or what is admissible simplification of reality within
410 Schools: General 0500
enterprises in the former Yugoslavia, for example, one does not get far by
examining policies adopted by the owner of the capital goods, which is to say
the State or the bureaucrats nominally in charge of the enterprise (Furubotn and
Pejovich, 1974b, p. 250; Barzel, 1989, pp. 98-113). It is more instructive to
look at the preferences and decisions of the workers, who were in charge,
through the Workers Council, of the policy decisions for their firm. Focusing
on the workers, one can readily explain why such firms were loath to let
workers go in circumstances which would make such a decision seem logical
for a comparable Western firm: the workers making such decisions would cut
the branch on which they were sitting.
More puzzling is the question why the firms did not maximise worker
salaries, but instead retained some profit as savings for future investments. Why
would workers invest in capital goods they did not own? As Furubotn and
Pejovich explain, workers would find this to be in their interest in so far as it
maximised the present value of the future income stream paid to the average
employee. Their conclusion is that the behaviour of the Yugoslav firm is
explicable in terms of rational decisions by persons who actually control the use
of the resources in the firm. The heuristic Furubotn and Pejovich draw from
this insight is that to explain the behaviour of the firm, one must look at the
property-rights structure at all levels (Furubotn and Pejovich, 1974b, p. 251).
It is clear that the term property-rights structure is not used here in its
legal sense. Property rights, in this usage, mean decision authority (Libecap,
1989, p. 1), the actual power to control the use of a good and to appropriate the
fruits. Property rights in this economic sense are a descriptive term, more
general than right of ownership (Furubotn and Pejovich, 1974a, p. 4). When
one speaks of my office, my secretary or when a gang speaks of its territory
the possessive term is used in this sense.
The term property rights used in the property rights approach has
created confusion with the legal meaning of the term. Be that as it may, the
approach no longer seems to constitute a separate school. Its insights have been
absorbed into law and economics proper as Posner first unified it.
presented in the conclusion of the piece on the History of Law and Economics
(0200): the role of institutions, historical research, the place of uncertainty,
discovery and entrepreneurship, strategic behaviour and bounded rationality.
4. Conclusion
Backhaus, Juergen (1996), Franz Bhm issue, 3 European Journal of Law and Economics, 297-376.
Barzel, Yoram (1989), Economic Analysis of Property Rights, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press.
Becker, Gary S. (1976), The Economic Approach to Human Behavior, Chicago, The University of
Chicago Press.
Becker, Gary S. (1996), Accounting for Tastes, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Behrens, Peter (1984), Die konomischen Grundlagen des Rechts - Politische konomie als
Rationale Jurisprudenz (The Economic Foundations of Law - Political Economy as Rational
Jurisprudence), Tbingen, J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck).
414 Schools: General 0500
Behrens, Peter (1993), Legalism, Economism, and Professional Attitudes Toward Institutional Design -
Comment, 149 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 141-147.
Blaug, Mark (1980), Kuhn versus Lakatos, or Paradigms versus Research Programmes in the History
of Economics, in Gutting, Gary (ed.),Paradigms and Revolutions - Appraisals and Applications
of Thomas Kuhns Philosophy of Science, Notre Dame, University of Notre Dame Press, 137-159.
De Geest, Gerrit (1995), Economische Analyse van het Contracten- en Quasi-Contractenrecht - Een
Onderzoek naar de Wetenschappelijke Waarde van de Rechtseconomie (Economic Analysis of
Contract and Quasi-Contract Law - An Inquiry into the Scientific Merit of the Economic Analysis
of Law), Antwerpen, Maklu Uitgevers.
de Jasay, Anthony (1992), Rational Choice in Conflict, in Radnitzky, Gerard (ed.), Universal
Economics - Assessing the Achievements of the Economic Approach, New York, Paragon House,
327-338.
Demsetz, Harold (1997), The Economics of the Business Firm - Seven Critical Commentaries,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Duxbury, Neil (1995), Patterns of American Jurisprudence, Oxford, Clarendon Press.
Ellickson, Robert C. (1998), Law and Economics Discovers Norms, 27 Journal of Legal Studies,
537-552.
Friedman, Milton (1953), The Methodology of Positive Economics, in Friedman, Milton (ed.), Essays
in Positive Economics, Chicago, The University of Chicago Press, 1-43.
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Pejovich, Svetozar (1974a), The Economics of Property Rights, Cambridge,
MA, Ballinger Publishing Cy.
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Pejovich, Svetozar (1974b), Property Rights and the Behavior of the Firm in
a Socialist State: The Example of Yugoslavia, in Furubotn, Eirik G. and Pejovich, Svetozar (eds),
The Economics of Property Rights, Cambridge, MA, Ballinger Publishing Cy, 227-251.
Grossekettler, Heinz (1996), Franz Bhm as a Pioneering Champion of an Economic Theory of
Legislative Science, 3 European Journal of Law and Economics, 309-329.
Kuhn, Thomas S. (1970), The Structure of Stientific Revolutions, Chicago, The University of Chicago
Press (1962), 2nd edn.
Lakatos, Imre (1970), Falsification and the Methodology of Scientific Research Programmes, in
Lakatos, Imre and Musgrave, Alan (eds), Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press, 91-196.
Lenel, Hans Otto (1996), The Life and Work of Franz Bhm, 3 European Journal of Law and
Economics, 301-307.
Libecap, Gary D. (1989), Contracting for Property Rights (Political Economy of Institutions and
Decisions), Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Mercuro, Nicholas and Medema, Steven G. (1997), Economics and the Law: From Posner to
Post-Modernism, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Minda, Gary (1989), The Law and Economics and Critical Legal Studies Movements in American
Law, in Mercuro, Nicholas (ed.), Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers,
87-122.
Posner, Richard A. (1998), Social Norms, Social Meaning, and Economic Analysis of Law: A
Comment, 27 Journal of Legal Studies, 553-565.
0500 Schools: General 415
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1989), Law and Economics: Paradigm, Politics, or Philosophy, in Mercuro,
Nicholas (ed.), Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 233-258.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1992), Rethinking the Progressive Agenda: The Reform of the American
Regu!atory State, New York, Free Press.
Rubin, Paul H. (1985), Some Notes on Methodology in Law and Economics, 7 Research in Law and
Economics, 29-39.
Sowell, Thomas (1998), Conquests and Cultures - An International History, New York, Basic Books.
Streit, Manfred E. (1992), The Freiburg School of Law and Economics, 148 Journal of Institutional
and Theoretical Economics, 675-704.
Streit, Manfred E. (1994), The Freiburg School of Law and Economics, in Boettke, Peter J. (ed.), The
Elgar Companion to Austrian Economics, Hants, Cheltenham, Edward Edgar Publishing Co.,
508-515.
Teijl, Rob and Holzhauer, Rudi W. (1990), Pluriformiteit in de Rechtseconomie: een Verkening van
Scholen (Pluriformity in Law and Economics: An Exploration of the Schools), 39(10) Ars Aequi,
617-631.
Teijl, Rob and Holzhauer, Rudi W. (1997), Wisselende Perspectieven in de Rechtseconomie (Varying
Perspectives in Law and Economics), Arnhem, Gouda Quint.
van den Hauwe, Ludwig (1996), Book Review : Economic Methodology and theEconomic Analysis
of Law, Gerrit De Geest, MAKLU: Antwerpen-Apeldoorn, 1994',3 European Journal of Law and
Economics, 97-103.
Vanberg, Viktor (1998), Freiburg School of Law and Economics, in Newman, Peter (ed.), The New
Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, Vol. 2, London, Macmillan, 172-179.
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1985), The Role of Economics in the Common Law, 7 Research in Law and
Economics, 41-64.
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1990), The Economics of Law - An Introductory Text, London, Institute of
Economic Affairs.
Walker, David M.(1980), The Oxford Companion to Law, Oxford, Clarendon Press.
Wolin, Sheldon S. (1980), Paradigms and Political Theories, in Gutting, Gary (ed.), Paradigms and
Revolutions - Appraisals and Applications of Thomas Kuhns Philosophy of Science, Notre
Dame, University of Notre Dame Press, 160-191.
0510
AUSTRIAN SCHOOL
Copyright 1999 Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest
Adelstein, Richard P. (1992), Charles E. Lindblom, in Samuels, Warren J. (ed.), New Horizons in
Economic Thought: Appraisals of Leading Economists, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, 202-226.
Barry, Norman P. (1984), The Austrian Perspective, in Whynes, David K. (ed.), What Is
Political Economy? Eight Perspectives, New York, Blackwell, 33-58.
Benson, Bruce L. (1991), An Evolutionary Contractarian View of Primitive Law: The Institutions
and Incentives Arising Under Customary American Indian Law, 5 Review of Austrian
Economics, 65-89.
Benson, Bruce L. (1993), The Impetus for Recognizing Private Property and Adopting Ethical
Behavior in a Market Economy: Natural Law, Government Law, or Evolving Self-Interest, 6
Review of Austrian Economics, 43-80.
Benson, Bruce L. (1994), Legal Philosophy, in Boettke, Peter J. (ed.), The Elgar Companion to
Austrian Economics, London, Edward Elgar, 270-275.
Crafton, Steven M. and Brinig, Margaret F. (1994), Quantitative Methods for Lawyers, Durham,
NC, Carolina Academic Press.
Dnes, Anthony W. (1988), The Efficiency of Central Planning, 35(4) Scottish Journal of Political
Economy, 404-410.
Dnes, Anthony W. (1989), Rent Seeking, Entrepreneurship, Subjectivism and Property Rights: A
Comment, 144 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 891-893.
Garello, P. (1995), Prsentation dun Dbat Fondamental en Science Economique et ses
Implications pour les Rapports entre Droit et Economie (Presentation of Fundamental Debate
in Economics and its Implication in the Relationship between Law and Econnomics), R.R.J. ,
Presses Universitaires dAix-Marseille., 419 p.
Hayek, Friedrich A. von (1973), Law, Legislation, and Liberty, Chicago, University of Chicago
Press.
Huerta De Soto, Jess (1994), Gnesis, Esenca y Evolucin de la Escuela Austraca de Economa
(Genesis, Essence and Evolution of the Austrian School of Economics), in X (ed.), Estudios de
Economa Poltica, Madrid, Unin Editorial, 17-55.
Kan, Steven S. (1993), Entrepreneurship, Transaction Costs, and Subjectivist Economics, 1(2)
Journal of Enterprising Culture, 159-182.
Kan, Steven S. and Hwang, Chun-Sin (1996), A Form of Government Organization from the
Perspective of Transaction Cost Economics, 7 Constitutional Political Economy, 197-220.
Kirzner, Israel M. (ed.) (1986), Subjectivism, Intelligibility and Economic Understanding: Essays
in Honor of Ludwig M. Lachmann on His Eighteenth Birthday, London, Macmillan.
Krecke, E.l. (1996), Law and the Market Order - An Austrian Critique of Economic Analysis of
Law, 8 Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines, 19 ff.
Leoni, Bruno (1991), Freedom and the Law, Indianapolis, Liberty Fund.
416
0510 Austrian School 417
McGee, Robert W. and Greaves, Bettina Bien (1993), Mises: An Annotated Bibliography,
Foundation for Economic Education, 405 p.
Paqu, Karl-Heinz (1985), How Far is Vienna from Chicago? An Essay on the Methodology of
Two Schools of Dogmatic Liberalism, 38 Kyklos, 412-434.
Prychitko, David L. (1990), Methodological Individualism and the Austrian Shool, 1 Journal des
Economistes et des Etudes Humaines, 171 ff.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1993), Time, Uncertainty, and Subjectivism: Giving More Body to Law and
Economics, 13 International Review of Law and Economics, 61-84.
Schwartzstein, Linda A. (1992), Austrian Economics and the Current Debate between Critical
Legal Studies and Law and Economics, 20 Hofstra Law Review, 1105 ff.
Schwartzstein, Linda A. (1994), An Austrian Economic View of Legal Process, 55 Ohio State
Law Journal.
Teijl, Rob and Holzhauer, Rudi W. (1994), De Betekenis van de Oostenrijkse School voor de
Rechtseconomie (The Impact of the Austrian School on Law and Economics), Arnhem, Gouda
Quint.
Teijl, Rob and Holzhauer, Rudi W. (1995a), The Impact of the Austrian School on Law and
Economics, in Bouckaert, Boudewijn and De Geest, Gerrit (eds), Essays in Law and
Economics II: Contract Law, Regulation, and Reflections on Law and Economics,
Antwerpen, Maklu, 247-266.
Teijl, Rob and Holzhauer, Rudi W. (1995b), The Impact of the Austrian School of Law and
Economics, in Bouckaert, Boudewijn and De Geest, Gerrit (eds), Essays in Law and
Economics II: Contract Law, Regulation, and Reflections on Law and Economics,
Antwerpen, Maklu, 247-265.
Van den Hauwe, Ludwig (1998a), German Income Tax Policy Between Equity and Efficiency, 5
European Journal of Law and Economics, 267-279.
Van den Hauwe, Ludwig (1998b), Evolution and the Production of Rules - Some Preliminary
Remarks, 5 European Journal of Law and Economics, 81-117.
Wonnell, Christopher T. (1986), Contract Law and the Austrian School of Economics, 54
Fordham Law Review, 507-543.
0520
INSTITUTIONAL LAW AND ECONOMICS
Steven G. Medema
Associate Professor of Economics, University of Colorado at Denver
Nicholas Mercuro
College of Natural Sciences, Michigan State University
Warren J. Samuels
Professor of Economics, Michigan State University
Copyright 1999 Steven G. Medema, Nicholas Mercuro and Warren J. Samuels
Abstract
418
0520 Institutional Law and Economics 419
1. Introduction
A. Institutional Economics
2. Overview
Because institutional economics has always been concerned with legal facets
of the economy (that is the relationship between the law and the
development and performance of the economy), there is no clear dividing
line or simplistic transition between institutional economics and institutional
law and economics. Thus, an understanding of the nature of the analyses
and the concerns of the major contributors to institutional economics
concomitantly provides an understanding and appreciation of the scope and
content of present-day institutional law and economics. This and the next
section are intended to help make this transition.
Certain of Thorstein Veblens ideas described above were given further
development by Clarence E. Ayres. Ayres received his PhD in philosophy
from the University of Chicago in 1917 writing on the relationship between
ethics and economics. He started his teaching career at Amherst College
assisting the legal-economist, Walton H. Hamilton in his course, Social and
Economic Institutions. After brief sojourns at the University of Wisconsin
and New York University, in 1930, his former colleague, Hamilton, was
influential in urging Ayres to move to the University of Texas at Austin
where he influenced a generation of institutionalist scholars.
Ayress perspective on the economy is found in his treatise The Theory of
Economic Progress (Ayres, 1944). As described by Breit (1973), it is a
theoretical work that attempts to explain the forces that have shaped the
economy, focusing on those factors that accelerated the economys
development as well as those that have impeded it. For Ayres, the challenge
confronting economics is to devise new organizational forms, to
pragmatically develop organizational arts to match, rather than contradict,
our science and technology (Breit, 1973, pp. 255-256).
Ayres saw human activity as reflective of two basic and ever-present
forces: technological behavior, a productive and progressive force, and
ceremonial behavior (as manifested in, for example, hierarchies, mores,
culture and ideology), which is counterproductive and inhibits change,
acting as a curb on technological progress. The central theme of this work is
that an exponentially expanding and advancing technology (defined
broadly as all human activities involving the use of tools, and thus including
both human and physical capital) is responsible for the enormous changes in
the welfare of society. The focus is not so much on the individuals, but on
technological progress as related to the advancement of the tools (that is, the
objective instruments capable of being variously combined) and the role of
technology in enhancing economic progress. Since the ceremonial
426 Institutional Law and Economics 0520
As Spiegel (1971, pp. 628-629) has pointed out, there was a pronounced
linkage between Commons institutional economics and the German
historical school (due in part to his teacher Elys attachment to the German
school). The influence of the American pragmatic philosophers on his
thinking was much less significant, although its presence is evidenced in his
emphasis on the pragmatic importance of using inductive analysis. And
unlike Thorstein Veblen, who sought a near total rejection of orthodox
economic theory, Commons (as well as Wesley C. Mitchell) held a much
more conciliatory position seeing institutional economics as a complement
to, rather than a substitute for, neoclassical analysis.
Commons institutional economics was conceived as a broad synthesis of
law, economics and ethics; it recognized both conflicts of interest and their
mutual dependencies as well as the need for security of expectations and
order (Spiegel, 1971, p. 638). In contrast to the strict methodological
individualism and the harmony of interests paradigm that imbued orthodox
economics, Commons placed a greater emphasis on the role of collective and
corporate activities in the economy and centered his analysis on the conflicts
of interest inherent in a modern economy. Human action was seen to be
socially or culturally determined; that is, human action and cultural
determinants were seen to interact with each other. Consequently, the free
will of individuals contributes to the cultural environment and is, in turn,
molded by that environment (Buckingham, 1958, p. 104).
As characterized by Parsons (1957, p. 23), for Commons, the main task
of economics consisted of determining the reasonableness of the working
rules underlying the general economic order in an age in which citizens,
corporations, and labor unions have economic power (see also Parsons,
1985). Institutional economics for Commons was an economics of rights,
duties, liberties and exposures and he looked at the economy as a series of
intended and purposeful changes - so-called managed equilibria. He
believed that the primary economic institutions were formed on the basis of
definite patterns of socially sanctioned habits and could be reshaped. This
belief led him to probe extensively the impact of institutions, particularly the
operation of the legal system (including the judiciary, the legislature and the
regulatory commissions) in working out solutions to conflicts and the impact
of those solutions on economic structure and performance.
In Legal Foundations of Capitalism (Commons, 1924) Commonss chief
concern was with uncovering the development, evolution and workings of
the institutions that ultimately impact the performance of the economic
system. It was a theoretical work that examined the legal foundations of the
capitalist economic system. The treatise was unlike anything that had come
before and benefited from Commonss close contact with law through his
extensive aforementioned involvement with the courts, his service on
0520 Institutional Law and Economics 429
and on the wage bargain. Thus, in the West, a movement was engendered
from a feudal and agrarian society to a capitalist system, with economic
change driving legal change, which in turn facilitated the economic
transformations. (See Samuels (1996) for a Readers Guide to the Legal
Foundations of Capitalism.)
The isolated, colonial or frontier farmer might produce and consume things,
attentive only to their use value, but the modern farmer lives by producing
social-use-values and buying other social-use-values produced and sold by other
business men. In this way he also produces exchange-value, that is, assets. He
farms for sale, not for use and while he has the doubtful alternative of falling back
on his own natural resources if he cannot sell his products, yet his farm and crops
are valuable because they are business assets, that is, exchange-values, while his
liabilities are his debts and his taxes, all of them measured by his expectations and
realizations on the commodity markets and money markets, in terms of
exchange-value or price. (Commons, 1924, p. 21)
434 Institutional Law and Economics 0520
That is, what in part distinguishes capitalism from the colonial and
feudal systems it replaced is the transition from production for ones own
use to production for the use of others and acquisition for the use of self
(Commons, 1924, p. 21) and it was the adoption of this more expansive
definition of property that helped to facilitate this economic transition.
Following Commons, the contemporary institutional approach to law and
economics is evolutionary, emphasizing the importance of historical process
and evolutionary change of law through time. As described by Samuels
(1989a, p. 1578), the legal-economic nexus is a continuing, explorative and
emergent process through which are worked out ongoing solutions to legal
problems. The legal-economic nexus is that sphere of decision making that
reflects the working out of whose interests are to count as rights, whose
values are to dominate and who is to make these decisions. The resolution of
these issues determines not just rights, but the allocation and distribution of
resources in society and hence power, income and wealth. The structure of
legal-economic institutions - the state (whether in the context of the
legislature, the bureaucracy, or the judiciary), the firm and the market -
channels legal-economic decision making and this structure is seen as the
outcome of an evolutionary process of legal-economic change rather than as
movement to a steady-state equilibrium (Schmid, 1989, p. 66). Legal
change, while gradual, has been continuous and has led to major
transformations of the legal system and of the pattern of rights and, thereby,
of the system of economic organization and control (Samuels and Mercuro,
1979, p. 167). The pervasiveness of legal change and the ongoing process of
legal-economic reconstruction through the nexus process thus makes
necessary an evolutionary-historical approach that accounts for the array of
factors and forces promoting both continuity and change over time.
Illustrative examples of this type of analysis are provided by Field (1979,
1981, 1984, 1991) and Bromley (1989).
Field (1979, 1984) argues that a meaningful analysis and explanation of
rules structures that organize and regulate economic activity cannot be
accomplished by incorporating the rules into an endogenous neoclassical
model. Rather, he asserts, a thorough understanding of the determinants and
consequences of institutions and rules requires a case-by-case approach that
maintains particular sensitivities to the historical, cultural and legal facets of
the particular legal-economic institution being studied, including the norms
that influence legal-economic behavior. In an analysis critical both of
Chicago law and economics and of neoinstitutionalist law and economics
(particularly the works of Posner and North and Thomas), Field (1981)
asserted that some subset of institutional structures needs to be treated as
parametric in the general equilibrium models and granted an explanatory
status analogous to that traditionally accorded tastes, technology and
0520 Institutional Law and Economics 435
world each individual has scarcity relationships with others. While it may be
that part of life deals with movements from positions off of contract curves
to positions on contract curves in the process of exhausting gains from trade,
the institutionalist approach places strong emphasis on (1) who gets to play,
(2) where one starts in the game and (3) the rules governing the game.
Given the importance of human interdependence and the emphasis on
who plays and what are the starting points, the focus of institutional law and
economics is on conflict rather than harmony, where [t]he role of the legal
system, including both common and constitutional law, is to provide a
framework or a process for conflict resolution and the development of legal
rights (Samuels and Mercuro, 1979, p. 166). The fundamental problem here
is that of order, which Samuels (1972a, p. 584) defines as the reconciling of
freedom and control, or autonomy and coordination including hierarchy and
equality, with continuity and change. The ultimate meaning of the legal
and economic processes says Samuels (1971, p. 449), is in terms of their
functioning toward resolving the problem(s) of order. The existence of
conflicting interests necessitates both a process (or processes) for deciding
between these competing interests and a method (or methods) for
determining how these conflicts are to be resolved.
At the micro level, the firm is seen as something more than a nexus of
contracts among isolated individual agents. It is a community designed in
part to suspend narrow, individualistic calculations of advantage and
facilitate the learning of standard objectives. This is more fully explored by
Hodgson (1988), Eisenberg (1990), Lazonick (1991) and Leibenstein (1987),
who focus not only on the social origins of individual preferences and goals
but on the complex processes by which individual utility functions are
constructed and revised and by which the meaning of profit maximization
is worked out by agents within the firm. Present within this and other
literature is a rich array of analyses of individual psychology, going beyond
the simplistic rationality assumption; of organizations, going beyond their
treatment as homogeneous, predetermined entities; of behavior in general,
going beyond the singular focus on isolated individuals to the institutional
and organizational environment in which they operate; and so on. Among
the sources of these analyses are modern Darwinian evolutionary theory,
cognitive psychology, organization theory and comparative economic
systems. Some of the analyses can appear to be either extensions of or
departures from neoclassical economic theory, while other analyses are
intended to be alternatives to mainstream economics. One result is the
showing that the unique determinate optimal equilibrium solutions of the
neoclassical research protocol are both presumptive and forced, heuristically
0520 Institutional Law and Economics 437
certain facets of the Chicago approach, Samuels (1981, pp. 148-149), for
one, has praised Posner for the usefulness of his analysis in once again
bringing to the attention of economists and legal scholars alike how
economic conditions affect the law and conversely. Nonetheless, one of the
hallmarks of the institutional approach to law and economics is the rejection
of the Chicago and general neoclassical emphasis on the determination of
the efficient resolution of legal disputes. The institutionalists do not reject
efficiency as an important variable in legal-economic analysis, but rather
maintain that efficiency alone cannot and should not, determine the
assignment of rights (Samuels, 1989a, p. 1563).
The starting point for the institutionalist critique of the efficiency
criterion is the recognition that economic activity - prices, costs, outputs,
risk, income, wealth, and so on - is not some sort of natural phenomenon,
but rather is determined by the structure of rights that exists in society, with
the levels of and changes in each of these variables being in part a function
of the legal structure and legal change over time (Samuels, 1971, p. 440,
1989a, p. 1565; and Schmid 1989, p. 67). Each particular rights structure
will give rise to a particular set of prices, costs, outputs, and so on and thus
to a particular efficient allocation of resources. Hence, there is no unique
efficient result. For the institutionalists, the purportedly positivist
Chicago-school rhetoric of atomistic industries or contestable markets
and the associated concept of price-taking behavior is exposed as nothing
more than deeply normative rights-taking behavior (Samuels and Mercuro,
1984). The institutionalists maintain that inasmuch as rights underlie
product prices and thus costs, to talk of price-takers bypasses virtually all
that is (or should be) important in Chicago law and economics and much of
public choice theory.
Because efficiency is a function of rights and not the other way around, it
is circular to maintain that efficiency alone can determine rights. Since
costs, prices, outputs, wealth and so on are derivative of a particular rights
structure, so too are cost minimization, value-of-output maximization and
wealth maximization. (For a detailed examination of the determination of
costs in this regard, see Samuels and Schmid, 1997.) Different specifications
of rights will lead to different (and economically noncomparable)
minimizing or maximizing valuations. The result is that an outcome that is
claimed to be efficient is efficient only with regard to the assumed initial
structure of rights (Schmid, 1989, pp. 68-69) the latter of which is often the
very matter at issue. Thus, as Samuels (1981, p. 154) asserts, [t]o argue that
wealth maximization [or any other efficiency criterion] can determine rights
serves only to mask a choice of which interests to protect as rights. Legal
decisions or changes can be said to be efficient only from the point of view
of the party whose interests are given effect through the identification and
assignment of rights.
0520 Institutional Law and Economics 441
governing the production of goods while at the same time selectively culling
out one subset of rights to make claims of wasteful, rent-seeking activity. It
is the proponents reliance on the model of competition that gives effect to
this selective perception. As is made clear in institutional law and
economics, models of the economy predicated on price-taking behavior are
in reality models of rights-taking behavior. Market prices are not absolute,
predetermined and independent of law, but, rather, are a partial function of
rights - the latter related directly to the governments ubiquitous role in
creating, defining, assigning, enforcing and altering rights. Moreover,
todays prevailing market prices of products and factors of production are all
predicated upon the past use of the state and past rent-seeking activities.
Market-generated product and factor prices that make up a firms
revenue-cost calculation are property-rights specific; as a consequence, so
too is its net revenue calculation a function of rights. The governments role
in the economy remains ubiquitous and, accordingly, a theory that purports
to identify rent-seeking behavior and the economic wastes therefrom is
question begging. There are no correct rights, prices, profits, or correct
structure of rents. Thus, rent-seeking theory is characterized as an artificial,
misguided normative theory that will mislead positive analysis and generate
artificial distinctions and thereby provide no real basis for distinguishing
between permissible and impermissible activities (Samuels and Mercuro,
1984, p. 67; see also Medema, 1991).
The driving force behind institutional law and economics is the need to
come to grips with the interrelations between legal and economic processes.
Samuels (1975, p. 72) identifies three efforts that are central to this process:
(1) models of legal-political and economic interaction must be developed;
(2) objective, positive, empirical studies of government as both a dependent
and independent variable and of economic activity as both an input and an
output of political-legal processes must be undertaken; and (3) efforts must
be made to wed both theoretical and empirical analyses toward a
self-consciously objective, positive comprehension of law and economics.
Such analysis will serve the twin purposes of deepening the understanding of
legal and economic processes and their interrelations and providing a more
sound basis upon which to predict the potential consequences of
legal-economic change.
The import of this becomes clear in the institutionalist assertion that the
essential normative element in political-legal-economic decision making
means that a choice must be made between alternative
444 Institutional Law and Economics 0520
viable approach to the study of the interrelations between law and economics
should be content with describing the full array of economic impacts
(including both the allocation and distribution of resources) of alternative
institutions and legal arrangements together with an articulation of whose
interests will be served and at whose expense (Mercuro, 1989b, p. 12). Such
analysis will not privilege one set of interests over others, but it will enable
those who study and participate in the processes of the legal-economic nexus
to better understand these processes and their resulting effects on law and
economy (Samuels, 1989a, p. 1578). Institutionalist-oriented case studies
include the works of Carter (1985), Schmid (1985), Seidman (1973) and
Wandschneider (1986). Carter (1985) criticizes the neoclassical
microeconomic explanation of institutional arrangements as at best partial
and at worst mystifying. Employing a Wisconsin institutionalist perspective
that recognizes both the relevance of economic power and the historical
context within which exchange occurs, Carter revisits Commonss analysis
of yellow dog labor contracts and analyzes the interlinked tenure-credit
contracts. Seidman (1973) contrasts the classical and anticlassical
perspectives on facilitative law and finds the latter, which recognizes the
asymmetric status and power of parties to a contract to be controlling, to
better describe what transpired in the colonial African economies of Kenya
and Ghana. Schmid (1985), writing on biotechnology-related property rights
issues in the agricultural sector, demonstrates that attempts to provide
exclusivity may inadvertently create added costs and affect the choice of
breeding method and agricultural technologies, was well as the division of
rents between inventors and the public. Wandschneider (1986) analyzes the
property rights institutions that allocate water in the northwest US He finds
that, as compared to the EPR (efficient property rights) model, an
institutionalist model that recognizes (1) that social norms may supersede
economic rationality and (2) that conflict over distributional issues may
block Pareto-better outcomes, is better able to explain the development of
rights to water in the US.
Of course normative judgments must be made in the process of reaching
legal decisions. Recognizing this, the institutional approach emphasizes the
need for openness and value clarification in the political-legal-economic
decision-making process, clearly a legacy of the legal realist movement
within the field of law (Samuels, 1989a, p. 1573). Economists, legal
scholars, policymakers and judges should strive to make the value premises
underlying their conclusions as explicit as possible, so that the choice
process can be effectuated carefully and overtly rather than carelessly and
446 Institutional Law and Economics 0520
covertly (Samuels, 1978, p. 113; 1989b). This call for openness is clearly
tied to the comparative institutional method:
Not only should normative premises be made explicit, but an array of studies
should be conducted on the basis of alternative normative (and factual)
assumptions. To do only one study is to give effect to only one perception and
specification of outputs, costs, benefits and rights. Alternative studies call
attention to the subtle intrusion of ideology and partisanship, emphasize the
necessary and inevitable critical choice of underlying values, highlight the
fundamental distributional consequences that depend on the political
determination of output definitions and so forth. (Samuels 1978, p. 112, emphasis
in original)
14. Summary
Acknowledgments
We wish to thank the Fritz Thyssen Foundation for its generous support and
the faculty and staff of the Erasmus Program in Law and Economics at the
University for Hamburg in providing Professor Mercuro a productive
environment in the time during which this project was completed. We are
indebted to A. Allan Schmid, the editors and two anonymous referees for
their insightful comments on earlier drafts of this material. The excellent
research assistance of Mary Therese Cogeos is also gratefully acknowledged.
Adams, Henry C. (1897), Economics and Jurisprudence, Reprinted in Dorfman, Joseph (ed.), Two
Essays By Henry Carter Adams: Relation of the State to Industrial Action and Economics
and Jurisprudence, New York, Augustus M. Kelley, 1969, 135-75.
450 Institutional Law and Economics 0520
Broder, Josef (1981), Citizen Participation in Michigan District Courts, in Samuels, Warren J. and
Schmid, A. Allan (eds) Law and Economics: An Institutional Perspective, Boston, Martinus
Nijhoff, 166-78.
Broder, Josef and Schmid, A. Allan (1983) Public Choice in Local Judicial Systems, 40 Public
Choice, 7-19.
Bromley, Daniel W. (1989), Economic Interests and Institutions, New York, Basil Blackwell.
Carter, Michael R. (1985), A Wisconsin Institutionalist Perspective on Microeconomic Theory of
Institutions: The Insufficiency of Pareto Efficiency, 19 Journal of Economic Issues, 797-813.
Commons, John R. (1924), Legal Foundations of Capitalism, New York, Macmillan. Reprinted,
Clifton, NJ, Augustus M. Kelley, 1974.
Commons, John R. (1925), Law and Economics, 34 Yale Law Journal, 371-82.
Commons, John R. (1934), Institutional Economics, New York, Macmillan.
Duxbury, Neil (1990), Robert Hale and the Economy of Legal Force, 53 The Modern Law
Review, 421-44.
Ely, Richard T. (1914), Property and Contract in Their Relation to the Distribution of Wealth, 2
vols, New York, Macmillan.
Field, Alexander J. (1979), On the Explanation of Rules Using Rational Choice Models, 13
Journal of Economic Issues, 49-72.
Field, Alexander J. (1981), The Problem with Neoclassical Institutional Economics, 18
Explorations in Economic History, 174-98.
Field, Alexander J. (1984), Microeconomics, Norms and Rationality, 32 Economic Development
and Cultural Change, 683-711.
Field, Alexander J. (1991), Do Legal Systems Matter?, 28 Explorations in Economic History,
1-35.
Griffin, Ronald (1991), The Welfare Analysis of Transaction Costs, Externalities and Institutional
Choice, 73 American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 601-14.
Griffin, Ronald (1995), On the Meaning of Economic Efficiency in Policy Analysis, 71 Land
Economics, 1-15.
Hale, Robert Lee (1924), Economic Theory and the Statesman, in Tugwell, Rexford G. (ed.), The
Trend of Economics, New York, Knopf.
Hale, Robert Lee (1927), Economics and the Law, in Ogburn, William F. and Goldenweiser,
Alexander A. (eds), The Social Sciences and Their Interrelations, Boston, Houghton Mifflin.
Hale, Robert Lee (1952), Freedom Through Law, New York, Columbia University Press.
Hamilton, Walton H. (1932), Property According to Locke, 41 Yale Law Journal, 864-80.
Kanal, Don (1985), Institutional Economics: Perspectives on Economy and Society, 19 Journal of
Economic Issues, 815-28.
Komesar, Neil K. (1981), In Search of a General Approach to Legal Analysis: A Comparative
Institutional Alternative, 79 Michigan Law Review, 1350-92.
Komesar, Neil K. (1994), Imperfect Alternatives: Choosing Institutions in Law, Economics and
Public Policy, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Lang, Mahlon G. (1980), Economic Efficiency and Policy Comparisons, 62 American Journal of
Agricultural Economics, 772-77.
0520 Institutional Law and Economics 451
Liebhafsky, H.H. (1987), Law and Economics from Different Perspectives, 21 Journal of
Economic Issues, 1809-36.
Llewellyn, Karl N. (1925), The Effect of Legal Institutions upon Economics, 15 American
Economic Review, 655-83.
Medema, Steven G. (1991), Another Look at the Problem of Rent Seeking, 25 Journal of
Economic Issues, 1049-65.
Medema, Steven G. (1994), Ronald H. Coase, London and New York, Macmillan and St Martins
Press.
Medema, Steven G. (1996a), Of Pangloss, Pigouvians and Pragmatism: Ronald Coase and Social
Cost Analysis, 18 Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 96-114.
Medema, Steven G. (1996b), Ronald Coase and American Institutionalism, 14 Research in the
History of Economic Thought and Methodology, 51-92.
Medema, Steven G. and Samuels, Warren J. (1997), Ronald Coase and Coasean Economics: Some
Questions, Conjectures and Implications, in Samuels, Warren J., Medema, Steven G. and
Schmid, A. Allan (eds), The Economy as a Process of Valuation, Aldershot, Edward Elgar.
Medema, Steven G. and Zerbe, Richard O., Jr. (1997), The Coase Theorem, in Bouckaert,
Boudewijn and De Geest, Gerrit (eds), Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, Aldershot,
Edward Elgar.
Mercuro, Nicholas (ed.) (1989a), Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Mercuro, Nicholas (1989b), Toward a Comparative Institutional Approach to the Study of Law
and Economics, in Mercuro, Nicholas (ed.), Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic
Publishers, 1-26.
Mercuro, Nicholas (1997), Ecology, Law and Economics, Lanham, University Press of America.
Mercuro, Nicholas and Medema, Steven G. (1995), Schools of Thought in Law and Economics: A
Kuhnian Competition, in Malloy, Robin Paul and Braun, Christopher K. (eds), Law and
Economics: New and Critical Perspectives, New York, Peter Lang, 65-126.
Mercuro, Nicholas and Medema, Steven G. (1997), Economics and the Law: From Posner to
Post-Modernism, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Mercuro, Nicholas and Ryan, Timothy P. (1980), Property Rights and Welfare Economics: Miller
et al. v. Schoene Revisited, 56 Land Economics, 202-12.
Mercuro, Nicholas and Ryan, Timothy P. (1984), Law, Economics and Public Policy, Greenwich,
CT, JAI Press.
Ostrom, Elinor (1986), A Method of Institutional Analysis, in Kaufman, Franz-Xarer (ed.),
Guidance, Control and Evaluation in the Public Sector, Berlin, Walter de Gruyter.
Rutherford, Malcolm (1994), Institutions in Economics: The Old and the New Institutionalism,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Samuels, Warren J. (1966), The Classical Theory of Economic Policy, Cleveland, World.
Samuels, Warren J. (1971), Interrelations Between Legal and Economic Processes, 14 Journal of
Law and Economics, 435-50.
Samuels, Warren J. (1972a), Ecosystem Policy and the Problem of Power, 2 Environmental
Affairs, 580-96.
452 Institutional Law and Economics 0520
Samuels, Warren J. (1972b), Welfare Economics, Power and Property, in Wunderlich, Gene and
Gibson, W.L., Jr. (eds), Perspectives of Property, University Park, PA, Institute for Research
on Land and Water Resources, Pennsylvania State University, 61-127.
Samuels, Warren J. (1973), The Economy as a System of Power and its Legal Bases: The Legal
Economics of Robert Lee Hale, 27 University of Miami Law Review, 261-371.
Samuels, Warren J. (1974), Commentary: An Economic Perspective on the Compensation
Problem, 21 Wayne Law Review, 113-34.
Samuels, Warren J. (1975), Approaches to Legal-Economic Policy and Related Problems of
Research, in Nagel, Stuart (ed.), Policy Studies and the Social Sciences, Lexington, MA,
Lexington Books, 65-73.
Samuels, Warren J. (ed.) (1976), The Chicago School of Political Economy, East Lansing,
Graduate School of Business, Michigan State University.
Samuels, Warren J. (1978), Normative Premises in Regulatory Theory, 1 Journal of Post
Keynesian Economics, 100-14.
Samuels, Warren J. (1981), Maximization of Wealth as Justice: An Essay on Posnerian Law and
Economics as Policy Analysis, 60 Texas Law Review, 147-72.
Samuels, Warren J. (ed.) (1988), Institutional Economics, 3 Vols, Aldershot, Edward Elgar
Publishing.
Samuels, Warren J. (1989a), The Legal-Economic Nexus, 57 George Washington Law Review,
1556-78.
Samuels, Warren J. (1989b), The Methodology of Economics and the Case for Policy Diffidence
and Restraint, 42 Review of Social Economy, 113-33.
Samuels, Warren J. (1992), Essays on the Economic Role of Government, 2 Vols, New York, New
York University Press.
Samuels, Warren J. (1993), Law and Economics: Some Early Journal Contributions, in Samuels,
Warren J., Biddle, Jeff and Patchak-Schuster, Thomas W. (eds), Economic Thought and
Discourse in the Twentieth Century, Aldershot, Edward Elgar Publishing, 217-85.
Samuels, Warren J. (1995), Reflections on the Intellectual Context and Significance of Thorstein
Veblen, 29 Journal of Economic Issues, 915-22.
Samuels, Warren J. (1996), Readers Guide to John R. Commons, Legal Foundations of
Capitalism, Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology, Archival
Supplement 5, 1-61.
Samuels, Warren J. and Mercuro, Nicholas (1979), The Role and Resolution of the Compensation
Principle in Society: Part One - The Role, 1 Research in Law and Economics, 157-94.
Samuels, Warren J. and Mercuro, Nicholas (1980), The Role and Resolution of the Compensation
Principle in Society: Part Two - The Resolution, 2 Research in Law and Economics, 103-28.
Samuels, Warren J. and Mercuro, Nicholas (1984), A Critique of Rent-Seeking Theory, in
Colander, David C. (ed.), Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and
DUP Activities, Cambridge, MA, Ballinger Publishing, 55-70.
Samuels, Warren J. and Schmid, A. Allan (eds) (1981), Law and Economics: An Institutional
Perspective, Boston, Martinus-Nijhoff Publishing, 268 p.
0520 Institutional Law and Economics 453
Samuels, Warren J. and Schmid, A. Allan (1997), The Concept of Cost in Economics, in Samuels,
Warren J., Medema, Steven G. and Schmid, A. Allan, The Economy as a Process of
Valuation, Aldershot, Edward Elgar Publishing.
Schmid, A. Allan (1985), Biotechnology, Plant Variety Protection and Changing Property
Institutions in Agriculture, 7 North Central Journal of Agricultural Economics, 129-38.
Schmid, A. Allan (1987), Property, Power and Public Choice: An Inquiry into Law and
Economics, 2nd edn, New York, Praeger.
Schmid, A. Allan (1989), Law and Economics: An Institutional Perspective, in Mercuro, Nicholas
(ed.), Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 57-85.
Schmid, A. Allan (1994), Institutional Law and Economics, 1 European Journal of Law and
Economics, 33-51.
Seidman, Robert (1973), Contract Law, the Free Market and State Intervention: A Jurisprudential
Perspective, 7 Journal of Economic Issues, 553-76.
Shepsle, Kenneth A. and Weingast, Barry (1984), Political Solutions to Market Problems, 78
American Political Science Review, 417-34.
Solo, Robert A. (1974), The Political Authority and the Market System, Cincinnati,
South-Western.
Trebing, Harry M. (ed.) (1976), New Dimensions in Public Utility Pricing, East Lansing, Institute
of Public Utilities, Michigan State University.
Trebing, Harry M. (1989), Telecommunications Regulation - The Continuing Dilemma, in
Nowotym, K., Smith, D.B. and Trebing, H.M. (eds), Public Utility Regulation, Boston, Kluwer
Academic Publishers, 120-22.
Trebing, Harry M. and Estabrooks, Maurice (1993), Telecommunications Policy in the Global
Information Economy of the Nineties, in Stevinson, Rodney, Oum, T.H. and Oniki, H. (eds),
International Perspectives on Telecommunications Policy, Greenwich, CT, JAI Press, 17-37.
Wandschneider, Philip (1984), Managing River Systems: Centralization versus Decentralization,
24 Natural Resources Journal, 1043-66.
Wandschneider, Philip (1986), Neoclassical and Institutionalist Explanations of Changes in
Northwest Water Institutions, 20 Journal of Economic Issues, 87-107.
Other References
Ackerman, Bruce A. and Stewart, Richard B. (1988), Reforming Environmental Law: The
Democratic Case for Market Incentives, 13 Columbia Journal of Environmental Law,
171-99.
Ayres, Clarence E. (1944), The Theory of Economic Progress, Chapel Hill, University of North
Carolina Press.
Baumol, William J. and Oates, Wallace E. (1988), The Theory of Environmental Policy (2nd edn),
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Bell, John F. (1967), Institutional Economics, in A History of Economic Thought, New York,
Ronald Press, 539-71.
Breit, William (1973), The Development of Clarence Ayress Theoretical Institutionalism, 54
Social Science Quarterly, 244-57.
454 Institutional Law and Economics 0520
Buchanan, James M., Tollison, Robert and Tullock, Gordon (1980), Toward a Theory of the
Rent-Seeking Society, College Station, Texas A&M University Press.
Buckingham, Walter S. (1958), Theoretical Economic Systems: A Comparative Analysis, New
York, Ronald Press Company, 89-124.
Calabresi, Guido (1985), Ideals, Beliefs, Attitudes and the Law: Private Law Perspectives on a
Public Law Problem, Syracuse, NY, Syracuse University Press.
Calabresi, Guido (1991), The Pointlessness of Pareto: Carrying Coase Further, 100 Yale Law
Journal, 1211-37.
Coase, Ronald H. (1960), The Problem of Social Cost, 3 Journal of Law and Economics, 1-44.
Cotterrell, Roger (1989), The Politics of Jurisprudence, London, Butterworths.
Demsetz, Harold (1969), Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint, 12 Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-22.
Dorfman, Joseph (1959), The Economic Mind in American Civilization, Volumes IV and V:
1918-1933, New York, The Viking Press. Reprinted by Augustus M. Kelley Publishers, 1969.
Duxbury, Neil (1995), Patterns of American Jurisprudence, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Eisenberg, Melvin A. (1990), An Overview of Law and Economics, Working Paper No. 90-9,
School of Law, University of California, Berkeley.
Frank, Jerome (1930), Law and the Modern Mind, New York, Brentanos.
Gordon, Robert A. (1964), Institutional Economics, Berkeley, University of California Press.
Hochman, Harold and Rodgers, J.D. (1969), Pareto-Optimal Redistributions, 59 American
Economic Review, 542-57.
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (1988), Economics and Institutions, Philadelphia, University of
Pennsylvania Press.
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (1994), Evolution, Theories of Economic, in Hodgson, Geoffrey M.,
Samuels, Warren J. and Tool, Mark R. (eds), The Elgar Companion to Institutional and
Evolutionary Economics, Aldershot, Edward Elgar Publishing, 218-24.
Hodgson, Geoffrey M., Samuels, Warren J. and Tool, Mark R. (eds) (1994), The Elgar Companion
to Institutional and Evolutionary Economics, Aldershot, Edward Elgar Publishing.
Kapp, K. William (1976), The Nature and Significance of Institutional Economics, 29 Kyklos,
209-32. Reprinted in Samuels, Warren J. (ed.) (1988), Institutional Economics, Vol. 1,
Aldershot, Edward Elgar Publishing.
Lazonick, William (1991), Business Organization and the Myth of the Market Economy,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Leibenstein, Harvey (1987), Inside the Firm, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Mishan, Ezra (1972), The Futility of Pareto-Efficiency in Policy Analysis, 62 American
Economic Review, 971-76.
Mitchell, Wesley C. (1914), Human Behaviour and Economics: A Survey of Recent Literature, 29
Quarterly Journal of Economics 29, 1-47.
Mitchell, Wesley C. (1928), Business Cycles: The Problem and its Setting, New York, National
Bureau of Economic Research.
0520 Institutional Law and Economics 455
Mitchell, Wesley C. (1937), The Backward Art of Spending Money and Other Essays, New York,
McGraw-Hill.
Parsons, Kenneth H. (1957), A New Look at Institutionalism, 47 American Economic Review,
21-26.
Parsons, Kenneth H. (1974), The Institutional Basis for an Agricultural Market Economy, 8
Journal of Economic Issues, 737-57.
Parsons, Kenneth H. (1985), Commons Relevance to Contemporary Economics, 19 Journal of
Economic Issues, 755-78.
Posner, Richard A. (1995), Overcoming Law, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Pound, Roscoe (1911a), The Scope and Purpose of Sociological Jurisprudence, Part I, 24
Harvard Law Review, 591-619.
Pound, Roscoe (1911b), The Scope and Purpose of Sociological Jurisprudence, Part II, 25
Harvard Law Review, 140-68.
Pound, Roscoe (1912), The Scope and Purpose of Sociological Jurisprudence, Part III, 25
Harvard Law Review, 489-516.
Pribram, Karl (1983), A History of Economic Reasoning, Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University
Press.
Solo, Robert A. (1967), Economic Organization and Social Systems, New York, Bobbs-Merrill.
Solo, Robert A. (1982), The Positive State, Cincinnati, South-Western.
Spiegel, Henry William (1971), The Growth of Economic Thought, Durham (NC), Duke
University Press.
Srivastava, Sik (1965), History of Economic Thought, Delhi, Atma Ram & Sons.
Stewart, Richard B. (1987), Crisis in Tort Law? The Institutional Perspective, 54 University of
Chicago Law Review, 184-99.
Stewart, Richard B. (1988), Controlling Environmental Risks Through Economic Incentives, 13
Columbia Journal of Environmental Law, 153-69.
Tool, Marc R. (1988), Evolutionary Economics, 2 Vols, Armonk, NY, M.E. Sharpe.
Tool, Marc R. (ed.) (1993), Institutional Economics: Theory, Method, Policy, Boston, Kluwer.
Veblen, Thorstein B. (1899), The Theory of the Leisure Class, New York, Macmillan.
Veblen, Thorstein B. (1904), The Theory of Business Enterprise, New York, Charles Scribners
Sons.
Veblen, Thorstein B. (1923), Absentee Ownership and Business Enterprise in Recent Times, New
York, B.W. Huebsch.
Whalen, Charles J. (1996), The Institutionalist Approach to Economics, in Foldvary, Fred (ed.),
Beyond Neoclassical Economics: Heterodox Approaches to Economic Theory, Aldershot:
Edward Elgar.
Cases
Allgeyer v. Louisiana
0530
NEW INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS
Peter G. Klein
Department of Economics, University of Georgia
Copyright 1999 Peter G. Klein
Abstract
1. Introduction
456
0530 New Institutional Economics 457
remember where the meeting was to take place. Furthermore, the friends cannot
contact each other to verify the location of the meeting; each must guess,
independently, a likely meeting place. What can they do? Obviously, this game
has multiple Nash equilibria: any outcome in which both friends choose the
same location - say, the corner of 34th Street and 5th Avenue - is a Nash
equilibrium to the game. According to Schelling, when faced with this kind of
problem, agents rely on cultural information outside the structure of the game.
Everyone simply knows, for example, that the logical place to meet in New
York City is beneath the clock in the main terminal of Grand Central Station.
This equilibrium is what Schelling called a focal point. Over time, he argued,
behavioral regularities develop so agents can solve these kinds of coordination
problems.
Ullman-Margalit (1977) calls these equilibria norms; Sugden (1986) calls
them conventions; Schotter (1981) calls them social institutions. In
Schotters (1981, p. 11) words, a social institution is a regularity in social
behavior that is agreed to by all members of society, specifies behavior in
specific recurrent situations and is either self-policed or policed by some
external authority. These regularities are presumed to arise over time as agents
interact repeatedly. Game theory itself, however, usually says little about how
a particular convention is chosen; it only identifies combinations of strategies
that are mutual best responses. More recently, some explicitly evolutionary
models (Witt, 1989; Wrnereyd, 1990; Boyer and Orlean, 1992) have tried to
explain the dynamic process by which particular equilibria are chosen. Axelrod
(1984) has shown experimentally that strategies of repeated cooperation tend
to be established relatively quickly.
Ellickson (1991) explains that social norms, as customary law, can be
superior to administrative or judicial dispute resolution among people with
close social ties. Ellickson studied disputes between cattle ranchers and farmers
in Shasta County, California and found that these disputes were usually
resolved by appeal to generally accepted social rules, not by bargaining over
legal rights (as the Coase Theorem would predict). [M]embers of a close-knit
group develop and maintain norms whose content serves to maximize the
aggregate welfare that members obtain in their workaday affairs with one
another (Ellickson, 1991, p. 167). That is, through repeated play, agents tend
to converge on strategies of cooperation that improve joint well being. These
strategies replace traditional legal remedies. Law solves the problem of
cooperation by altering the payoff structure in each game; relationships solve
the problem by repeating the game. In Shasta County, where both solutions are
available, relationships prevail over law (Cooter, 1993, p. 423). Informal
norms, in these cases, replace law.
Norms and law are not necessarily substitutes, however. Law can shape the
outcome of private bargaining by serving as a backup mechanism for resolving
disputes that cannot be resolved privately. If the alternative to private dispute
resolution is resolution in court, then the expected outcome at trial determines
the parties threat values in bargaining. Bargaining typically takes place in
0530 New Institutional Economics 461
the shadow of the law (Cooter, Marks and Mnookin, 1982). Moreover, norms
can help shape the law, if judges look to social norms as guidelines for legal
decisions. The traditional account of the medieval law merchant illustrates this
phenomenon. During the commercial revolution merchants developed a system
of private courts to resolve disputes among themselves. The rules of these
courts became general merchant practice, enforced by the threat of ostracism.
As the English legal system developed, judges began to hear commercial
disputes once handled privately. In resolving these disputes, English
common-law judges tended to enforce the merchant customs already in place.
In this way the common law came to embody the principles that already
existed, principles developed through private interaction among merchants.
(On the law merchant see Trakman, 1983 and Benson, 1989). Today, many
commercial disputes are resolved privately, through organizations such as the
VISA Arbitration Committee (Solove, 1986; Cooter, 1994).
These rules and customs that make up the institutional environment are
primarily economy-side phenomena. Another aspect of the new institutional
economics focuses on agreements made by specific individuals to govern their
own relationships. Such institutional arrangements - what Williamson (1996b,
p. 5) calls the institutions of governance - include contracts and organizations
and in particular, the business firm. The study of governance is more prosaic
than the study of the institutional environment. Mundane questions of whether
to make or buy a component to be used in the manufacture of an automobile or
whether to expand the hospital into outpatient and home health services are
ones that arise at the level of governance. By contrast, composite economic
growth and income distribution are more apt to be the objects of interest in an
inquiry into the institutional environment (Williamson, 1996b, p. 5). However,
the study of governance - in particular, the theory of the firm - is arguably more
developed than the study of the institutional environment.
Coase once described his 1937 paper on the firm as much cited and little
used (Coase, 1972, p. 56). Today, the theory of the firm is one of the
fastest-growing areas in applied microeconomics. For overviews of the modern
theory of the firm, see Holmstrm and Tirole (1989), Milgrom and Roberts
(1992), Radner (1992), Holmstrm and Milgrom (1994), Hart (1995) and
Buckley and Michie (1996). For critiques and alternative perspectives see
Langlois and Robertson (1995) and Foss (1997).
produced together. Yet this does not explain why the joint production must take
place in a single firm; absent transactional difficulties, two independent firms
could simply contract to share the same plant or facility and jointly produce the
efficient level of output (Teece, 1980, 1982). Whether the firms will integrate
thus depends on the cost of writing and enforcing contracts, not only on the
underlying productive technology.
The black-box model is really a theory about a plant or production process,
not a firm. Textbook treatments frequently blur the distinction between firm
and plant (for a welcome exception, see Sharkey, 1982, pp. 73-83), but the two
are quite distinct. A single firm can own and operate multiple production
processes, just as two or more firms can contract to operate jointly a single
production process (as in a research joint venture). For this reason, the
production-function approach cannot fully explain such real-world business
practices as vertical and lateral integration, acquisitions, geographic and
product-line diversification, franchising, long-term commercial contracting,
transfer pricing and joint ventures, nor is it an adequate guide for antitrust and
regulatory policy. Instead, the new institutional economics sees the firm as a set
of arrangements - as an organization - itself worthy of economic analysis.
the firms activities; it fails if managers cannot effectively coordinate and match
people and inputs to current technologies and markets. At the very top of the firm
are the relationships among the firms shareholders, its directors and its senior
managers. If those relationships are dysfunctional, the firm is more likely to
stumble.
The modern theory of the firm comprises several approaches. The moral-hazard
or agency-theoretic approach begins with Berle and Meanss (1932)
identification of the separation of ownership and control in the large firm.
The modern corporation, they claimed, is run not by owners (shareholders), but
by salaried managers, whose goals often differ from those of the owners.
Managers may use their discretion to shirk or otherwise pursue personal
objectives (firm growth, personal power, entrenchment, perquisites) at the
expense of shareholder value.
The Berle-Means account omits the possibility that competition might
impose discipline on shirking managers. Product-market competition,
competition in the internal market for managers (Fama, 1980) and competition
in the market for corporate control (Manne, 1965) all place limits on
managerial discretion. Still, their basic model of conflict between shareholders
and managers - what we would now call a principal-agent problem - remains
a powerful lens for viewing the internal organization of the firm. Agency
theory, as developed by Jensen and Meckling (1976), Fama (1980), Fama and
Jensen (1983) and Jensen (1986), has become the standard language of
corporate finance.
Agency theory studies the design of ex-ante incentive-compatible
mechanisms to reduce agency costs in the face of potential moral hazard
(malfeasance) by agents. Agency costs are defined by Jensen and Meckling
(1976, p. 308) as the sum of (1) the monitoring expenditures of the principal,
(2) the bonding expenditures by the agent and (3) the residual loss. The
residual loss represents the potential gains from trade not realized because
principals cannot provide perfect incentives for agents when the agents actions
are unobservable. In a typical agency model, a principal assigns an agent to do
some task (producing output, for instance), but has only an imperfect signal of
the agents performance (for example, effort). The agency problem resembles
the signal-extraction problem popularized in macroeconomics by Lucas (1972):
how much of the observable outcome (output) is due to the agents effort and
how much is due to factors beyond the agents control? The optimal incentive
contract balances the principals desire to give the agent incentives to increase
effort (for example, by basing compensation on the outcome) with the agents
466 New Institutional Economics 0530
desire to be insured from the fluctuations in compensation that come from these
factors beyond his control.
In the agency literature, the firm itself is not the subject of attention.
According to Alchian and Demsetz (1972) and Jensen and Meckling (1976),
the firm is simply a convenient label for the collection of contracts between
owners and managers, managers and employees and the firm and its customers
and suppliers. The firm is a nexus of a set of contracting relationships. ... The
firm is a legal fiction which serves as a focus for a complete process in which
the conflicting objectives of individuals ... are brought into equilibrium within
a framework of contractual relations (Jensen and Meckling, 1976, pp.
311-12).
The question of interest is thus the degree to which various contracts can
mitigate these conflicts; the boundary of the firm is a secondary issue.
Langlois, 1992a, 1992b; Teece et al., 1994; Argyres, 1996) further empirical
work is needed to develop the economics of firm capabilities.
The same criticism has been leveled at the theory of the firm more generally.
Simon (1991, p. 27), for example, has charged the new institutional economics
and transaction cost economics in particular, with lacking sufficient empirical
support. Until the relevant empirical studies have been done, he says, the new
institutional economics and related approaches are acts of faith, or perhaps of
piety. However, much empirical work has already been carried out. (Shelanski
and Klein, 1995, provide a comprehensive survey; Masten, 1996, collects many
of the important articles.) On balance, a remarkable amount of this empirical
work is consistent with TCE - much more so, perhaps, than is the case with
most of industrial organization (Joskow, 1991, p. 81). As Williamson (1996a,
p. 55) puts it: TCE is an empirical success story.
Much of the empirical research in TCE follows the same basic model. The
efficient form of organization for a given economic relationship - and,
therefore, the likelihood of observing a particular organizational form or
governance structure - is a function of certain properties of the underlying
transaction or transactions: asset specificity, uncertainty, complexity and
frequency. Organizational form is the dependent variable, while asset
specificity, uncertainty, complexity and frequency are independent variables.
Specifically, the probability of observing a more integrated governance
structure depends positively on the amount or value of the relationship-specific
assets involved and, for significant levels of asset specificity, on the degree of
uncertainty about the future of the relationship, on the complexity of the
transaction and on the frequency of trade.
Empirical work in TCE implicitly assumes that market forces work to cause
an efficient sort between transactions and governance structures, so that
exchange relationships observed in practice can be explained in terms of
transaction cost economizing. Williamson (1988, p. 174) acknowledges this,
while recognizing that the process of transaction cost economizing is not
automatic:
The [transaction cost] argument relies in a general, background way on the efficacy
of competition to perform a sort between more and less efficient modes and to shift
resources in favor of the former. This seems plausible, especially if the relevant
outcomes are those that appear over intervals of five and ten years rather than in the
very near term. This intuition would nevertheless benefit from a more fully
developed theory of the selection process. Transaction cost arguments are thus open
to some of the same objections that evolutionary economists [for example, Nelson
and Winter] have made of orthodoxy.
0530 New Institutional Economics 471
Vertical Integration
Vertical integration, or the make-or-buy decision, was the first topic studied
extensively within the TCE framework. Traditionally, economists viewed
vertical integration as an attempt to earn monopoly rents by gaining control of
input markets or distribution channels. But in the early 1980s a few authors
began to investigate transaction-cost (that is, efficiency) rationales for vertical
integration. Monteverde and Teece (1982) made one of the first systematic
efforts to test a contractual interpretation of vertical integration. They examined
the effects of asset specificity, defined as worker-specific knowledge or
applications engineering effort, on the decision to produce components
in-house or to obtain them from outside suppliers. They found applications
engineering effort to be a statistically significant determinant of backwards
integration. The results are consistent with case-study evidence from
Globerman (1980) on firm-specific technical knowledge and integration in the
Canadian telecommunications industry. Globerman studied evidence from
public hearings and found a tendency toward common ownership of telephone
lines and equipment as the research and development demands of a carrier on
its equipment suppliers become more complex and uncertain and require more
relationship-specific investments.
Other studies of component procurement have found similar support for
transactional explanations of vertical relationships. Two studies by Walker and
Weber (1984, 1987) focus on uncertainty as a determinant of vertical
integration in the auto industry. Like Monteverde and Teece, they worked with
a list of automobile components, coded as made or bought, as the dependent
variable. They found that greater uncertainty about production volume raises
the probability that a component is made in-house, but that technological
uncertainty, measured as the frequency of changes in product specification and
the probability of technological improvements, has little effect. Their second
(1987) study included measures of market competition, testing the interactive
effects of both uncertainty in production and competition among suppliers and
added the qualification that volume uncertainty matters only when supply
markets are thin.
In a further refinement, Masten, Meehan and Snyder (1989) distinguished
among types of specific assets, comparing the relative importance of
relationship-specific human and physical capital. They also studied automobile
component production, finding that engineering effort, as a proxy for human
asset specificity, appears to affect the integration decision more than physical
or site specificity. Klein (1988), in a discussion of the G.M.-Fisher Body case,
also suggests that specific human capital in the form of technical knowledge
was a major determinant of G.M.s decision to buy out Fisher.
The relationship between G.M. and Fisher Body in the 1920s is a frequently
discussed application of TCE. Both Klein, Crawford and Alchian (1978) and
Williamson (1985, pp. 114-15) explain G.M.s buyout of Fisher in terms of the
specific physical assets that accompanied the switch from wooden- to
0530 New Institutional Economics 473
DeCanio and Frech (1993) tried to measure more precisely the efficiency
gains from long-term contracts in natural gas. Relationship-specific
investments are critical for transactions between wellhead owners and
pipelines. For that reason, take-or-pay contracts, in which the buyer must pay
for some minimum quantity even if delivery is not taken, are often used to
safeguard against buyer (pipeline) opportunism. In 1987, the Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission (FERC) outlawed take-or-pay contracts. The authors
used data from before and after the FERC order to test its effect on spot gas
prices and prices at the wellhead. They found that FERCs interference with
parties ability to craft long-term governance mechanisms raised natural gas
prices between 21 percent and 31 percent in the year following FERCs order.
The results support TCE explanations for the relative efficiency of long-term
contracts where asset specificity is required, while representing an effort to
quantify that efficiency gain. (Mulherin, 1986, and Masten and Crocker, 1985,
also examine take-or-pay contracts.)
Another hybrid form of organization is a partial ownership agreement or
equity linkage. Pisano (1990) asks why firms may rely on equity linkages
instead of contracts to support certain transactions. He argues that partial
ownership will dominate contractual governance when a relationship involves
uncertainty, transaction-specific capital and other variables. He hypothesizes
that equity linkages are more likely when R&D is to be done during
collaboration and when collaboration encompasses multiple projects and less
likely when there are more potential collaborators. His study of collaborative
arrangements in the biotechnology industry supported all these claims. Pisano,
Russo and Teece (1988) applied a similar analysis to the telecommunications
equipment business and found that the same basic framework can explain the
choice between equity linkages and other forms of cooperative ventures (joint
ventures, consortiums, or other non-equity linkages).
Allen and Lueck (1993) studied cropshare contracts between farmers and
landowners. Such contracts specify sharing rules for both inputs and outputs;
in doing so, they pool enforcement costs by making both the farmer and the
landowner residual claimants. This reduces the farmers incentive to deplete
the capital value of the soil. Allen and Lueck show that optimal sharing rules
will involve either full payment of inputs by farmers or sharing input costs in
proportion to the output-sharing rule. Nee (1992) studied hybrid governance
structures in Chinas transitional economy such as small, family-owned firms
run by peasant entrepreneurs (cadre-entrepreneurs) and collectively owned
enterprises leased to private operators (marketized firms). On hybrids see also
Gallick (1984), Masten and Snyder (1993), Lafontaine and Masten (1995) and
Menard (1996).
Informal Agreements
Like other parts of the new institutional economics, TCE pays special attention
to the importance of private solutions to resolve disputes, in contrast to the
0530 New Institutional Economics 475
this action was abolished, a broken engagement could trigger a lawsuit, because
a woman in this situation faced considerable loss of reputation. Once the cause
of action was eliminated, however, another arrangement was needed to ensure
the credibility of the marriage commitment. Diamond engagement rings filled
that role. In this way, rings may be seen as a governance structure: They
safeguard the future brides relationship-specific investment - her good
reputation.
Franchise Contracting
Williamsons (1976) case study of the Oakland, California Cable TV (CATV)
franchise was an early empirical study using transactional reasoning.
Responding to the Posner-Demsetz argument that competitive bidding for
monopoly franchises would result in competitive prices, Williamson claimed
that once idiosyncratic investments are in place, what was a large-numbers
bargaining situation during the bidding process is transformed into a bilateral
monopoly. Because of this change, the terms of the original contract may no
longer be suitable. Williamson outlined the difficulties faced by Oakland in the
early 1970s over its CATV franchise. The franchise was awarded to the lowest
bidder in 1970. After the franchise was awarded, however, the construction
process went more slowly than expected, fewer households signed up than
predicted and costs escalated. Consequently, the franchisee requested a
renegotiation of the contract. A complex dual-source agreement was eventually
reached, but this outcome was far different from that specified in the initial
agreement.
Two later studies of CATV have looked for similar problems, with mixed
results. Zupan (1989) examined a series of public cable franchise agreements,
comparing the terms of trade struck during the original franchise agreement
with those prevailing at the time of renewal, after relationship-specific
investments had been made; he found no significant differences in those terms.
Prager (1990), however, found that opportunistic behavior by the franchisee,
as perceived by cable customers, was higher for franchises awarded through
competitive bidding.
Of course, it is not always the franchisee who is opportunistic; the
franchiser may be as well. Grandys (1989) examination of nineteenth-century
railroad regulation in New Jersey found that the railroads in that state were
willing to make large specialized investments only when they were protected
by special corporation charters limiting state action against them. Levy and
Spillers (1994) comparative study of telecommunications regulation in
Argentina, Chile, Jamaica, the Philippines and the UK shows that private
investment is forthcoming only when regulators can commit not to pursue
arbitrary administrative actions. Furthermore, many private franchise contracts
can also be explained through TCE (Norton, 1989; Dnes, 1992).
Besides these contractual phenomena, TCE has been brought to bear on
such diverse topics as labor market contracts and regulation (Barker and
Chapman, 1989), tie-ins and block booking (Kenney and Klein, 1983),
0530 New Institutional Economics 477
A more general concern is that most of the empirical studies discussed here
establish correlations, not causal relations, between asset specificity and
internal governance. These studies typically test a reduced-form model where
the probability of observing a more hierarchical form of governance increases
with the degree of relationship-specific investments. Plausibly, if the presence
of such investments reduces the costs of internal organization, then asset
specificity could lead to integration, independent of the holdup problem or
other maladaptation costs (Masten, 1994, p. 10). Masten, Meehan and Snyder
(1991) attempt to distinguish these two effects in the context of human capital.
They find that specific human capital investments appear to reduce internal
governance costs more than they increase market governance costs. Further
studies of this type would be valuable in assessing the implications of the
evidence for the reduced-form version of the basic theory. However, we do not
yet have a general theory of how relationship-specific assets might reduce the
costs of internal organization. By contrast, the underinvestment problem
associated with specific assets and market governance is fairly well understood.
Theoretical and empirical research in the NIE has strong implications for
antitrust, regulation and other aspects of public policy. This is particularly true
for the studies of institutional arrangements discussed in the previous section.
A basic conclusion of transaction cost economics is that vertical mergers, even
when there are no obvious technological synergies, may enhance efficiency by
reducing governance costs. Hence Williamson (1985, p. 19) takes issue with
what he calls the inhospitality tradition in antitrust - namely, that firms
engaged in non-standard business practices like vertical integration, customer
and territorial restrictions, tie-ins, franchising, and so on, must be seeking
monopoly gains. In the ten years between the celebrated Schwinn (1967) and
GTE-Sylvania (1977) cases, Williamson argues, economists began to
incorporate transaction cost considerations into their understanding of vertical
restrictions. This change in the intellectual climate was reflected in the
Supreme Courts reversal in GTE-Sylvania of its earlier position that vertical
restraints are necessarily anticompetitive.
Joskow (1991, pp. 79-80) points out that this change may reflect sensitivity
to claims that vertical integration and restraints need not reduce competition,
rather than to claims that such arrangements provide contractual safeguards.
While the NIE argued that nonstandard business practices may reduce
transaction costs, Chicago-school writers like Posner, Peltzman and Bork were
maintaining that such practices do not necessarily result in reduced
competition. Of course, these arguments are largely complementary. Moreover,
the Chicago position on vertical restraints relies largely (though not explicitly)
on transaction-cost reasoning (Meese, 1997). In this sense, NIE has played an
0530 New Institutional Economics 479
9. Summary
Acknowledgements
clarifications. This paper draws on material in Shelanski and Klein (1995) and
Klein and Shelanski (1996).
Acheson, James A. (1985), The Maine Lobster Market: Between Market and Hierarchy, 1 Journal
of Law, Economics, and Organization, 385-398.
Acs, Zoltan J. and Gerlowski, Daniel A. (1996), Managerial Economics and Organization,
Englewood Cliffs, NJ, Prentice-Hall.
Alchian, Armen A. (1961), Some Economics of Property, Santa Monica, Rand Corporation.
Alchian, Armen A. and Demsetz, Harold (1972), Production, Information Costs, and Economic
Organization, 62 American Economic Review, 777-795.
Allen, Douglas W. and Lueck, Dean (1993), Transaction Costs and the Design of Cropshare
Contracts, 24 Rand Journal of Economics, 78-100.
Alston, Lee J. and Higgs, Robert (1982), Contractual Mix in Southern Agriculture since the Civil War:
Facts, Hypotheses, and Tests, 42 Journal of Economic History, 327-353.
Alston, Lee J., Datta, S. and Nugent, Jeffrey B. (1984), Tenancy Choice in a Competitive Framework
with Transaction Costs, 92 Journal of Political Economy, 1121-1133.
Argyres, Nicholas (1996), Evidence on the Role of Firm Capabilities in Vertical Integration
Decisions, 17 Strategic Management Journal, 129-150.
Armour, Henry O. and Teece, David J. (1980), Vertical Integration and Technological Innovation,
62 Review of Economics and Statistics, 470-474.
Axelrod, R. (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation, New York, Basic Books.
Bardhan, Pranab K. (1989), The New Institutional Economics and Development Theory: A Brief
Critical Assessment, 17(9) World Development, 1389-1395.
Barker, George R. and Chapman, Ralph B. (1989), Evaluating Labor Market Contracting and
Regulation: A Transaction Costs Perspective with Particular Reference to New Zealand, 145
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 317-342.
Barzel, Y. (1989), Economic Analysis of Property Rights, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Benson, Bruce L. (1989), The Spontaneous Evolution of Commercial Law, 55 Southern Economic
Journal, 644-661.
Benson, Bruce L. (1990), The Enterprise of Law: Justice Without the State, San Francisco, Pacific
Research Institute for Public Policy.
Benson, Bruce L. (1992), The Development of Criminal Law and its Enforcement: Public Interest or
Political Transfers?, 3 Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines, 79-108.
Benson, Bruce L. (1994), Are Public Goods Really Common Pools? Considerations of the Evolution
of Policing and Highways in England, 32 Economic Inquiry, 249-271.
Besanko, D., Dranove, D. and Shanley, Mark (1990), Economics of Strategy, New York, Wiley.
Boyer, Robert and Orlean, Andre (1992), How Do Conventions Evolve?, 2 Journal of Evolutionary
Economics, 165-177.
Brinig, Margaret F. (1990), Rings and Promises, 6 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization,
203-215.
Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon (1962), The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations
of Constitutional Democracy, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press.
0530 New Institutional Economics 481
Buckley, Peter J. and Michie, Jonathan (1996), Firms, Organizations, and Contracts: A Reader in
Industrial Organization, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Chandler, Alfred D., Jr (1992), Organizational Capabilities and the Economic History of the Industrial
Enterprise, 6 Journal of Economic Perspectives, 79-100.
Clark, Andy (1997), Economic Reason: The Interplay of Individual Learning and External Structure,
in Drobak, John N. and Nye, John V.C. (eds), The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics,
San Diego, Academic Press, 269-290.
Coase, Ronald H. (1937), The Nature of the Firm, in Coase, Ronald H. (ed.), The Firm, the Market,
and the Law, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 33-55.
Coase, Ronald H. (1964), The Regulated Industries: Discussion, 54 American Economic Review,
194-197.
Coase, Ronald H. (1972), Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research, in Coase, Ronald H.
(ed.), The Firm, the Market, and the Law, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 57-74.
Coase, Ronald H. (1974), The Lighthouse in Economics, in Coase, Ronald H. (ed.), The Firm, the
Market, and the Law, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 187-213.
Coase, Ronald H. (1984), The New Institutional Economics, 140 Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics, 229-232.
Coase, Ronald H. (1988), The Firm, the Market, and the Law, in Coase, Ronald H. (ed.), The Firm,
the Market, and the Law, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 1-31.
Coase, Ronald H. (1992), The Institutional Structure of Production, 82 American Economic Review,
713-719.
Cooter, Robert D. (1993), Against Legal Centralism, 81 California Law Review, 417-429.
Cooter, Robert D. (1994), Structural Adjudication and the New Law Merchant: A Model of
Decentralized Law, 14 International Review of Law and Economics, 215-231.
Cooter, Robert D., Marks, Stuart and Mnookin, Robert H. (1982), Bargaining in the Shadow of the
Law: A Testable Model of Strategic Behavior, 11 Journal of Legal Studies, 225-251.
Crocker, Keith J. and Masten, Scott E. (1988), Mitigating Contractual Hazards: Unilateral Options and
Contract Length, 19 Rand Journal of Economics, 327-343.
Crocker, Keith J. and Masten, Scott E. (1991), Pretia Ex Machina? Prices and Process in Long-Term
Contracts, 24 Journal of Law and Economics, 69-99.
Crocker, Keith J. and Reynolds, Kenneth J. (1993), The Efficiency of Incomplete Contracts: An
Empirical Analysis of Air Force Engine Procurement, 24 Rand Journal of Economics, 126-146.
Datta, Samar K., OHara, Donald J. and Nugent, Jeffrey B. (1986), Choice of Agricultural Tenancy
in the Presence of Transaction Costs, 62 Land Economics, 145-158.
Davis, Lance E. and North, Douglass C. (1971), Institutional Change and American Economic
Growth, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
De Alessi, Louis (1980), The Economics of Property Rights: A Review of the Evidence, Research in
Law and Economics, 1-47.
DeCanio, Stephen J. and Frech, H.E. III (1993), Vertical Contracts: A Natural Experiment in Natural
Gas Pipeline Regulation, 149 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 370-392.
Demsetz, H. (1967), Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 57 American Economic Review, 347-359.
Denzau, Arthur and North, Douglass C. (1994), Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions,
47 Kyklos, 3-31.
Dnes, Antony W. (1992), Unfair Contractual Practices and Hostages in Franchise Contracts, 148
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 484-504.
482 New Institutional Economics 0530
Drobak, John N. and Nye, John V.C. (1997), The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, San
Diego, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.
Eggertsson, Thrainn (1990), Economic Behavior and Institutions, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press.
Ellickson, R.C. (1989), A Hypothesis of Wealth-Maximizing Norms: Evidence from the Whaling
Industry, 5 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 83-97.
Ellickson, R.C. (1991), Order Without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes, Cambridge, MA,
Harvard University Press.
Enelow, James M. and Hinich, Melvin J. (1984), The Spatial Theory of Voting, New York, Cambridge
University Press.
Fama, Eugene F. (1980), Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm, 88 Journal of Political
Economy, 288-307.
Fama, Eugene F. and Jensen, Michael C. (1983), Separation of Ownership and Control, 26 Journal
of Law and Economics, 301-326.
Fishback, P.V. (1986), Did Coal Miners Owe Their Souls to the Company Store? Theory and
Evidence from the Early 1900s, 46 Journal of Economic History, 1011-1029.
Fishback, P.V. (1992), The Economics of Company Housing: Historical Perspectives from the Coal
Fields, 8 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 346-365.
Foss, Nicolai J. (1996), On the Relations Between Evolutionary and Contractual Theories of the
Firm, Department of Industrial Economics and Strategy, Copenhagen Business School.
Foss, Nicolai J. (1997), Resources, Firms, and Strategy: A Reader in the Resource-Based Approach,
Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Furubotn, Eirik and Pejovich, Svetozar (1972), Property Rights and Economic Theory: A Survey of
Recent Literature, 10 Journal of Economic Literature, 1137-1162.
Furubotn, Eirik and Pejovich, Svetozar (1974), The Economics of Property Rights, Cambridge, MA,
Ballinger.
Furubotn, Eirik and Richter, Rudolf (1991), The New Institutional Economics: An Assessment,
College Station, TX, Texas A&M University Press.
Furubotn, Eirik and Richter, Rudolf (1997), Institutions and Economic Theory: The Contribution of
the New Institutional Economics, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press.
Galanter, Marc (1981), Justice in Many Rooms: Courts, Private Ordering, and Indigenous Law, 19
Journal of Legal Pluralism, 1-47.
Gallick, Edward C. (1984), Exclusive Dealing and Vertical Integration: The Efficiency of Contracts
in the Tuna Industry, Washington, DC, Bureau of Economics, Federal Trade Commission.
Gatignon, Hubert and Anderson, Erin (1988), The Multinational Corporations Degree of Control over
Foreign Subsidiaries: An Empirical Test of a Transaction Cost Explanation, 4 Journal of Law,
Economics, and Organization, 305-336.
Gifford, Adam, Jr. (1993), The Economic Organization of 17th- through mid-19th-Century Whaling
and Shipping, 20 Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 137-150.
Globerman, S. (1980), Markets, Hierarchies, and Innovation, 14 Journal of Economic Issues,
977-998.
Globerman, S. and Schwindt, R. (1986), The Organization of Vertically Related Transactions in the
Canadian Forest Products Industries, 7 Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,
199-212.
Goldberg, Victor P. (1980), Relational Exchange: Economics and Complex Contracts, 23 American
Behavioral Scientist, 337-352. Reprinted in Putterman, Louis (ed.), The Economic Nature of the
Firm: A Reader, New York, Cambridge University Press, 1986.
0530 New Institutional Economics 483
Goldberg, Victor P. and Erickson, John R. (1987), Quantity and Price Adjustment in Long-Term
Contracts: A Case Study of Petroleum Coke, 30 Journal of Law and Economics, 369-398.
Grandy, Christopher (1989), Can Government be Trusted to Keep its Part of a Social Contract? New
Jersey and the Railroads, 1825-1888' 5 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 249-269.
Greif, Avner (1989), Reputation and Coalitions in Medieval Trade: Evidence on the Maghribi
Traders, 49 Journal of Economic History, 857-882.
Grossman, Sanford J. and Hart, Oliver D. (1986), The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of
Vertical and Lateral Integration, 94 Journal of Political Economy, 691-719.
Hallwood, Paul C. (1991), On Choosing Organizational Arrangements: The Example of Offshore Oil
Gathering, 38 Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 227-241.
Hart, Oliver D. (1995), Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure, Oxford, Oxford Clarendon Press.
Hart, Oliver D. and Moore, John (1990), Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm, 98 Journal of
Political Economy, 1119-1158.
Hayek, F.A. (1973), Law, Legislation, and Liberty, vol. 1, Rules and Order, Chicago, University of
Chicago Press.
Heide, J.B. and John, G. (1988), The Role of Dependence Balancing in Safeguarding
Transaction-Specific Assets, 52 Journal of Marketing, 20-35.
Helper, Susan, MacDuffie, John Paul and Sabel, Charles F. (1997), The Boundaries of the Firm as a
Design Problem, Mimeo, Columbia Law School.
Hennart, Jean-Franois (1988), Upstream Vertical Integration in the Aluminum and Tin Industries,
9 Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 281-299.
Hennart, Jean-Franois (1989), The Transaction Cost Rationale for Countertrade, 5 Journal of Law,
Economics, and Organization, 127-153.
Holmstrm, B. (1979), Moral Hazard and Observability, 10 Bell Journal of Economics, 74-91.
Holmstrm, B. and Milgrom, P. (1994), The Firm as an Incentive System, 84 American Economic
Review, 972-991.
Holmstrm, B. and Tirole, Jean (1989), The Theory of the Firm, in Schmalensee, Richard and Willig,
Robert (eds), Handbook of Industrial Organization, 61-133.
Hubbard, R. Glenn and Weiner, Robert J. (1991), Efficient Contracting and Market Power: Evidence
from the U.S. Natural Gas Industry, 34 Journal of Law and Economics, 25-67.
Jensen, Michael C. (1986), Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers, 76
American Economic Review, 323-329.
Jensen, Michael C. and Meckling, W. (1976), Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency
Costs, and Ownership Structure, 3 Journal of Financial Economics, 305-360.
Joskow, Paul L. (1985), Vertical Integration and Long-Term Contracts: The Case of Coal-Burning
Electric Generating Plants, 1 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 33-80.
Joskow, Paul L. (1987), Contract Duration and Relationship-Specific Investments: Empirical Evidence
from Coal Markets, 77 American Economic Review, 168-185.
Joskow, Paul L. (1988), Price Adjustment in Long-Term Contracts: The Case of Coal, 31 Journal
of Law and Economics, 47-83.
Joskow, Paul L. (1990), The Performance of Long-Term Contracts: Further Evidence from the Coal
Markets, 21 Rand Journal of Economics, 251-274.
Joskow, Paul L. (1991), The Role of Transaction Cost Economics in Antitrust and Public Utility
Regulatory Policies, 7 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 53-83.
484 New Institutional Economics 0530
Kenney, Roy W. and Klein, Benjamin (1983), The Economics of Block Booking, 26 Journal of Law
and Economics, 497-540.
Klein, Benjamin, Crawford, Robert A. and Alchian, Armen A. (1978), Vertical Integration,
Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process, 21 Journal of Law and
Economics, 297-326.
Klein, Benjamin (1988), Vertical Integration as Organized Ownership: The Fisher Body-General
Motors Relationship Revisited, 4 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 199-213.
Klein, Peter G. and Shelanski, Howard A. (1996), Transaction Cost Economics in Practice:
Applications and Evidence, 1 Journal of Market-Focused Management, 277-296.
Klein, Saul, Frazier, Gary L. and Roth, Victor J. (1990), A Transaction Cost Analysis Model of
Channel Integration in International Markets, 27 Journal of Marketing Research, 196-208.
Kogut, Bruce and Chang, Sea Jin (1991), Technological Capabilities and Japanese Foreign Direct
Investment in the United States, 73 Review of Economics and Statistics, 401-413.
Kreps, David M. (1990), A Course in Microeconomic Theory, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Lafontaine, F. and Masten, Scott E. (1995), Franchise Contracting, Organization, and Regulation:
Introduction, 2 Journal of Corporate Finance: Contracting, Governance and Organization,
1-7.
Langbein, John H. (1987), Comparative Civil Procedure and the Style of Complex Contracts, 35
American Journal of Comparative Law, 381-394.
Langlois, Richard N. (1992a), Capabilities and Vertical Disintegration in Process Technology: The
Case of Semiconductor Fabrication Equipment, Working Paper 92-10, Consortium on
Competitiveness and Cooperation.
Langlois, Richard N. (1992b), External Economies and Economic Progress: The Case of the
Microcomputer Industry, 66 Business History Review, 1-50.
Langlois, Richard N. and Robertson, Paul L. (1989), Explaining Vertical Integration: Lessons from
the American Automobile Industry, 49 Journal of Economic History, 361-375.
Langlois, Richard N. and Robertson, Paul L. (1995), Firms, Markets, and Economic Change: A
Dynamic Theory of Business Institutions, London, Routledge.
Levy, Brian and Spiller, Pablo T. (1994), The Institutional Foundations of Regulatory Commitment:
A Comparative Analysis of Telecommunications Regulation,10 Journal of Law, Economics, and
Organization, 201-246.
Levy, David (1985), The Transaction Cost Approach to Vertical Integration: An Empirical
Examination, 67 Review of Economics and Statistics, 438-445.
Lieberman, Marvin B. (1991), Determinants of Vertical Integration: An Empirical Test, 39 Journal
of Industrial Economics, 451-466.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr (1972), Expectations and the Neutrality of Money, 4 Journal of Economic
Theory, 103-124.
MacDonald, James M. (1985), Market Exchange or Vertical Integration: An Empirical Analysis, 67
Review of Economics and Statistics, 327-331.
MacMillan, Ian C., Hambrick, Donald C. and Pennings, Johannes M. (1986), Uncertainty Reduction
and the Threat of Supplier Retaliation: Two Views of the Backward Integration Decision, 7
Organization Studies, 263-278.
Masten, Scott E. (1984), The Organization of Production: Evidence from the Aerospace Industry, 27
Journal of Law and Economics, 403-417.
0530 New Institutional Economics 485
Palay, Thomas M. (1985), Avoiding Regulatory Constraints: Contracting Safeguards and the Role of
Informal Agreements, 1 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 155-176.
Parisi, Francesco (1999), Coase Theorem and Transaction Cost Economics in the Law,in J.G.
Backhaus, J.G. (ed.), Elgar Companion to Law and Economics, Ashgate, Edward Elgar.
Pejovich, Svetozar (1995), Economic Analysis of Institutions and Systems, Dordrecht, Kluwer.
Penrose, E.T. (1959), The Theory of the Growth of the Firm, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Pisano, Gary (1990), Using Equity Participation to Support Exchange: Evidence from the
Biotechnology Industry, 5 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 109-126.
Pisano, Gary, Russo, Michael V. and Teece, David J. (1988), Joint Ventures and Collaborative
Arrangements in the Telecommunications Equipment Industry, in Mowery, David (ed.),
International Collaborative Ventures in U.S. Manufacturing, Cambridge, MA, Ballinger, 23-70.
Poppo, Laura and Zenger, Todd (1997), Testing Alternative Theories of the Firm: Transaction Cost,
Knowledge-Based, and Measurement Explanations for Make-or-Buy Decisions in Information
Services, 19 Strategic Management Journal, 853-877.
Posner, Richard A. (1993), The New Institutional Economics Meets Law and Economics, 149
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 73-87.
Prager, Robin A. (1990), Firm Behavior in Franchise Monopoly Markets, 21 Rand Journal of
Economics, 211-225.
Radner, Roy (1992), Hierarchy: The Economics of Managing, 30 Journal of Economic Literature,
1382-1415.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1991), Indentured Prostitution in Imperial Japan: Credible Commitments in the
Commercial Sex Industry, 7 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 89-116.
Riker, William H. (1981), Implications from the Disequilibrium of Majority Rule for the Study of
Institutions, 74 American Political Science Review, 432-447.
Roumasset, James A. and Uy, Marilou (1980), Piece Rates, Time Rates, and Teams: Explaining
Patterns in the Employment Relation, 1 Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,
343-360.
Rubin, Paul H. (1990), Managing Business Transactions: Controlling the Cost of Coordinating,
Communicating, and Decision Making, New York, NY, Free Press.
Rumelt, Richard P. (1984), Towards a Strategic Theory of the Firm, in Lamb, Robert B. (ed.),
Competitive Strategic Management, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, Prentice-Hall, 566-570.
Schelling, Thomas C. (1960), The Strategy of Conflict, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Schotter, Andrew (1981), The Economic Theory of Social Institutions, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press.
Selgin, George and White, Lawrence H. (forthcoming), A Fiscal Theory of Governments Role in
Money, Economic Inquiry.
Sharkey, William W. (1982), The Theory of Natural Monopoly, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press.
Shelanski, Howard A. and Klein, Peter G. (1995), Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Economics:
A Review and Assessment, 11 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 335-361.
Silverman, Brian S., Nickerson, Jack A. and Freeman, John (1997), Profitability, Transactional
Alignment, and Organizational Mortality in the U.S. Trucking Industry, 18 Strategic
Management Journal, 31-52.
0530 New Institutional Economics 487
Simon, Herbert A. (1991), Organizations and Markets, 5 Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25-44.
Spiller, Pablo T. (1985), On Vertical Mergers, 1 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization,
285-312.
Spulber, Daniel F. (1989), Regulation and Markets, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.
Stuckey, John (1983), Vertical Integration and Joint Ventures in the Aluminum Industry, Cambridge,
MA, Harvard University Press.
Sugden, Robert (1986), The Economics of Rights, Cooperation, and Welfare, Oxford, Basil
Blackwell.
Teece, David J. (1980), Economies of Scope and the Scope of the Enterprise, 1 Journal of Economic
Behavior and Organization, 223-247.
Teece, David J. (1982), Towards an Economic Theory of the Multi-Product Firm, 3 Journal of
Economic Behavior and Organization, 39-64.
Teece, David J., Dosi, Giovanni, Rumelt, Richard P. and Winter, Sidney G. (1994), Understanding
Corporate Coherence: Theory and Evidence, 23 Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization, 1-30.
Trakman, Leon E. (1983), The Law Merchant: The Evolution of Commercial Law, Littleton, CO,
Rothman.
Ullman-Margalit, Edna (1977), The Emergence of Norms, Oxford, Oxford Clarendon Press.
Walker, Gordon and Weber, David (1984), A Transaction Cost Approach to Make-or-Buy Decisions,
29 Administrative Science Quarterly, 373-391.
Walker, Gordon and Weber, David (1987), Supplier Competition, Uncertainty and Make-or-Buy
Decisions, 30 Academy of Management Journal, 589-596.
Wallis, J. and North, Douglass C. (1986), 'Measuring the Transaction Sector in the American Economy,
1870-1970', in Engerman, Stanley L. and Gallman, Robert (eds), Income and Wealth: Long-Term
Factors in American Economic Growth, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Wrnereyd, Karl (1990), Conventions: An Evolutionary Approach, 62 Public Choice, 155-173.
Weingast, Barry R. (1995), The Economic Role of Political Institutions: Federalism, Markets, and
Economic Development, 11 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 1-31.
Weingast, Barry R. (1996), Rational Choice Perspectives on Institutions, in Goodin, Robert E. and
Klingemann, Hans-Dieter (eds), A New Handbook of Political Science, New York, NY, Oxford
University Press.
Werin, Lars and Wijkander, Hans (1992), Contract Economics, Cambridge, MA, Blackwell.
Wernerfelt, Birger (1984), A Resource-based View of the Firm, 5 Strategic Management Journal,
171-180.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1971), The Vertical Integration of Production: Market Failure Considerations,
61 American Economic Review, 112-123.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications, New
York, NY, Free Press.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1976), Franchise Bidding for Natural Monopolies - In General and with
Respect to CATV, 7 Bell Journal of Economics, 73-104.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1983), Credible Commitments: Using Hostages to Support Exchange, 73
American Economic Review, 519-540.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York, NY, Free Press.
488 New Institutional Economics 0530
Williamson, Oliver E. (1988), The Economics and Sociology of Organization: Promoting a Dialogue,
in Farkas, George and England, Paula (eds), Industries, Firms, and Jobs: Sociological and
Economic Approaches, New York, Plenum, 159-185.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1990), A Comparison of Alternative Approaches to Economic Organization,
146 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 61-71.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1991a), Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete
Structural Alternatives, 36 Administrative Science Quarterly, 269-296.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1991b), Economic Institutions: Spontaneous and Intentional Governance,7(S)
Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 159-187.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1991c), Strategizing, Economizing, and Economic Organization, 23 Strategic
Management Journal, 75-94.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1993), Transaction Cost Economics Meets Posnerian Law and Economics,
149 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 99-118.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1996a), Economic Organization: The Case for Candor, 21 Academy of
Management Review, 48-57.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1996b), The Mechanisms of Governance, New York, NY, Oxford University
Press.
Wilson, James A. (1980), Adaptation to Uncertainty and Small Numbers Exchange: The New England
Fresh Fish Market, 4 Bell Journal of Economics, 491-504.
Witt, Ulrich (1989), The Evolution of Economic Institutions as a Propagation Process, 1
Constitutional Political Economy, 83-109.
Yarbrough, Beth V. and Yarbrough, Robert M. (1987), Institutions for the Governance of
Opportunism in International Trade, 3 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 129-139.
Zupan, Mark A. (1989), Cable Franchise Renewals: Do Incumbent Firms Behave Opportunistically?,
20 Rand Journal of Economics, 473-482.
Other References
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1963), Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care, 53 American
Economic Review, 941-73.
Berle, Adolph A. and Means, Gardiner C. (1932), The Modern Corporation and Private
Property, New York, Macmillan.
Chandler, Alfred D., Jr (1962), Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of the American
Industrial Enterprise, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.
Denzau, Arthur and Mackay, Robert (1983), Gate Keeping and Monopoly Power of Committees, 27
American Journal of Political Science, 740-62.
Friedman, Milton (1953), The Methodology of Positive Economics, in idem, Essays in Positive
Economics, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 3-43.
Gruchy, Allan G. (1972), Contemporary Economic Thought: The Contribution of Neo-Institutional
Economics, Clifton, NJ, Augustus M. Kelley.
Gruchy, Allan G. (1987), The Reconstruction of Economics: An Analysis of the Fundamentals of
Institutional Economics, Westport, CT, Greenwood Press.
Hayek, F.A (1937), Economics and Knowledge, in idem (1948), Individualism and Economic
Order, London, Routledge and Kegan Paul, 33-56.
Hayek, F.A. (1945), The Use of Knowledge in Society, in idem (1948), Individualism and Economic
Order, London, Routledge and Kegan Paul, 77-91.
0530 New Institutional Economics 489
Hayek, F.A. (1967), The Results of Human Action but Not of Human Design, in idem, Studies in
Philosophy, Politics, and Economics, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 96-105.
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (1998), The Approach of Institutional Economics, 36 Journal of Economic
Literature, 166-92.
Knight, Frank H. (1921), Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, New York, Hart, Schaffner & Marx.
Langlois, Richard N. (1989), What was Wrong with the Old Institutional Economics? (And What
is Still Wrong with the New?), 1 Review of Political Economy, 272-300.
Llewellyn, Karl N. (1931), What Price Contract? An Essay in Perspective, 40 Yale Law Review,
704-51.
Macneil, Ian R. (1974), The Many Futures of Contracts, 47 Southern California Law Review,
691-816.
Macneil, Ian R. (1978), Contracts: Adjustments of Long-Term Economic Relations under Classical,
Neoclassical, and Relational Contract Law, 72 Northwestern University Law Review, 854-906.
Manne, Henry G. (1965), Mergers and the Market for Corporate Control, 73 Journal of Political
Economy, 110-20.
Menger, Carl (1883), Untersuchungen ber die Methode der Socialwissenschaften und der
Politischen Oekonomie insbesondere, translated as Investigations into the Method of the Social
Sciences with Special Reference to Economics, New York, New York University Press, 1985.
Mirowski, Phillip A. (1987), The Philosophical Basis of Institutional Economics, 21 Journal of
Economic Issues, 1001-38.
Moe, Terry M. (1989), The Political Structure of Agencies, in Chubb, John E. and Peterson, Paul E.
(eds), Can Government Govern?, Washington, DC, Brookings Institution.
Priest, George L. (1977), The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules, 6 Journal
of Legal Studies, 65-82.
Richter, Rudolf (1996), Bridging Old and New Institutional Economics: Gustav Schmoller, the Leader
of the Younger German Historical Schook, Seen with Neoinstitutionalists Eyes, 152 Journal of
Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 567-92.
Robbins, Lionel (1932), The Nature and Significance of Economic Science, London, Macmillan.
Roe, Mark (1994), Strong Managers, Weak Owners: The Political Roots of American Corporate
Finance, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Rubin, Paul H. (1977), Why is the Common Law Efficient?, 6 Journal of Legal Studies, 51-63.
Rutherford, Malcolm H. (1983), J.R. Commonss Institutional Economics, 17 Journal of Economic
Issues, 721-44.
Seckler, David W. (1975), Thorstein Veblen and the Institutionalists: A Study in the Social
Philosophy of Economics, Boulder, CO, Colorado Associated University Press.
Shepsle, Kenneth A. and Weingast, Barry R. (1987), The Institutional Foundations of Committee
Power, 81 American Political Science Review, 85-194.
Simon, Herbert A. (1961) [1947], Administrative Behavior, 2nd Ed, New York, Macmillan.
Solove, Ronald L. (1986), Alternative Means to Resolve Corporate Disputes: A Survey, 91
Commercial Law Journal, 133-140.
Weingast, Barry R. (1994), Institutions and Political Commitment: A New Political Economy of the
American Civil War Era, manuscript, Stanford University.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1996c), Revisiting Legal Realism: The Law, Economics, and Organization
Perspective, 5 Industrial and Corporate Change, 383-420.
0540
PROPERTY RIGHTS APPROACH
Copyright 1999 Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest
Alchian, Armen A. (1961), Some Economics of Property Rights, Rand Paper, Rand Corporation.
Alchian, Armen A. (1978), Economic Laws and Political Legislation, in Siegan, Bernard H. (ed.),The
Interactions of Economics and the Law, Lexington, MA, Lexington Books, 139-148.
Alchian, Armen A. and Demsetz, Harold (1973), The Property Right Paradigm, 33 Journal of
Economic History, 16-27.
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1979), The Property Rights Doctrine and Demand Revelation under Incomplete
Information, in Boskin, Michael J. (ed.), Economics and Human Welfare: Essays in Honor of
Tibor Scitovsky, New York, Academic Press, 23-39.
Avio, Kenneth L. (1994), Aboriginal Property Rights in Canada: A Contractarian Interpretation of R.
v. Sparrow, 20 Canadian Public Policy, 415-429.
Bajt, Aleksander (1993), The Property Rights School: Is Economic Ownership the Missing Link?, 13
International Review of Law and Economics, 85-97.
Barzel, Yoram (1974), A Theory of Rationing by Waiting, 17 Journal of Law and Economics,
73-95.
Barzel, Yoram (1977), An Economic Analysis of Slavery, 20 Journal of Law and Economics,
87-110.
Barzel, Yoram (1989), Economic Analysis of Property Rights, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press, 122 p.
Barzel, Yoram (1994), The Capture of Wealth by Monopolists and the Protection of Property Rights,
14 International Review of Law and Economics, 393-409.
Benson, Bruce L (1990), The Enterprise of Law: Justice Without the State, San Francisco, Pacific
Research Institute for Public Policy.
Benson, Bruce L. (1984), Rent Seeking from a Property Rights Perspective, 51 Southern Economic
Journal, 388-400.
Benson, Bruce L. (1986a), Boom Towns in the West: Is Profit the Culprit?, 11 Review of Regional
Economics and Business, 27-38.
Benson, Bruce L. (1986b), The Lost Victim and Other Failures of the Public Law Experiment, 9
Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy, 399-427.
Benson, Bruce L. (1991), An Evolutionary Contractarian View of Primitive Law: The Institutions and
Incentives Arising Under Customary American Indian Law, 5 Review of Austrian Economics,
65-89.
Benson, Bruce L. (1992a), Customary Indian Law: Two Case Studies, in Anderson, Terry L. (ed.),
Property Rights and Indian Economics, Rowman and Littlefield Press.
Benson, Bruce L. (1992b), The Development of Criminal Law and its Enforcement: Public Interest
or Political Transfers, 3 Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines, 79-108.
490
0540 Property Rights Approach 491
Benson, Bruce L. (1993), The Impetus for Recognizing Private Property and Adopting Ethical
Behavior in a Market Economy: Natural Law, Government Law, or Evolving Self-Interest, 6
Review of Austrian Economics, 43-80.
Benson, Bruce L. (1994a), Legal Philosophy, in Boettke, Peter J. (ed.), The Elgar Companion to
Austrian Economics, London, Edward Elgar, 270-275.
Benson, Bruce L. (1994b), Are Public Goods Really Common Pools: Considerations of the Evolution
of Policing and Highways in England, 39 Economic Inquiry, 249-271.
Benson, Bruce L. (1994c), Emerging from the Hobbesian Jungle: Might Takes and Makes Rights, 5
Constitutional Political Economy, 129-158. Translated into Spanish and republished (1995) Las
Instituciones y Los Derechos de Propiedad al Emerger de la Jungla Hobbesiana: La Fuerza Quita
los Reprinted Derechos y los Crea Libertas, 12, 35-75.
Benson, Bruce L. (1995a), Competition Among Legal Institutions: Implications for the Evolution of
Law, in Gerken, Luden (ed.), Competition Among Institutions, London, MacMillan, 153-175.
Benson, Bruce L. (1995b), Rights, Entitlements, and Individual Responsibility in the Welfare State,
in Karslon, Nils (ed.), Can the Present Problems of Mature Welfare States Such as Sweden be
Solved?, Stockholm, City University Press, 88-98.
Benson, Bruce L. (1995c), Toxic Torts by Government, Independent Policy Report, Oakland,
Independent Institute.
Benson, Bruce L. (1996a), Restitution in Theory and in Practice, 12 Journal of Libertarian Studies,
75-98.
Benson, Bruce L. (1996b), Uncertainty, the Race for Property Rights, and Rent Dissipation due to
Judicial Changes in Product Liability Tort Law, Cultural Dynamics.
Benson, Bruce L. and Wollan, Laurin A., Jr (1989), Prison Overcrowding and Judicial Incentives, 3
Madison Paper Series, 1-22.
Blmel, Wolfgang, Pethig, Rdiger and Von Dem Hagen, Oskar (1986), The Theory of Public Goods:
A Survey of Recent Issues, 142 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 241 ff.
Bbel, Ingo (1988), Eigentum, Eigentumsrechte und Institutioneller Wandel (Property, Property
Rights and Institutional Change), Berlin, Springer, 360 p.
Bhm, Stephan (1987), Handlungsrechte, Wettbewerb und Privatisierung (Property Rights,
Competition and Privatization), 34 Wirtschaftspolitische Bltter, 576-583.
Bottomley, Anthony (1963), The Effect of Common Ownership of Land upon Resource Allocation in
Tripolitania, 39 Land Economics, 91-95.
Brenner, Reuven (1983), History - the Human Gamble, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Reprinted in Spanish edition: Fondo de Cultura Economics, Mexico - Spain, 1989.
Brenner, Reuven (1990), The Long Road from Serfdom, and How to Shorten it, 17(2) Canadian
Business Law Journal, 195-226. Reprinted in Maruyana, M. (ed.), Management Reform in
Eastern and Central Europe, Aldershot: Dartmouth, 1993, 81-109.
Brenner, Reuven (1991), Legal Reforms in the Eastern Bloc: a Precondition to Monetary and Fiscal
Policies, in Claassen, E.M. (ed.), Exchange Rate Policies of the Less Developed Market and
Socialist Economies, 151-174. Reprinted in French in Journal des Economistes et des Etudes
Humaines: Bilingual Journal of Interdisciplinary Studies, vol. 1, no. 3, October, 1990: 253-277.
492 Property Rights Approach 0540
Brenner, Reuven (1993), From Envy and Distrust to Trust and Ambition, in Baldassari, M. and
Mundell, R. (eds), Building of New Europe, London, St Martins Press, 33-59.
Brenner, Reuven (1994), The Road from Serfdom: Entrepreneurship and Property Rights Before,
During and After Communism, in Kirzner, Israel M. and Rizzo, M. (eds), Advances in Austrian
Economics, Greenwood, JAI Press, 145-174.
Buhbe, Matthes (1980), konomische Analyse von Eigentumsrechten - Der Beitrag der economics
of property rights zur Theorie der Institutionen (Economic Analysis of Property Rights - The
Contribution of the Property Rights Approach to the Theory of Institutions), Frankfurt am Main,
Peter D. Lang, 185 p.
Bydlinski, Franz (1988), Fundamentale Rechts grundstze (Fundamental Principles of Law), New
York, Springer Publishers.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1972), The Enforcement of Property Rights in Children, and the Marriage
Contract, 82 Economic Journal, 641-657.
Clarkson, Kenneth W. (1972), Some Implications of Property Rights in Hospital Management, 15
Journal of Law and Economics, 363-384.
Coase, Ronald H. (1959), The Federal Communications Commission, 2 Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-40.
Cooter, Robert D. (1993), Against Legal Centrism: Review of Robert C. Ellicksons Order Without
Law, California Law Review, 417 ff.
Copes, Parzival (1984), The Market as an Open Access Commons: A Neglected Aspect of Excess
Capacity, 132 De Economist, 49-60.
Crain, W. Mark and Tollison, Robert D. (1977), Attenuated Property Rights and the Market for
Governors, 20 Journal of Law and Economics, 205-211.
Crain, W. Mark and Zardkoohi, Asghar (1978), A Test of the Property-Rights Theory of the Firm:
Water Utilities in the United States, 21 Journal of Law and Economics, 395-408.
Davies, David G. (1981), Property Rights and Economic Behavior in Private and Government
Enterprises: The Case of Australias Banking System, 3 Research in Law and Economics,
111-142.
De Alessi, Louis (1980), The Economics of Property Rights: A Review of the Evidence, 2 Research
in Law and Economics, 1-47.
De Alessi, Louis (1983a), Property Rights, Transaction Costs, and X-Efficiency: An Essay in
Economic Theory, 73 American Economic Review, 64-81.
De Alessi, Louis (1983b), Property Rights and X-Efficiency: Reply, 73 American Economic Review,
843-845.
De Alessi, Louis (1990), Form, Substance, and Welfare Comparisons in the Analysis of Institutions,
146 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 5-23.
De Alessi, Louis and Staaf, Robert J. (1989), Property Rights and Choice, in Mercuro, Nicholas (ed.),
Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 175-200.
Demsetz, Harold (1966), Some Aspects of Property Rights, 9 Journal of Law and Economics, 61-70.
Demsetz, Harold (1983), The Structure of Ownership and the Theory of the Firm, 26 Journal of Law
and Economics, 375-390.
Dilorenzo, T.J. (1988), Property Rights, Information Costs, and the Economics of Rent Seeking, 144
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 318-322.
Dnes, Anthony W. (1985), Rent Seeking Behaviour and Open Access Fishing, 32(2) Scottish Journal
of Political Economy, 159-170.
0540 Property Rights Approach 493
Dnes, Anthony W. (1989), Rent Seeking, Conflict and Property Rights, 36(4) Scottish Journal of
Political Economy, 366-374.
Dragun, A.K. (1987), Property Rights in Economic Theory, 21 Journal of Economic Issues,
859-868.
Eggertsson, Thrainn (1990a), Economic Behaviour and Institutions, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press, 385 p.
Eggertsson, Thrainn (1990b), The Role of Transaction Costs and Property Rights in Economic
Analysis, 34 European Economic Review, 450-457.
Elder, Harold W. (1987), Property Rights Structures and Criminal Courts: An Analysis of State
Criminal Courts, 7 International Review of Law and Economics, 21-32.
Epstein, Richard A. (1982), Private Property and the Public Domain: The Case of Antitrust, in
Pennock, J. Roland and Chapman, John W. (eds), Nomos XXIV: Ethics, Economics and the Law,
New York, New York University Press, 48-82.
Eschenburg, Rolf (1978), Mikrokonomische Aspekte von Property Rights (Micro-economic Aspects
of Property Rights), in Schenk, K.E. (ed.), konomische Verfgungsrechte und
Allokationsmechanismen in Wirtschafsystemen, Berlin, Duncker and Humblot, 9-27.
Evangelopoulos, Panagiotis (1996), E Analyse ton Periousiakon Dikaiomaton kai e Ideologia tes
Eleutheres Agoras (Property Rights Analysis and Free-Market Ideology), 6 Aissymnetes.
Evangelopoulos, Panagiotis (1997), Oikonomike Analyse ton Periousiakon Dikaiomaton kai o
Mechanismos tes Agoras (Economic Analysis of Property Rights and the Market Mechanism),
PhD Thesis, University of Athens, Dept. of Economics. Reprinted as monograph: Athens, Libro,
1999
Evangelopoulos, Panagiotis (1998), O Kanon tes Pleiopsefias kai o Prosdiorismos ton Dikaiomaton
(The Majority Rule and the Stipulation of Rights), 1 Episteme kai Koinonia.
Fezer, Karl-Heinz (1986), Aspekte einer Rechtskritik an der economic analysis of law und am property
rights approach (Critical Aspects of the Economic Analysis of Law and the Property Rights
Approach from a Lawyers Viewpoint), 41 Juristenzeitung, 817-824.
Fleisher, Arthur A. III, Shughart, William F., II and Tollison, Robert D. (1989), Ownership Structure
in Professional Sports, 12 Research in Law and Economics, 71-75.
Frech, H. Edward III (1975), Property Rights and Dynamic Inefficiency of Capitalism: Comment,
83(1) Journal of Political Economy, 209-214.
Frech, H. Edward III (1980a), The Property Rights Theory of the Firm and Competitive Markets for
Top Decision-Makers, 2 Research in Law and Economics, 49-63.
Frech, H. Edward III (1980b), Managerial Incentives in Nonproprietary Institutions, S.1 Research
in Law and Economics, 46-49.
Frech, H. Edward III and Ginsburg, Paul B. (1981), Property Rights and Competition in Health
Insurance: Multiple Objectives for Nonprofit Firms,3 Research in Law and Economics, 155-171.
Frey, Bruno S. and Buhofer, Heinz (1988), Prisoners and Property Rights, 31 Journal of Law and
Economics, 19-46.
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Pejovich, Svetozar (1972), Property Rights and Economic Theory: A Survey
of Recent Literature, 10 Journal of Economic Literature, 1137-1162.
494 Property Rights Approach 0540
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Pejovich, Svetozar (1973), Property Rights, Economic Decentralization and
the Evolution of the Yugoslav Firm, 1965-1972, 16 Journal of Law and Economics, 275-302.
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Pejovich, Svetozar (eds) (1974), The Economics of Property Rights,
Cambridge, MA, Ballinger, 367 p.
Gfgen, Grad (1983), Entwicklung und Stand der Theorie der Property Rights. Eine kritische
Bestandsaufnahme (Development and Actual Situation of the Property Rights), in Neumann, M.
(ed.), Ansprache, Eigentums- und Verfgungsrechte, Berlin, Duncker and Humblot, 43-62.
Gantner, Manfred (1984), Schwierigkeiten der Verrechtlichung konomischer Tatbestnde (The
Difficuly of Transforming Economic Issues into Law),31 Wirtschaftspolitische Bltter, 423-430.
Gay, David E.R. (1975a), Book Review of The Economics of Property Rights, ed. by Furubotn and
Pejovich, 42 Southern Economic Journal, 162-164.
Gay, David E.R. (1975b), Property Rights and Adam Smith,33 Review of Social Economy, 177-179.
Gay, David E.R. (1976), Book Review of Henry Manne, The Economics of Legal Relationships, 42
Southern Economic Journal, 765-766.
Gay, David E.R. (1978), Book Review of Economic Forces at Work, Armen Alchian, 31 Kyklos,
504-505.
Gay, David E.R. (1981a), Towards a Theory of Entitlements in Comparative Economics, 25 Rivista
Internazionale di Scienze Economiche e Commerciali, 1021-1028.
Gay, David E.R. (1981b), Entitlements and Public Policy, 18 Social Science Journal, 87-100.
Gay, David E.R. (1982), Book Review of Mercantilism as a Rent-Seeking Society: Economic
Regulation in Historical Perspective, Robert B. Ekelund and Robert D. Tollison, 35 Kyklos,
732-733.
Gay, David E.R. (1989), Viticultural Rent Seeking and Public Policy in Arid Lands, 5 Forum of the
Association for Arid Lands Studies, 33-40.
Gay, David E.R. (1990), A Note on the Deprivatization of the Grand Canyon, 6 Forum of the
Association for Arid Lands Studies, 41-43.
Gay, David E.R. (1992), Teaching Privatization in the Soviet Union: An Experimental Economics
Approach, 1 Classroom Expernomics, 5-6.
Gay, David E.R. (1994), Incentives and Privatization: An Experimental Economics Approach, 22
Atlantic Economic Journal, 79 ff.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1991), Thesmikes Analyseis sten Oikonomike: E Theoria ton Praxiakon
Dikaiomaton (Institutional Analyses in Economics: The Property Rights Theory), 4 Aissymnetes,
27-48.
Goldberg, Victor P. (1986), Fishing and Selling, 15 Journal of Legal Studies, 173-180.
Gordon, Scott and Stegemann, Klaus (1985), The Market as a Commons: Is Catching Customers Like
Catching Fish?, 133 De Economist, 218-231.
Gotthold, Jrgen (1980), Zur konomischen Theorie des Eigen tums. Eine kritische Einfuhrung (The
Economic Theory of Property - A Critical Introduction), 144 Zeitschrift fr das gesamte
Handels- und Wirtschaftsrecht, 545-562.
Hafner, Gerhard (1987), Seerechtliche Verteilung von Nutzungsrechten (The Assignment of Property
Rights on the Sea), New York, Springer Publishers, 533 p.
0540 Property Rights Approach 495
Hanner, John (1981), Governement Response to the Buffalo Hide Trade, 1871-1883, 24 Journal of
Law and Economics, 239-271.
Hardin, Garrett (1968), The Tragedy of the Commons, 162 Science, 1243-1248.
Hardin, Garrett and Baden, John A. (eds) (1977), Managing the Commons, San Francisco, Freeman,
294 p.
Hesse, Gnter (1980), Der Property-Rights-Ansatz. Eine konomische Theorie der Vernderung des
Rechts? (The Property Rights Approach. An Economic Theory of Legal Change?), 195 Jahrbuch
fr Nationalkonomie und Statistik, 481 ff.
Hesse, Gnter (1983), Zur Erklrung der nderung von Handlungsrechten mit Hilfe der
konomischen Theorie (The Explanation of the Change of Property Rights with Economic
Theory), in Schller, Alfred (ed.), Property Rights und konomische Theorie, Mnchen, Vahlen,
79-109.
Hutter, Michael (1975), The Property Rights Paradigm: A Comment, 188 Jahrbuch fr
Nationalkonomie und Statistik, 552-556.
Hutter, Michael (1979), Die Gestaltung von Property Rights als Mittel
gesellschaftlichwirtschaftlicher Allokation (The Structure of Property Rights as a Means of
Social-Economic Allocation), Gttingen, Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht, 245 p.
Jelic, Ranko (1995), Drustvena i drzavna svojina (Social and State Property), Belgrade, Nomos.
Johnsen, D. Bruce (1991), Property Rights to Cartel Rents: The Socony-Vacuum Story, 34 Journal
of Law and Economics, 177-202.
Johnsen, D. Bruce (1992), The Incentive Effects of Soft Dollar Brokerage, in Lehn, Kenneth and
Kamphuis, Robert (eds), Modernizing US Securities Regulations: Economic and Legal
Perspectives, 511-519.
Johnsen, D. Bruce (1994), Property Rights to Investment Research: The Agency Costs of Soft Dollar
Brokerage, 11 Yale Journal on Regulation, 75-113.
Johnsen, D. Bruce (1995), The Quasi-Rent Structure of Corporate Entreprise: A Transaction Cost
Theory, 44 Emory Law Journal, 1277 ff.
Johnsen, D. Bruce, Habib, Michel A. and Naik, Narayan Y. (forthcoming), Spin-offs and Information,
Journal of Financial Intermediation.
Jovanovic, Aleksandra (1994), Transakcioni Troskovi Privatizacije (Transaction Costs of
Privatisation), 43(9-10) Pravni zivot, 895-905.
Kaulmann, Peter (1987), Property rights und Unternehmungstheorie. Stand und Weiterentwicklung
der empirischen Forschung (Property Rights and the Theory of the Firm), 3 Schriftenreihe Law
and Economics.
Kerber, Wolfgang (1992), Innovation, Handlungsrechte und Evolutionrer Marktproze (Innovation,
Property Rights and Evolutionary Market Process), in Witt, Ulrich (ed.), Studien zur
Evolutorischen konomik II, Berlin, 171-195.
Koboldt, Christian (1995), Property Rights und Urheberschutz (Property Rights and Copyright), in
Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), Okonomische Analyse der rechtlichen Organisation
von Innovationen, Tbingen, Mohr.
Khler, Helmut (1980), Vertragsrecht und Property Rights- Theorie, Zur Integration konomischer
Theorien in das Privatrecht (Contract Law and Property Rights Theory - On the Integration of
Economic Theories into Private Law), 144 Zeitschrift fr das gesamte Handels- und
Wirtschaftsrecht, 589-607.
496 Property Rights Approach 0540
Miller, Geoffrey P. (1987), Economic Efficiency and the Lockean Proviso, 10 Harvard Journal of
Law and Public Policy, 401 ff.
Mortensen, Dale T. (1982), Property Rights and Efficiency in Mating, Racing and Related Games,
72 American Economic Review, 968-979.
Nutzinger, Hans G. (1982), The Economics of Property Rights - A New Paradigm in Social Science?,
in Stigmuller, W. (ed.), Philosophy of Economics, Berlin, Springer.
OHara, Maureen (1981), Property Rights and the Financial Firm, 24 Journal of Law and
Economics, 317-332.
Ostrom, Elinor (1990), Governing the Commons. The Evolution of Institutions, New York,
Cambridge University Press.
Parisi, Francesco (1995), Private Property and Social Costs, 2(2) European Journal of Law and
Economics, 149-173. Reprinted in Posner, Richard A. and Parisi, Francesco (eds), Law and
Economics 597-622 (Elgar-Ashgate, 1997)
Parisi, Francesco (1998), A Property-Right Theory of Democratic Voting, George Mason University
Law and Economics Working Paper Series, #98-04.
Pejovich, Svetozar (1982), Karl Marx, Property Rights School and the Process of Social Change, 35
Kyklos, 383-397.
Pejovich, Svetozar (1984), Fundamentals of Economics: A Property Rights Approach, Dallas, Fisher
Institute, 258 p.
Pejovich, Svetozar (1990), The Economics of Property Rights: Towards a Theory, Dordrecht, Kluwer,
224 p.
Polinsky, A. Mitchell (1979), Controlling Externalities and Protecting Entitlements: Property Right,
Liability Rule, and Tax-Subsidy Approaches, 8 Journal of Legal Studies, 1-48.
Polinsky, A. Mitchell (1980), On the Choice Between Property Rules and Liability Rules, 18(2)
Economic Inquiry, 233-246.
Polinsky, Mitchell A. (1979), Controlling Externalities and Protecting Entitlements: Property Right,
Liability Rule, and Tax-Subsidy Approaches, 8 Journal of Legal Studies, 1-48.
Polinsky, Mitchell A. (1980), On the Choice Between Property Rules and Liability Rules, 18(2)
Economic Inquiry, 233-246.
Posin, Daniel Q. (1990), The Coase Theorem: If Pigs Could Fly, 37 Wayne Law Review, 89-120.
Posin, Daniel Q. (1991), Bringing Home the Bacon: A Response to Critics, 38 Wayne Law Review,
107 ff.
Posin, Daniel Q. (1995), Risk and the Error of the Coase Theorem, 62 Tennessee Law Review,
1057-1071.
Posin, Daniel Q. (1996), Silicone Breast Implant Litigation and My Father-in-Law: A Neo-Coasean
Analysis, 70 Tulane Law Review, 2565-2582.
Posin, Daniel Q. (1997), The Coase Theorem: Through a Glass Darkly, 61 Tennessee Law Review,
868 ff.
Reynolds, R. Larry (1985), Institutionally Determined Property Claims, 19 Journal of Economic
Issues, 941-949.
Richter, Rudolf (1993), konomische Theorie des Privateigentums, Thema und Variationen
(Economics of Property Rights), Jahrbuch fr Sozialwissenschaft.
498 Property Rights Approach 0540
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1985), Inalienability and the Theory of Property Rights, 85 Columbia Law
Review, 931-969. Reprinted in Coleman, J. and Lange, J. (eds), New York University Press, Law
and Economics, Vol. I, New York, 1992, 421-459.
Rowley, Charles K. and Yarrow, G.K. (1981), Property Rights, Regulation and Public Enterprise: The
Case of the British Steel Industry 1957-1975, 1 International Review of Law and Economics,
63 ff.
Runge, Carlisle Ford (1985), The Innovation of Rules and the Structure of Incentives in Open Access
Resource, 67 American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 368-372.
Ryssdal, Stray A.C. (1995), Legal Realism and Economics as Behavior - A Scandinavian Look at the
Economic Analysis of Law, Oslo, Juridisk Forlag.
Samuels, Warren J. (1972), Welfare Economics, Power, and Property, in Wunderlich, Gene and
Gibson, W.L., Jr (eds), Perspectives of Property, University Park, PA, Institute for Research on
Land and Water Resources, Pennsylvania State University, 61-127.
Schap, David (1988), Property Rights and Decision Making in the Soviet Union: Interpreting Soviet
Environmental History, 26 Economic Inquiry, 389-401.
Schap, David (1989), Pricing and Property Rights in Government Enterprises: Some Dynamic
Aspects, 11 Research in Law and Economics, 113-127.
Schenk, Karl-Ernst (1988), Property Rights und Theorie der Institutionen (Property Rights and Theory
of Institutions), Das Wirtschaftsstudium.
Schmid, A. Allan (1976), The Economics of Property Rights: A Review Article, in Samuels, Warren
J. (ed.), The Chicago School of Political Economy, East Lansing, MI, Division of Research,
Graduate School of Business Administration, Michigan State University, 469-478.
Schmid, A. Allan (1981), Predicting the Performance of Alternative Institutions, in Samuels, Warren
J. and Schmid, A. Allan (eds), Law and Economics: An Institutional Perspective, Boston, Nijhoff,
76-94.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1983), Property Rights, Freiheit und Wettbewerbspolitik (Property Rights,
Freedom and Competition Policy), Tbingen, Mohr, 71 p.
Schller, Alfred (1978), Property Rights, Unternehmerische Legitimation und Wirtschaftsordnung.
Zum vermgenstheoretischen Ansatz einer allgemeinen Theorie der Unternehmung (Property
Rights, Entrepreneurial Legitimation and Economic System. On the Property Rights Approach of
a General Theory of the Enterprise), in Schenk, K.E. (ed.), konomische Verfgungsrechte und
Allokationsmechanismen in Wirtschafsystemen, Berlin, Duncker and Humblot, 29-87.
Schller, Alfred (1979), Eigentumsrechte, Unternehmenskontrollen und Wettbewerbsordnung
(Property Rights, Corporate Control and Competition), 30 Ordo: Jahrbuch fr die Ordnung von
Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, 325-364.
Schller, Alfred (1985), Zur konomik der Property Rights (On the Economics of Property Rights),
14(5) Das Wirtschaftsstudium, 259-265.
Schumann, Joachim (1978), Neue Mikrokonomik und Theorie des Eigentumsrechte. Anstze zur
Ergnzung der mikrokonomischen Theorie (New Microeconomics and Property Rights Theory.
An Introduction to the Completion of Microeconomic Theory), 7 Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches
Studium, 307-311.
Schwartz, Pedro (1987), The Market and the Metamarket: A Review of the Contributions of the
Economic Theory of Property Rights, in Pejovich, Svetozar (ed.), Socialism: Institutional,
Philosophical and Economic, Dordrecht, Kluwer, 11-32.
0540 Property Rights Approach 499
Sevic, Zeljko (1995), Svojinski oblici i efikasnost funkcionisanja bankarskog sistema (Property Forms
and the Banking System Efficiency), 9 Pravni zivot, 647-660.
Smith, Janet Kiholm and Smith, Richard L. (1984), State and Local Fiscal Policy: Implications for
Property Values and Economic Growth, 12 Public Finance Quarterly, 51-76.
Swaney, James A. (1990), Common Property, Reciprocity, and Community,24 Journal of Economic
Issues, 451-462.
Sweeney, Richard James, Tollison, Robert D. and Willett, Thomas D. (1974), Market Failure, the
Common-Pool Problem, and Ocean Resource Exploitation, 17 Journal of Law and Economics,
179-192.
Teixeira, Pedro Gustavo (1994), A questo da proteco dos consumidores nos contratos
plurilocalizados (Consumer Protection in International Contracts), 54 Revista da Ordem dos
Advogados, 181-343.
Tietzel, Manfred (1981), Die konomie Der Property Rights: Ein berblick (The Economics of
Property Rights: A Survey), 30 Zeitschrift fr Wirtschaftspolitik, 207-243.
Turnbull, Shann (1991), Ownership: Never for Ever, New Economics and its Writing: History of
Political Economy, 4 ff.
Turnbull, Shann (1997), Stakeholder Governance: A cybernetic and property rights analysis, 5(1)
Corporate Governance: An International Review, 11-23.
Von Weizscker, Carl-Christian (1984), Was leistet die Property Rights Theorie fr aktuelle
wirtschaftspolitische Fragen? (What Brings the Property Rights Theory for Actual Economic
Issues?), in Neumann, M. (ed.), Ansprache, Eigentums- und Verfgungsrechte, Berlin, Duncker
and Humblot, 123-152.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1990), A Comparison of Alternative Approaches to Economic Organization,
146 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 61-71.
Winiecki, J. (1989), Buying Out Property Rights to the Economy from the Ruling Stratum: The Case
of Soviet-Type States, 9 International Review of Law and Economics, 79-85.
Yang, Xiaokai and Wills, Ian R. (1990), A Model Formalizing the Theory of Property Rights, 14
Journal of Comparative Economics, 177-198.
0550
GAME THEORY APPLIED TO LAW
Copyright 1999 Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest
Aivazian, Varouj A. and Callen, Jeffrey L. (1981), The Coase Theorem and the Empty Core, 24
Journal of Law and Economics, 175-181.
Aivazian, Varouj A., Callen, Jeffrey L. and Lipnowski, Irwin F. (1988), The Coase Theorem and
Coalitional Stability, 54 Economica, 517-520.
Baird, Douglas G., Gertner, Rober and Picker, Randal C. (1995), Game Theory and the Law,
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Ben-Shahar, Omri (1992), Strategic Behavior in Judicial Panels, Discussion Paper, Program in Law
and Economics, Harvard Law School, No. 107.
Bonus, Holger (1979), ffentliche Gter, Verfhrung und Gefangenendilemma (Public Goods,
Temptation and the Prisoners Dilemma), 10(2) List Forum, 69-102. Reprinted in Grundtexte zur
Sozialen Marktwirtschaft, Stuttgart/New York, Gustav Fischer Verlag. 1979/80, pp. 283-305
Bonus, Holger (1980), ffentliche Gter und Gefangenendilemma (Public Gooods and the Prisoners
Dilemma), in Dettling, W. (ed.), Die Zhmung des Leviathan. Neue Wege der Ordnungspolitik,
Baden-Baden, Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft, 129-160.
Chang, Howard F. (1997), Carrots, Sticks and International Externalities, 17 International Review
of Law and Economics, 309-324.
Cooter, Robert D., Marks, Stephen V. and Mnookin, Robert H. (1982), Bargaining in the Shadow of
the Law: A Testable Model of Strategic Behavior, 11 Journal of Legal Studies, 225-251.
Reprinted in Coleman, Jules and Lange, Jeffrey (eds), Law and Economics, Volume 2, New York,
University Press, 1992.
Curran, Christopher (1994), The Burden of Proof and the Liability Rule for Suppliers of Services in
the EEC, 70 Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance, 85-98.
Dana, James D., Jr and Spier, Kathryn E. (1993), Expertise and Contingent Fees: The Role of
Asymmetric Information in Attorney Compensation, 9 Journal of Law, Economics, and
Organization, 349-367.
Dana, James D., Jr and Spier, Kathryn E. (1994), Designing a Private Industry: Government Auctions
with Endogenous Market Structure, 53 Journal of Public Economics, 127-147.
Daughety, Andrew F. and Reinganum, Jennifer F. (1993), Endogenous Sequencing in Models of
Settlement and Litigation, 9 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 314-348.
Daughety, Andrew F. and Reinganum, Jennifer F. (1994), Settlement Negotiations with Two Sided
Asymmetric Information: Model Duality, Information Distribution, and Efficiency, 14
International Review of Law and Economics, 283-298.
Daughety, Andrew F. and Reinganum, Jennifer F. (1995a), Keeping Society in the Dark: On the
Admissibility of Pretrial Negotiations as Evidence in Court, 26 Rand Journal of Economics,
203-221.
Daughety, Andrew F. and Reinganum, Jennifer F. (1995b), Product Safety: Liability, R&D, and
Signaling, 85 American Economic Review, 1187-1206.
500
0550 Game Theory Applied to Law 501
Kahan, Marcel and Tuckman, Bruce (1993), Do Bondholders Lose From Junk Bond Covenant
Changes, 66 Journal of Business, 499 ff.
Katz, Avery (1988), Judicial Decisionmaking and Litigation Expenditure, 8 International Review
of Law and Economics, 127-143.
Katz, Avery (1990a), The Strategic Structure of Offer and Acceptance: Game Theory and the Law of
Contract Formation, 89 Michigan Law Review, 215-295.
Katz, Avery (1990b), Your Terms or Mine: The Duty to Read the Fine Print in Contracts, 21 Rand
Journal of Economics, 518-537.
Katz, Avery (1996), The Economics of Promissory Estoppel in Preliminary Negotiations, 105 Yale
Law Journal, 1249-1309.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1989), Recht en Speltheorie: een Economisch Model voor het Ontstaan van
Staten en Recht (Law and Game Theory: an Economic Model for the Emergence of State
Organization and Law), Rotterdam, Erasmus University, 212 p.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1995), Game Theory as a Method in Law and Economics, in Bouckaert,
Boudewijn and De Geest, Gerrit (eds), Essays in Law and Economics II: Contract Law,
Regulation, and Reflections on Law and Economics, Antwerpen, Maklu, 267-285.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1996), Boekbespreking: Baird, D.C., Gertner, R.H. and Picker, R.C., Game
Theory and the Law, 25 Tijdschrift voor Rechtsfilosofie en Rechtstheorie, 72-75.
Kobayashi, Bruce H. (1992), Deterrence with Multiple Defendants: an Explanation for Unfair Plea
Bargaining, 23 Rand Journal of Economics, 507-515.
Koboldt, Christian (1993), Zeitinkonsistenz, Separabilitt und Teilspielperfektheit, vom mglichen
Segen der beschrnkten Rationalitt (Time Inconsitstency, Separability, ans Subgame Perfectness,
On the Possible Blessing of the Bounded Rationality), 10 Homo Oeconomicus.
Kort, P.M., Feichtinger G., Hartl, R.F. and Haundschmied, J.L. (1995), Optimal Enforcement Policies
(Crackdowns) On a Drug Market, Working Paper, Maastricht, Tilburg University, Department
of Economietrics and CentER.
Krauss, Michael I. (1994), La rglementation contre le march dans le dveloppement de normes
(Regulation against the Market in Norms Formation), 5 Journal des Economistes et des Etudes
Humaines, 573-599.
Mackaay, Ejan (1988), Lordre spontan comme fondement du droit - un survol des modles de
lmergence des rgles dans la socit civile (Spontaneous Order as the Foundation of Law - A
Survey of Models of the Emergence of Rules in Civil Society), 22 Revue Juridique Themis,
347-383. Reprinted in 3 Revue Internationale de Droit Economique, 247-287.
Mackaay, Ejan (1991), Le Droit Saisi par le Jeu (Game-Theory Applied to Law), Droit et Socit,
57-81. Reprinted in Ost, Franois and Van De Kerkhove, Michel (eds), Le Jeu: un Paradigme
pour le Droit, Paris, Librairie Gnrale de Droit et de Jurisprudence, 81-110.
Mackaay, Ejan (1992), Rgle et Dcision en Droit (Rule and Decision in Law), in Bourcier, Danile
and Mackay, Pierre (eds), Lire le droit - Langue, texte, cognition, Paris, Librairie Gnrale de
Droit et de Jurisprudence, 41-69.
Parisi, Francesco (1997a), The Genesis of Liability in Ancient Law, George Mason University Law and
Economics Working Paper Series, No. 97-07.
0550 Game Theory Applied to Law 503
Parisi, Francesco (1997b), Rent-Seeking Through Litigation: Adversarial and Inquisitorial Systems
Compared, George Mason University Law and Economics Working Paper Series, No. 97-09.
Png, Ivan Paak-Liang (1983), Strategic Behavior in Suit, Settlement and Trial, 14 Bell Journal of
Economics, 539-550. Reprinted in Levine, D.K. and Lippman, S.A. (eds), The Economics of
Information, Cheltenham, UK, Edward Elgar.
Png, Ivan Paak-Liang (1987), Litigation, Liability, and Incentives for Care, 34 Journal of Public
Economics, 61-85.
Posner, Eric A. (1998), Symbols, Signals, and Social Norms in Politics and the Law, 27 Journal of
Legal Studies.
Rasmusen, Eric and Ramseyer, Mark J. (1994), Cheap Bribes and the Corruption Ban: A Coordination
Game Among Rational Legislators, 78 Public Choice, 305 ff.
Rasmusen, Eric B., Ramseyer, Mark J. and Wiley, John Shepard, Jr (1991), Naked Exclusion, 81
American Economic Review, 1137 ff.
Reinganum, Jennifer F. (1988), Plea Bargaining and Prosecutorial Discretion, 78 American
Economic Review, 713-728.
Reinganum, Jennifer F. (1993), The Law Enforcement Process and Criminal Choice,13 International
Review of Law and Economics, 115-134.
Reinganum, Jennifer F. and Wilde, Louis L. (1986), Settlement, Litigation, and the Allocation of
Litigation Costs, 17 Rand Journal of Economics, 557-566.
Roin, Julie, A. (1995), Rethinking Tax Treaties in a Strategic World with Disparate Tax Systems, 81
Virginia Law Review, 1753 ff.
Ryssdal, Stray A.C. (1995), An Economic Analysis of Civil Suits and Appels, Oslo, Juridisk Forlag.
Sanchirico, Chris William (1997a), Evidence Production, Adversarial Process and the Private
Instigation of Suits, mimeo, Columbia University Economics Department.
Sanchirico, Chris William (1997b), Enforcement by Hearing: An Integrated Model of Evidence
Production, mimeo, Columbia University Economics Department.
Sanchirico, Chris William (1997c), The Burden of Proof in Civil Litigation: A Simple Model of
Mechanism Design, 17 International Review of Law and Economics, 431-447.
Schap, David (1986), Executive Veto and Informational Strategy: A Structure-Induced Equilibrium
Analysis, 30 American Journal of Political Science, 755-770.
Schap, David (1988), In Search of Efficacious Executive Veto Authority, 58 Public Choice, 247-257.
Schap, David (1990), Executing Veto and Spending Limitation: Positive Political Economy with
Implications for Institutional Choice, 65 Public Choice, 239-256.
Schap, David and Carter, John R. (1987), Executive Veto, Legislative Override and Structure-Induced
Equilibrium, 52 Public Choice, 227-244. Reprinted in Rowley, Charles (ed.), Public Choice
Theory, Edward Elgar, 1993, vol. 3, pp. 47-64.
Schap, David and Carter, John R. (1990), Line-Item Veto: Where is Thy Sting?, 4 Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 103-118.
Schap, David and Daerden, James A. (1994), The First Word and the Last Word in the Budgetary
Process: A Comparative Institutional Analysis of Proposal and Veto Authorities, 80 Public
Choice, 35-53.
Schavell, Steven and Spier, Kathryn E. (1996), Threats Without Binding Commitment,5461 National
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper.
504 Game Theory Applied to Law 0550
Schmidtchen, Dieter and Kirstein, Roland (1997), Abkoppelung der Prozekosten vom Streitwert?
Eine konomische Analyse von Reformvorschlgen (Separation of Litigation Costs and the Value
of the Case? An Economic Analysis of Reform Proposals), in Prtting, H. and Rssmann, H. (eds),
Verfahrensrecht am Ausgang des 20. Jahrhunderts. Festschrift fr Gerhard Lke zum 70.
Geburtstag, Mnchen 1997, Mnchen, 741-766.
Spier, Kathryn E. (1992a), Incomplete Contracts and Signalling, 23 Rand Journal of Economics,
432-443.
Spier, Kathryn E. (1992b), The Dynamics of Pretrial Negotiation, 59 Review of Economic Studies,
93-108.
Spier, Kathryn E. (1994a), Settlement Bargaining and the Design of Damage Awards, 10 Journal of
Law, Economics, and Organization, 84-95.
Spier, Kathryn E. (1994b), Pretrial Bargaining and the Design of Fee-Shifting Rules, 25 Rand
Journal of Economics, 197-214.
Spier, Kathryn E. and Dana, James D., Jr (1993), Expertise and Contingent Fees: The Role of
Asymmetric Information in Attorney Compensation, 9 Journal of Law, Economics, and
Organization, 349-367.
Spier, Kathryn E. and Dana, James D., Jr (1994), Designing a Private Industry: Government Auctions
with Endogenous Market Structure, 53 Journal of Public Economics, 127-147.
Spier, Kathryn E. and Spulber, Daniel (1993), Pretrial Bargaining and Asymmetric Information: The
Mechanism-Design Approach, mimeo, July 1993.
Spier, Kathryn E. and Hay, Bruce L. (1996), Burdens of Production in Civil Litigation: An Economic
Perspective, Journal of Legal Studies.
Spier, Kathryn E. and Whinston, Michael (1995), On the Efficiency of Privately Stipulated Damages
for Breach of Contract: Entry Barriers, Reliance, and Renegotiation, 26 Rand Journal of
Economics, 180-202.
Spier, Kathryn E. and Shavell, Steven (1996), Threats Without Binding Commitment, National
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper.
Spier, Kathryn E. and Sykes, Alan O. (1996), Capital Structure, Priority Rules, and the Settlement
of Civil Claims, Mimeo, August 1996.
Spier, Kathryn E. and Weinstein, David E. (1995), Retaliatory Mechanisms for Eliminating Trade
Barriers: Aggressive Unilateralism vs GATT Cooperation, in Chang, Winston W. and Katayama,
Seiichi (eds), Imperfect Competition in International Trade, Dordrecht, Kluwer Academic
Publishers.
Spier, Kathryn E. and Whinston, Michael D. (1995), On the Efficiency of Privately Stipulated
Damages for Breach of Contract: Entry Barriers, Reliance and Renegotiation, 26 Rand Journal
of Economics, 180-202.
Stout, Lynn A. (1996), Insurance or Gambling? Derivatives Trading in a World of Risk and
Uncertainty, 39 Brookings Review.
Vracar, K. Stevan (1994), Preispitivanja pravne metodologije: Nagovestaji drzavno-pravnog
integralizma (Reexamination of the Legal Methodology: Indications of State-Legal Integralism),
Belgrade, Naucna knjiga.
Williams, Stephen F. (1973), Optimizing Water Use: The Return Flow Issue, 44 University of
Colorado Law Review, 301-321.
0560
COMPARATIVE LAW AND ECONOMICS
Ugo A. Mattei, Luisa Antoniolli and Andrea Rossato
Universit Degli Studi di Trento
Copyright 1999 Ugo A. Mattei, Luisa Antoniolli and Andrea Rossato
Abstract
This chapter aims at providing a definition of this rather new subject, which is
situated at the crossroads of two different scholarly traditions, comparative law
and economic analysis of the law. Comparative law and economics combines
the instruments and methodologies of both these two disciplines because in this
way it is possible to better understand the reasons of existing legal rules and
institutions and of their evolution. It uses a dynamic approach to law, by
focusing on the study of phenomena of legal divergence and convergence.
These phenomena may take place within a single legal system, and in this case
the analysis of legal formants (a technique created by comparative law)
provides the analytical tool for verifying the law in action, which may be
hidden behind different formal rules. Interaction may also happen among
different legal systems, and we term this latter phenomenon legal transplant,
which can take place for single rules or institutions or for entire branches of
law, and can be determined by different reasons which range from prestige to
forced imposition. Economic analysis of law provides further analytical tools
that help measure the level and entity of analogy or divergence. Beside the
traditional tools of neoclassical economics, useful insights may be gained
through the instruments of the new institutional economics, particularly
path-dependence, which, through the analysis of the relationship between
formal and informal institutions, and of these with organizations, opens new
lines of interpretation of legal change.
JEL classification: 0560
Keywords: Comparative Law, Law and Economics, Methodology
Comparative law and law and economics are well-established legal specialties.
The two disciplines may benefit from each other, both having a strong
non-state-centric approach to legal analysis. Specifically, comparative law may
gain theoretical perspective by using the kind of functional analysis employed
in economic analysis of law. Comparative law may proceed a step forward in
its target of measuring and understanding analogies and differences among
505
506 Comparative Law and Economics 0560
(1) convergence: legal systems starting from different points tend to converge
toward similar solutions;
(2) divergence: legal systems moving from similar starting points tend, in the
course of time, to reach different legal solutions.
to attract forum shoppers, or between different sources of the law within a given
system (Reich, 1992; Antoniolli, 1995, 1996). Of course, these two main
patterns do not exclude one another. Applied law is the outcome of a
competitive process between legal formants. More generally, law is the
synthesis both of exogenous factors, determined by culture, economic structure,
and political system, and of endogenous elements. The works of the Austrian
school, particularly Hayeks concept of competition with its emphasis on the
working of the competitive process rather than the characteristics of
competitive equilibrium, is appropriate to describe the formation of the legal
rule (Hayek, 1973). From his theory of knowledge, Hayek formulates one of his
more fundamental criticisms of perfect competition: knowledge and
information, rather than being the basis for, are the results of the competitive
process. This reverses the causal relationship assumed by traditional economic
theory.
Considering the sources of law in competition with each other despite the
official hierarchy does not lead us to assume a jurisprudence of hunches due
to the staggering variety of the possible outcomes of the competitive process
and to the impossibility to predict which legal formant will actually win.
Indeed, the result of competition is not less predictable than that of cooperation.
It is only more realistic.
Does competition lead to efficient law? It is tempting to conclude that in
the long run, within a group of cases, a legal trend may be foreseen as a result
of a spontaneous order. It would be even more tempting to say that an
invisible hand leads one efficient rule to triumph over all others.
Unfortunately, the mentioned complexity of legal systems does not allow us to
reach these conclusions (Mattei, 1994a). While in the world of zero transaction
costs such evolution towards efficiency could be expected, this is not the case
in the real world where institutional and cultural constrains introduce high
transaction costs.
3.2 Property Rights, Liability Rules and the Theory of Transactions Costs
By discussing the historical and comparative law roots of the notion of property
rights used in the economic analysis of law (Alchian, 1987), one can examine
what may be regarded as the most important difference between comparative
law and economics and traditional economic analysis of law. While this
approach attempts to account for the different institutional alternatives
presented by real-world legal systems, law and economics elaborates its theories
on institutional backgrounds which are either abstract natural law models, or
which uncritically postulate the modern institutional background of US law
(Ajani and Mattei, 1995; Benson, 1989; Benson, 1995).
Comparative law is essentially a historical branch of scholarship which
seeks to discern both differences and similarities among alternative legal
institutions (Schlesinger, 1988). Its methodology may prove very helpful to law
and economics, since it offers a more global perspective on different legal
structures and on the evolution of these structure which may shed new light on
- and challenge at the same time - certain previously undisputed assumptions
of traditional law and economics. As a result, comparative law and economics
does not conceive the legal system as a static background for economic analysis
able to be captured by a few, never revisited, simplified assumptions. Nor does
it assume that the contingencies of the American legal process are the necessary
substratum for theories concerning the efficiency of law. The legal background
represents a dynamic variable which economic analysis of law must reflect in
both its positive and in its normative dimension.
The natural law conception of property is an intellectual category which
does not exist, and never existed, as law in action in any legal system
(Gambaro, Candian and Pozzo, 1992). Using comparative analysis, it is easy
to show that applied law only knows more complex forms of property rights
based on a mixture of property and liability rules allocated in different ways to
different individuals by different institutional agencies in different legal
systems (conjunctive property rights).
The idea of property rights which serves as the institutional background
for traditional law and economics is that of a bundle of rights that a person has
over certain resources. Included in this notion are the enjoyment and
0560 Comparative Law and Economics 517
The lack of comparative understanding within the legal community has created
a two-fold problem for law and economics. American law and economics has
been remarkably parochial, unable to question the presumed need and
immutability of a legal process patterned after the American one. Traditionally,
law and economics contributions tend to presume a court system and, more
generally, a legal process organized on the American style.
In Europe, the same lack of comparative understanding has prevented
committed law and economics scholars from developing original insights
capable of shedding new light on the civilian legal process (Mattei and
Pardolesi, 1991). Many civilian law and economics scholars have uncritically
applied theories which only work in the American scenario to the different
background of their legal systems.
More generally, the widespread legal parochialism on both sides of the
Atlantic has precluded a distinction between institutional arrangements which
are local contingencies incapable of generalization, and deeper levels of legal
analysis that can be used in understanding the law as a general phenomenon of
social organization. The same lack of comparative understanding has,
moreover, fueled the false impression that, because of the structure of the civil
law tradition, law and economics is less useful as a tool of analysis in Europe
than in the United States. The attempt to build models which reflect the
complexities of the real world of the law is exactly what comparative law and
0560 Comparative Law and Economics 519
borrowing its analytical tools from comparative law, accounts for this gap. At
the same time, it borrows from law and economics the tools necessary to bridge
it.
In approaching the question of the gap, a dynamic perspective on
comparative law is needed (Calabresi, 1982). As a result, we will assume that
the dimension of the gap is not fixed, but rather varies in both time and space.
Deep structural differences are not, of course, a differently worded statute or
regulation, or a supposedly different formalistic reasoning of the courts.
Relevant legal process differences include: the way of acquiring information in
the legislative process; the different role of public law; structural regulation of
class actions; the presence or absence of a jury in the fact-finding process; the
completely different system of incentives to sue due to different distribution of
the costs of litigation; and the different ways in which courts acquire
information (Stein, 1984).
From the timing perspective, the comparative law community agrees that
the division between common law and civil law is rooted in the early
development of centralized courts of law in England and of academic legal
training on the Continent (Baker, 1990). There is also general agreement that,
after a peak in the course of the nineteenth century, when the civilian nations
codified national systems of law, the significance of the gap has progressively
declined.
One of the major issues of law and economics concerns the role of the
judge in finding efficient outcomes for legal disputes. Great emphasis is given
to the different role of the judge in the common law vis--vis the civil law
(Eisenberg, 1988; Atiyah, 1987). Consequently, it becomes important to
scrutinize such difference to see whether it introduces a fundamental limit to
the application of law and economics in the civil law.
According to traditional comparative law doctrine, the civil law is mostly
a codified system where the role of bureaucratically recruited judges is to
interpret and apply a written body of statutes (David and Brierley, 1985; von
Mehren and Gordley, 1977). Common law, conversely, consists mostly of case
law where technocratic judges are concerned with finding the applicable rule
within the body of law made up of legal precedents. If such is the picture of the
differences between the two legal traditions, there is no doubt that law and
economics, being mainly concerned with efficient judicial decision making,
seems at odds with civil law systems where judges limit themselves to
mechanically applying the law contained in written codes. If this picture were
correct and the judges role as decision maker in common law and civil law was
so different, indeed allocating them the same decision making powers would
be very unwise from a legal process perspective. The traditional image of a civil
law bureaucratic judge, whose role is not to decide cases in terms of public
policy but of a mere interpreter of the political will contained in a statute (the
code), has been a widespread commonplace of comparative misunderstanding.
0560 Comparative Law and Economics 521
A new fruitful perspective in the study of legal change and legal transplants has
been opened to comparative law and economics by recent developments of
neoinstitutional economics. Particularly, the idea of path-dependence seems to
be a very powerful analytical tool for studying and explaining the evolution of
legal systems, where all innovation, be it endogenous or the result of a
transplant, depends heavily on the existing institutional framework.
Path-dependent systems are those systems that cannot shake off the effects
of past events because small events of a random character, especially those
occurring early on the path, influence the selection of one or another among the
set of stable equilibria. For this reason ex ante predictions of outcomes may not
be possible, and consequently it is difficult to foresee future changes. In this
situation there is a marked distinction between the notion of ex ante efficiency
and ex post efficiency: the final result may not be the most efficient one in a
theoretical world, but it may well be the best achievable in the light of the
existing constraints. In other terms, lock-in phenomena, characterized by
multiple equilibrium processes and dynamic co-ordination games, may yield
Pareto inferior outcomes that tend to be stable (David, 1975). This is a typical
result for decentralized decision situations, where a large number of individual
agents are linked in a social and informational network; therefore, we may use
the term network externalities. In a network context every single decision is
522 Comparative Law and Economics 0560
measurement costs) and those for monitoring and ensuring the implementation
of the agreements, that is for protecting rights (implementation costs).
Production costs, which are the key concept of microeconomic theory, are the
sum of transformation costs and transaction costs. The neoclassical model is
modified in order to take into consideration transaction costs, by posing
asymmetrical information (Akerlof, 1970) and exchanges that are not instant;
it therefore requires mechanisms for ensuring complete and correct
implementations of the agreements. Institutions are created in order to limit
those transaction costs by devising rules that dictate behaviors and by creating
incentives and sanctions that render implementation of agreements easier (as
for example the role of property law in determining rights and protecting
them). Institutions, in short, create the structure in which exchanges take place
(North, 1990); the more complex the exchanges (that is the more we move
away from the neoclassical model of perfect markets), the more sophisticated
and diversified the institutional framework that regulates them. For instance,
contracts are generally multidimensional, not instantaneous and incomplete,
with significant measurement costs and implementation costs. In a setting of
close personal relationships there will be strong incentives to stick to deals and
to perform contracts. In more complex and impersonal contexts those bonds
tend to become weaker, and different mechanisms are required to ensure
implementation, since the drive to opportunistic behaviors is stronger. In this
case, the most efficient solution will be to use a third party that controls the
correctness of the behaviors and can intervene with sanctions in case of
transgression; this new institution will decrease transaction costs for the
bargaining parties, but at the same time it will absorb resources for its own
management, thereby creating a new kind of transaction costs. All those feature
are typical of the structure of the State, which produces public goods like legal
rules and bodies for implementing them (judiciary, administrative agencies,
and so on).
Institutional change is the mechanism that explains the history of every
society, therefore in order to understand historical change we need to focus on
institutions (Braudel, 1977). Changes usually happen in an incremental way,
and they can move both in an efficient or an inefficient direction, depending on
the pre-existing institutional setting and on the kind of incentives they create;
the process, therefore, can be defined as path-dependent. The higher transaction
costs and the less complete the available information, the more the outcome of
evolution will tend to be inefficient. The incremental process of institutional
change is attained by marginal adjustments in response to the variation of
relative prices (technology, information costs, input factors, and so on) and/or
preferences, and it ensures the continuity of systems in spite of their continuous
modification. These variations can be determined both by endogenous and
exogenous factors and they may start both from the formal and informal
institutions. A change of the informal ones is a dispersed process, whereas the
524 Comparative Law and Economics 0560
the other hand the characteristics of these systems and the kind of data that are
required by this type of analysis make it more difficult to build theoretical
models and to make predictions (Crick, 1988). Some efforts in the building of
new models and instruments have already been produced in the field of biology
and other branches that are referred to as sciences of complexity (Stein,
1989). Nevertheless, social scientists, like lawyers and economists, should be
aware that the systems that they study contain volitional agents (that is agents
whose actions reflect intentions based on expectations), and therefore they have
specific characteristics which are absent in biology or other natural phenomena.
Reality shows an enormous variety of systems, and history does not seem
to point to a general trend to evolve towards more efficient solutions. In fact,
many systems with very low returns prove to be extremely resistant, and this
fact seems to contradict the evolutionary hypothesis as applied to institutions
(Alchian, 1950). This enduring inefficiency can be explained by transaction
costs and path-dependence: once an institutional framework has been built, it
affects the possible evolutionary trends; if the kind of incentives it creates are
inefficient, it is very likely that evolution will be inefficient, too (David, 1985).
5.1 Two Examples of Path-dependancy in Law: the HIV Problem and the
Organization of the Legal Profession
The possible use of path-dependence for understanding legal change is
exemplified by the study of legal reactions in the world to the hemophiliacs
with an HIV problem (Mattei, 1997b). This problem struck all legal systems in
the same way, since it has required quick and difficult decisions involving
different areas, like politics, law, culture and technology. The solutions adopted
by several countries (Italy, France, United States, Japan) show that under a
situation of distress all legal systems react with path-dependent solutions, that
is, solutions that are determined by the institutions and organizations that are
already well established. This is also because, by happening simultaneously
everywhere and requiring quick reaction, it could not be expected that solutions
could circulate easily through transplant; in fact, a major difference in legal
transplants runs between those that take place in an incremental and slow way,
due mainly to the prestige of the exported model, and those that are the result
of single instant decisions, as happens after a revolution (for example the
export of Western legal institutions in former Socialist countries) or through
forced imposition (for example in former colonial states).
The technical solution to the hemophiliacs with the HIV problem was
quickly found by introducing heat treatment techniques in the early 1980s, but
the institutional reactions followed different paces and paths. Two sets of
elements have been crucial in shaping the outcomes. The first refers to the
interplay of formal and informal institutions: the more formal institutions are
526 Comparative Law and Economics 0560
at odds with informal ones, the less efficient are the results achieved, since
informal institutions will resist application of rules that contrast with them.
Informal bonds exist in all societies, because they are essential for guaranteeing
order in social relationships. Even if their role is clearer in simple societies, it
remains crucial also in complex developed societies, which have a strong
framework of formal institutions, in the form of moral codes, behavioral norms
and implicit conventions. Those informal rules are diffused and dispersed in
society, and they create what can be generally termed culture, which is the
means of transmission through generations of values that shape behaviors
through teaching and imitation processes. In societies without a state (Sacco
and Gambaro, 1996, pp. 26-27; Sacco, 1996) these kind of ties are very
important and stable, since they shape the relationships of a social group that
is very homogeneous and closely connected by personal bonds (Colson, 1974).
In modern developed societies a general framework of formal institutions is
required to manage complexity, but in smaller and more homogeneous sectors
within it informal rules can still be essential, as for example in the case of rules
of conduct in political parties. The relationship between formal and informal
institutions, which form a complex network, is typical of every society and
every historical epoch, and it is crucial for understanding the patterns of
change; it must be underlined, in any case, that the difference between formal
and informal institutions is a matter of degree, moving along a continuum
(North, 1990). In the short run, culture determines the choices that are made;
in the long run, informal rules may change the institutional framework, and
they may even lead to a change of formal rules. The easiness of this transition
depends on the existing transaction costs: if the costs for propounding values
and ideas are low, they will have a strong push in changing the institutions.
The other element that has influenced the institutional reaction to the HIV
problem concerns the prevailing component of every legal system; broadly
speaking, legal systems may be grouped according to the prevalence of one of
three patterns of law: traditional law, professional law and political law
(Mattei, 1997d). The prevailing pattern will determine the legal reaction in the
short run, creating a process which is path-dependent, because it is determined
by the pre-existing situations. Once more, the time dimension will be crucial,
because the lack of time will make it harder to try and transplant a foreign
solution, making it much more likely that the existing institutions will be used
to perform the new task, as happened in other fields like environmental
pollution, car accidents and illegal immigration. In fact, three out of four
examined systems reacted in a predictable way: the US with the use of tort law
through the judicial system; France and Italy with criminal sanctions and an
administrative compensation system, typical of strongly centralized and
bureaucratic systems. Only Japan reacted in an unpredictable way, by resorting
to tort litigation, instead of the traditional solution of mediation. This outcome
0560 Comparative Law and Economics 527
is due to the strong opposition of hemophiliacs, who wanted the ruling class to
take political responsibility for the HIV problem. The fact that the problem has
turned from legal to political explains a revolutionary, not path-dependent
reaction (Mattei, 1997b).
The importance of the institutional structure of every legal system can also
help to explain the changes undergone by the legal profession in Western
countries, which are not explicable on the basis of the traditional distinction
between common law and civil law (Mattei, 1997c). We may view the legal
profession as an organization that uses the institutional setting to achieve its
ends; in this process it is shaped by existing institutions and in its turn it
influences the evolution of the institutions themselves. The two existing models
of organization for the legal profession are the unitary and the divided bar. As
we have mentioned, the dividing line does not run along the civil law/common
law distinction (Abel and Lewis, 1988): the analysis of some of the worlds
paradigmatic systems (USA, England, France and Germany) shows that there
is a converging trend towards a unified profession since both England and
France, although at a different speed, are moving in that direction, while
Germany and the US have always been using this model (Mattei, 1997c). The
United States are isolated from the rest of the countries in giving strong
incentives to competition and litigation through the use of mechanisms like
aggressive advertising and contingent fees. In European countries, on the other
hand, legal professions do not push in the sense of stimulating the demand for
services, but rather on limiting the supply by rigid control of access to the
profession and on avoiding competition by neighboring professions. The effects
of endogenous pressures, like the introduction of uniform rules by the European
Community, and the push of international competition and the globalization of
markets, may well force relevant changes in the future, but the reactions in the
short run are bound to be path-dependent.
Endnote
Adelstein, Richard P. (1981), The Plea Bargain in England and America: A Comparative Institutional
View, in Burrows, Paul and Veljanovski, Cento G. (eds), The Economic Approach to Law,
London, Butterworths, 226-252.
Ajani, Gianmaria and Mattei, Ugo (1995), Codifying Property Law in the Process of Transition: some
528 Comparative Law and Economics 0560
Insights from Comparative Law and Economics, 19 Hastings International and Comparative
Law Review, 117-137.
Alchian, Armen (1965), Some Economics of Property Rights, 30 Il Politico, 816-829.
Antoniolli Deflorian, Luisa (1995), Il Formante Giurisprudenziale e la Competizione fra il Sistema
Communitario e gli Ordinamenti Interni: la Svolta Inefficiente di Faccini Dori (The Judicial
Formant and Competition Between the Community Legal System and National Systems: the
Inefficient Turn of Faccini Dori), 13 Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato, 735-760.
Antoniolli Deflorian, Luisa (1996), La Struttura Istituzionale del Nuovo Diritto Commune Europeo:
Competizione e Circolazione dei Modelli Giuridici (The Institutional Structure of the New
European Common Law: Competition and Circulation of Legal Models), Trento, Dipartimento di
Scienze Giurdiche.
Benson, Bruce L. (1986), The Lost Victim and other Failures of the Public Law Experiment, 9
Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy, 399-427.
Benson, Bruce L. (1989), Enforcement of Private Property Rights in Primitive Societies: Law Without
Government, 9 Journal of Libertarian Studies, 1-26.
Benson, Bruce L. (1990a), Customary Law with Private Means of Resolving Disputes and Dispensing
Justice: A Description of a Modern System of Law and Order without State Coercion, 9 Journal
of Libertarian Studies, 25-42. Reprinted in Law and Order without State Coercion, in
Veljanovski, Cento (ed.), Regulation, Regulators and the Market, 1991, London, Institute of
Economic Affairs, 159-179.
Benson, Bruce L (1990b), The Enterprise of Law: Justice Without the State, San Francisco, Pacific
Research Institute for Public Policy.
Benson, Bruce L. (1991a), Reciprocal Exchange as the Basis for Recognition of Law: Examples from
American History, 10 Journal of Libertarian Studies, 53-82.
Benson, Bruce L. (1991b), An Evolutionary Contractarian View of Primitive Law: The Institutions
and Incentives Arising under Customary American Indian Law, 5 Review of Austrian Economics,
65-89.
Benson, Bruce L. (1992a), Customary Indian Law: Two Case Studies, in Anderson, Terry L. (ed.),
Property Rights and Indian Economics, Maryland, Rowman and Littlefield Press.
Benson, Bruce L. (1992b), The Development of Criminal Law and Its Enforcement: Public Interest
or Political Transfers, 3 Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines, 79-108.
Benson, Bruce L. (1993), The Impetus for Recognizing Private Property and Adopting Ethical
Behavior in a Market Economy: Natural Law, Government Law, or Evolving Self-Interest, 6
Review of Austrian Economics, 43-80.
Benson, Bruce L. (1994), Emerging from the Hobbesian Jungle: Might Takes and Makes Rights, 5
Constitutional Political Economy, 129-158. Translated into Spanish and republished (1995), Las
Instituciones y Los Derechos de Propiedad al Emerger de la Jungla Hobbesiana: La Fuerza Quita
los Reprinted Derechos y los Crea Libertas, 12, 35-75.
Benson, Bruce L. (1995), Rights, Entitlements, and Individual Responsibility in the Welfare State,
in Karslon, Nils (ed.), Can the Present Problems of Mature Welfare States such as Sweden be
Solved?, Stockholm, City University Press, 88-98.
Benson, Bruce L. (1996), Restitution in Theory and in Practice, 12 Journal of Libertarian Studies,
75-98.
0560 Comparative Law and Economics 529
Brietzke, Paul H. (1994), Designing the Legal Frameworks for Markets in Eastern Europe, 7
Transnational Lawyer, 35-63.
Burrow, Paul and Veljanovski, Cento G. (eds) (1981), The Economic Approach to Law, London,
Butterworths.
Buscaglia, Edgardo (1995), Judicial Reform in Latin America: The Obstacles Ahead, 4(2) Journal
of Latin American Affairs, 8-16.
Buscaglia, Edgardo and Domingo, Pilar (1996), Political and Economic Impediments to Judicial
Reform in Latin America, in Buscaglia, Edgardo, Ratliff, William and Cooter, Robert (eds), Law
and Economics of Development, Greenwood, JAI Press.
Bussani, Mauro and Mattei, Ugo (1997), Making the Other Path Efficient, in Buscaglia, Edgardo,
Ratliff, William and Cooter, Robert, Law and Economics of Development, London, JAI Press.
Centner, Terence J. (1995a), Adopting Good Samaritan Immunity for Defendants in the Horse
Industry, 12 Agriculture and Human Values, 69-78.
Centner, Terence J. (1995b), The New Equine Liability Statutes, 62 Tennessee Law Review,
997-1039.
Centner, Terence J. and Wetzstein, Michael E. (1992), Agricultural Pesticide Contamination of
Groundwater: Developing a Right-to-Spray Law for Blameless Contamination, 14 Journal of
Agricultural Taxation and Law, 38-52.
Cooter, Robert D. (1995), Law and Unified Social Theory, 22 Law and Society, 50-67. Reprinted in
Galligan, D.J. (ed.), Socio-Legal Studies in Context: The Oxford Centre Past and Future,
Blackwell Publishers, Oxford, 50-67.
Cooter, Robert D. and Drexl, Josef (1994), The Logic of Power in the Emerging European
Constitution: Game Theory and the Division of Powers, 14 International Review of Law and
Economics, 307-326.
Cooter, Robert D. and Ginsburg, Tom (1996), Comparative Judicial Discretion: an Emperical Test of
Economic Models, 16 International Review of Land and Economics, 295-313.
Cooter, Robert D. and Gordley, James (1991), Economic Analysis in Civil Law Countries: Past,
Present, Future: Introduction to a Symposium, 11 International Review of Law and Economics,
261-263.
Finsinger, Jrg, Hoehn, T. and Pototschnig, A. (1991), The Enforcement of Product Liability Rules:
A Two-Country Analysis of Court Cases, 11 International Review of Law and Economics,
133-148.
Gambaro A., Candian and Pozzo (1992), Property, Proprit, Eigentum, Padova, Cedam.
Gordley, James (1984), Common Law v. Civil Law: una Distinzione che sta Scomparendo (Common
Law v. Civil Law: a Disappearing Difference), in Cendon, P. (ed.), Studi in Onore, Milano,
Giuffr.
Hansmann, Henry B. and Mattei, Ugo (1998), The Functions of Trust Law: A Comparative and
Economic Analysis, 73 New York University Law Review, 434-479.
Hertig, Gerard (1991a), Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries: Switzerland, 11 International
Review of Law and Economics, 293-300.
Hertig, Gerard (1991b), The European Community,11 International Review of Law and Economics,
331-342.
Hirsch, Werner Z. (1981), Landlord-Tenant Relations Law, in Burrows, Paul and Veljanovski, Cento
G. (eds), The Economic Approach to Law, London, Butterworths.
Kaplow, Louis and Shavell, Steven (1996), Property Rules versus Liability Rules: An Economic
530 Comparative Law and Economics 0560
Mattei, Ugo and Pardolesi, Roberto (1991), Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries: A
Comparative Approach, 11 International Review of Law and Economics, 265-275.
Mattei, Ugo and Pulitini, Francesco (1991), A Competitive Model of Legal Rules, in Breton, Galeotti
and Salmon, Wintrobe (eds), The Competitive State, Dordrecht, Kluwer.
Moller, Michael and Nielsen, Niels Chr. (1994), Okonomers og juristers syn p arv (Economists and
Lawyers View of Inheritance), in Lynge Andersen, Lennart and Mogelvang-Hansen, Peter (eds),
G.E.C. Gad.
Ota, Shozo (1991), Law and Economics in Japan: Hatching Stage, 11 International Review of Law
and Economics, 301-308.
Palmer, Matthew S.R. (1995), Toward an Economics of Comparative Political Organization:
Examining Ministerial Responsibility, 11 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization,
164-188.
Parisi, Francesco (1994) , Alterum non Laedere: An Intellectual History of Civil Liability,
39 American Journal of Jurisprudence, 317-351.
Parisi, Francesco (1999), Rent-Seeking Through Litigation: Adversarial and Inquisitorial
Systems Compared, International Review of Law and Economics, forthcoming.
Parisi, Francesco and Frezza, Giampaolo (1999), Family Law and Successions in U. Mattei (ed.),
Introduction to Italian Law, Boston, Kluwer Law International.
Parisi, Francesco and Frezza, Giampaolo (1999), Il Concorso di Colpa: Analisi Economico-Comparata
(Parte II), in Rivista Trimestrale di Diritto e Procedura Civile forthcoming.
Pastor, Santos (1991), Law and Economics in Spain, 11 International Review of Law and
Economics, 309-317.
Prichard, J. Robert S. (1988), A Systematic Approach to Comparative Law: The Effect of Cost, Fee
and Financing Rules on the Development of the Substantive Law, 17 Journal of Legal Studies,
451-475.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1986), Lawyers, Foreign Lawyers, and Lawyer-Substitutes: The Market for
Regulation in Japan, 27 Harvard International Law Journal, 499-986.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1987), Takeovers in Japan: Opportunism, Ideology and Corporate Control, 35
UCLA Law Review, 1-64.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1989), Water Law in Imperial Japan: Public Goods, Private Claims, and Legal
Convergence, 18 Journal of Legal Studies, 51-77.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1991a), Indentured Prostitution in Imperial Japan: Credible Commitments in the
Commercial Sex Industry, 7 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 89-116.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1991b), Legal Rules in Repeated Deals: Banking in the Shadow of Defection in
Japan, 20 Journal of Legal Studies, 91 ff.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1993a), Columbian Cartel Launches Bid for Japanese Firms, 102 Yale Law
Journal, 2005 ff.
Ramseyer, Mark J. (1993b), Credibly Committing to Efficiency Wages: Cotton Spinning Cartels in
Imperial Japan, University of Chicago Law School Roundtable.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1994a), Explicit Reasons for Implicit Contracts: The Legal Logic to the Japanese
Main Bank System, in Masahiko, Aoki and Patrick, Hugh T. (eds), The Japanese Main Bank
System: Its Relevance For Developing and Transforming Economies, Oxford, Oxford University
Press, 231 ff.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1994b), The Puzzling (In)Dependence of Courts: A Comparative Approach, 23
Journal of Legal Studies, 721-747.
532 Comparative Law and Economics 0560
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1995), The Market for Children: Evidence from Early Modern Japan, 11 Journal
of Law, Economics, and Organization, 27 ff.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1996a), Products Liability Through Private Ordering: Notes on A Japanese
Experiment, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 1823-1840.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1996b), Odd Markets in Japanese History: Law and Economic Growth, New
York, Cambridge University Press.
Ramseyer, J. Mark and Rosenbluth, Frances McCall (1993), Japans Political Marketplace,
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Ramseyer, J. Mark and Nakazato, Minoru (1989), The Rational Litigant: Settlement Amounts and
Verdict Rates in Japan, 18 Journal of Legal Studies, 263 ff.
Rasmussen, David W. and Benson, Bruce L. (eds) (1994), The Economic Anatomy of a Drug War:
Criminal Justice in the Commons, Lanham, MD, Rowman and Littlefield.
Reich, Norbert (1992), Competition between Legal Orders: A New Paradigm of EC Law, 29
Common Market Law Review, 861-896.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1995), Controlling Environmental Policy: The Limits of Public Law in
Germany and The United States, New Haven, Yale University Press.
Rubin, Edward L. (1996), The New Legal Process, the Synthesis of Discourse and the Microanalysis
of Institutions, 109 Harvard Law Review, 1393 ff.
Rudden, Bernard (1987), Economic Theory v. Property Law: The Numerus Clausus Problem, in
Eekelaar, John and Bell, John (eds), Oxford Essays in Jurisprudence, Third Series, Oxford,
Oxford Clarendon Press, 239 ff.
Salzberger, Eli M. (1993), A Positive Analysis of the Doctrine of Separation of Powers, or: Why do
we have an Independent Judiciary?, 13 International Review of Law and Economics, 349-379.
Sinden, J.A. (1994), Learning to Love Japan: Social Norms and Market Incentives, 31 University of
San Diego Law Review, 263 ff.
Skogh, Gorajn (1991), Law and Economics in Sweden, 11 International Review of Law and
Economics, 319-324.
Turnbull, Shann (1997), Evolution of Business and the Corporate Structure, Corporate Directors
Diploma Course, University of New England, Armidale, Australia, Topic 1.1.
Ulen, Thomas S. (1996), Comparative Law and Economics of Federalism,2 Cardozo Electronic Law
Bulletin, http://www.gelso.unitn.it/card-adm/Comparative/Ulen-1996/ulen1.htm.
Watson, Alan (1974), Legal Transplants: An Approach to Comparative Law, Charlottesville, VA,
University Press of Virginia.
Watson, Alan (1978a), Society and Legal Change, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Weigel, Wolfgang (1991), Prospects for Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries: Austria, 11
International Review of Law and Economics, 325-329.
Williams, Philip L. (1994), The Exercise of Market Power: Its Treatment under the Australian and
New Zealand Statutes, 9 Review of Industrial Organization, 607-626.
Other References
Abel, Richard L. and Lewis, Philip S.C. (eds) (1988-89, 3 vols; 1995, abridged updated edition),
Lawyers in Society, Berkeley, University of California Press.
Agostini, Eric (1988), Droit Compar (Comparative Law), Paris, Presses Universitaires de France
0560 Comparative Law and Economics 533
(PUF).
Ajani, Gianmaria (1991), The Soviet Experience with Codification: Theoretical and Comparative
Perspectives in Buxbaum, Richard M.and Hendley, Kathryn (eds), The Soviet Sobranie of Law,
Berkeley, International and Area Studies, University of California at Berkeley.
Ajani, Gianmaria (1995),By Chance and Prestige: Legal Transplants in Russia and Eastern Europe,
43 American Journal of Comparative Law, 93-117.
Akerlof, George A. (1970), The Market for Lemons: Qualitative Uncertainty and the Market
Mechanism, 84 Quarterly Journal of Economics, 488-500.
Alchian, Armen A. (1950), Uncertainty, Evolution and Economic Theory, 58 Journal of Political
Economy, 211-221.
Alchian, Armen A. (1987), Property, The New Pagrave - A Dictionary of Economics, London,
Macmillan.
Arthur, W.B. (1988), Self-reinforcing Mechanisms in Economics, in Anderson, Philip, Arrow,
Kenneth and Pines, David, The Economy as an Evolving Complex System, Reading, MA, Addison
Wesley.
Atiyah, Patrick S. (1987), Common Law, The New Palgrave - A Dictionary of Economics, London,
Macmillan.
Baker, John Hamilton (1990), An Introduction to English Legal History, 2nd edn, London,
Butterworths.
Berman, Harold Joseph (1983) Law and Revolution: The Formation of the Western Legal Tradition,
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Boyd, Robert and Richardson, Peter J. (1985), Culture and the Evolutionary Process, Chicago,
University of Chicago Press.
Braudel, Fernand (1977), Afterthoughts on Material Civilization and Capitalism, Baltimore, Johns
Hopkins University Press.
Calabresi, Guido (1961), Some Thoughts about Risk Distribution and the Law of Torts, 70 Yale Law
Journal, 499-553.
Calabresi, Guido (1970), The Cost of Accidents: A Legal and Economic Analysis, New Haven,
Conn., Yale University Press.
Calabresi, Guido (1982), A Common Law for the Age of Statutes, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press.
Calabresi, Guido (1991), The Pointlessness of Pareto. Carrying Coase Further, 100 Yale Law Joural,
1211-1237.
Calabresi, Guido and Melamed, D. (1972), Property Rules, Liability Rules, Inalienability: One View
of the Cathedral, 85 Harvard Law Review, 1089-1128.
Cannata, Carlo Augusto and Gambaro, Antonio (1989), Lineamenti di storia della giurisprudenza
europea (Elements of History of European Jurisprudence), 4th edn, Torino, Giappichelli.
Castan, Tobenas and Don, Jose (1988), Contemporary Legal Systems of the Western World, 25
Comparative Juridical Review, 105-171.
Cheshire, Geoffrey Chevalier and Burn, Edward Hector (1988), Modern Law of Real Property, 14th
edn, London, Butterworths.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1991), Common Property Rights, The New Palgrave - The World of
Economics, London, Macmillan.
Coase, Ronald (1937), The Nature of the Firm, 4 Economica, 386-405.
534 Comparative Law and Economics 0560
Coase, Ronald ([1960] 1988), The Problem of Social Cost, 3 Journal Law and Economics, 1-44,
(1988), The Firm, the Market and the Law, Chicago, Chicago University Press.
Colson, Elisabeth (1974), Tradition and Contract: The Problem of Order, Chicago, Adeline.
Cooter, Robert (1982), Law and the Imperialism of Economics: an Introduction to the Economic
Analysis of Law and a Review of the Major Books, 29 University of California Los Angeles Law
Review, 1260-1269
Cooter, Robert (1982a), The Cost of Coase, 11 Journal of Legal Studies, 1-33.
Cooter, Robert (1987), The Coase Theorem, The New Palgrave - A Dictionary Of Economics,
London, Macmillan.
Cooter, Robert (1989), The Best Right Laws. Value Foundations of the Economic Analysis of Law,
64 Notre Dame Law Review, 817-837.
Cooter, Robert and Ulen, Thomas (1988), Law and Economics, Glenview, Ill, Scott and Foresman.
Crick, Francis (1988), What Mad Pursuit?, New York.
Damaska, Mirjan R. (1986), The Faces of Justice and State Authority, New Haven, Yale University
Press.
David, Paul A. (1985), Clio and the Economics of QWERTY, 75 American Economic Review,
332-337.
David, Paul A. (1988), Path-Dependence: Putting the Past into the Future of Economics, Institute for
Mathematical Studies in the Social Sciences, Technical Report 533, Stanford University.
David, Paul A. (1975), Technical Choice, Innovation and Economic Growth: Essays on American
and British Experience in the Nineteenth Century, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
David, Ren (ed.) (1971), Sources of Law, International Encyclopedia of Comparative Law,
Tuebingen, Mohr; Den Haag, Nijhoff.
David, Ren and Brierley, John E.C. (1985), Major Legal Systems in the World Today, 3rd edn,
London, Stevens.
Dawson, John Philip (1968), The Oracles of the Law, Westport, Conn.: Greenwood.
Demsetz, Harold (1967), Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 57 American Economic Review,
347-359.
Dias, C.J. et al. (eds) (1981), Lawyers in the Third World: Comparative and Developmental
Perspective, Uppsala: Scandinavian Institute of African Studies; New York, International Center
for Law in Development.
Dworkin, Ronald M. (1978), Taking Rights Seriously, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Eggertsson, Thrainn (1990), Economic Behavior and Institution, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press.
Eisenberg, Melvin Aron (1988), The Nature of the Common Law, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press.
Epstein, Richard A. (1985), Takings: Private Property and the Power of Eminent Domain,
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Epstein, Richard A. (1986), Past and Future: The Temporal Dimension in the Law of Property, 64
Washington University Law Quarterly, 667-722.
Eskridge, William N. and Frickey, Philip P. (1994), The Making of the Legal Process, 107 Harvard
Law Review, 2031- 2055.
0560 Comparative Law and Economics 535
Friedman, David (1987), Law and Economics, The New Palgrave - A Dictionary of Economics,
London, Macmillan.
Gambaro, Antonio (1983), Il Succeso del Giurista, 5 Foro Italiano, 85-93.
Gambaro, Antonio (1992), Property, in Gambaro, Antonio et al. (1992), Property, Proprit,
Eigentum, Padova, CEDAM.
Gambaro, Antonio (1994), Codes and Constitutions in Civil Law, in Rabello, Alfredo Mordechai
(ed.), European Legal Tradition and Israel, Jerusalem, Nevo.
Gely, Rafael and Spiller, Pablo T. (1990), A Rational Choice Theory of Supreme Court Statutory
Decisions with Applications to the State Farm anf Grove City Cases, 6 Journal of Law,
Economics and Organization, 263-300.
Gilmore, Grant (1977), The Ages of American Law, New Haven: Yale University Press.
Glendon, Mary Ann, Gordon, Michael Wallace and Osakwe, Christopher (1994), Comparative Legal
Traditions, 2nd edn, St Paul, Minn., West Publishing.
Gordley, James (1991), The Philosophical Origin of Modern Contract Doctrine, Oxford, Clarendon.
Gordley, James (1993), Common Law and Civil Law, 3 Zeitschrift fr Europisches Privatrecht,
498 ff.
Gordley, James (1994), Common Law versus Civil Law: una Distinzione che sta Scomparendo
(Common Law versus Civil Law: a Disappearing Difference), in Cendon, P. (ed.), Studi in Onore
di Rodolfo Sacco, Milano, Giuffr.
Gordley, James and Mattei, Ugo (1996), Protecting Possession, 44 American Journal of
Comparative Law.
Gorla, Gino (1981), Diritto Comparato e Diritto Comune Europeo (Comparative Law and European
Common Law), Milano, Giuffr.
Grande, Elisabetta (ed.) (1995), Transplants, Innovation and Legal Tradition in the Horn of Africa,
Torino: Harmattan.
Graziadei, Michele and Rudden, Bernard (1992), Il Diritto Inglese dei Beni ed il Trust: Dalle Res al
Fund (The English Law on Goods and the Trust: from Res to Fund), Quadrimestre 458
Hart, Henry M. and Sachs, Albert M. ([1958] 1994), The Legal Process. Basic Problems in the
Making and Application of Law, edited by W.M. Eskridge and P.P. Frickey, Westbury, NY.
Hart, Herbert Lionel A. (1961), The Concept of Law, Oxford, Clarendon.
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1960), The Constitution of Liberty, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1973), Law, Legislation and Liberty, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Heiner, Ronald (1986), Imperfect Decisions and the Law: On the Evolution of Legal Precedent and
Rules, 15 Journal Legal Studies, 227-262.
Hirshleifer, Jack (1987), Economic Behavior in Adversity, Chicago, Chicago University Press.
Horn, Norbert, Kotz, Hein and Leser, Hans G., translated by Weir, Tony (1982), German Private and
Commercial Law. An Introduction, Oxford, Clarendon Press.
Horwitz, Morton J. (1992), The Transformation of American Law 1870-1960, The Crisis of Legal
Hortodoxy, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Hovenkamp, Herbert (1990), Positivism in Law and Economics, 78 California Law Review,
815-852.
536 Comparative Law and Economics 0560
Laffont, J.J (1987), Externalities, The New Palgrave - A Dictionary of Economics, London,
Macmillan.
Lawson, Frederick Henry and Rudden, Bernard (1984), An Introduction to the Law of Property,
Oxford, Clarendon Press.
Legrand, Pierre (1995), Strange Power of Words: Codification Situated, 9 Tulane European and
Civil Law Forum, 1 ff.
Lupoi, Maurizio (1994), Introduzione ai Trusts (An Introduction to the Law of Trusts), Milano:
Giuffr.
Malloy, R.P. Evensky, J. (eds) (1994), Adam Smith and the Philosophy of Law and Economics,
Dordrecht, Kluwer.
Manne, Henry J. (1977), The Economics of Legal Relationship, Readings in the Theory of Property
Rights, St Paul, West Publishing.
Mattei, Ugo (1988), Stare Decisis, Milano, Giuffr.
Mattei, Ugo (1994e), Common Law: Il Diritto Anglo-Americano (Common Law: Anglo-American
Law), Torino, UTET.
Mattei, Ugo (1994f), Why the Wind Changed: Intellectual Leadership in Western Law, 42 American
Journal of Comparative Law, 195-218.
Mattei, Ugo (1994g), Verso una Tripartizione non Eurocentrica dei Sistemi Giuridici (Towards a
non-Eurocentric Tripartition of Legal Systems), in Studi in memoria di Gino Gorla.
Merryman, John Henry (1969), The Civil Law Tradition: An Introduction to the Legal Systems of
Western Europe and Latin America, Stanford, Stanford University Press.
Michelman, Frank I. (1971), Pollution as a Tort: A Non-accidental Perspective on Calabresis Costs,
80 Yale Law Journal, 647-686.
Milsom, Stroud Francis Charles (1969), Historical Foundations of the Common Law, London,
Butterworths.
Monateri, Pier Giuseppe (1986), Legal Doctrine as a Source of Law: A Transnational Factor and a
Historical Paradox, Italian National Reports, 12 Congress of the International Academy of
Comparative Law, Milano, Giuffr.
Monateri, Pier Giuseppe (1984), La Sineddoche (The Synecdoche), Milano, Giuffr.
Monateri, Pier Giuseppe, Sacco, Rodolfo (1998), Legal Formants, in The New Palgrave - A
Dictionary of Economics, London, Macmillan.
Nader, Laura (1967), The Anthropological Study of Law, 67 American Anthropologist, 3 ff.
North, Douglass C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass C. (1994), Istitutuzioni, Cambiamento Istituzionale, Evoluzione dellEconomia
(Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance), Bologna, Il Mulino.
Pejovic, Svetozar (1990), The Economics of Property Rights: Towards A Theory of Comparative
Systems, Dordrecht, Kluwer.
Pelikan, P. (1987), The Formation of Incentive Mechanisms in Different Economic Systems, in
Hedlund Stefan (ed.), Incentives in Economic Systems, New York, New York University Press.
Pigou, Arthur C. (1960), The Economics of Welfare, 4th edn, New York, NY, Macmillan.
Pizzorusso, Alessandro and Capotorti, Francesco (1988), Law in the Making: A Comparative Survey,
Berlin, Springer.
0560 Comparative Law and Economics 537
Polinsky, A. Mitchell (1989), An Introduction to Law and Economics, 2nd edn, Boston, MA, Little,
Brown.
Posner, Richard (1992), Economic Analysis of the Law, 4th edn, Boston, MA, Little, Brown.
Prosser, William Lloyd and Keeton, W. Page (1984), The Law of Torts, 5th edn, St Paul, Minn., West.
Rabello, Alfredo Mordechai (ed.) (1994), European Legal Tradition and Israel, Jerusalem, Nevo.
Rebuffa, Giorgio (1981), Analisi giuridica ed analisi economica (Legal analysis and economic
analysis), in Tarello, Giovanni (1981), Materiali per una Storia della Cultura Giuridica
(Materials for a History of Legal Culture), Bologna, Il Mulino.
Reyntjens, Filip (1991), Note sur lUtilit dIntroduire un Systme Juridique "Pluraliste" dans la
Macro-Comparaison des Droits (Note on the Utility of Introducing a "Pluralist" Legal System in
the Macro-Comparison of Law), Revue du Droit International et Droit Compar, 41.
Rouland, Norbert (1988), Anthropologie Juridique (Legal Anthropology), Paris, Presses Universitaires
de France.
Rudden, Bernard (1994), Things as Thing and Things as Wealth, 14 Oxford Journal of Legal
Studies, 81-97.
Sacco, Rodolfo (1974), Les Buts et les Mthodes de la Comparaison du Droit (Aims and Methods of
Comparative law), in X (ed.), Rapports Nationaux Italiens au IX Congrs de Droit Compar,
Teheran, Milano, Giuffr.
Sacco, Rodolfo (1991), Legal Formants, A Dynamic Approach to Comparative Law, 39 American
Journal of Comparative Law, 1-39; 343-401
Sacco, Rodolfo (1992a), The Uniformization of Private Law, in Pizzorusso, Alessandro (ed.), Italian
Studies in Law 1.
Sacco, Rodolfo (1992b), Introduzione al Diritto Comparato (Introduction to Comparative Law)
Torino, UTET.
Sacco, Rodolfo (1996), Diritto dei Paesi Africani (Law of African Countries), Torino: UTET.
Sacco, Rodolfo and Gambaro, Antonio (1996), Sistemi Giuridici Comparati (Comparative Legal
Systems), Torino, UTET.
Schlesinger, Rudolf B. (1969), Formation of Contract. A Study into the Common Core of Legal
Systems, Dobbs Ferry, Oceana.
Schlesinger, Rudolf B. et al. (1988), Comparative Law: Cases, Texts, Materials, 5th edn, Mineola,
Foundation.
Schuck, Peter H. (1991), Tort Law and the Public Interest, New York, Norton.
Shapiro, Martin M. (1981), Courts: A Comparative and Political Analysis, Chicago, University of
Chicago Press.
Simmonds, N.E. (1987), Natural Law, in The New Palgrave - A Dictionary of Economics, London,
Macmillan.
Simon, Herbert (1986), Rationality in Psychology and Economics, in Hogarth, R.M. and Reder, M.W.
(eds), The Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory, 59 Journal of Business (supplement),
209-224.
Simpson, Alfred William Brian (1987), A History of the Common Law of Contract, Oxford:
Clarendon.
Smith, Adam (1981a), Lectures on Jurisprudence, edited by R.L. Mek, D.D. Raphael and P.G. Stein,
Indianapolis, Liberty Classics.
538 Comparative Law and Economics 0560
Smith, Adam (1981b), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations edited by R.H.
Campbell and A.S. Skinner, Indianapolis, Liberty Classics.
Sonneveldt, Frans and van Mens, Herrie L. (eds) (1992), The Trust. Bridge or Abyss Between
Common Law and Civil Law Jurisdictions?, Deventer; Boston, Kluwer.
Stein, Daniel L. (1989), Lectures in the Sciences of Complexity, Redwood City, CA, Addison Wesley.
Stein, Peter (1984), Legal Institutions: the Development of Dispute Settlement, London, Butterworths.
Stein, Peter and Shand, John (1974), Legal Values in Western Society, Edinburgh, Edinburgh
University Press.
Stigler, George (1987), Competition, The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, London,
Macmillan.
Sugden, R. (1989), Spontaneous Order, 3 Journal of Economic Perspectives, 85-98.
Symposium (1993), Selecting Minds, 41 American Journal of Comparative Law, 351-499.
Symposium (1980), Efficiency as Legal Concern, 8 Hofstra Law Review, 485-770.
Symposium (1987), Economists on the Bench, 50 Law and Contemporary Problems, 1-286.
Symposium (1989), Post-Chicago Law and Economics, 65 Chicago-Kent Law Review, 23-191.
Symposium (1996), Law, Economics and Norms, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law Review.
Van Caenegem, Raoul Charles (1987), Judges, Legislators and Professors: Chapters in European
Legal History, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1643-2339.
Vanderlinden, Jacques (1982), A Propos des Familles de Droits en Droit Civil Compar, in X. (ed.),
Hommages R. Dekkers, Bruxelles, Bruylant, 363 ff.
Varga, Csaba (1991), Codification as a Socio-Historical Phenomenon, Budapest: Akademiai Kiado.
Vining, Joseph (1984), Legal Identity: The Coming Age of the Public Law, New Haven, Yale
University Press.
Von Mehren, Arthur Taylor and Gordley, James (1977), The Civil Law System: An Introduction to
the Comparative Study of Law, 2nd edn, Boston, Little Brown.
Watson, Alan (1978b), Comparative Law and Legal Change, 313 Cambridge Law Journal, 318 ff.
Watson, Alan (1993), Legal Transplants: An Approach to Comparative Law, 2nd edn, Athens,
University of Georgia Press.
Watson, Alan (1995), From Legal Transplants to Legal Formants, 43 American Journal of
Comparative Law, 469-476.
White, J.B. (1987), Economics and Law: Two Cultures in Tension, 54 Tennessee Law Review,
161-202.
Wiegand, Wolfgang (1991), Reception of American Law in Europe, 39 American Journal of
Comparative Law, 229-248.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1991), Economic Institutions: Spontaneous and Intentional Governance, 7
Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 159-187.
Zweigert, Konrad and Ktz, Hein (1998), An Introduction to Comparative Law, 3rd edn (translated
from the German by Weir, Tony), Oxford, Clarendon.
0570
EXPERIMENTAL LAW AND ECONOMICS
Richard H. McAdams
Professor of Law, Boston University School of Law
Copyright 1999 Richard H. McAdams
Abstract
A. Introduction
1. Introduction
539
540 Experimental Law and Economics 0570
2. Experimental Methodology
expected utility theory, cognitive errors and biases. For reviews, see Camerer
(1995), Davis and Holt (1993, pp. 435-504); Thaler and Tversky (1992).
The nature of individual decision making is obviously important to legal
analysis. Consider two examples. First, Hoffman and Spitzer (1993), survey the
extensive economic literature on the difference in willingness to pay and
willingness to accept, finding the deviation relevant to the choice between
property and liability rules (pp. 104-112). This subject is perhaps the topic of
greatest overlap with psychological experiments. For examples, see Korobkin
(1998) and Rachlinski and Jourden (1998).
Second, the quality of decision making under risk is relevant to virtually any
area of law. Hasen (1990), for example, finds one area of this research -
framing effects - relevant to the rules governing products liability and
contracts of adhesion. A separate issue is how differences in risk-preferences
might affect legal analysis. Block and Gerety (1995) report an experiment
showing that students are more risk averse than prisoners. Relative to one
another, students were deterred more by increases in the severity of
punishment, while prisoners were more sensitive to changes in the certainty.
Brinig (1995a, 1995b) reports experimental data on the link between gender
and risk aversion and considers how a gender gap in risk preference could be
relevant to divorce law.
Bargaining
Bargaining experiments test how frequently individuals will reach agreement
and how frequently the agreement will be efficient. For reviews, see Davis and
Holt (1993, pp. 241-275) and Roth (1995b). This subject is the matter at issue
in the Coase Theorem and of great relevance when choosing between liability
and property rules. See Hoffman and Spitzer (1985, pp. 1009-1013).
Bargaining experiments are also relevant to predicting settlement of litigation
0570 Experimental Law and Economics 543
Auctions.
Auction experiments isolate the conditions that facilitate and hinder
competitive pricing. For reviews, see Davis and Holt (1993, pp. 125-172,
275-305) and Kagel (1995). Competitive pricing is an obvious concern of
antitrust law. In addition, these experiments reveal incentive-compatible
means of measuring the demand for public goods - a matter relevant to efficient
regulation and taxation (see Hoffman and Spitzer, 1985, pp. 1002-1009,
1015-1020). Auction experiments are also relevant to public contract law, by
which the government seeks to structure competitive bidding to obtain
competitive prices. See, for example, Ayres and Cramton (1996); Marshall,
Meurer and Richard (1991).
Industrial Organization
Experiments in industrial organization reveal how different institutions and
industrial structures facilitate competition or collusion, central issues for
antitrust and consumer protection law. For reviews, see Davis and Holt (1993,
pp. 173-240) and Holt (1995). Experimental markets also reveal the number of
informed shoppers and the level of warranty enforcement necessary to ensure
competitive pricing, a subject of obvious import for consumer protection law,
contracts and antitrust (see Hoffman and Spitzer, 1985b, pp. 1021-1023).
Many law and economics scholars have begun to apply the data from economic
(and other) experiments to the economic analysis of law. The applications grow
increasingly common. For an illustrative example, see Jolls, Sunstein and
Thaler (1998). Law and economics scholars have also contributed directly to
this literature by conducting experiments themselves. Two series of law and
economics experiments deserve extended attention, which begins in the next
section: (1) experiments relating to the Coase Theorem, that is, that concern
bargaining around legal entitlements; and (2) experiments relating to pre-trial
544 Experimental Law and Economics 0570
0 0.00 12.00
1 4.00 10.00
546 Experimental Law and Economics 0570
2 6.00 6.00
3 8.00 4.00
4 9.00 2.00
5 10.00 1.00
6 11.00 0.00
1 10 No 0
2 10 Yes 20
cooperative gain and only 65 percent (70) included the efficient relocation
clause. Nonetheless, Schwab confirms what he terms the weak efficiency
hypothesis. For the relocation term, Schwab had created varying contract
presumptions, specifying that, unless otherwise agreed, the company either
could or could not relocate. Regardless of condition, there was no statistically
significant difference in the number of contracts requiring the company to stay
or in the number of contracts reaching the optimal result for this issue, which
varied across contracts within each condition (p. 252). Thus, the parties
achieved roughly the same less-than-perfect level of efficiency regardless of
how the legal entitlement was allocated.
Because there are many differences between Schwabs experiment and the
Hoffman and Spitzer design, it is not possible, without additional work, to
specify which conditions produced the different rates of efficient contracts.
Perhaps Schwabs results apply to complex bargaining over a set of issues while
the earlier experiments are valid for bargaining over an single issue. Or,
possibly, Schwab failed to induce the subjects to put forth enough effort because
he did not pay them for their efforts. Perhaps, however, the Hoffman and
Spitzer design is flawed because it remains abstracted from actual legal
entitlements: (i) the controller subjects are never told that the law gives them
the right to select the control number, and (ii) the non-controller subject is
never told that he or she suffers from an externality caused (in part) by the
controller. If these omissions are important, Schwabs experiment may have
elicited typical emotional reactions that impede bargaining, while Hoffman and
Spitzers design did not. To use one of Hoffman and Spitzers examples, it
would be interesting to employ their design, but to inform the subjects that, for
purposes of the experiment, they should assume that one of them owns a noisy,
smelly dog kennel and the other owns a nearby residence, and that the law
entitles one of them to select unilaterally the level of kennel operations.
Admittedly, Hoffman and Spitzer found similar results (concerning
efficiency) when subjects were told one of them earned the right to be
controller by defeating the other subject in a simple game. But perhaps parties
bargain differently if they are told - as Schwabs subjects were - that the source
of their entitlements is legal. Hoffman and Spitzer also used SOA to test
whether subjects would bargain over matters affecting their dignity. But the
abstract experimental design does not make it appear that one subject (rather
than the experimenter) is causing or threatening to cause the other to taste
SOA. Providing a real world factual scenario - where a kennel owner causes the
neighbor to smell something unpleasant - might invoke a different or stronger
set of emotions and impede bargaining.
Of course, Schwabs results confirm Hoffman and Spitzer on the claim that
legal entitlements will not affect the degree to which people bargain to the
efficient result. But the experiments do not yet justify Hoffman and Spitzers
550 Experimental Law and Economics 0570
claim for a factual presumption that parties will bargain around legal
entitlements. What their experiments appear to demonstrate is that, if potential
bargainers are (i) enticed by money or grades to meet together in a room and
(ii) invited to bargain, then the initial assignment of entitlements will not affect
the percentage of efficient agreements they create. Hoffman and Spitzer
generalize from this data to predict how people in the real world will react to
externalities. Yet many individuals may never consider offering to sell or buy
a legal entitlement that is not explicitly a market good. The neighbor of the dog
kennel may not - without the kind of prompting provided in the experiment -
consider offering the kennel owner money to limit the noise or smell of his
operations. In addition, when individuals are interested in bargaining - and
especially when large groups are involved - a crucial barrier may be the cost of
gathering the parties together at a single place and time. Indeed, one strategy
of hard bargaining is to pretend to be uninterested in even meeting with the
other side. However compelling the experiments are for demonstrating what
happens after parties meet for the purpose of bargaining, they do not provide
evidence that parties in the real world will get that far.
In sum, even though this area is one of the richest for experimental work,
these experiments only begin to identify the conditions under which
face-to-face bargaining will achieve an efficient outcome.
researchers told the subjects the winner had earned that right. (2) Some
controllers were selected by a coin flip and told that the winner earned the
right. The remaining controllers were selected by winning (3) the game or (4)
a coin flip, but with no statement. In the latter two conditions, with no moral
authority statement, 61 percent of the bargains resulted in nearly even splits
(p. 275). Conversely, in the first condition, with the game plus moral
authority, only 32 percent were nearly even splits. The second condition fell
in between: 50 percent nearly even splits (p. 277). Further analysis revealed
that the moral authority statement significantly affected the allocation; the
method of selection was also weakly significant (p. 280).
Hoffman and Spitzer speculate about the significance of these interesting
findings. But they do not acknowledge the potential limitation the results have
for the design of their experiment: fairness might be a restraint on bargaining.
If individuals react strongly to the perceived fairness of the situation - if they
are willing to sacrifice money in order to achieve a fair outcome - then they
might refuse to consent to a bargain that produced an unfair result, even if it
constituted the joint maximum payoff. Perhaps an individual would think it
unfair for a polluter to benefit by being paid to refrain from exercising its
legal entitlement to pollute. As stated above, one cannot confidently predict that
parties will bargain around legal entitlements in the real world unless the
experiment has attempted to elicit all the responses - including, potentially,
fairness concerns - that might inhibit bargaining. Yet the Hoffman and Spitzer
design, though it elicits such fairness concerns in the distribution of the payoff,
seems too abstract to test fairness as a constraint on bargaining. For a more
general discussion of fairness in experiments, see Roth (1995b, pp. 270-274,
279-281).
Perhaps the concern is overstated. In the similar experiment by Harrison
and McKee (1985), researchers used a coin flip to select the controller, but their
experiment provided different explanations for the payoff sharing in these
experiments. First, they found that altruistic payoff divisions declined as the
stakes increased (p. 662). Increasing the available surplus from $1 to $2
decreased such divisions from 60 percent (9 of 15) to 11 percent (1 of 9).
Second, learning decreased altruistic payoff divisions (p. 665). Harrison and
McKee created a condition involving joint property rights, where both parties
must agree to the number or they receive either a random payoff or a payoff of
zero. When subjects trained under this condition were then given the power
of a unilateral controller, they received at least their individual maxima payoff
in 76.5 percent (13 of 17) of the bargains.
With these manipulations, the legal entitlements did affect the distribution
of wealth, almost as much as theory predicts. But there is one situation where
economic theory does not expect an entitlement to affect distribution: where it
merely states a presumption. Nonetheless, Schwab (1988) found that a waivable
552 Experimental Law and Economics 0570
Law and economics scholars have also used experiments to investigate pre-trial
bargaining and settlement. Along with empirical studies of litigation, the
accumulated evidence is beginning to have some effect on the theoretical
models describing the decision to proceed to trial. Settlement models are also
affected by psychology experiments on the subject. For example, see Korobkin
and Guthrie (1997).
As a preliminary matter, note that the Coase Theorem experiments reviewed
above (and bargaining experiments generally) are relevant to the settlement of
litigation. Both involve bargaining with potential cooperative surplus. The
Hoffman and Spitzer design is sufficiently abstract to encompass litigation
settlement, if one imagines the controller - whether A or B - as a plaintiff who
can, by going to trial, obtain a judgment equal to the maximum payoff available
to him or her on the payoff schedule. The joint maximum represents the
settlement alternative, larger than any non-cooperative outcome because it
avoids the costs of trial. If so, the results are encouraging because litigation is
a context in which parties, or their agents, usually contemplate a bargaining
solution. Nonetheless, the limitations of the Coase Theorem experiments are
significant, most notably because they do not model the risks involved in the
outcome of litigation.
0570 Experimental Law and Economics 553
More recent studies continue to use very simple bargaining games to study
pre-trial negotiation and settlement. Thomas (1995) created a settlement game
with monetary payoffs. He gave the subjects (students) an estimate of the
expected outcome of trial along with a range of error uniformly distributed
around the estimate. He found support for the Priest-Klein claim that disputes
close to the decision standard - meaning where the defendants conduct is just
above or below the level at which liability is imposed - go to trial at a higher
rate than do other disputes. He could not confirm a second claim, however,
that the improvements in the ability of parties to evaluate information increase
556 Experimental Law and Economics 0570
the settlement rate, though the coefficient for error had the expected sign (p.
219).
Croson and Mnookin (1997) conducted an experiment to test the claim of
Gilson and Mnookin (1994) that parties to a lawsuit can achieve gains by
employing lawyers as agents. The claim is that lawyers develop reputations for
conducting litigation either in a highly contentious and costly manner - as
gladiators - or a cooperative mode - as cooperators. If parties who do not
trust each other choose cooperative agents, they may lower the joint costs of
conducting the litigation. To test the idea, Croson and Mnookin ran modified
prisoners dilemma games in which subjects (law students) chose one or the
other type of lawyer (or a third type without a reputation) to represent them for
10 rounds. In the litigation game, the dominant strategy was to select a
gladiator, which most subjects did. But in the prelitigation game, a subject
could change his or her lawyer if, but only if, he or she had selected a
cooperator for the prior round but the opponent had selected a gladiator. For
this game, there are two Nash equilibria - two cooperators or two defectors. The
result was that 76 percent of subjects employed cooperators in the prelitigation
game as opposed to 17.5 percent in the litigation game (p. 341). Generalizing
the result is difficult, however, since litigants in the real world are able to
switch from, as well as to, gladiators.
In sum, the experiments on litigation settlement are not yet sufficiently
plentiful to allow strong generalizations. As with experiments on Coasean
bargaining, there is some indication - not yet proved or disproved - that the
process of negotiation may be affected by the factual nature of what is being
negotiated.
D. Conclusion
Experimentation is still relatively new to economics and even more novel for
law and economics. Kagel and Roth (1995) and Davis and Holt (1993)
comprehensively review the experimental economics literature, virtually all of
which is relevant to law. Two series of bargaining experiments directly test
claims of law and economics theory: experiments related to the Coase theorem
and to pre-trial settlement. Both are still fairly undeveloped, leaving open a
great need for further work merely to resolve the different results of existing
experiments. Such work could be very fruitful as experimentation remains a
powerful tool for testing and refining theory.
0570 Experimental Law and Economics 557
Acknowledgments
Ashenfelter, Orley, Currie, Janet, Farber, Henry S. and Spiegel, Matthew (1992), An Experimental
Comparison of Dispute Rates in Alternative Arbitration Systems, 60 Econometrica, 1407-1433.
Babcock, Linda, Loewenstein, George, Issacharoff, Samuel and Camerer, Colin F. (1995), Biased
Judgments of Fairness in Bargaining, 85 American Economic Review, 1337 ff.
Block, Michael K. and Gerety, Vernon E. (1995), Some Experimental Evidence on Differences
between Student and Prisoner Reactions to Monetary Penalties and Risk, 24 Journal of Legal
Studies, 123-138.
Brinig, Margaret F. (1995a), Does Mediation Systematically Disadvantage Women?, 2 William and
Mary Journal of Women and the Law, 1-34.
Brinig, Margaret F. (1995b), Why Cant a Woman be More Like a Man? or Do Gender Differences
Affect Choice?, in Simon, Rita J. (ed.), Neither Victim nor Enemy, Lanham, MD, University Press
of America, 29-59.
Camerer, Colin (1995), Individual Decision Making, in Kagel, John H. and Roth, Alvin E. (eds), The
Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton, Princeton University Press, 587-703.
Coursey, Don L. and Stanley, Linda R. (1988), Pretrial Bargaining Behavior within the Shadow of the
Law: Theory and Experimental Evidence, 8 International Review of Law and Economics,
161-179.
Coursey, Don L., Hoffman, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1987), Fear and Loathing in the Coase
Theorem: Experimental Tests Involving Physical Discomfort, 16 Journal of Legal Studies,
217-248.
Coursey, Don L., Isaac, R. Mark and Smith, Vernon L. (1984), Natural Monopoly and Contested
Markets: Some Experimental Results, 27 Journal of Law and Economics, 91-113.
Crafton, Steven M. and Brinig, Margaret F. (1994), Quantitative Methods for Lawyers, Durham, NC,
Carolina Academic Press.
Croson, Rachel and Mnookin, Robert H. (1997), Does Disputing Through Agents Enhance
Cooperation? Experimental Evidence, 26 Journal of Legal Studies, 331-345.
Davis, Douglas and Holt, Charles A. (1993),Experimental Economics, Princeton, Princeton University
Press.
Dutta, Shantanu and John, George (1995), Combining Lab Experiments and Industry Data in
Transaction Cost Analysis: The Case of Competition as a Safeguard, 11 Journal of Law,
Economics and Organization, 87-111.
Forsythe, Robert, Kennan, John and Sopher, Barry (1991), An Experimental Analysis of Bargaining
and Strikes with One-sided Private Information, 81 American Economic Review, 253-278.
558 Experimental Law and Economics 0570
Gay, David E.R. (1992), Teaching Privatization in the Soviet Union: An Experimental Economics
Approach, 1 Classroom Expernomics, 5-6.
Harrison, Glenn W. and McKee, Michael (1985), Experimental Evaluation of the Coase Theorem,
28 Journal of Law and Economics, 653-670.
Harrison, Glenn W., Hoffman, Elizabeth, Rustrom, E.E. and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1987), Coasian
Solutions to the Externality Problem in Experimental Markets, 97 Economic Journal, 388-402.
Hoffman, Elizabeth (1985), Bibliography of Work on Experimental Economicsa, 85 Columbia Law
Review, 1025-1035.
Hoffman, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1982), The Coase Theorem: Some Experimental Tests,
25 Journal of Law and Economics, 73-98.
Hoffman, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1985a), Entitlements, Rights, and Fairness: An
Experimental Examination of Subjects Concepts of Distributive Justice, 14 Journal of Legal
Studies, 259-297.
Hoffman, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1985b), Experimental Law and Economics: An
Introduction, 85 Columbia Law Review, 991-1024.
Hoffman, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1986), Experimental Tests of the Coase Theorem with
Large Bargaining Groups, 15 Journal of Legal Studies, 149-171.
Hoffman, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1993), Willingness to Pay vs. Willingness to Accept:
Legal and Economic Implications, 71 Washington University Law Quarterly, 59-114.
Hoffman, E., McCabe, Kevin A., Shachat, K. and Smith, V.K. (1994), Preferences, Property Rights
and Anonymity in Bargaining Games, 7 Games and Economic Behavior, 346-380.
Holt, Charles A. (1989), The Exercise of Market Power in Laboratory Experiments, 32S Journal of
Law and Economics, 107-130.
Holt, Charles A. (1995), Industrial Organizations: A Survey of Laboratory Research, in Kagel, John
H. and Roth, Alvin E. (eds), The Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton, Princeton
University Press, 349-444.
Kagel, John H. (1995), Auctions: A Survey of Experimental Research, in Kagel, John H. and Roth,
Alvin E. (eds), The Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton, Princeton University Press,
501-586.
Kagel, John H. and Roth, Alvin E. (eds) (1995), Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton,
Princeton University Press.
Kelman, Mark G. (1985), Comment on Hoffman and Spitzers Experimental Law and Economics,
85 Columbia Law Review, 1037-1047.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. and Schotter, Andrew (1990), An Experimental Study of Single-Actor
Accidents, 19 Journal of Legal Studies, 203-233.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. and Schotter, Andrew (1992), An Experimental Study of Two-Actor Accidents,
C.V. Starr Center for Applied Economics, Research Report, No. 92-57.
Ledyard, John O. (1995), Public Goods: A Survey of Experimental Research, in Kagel, John H. and
Roth, Alvin E. (eds), The Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton, Princeton University
Press, 111-194.
Loewenstein, George, Issacharoff, Samuel, Camerer, Colin and Babcock, Linda (1993), Self-Serving
Assessments of Fairness and Pretrial Bargaining, 22 Journal of Legal Studies, 135-159.
0570 Experimental Law and Economics 559
McCabe, Kevin A., Rassenti, Stephen J. and Smith, Vernon L. (1991), Experimental Research on
Deregulated Markets for Natural Gas Pipeline and Electric Power Transmission Networks, 13
Research in Law and Economics, 161-189.
Ochs, Jack (1995), Coordination Problems, in Kagel, John H. and Roth, Alvin E. (eds), The
Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton, Princeton University Press, 195-251.
Plott, Charles R. (1991), Will Economics Become an Experimental Science?, 57 Southern Economic
Journal, 901-919.
Rabin, Matthew (1998), Psychology and Economics, 36 Journal of Economic Literature, 11-46.
Radner, Roy and Schotter, Andrew (1989), The Sealed Bid Mechanisms: An Experimental Study, 48
Journal of Economic Theory, 179-220.
Roth, Alvin E. (web), Web Page on Game Theory and Experimental Economics, at
http://www.pitt.edu:81/~alroth.html.
Roth, Alvin E. (1986), Laboratory Experimentation in Economics, 2 Economics and Philosophy,
245-273.
Roth, Alvin E. (1987a), Introduction and Overview, in Roth, Alvin E. (ed.), Laboratory
Experimentation in Economics: Six Points of View, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press,
1-13.
Roth, Alvin E. (ed.) (1987b), Laboratory Experimentation in Economics: Six Points of View,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Roth, Alvin E. (1988), Laboratory Experimentation in Economics: A Methodological Overview, 89
Economics Journal, 974 ff.
Roth, Alvin E. (1993), The Early History of Experimental Economics, 15 Journal of the History of
Economic Thought, 184-209.
Roth, Alvin E. (1994), Lets Keep the Con Out of Experimental Econ.: A Methodological Note, 19S
Empirical Economics, 279-289.
Roth, Alvin E. (1995a), Introduction to Experimental Economics, in Kagel, John H. and Roth, Alvin
E. (eds), The Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton, Princeton University Press,
3-109.
Roth, Alvin E. (1995b), Bargaining Experiments, in Kagel, John H. and Roth, Alvin E. (eds), The
Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton, Princeton University Press, 253-348.
Schwab, Stewart (1988), A Coasean Experiment on Contract Presumptions, 17 Journal of Legal
Studies, 237-268.
Shelanski, H. and Klein, Peter G. (1995), Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Economics: A
Review and Assessment, 11 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization in Frech, H.E. (ed.),
Regulating Doctors Fees: Competition, Benefits, and Controls under Medicare, Washington,
DC, American Enterprise Institute, 335 ff.
Shogren, Jason F. (1992), An Experiment on Coasian Bargaining Over Ex Ante Lotteries and Ex Post
Rewards, 17S Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 153-169.
Smith, Vernon (1982), Microeconomic Systems as an Experimental Science, 72 American Economic
Review, 923 ff.
Smith, Vernon (1989), Theory, Experiment and Economics, 3 Journal of Economic Perspectives,
151-169.
Smith, Vernon (1991), Rational Choice: The Contrast between Economics and Psychology, 99
Journal of Political Economy, 877-897.
560 Experimental Law and Economics 0570
Stake, Jeffrey E. (1995), Loss Aversion and Involuntary Transfers of Title, in Malloy, Robin P. and
Braun, Christopher K. (eds), Law and Economics: New and Critical Perspectives, New York,
Peter Lang, 331-360.
Stanley, Linda R. and Coursey, Don L. (1990), Empirical Evidence on the Selection Hypothesis and
the Decision to Litigate or Settle, 19 Journal of Legal Studies, 145 ff.
Sunder, Shyam (1995), Experimental Asset Markets: A Survey, in Kagel, John H. and Roth, Alvin
E. (eds), The Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton, Princeton University Press,
445-500.
Thaler, Richard H. (1991), Quasi Rational Economics, New York, Russel Sage Foundation.
Thaler, Richard H. (1992), The Winners Curse: Paradoxes and Anomalies of Economic Life,
Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Thaler, Richard H. and Tversky, Amos (1992), Preference Reversals, in Thaler, Richard, The
Winners Curse: Paradoxes and Anomalies of Economic Life, Princeton, Princeton University
Press, 79-91.
Thomas, Robert E. (1995), The Trial Selection Hypothesis without the 50 Percent Rule: Some
Experimental Evidence, 24 Journal of Legal Studies, 209-228.
Wilde, Louis L. (1981), On the Use of Laboratory Experiments in Economics, in Pitt, Joseph C. (ed.),
Philosophy in Economics, Boston, D. Reidel, 137-148.
Wittman, Donald A., Friedman, Daniel, Crevier, S. and Braskin A. (1997), Learning Liability Rules,
25 Journal of Legal Studies.
Zeisel, Hans (1973), Reflections on Experimental Techniques in the Law, 2 Journal of Legal Studies,
107-124.
Other References
Ayres, Ian and Cramton, Peter (1996), Deficit Reduction Through Diversity: How Affirmative Action
at the FCC Increased Auction Competition, 48 Stanford Law Review, 761-814.
Donohue, John J., III (1989), Diverting the Coasean River: Incentive Schemes to Reduce
Unemployment Spells, 99 Yale Law Journal, 549-609.
Ellickson, Robert C. (1989), The Case for Coase and against Coaseanism, 99 Yale Law Journal,
611-630.
Gilson, Ronald J. and Mnookin, Robert H. (1994), Disputing through Agents: Cooperation and
Conflict between Lawyers in Litigation, 94 Columbia Law Review, 509-566.
Hasen, Richard L. (1990), Efficiency Under Informal Asymmetry; The Effect of Framing on Legal
Rules, 38 UCLA Law Review, 391-438.
Jolls, Christine, Sunstein, Cass. R. and Thaler, Richard (1998), A Behavioral Approach to Law and
Economics, 50 Stanford Law Review, 1471-1550.
Korobkin, Russell (1998), The Status Quo Bias and Contract Default Rules, 83 Cornell Law Review,
608-687.
Korobkin, Russell and Guthrie, Chris (1997), Psychology, Economics, and Settlement: A New Look
at the Role of the Lawyer, 76 Texas Law Review, 77-141.
Lindgren, James (1990), Ol Man River ... He Keeps on Rollin Along: A Reply to Donohues
Diverting the Coasean River, 78 Georgetown Law Journal, 577-591.
0570 Experimental Law and Economics 561
Marshall, Robert C., Meurer, Michael J. and Richard, Jean-Francois (1991), The Private Attorney
General Meets Public Contract Law: Procurement Oversight by Protest, 20 Hofstra Law Review,
1-71.
McAdams, Richard H. (1995), Cooperation and Conflict: The Economics of Group Status Production
and Race Discrimination, 108 Harvard Law Review, 1003-1084.
Priest, George L. (1985), Reexamining the Selection Hypothesis: Learning from Wittmans Mistakes,
14 Journal of Legal Studies, 215-243.
Priest, George L. and Klein, Benjamin (1984), The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13 Journal
of Legal Studies, 1-55.
Rachlinski, Jeffrey J. and Jourden, Forest (1998), Remedies and the Psychology of Ownership, 51
Vanderbilt Law Review.
0580
LAW AND ECONOMICS OF DEVELOPMENT
Edgardo Buscaglia
Hoover Institute, Stanford University
Copyright 1999 Edgardo Buscaglia
Abstract
This chapter provides a review of the main channels through which legal
systems affect economic development. High costs for determining property
rights are still common in most developing countries. Confiscations; multiple,
high and unanticipated taxation applied to the same bundle of property rights
again and again; unclear definition of contractual obligations; inconsistent
application of the laws coupled with corruption, and ad hoc regulations make
property rights more insecure and have also caused increased transaction costs
within the marketplace. This institutional instability increases the discount rate
applied to social interactions in future periods, thereby hampering investments,
savings and the consumption of durable goods.
This chapter approaches the main substantive and procedural legal factors
that nations need to address in order to promote economic growth and
development. The substantive legal requirements for economic development are
analyzed here by identifying the efficiency enhancing sources of legal norms
(that is, bottom-up formalization of legal norms, legal transplants and legal
integration). Economic growth and social development are also affected by
legal procedures and the mechanisms through which norms are enforced and
interpreted by the court system and alternative dispute resolution mechanisms.
This chapter also identifies how corruption and the lack of efficiency and
effectiveness found in dysfunctional court systems affect investment and
economic development.
JEL classification: K00, O54
Keywords: Law and Economics, Development, Judiciary, Research
1. Introduction
To what degree does law promote economic development? To what extent does
creating wealth through the accumulation of human and nonhuman capital
require a set of rules securing property rights, governing civil and commercial
relationships, and making the exercise of the states power more predictable?
To what extent might economic growth be affected if rules are clearly defined,
made public, and applied in a consistent manner? To what extent are
562
0580 Law and Economics of Development 563
Yet high costs for determining property rights are still common in most
developing countries. Confiscations and multiple, high and unanticipated
taxation applied to the same bundle of property rights again and again, unclear
definition of contractual obligations, inconsistent application of the laws
coupled with corruption, and ad hoc regulations have all made property rights
more insecure and have also caused increased transaction costs within the
marketplace. This institutional instability increases the discount rate applied to
social interactions in future periods, thereby hampering investments, savings,
and the consumption of durable goods. The most interesting question then
remains: What are the structures of the most effective legal and judicial
mechanisms that would be able to interpret and translate those social norms
into laws in less developed countries?
0580 Law and Economics of Development 565
judge-made law sustained by stare decisis has suffered from the significant
expansion of administrative law. In this scenario, administrative law, as the
framework establishing the rules to be followed in the relationship between the
state and private individuals, has been the byproduct of the expansion of the
government role in western societies. Therefore, these legal traditions are in a
constant state of flux.
The civil law systems are currently facing a choice between either legalizing
and enforcing social norms in a bottom-up approach by following the policy
prescriptions of Hayek (1973) or creating regulations in a centralized top-down
manner. For example, the civil code can either capture the norms of local and
international business communities or simply impose rules on a top-down
approach. One of the most important dilemmas facing developing countries in
their current legal evolution is the choice between centralized law versus
decentralized law-making capabilities. Following Hayek (1973), one could
argue that the higher information constraints that are the product of added
social complexity require public policy to decentralize law-making by capturing
norms and thus reducing market transaction costs. As Cooter (1996a, p. 148)
states, efficiency requires the enforcement of customs in business communities
to become more important relative to the regulation of business. As he (p. 154)
also argues, customs arise when external effects align with incentives for
signaling. From this perspective, the irrelevance of the laws enacted by
parliaments in many countries must be understood as a reflection of the lack of
links between the essence of what the law stipulates and the social norms
followed by people and businesses in their daily life. When regulations or laws
show this lack of compatibility, the costs of complying and enforcing the law
become higher. These are the so-called bad laws mentioned by de Soto (1989)
in his path-breaking work in which he identifies a deficient rule by comparing
the approximate transaction cost of complying with the law against the
transaction cost of following the social norm within an informal market. In de
Sotos work one can observe that these higher transaction costs are rooted in
the drive of governments to centralize lawmaking without regard to the true
social practices followed by people. Only when the laws and regulations reflect
these practices will the transaction costs of the social interactions affected
decline and a movement towards efficiency occur. From de Sotos (1996a)
perspective, the size of many informal sectors around the globe is intimately
related to the way laws and regulations fail to capture the social practices
followed by society.
By following the pioneering studies by Cooter (1994, 1996a) and Mattei
(1993) we could argue that the laws generating obedience are the ones truly
compatible with the ethical code prevailing in society. Individuals in social
frameworks seek the kind of predictability that will tend to increase their
capacity to generate wealth through their interactions. The state of nature or
grab what you can is not a priori desirable or compatible with long-term
0580 Law and Economics of Development 567
and Ulen (1997) point out that the economic efficiency hypothesis proposes that
different legal systems may compute the costs and benefits of legal rules for the
same situation differently because real economic factors (such as resource
endowments and tastes) are different across regions and nations. At the same
time, it is also true that legal reforms are subject to the political supply and
demand given by vested interests. That is, professional interests which may be
threatened by any profound alteration in the legal system as it exists and from
which they have benefited. To a large extent, the successful implementation of
any reform depends on these agents, ultimately responsible for effective
law-enforcement.
Buscaglia and Ulen (1994) apply the above cost-benefit approach to transplants
to the recent adoption of intellectual property laws under the GATT umbrella.
Recent empirical studies conducted by Foray and Freeman (1993) show that in
order to ensure a catching-up growth process, developing countries need to
expand the size of their domestic savings and human capital pools through the
application of clear laws and consistent enforcement. The observed differences
in wealth among countries has always captured the attention of scholars in
many fields. Lucas (1988) describes the powerful effects of technological
change and the need to enhance technological learning in the process of
economic development. Yet catching-up is a process that depends on much
more than just technological change, understood as increasing the
incorporation of new technologies into the production capacity of firms. Bell
and Pavitt (1993) bring to our attention the importance of technological
learning, defined as an increase in the resources needed for generating and
managing technical change. In this context, what needs to be addressed is not
just the lack of industrial capacity or technical change but also the dearth of
technological capability as the most basic and acute deficiency in most less
developed countries (LDCs). Technological learning, however, requires a
deeper transformation in a society than technological change does.
Technological learning implies the building of institutions and skills capable
of generating technical change in the future. It is at this deeper level that, for
example, the intellectual property framework will affect future technical
change.
The increasing permeability of national frontiers subject to international
trade and ideas is of such magnitude that it has forced national authorities to
reconsider the legal foundation of intellectual property rights. The Paris and
Berne Conventions provided a legal framework for more than a century
containing two main doctrines. The doctrine known as territoriality sustaining
that property rights are to be honored according to each states rules; and the
0580 Law and Economics of Development 569
The new reality shows that the United States (US), the European Union (EU)
and Japan are increasingly dependent for their competitiveness on their ability
to protect the value inherent in intellectual property. At the same time, most of
the LDCs are extremely dependent on exports to advanced economies. Many
of these LDC exports benefit from the Generalized System of Preferences (GSP)
granted by the European Union and the United States, whereby special lower
tariffs or preferences are applied to designated LDC exports. This mutual
dependence made it possible for advanced and developing economies to start
bilateral negotiations with a potential for mutually beneficial agreements in
order to find a solution to the lack of protection of intellectual property rights.
The stick in these negotiations was provided by the threat of loss of access to
the United States and European markets through the cancellation of GSP
benefits. But foreign pressure is not the only force that is able to explain legal
reforms in LDCs.
Since 1995 and under the World Trade Organization (WTO) supervision,
many less-developed countries have adopted trade-related intellectual property
rights (TRIPs) that are more compatible with the American and European
minimum standards of protection. Some may even classify these legal reforms
as transplants. As part of the GATT framework, the WTO will (a) finally
enforce a set of internationally recognized standards for the protection of
intellectual property rights for incorporation into national laws; and (b) develop
a consultation and dispute settlement mechanism for overseeing the
implementation of the international norms and resolve any government to
government disputes regarding the interpretation of such norms.
Primo-Braga (1990a) observes that modern intellectual property rules have
not been applied or enforced by governments in developing countries even
when the benefits of such rules are widely recognized by local business interests
and by the countries generating the essential technologies needed for
development. However, the forces explaining this pre-GATT inertia or the
causes behind the current emergence of a region-wide intellectual property
reform throughout Latin America have been overlooked. This oversight is
explained by the failure to recognize how the costs and benefits of legal reform
operate on a different time frame. More specifically, the costs of legal reform
are seen by politicians in less developed countries as a short-term liability
0580 Law and Economics of Development 571
hampering their chances for reelection. On the other hand, the benefits of
defining and enforcing intellectual property rights are perceived as more distant
and less tangible.
As stated in Buscaglia and Ulen (1994, p. 159), legal reforms in developing
countries must be seen as the joint effect of local political conditions and
foreign economic pressures. These two forces explain the international legal
convergence observed in the intellectual property arena. As stated above, the
foreign economic pressures to reform intellectual property laws arise
particularly because an increasing proportion of imports to Latin America
consist of information-intensive goods and services. From a domestic policy
perspective, the movement toward intellectual property reform corresponds
with the complete failure of the import substitution approach to development.
From the early 1930s until the late 1980s, most developing countries
encouraged domestic (import substitution) manufacturing investment,
suppressed agricultural prices and expanded the size of their public sector
enterprises while attempting to stimulate savings and investment through
taxation and credit allocated by the public sector. The prevailing view,
represented in Prebisch (1950), was that a shortage of domestic physical capital
was the key impediment to development. Import substitution industries grew
behind protective walls based on subsidies and tariffs in a milieu where many
other determinants of the rate of economic growth, such as investment in
human capital and the role of microeconomic incentives, were completely
ignored by policymakers. Protection of import substitution industries allowed
domestic prices and costs to far exceed international prices and created little
incentive for efficiency. These protected industries produced substitutes for
imports but usually depended on the import of raw materials and technology.
Import demand grew rapidly as these firms imported capital goods to accelerate
investment. The anti-export bias, combined with the import-substitution
program, caused a scarcity of foreign exchange and this, in turn, created a
structural barrier to the investment in expensive first-rate technologies. Within
this environment protected from international trade, however, firms could still
survive investing in second-rate technologies. As described in Buscaglia (1993)
this approach to development came to an end during the international debt
crisis of the 1980s when developing countries policymakers realized that
internal markets and import substitution were not enough to assure sustainable
growth. The demise of the import-substitution model left most developing
countries with no other option for economic growth than to eliminate trade
barriers and promote competitive exports through the incorporation of
world-class technologies. As a result of these foreign and domestic pressures,
LDCs were forced to reconsider many of their legal institutions, including their
national intellectual property laws. In this context, the international economic
and political environment described here has produced a convergence of LDC
laws towards the intellectual property legal frameworks prevailing in nations
generating standard technologies.
572 Law and Economics of Development 0580
Judges allegedly make law in civil law systems by interpreting codes, not finding
social norms. Compared to common law countries, the codifiers in civil law
countries apparently have more influence and the judges allegedly have less
influence. Interpreting some codes, however, looks a lot like finding social norms.
Comparative lawyers, consequently, debate whether the apparent differences in the
two systems are real or illusory
From this perspective, one could argue that civil law systems have the capacity
to react to efficiency forces as much as common law systems do. Moreover, it
may come as a surprise to many sponsoring a centralized legal system that the
civil law originally evolved as a common law system. In Watson (1978a) we
can find an excellent account of this evolution. Let us not forget that, before the
nineteenth century, the European ius commune was based on the judges
interpretation of Roman law within the local norms and practices. The
centralization of law making through legislatures aimed at replacing laws based
on social norms, practiced by people and found by judges, with what Cooter
(1996a) calls rational rules that were designed to engineer a better way of
life for society. The judge was supposed to only interpret laws generated by
legislatures and not find norms. The interpretation of norms, however, was also
subject to an implicit and subtle application of social norms as inputs in the
opinions of judges. Yet, this post Napoleonic framework took away power from
the judicial branch and made it more dependent.
The formation of trading blocks can be analyzed with the same tools that
law and economics has applied to the analysis of federalism. This approach
focuses on identifying and measuring the benefits versus the costs of generating
added political and economic integration. Long and Buscaglia (1997) recently
advanced empirical research in this area. It is useful to present a summary of
this empirical study on economic integration below. The methodology used in
this piece provides an alternative research path where the links between the
existence of legal transplants and economic structures can be explored and
discussed in future studies.
Developing nations are currently facing a unique opportunity created by
global free trade, the continuous decline in transportation and communication
costs coupled with the unprecedented availability of generic applied knowledge
and the expanding flows of international financial investments. However, many
of these countries lack the institutional capability to create or absorb the applied
knowledge aforementioned. Legal and economic reforms that are currently
occurring in LDCs are, in some cases, strengthening the foundations for
economic growth. In all cases, these legal and economic reforms are based on
strategies aimed at giving domestic producers a more important role in the
development of their economies.
574 Law and Economics of Development 0580
Legal integration is another main external source of legal changes that have an
impact on efficiency in many developing countries. Of central interest, in our
analysis, is why governments choose some strategies over others in pursuing
legal/economic integration. Long and Buscaglia (1997) propose that a
successful legal/economic integration is a function of the convergence of three
broad conditions: (1) the compatibility of political systems; (2) the public
sectors expectation of gains from liberalizing international trade; and (3) the
private sectors expectation of gains from regionalizing production, transferring
capital and technology and harmonizing trade-related rules. Some or all of
these factors are key driving forces behind the main trade agreements within
the western hemisphere, Europe and Asia: the North American Free Trade
Agreement (NAFTA) of the United States, Canada and Mexico; the Andean
Pact involving Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru and Venezuela; and the
Common Market of the South (MERCOSUR) covering Argentina, Brazil,
Chile, Paraguay and Uruguay, the European Union and the Asian Economic
bloc. As a case study, the empirical study summarized below concentrates on
providing an empirical verification of the above third condition in Latin
America.
The ongoing Latin American economic transformation has created a need
for new and major legal developments. Yet, what are the main economic forces
explaining the drive to integrate throughout Latin Americas economic history?
A jurimetric analysis in Long and Buscaglia (1997) shows that growth in
international intra-sectoral trade comes hand-in-hand with the private sectors
growing demand for the harmonization of trade-related laws. In addition to the
legal issues mentioned above, harmonization does occur in many other areas.
A survey of the legal history of economic integration reveals that
harmonization occurs in specific areas such as banking, insurance, securities,
liberal professions, international securities exchange regulations and transport.
We see that the future of hemispheric integration and trade processes
0580 Law and Economics of Development 575
Table 1
Legal Changes vs. Economic Structure During 1850-1990
Argentina 515 16 31
Bolivia 19 1 3
Brazil 521 14 35
Chile 467 11 25
576 Law and Economics of Development 0580
Colombia 9 0 7
Ecuador 14 1 6
Peru 56 0 12
Uruguay 12 1 5
Venezuela 5 2 1
Table 2 shows a clear pattern where the regions most dynamic economies are
also the ones that are more likely to enter into international legal agreements
with each other involving harmonization of private law. One can argue that as
an increasing number of business exchanges occur in countries with
overlapping growing trade-related sectors, their need for legal harmonization
will tend to increase. This explains why in Table 2 we observe that most
attempts to harmonize legal frameworks have mainly involved countries such
as Argentina, Brazil and Chile. These countries all experienced growth in the
most dynamic trade-related sectors (for example, agro-manufacturing,
minerals, steel, financial services, transportation and energy).
Table 2
Matrix of Inter-Country Legal Agreements
Covering Commercial Areas
Argentina 0 14 1 10 2 1 2 1 0
Brazil 14 0 2 7 3 2 4 2 1
Bolivia 1 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Chile 10 7 0 0 2 1 3 1 1
Colombia 2 3 0 2 0 0 0 0 0
Ecuador 1 2 0 1 0 0 2 0 0
Peru 2 4 0 3 0 2 0 0 1
Uruguay 1 2 0 1 0 0 0 0 1
Venezuela 0 1 0 1 0 0 1 1 0
0580 Law and Economics of Development 577
Based on the evidence found in Table 1 and Table 2 taken from Long and
Buscaglia (1997), we can assert that many Latin American experiments aimed
at legal harmonization may have failed to produce substantive results due to a
lack of private sector lobbying pushing for compatible legal solutions
addressing trade issues. More specifically, countries with overlapping dynamic
trade-related sectors (that is, experiencing a higher proportion of intra-sectoral
international exchanges as a proportion of total trade) will at the same time
possess private sectors demanding compatible legal frameworks within the
areas affecting their products. This also explains the push for intellectual
property and competition reforms and harmonization of rules among
Argentina, Brazil and Chile. In this context, imagine two types of countries
hoping to harmonize their commercial laws: countries where private
commercial laws are not far from their evolutionary base and where no
dynamic trade-related non-agricultural sectors producing information-intensive
products exist (for example, Bolivia, Colombia, Uruguay) and, in contrast,
countries with relatively evolved commercial legal systems and with a high
proportion of their trade concentrated on dynamic sectors (such as Argentina,
Brazil, Chile). The quantitative evidence (Tables 1 and 2) and the analysis
advanced above would predict that legal harmonization between these two types
of countries will have less chances of success. In these cases, the private sectors
within each of these types of countries will demand different kinds of
commercial legal frameworks. As a result, integration will be more difficult.
For example, one can observe that private sector firms in Bolivia importing
Brazilian computer software and hardware, compact disks, or movies, do not
have an incentive to lobby for the enactment of intellectual property,
government procurement, or competition laws compatible with the needs and
interests of the Brazilian firms exporting these products to Bolivia. Figure 1
shows that the main drive to harmonize trade-related laws was concentrated
among those countries experiencing high levels of international intra-sectoral
trade. For example, we see that Brazil and Argentina with 35 and 31
trade-related legal agreements, respectively, are also the countries with the
highest level of intra-sectoral trade.
Clearly, Argentina, Brazil and Chile are the countries with the highest
levels of intra-sectoral trade as a proportion of their total trade that, according
to our argument, also possess the most dynamic private sectors lobbying for
legal integration. The number of legal agreements attached to each of these
three countries during the period 1890-1990 clearly support our claim. In fact,
those industries involved in intra-sectoral trade within MERCOSUR were the
main forces lobbying for legal harmonization of standards and regulations. Let
us note that intra-sectoral trade within MERCOSUR grew at an unprecedented
rate after tariffs were first reduced in 1988 as part of the ABIP Treaty. The
578 Law and Economics of Development 0580
Figure 1
Legal Treaties vs. Avarage Sectoral Trade: 1890-1990
One could also claim that the relatively larger countries (Argentina and Brazil),
due to the larger stakes in trade and their larger GDP, will seek to determine
a specific type of legal harmony with their main trade partners through legal
agreements. On the other hand, smaller countries in Latin America (for
example, Uruguay and Ecuador) will just free ride by transplanting legal
frameworks to their own environment. A regression analysis covering the
variables aforementioned will test this and the above claims. We can see in
Table 3 below that the number of legal agreements during the period
1890-1990 in the twenty countries surveyed is our dependent variable. The
number of amendments to the commercial codes (AMEND), the number of
non-agricultural trade-related sectors (NO_TRNA) and the average
intra-sectoral trade as a proportion of total trade (AV_INTRA) are all
predictors. These are all variables that help to predict the drive to harmonize
legal frameworks within Latin America during the period 1850-1990. As we
0580 Law and Economics of Development 579
can see, all these explanatory variables are significant at the 5 percent level. On
the other hand, the relative size of the GDP (%GDP/T.GDP) is not a significant
variable. In other words, relative size does not explain the drive to harmonize
legal frameworks. Finally, we see that 62.7 percent of the variability in our
dependent variable is explained by the independent variables included.
Table 3
Multiple Regression Analysis
AMEND 10 1 95 749 2
NO TRNA 43 5 95 861 0
AV INTRA 72 23 99 316 0
%GDP/T.GDP 5 15 86 33 34
the judicial sector within the economic system consists of resolving conflicts by
providing the substantive and procedural structure to facilitate the exchange of
rights to physical and intangible assets. Judiciaries in most developing
countries, however, suffer from increasing backlogs, delay and corruption. As
shown in many Gallup polls, this has generated complete distrust of the system
by the private sector and the public in general. Moreover, the judiciary can also
affect the behavior of private investment. Lack of access to an equitable and
efficient judicial system creates added uncertainty and hampers the realization
of beneficial transactions. In the absence of an impartial and efficient judiciary,
the performance of mutually beneficial transactions depends upon the presence
of pre-existing reputation and repeated transactions among parties. This
requirement excludes many potentially beneficial transactions involving
previously unfamiliar parties or startup businesses from occurring.
Legal principles supporting the prevailing economic systems in many
developing countries are nominally based on the freedom to exercise individual
property rights. But legislation is meaningless without an effective judicial
system to interpret it. Consistent interpretation and application of the laws by
courts provides a stable institutional environment in which the long-term
consequences of economic decisions can be assessed by businesses and the
public. In this context, an ideal judicial system is composed of institutions
capable of applying and interpreting laws equitably and efficiently. Under most
of the judicial systems in Latin America, however, laws are not subject to
predictable interpretation. This uncertainty, coupled with delays in resolving
cases, further increases the costs of access to justice and doing business.
The belief that the judicial sector in Latin America is ill-prepared to foster
private sector development within a market system is growing. Business
surveys conducted by the World Bank (1993) indicate that the judicial system
is considered to be among the top ten significant constraints to private sector
development. Basic elements that constitute an efficient judicial system are
missing: relatively predictable outcomes within the courts; accessibility of the
courts by the population, regardless of income level; reasonable time to
disposition; and adequate court-provided remedies. Increasing delays, backlogs
and the uncertainty associated with expected court outcomes have diminished
the quality of justice throughout the region. The judiciary is faced with several
obstacles, including a dysfunctional administration of justice, lack of
transparency and a perception of corruption.
As an example found in Buscaglia (1995), Table 4 presents country
comparisons in the monthly percentage changes in delays and backlogs in
0580 Law and Economics of Development 583
Table 4
Change in Delay and Backlogs in Latin American Courts, 1973-93
This data may also explain the results from a recent survey of the regions
judicial systems conducted by the World Economic Forum (1993) that shows
the majority of court users are not inclined to bring disputes to court because
they perceive the system as slow, uncertain and costly, or of poor quality.
Lack of confidence in the administration of justice is more pronounced among
small economic units and low-income families.
One of the main premises within the economic analysis of the law is that
institutions transmit implicit prices. An empirical analysis of legal procedures
must identify the extent to which the prices imposed by legal procedures change
the court users behavior. The following example given in Buscaglia (1996a)
provides an option for future research. In this example, the court system can
increase the cost of resolving disputes when times to disposition increase.
Figures 2 and 3 apply to the Civil Courts in Ecuador and Argentina. These
graphs clearly show that the yearly percentage growth in the times to
dispositions faced by the general public (measured on the horizontal axis) have
been increasing in both countries since 1984. The median percentage increase
in the times to disposition have been pronounced during the period 1984-94.
584 Law and Economics of Development 0580
Figure 2
Ecuador's Civil Cases: 1984-1994
0580 Law and Economics of Development 585
Figure 3.
Argentina's Civil Cases: 1984-1994
The enhancement of the capability of the courts to satisfy the demand for
dispositions is one of the most challenging and important aspects of judicial
reform. Almost everywhere in Latin America, courts are unable to supply
enough services to satisfy the current demand. The lack of ability to satisfy this
demand manifests itself through the increasing backlogs and time delays
observed in Table 1. These delays are usually ascribed to lack of resources or
procedural defects. For example, it is often argued that many countries in Latin
America provide inadequate budgets to the courts, which impedes the judiciary
from sustaining even the minimal needs to ensure the publics access to justice.
It is also believed that inadequate budgets perpetuate the dependence of the
judiciary, generate corruption among court personnel and prevent the judiciary
from attracting well-qualified judges and support staff. In this context, many
judges and legal scholars argue that the judiciary must have a separate budget
subject to its control and management. The jurimetric analysis in Buscaglia and
Ulen (1997) provides a statistical framework within which those key variables
affecting the times to disposition are identified through non-parametric
techniques.
If the judiciary is to provide the impartiality and efficiency necessary for
public trust, a well defined program for judicial reform needs to address the
586 Law and Economics of Development 0580
major causes of deterioration in the quality of court services. This reform effort
must address the root political, economic and legal causes of an inefficient and
inequitable judiciary and not simply deal with its symptoms. Basic elements of
judicial reform must include improvements in the administration of the courts
and case management practices; the redefinition and/or expansion of legal
education programs and training for students, lawyers and judges; the
enhancement of public access to justice through legal aid programs and legal
education aimed at fomenting public awareness of its rights and obligations in
the courts; the availability of ADR mechanisms, such as arbitration, mediation
and conciliation; the existence of judicial independence (that is, budget
autonomy, transparency of the appointment process and job security) coupled
with a transparent disciplinary system for court officers; and the adoption of
procedural reforms, where necessary. Each component is an integral part of
judicial reform as a whole. It is unrealistic, however, to think that all the
components can be dealt with at once. Stages of action must be planned with
consideration given to the costs and benefits of reform as perceived by the
judiciary.
Some countries in Latin America have proposed allotting a pre-specified
proportion of the governments budget to the judiciary as a way to address the
low-salary problem but also as a mechanism to reduce times to disposition and
backlogs. However, a country-by-country approach is always required.
International differences in procedural requirements, substantive law and
cultural legal history mean that the resources needed by courts in commercial
jurisdictions to produce a certain type and quantity of services (for example,
1000 bankruptcy rulings) will greatly vary among countries. This means that
3 percent of the government budget devoted to the judiciary in one country may
have a very different impact on times to disposition than the same amount
devoted to the courts in another country. Therefore, it is doubtful that a higher
fixed proportion of the governments budget would necessarily improve the
functioning of the judicial system.
Based on these figures and the times to disposition in Figure 1, there is no
proven significant international correlation between judicial efficiency
(measured in terms of backlogs and times to disposition) and size of the
government budget allocated to the courts. Figure 4 clearly demonstrates this
lack of correlation within Latin America. The country-specific average
percentage changes in the median times to disposition are measured on the
vertical axis with a two-year lag after the average percentage changes in real
spending devoted to the judiciary (measured on the horizontal axis) are
introduced. The changes in real spending are adjusted for population and
economic growth in each of the countries considered. These measurements are
applied to the civil jurisdictions in each country. As we can see, countries with
the largest changes in spending are not usually those experiencing the lowest
times to disposition. For example, Brazil and Chile are clear examples of this
lack of correlation.
0580 Law and Economics of Development 587
Figure 4
Judicial Efficiency and Allocated Budget
The reason for this lack of correlation lies in the fact that, on the one hand,
additional resources (personnel and capital) initially reduce backlogs and delay
due to improvements in court productivity. But after our two-year lag, a better
endowed judiciary starts attracting additional demand (filings per court) from
citizens and businesses that otherwise would be reluctant to use the courts due
to the previously high litigation costs. The joint effects of both forces make it
difficult to determine the consequences of adding or subtracting resources
devoted to the judiciary. It is therefore much more sensible to implement a
budgetary mechanism where courts can request funds based on projected
increases in filings within each subject matter and geographical jurisdiction.
The enhancement of the courts capacity to satisfy the demand for
dispositions is one of the most challenging and important aspects of judicial
reform. Everywhere in Latin America courts are unable to perform their basic
function as mechanisms for the interpretation and application of the law. The
inability to satisfy this demand manifests itself in increasing backlogs and time
delays observed throughout the region. These delays are due, in part, to the lack
of resources or, in many cases, to procedural defects. Other reasons are the lack
of legal training, the absence of an active case management style, or an
excessive administrative burden falling on judges. For example, Buscaglia,
Ratliff and Dakolias (1995) found that approximately 70 percent of Argentine
588 Law and Economics of Development 0580
control and planning and adjudicating cases) create incentives for corrupt
behavior due to the lack of external and internal organizational control
mechanisms. Addressing these substantive, procedural and organizational
factors is a necessary condition to eradicate corruption within the court systems.
If the judicial sector and other members of the government use the courts
for rent-seeking purposes, then it should not be surprising to find members of
the bench and their clerks blocking efficiency-enhancing judicial reforms. In
this context, court reforms promoting uniformity, transparency and
accountability in the process of enforcing laws would necessarily diminish the
courts capacity to extract rents, in the form of illicit payments from the private
sector.
Previous studies argue that judicial inertia in enacting reform stems from
the long-term nature of the benefits of reform, such as added economic growth
or investment. These benefits cannot be directly captured in the short term by
potential reformers within the government. Contrast the long-term nature of
these benefits with the short-term nature of the main costs of reform, notably
a perceived decrease in rents to the courts (for example, explicit payoffs and
other informal inducements provided to court officers). This asymmetry
between short-term costs and long-term benefits tends to block judicial reforms
and explains why court reforms, which eventually benefit most segments of
society, are often resisted and delayed. Reform sequencing, then, must ensure
that short-term benefits compensate for loss of rents by court officers
responsible for implementing the changes. That is, initial reforms should allow
for short-term benefits for court officers. In turn, court reform proposals
generating longer-term benefits to the judiciary need to be implemented in later
stages of the reform process.
Additional forces also enhance the judicial reform process. We usually
observe that periods of judicial crisis come hand-in-hand with a general
consensus to reform the court system. As stated above, a judicial crisis begins
at the point where backlogs, delays and payoffs increase the cost (implicit or
explicit) of accessing the system. When costs become too high, people restrict
their use of the judiciary, as shown in Figures 2 and 3 above, to the point where
the capacity of the courts to extract rents will diminish. At that point members
of the court and governments embrace judicial reforms in order to recover their
prestige and rent seeking capacity. The judiciary would more likely be willing
to conduct deeper court reforms during a crisis as long as reform proposals
contain sources of short-term benefits, such as greater administrative power of
lower courts, judicial independence and increased court resources.
It comes as no surprise, then, that those Latin American countries
undertaking judicial reforms have all experienced a deep crisis as characterized
above - that is, sharp decreases in average filings per civil court. Important
judicial reforms are being implemented in Ecuador, Mexico and Venezuela. In
590 Law and Economics of Development 0580
each of these three cases, additional short-term benefits guaranteed the political
support of key magistrates who were willing to discuss judicial reform
proposals only after a deep crisis diminished their capacity to serve the public.
These benefits included generous early retirement packages, promotions for
judges and support staff, new buildings and expanded budgets. Nevertheless,
to ensure lasting judicial reform, short-term benefits must be channeled through
institutional mechanisms capable of sustaining reform. The best institutional
scenario is one in which judicial reforms are the byproduct of a consensus
involving the judiciary and at least one of the other two branches of power, the
legislative and executive branches. Additionally, the political leverage of
expected winners from reform should counteract the activities of potential
rent-losers.
In short, according to Buscaglia, Ratliff and Dakolias (1995, pp. 34-36), two
counteracting forces explain why many developing-country governments have
failed to provide an efficient judicial sector compatible with a market economy.
On the one hand, efficiency-enhancing institutional change accounts for the
actual reform and institutional transformation of Latin American judiciaries,
while on the other hand, issues related to corruption within the courts account
for institutional inertia in enacting judicial reform. Then, the nature of the
relationship between a society, its legal rules and its judicial sector can be
explained in terms of political rent-seeking activities and economic efficiency
arguments. These two influences can also contribute to the understanding of the
legal and judicial development of a nation.
Before a judicial crisis strikes, however, corruption runs rampant within the
judiciary. In all cases one can observe that corruption generates immediate
positive results for the individual court-user who is willing and able to pay the
bribe. Nevertheless, the widespread effects of corruption on the overall social
system are extremely pernicious. Those court-users who are not able or willing
to supply illicit incentives will be excluded from the provision of a supposedly
public good (that is, court services) that in reality corruption transforms into
a private good subject to an uncertain price. Even though corruption may
remove red tape for those who are able to pay the bribe, the judicial system
becomes inequitable in the perception of all of those who are excluded from the
system. This sense of inequity has a long-term effect on social interaction. A
corrupt judiciary promotes an inequitable social system where the allocation of
resources subject to adjudication is less correlated to rights and obligations and
more directly determined by the initial endowment of resources held by the
court-user.
0580 Law and Economics of Development 591
C. Conclusion
As a body of knowledge within the social sciences, the economic analysis of the
law certainly needs to reinforce its power to verify claims based on
observations. Here, of course, we would depart from the Austrian Schools
tradition of limiting itself to the identification of logical truths in the study of
human action and interaction and side with a legal realism which allows to
develop a more structured public policy in the legal realm. In no other area is
the development of a tool kit of empirical capabilities more necessary than in
the legal and economic study of development.
We have approached law and economics of development in this chapter by
covering the main theoretical and empirical scholarly work identifying the
substantive sources of efficiency-enhancing legal doctrines (that is, bottom-up
approach to law making, legal transplants and legal integration) in less
developed countries. We have also discussed the main procedural requirements
needed to sustain an economic system based on impersonal exchange (a judicial
sector with alternative dispute resolution mechanisms) while also exploring
some of the main symptoms of a dysfunctional judiciary (corruption and lack
of efficiency in the courts).
592 Law and Economics of Development 0580
Acknowledgments
Alesino, Alberto, Ozler, Sule, Roubini, Nouriel and Sweagel, Phillip (1992), Political Instability and
Economic Growth, 4173 NBER Working Paper.
Andvig, Jens C. and Moene, Karl Ove (1990), How Corruption May Corrupt, 13 Journal of
Economic Behavior and Organization, 63-76.
Arantes, Peter, Gellhorn, Ernest A. and Robinson, Glen O. (1983), A Theory of Legislative
Delegation, 68 Cornell Law Review, 23-56.
Axelrod, R. (1981), The Emergence of Cooperation Among Egoists, 75 American Political Science
Review, 306-318.
0580 Law and Economics of Development 593
Axelrod, Robert (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation, New York, Basic Books.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (1996), An Economic Analysis of Constitutional Law, in Buscaglia, Edgardo,
Ratliff, William and Cooter, Robert (eds), Law and Economics of Development, JAI Press.
Bardhan, Pranab K. (1989), The New Institutional Economics and Development Theory: A Brief
Critical Assessment, 17(9) World Development, 1389-1395.
Barragan, Julia (1994), Como se Hacen Las Leyes, Venezuela, Caracas, Editorial Planeta.
Barton, John (1996), The Economic and Legal Context of Contemporary Technology Transfer, in
Buscaglia, Edgardo, Ratliff, William and Cooter, Robert (eds), Law and Economics of
Development, JAI Press.
Barzel, Yoram (1990), Economic Analysis of Property Rights, New York, Cambridge University
Press.
Becker, Gary S. (1976), The Economic Approach to Human Behavior, Chicago, University of
Chicago Press, 314 p.
Becker, Gary S. (1983), A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence, 98
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 371-383.
Bell, Martin and Pavitt, Keith (1993), Technological Accumulation and Industrial Growth: Contrasts
Between Developed and Developing Countires, 2 Industrial and Corporate Change, 157-210.
Benson, Bruce L. (1984), Rent Seeking from a Property Rights Perspective, 34 Southern Economic
Journal, 345-378.
Birch, Melissa and Primo-Braga, Carlos Alberto (1992), Regulation in Latin America: Prospects for
the 1990s, in, Texas Papers on Latin America 93-08, Illinois, Latin America 2000 Conference,
University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign, Illinois.
Boyd, James (1996), Environmental Liability Reform and Privatization in Central and Eastern
Europe, 3 European Journal of Law and Economics.
Brenner, Reuven (1994), Labyrinths of Prosperity, Ann Arbor, MI, University of Michigan Press.
Bromley, Daniel W. (1989), Property Relations and Economic Development: The Other Land
Reform, 17 World Development, 867-877.
Bromley, Daniel W. (1993), Reconstituting Economic Systems: Institutions in National Economic
Development, 11 Development Policy Review, 131-151.
Bromley, Daniel W. (1994), The Enclosure Movement Revisited: The South African Commons, 28
Journal of Economic Issues, 357-365.
Burke, John J.A. (1996), The Economic Basis of Law as Demonstrated by the Reformation of NIS
Legal Systems, 18 Loyola of Los Angeles International and Comparative Law Journal, 207 ff.
Buscaglia, Edgardo (1993), Law, Technological Progress and Economic Development, California,
Stanford University Press, Hoover Institution, International Studies Program, Stanford.
Buscaglia, Edgardo (1994), Legal and Economic Development: The Missing Links, 35 Journal of
Inter-American Studies and World Affairs, 153-169.
Buscaglia, Edgardo (1995), Judicial Reform in Latin America: The Obstacles Ahead, 4 Journal of
Latin American Affairs, 8-16.
Buscaglia, Edgardo (1996a), Legal and Economic Integration in Latin America: The Lessons of
MERCOSUR, Paper Presented at the Comparative Law and Economics Meeting in Siena, Italy
May 13-14.
594 Law and Economics of Development 0580
Carvallho, Jose L. (1994), Private Sector Development and Property Rights in Latin America,
Washington, DC, World Bank, Latin America Technical Department.
Clagett, Helen (1952), The Administration of Justice in Latin America, Dobbs-Ferry, NY, Oceana
Publications.
Coase, Ronald H. (1960), The Problem of Social Cost, 3 Journal of Law and Economics, 1-44.
Reprinted in Ackermann, Bruce A. (ed.), Economic Foundations of Property Law, Boston, Little
Brown, 1975, 17-22. Reprinted in Medema, Steven G. (ed.),The Legacy of Ronald Coase in
Economic Analysis, Vol.2, Aldershot, Edward Elgar Publishing, 1995, 5-48. Reprinted in Coase,
Ronald H., The Firm, the Market and the Law, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 1988.
Coase, Ronald H. (1991), The Institutional Structure of Production, in Coase, Ronald H. (ed.),Essays
on Economics and Economists, Chicago, IL, University of Chicago Press.
Coelho, Philip R.P. (1985), An Examination into the Causes of Economic Growth, 7 Research in Law
and Economics, 89-116.
Cooter, Robert (1994), Structural Adjudication and the New Law Merchant: A Model of Decentralized
Law, 14 International Review of Law and Economics, 215-231.
Cooter, Robert D. (1989), The Best Right Laws: Value Foundations of the Economic Analysis of
Law, 64 Notre Dame Law Review, 816-819.
Cooter, Robert D. (1991), Inventing Market Property: The Land Courts of Papua New Guinea, 25
Law and Society Review, 759-801.
Cooter, Robert D. (1996a), Decentralized Law for a Complex Economy: The Structural Approach to
Adjudicating the New Law Merchant, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 1643-1696.
Cooter, Robert D. (1996b), The Theory of Market Modernization of Law, 16 International Review
of Law and Economics, 141-172.
Cooter, Robert D. and Ginsburg, Tom (1996), Comparative Judicial Discretion: An Empirical Test
of Economic Models, Working Paper No 95-1, Program in Law and Economics, Working Paper
Series, School of Law, University of California at Berkeley.
Cooter, Robert D. and Gordley, James (1991), Economic Analysis in Civil Law Countries: Past,
Present, Future - Introduction to a Symposium, 11 International Review of Law and Economics,
261-263.
Cooter, Robert D. and Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1980), Can Litigation Improve the Law without the Help
of Judges, 9 Journal of Legal Studies, 139-163.
Cooter, Robert D. and Ulen, Thomas S. (1988), Law and Economics, Glenview, IL, Scott, Foresman
and Company.
Cowell, Frank A. (1990), Cheating the Government: The Economics of Evasion, Cambridge, MIT
Press, 267 p.
David, Ren and Brierley, John E.C. (1985), Major Legal Systems in the World Today, 3rd Edition,
New York, The Free Press.
Dawson, John P. (1968), The Oracles of the Law, Ann Arbor, MI, University of Michigan Press.
De Meza, David and Gould, J.R. (1992), The Social Efficiency of Private Decision to Enforce Property
Rights, 100 Journal of Political Economy, 561-580.
de Soto, Hernando (1989), The Other Path, New York, Harper and Row.
de Soto, Hernando (1996a), Property Rights and Economic Progress in Developing Countries: The
Peruvian Experience, in Buscaglia, Edgardo, Ratliff, William and Cooter, Robert (eds), Law and
Economics of Development, JAI Press.
596 Law and Economics of Development 0580
de Soto, Hernando (1996b), Preface, in Buscaglia, Edgardo, Ratliff, William and Cooter, Robert
(eds), Law and Economics of Development, JAI Press.
Dezalay, Yves and Garth, Bryant G. (1995), Merchants of Law as Mortal Entrepreneurs: Constructing
International Justice from the Competition for Trasnational Business Disputes, 29 Law and
Society Review, 27-64.
Dolinger, Jacod and Rosen, Keith (1992), A Panorama of Brazilian Law, North-South Center and
Editora Explanada Ltd.
Douglas, Mary (1986), How Institutions Think, Syracuse, NY, Syracuse University Press.
Eggertsson, Thrainn (1990), Economic Behaviour and Institutions, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press, 385 p.
Eisenberg, Melvin Aron (1988),The Nature of the Common Law, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press, 204 p.
Elliott, E. Donald, Ackerman, Bruce A. and Millian, John (1985), Toward a Theory of Statutory
Evolution: The Federalization of Environmental Law, 1 Journal of Law, Economics and
Organization, 313-340.
Emiola, Akintude (1987), Nigerian Labor Law, 2nd edn, Ethiope Publishing Company.
Farber, Daniel A. and Frickey, Philip P. (1991), Law and Public Choice: A Critical Introduction,
Chicago, IL, University of Chicago Press, 159 p.
Fiorina, M. (1982), Legislative Choice of Regulatory Forms: Legal Process or Administrative
Proces?, 39 Public Choice, 33 ff.
Fleisig, Heywood (1994), Law. Legal Procedure and the Economic Value of Collateral: The Case
of Bolivia, Washington, DC, World Bank, Private Sector Development Department.
Foray, Dominique and Freeman, Christopher (eds) (1993), Technology and the Wealth of Nations,
Stanford, CA, Stanford University Press, 23-34.
Galanter, Michael (1974), Why Haves Come Out Ahead: Speculation on the Limits of Legal
Change, 9 Law and Society Review, 95 ff.
Garland, David (1990), Punishment in Modern Society: A Study in Social Theory, Chicago, IL,
University of Chicago Press.
Gil Diaz, Francisco and Fernandez, Arturo (1991), Del Desarrollo Institutcional al progreso
Economico (Institutional Development and Economic Progress), in Gil Diaz, Francisco and
Fernandez, Arturo (eds), El Efecto de la Regulacionen Algunos de los Sectores de la Economia
Mexican, Fondo de Cultura Economica, Instituto Technologica Autonomo de Mexico/ and Centro
Internacional para el Desarrollo Economico, 134-189.
Goodman, M. (1978), An Economic Theory of the Evolution of the Common Law, 7 Journal of
Legal Studies, 393 ff.
Gould, David J. (1980), Bureacratic Corruption and Underdevelopment in the Third World: The
Case of Zaire, New York, Pergamon Press.
Gould, David J. and Amaro Reyes, Jose A. (1983), The Effects of Corruption on Administrative
Performance: Illustrations from Developing Countries, World Bank Staff Working Paper No 580,
Management and Development Series, Washington DC: The World Bank.
Granado del, Juan Javier (1996), Legis Imperium, Bolivia, La Paz, Fondo Editorial de la Univesidad
Iberoamericana.
Guasch, Luis and Spiller, Pablo T. (1994), Regulation and Private Sector Development in Latin
America, Washington, DC, World Bank, Latin America Technical Department.
0580 Law and Economics of Development 597
Hachette, Dominique and Luders, Rolf (1993), Privatization in Chile: An Economic Analysis, San
Francisco, CA, ICS Press.
Hansmann, Henry B. and Mattei, Ugo (1994), The Comparrative Law and Economics of Trusts,
Paper Presented at CLEF at Geneva, Switzerland.
Hayashida, Seimei (1992a), Ho ha Keizaidearu (Law is Economics), 42 Hokudai Hogaku Ronshu
(Hokkaido Law Review), 1369-1412.
Hayashida, Seimei (1992b), Ho to Keizai, Keizaibunseki, Hihan to Paradaimu (Law and Economics,
Economic Analysis, Its Critique and Paradigm), 42 Hokudai Hogaku Ronshu (Hokkaido Law
Review), 905-956. Part 2, 1234-1272.
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1973), Law, Legislation and Liberty, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Hirshleifer, Jack (1982), Evolutionary Models in Law and Economics, Research in Law and
Economics.
Hirshleifer, Jack and Coll Martinez, Juan Carlos (1988), What Strategies can Support the Evolutionary
Emergence of Cooperation?, 32 Journal of Conflict Resolution, 367-398.
Huanca Ayaviri, Felix (1995), Analisis Economico del Derecho, Bolivia, La Paz, Fondo Editorial de
la Universidad Iberoamericana.
Huntington, Samuel (1979), Modernization and Corruption, in Ekpo (ed.), Monday, Bureaucratic
Corruption in Sub-Saharan Africa: Towards a Search for Causes and Consequences,
Washington, DC, University Press of America.
Inman, Richard (1990), Markets, Government and the New Political Economy, Cambridge, MA,
The MIT Press.
James, William Roden (1973), Modern Land Law in Nigeria, Nigeria, University of Ife Press.
Karst, Kenneth L. (1966), Latin American Legal Institutions: Problems for Comparative Study, Los
Angeles, UCLA Latin American Center.
Karst, Kenneth L. and Rosen, Keith (1975), Law and Development in Latin America, Berkeley,
University of California Press.
Kikeri, Sunita, Nellis, John and Shirley, Mary (1992), Privatization: The Lessons of Experience,
Washington, DC, The World Bank.
Kirchner, Christian (1991), The Difficult Reception of Law and Economics in Germany, 11
International Review of Law and Economics, 277-292.
Kitch, Edmund W. (1983), Intellectual Foundations of Law and Economics, 33 Journal of Legal
Education, 183-209.
Klitgaard, Robert (1988), Controlling Corruption, Berkeley, University of California Press, 220 p.
Klitgaard, Robert (1991), Adjusting to Reality: Beyond State versus Market in Economic
Development, San Francisco, CA, ICS Press.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1984), The Great Image of Authority, 36 Stanford Law Review, 349-389.
Larson, Bruce A. and Bromley, Daniel W. (1990), Property Rights, Externalities and Resource
Degradation: Locating the Tragedy, 33 Journal of Development Economics, 235-362.
Leff, Arthur A. (1974), Economic Analysis of Law: Some Realism About Nominalism, 60 Virginia
Law Review, 78 ff.
Leoni, Bruno (1991), Freedom and the Law, Indianapolis, Liberty Fund.
598 Law and Economics of Development 0580
Long, Clarisa and Buscaglia, Edgardo (1997), A Quantitative Analysis of the Legal and Economic
Integration in Latin America, in Buscaglia, Edgardo, Ratliff, William and Cooter, Robert (eds),
Law and Economics of Development, JAI Press.
Lucas, Robert E. (1988), On the Mechanics of Economic Development, 22 Journal of Monetary
Economics, 248-257.
Makgetla, Neva and Seidman, Robert B. (1989), The Applicability of Law and Economics to
Policymaking in the Third World, 23 Journal of Economic Issues, 35-77.
Malloy, Robin Paul (1986), Equating Human Rights and Property Rights. the Need for a Moral
Judgment in an Economic Analysis of Law and Social Policy, 163 Ohio State Law Journal,
78-89.
Marasinghe, M.L. (1984), Towards a Third World Perspective of Jurisprudence, in Marasingue, M.L.
and Conklin, W.E. (eds), Essays on Third World Perspective in Jurisprudence, Singapore,
Malaysian Law Journal PTE, Ltd.
Margadant, Guillermo Floris (1983), An Introduction to the History of Mexican Law, Dobbs-Ferry,
NY, Oceana Publications.
Martinez, Gabriel (1997), Competition Policy and Deregulation in Mexico in the late 1990s, in
Buscaglia, Edgardo, Ratliff, William and Cooter, Robert (eds), Law and Economics of
Development, JAI Press.
Mathews, R.C.O. (1986), The Economics of Institutions and the Source of Growth, 69 Economic
Journal.
Mattei, Ugo (1993), Law and Economics in Civil Law Countires: A Comparative Approach, 14
International Review of Law and Economics, 265-275.
Mattei, Ugo (1994), Efficiency in Legal Transplants: An Essay in Comparative Law and Economics,
14 International Review of Law and Economics, 245 ff.
Mattei, Ugo and Pardolesi, Roberto (1991), Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries: A
Comparative Approach, 11 International Review of Law and Economics, 265-275.
Mattick, Ross (1992), Agrarian Reform in West Bengal: The End of an Illusion, 20(5) World
Development, 735-750.
Mauro, Paolo (1995), Corruption and Growth, 111 Quarterly Journal of Economics, 681-711.
McGee, Robert W. (1992), The Market Solution to Economic Development in Eastern Europe, The
Edwin Mellen Press, 320 p.
McKinnon, Ronald I. (1991), Lessons of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the
Transition to a Market Economy, Baltimore, MD, John Hopkins University Press.
Mercuro, Nicholas and Ryan, Timothy P. (1984),Law, Economics and Public Policy, Greenwood, JAI
Press.
Merryman, John Henry (1985), The Civil Law Tradition, Stanford, CA, Stanford University Press.
Merryman, John Henry and Clark, David (1978), Comparative Law: Western European and Latin
American Legal Systems-Cases and Meterials, Indianapolis, Bobbs-Merrill.
Milgrom, Paul R. and Roberts, John (1988), An Economic Approach to Influence Activities in
Organizations, 94 American Journal of Sociology, supplement.
Myrdal, Gunnar (1989), Corruption as a Hindrance to Modernization in South Asia, in Heidenheimer,
Arnold J., Jophnson, Michael and Le Vine, Victor (eds), Political Corruption: A Handbook, New
Brunswick, NJ, Transaction Press, 406-407.
North, Douglass (1981), Sturcture and Change in Economic History, New York, W.W. Norton.
0580 Law and Economics of Development 599
North, Douglass (1987), Institutions, Transaction Costs and Economic Growth, 25 Economic
Inquiry, 456-489.
North, Douglass (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Growth Performance,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass (1991), Institutions, 5(1) Journal of Economic Perspectives.
Nozick, Robert (1974), Anarchy, State and Utopia, New York, Basic Books.
Ogus, Anthony I. (1995), Economics and Law Reform: Thirty Years of Law Commission Endeavor,
11 Law Quarterly Review, 407-420.
Olson, Mancur (1965), The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups,
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press, 186 p.
Olson, Mancur (1982), The Rise and Decline of Nations, New haven, Yale University Press.
Olson, Mancur (1993), Dictatorship, Democracy and Development, 87 American Political Science
Review, 567-576.
Orr, Daniel and Ulen Thomas S. (1993), The Role of Trust and the Law in Privatization, 33
Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 135-155.
Ostrom, Elnor (1990), Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Ott, Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (1991), Emergence and Construction of Efficient Rules in the
Legal System of German Civil Law, Paper Presented at the European Law and Economics
Association.
Paredes, Ricardo (1997), Jurisprudence of the Antitrust Commissions in Chile, in Buscaglia, Edgardo,
Ratliff, William and Cooter, Robert (eds), Law and Economics of Development, JAI Press.
Pator, Santos (1989), Economia y Sistema Juridico. Una Introduccion al Analisis Economico del
Derecho (Introduction to Economic Analysis of Law), Madrid, Tecnos.
Pinheiro, Neto (1990), Consumer Protection in Brazil, Sao Paolo, Advogados.
Posner, Richard A. (1980), A Theory of Primitive Society, with Special Reference to Law, 23 Journal
of Law and Economics, 1-25.
Posner, Richard A. (1992), Economic Analysis of Law, 4th edn, Boston, Little Brown and Company.
Prebisch, Raul (1950), The Economic Development of Latin America and its Principal Problems,
New York, Lake Success, United Nations.
Priest, George L. (1987), Measuring Legal Change, 3 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization,
193-225.
Primo-Braga, Carlos Alberto (1990a), The Developing Country Case for or Against Intellectual
Property Protection, in Strengthening Protection of Intellctual Property in Developing
Countries, Washinton DC, The World Bank, 69-87.
Primo-Barga, Carlos Alberto (1990b), Strengthening Protection of Intellectual Property in
Developing Countries, Washington, DC, The World Bank.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1989), Water Law in Imperial Japan: Public Goods, Private Claims and Legal
Convergence, 18 Journal of Legal Studies, 51-77.
Ramseyer, J. Mark and Rosenbluth, Frances M. (1995), The Politics of Oligarchy: Institutional
Choice In Imperial Japan, New York: Cambridge University Press.
Rapp, Richard Tilden and Rozek, Richard P. (1990), Benefits and Costs of Intellectual Property
Protection in Developing Countries, 24 Journal of World Trade, 75-102. Reprinted in How
Property Protection Fuels Economies, 3 Les Nouvelles, 1992.
600 Law and Economics of Development 0580
Ratliff, William and Rosenbluth, Frances M. (1997), Judicial Reform: The Neglected Priority in Latin
America, in Rich, Paul and de los Reyes, Guillermo (eds), The Annals of the American Academy
of Political and Social Science, London, Sage Press.
Rawls, John (1971), A Theory of Justice, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Reuven, Brenner (1980), Economics: An Imperialistic Science?, 9 Journal of Legal Studies, 184 ff.
Roemer andrs (1989), Evaluacion Juridica, Finmanciera, y Economicade la Camaronicultura en
Mexico, Instituto Tecnologico Autonomo de Mexico.
Roemer andrs (1993), Introduccion al Analisis Economico del Derecho, Mexico City, Fondo de
Cultura Economica.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1978), Corruption: A Study in Political Economy, New York, Academic
Press. Reprinted as Problem Der konomischen Theorie, in Fleck, C. and Helmut Kuzmics (eds),
Korruption: Zur Soziologie.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1980), Risktaking and Reelection: Does Federalism Promote Innovation?,
89 Journal of Legal Studies, 593-616.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1981a), Does Federalism Matter: Political Choice in a Federal Republic, 89
Journal of political Economy, 347 ff.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1981b), Does Federalism Matter?: Political Choice in a Federal Republic,
89 Journal of Political Economy, 152-165.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1986), Reforming Public Bureaucracy through Economic Incentives?, 2
Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 131 ff.
Rosenn, Keith S. (1984), Brazils Legal Culture: The Jeto Revisited, 1 Florida International Law
Journal.
Rubin, Edward L. (1996), The New Legal Process, the synthesis of Discourse and the Microanalysis
of Institutions, 109 Harvard Law Review, 1393 ff.
Rubin, Paul H. (1993), Growing a Legal System, with Special Reference to the Post-Communist
Economies Center for International Reform and the Informal Sector, Working Paper No 63.
Saharay, H.K. (1988), Labor and Social Laws in India, Eastern Law House.
Santhanam Committee (1994), Report by the Committee on Prevention of Corruption, Government
of India, Ministry of Home Affairs.
Schlesinger, Rudolf B. (1959), Common Law and Civil Law-Comparison of Methods and Sources,
in, Comparitive Law Cases, Texts and Materials, Foundation Press.
Seidman, Ann and Seidman, Robert B. (1996), Drafting Legislation for Development: Lessons from
a Chinese Project, 44 American Journal of Comparative Law, 1 ff.
Seidman, Robert B. (1978), State, Law and Development, New York, St Martins Press.
Shleifer, Andrei (1994), Establishing Property Rights, in, Proceedings of the World Bank at the
Annual Conference on Development Economics, Washington, DC, The World Bank.
Shleifer Andrei and Vishny, Robert W. (1993), Corruption, 108 Quarterly Journal of Economics,
599-617.
Simpson, Alfred William Brian (1975), A History of Common Law of Contract, Oxford, Clarendon
Press.
Sjaastad, Espen and Bromley, Daniel W. (1997), Indigenous Land Rights in Sub-Saharan Africa:
Appropriation, Security and Investment Demand, 25 World Development, 549-562.
Stone, Andrew, Levy, Brian and Paredes, Ricardo (1992), Public Institutions and Private Transactions:
The Legal and Regulatory Environment for Business Transactions in Brazil and Chile, Policy
0580 Law and Economics of Development 601
Research Working Paper Series 891, World Bank: Country Economics Department, Washington
DC.
Swallow, Brent and Bromley, Daniel W. (1994), Co-Management or No Management: The Prospects
for Internal Governance of Common Property Regimes through Dynamic Contracts, 22 Oxford
Agrarian Studies, 3-16.
Swallow, Brent and Bromley, Daniel W. (1995), Institutions, Governance and Incentives in Common
Property Regimes for African Rangelands, 6 Environmental and Resource Economics, 99-118.
Tokman, Victor (1989), Policies for a Heterogeneous Informal Sector in Latin America, 17 World
Development, 1067-1076.
Tokman, Victor (1992), Beyond Regulation: The Informal Economy in Latin America, Boulder, CO,
Lynne Rienner.
Trebilcock, Michael J. (1983), The Prospects of Law and Economics: A Canadian Perspective, 33
Journal of Legal Education, 288-290.
Trebilcock, Michael J. (1997), What Makes Poor Countries Poor?: The Role of Institutional Capital
in Economic Development, in Buscaglia, Edgardo, Ratliff, William and Cooter, Robert (eds), Law
and Economics of Development, JAI Press.
Trubek, E. (1972), Towards a Social Theory of Law: An Essay on the Study of Law and
Development, 82 Yale Law Journal, 1 ff.
Ulen, Thomas S. (1996), The Comparative Law and Economics of Federalism, Paper Presented at the
Comparative Law and Economics of Legal Integration Conference in Siena, Italy, May 13-14.
Ulen, Thomas (1997), Laws Contributions to Economic Growth, in Buscaglia, Edgardo, Ratliff,
William and Cooter, Robert (eds), Law and Economics of Development, JAI Press.
Uvieshara, E.E. (1976), Trade Union Law in Nigeria, Benin City, Ethiope Publishing Company.
Van Den Bergh, Roger (1992), Law and Economics in Europe: Present State and Future Prospects,
in Bouckaert, Boudewijn and De Geest, Gerrit (eds), Bibliography of Law and Economics,
Deventer, Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Van den Brink, Rogier, Chavas, Jean-Paul and Bromley, Daniel W. (1995), The Economics of Cain
and Abel: Agro-Pastoral Property Rights in the Sahel, 31 Journal of Development Studies,
373-399.
Watson, Alan (1974), Legal Transplants: An Approach to Comparative Law, Cambridge, MA,
Harvard University Press.
Watson, Alan (1978a), Comparative Law and Legal Change, 313 Columbia Law Journal, 45-67.
Watson, Alan (1978b), Society and Legal Change, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
White, Eduardo (1975), Control of Restrictive Practices in Latin America, New York, Viking Press.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1991), Intellectual Foundations: The Need for a Broader View, 33 Journal
of Legal Education, 210-216.
Wilson, James Q. (1989), Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies Do and Why they Do It, New
York, Basic Books.
World Bank (1993), Ecuador: Constraints to Private Sector Development, Washington, DC, The
World Bank, Trade, Finance and Private Sector Development Division, LAC Country Department
IV.
602 Law and Economics of Development 0580
World Economic Forum (1993), World Competitiveness Report, Baltimore, MD, John Hopkins
University Press.
X (1990), Pinheiro Neto, Sao Paulo: Advogados.
X (1991), Consumer Protection Law in India, Bombay, N.M. Tripathi Pvt. Ltd.
Xue-Lascoux, Zhiqun and Bromley, Daniel W. (1996), Necessity and Purpose in Chinese Agriculture:
1949-95', 24 Oxford Development Studies, 261-280.
Ziskind, David (1987), Labor Provisions in African Constitutions, Los Angeles, Litlaw Foundation.
0610
PUBLIC CHOICE, CONSTITUTIONAL
POLITICAL ECONOMY AND LAW AND
ECONOMICS
Ludwig Van den Hauwe
Brussels, Belgium
Copyright 1999 Ludwig Van den Hauwe
Abstract
1. Introduction
As the title of this chapter suggests, the new law and economics movement
on the one hand and the now rapidly emerging field of constitutional
political economy - as well as the somewhat older public choice branch of
economics from which it emerged - on the other hand, are research traditi-
ons that are in some respects genuinely related. In other respects the diffe-
rences between them are sufficiently important, however, to warrant a more
or less detailed discussion.
603
604 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 0610
politics as exchange. The Calculus was the first book that integrated these
two elements into a coherent, logical structure. Moreover, the Calculus
differed from the precursory works in that it embodied justificatory
argument. It sought to outline, at least in very general terms, the conditions
that must be present for an individual to find it advantageous to enter into a
political entity with constitutionally delineated ranges of activity or to
acquiesce in membership in a historically existing polity. It was recognized
that, if one remains within the presuppositions of methodological
individualism, the state or the polity must ultimately be justified in terms of
its potential for satisfying individuals desires (see also Buchanan, 1987, p.
133).
Furthermore, The Calculus of Consent confronted the market failure
presumption of the new welfare economics by demonstrating that the
problems associated with markets were ubiquitous, indeed entered into the
calculus of political consent arguably with far greater significance because of
the indivisibility of collective action (Rowley, 1993, p. xiii; Goetz, 1991, p.
10). The market failure concepts were applied evenhandedly to the
alternative institutional arrangements, especially those of political control,
and for the first time various policy arguments could benefit from a
consistent and balanced approach.
Finally, the Calculus contained the germs of the recent developement of
the research programme of constitutional political economy. It seems that
Tullocks complaint about the lack of further research along the lines
suggested in the Calculus was premature (Tullock, 1987, p. 139). The
boundary between public choice, in its non-constitutional aspects of inquiry,
and constitutional political economy may seem somewhat fuzzy. It is
generally considered that public choice, in which attention is concentrated
on analyses of alternative political choice structures and on behaviour within
those structures is, through its focus on predictive models of political
interactions, a preliminary but necessary stage to the more general
constitutional inquiry.
On the other hand, law and economics remains somewhat closer to
orthodox economic theory than either constitutional economics or public
choice. The standard efficiency norm remains central to the law and
economics subdiscipline, both as an explanatory benchmark and as a
normative ideal.
The complex relationships between law and economics and public choice
were carefully analysed in (Rowley, 1989). A masterly survey of the public
choice literature is contained in Mueller (1989). Equally recommendable is
Rowleys (1994) essay on Public choice economics in Boettke (1994). In
the present chapter we propose to draw some lessons for law and economics
from recent developments in the re-emerging field of constitutional political
economy.
606 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 0610
2. Leading Journal
evaluated by the same criteria. The analysis and comparison of the working
properties of underlying sets of rules or constraints constitutes the domain of
constitutional economics.
A market is always a system of social interaction characterized by a
specific institutional framework, that is, by a set of rules defining certain
restrictions on the behaviour of the market participants. Market failure
arguments sometimes tend to ignore that the rules upon which a market is
based may well be variable and that an adjustment in these rules is possibly
a better way to deal with alleged shortcomings than to replace market forces
by a political mechanism.
When it is said that the rules upon which a market is based may well be
variable, this should not be misunderstood. It means that the rules can be
varied at the level of constitutional choice. At the level of sub-constitutional
(or post-constitutional) choice, the rules are parameters: they are items that
single economic entities cannot adjust and, indeed, must adjust to. Coases
(1960) tradable property rights are not really rules as the constitutional
economist defines them. Coases tale was about trading defined rights, about
private rearrangements of rights within a given legal structure, not about
redefining the rights that the market participants hold. We will take a closer
look at Coases contribution in the next section.
Elementary to any constitutional analysis is therefore the explicit
recognition of a notion of hierarchy. Any constitutional analysis will
distinguish between at least two levels of choice - constitutional choice and
sub-constitutional (or non-constitutional) choice - and correspondingly also
between constitutional and sub-constitutional preferences. Constitutional
choices are choices among alternative rules (constraints). Sub-constitutional
choices are among alternative strategies available within rules (constraints),
such as ordinary market choices.
4. Methodological Individualism
5. Homo Economicus
6. Normative Individualism
Recapitulating and summarizing, we can say that the two most important
aspects of Buchanans position are his emphasis on rules of the game and
his analysis of efficiency as involving consent. At the most fundamental
level of constitutional choice, consent serves as the basis of justification. It
provides the ultimate criterion of efficiency. Unlike other economists who
have emphasized either the efficiency or rationality of rules, Buchanan is
concerned exclusively with whether or not people consent to them.
It should be noted that Buchanan and traditional economic analysts
develop the relationship between autonomy and efficiency in exactly
opposite ways (Coleman, 1990, p. 141). Traditional economists believe that
efficiency can be defined as a property of social states independent of the
process of voluntary exchange. For example, the perfectly competitive
market is efficient, but the outcome of the prisoners dilemma is not. And
given the logic of the relevant concepts - especially Pareto superiority - it
follows logically that people would consent to efficient rules. Consent
follows from efficiency. Buchanan puts the matter exactly the opposite way.
What people consent to is efficient. Efficiency follows from consent.
In contrast with Paretian optimum resource allocation, a situation of
Wicksellian efficiency will be characterized by the fact that citizens are
satisfied that the existing system of rules, institutions and policies of their
society is free from improper coercion (Wiseman, 1990, p. 110).
The Wicksellian criterion of social efficiency focuses on subjective choice
processes, in marked contrast to the Paretion optimality condition of
neoclassical welfare economics, which permits an external observer to use
individual utility as an objective measure of welfare. Social efficiency is too
complex a notion to be reduced to a set of technical propositions concerning
resource-use. Efficiency is not a property of social states that could be
specified or defined independently of the actions of individuals and the
process of voluntary exchange.
The limitations of conventional Pareto criteria in assessing efficiency are
also discussed by De Alessi (1992).
However, Wicksell did not move beyond the development of criteria for
evaluating policy alternatives one at a time.
Buchanan and Tullock (1962) operationalized Wicksells (1896) insights
and extended the applicability of the unanimity or consensus criterion from
the level of particular proposals to the level of rules - to constitutional rather
than post-constitutional or in-period choices.
For Buchanan and Tullock (1962, Chapter 6) constitutional design was a
matter of determining which voting rule or choice mechanism would be
specified by the constitution for each state activity. The best public decision
rule for each activity was the one that minimized interdependence costs. It
was specified that the representative individual perceived interdependence
0610 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 613
costs for an activity as the sum of the anticipated external costs levied on
that individual if not part of the decision set, and the anticipated decision
making costs experienced by the individual if part of the decision set.
External costs arise because some individuals cash in the benefits of
collective decisions but shift the costs to other individuals. The group forces
an individual to contribute to collective action that is not wanted by that
individual (at that price). From the point of view of the individual in
question, external costs are the result of wrong decisions. The higher the
percentage required for a group decision, the lower the chance of wrong
decisions being made, so that the corresponding curve will show a declining
trend. Decision-making costs are the individual investment of time and
energy in the process of negotiation, expressed in money value. The closer
the requirement of unanimity comes to being met, the higher the decision
costs will be because, among other reasons, strategic behaviour of
individuals becomes more profitable. The corresponding curve therefore has
a rising trend. The sum of both external costs and decision costs was shown
to have a unique minimum somewhere between the extremes of individual
rule and unanimity rule, the exact position depending on relative external
and decision costs.
The shift of the Wicksellian criterion to the constitutional stage of choice
has some remarkable consequences. It becomes conceivable to allow for the
possibility that preferred and agreed-on decision rules might embody sizable
departures from the unanimity limit, including simple majority voting in
some cases and even less than majority voting in others (Buchanan, 1987, p.
135). The constitutional calculus suggests that both the costs of reaching
decisions under different rules and the importance of the decisions are
relevant. Since both of these elements vary, the preferred rule will not be
uniform over all ranges of potential political action. The in period Wickselli-
an criterion may remain valid as a measure of the particularized efficiency of
the single decision examined. But the in period violation of the criterion
does not imply the inefficiency of the rule as long as the latter is itself
selected by a constitutional rule of unanimity.
As a consequence, while it was recognized that unanimity and not
majority rule is the pivot of constitutional democracy, it was equally
demonstrated that at best, majority rule should be viewed as one among
many practical expedients made necessary by the costs of securing
widespread agreement on political issues when individual and group inte-
rests diverge (Buchanan and Tullock, 1962, p. 96).
The appropriate degree of inclusiveness of the collective decision-making
rule - for example qualified majority rule - as an instrument to cope with
perverse forms of uncertainty about the incidence of collective decisions is
discussed in Pinto Barbosa (1994).
614 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 0610
C D
A C 3,3 1,4
D 4,1 2,2
that the collectives loss purchases the subgroups gain (Schmidtz, 1991, p.
91).
Buchanan and Lee (1991) demonstrate that the gains from politically
generated restrictions on markets, even to organized producing interests, are
more apparent than real. The analysis demonstrates that under plausibly
realistic assumptions concerning coalition sizes, excess burdens,
organizational costs and rent seeking outlay, a genuine utility-maximizing
calculus may dictate support for constitutional prohibition of all market
restrictions, by all members of the polity, including those producer interests
that might be considered to be potentially identifiable beneficiaries of
cartelization.
Principal-agent theory has been used to examine the rent-seeking
problem (Anderson and Hill, 1986; Merville and Osborne, 1990). The
principal, also the citizen, grants the agent (the government) the power of
coercion. In exchange, the agent supplies the principal with public goods.
Since the capitalized value of public assets is owned collectively, public-
good outputs of the government are like communal resources with widely
diffused benefits. It soon becomes evident to vote-maximizing agents or
legislators that they can maximize their political support by significantly
reducing the provision of public goods to the population at large in favor of
greater transfers to interest groups. These transfers are financed by general
tax collections and provide concentrated benefits to designated groups. Such
collusion between agents and special interest groups will invariably lead to
the development of a Leviathan state.
Merville and Osborne (1990) use agency theory to demonstrate formally
that, in majority-rule political systems, coalitions of minority factions will
induce politicians to systematically break the constitutional contract in order
to supply special interest projects. Unlike contracts in private markets,
political contracts are much more susceptible to this kind of opportunism.
Is the rent-seeking trap inescapable? A serious consideration of this
question will take us a long way to the understanding of constitutional
political economy.
By far the most important problem with respect to ensuring the self-
enforcing character of a constitutional contract is that it must successfully
constrain the power of the Leviathan state itself. Whereas Brennan and
Buchanan (1980) endow Leviathan with the objective of revenue max-
imization, La Manna and Slomp (1994) argue that Hobbess political con-
struct envisages a sovereign-principal who devises rules and incentives to
induce his subjects-agents to contribute to his own preservation and glory.
Leviathan is a glory seeker instead of a revenue maximizer.
Generally speaking substantive constraints on government have been
dismissed as ineffective precisely because of the wide latitude they allow for
reinterpretation. Wagner and Gwartney (1988, pp. 44-49) make a strong
0610 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 617
9. Judicial Independence
Does independence of the judiciary serve the long-term public good? The
traditional view of the purpose of judicial independence has been attacked as
naive by law and economics and public choice scholars. Unlike many legal
contracts, it is argued, there is no third-party enforcer, external to the
contract, who can ensure that defectors are caught and forced to comply with
the terms of the agreement. Though many countries have a nominally
independent Supreme Court whose purpose is to enforce the constitution, the
Supreme Court can only do this imperfectly in most cases, because the
judges themselves are not totally immune from political pressure by groups
wishing to subvert the original intent of the constitution. Thus, given the
unreliability of third-party enforcement, and given the strong individual
incentives to defect from social cooperation, the constitutional contract
should somehow be self-enforcing if it is to be maintained.
The interest group theory first advanced by Landes and Posner (1975)
makes the independent judiciary an integral part of the system of rent-
seeking engineered by Congress. However, the debate goes on. A very
detailed criticism of the Landes-Posner theory is contained in Boudreaux
and Pritchard (1994). They argue that the Landes-Posner theory is seriously
deficient and conclude that the United States federal judiciary is truly
independent of Congress and the President, and that this independence was
designed by the Constitutions framers as a means of furthering sound
government.
Blankart (1994) compares the legal rules for private clubs with the
constitutions of representative governments. A nearly perfect laboratory case
for a club government can be found in the example of Switzerland. The
Swiss do not have a constitutional court, but have developed instead a
system of popular voting rights serving as a substitute for a judicial review
by a constitutional court. Though this system does not work perfectly, it has
relative advantages in comparison to constitutional courts, which often tend
618 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 0610
C D
A C 3,3 X
D X 2,2
The notion of exit has thus been invoked to give more operational
substance to the concept of voluntary agreement. It is derived from
Hirschmans (1970) classic distinction between exit and voice. Exit (and
entry) is an important means by which individuals are able to express their
preferences, and is precisely the method through which preferences are
revealed in competitive markets for private goods.
An exit option introduces an element of market-like competition into the
contracting process, which limits the ability of any party to wield power over
another party. It is not even necessary that this exit option be exercised,
since merely the threat of its use should be enough to restrain rent
appropriation. The scope for opportunism is effectively constrained by
competition, actual or potential.
Furthermore, it is argued that exit options can help to solve the
constitutional maintenance problem by establishing a competitive
environment for post-constitutional political and market exchange
(Lowenberg and Yu, 1992).
rules can be expected to have on them, that is, by whatever tends to thicken
the veil. The veil notion can be seen as a summary label for factors that, by
increasing uncertainty, tend to alleviate potential conflicts in constitutional
interests.
It should be noted that potential knowledge-based disagreement
obviously requires the opposite cure. The prospects of agreement on
desirable or efficient rules and the prospects for adopting such rules are
enhanced, not by creating uncertainty, but, on the contrary, by raising the
level of mutually-shared information and knowledge on the general working
properties of alternative rules. The Buchanan-Tullock veil of uncertainty
and the Rawlsian veil of ignorance are assumed to render persons
uncertain or ignorant about their particularized interests while not inhibiting
their capability accurately to anticipate the general effects of potential
alternative rules. In other words, their constitutional theories are supposed to
be perfect and non-controversial. Informational problems with regard to the
general working properties of rules do not exist.
This section is concerned with the interest dimension, that is, with the
difficulties involved in any attempt to achieve agreement on rules among
persons with potentially-conflicting constitutional interests. Moreover, once
agreement has been achieved, the agreement must be enforceable because
each individual has a subsequent incentive to defect from the cooperative
agreement.
It is recaIled that in the contractarian and neo-contractarian literature
two lines of reasoning have been pursued which focus central attention on
the interest-component in constitutional choice with a view toward
modification of the constitutional choice setting so as to reconcile potential
divergences. Both are concerned with the general problem of constitutional
efficiency and survivability.
The first line of argument, which is discussed in this section, focuses
attention on the need for a veil of uncertainty as a precondition for an
efficient constitution. The second line of argument adopts an exit (entry)
perspective.
Though Rawlss idea of constitutional choice behind the veil of
ignorance and Buchanans notion of conceptual agreement cannot be
expected to provide a workable criterion upon which actual normative
judgements on existing social arrangements could be based, they do serve a
useful heuristic function by directing attention to the question of whether -
based on our general understanding of the nature of human choice - it can be
plausibly assumed that some existing set of rules could have been voluntarily
agreed upon by all participants at some original stage of decision.
A notion that is typically used in this respect in contractarian theories is
fairness. Fairness can be induced by two independent factors: (1)
632 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 0610
uncertainty, as has been indicated already, and (2) the concern for stability,
which will be discussed below.
In real-world settings persons are typically not totally ignorant about
their particular constitutional interests. But they are not perfectly certain
about these interests either. They typically find themselves behind a veil of
uncertainty that prevents them from accurately anticipating the particular
ways in which they will be affected by the prospective working properties of
alternative rules.
The veils thickness may vary, depending on certain characteristics of the
actual choice situation. As the veils thickness increases so will the prospect
of achieving agreement. The variables that affect the veils thickness can to
some extent be manipulated and rational actors can take deliberate measures
designed to put themselves behind a thicker veil, thereby enhancing the
prospects of realizing potential gains from constitutional agreement.
In this respect the following observations are made. The degree of
uncertainty is, in part, a function of the sort of rules that are under
consideration. The essential dimensions here are the generality and the
durability of rules. The more general rules are and the longer the period over
which they are expected to be in effect, the less certainty persons can have
about the particular ways in which alternative rules will affect them. They
will therefore be induced to adopt a more impartial perspective and,
consequently, they will be more likely to reach agreement. The veil of
uncertainty works by moderating the differences among identifiable
constitutional interests, thus inducing fairness or impartiality and facilitating
agreement in constitutional choice.
There is an additional factor through which fairness can be induced,
independent from the uncertainty factor, but working in the same direction.
This factor is the concern for stability. The possibility of realizing gains by
operating under constitutional constraints is not just a matter of securing
some initial agreement; it is also a matter of a sufficient level of ongoing
agreement, of continuing acquiescence in an ongoing co-operative
arrangement. Stability refers to the viability of a constitutional arrangement
over time. Rational actors can be expected to take considerations of stability
into account when engaging in constitutional choice. To the extent that
fairness and stability are interrelated, the concern for stability will induce a
concern for fairness or impartiality even in persons who may be perfectly
aware of the particular effects that alternative rules will have on them. It is
not the uncertainty about ones own particular position that will induce
impartiality, but the anticipation that a constitutional arrangement is
unlikely to be stable if it is only designed to serve ones own particular
interests.
How precisely are stability and fairness interrelated? Two aspects of the
stability problem should be distinguished. They are not always sufficiently
0610 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 633
Buchanan (1977) criticized Posner (1972) for its failure to make the vital
distinction between the two functional roles in which lawyers may find
themselves: Posner appears to offer potential advice and counsel to future
judges and legislators alike. But, recalls Buchanan, the judge should not
change the basic law because by such behaviour he would be explicitly
abandoning the role of jurist for that of legislator. In his role of jurist he
should enforce existing law instead of enacting new legislation. Buchanan
referred explicitly to Leonis (1961) distinction between law and legislation.
It follows from Buchanans argument that there is no justification at all for a
judicial introduction of the putative efficiency norm, presumably to be
imposed independently of the political process. This view is implied by the
adoption of the subjectivist-contractarian consensus or unanimity rule as a
benchmark for efficiency. The normative economist can advance alternative
sets of rules as a hypothesis to be tested in the political exchange process,
but he should never be allowed to take the arrogant stance of suggesting that
this or that set of institutions is or is not more efficient.
In a similar vein De Alessi and Staaf (1991) argue that the law and
economics view of the common law as an efficient process that promotes the
evolution of efficient rules through an auction-like mechanism is flawed
because it fails to cope with the problem of aggregating preferences. They
argue that the belief that the efficiency of the common law is enhanced by
assigning disputed rights so as to lower transaction costs is also flawed. The
common law provides a form of unanimity by allowing individuals to
contract around the rule and provides order by maintaining transitivity,
through the use of precedent, in the application of the rule to new situations.
Aranson (1992) highlights another problem: in the neoclassical approach
to law and economics, the common law judges, in rendering decisions that
maximize wealth, are placed in the position of calculators of comparative
values. However, this task confronts the courts with an insoluble economic
calculation problem, analogous to the problem faced by central economic
planners. Therefore, courts should prefer to stay as close by as they can to a
rights-based jurisprudence.
Wagner (1992) argues that social processes regarding the formation of
rules should be assessed in terms of their ability to provide a framework of
stable rules guaranteeing the stability of expectations and allowing people to
plan their economic activities. The dichotomy between statutory and
common law is overdrawn, because both derive from the same source in a
setting where there are no longer polycentric sources of competing authority,
since the contemporary nation-state - presumably Wagner has the United
0610 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 635
States of America in mind - has the capacity to absorb all alternative sources
of authority into itself.
More radically Benson (1992b) argues that the government-backed
common law system is more likely to adopt inefficient rules than a genuine
customary law system. Though he recognizes that much of common law was
simply a codification of the basic norms common to Anglo-Saxon society,
Benson recalls that common law was also royal law and that even during its
earliest periods of development some aspects of it were legislated and
imposed by authoritarian kings. Furthermore, when a governments judges
make new law through precedent, it becomes enforceable law for everyone in
the society whether it is a mutually beneficial law or not. Common law
precedents are backed by the coercive power of the state and, therefore they
take on the same authority as statute law.
Yandle (1991) develops a vision of the Common Law as an organic
Constitution, reflecting evolved social norms, a result that causes ordinary
people to accept the authority of judges.
the rules or principles of a liberal order rather than on the outcomes, James
Madison can properly be viewed as a pioneering constitutional political
economist. Drawing on the political theory of Locke and the economic
theory of Smith, Madison successfully combined the two to form a coherent
theory of constitutional economics. Adopting a self-interest postulate, he
showed that social and economic order are best achieved by allowing open
competition to prevail under a rule of law protecting private property and
freedom of contract. Thus, he clearly recognized the close relation between
political order and economic order, and he anticipated many of the themes
in the public choice/constitutional economics literature.
One of the insights of Madison and other framers of the US constitution
was that a bicameral legislature might function as a device to limit the
power of legislative coalitions. The idea was that each house would be
elected differently and consequently would represent different interests. The
requirement of a simultaneous majority in both houses in order for
legislation to be enacted would then guarantee a broad social consensus. It
should be noted that the differences between the two chambers have been
eroded subsequently. However, the argument for bicameral legislatures on
efficiency grounds and the urge that the two houses be elected by radically
different methods, was at the theoretical level revived in this century by
Tullock (see Buchanan and Tullock, 1962, Chap. 16, written by Tullock; see
also Tullock, 1987).
Elazar (1991) argues that the work of an early political scientist,
Johannes Althusius, who developed his theory of the polity on the eve of the
modern epoch at the end of the sixteenth century, offers an important
starting point for building a postmodern theory of political and social
organization. Althusius (1991) is a collection of excerpts from his Politica
Methodice Digesta (1603/1614).
Sir Edward Cokes role as a constitutional entrepreneur in seventeenth-
Century England is highlighted in Yandle (1993).
Streit (1993) brings out clearly how Hayeks approach to the social
sciences, especially to economics, is rooted in his epistemological position,
particularly as he set it out in Hayek (1952). Butos and Koppl (1993) outline
a theory of expectations based on Hayeks cognitive theory. The central tenet
of the theory, which is intended to have both policy implications and testable
empirical content, is that economic expectations will serve as reliable guides
to action only when certain filtering conditions, that is certain consti-
tutional constraints such as the atomicity of the market process and the
stability of the rules governing that process are satisfied. A failure of either
condition creates a loose system constraint and thus a loose link between
environment and expectation, as the theory of big players illustrates. Big
players, of which central bankers are a prototypical example, introduce a
wedge between epistemic knowledge and social reality. The theory
highlights the connection between the choice of constraints and its epistemic
consequences. The big player theory also suggests a possible direction for
future empirical work in a Hayekian tradition. Within the adopted
framework neoclassical economics and radical Keynesianism may be
seen in a sense as limiting cases. When certain filtering conditions are in
place, the results of the market process may be described by neoclassical
models of rational maximizing and action will seem predictable at least at
some aggregate level. To the extent that these conditions fail, the market
process will be influenced by animal spirits and the like and action will seem
unpredictable to the observing economist. Thus the evolutionary logic of
Hayekian economics provides the general theoretical foundations for special
empirical theories, such as the big player theory, which may identify the
precise causes and consequences of observed deviation from the neoclassical
model.
It is to be regretted that the recently developing literature on, say,
monetary constitutionalism has largely failed to incorporate these Hayekian
insights. Recent events in the European Monetary System on the one hand,
and monetary disintegration in the former Soviet Union on the other, have
revived interest in the question of how to design and choose a monetary
regime that ensures monetary stability for both parts of Europe. Even among
economists who are otherwise considered staunch advocates of laissez-faire
policy, money is still regarded as the prime and uncontroversial example of
a good that has to be provided by government. Buchanan (1962), accepting
the premise that money is a public good that can only be provided by
government, derives its optimal properties from a constitutional perspective.
In the same vein Spinelli and Masciandaro (1993) argue for a
constitutionalization of the target of monetary stability in Italy.
Hefeker (1995) has argued that the objective of monetary stability can be
achieved either by complete monetary union or by currency competition and
that both regimes may be viable solutions depending on the circumstances.
638 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 0610
His paper makes the case for monetary union in Western Europe, even
though he recognizes that monetary union is no alternative for Eastern
Europe and the former Soviet Union.
We believe that the critical examination and evaluation of the properties
of alternative monetary regimes constitutes one of the most interesting and
exciting lines of future research within the field of constitutional economics.
Choi (1993) offers a critical evaluation of Hayeks atavism of social
justice thesis, suggesting an alternative explanation for the widespread
demands for social justice in contemporary society, based on the analysis of
the nature of entrepreneurship and its tendency to incite envy.
Tuerck (1995) re-interprets Hayeks theory of mind in the light of
contemporary philosophy of artificial intelligence.
21. Redistribution
There have been two recent attempts to provide a rationale for redistribution
within the scope of constitutional political economy. Kliemt (1993b) argues
that redistribution can be institutionalized at the constitutional level to attain
a minimum welfare state without violating basic principles or incurring
risks beyond those that are present in the minimal state itself. Wessels
(1993) describes a situation in which individuals may unanimously agree to
transfer income at the constitutional stage on the grounds that redistribution
provides income insurance. Both are criticized, invoking the usual
arguments, by Pasour (1994).
Streit and Mussler (1994) analyse the changes in the economic constitution
of the European Community since its foundation in 1958. It is argued that as
far as the economic constitution is concerned, the Treaty of Maastricht is
640 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 0610
E. Conclusions
Throughout the writing of the present article we constantly had in mind the
editors aim of providing the readers of the Encyclopedia of Law and
Economics with a well-informed overview of the existing literature. Some
readers may find that our strategy of favouring comprehensiveness at the
expense of structure has to some degree distracted from the flow of
argument. However, we are reasonably confident that the unifying theme
0610 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 641
Adelstein, Richard P. (1991), Deciding for Bigness: Constitutional Choice and the Growth of
Firms, 2 Constitutional Political Economy, 7-30.
Althusius, Johannes (1991), An Early Contractarian Constitutionalist (Excerpts from his Politica
Methodice Digesta), 2 Constitutional Political Economy, 209-223.
Anderson, Gary M. and Tollison, Robert D. (1992), Morality and Monopoly: The Constitutional
Political Economy of Religious Rules, 12 Cato Journal, 373-392.
Anderson, Terry L. and Hill, Peter J. (1986), Constraining the Transfer Society: Constitutional and
Moral Dimensions, 6 Cato Journal, 317-341.
Apolte, T. (1995), Democracy, Dictatorship, and Transformation: A Proposal for a
Constitution-Guided Systematic Change in Formerly Soviet Republics, 6 Constitutional
Political Economy, 5-20.
Aranson, Peter H. (1991), Calhouns Constitutional Economics, 2 Constitutional Political
Economy, 31-52.
Aranson, Peter H. (1992), The Common Law as Central Economic Planning, 3 Constitutional
Political Economy, 289-319.
Arantes, Peter, Gellhorn, Ernest A. and Robinson, Glen O. (1983), A Theory of Legislative
Delegation, 68 Cornell Law Review, 23-56.
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1951), Social Choice and Individual Values, New York, John Wiley and Sons.
Axelrod, Robert (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation, New York, Basic Books.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (1978), Pareto on Public Choice, 33 Public Choice, 5-17.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (1995), An Economic Analysis of Constitutional Law, research
memorandum, Maastricht, University of Limburg.
Backhaus, Jrgen G. (1996), An Economic Analysis of Constitutional Law, in Buscaglia,
Edgardo, Ratliff, William and Cooter, Robert (eds), Law and Economics of Development,
Greenwood, JAI Press.
Baird, Charles W. (1989), James Buchanan and the Austrians: The Common Ground, Cato
Journal, 201 ff.
Barnes, David W. and Stout, Lynn A. (1992), Economics of Constitutional Law and Public
Choice, St Pauls West Publishing Company.
Becker, Gary S. (1983), A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence,
98 Quarterly Journal of Economics, 371-383.
Ben-Shahar, O. (1992), Strategic Behavior in Judicial Panels, Discussion Paper No. 107, Program
in Law and Economics, Harvard Law School.
Benson, Bruce L. (1981a), Why are Congressional Committees Dominated by High Demand
Legislators?, 48 Southern Economic Journal, 68-77.
Benson, Bruce L. (1981b), A Note on Corruption of Public Officials: The Black Market for
Property Rights, 5 Journal of Libertarian Studies, 305-311.
Benson, Bruce L. (1983a), High Demand Legislative Committees and Bureaucratic Output, 11
Public Finance Quarterly, 259-281.
Benson, Bruce L. (1983b), The Economic Theory of Regulation as an Explanation of Policies
Toward Bank Mergers and Holding Company Acquisitions, 28 Antitrust Bulletin, 839-862.
0610 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 643
Benson, Bruce L., Kim, Iljoong and Rasmussen, David W. (1994), Estimating Deterrence Effects:
A Public Choice Perspective on the Economics of Crime Literature, 61 Southern Economic
Journal, 161-168.
Benson, Bruce L., Rasmussen, David W. and Sollars, David L. (1995), Police Bureaucrats, Their
Incentives, and the War on Drugs, 83 Public Choice, 21-45.
Bergstrom, John C. and Centner, Terence J. (1989), Agricultural Nuisances and Right to Farm
Laws, 19 Review of Regional Studies, 23-30.
Binmore, Ken (1990), Evolution and Utilitarianism: Social Contract III, 1 Constitutional
Political Economy, 1-26.
Black, D. (1958), The Theory of Committees and Elections, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press.
Blankart, Charles B. (1994), Club Governments versus Representative Governments, 5
Constitutional Political Economy, 273-285.
Blankart, Charles B. (1996), The European Unions Debt Question: A Conceptual Viewpoint, 7
Constitutional Political Economy, 257-265.
Boettke, Peter (ed.) (1994), The Elgar Companion to Austrian Economics, Brookfield, Edward
Elgar.
Boudreaux, D.J. and Pritchard, A.C. (1994), Reassessing the Role of the Independent Judiciary in
Enforcing Interest-Group Bargains, 5 Constitutional Political Economy, 1-21.
Brennan, Geoffrey (1987), The Buchanan Contribution, 45 Finanzarchiv, 1-24.
Brennan, Geoffrey (1990), James Buchanans Public Economics: One Proposition, Two
Speculations and Three Queries, 1 Constitutional Political Economy, 113-133.
Brennan, G. and Buchanan, James M. (1980), The Power to Tax: Analytical Foundations of a
Fiscal Constitution, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Brennan, G. and Hamlin, A (1995), Economizing on Virtue, 6 Constitutional Political Economy,
35-56.
Brennan, Geoffrey and Kliemt, Hartmut (1990), Logo Logic, 1 Constitutional Political Economy,
125-127.
Brennan, Geoffrey and Pardo, Jose Casas (1991), A Reading of the Spanish Constitution (1978), 2
Constitutional Political Economy, 53-79.
Brinig, Margaret F. (1992), Politics, Economics and the McCarren Ferguson Act, 73 Public
Choice, 371-383.
Brinig, Margaret F. (1993), The Law and Economics of No-Fault Divorce, 27 Family Law
Quarterly, 453-470.
Brinig, Margaret F. (1995), Through a Glass Darkly, a Review of Neil Komesars Imperfect
Alternatives, 78 Public Choice, 190-194.
Brinig, Margaret F., Holcombe, Randall G. and Schwartzstein, Linda A. (1993), Public Choice and
Lobbying Regulation, 74 Public Choice, 377-384.
Brooks, Michael (1997), Some Reflections on The Calculus of Consent, 8 Constitutional Political
Economy, 3-13.
Brunetti, Aymo and Weder, Beatrice (1994), Political Credibility and Economic Growth in Less
Developed Countries, 5 Constitutional Political Economy, 23-43.
Buchanan, James M. (1959), Positive Economics, Welfare Economics, and Political Economy, 2
Journal of Law and Economics, 124-138.
0610 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 645
de Figueiredo, John M. and Tiller, Emerson H. (1996), Congressional Control of the Courts: A
Theoretical and Empirical Analysis of Expansion of the Federal Judiciary, 39 Journal of Law
and Economics, 435-462.
Dnes, Antony W. (1988), Rent Seeking, Entrepreneurship, Subjectivism and Property Rights: A
Comment, 144 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 891-893.
Dnes, Antony W. (1989), Rent Seeking, Conflict and Property Rights, 36 Scottish Journal of
Political Economy, 366-374.
Dorn, James A. (1991), Madisons Constitutional Political Economy: Principles for a Liberal
Order, 2 Constitutional Political Economy, 163-186.
Downs, A. (1957), An Economic Analysis of Democracy, New York, Harper and Row.
Dreyer, M. (1993), German Roots of the Theory of Pluralism, 4 Constitutional Political
Economy, 7-39.
Dwight, Lee (1997), Dennis C. Mueller: Constitutional Democracy (Book Review), 8
Constitutional Political Economy, 165-167.
Eichenberger, Reiner (1994), The Benefits of Federalism and the Risk of Overcentralization,
47(3) Kyklos, 403-420.
Elazar, Daniel J. (1991), The Multifaceted Covenant: The Biblical Approach to the Problem of
Organizations, Constitutions, and Liberty as Reflected in the Thought of Johannes Althusius, 2
Constitutional Political Economy, 187-208.
Elhauge, Einer Richard (1991), Does Interest Group Theory Justify More Intrusive Judicial
Review?, 101 Yale Law Journal, 31 ff.
Elhauge, Einer Richard (1996), Are Term Limits Undemocratic, 63 University of Chicago Law
Review.
Farber, Daniel A. and Frickey, Philip P. (1991), Law and Public Choice: A Critical Introduction,
Chicago, IL, University of Chicago Press, 159 p.
Fischel, William A. (1979), Determinants of Voting on Environmental Quality: A Study of a New
Hampshire Pulp Mill Referendum, 6 Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management, 107-118.
Fischel, William A. (1980), Zoning and Land Use Reform: A Property Rights Perspective, 1
Virginia Journal of Natural Resources Law, 69-93.
Fischel, William A. (1992), Property Taxation and the Tiebout Model: Evidence for the Benefit
View from Zoning and Voting, 30 Journal of Economic Literature, 163-169.
Fischel, William A. (1996), The Political Economy of Just Compensation: Lessons from the
Military Draft for the Takings Issue, 19 Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy.
Fischel, William A. and Campbell, Colin D. (1996), Preferences for School Finance Systems:
Voters versus Judges, 49 National Tax Journal, 1-15.
Fishel, William A. and Shapiro, Perry (1988), Takings, Insurance and Michelman: Comments on
Economic Interpretations of Just Compensation Law, 17 Journal of Legal Studies, 269-293.
Reprinted in Ellickson, Robert, Rose, Carol and Ackerman, Bruce (eds), Perspectives on
Property Law, 2nd edn, 514-530, Boston, Little Brown, 1995.
Fischel, William A. and Shapiro, Perry (1989), A Constitutional Choice Model of Compensation
for Takings, 9 International Review of Law and Economics, 115-128.
648 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 0610
Frech, H. Edward III (1972), The Public Choice Theory of Murray N. Rothbard: A Modern
Anarchist, 14 Public Choice, 143-154.
Frech, H. Edward III, Deacon, Rovert, Decanio, Stephen J. and Johnson, Bruce M. (1990), Taxing
Energy: Oil Severence Taxation and the Economy, New York, Holmes and Meyer.
Frey, Bruno S. (1990), From Paradoxes to Social Rules, or: How Economics Repeats Itself, 1
Constitutional Political Economy, 27-34.
Frey, Bruno S. (1996), A Directly Democratic and Federal Europe, 7 Constitutional Political
Economy, 267-279.
Garcia Villarejo, Salinas, Avelino and Snchez, Javier (1993), Manual de Hacienda Pblica
general y de Espaa (Public Treasury Manual), Madrid, Tecnos.
Garcia Viuela, Enrique (1996a), Financing Political Parties: A Public Choice Approvach,
Economia delle Scelte Pubbliche, 2-3.
Garcia Viuela, Enrique (1996b), La Financiacin de los Partidos Polticos: un Enfoque de
Eleccin Pblica (Financing Political Parties: A Public Choice Approach), 92 Revista de
Estudios Polticos.
Garcia Viuela, Enrique (1996c), Una nota sobre la Teora del Estado de Anthony de Jasay (A
Note on Anthony de Jasays Theory of the State), 136 Hacienda Pblica Espaola.
Garcia Viuela, Enique and Vazquez Vega, Pablo (1996a), Financing the Political Parties: A
Public Choice Approach, 2-3 Ecomonia delle Scette Pubbliche, 139-153.
Garcia Viuela, Enrique and Vazquez Vega, Pablo (1996b), La Financiacin de los Partidos
Politicos. Un Enfoque de Eleccin Pblica (Financing Political Parties: A Public Choice
Approach), 92 Revista de Estudios Polticos.
Gaus, Gerald F. (1991), Public Justification and Democratic Adjudication, 2 Constitutional
Political Economy, 251-281.
Goetz, C.J. (1991), Uncommon Common-sense vs. Conventional Wisdom: The Virginia School of
Economics, Prepared for the Seventh Annual Lecture in the Virginia Political Economy.
Goldberg, Victor P. (1974), Public Choice - Property Rights, 8 Journal of Economic Issues,
555-579. Reprinted in Samuels (ed.), Methodology of Economic Thought, New Brunswick,
NJ, Transaction Books, 1978.
Goldberg, Victor P. (1977), On Positive Theories of Redistribution, 11 Journal of Economic
Issues, 119-132.
Goldberg, Victor P. (1982), Peltzman on Regulation and Politics, 39 Public Choice, 291-297.
Goldberg, Victor P. (1988), Clarifying the Record: A Comment, 144 Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics, 885-888.
Goldberg, Victor P. and Olmstead, Alan L. (1975), Institutional Change and American Economic
Growth - A Critique of Davis and North, 12 Explorations in Economic History, 193-210.
Gray, John H. (1990), Buchanan on Liberty, 1 Constitutional Political Economy, 149-168.
Greenhut, Melvin L. and Benson, Bruce L. (1989), American Antitrust Law in Theory and in
Practice, Aldershot, Avebury.
Gruner, Hans Peter (1995), Evolutionary Stability of Social Norms in a Socioeconomic
Equilibrium Model, 6 Constitutional Political Economy, 233-245.
0610 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 649
Gunter, Frank R. (1991), Thomas Jefferson on the Repudiation of Public Debt, 2 Constitutional
Political Economy, 283-301.
Hardin, Russell (1990), Contractarianism: Wistful Thinking, 1 Constitutional Political Economy,
35-52.
Hasen, Richard L. (1993), An Enriched Economic Model of Political Patronage and Campaign
Contributions: Revising Supreme Court Jurisprudence, 14 Cardozo Law Review, 1311 ff.
Hasen, Richard L. (1996a), Voting Without Law?, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law Review,
2135 ff.
Hasen, Richard L. (1996b), Clipping Coupons for Democracy: An Egalitarian/Public Choice
Defense of Campaign Finance Vouchers, 84 California Law Review, 1 ff.
Hefeker, Carsten (1995), Monetary Union or Currency Competition? Currency Arrangements for
Monetary Stability in East and West, 6 Constitutional Political Economy, 57-69.
Heiner, Ronald A. (1983), The Origin of Predictable Behavior, 73 American Economic Review,
560-595.
Heiner, Ronald A. (1990), Rule-Governed Behavior in Evolution and Human Society, 1
Constitutional Political Economy, 19-46.
Hirschman, Albert O. (1970), Exit, Voice and Loyalty, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Holcombe, Randall G. (1991), Constitutions as Constraints: A Case Study of Three American
Constitutions, 2 Constitutional Political Economy, 303-328.
Holcombe, Randall G. (1996), Viberts Vision: Constitutional Theory in Search of a Constitution,
7 Constitutional Political Economy, 281-291.
Isaac, R. Mark, Mathieu, Deborah and Zajac, Edward E. (1991), Institutional Framing and
Perceptions of Fairness, 2 Constitutional Political Economy, 329-370.
Kiser, Larry L. (1994), A Constitutional Theory of Public Enterprise, 5 Constitutional Political
Economy, 287-306.
Klein, Daniel B. (1990), The Microfoundations of Rules vs. Discretion, 1 Constitutional Political
Economy, 1-19.
Kliemt, Hartmut (1993a), Constitutional Commitments, 12 Jahrbuch fr Neue Politische
konomie, 145-173.
Kliemt, Hartmut (1993b), On Justifying a Minimum Welfare State, 4 Constitutional Political
Economy, 159-172.
Kliemt, Hartmut (1995), Rule of Law and the Welfare State, 56 Philosophica, 121-132.
Kratochwil, Friedrich (1992), International Order and Individual Liberty: A Critical Examination
of Realism as a Theory of International Politics, 3 Constitutional Political Economy, 29-50.
Kuran, Timur (1993), Mitigating the Tyranny of Public Opinion: Anonymous Discourse and the
Ethic of Sincerity, 4 Constitutional Political Economy, 41-78.
Kurz, Heinz D. (ed.) (1993), United Germany and the new Europe, Aldershot, Elgar, 333 p.
La Manna, Manfredi M.A. and Slomp, Gabriella (1994), Leviathan: Revenue Maximizer or Glory
Seeker?, 5 Constitutional Political Economy, 159-172.
Langlois, Richard N. (1995), Do Firms Plan?, 6 Constitutional Political Economy, 247-261.
650 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 0610
Miller, Geoffrey P. and Macey, Jonathan R. (1987), Toward an Interest Group Theory of Delaware
Corporate Law, 65 Texas Law Review, 469 ff.
Mitchell, W.C. (1988), Virginia, Rochester and Bloomington: Twenty-five Years of Public Choice
and Political Science, 56 Public Choice, 101-119.
Moser, Peter (1994), Constitutional Protection of Economic Rights: The Swiss and U.S. Experience
in Comparison, 5 Constitutional Political Economy, 61-79.
Mueller, Dennis C. (1989), Public Choice II, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 518 p.
Mueller, Dennis C. (1990), James M. Buchanan: Economist cum Contractarian, 1 Constitutional
Political Economy, 169-196.
Mueller, Dennis C. (1996), Constitutional Quandaries in Europe, 7 Constitutional Political
Economy, 293-302.
Niskanen, William A. (1990), Conditions Affecting the Survival of Constitutional Rules, 1
Constitutional Political Economy, 53-62.
Ordeshook, Peter C. (1992), Constitutional Stability, 3 Constitutional Political Economy,
137-175.
Ordeshook, P.C. and Shvetsova, O. (1995), If Hamilton and Madison were Merely Lucky, What
Hope is there for Russian Federalism?, 6 Constitutional Political Economy, 107-126.
Ostrom, Vincent (1996), Faustian Bargains, 7 Constitutional Political Economy, 303-308.
Parisi, Francesco (1995), Toward a Theory of Spontaneous Law, 6 Constitutional Political
Economy, 211-231.
Pasour, E.C., Jr (1994), Redistribution and Constitutional Political Economy, 5 Constitutional
Political Economy, 81-98.
Pauly, Mark V. (1994), Avoiding the Mistreatment of Bad Risks in a Democracy: Universal Health
Insurance from a Constitutional Perspective, 5 Constitutional Political Economy, 307-318.
Pelikan, Pavel (1993), Ownership of Firms and Efficiency: The Competence Argument, 4
Constitutional Political Economy, 349-392.
Pies, Ingo (1996), Public Choice versus Constitutional Economics: A Methodological
Interpretation of the Buchanan Research Program, 7 Constitutional Political Economy, 21-34.
Pinto Barbosa, A.S. (1994), Manipulating Uncertainty, 5 Constitutional Political Economy,
255-271.
Posner, Eric (1997), The Political Economy of the Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978', 96 Michigan
Law Review.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1987), El Programa de la Economa Constitucional: Una Sntesis (The
Constitutional Economics Program: an Abstract), 192 Revista de Derecho Financiero y
Hacienda Pblica, 1181-1194.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1991), Contractualismo y Justicia (Contractualism and Justice), in M. Otero, C.
Rovira y M. Segura (Coords), Problemas de la Ciencia Jurdica. Homenaje a Francisco Puy
Muoz, Santiago, Servicio de Publicacins da Universidade de Santiago de Compostela,
269-289.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1993), Anlisis Econmico del Derecho y la Poltica (Economic Analysis of
Law and Politics), Santiago de Compostela, Fundacin Alfredo Braas, 224 p.
652 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 0610
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1994), Eleccin Pblica y Estado del Bienestar (Public Choice and Welfare
State), in Luis Carams (ed.), La Crisis del Estado del Bienestar, Santiago de Compostela,
Asociacin Galega de Estudios de Economa do Sector Pblico, 481-506.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1995a), Democracia Representativa e Reforma Constitucional (Representative
Democracy and Constitutional Reform), in Leiceaga, Fernndez, Rodrguez, Jordn, Iglesias,
E. Lpez and Deza, X. Vence (eds), Estudos en Homenaxe Profesor Xose Manuel Beiras
Torrado, Universidade de Santiago de Compostela, 141-161.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1995b), Economa y Poltica en Yugoslavia (1945-1990): el Fracaso de un
Experimento de Organizacin Econmica y Social, in Economics and Politics in Jugoslavia
(1945-1990): A Failed Experiment of Social and Economic Organization; La crisis de los
Balcanes, monografas del CESEDEN, Madrid, Ministerio de Defensa, 115-136.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1995c), Economa en Broma y en Serio (Economics for Fun and Serious),
Madrid, Minerva, Fundacin Alfredo Braas, 163 p.
Puy Fraga, Pedro (1995d), Economa constitucional y Constitucin espaola de 1978
(Constitutional Political Economy and The Spanish Constitution of 1978), Santiago de
Compostela, edicin en microficha, Servicio de Publicaciones da Universidade de Santiago de
Compostela.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1994), The Puzzling (In)Dependence of Courts: A Comparative Approach, 23
Journal of Legal Studies, 721-747.
Ramseyer, J. Mark and Rosenbluth, Frances McCall (1993), Japans Political Marketplace,
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Ramseyer, J. Mark and Rosenbluth, Frances M. (1995), The Politics of Oligarchy: Institutional
Choice in Imperial Japan, New York, Cambridge University Press.
Rasmusen, Eric and Ramseyer, J. Mark (1994), Cheap Bribes and the Corruption Ban: A
Coordination Game Among Rational Legislators, 78 Public Choice, 305 ff.
Rasmussen, David W. and Benson, Bruce L. (eds) (1994), The Economic Anatomy of a Drug War:
Criminal Justice in the Commons, Lanham, MD, Rowman and Littlefield.
Rawls, John (1971), A Theory of Justice, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Ribstein, Larry E. (1992a), Efficiency, Regulation and Competition: A Comment on Easterbrook
and Fischel, 87 Northwestern University Law Review, 254 ff.
Ribstein, Larry E. (1992b), Corporate Political Speech, 49 Washington and Lee Law Review, 109
ff.
Ribstein, Larry E. (1993), The Mandatory Rules of the ALI Code, 61 George Washington Law
Review, 984 ff.
Ribstein, Larry E. (1995), The Constitutional Conception of the Corporation, 4 Supreme Court
Economic Review, 95 ff.
Roin, Julie, A. (1988), United they Stand, Divided They Fall: Public Choice Theory and the Tax
Code, 74 Cornell Law Review, 62-134.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1992), Rethinking The Progressive Agenda: The Reform of The
American Regulatory State, New York, Free Press, 1992.
Rowley, Charles K. (1989), Public Choice and the Economic Analysis of Law, in Mercuro,
Nicholas (ed.), Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 123-174.
Rowley, Charles K. (1992), The Supreme Court and Takings Judgments: Constitutional Political
Economy versus Public Choice, in Mercuro, Nicholas (ed.), Taking Property and Just
0610 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 653
Compensation: Law and Economics Perspectives of the Takings Issue, Boston, Kluwer
Academic Publishers, 79-124.
Rowley, Charles K. (1993), Introduction, in Rowley, Charles K. (ed.), Public Choice Theory
Volume I, The International Library of Critcal Writings in Economics, Aldershot, Edward
Elgar, ix-xxix.
Rowley, Charles K. (1994), Public Choice Economics, in Boettke, Peter, The Elgar Companion
to Austrian Economics, Brookfield, VT, Edward Elgar, 285-293.
Rubin, Paul H. (1975), On the Form of Special Interest Legislation, Public Choice, 75-90.
Rubin, Paul H. (1979), Public Interest Lobbies: Membership and Influence, Public Choice, 45-54.
Rubin, Paul H. and Kau, James B. (1978), Voting on Minimum Wages: A Time Series Analysis,
Journal of Political Economy, 337-342.
Rubin, Paul H. and Kau, James B. (1981), The Impact of Labor Unions on the Passage of
Economic Legislation, Journal of Labor Economics, 133-145.
Rubin, Paul H. and Kau, James B. (1993), Ideology, Voting and Shirking, Public Choice,
151-172.
Rubin, Paul H., Kau, James B. and Keenan, Donald C. (1982), A General Equilibrium Model of
Congressional Voting, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 271-294.
Ruiter, Dick W.P. (1994), Economic and Legal Institutionalism: What can they Learn from Each
Other?, 5 Constitutional Political Economy, 99-115.
Ruiz-Huerta Carbonell, Jess (1992), Vigencia y Operatividad del Principio de la no
Confiscatoriedad de los Tributos en el Ordenamiento Espaol (The Principle of Non
Confiscation of Taxes: Enforcement in Spain), 64 Revista Crnica Tributaria.
Ruiz-Huerta Carbonell, Jess (1994), The Dimension, Effectiveness and Effciency of Public
Expenditure, in, Wildavsky, Aaron and Zapico-Goni, Eduardo (eds), National Budgeting for
Economic and Monetary Union, European Institute of Public Administration, 195-199.
Ruiz-Huerta Carbonell, Jess (1995), Las Rentas de las Personas Mayores (Eldest Citizens
Income), SECOT.
Ruiz-Huerta Carbonell, Jess and Gimnez, Antonio (eds) (1993), Estructura Institucional y
Gestin del Gasto Pblico en Algunos Paises de la OCDE (Institutuional Structure and
Managment of Public Expenditure in Some Countries), Estudios de Hacienda Pblica, Instituto
de Estudios Fiscales.
Ruiz-Huerta Carbonell, Jess, Alvarez, Jess, Ayala, Luis, Iriondo, Iaki, Martinez, Rosa and
Palacios, Juan Ignacio (1995), La Distribucin Funcional y Personal de la Renta en Espaa
(Functional and Personal Distribution of Income in Spain), Premio de Investagin 1995 del
Consejo Econmico y Social.
Ryssdal, Stray A.C. (1995), Legal Realism and Economics as Behavior - A Scandinavian Look at
the Economic Analysis of Law, Oslo, Juridisk Forlag AS, Nerenius & Santrus Frlag AB Gad
Jura AS.
Salinas, Javier (1980), Traduccin e Introduccin a la Versin Espaola (The Calculation of
Consensus), in Buchanan, J.M. and Tullock, G., El Clculo del Consenso, Madrid, Ed.
Espasa Calpe.
Salinas, Javier (1991), Economa Poltica del Federalismo Fiscal Espaol (Political Economy of
the Spanish Fiscal Federalism), Madrid, Instituto de Estudios Fiscales.
654 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 0610
Schumpeter, Jospeh A. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, New York, Harper and
Row.
Schwartzstein, Linda A. (1991), Bureaucracy Unbounded: The Lack of Effective Constraints on
the Judicial Process, 35 St Louis University Law Journal, 597 ff.
Shaviro, Daniel N. (1990), Beyond Public Choice and Public Interest: A Study of the Legislative
Process As Illustrated by Tax Legislation in the 1980s, 139 University of Pennsylvania Law
Review, 1-123.
Shaviro, Daniel N. (1997), Do Deficits Matter?, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Simon, Herbert A. (1976), From Substantive to Procedural Rationality, in Latsis, S.J. (ed.),
Method and Appraisal in Economics, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 129-148.
Sinn, Stefan (1992), The Taming of Leviathan: Competition Among Governments, 3
Constitutional Political Economy, 177-196.
Sobel, Russell S. (1994), The League of Nations Covenant and the United Nations Charter: An
Analysis of Two International Constitutions, 5 Constitutional Political Economy, 173-192.
Sobel, Russell S. (1996), Viberts European Union: A United Nations or a United States?, 7
Constitutional Political Economy, 309-316.
Solvason, Birgir T.R. (1993), Institutional Evolution in the Icelandic Commonwealth, 4
Constitutional Political Economy, 97-125.
Spence, David B. (1997), Administrative Law and Agency Policymaking: Rethinking the Positive
Theory of Political Control, 14 Yale Journal on Regulation.
Spindler, Z.A. (1990), Constitutional Design for a Rent Seeking Society: Voting Rule Choice, 1
Constitutional Political Economy, 73-82.
Spinelli, Franco and Masciandaro, Donato (1993), Towards Monetary Constitutionalism in Italy:
With a Rehearing of the Debate for the Drawing up of the Present Constitution, 4
Constitutional Political Economy, 211-222.
Stout, Lynn A. (1992), Strict Scrutiny and Social Choice: An Economic Inquiry into Fundamental
Rights and Suspect Classifications, 80 Georgetown Law Journal, 1787-ff.
Stout, Lynn A. (1993), Poverty and Failure in the Market for Human Capital, 81 Georgetown
Law Journal, 1947 ff.
Stout, Lynn A. and Barnes, David D. (1992), Cases and Materials on Law and Economics, St
Pauls West Publishing Company.
Stout, Lynn A. and Barnes, David D. (1992), Economics of Constitutional Law and Public
Choice, St Pauls West Publishing Company.
Streit, Manfred E. (1993), Cognition, Competition, and Catallaxy: In Memory of Friedrich August
von Hayek, 4 Constitutional Political Economy, 223-262.
Streit, Manfred E. and Mussler, Werner (1994), The Economic Constitution of the European
Community: From Rome to Maastricht, 5 Constitutional Political Economy, 319-353.
Streit, Manfred E. and Voigt, Stefan (1993), The Economics of Conflict Resolution in International
Trade, in Friedmann, D. and Mestmcker, E.J. (eds), Conflict Resolution in International
Trade, Baden-Baden: Nomos, 39-77.
Streit, Manfred E. and Voigt, Stefan (1996), Toward Ever Closer Union - Or Ever Larger? Or
Both? Entry to the European Union from the Perspective of Constitutional Economics, 16
International Review of Law and Economics, 385-388.
656 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 0610
Other References
Alchian, Armen A. (1950), Uncertainty, Evolution and Economic Theory, 58 Journal of Political
Economy, 211-221. Reprinted in: Alchian, Armen A., Economic Forces at Work, 1977,
Indianapolis, LibertyPress, Chapter 1.
Buchanan, James M. (1969), Cost and Choice, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
Calabresi, Guido (1961), Some Thoughts on Risk Distribution and the Law of Torts, 70 Yale Law
Journal, 499-553.
Coase, Ronald H. (1992), The Institutional Structure of Production, 82 American Economic Re-
view, 713-719.
Cooter, Robert D. (1982), The Cost of Coase, 11 Journal of Legal Studies, 1-34.
Demsetz, Harold (1969), Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint, 12 Journal of Law and
Economics , 1-22.
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1952), The Sensory Order, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1973), Rules and Order, London, Routledge.
Landes, William M. and Posner, Richard A. (1975), The Independent Judiciary in an Interest-
Group Perspective, 18 Journal of Law and Economics, 875-901.
Leoni, Bruno (1961), Freedom and the Law, Princeton, D. Van Nostrand.
0610 Public Choice and Constitutional Political Economy 659
Abstract
1. Introduction
660
0620 Law and Macroeconomics 661
market failure about which microeconomists have become more skeptical, (5)
these weaknesses imply that no clear macroeconomic benefits offset the
microeconomic drawbacks of regulations of individual markets, and (6)
extensive deregulation would produce substantial microeconomic and
macroeconomic benefits, but the microeconomic case is much stronger.
Dealing with these points requires much effort. The prior two paragraphs
not only make sweeping assertions, but use numerous ambiguous terms. The
article then seeks to undertake four tasks. (1) The terms are clarified. (2)
Selected parts of the debates over macroeconomics are reviewed. As the
literature review below seeks to suggest, the chapter necessarily cannot even
fully cover every idea encountered. Choice is limited to those that seem more
relevant. Others can (and indeed in the refereeing process did) stress different
viewpoints. (3) The microeconomics of market behavior are sketched. (4)
Perspective is provided on the history of proposals to use microeconomic
policies to secure macroeconomic goals.
The central policy distinction made here is between the monetary and fiscal
policies that are the focus of traditional macroeconomics and regulatory
initiatives. Monetary policy relates to control by various means of the supply of
money in the economy. (Such financial innovations as mutual funds that invest
in short-term securities and allow owners to withdraw funds by writing checks
and credit and debit cards have increased the always difficult problem of
distinguishing money from other financial assets. This problem is not relevant
here.) Fiscal policy relates to the effects of government tax and spending policy.
Regulation here means those government policies that control the behavior
of individual firms and households in the economy. The concept considered
here is somewhat broader than that used in other discussions of regulation. In
particular, a key element proves government policies governing the
compensation and rights of workers and the treatment of trade unions.
Regulatory economists tend to leave most of these issues to labor economists.
Stress is on good market controls; the only labor policies treated are health and
safety regulation. Regulatory policies are the focus of many articles in this
encyclopedia. For that reason and because of space limitations, I neither
delineate in detail nor evaluate the microeconomic problems of such policies.
0620 Law and Macroeconomics 663
economy). Much effort was devoted to arguing that active policies were
desirable without indicating whether the activism significantly differed from
following policy rules. Attention turns to arguing that, given these limitations
and the widely known microeconomic drawbacks, increased regulation of
nonfinancial markets is not an attractive alternative stabilization policy.
Unfortunately, reasonably treating these supposedly limited questions
requires examination of most of the thorniest issues of both macroeconomics
and microeconomics. In particular, the proposition that regulating individual
markets is a desirable macroeconomic policy presumes that actual economies
are best described by theories of imperfect markets. Acceptance of the empirical
relevance of such theories, moreover, does not suffice to justify market
regulation. It must also be shown that such regulation is a desirable way to
offset the effects of market imperfections. In particular, the intervention must
reduce unemployment and not produce other effects, such as increased inflation
or undesirable impacts on the regulated markets, that cause harms that
outweigh the employment benefits.
The issues have been major concerns in economics for nearly seven decades.
All of the key questions remain unresolved and indeed often not even clearly
raised. The characteristics, causes and cures of economic instability and how
best to analyze them are all bitterly debated. A growing stress on theoretic
prowess may have caused analysts inadequately to consider the empirical
relevance of the theories. At least three issues arise about macroeconomics. The
first is what comprises the theoretically sound models of instability. The second
is which of these models best explains reality. The issue about theory choice
stressed here is whether market imperfections are the primary causes of
economic instability. It must be shown that the theoretically possible alternative
mechanism prevails in practice.
The third concern stressed here is what the realistic models say about the
correctability of behavior. They must show that the characteristics of the
economy also allow effective stabilization policy.
5. Viewpoints
6. The Skeptics
needed. (Patinkin makes this case tacitly.) The implications of major departures
from the core assumptions of the theory of competitive markets are too obvious
to justify terming the consideration of imperfections a revolution. The attacks
on classical economics in General Theory are deemed to suggest flaws in the
old analysis less obvious than neglect of market imperfections.
Patinkin focused on an issue that then and now traditional theory cannot
treat, the speed of adjustment. He suggested that this adjustment might be too
slow, where too slow means slow enough that governmental intervention could
effectively speed the process. This viewpoint, however, has received few
adherents. Economic rigidity models of various forms discussed below remain
the mainstay of theories of persistent unemployment. Keyness exposition is too
fuzzy to resolve definitely whether he postulated a more subtle problem,
overstated the newness of his theory, or both. Validating Patinkins view of
Keynes or the similar contentions of Clower (1965) and Leijonhufvud (1968)
is not feasible or essential. The observation that the implications of market
imperfections is (better) treated by classical economics remains valid whatever
Keynes believed.
Haberlers (1958) study of economic instability largely written before the
appearance of the General Theory anticipates the concern over stress on market
imperfections: It might therefore just as well be maintained that rigidity of our
economic system, or its financial or monetary organisation, or particular
features of the latter, are the causes of the cycle as that inventions or crop
changes or changes in demand are responsible (p. 6).
By itself, this debate over what comprises the most relevant macroeconomic
models and how consistent that model is with that of Keynes could be and often
is a mere intellectual exercise. The germane concern is about the practical
implications of whatever is the right model. In particular, the central issue is
whether the characteristics of actual macroeconomics justify and permit
effective countercyclical policies.
While many different models exist, the number of possible outcomes is limited.
The basic possibilities are stagnation (unemployment that inspires no market
generated corrections), a business cycle sufficiently prolonged that public policy
can lessen its impacts, and a business cycle so transitory that public policy
cannot lessen the impacts. Feasibility depends upon the comparative length of
the cycle and of policy response.
The stagnation idea was one that arose in the depression of the 1930s and
died with the boom after World War Two. Whatever Keynes believed, some of
those whom Keynes inspired initially argued that unemployment was chronic.
The original Keynesian approach, therefore, stressed the existence of inherently
correctable persistent demand deficiencies in the economy. Fears of massive
670 Law and Macroeconomics 0620
persistent unemployment faded and with them interest in equally massive and
slow moving programs of government spending.
The alternative view that temporary periods of unemployment, the problem
often called the business cycle, arise now predominates. The Keynesian
position is that public policy can fruitfully counteract these transitory
downturns. The classical approach stressed here is essentially an attack on the
legitimacy of this extension to short recessions of claims plausible to persistent
depressions. (In fact, such concerns have been raised within the Keynesian
traditions, see Phillips, 1950, 1954, 1956 and Allen, 1956.)
Inflation proved a more persistent problem than many Keynesians (but not
Keynes himself) expected. Reflecting these changes, Keynesian economics
greatly altered its focus from 1936 to its crisis in the 1970s. The revised belief
was that the fluctuations that did occur had characteristics that should and
could be counteracted by active government policies. The initial successes in
the 1960s produced faith (indeed in the worst cases arrogance) that this view
had been vindicated.
During the years immediately after World War Two, only a few economists,
most notably Milton Friedman, argued that the problems and the ability to deal
with them had been overstated. To be sure, there were a substantial number of
older economists, of whom Haberler is an example, who were unimpressed by
Keyness analysis when it appeared and never recanted. Paul Samuelsons
fascination (for example 1977, p. 878) with Kuhns concept of scientific
revolutions undoubtedly involved appreciation of Kuhns concept of a
recalcitrant old guard who refused to recognize the truth. Long before Kuhn
provided supporting rationales, the Keynesians were quite successful at
dismissing older critics as obdurate. The revival of more classical approaches
implies the dismissals may have been premature. The old school lived to see
their earlier doubts gain support that attracted new disciples. Snowdon, Vane
and Wynarczk (1995, p. 21) suggest that indeed Kuhns analysis is generally
inappropriate for economics because no outlooks are abandoned.
Stagflation (high unemployment, inflation, and slow growth) in the 1970s
caused greater attention to Friedmans views. A group of economists termed the
new classical economists developed models that raised the possibility that
Friedmans criticisms understated the drawbacks of intervention.
Friedman and similar critics stress the existence of long and unknown lags
in the recognition of problems, design of response, and reaction to the response.
Given all these lags, active public policy cannot clearly produce improvement
and might even be harmful. This position has been enormously influential.
Many fully accept the arguments. More importantly, those who defend active
0620 Law and Macroeconomics 671
stabilization policy advocate actions far less ambitious than those proposed in
the 1960s.
After the disastrous performance in the 1970s, Friedmans argument that
instability was not necessarily inherent and definitely was not correctable
received increased attention. This encouraged economists too young to be
influenced by the experiences of the 1930s to examine what lay behind the
earlier beliefs. In particular, economists such as Lucas and Sargent developed
an alternative, more formal analysis to deal with Friedmans assertions. (At
least three major anthologies are available on new classical economics: Lucas
and Sargent, 1981, a large collection of pieces by many writers who deal with
economics principles, statistical techniques, and empirical evidence; Lucas,
1981a, a collection of work authored or co-authored by Lucas; and Miller,
1994, a collection stressing later work, all associated with the Federal Reserve
Bank of Minneapolis.) The new analysis showed that under some conditions
intervention was totally ineffective.
correctable confusion over what the monetary authorities are doing. Lucas
himself relies on such a lag. The minimum contribution of a rational
expectations benchmark is warning that the magnitude and duration of effects
depends upon precisely what economic analysis cannot treat, the precise degree
to which reality differs from idealized conditions.
A further implication is that, as is surely true in 1997, after decades of
active monetary policy the private sector will better understand and anticipate
the actions of the monetary authorities. In short, monetary policy can create
disturbances, but their nature is too unclear and so subject to eventual erosion
to permit counteraction. Attacks on rationality, moreover, have overstated what
one must know. What is involved is knowledge about what the monetary
authorities are doing and what it implies. The leading newspapers and
television networks have managed to grasp such information.
Houthakkers (1957) research on the operation of futures markets suggested
that the few full-time professionals with knowledge of market conditions
dominated the markets and made them efficient. (This is an implicit application
of Hayeks arguments about how markets economize on knowledge
acquisition.) Similar specialists could operate in other markets to ensure they
two were guided by the best possible knowledge.
as a threat than as an all knowing benevolent force. This, in turn, hits at a main
weakness of the neoclassical synthesis, the inconsistencies between its views of
government in microeconomics as opposed to macroeconomics. It is possible
that macroeconomic problems are so much more serious or more tractable that
government can be trusted more in macroeconomics than in microeconomics.
It also is possible that the drawbacks that arise in microeconomic problems also
occur in macroeconomics. These conclusions become muted but still relevant
if less classical explanations are more valid. We are left with concerns that, as
already noted, all responsible observers share, about the severe limits to active
intervention.
Keynesian and other widely used macroeconomic models have a flaw of dealing
only with equilibrium at a specific moment. A long tradition has at least tacitly
recognized that this approach ignores the expansion of the economy and the
variations in expansions traditionally termed business cycles. Early Keynesians
expressed their recognition by developing models explicitly treating cycles.
More classical economists directly attacked neglect of cyclicality as a fatal flaw
of Keynesian economics.
In its most general and useful sense, the business cycle idea suggests that
increased unemployment occurs in an ever-changing economy and that
economy may spontaneously generate measures to eliminate the unemployment.
To understand the debate, we must recall now abandoned work in economics.
Staring in the 1930s, various economists, most notably the very young Paul
Samuelson, tried to devise macroeconomic models that accounted for these
cyclical forces. Samuelson and those who followed him concentrated on the
existing theory most readily reduced to a manageable model. In particular, he
treated an accelerator model in which investment depended on the most recent
change in national output. (By modern standards, this is a hopelessly naive
model since it ignore anticipations.) This effort reached a dead-end in the
1950s (see Allen, 1956). The models had become unmanageable long before
they produced a plausible analysis of cyclicality. Macroeconomists abandoned
not only the development but also the recollection of cyclical analysis. In the
process of abandoning this approach, a critical insight was weakened. Studies,
particularly those of Phillips (1950, 1954, 1956, 1957), of stabilization policies
in a cyclical economy showed the difficulty of producing desirable results in a
steadily moving economy. A basic problem of any interventionist strategy is
that long effort has failed to produce a convincing analysis of cyclicality. It can
be argued that the analysts have lost sight of the difficulties involved.
Cycle theory was followed by steady-state growth theory that traced the
effects of steady increases in the ability to produce. Here too, the difficulties of
analyzing complex cases long hindered progress; some signs of revival have
arisen but are treated here. However, the pioneering models in this realm are
widely cited in later macroeconomic models.
Shortly after the appearance of the General Theory, the League of Nations
published a survey of business cycle economics. The review was by Gottfried
Haberler, an Austrian trained economist long associated (particularly in his
long career after the book was published) with anti-intervention views on the
economy. (Haberler revised the book twice for the League and finally in 1957
the Harvard University Press issued a fourth edition. The last is used here.
According to that edition, every edition had two main parts, the survey of
different theories and a Synthetic Exposition Relating to the Nature and
Causes of Business Cycles. The fourth edition omitted much material from
earlier editions, retained a chapter on Keynes added to the second edition, and
0620 Law and Macroeconomics 677
1107-1124) and its extensions. This theory builds on the fact that investment
either replaces retired capital goods or adds to productive capacity. A simple
rule is that investment to add new capacity is proportional to the change in
output in the recent past. While the level of economic output changes slowly,
the changes and thus investment can move radically. Haberler ends his
discussion of qualifications to the theory with consideration of expectations. He
notes any investment, directly or indirectly is looking forward to, and is made
in the expectation of, a future demand for consumers goods (p. 97). His
concern is more qualified than that of the 1970s. Haberler talks only of types
of investment which look forward to their utilisation to a very distant future
(p. 98).
The cost change theory that Haberler stresses is that as a boom proceeds,
firms start operating on a steeply rising portion of their cost curves. Haberler
recognizes that this would not be problematic unless real wages and prices
failed to adjust to these changes. Horizontal maladjustments are the lack of
correspondence between demand and supply in goods and factor markets.
According to Haberler (1957, p. 115), the overindebtedness theory is most
satisfactory in warning that existing debt hinders response to downturns and
less satisfactory in suggesting that the rise in burdens restrain activity and
produce downturns. The financial organization explanation is that valuing
financial assets in nominal money reduces price flexibility.
Haberler views overconsumption as a grab-bag of illformulated, often
invalid theories. The valid theories, moreover, are often restatements of theories
best classified under his other categories. He indicates that many theories
involve economically unsound ideas that consumption is inherently unable to
expand as rapidly as productive capacity. Haberler indicates that valid theories
involve short-run imbalances among consumption, savings, investment and
productive capacity. In some of these models, stress is on income distribution
effects. A shift of income from wages to profits undesirably reduces
consumption.
Haberler views psychological theories as attempting to postulate swings
arising from optimism and pessimism distinct from the fluctuations observed
in other theories. Haberler notes the difficulties of distinguishing these effects
but does not deny their existence.
As suggested above, Haberlers leaves us with many ideas and no clear way
to determine whether any of those that are theoretically sound are empirically
relevant. In short, he documents the case that a satisfactory explanation is
unavailable. It is argued above that little progress has been made in the last six
decades at overcoming these problems.
The case here is that work to date falls far short of fulfilling the requirements
just set. It is suggested that all that has been done yet is produce theories that
show how imperfections might produce major macroeconomic effects.
Empirical verification has not been provided. Moreover, considerable evidence
exists that even the developers of the theory are concerned about this limitation.
Stress here is on a group of US economists who have termed themselves
new Keynesians and Europeans who have emphasized labor market
imperfection issues. New Keynesian analysis is the effort of a newer generation
of economists to evaluate the attacks on the Keynesian faith of the leading
academics (notably Samuelson in his textbook and Tobin in his extensive
writings on macroeconomics) of the immediate post-World War Two years. US
new Keynesians come from leading universities, particularly those in the
forefront of advancing the Keynesian revolution, and publish in the major long
established journals.
The focus is governed by the high accessibility of the work, particularly in
the Mankiw and Romer anthology noted above. The term new Keynesian might
suggest that active macroeconomic is feasible. However, even the advocates of
the concepts are more cautious. They admit that the work only suggests
arguments that might lead to revival of belief in active monetary and fiscal
policy. Mankiw and Romer (in their introduction) add that some of the
developers of the models reach the new classical conclusion that it is infeasible
in practice to implement such policies.
Whatever their influence on microeconomics, the models of imperfect
markets were seized upon (in many cases by their developers such as Carlton,
Stiglitz and Shapiro, all also contributors to Schmalensee and Willig) in the
1980s as the basis of more sophisticated models of the macroeconomics
implications of violations of core assumptions. In the process, newer forms of
disfunction were discovered (see below).
This methodology can be contrasted with the older post-Keynesian
movement. As one proponent of the group (Sawyer, 1991, p. 202) notes, the
term post Keynesian evolved from a umbrella for all reviews of Keynes to a
description of a specific approach to macroeconomics that includes concern
over the impacts of market imperfections. The post Keynesians, however, seem
to revel in unorthodoxy and separation from the rest of the macroeconomics
profession (see Snowdon, Vane and Wynarczk, 1995, pp. 367-380).
A curiosity here is that so little attention has been given to the possibility that
bad regulation is a major cause of instability. Aspects of a bad policy model
were (a secondary) part of the early classical approach to instability and at least
one new theory revives this approach. The traditional arguments noted how
trade union insistence on rigid nominal wages was the major barrier to effective
macroeconomic adjustment. Union success was blamed on the willingness of
governments to support union activity. While many expressions of this view
appeared, that from Mises (1966, pp. 769-779) seems to be the only one still
widely available.
This is not a central point of Austrian macroeconomics. The epitomes both
by Mises (1966, pp. 538-586) and by Snowdon, Vane and Wynarczk suggest
that the crux is a monetary theory involving uneven receipt of the increased
money supply that produces incorrect perceptions and distortions in the
behavior of real variables. Mises (p. 580) talks of the futile attempts to explain
the cyclical fluctuations by a nonmonetary doctrine, Snowdon, Vane and
Wynarczk (p. 363) view wage and rigidity arguments as elements added on to
explain the severity of the great depression. It is presumably the existence of
0620 Law and Macroeconomics 685
20. Conclusions
Thousands of books and articles on these issues have appeared. The books
include many comprehensive textbooks and a few more specialized surveys.
0620 Law and Macroeconomics 687
Despite their mass, no single book fully covers all the issues or adequately cites
the literature.
The articles appear in the many journals directed at professional
economists, the various periodicals produced by banks, particularly the regional
Federal Reserve Banks in the United States, and symposium volumes
originating from among others again the regional Federal Reserve Banks and
research institutes such as Brookings and the National Bureau of Economic
Research. Numerous anthologies, some devoted to a topic and others to a
specific author, have appeared. Some major articles have multiple incarnations.
Among the participants in the debates for whom anthologies of relevant
writings exist are Keynes, Hicks, Samuelson, Tobin, Friedman and Lucas.
Each item consulted adds references to more publications. The listings here
are deliberately limited. I have selected anthologies, texts and treatises that
collectively include or discuss a large part of macroeconomics from the 1930
to the 1990s. Much of the material contained is not explicitly cited. Thus, while
some classics are not listed, they often are contained in what is cited. Another
limitation is that no pretense was made exhaustively to examine the many texts
designed for the second (in US academic jargon, intermediate) undergraduate
course in macroeconomic theory. My citations of texts consist of two long
extant ones that are frequently cited and one, recommended by a colleague, that
I found a good alternative; the citations whenever possible are to the latest
edition of which I was aware rather than to the edition actually examined.
In the process of preparing my 1994 book, I began compiling a master
bibliography of works cited in summary volumes on microeconomics and
macroeconomics consulted. Part of the effort was to overcome the irritating
failure of many authors to provide an integrated bibliography. My bibliography
became unmanageably massive as I extended its reach. The germane literature
in macroeconomics alone is too extensive to treat adequately and the literature
on modern industrial organization, while smaller, is still overwhelming.
The books cited here include anthologies that contain at a minimum
important parts of the literature and at their best helpful guides to the rest of the
literature. Miller alone of these books has a unified bibliography. Mankiw and
Romer have an extensive bibliography (broken into separate parts by topic
areas), but it falls far short of presenting everything cited in the book. Among
surveys, Snowdon, Vane and Wynarczk uniquely provides a unified and
extensive bibliography. Blanchard and Fischer prepare separate bibliographies
for each chapter. Even when a bibliography exists, it does not necessarily
provide all the critical information. In particular, often the reprinting in
anthologies is not noted. Generally, I have provided both the original citation
and at least one of the reprints of which I was aware for articles. However, I
have not attempted to examine every writers collected works. The main
exception is Samuelson. So much of what is cited comes from inaccessible
original sources such as symposium volumes that his collected works are the
best source.
688 Law and Macroeconomics 0620
Akerlof, George A. and Yellen, Janet L. (1985), A Near-Rational Model of the Business Cycle with
Wage and Price Inertia, 100 Quarterly Journal of Economics, supplement, 176-213. Reprinted
in Mankiw and Romer (1991), vol. 1, 43-58.
Allen, R.G.D. (1956), Mathematical Economics, London, Macmillan and Co. and New York, St
Martins Press
Bain, Joe S. (1956), Barriers to New Competition: Their Character and Consequences in
Manufacturing Industries, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Bain, Joe S. (1968), Industrial Organization, 2nd edn, New York, John S. Wiley & Sons.
Barro, Robert J. (1972), A Theory of Monopolistic Price Adjustment, 39 Review of Economic
Studies, (January), 17-26.
Blanchard, Olivier Jean, and Fischer, Stanley (1989), Lectures on Macroeconomics, Cambridge , MA,
The MIT Press.
Bork, Robert H. (1978), The Antitrust Paradox, a Policy at War with Itself, New York, Basic Books.
Bradley, Robert L., Jr. (1995), Oil, Gas and Government.: The U.S. Experience, Lanham, Rowman
& Littlefield.
Bryant, John B. (1983), A Simple Rational-Expectations Keynes-Type Model, 98 Quarterly Journal
of Economics, (August), 525-528. Reprinted in Mankiw and Romer (1991), vol. 2, 25-29.
Burstein, M. L. (1963), Money, Cambridge, MA, Schenkman Publishing.
Calomiris, Charles. W. (1993), Financial Factors in the Great Depression, 7 Journal of Economic
Perspectives, (Spring), 61-85.
Carlton, Dennis W. and Perloff, Jeffrey M. (1994), Modern Industrial Organization, 2nd edn, New
York, Harper Collins.
Cato Institute (1997), Cato Handbook for Congress: 105th Congress, Washington, DC, The Cato
Institute.
Clower, Robert W. (1965), The Keynesian Counter Revolution: An Appraisal, in Hahn, Frank and
Brechling, F. (eds), The Theory of Interest Rates, London, Macmillan. Excerpted in Clower (ed.)
(1969), 270-297.
Clower, Robert (ed.) (1969), Monetary Theory, Harmondsworth, Penguin Books.
Dornbusch, Rudiger and Fischer, Stanley (1993), Macroeconomics, 6th edn, New York, McGraw-Hill
Book Company.
Fellner, William and Haley, Bernard F. (eds) (1951), Readings in the Theory of Income Distribution,
Philadelphia, Blakiston.
Fischer, Stanley (1977), Long Term Contracts, Rational Expectations, and the Optimal Money
Supply, 85 Journal of Political Economy, (February), 191-206. Reprinted in Lucas and Sargent
(1981), 261-275 and in Mankiw and Romer (1991), vol. 1, 216-231.
Fisher, Franklin M. (1991), Organizing Industrial Organization: Reflections on the Handbook of
Industrial Organization, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics 1991,
201-240. (Comments, 226-238)
Friedman, Milton (1948), A Monetary and Fiscal Framework for Economic Stability, 38 American
Economic Review, (June), 245-264. Reprinted in Friedman (1953), 117-156 and in Lutz and
Mints (1951), 369-393.
Friedman, Milton (1953), Essays in Positive Economics, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Friedman, Milton (1956),The Quantity Theory of Money: A Restatement, in Milton Friedman (ed.),
Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money, Chicago, University of Chicago Press. Reprinted in
Friedman (1969), 51-67 and Friedman (1987), 285-303.
0620 Law and Macroeconomics 689
Friedman, Milton (1968), The Role of Monetary Policy, 58 American Economic Review, (March),
1-17. Reprinted in Friedman (1987), 387-403.
Friedman, Milton (1969), The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays, Chicago, Aldine.
Friedman, Milton (1970), A Theoretical Framework for Monetary Analysis, 78 Journal of Political
Economy, (March/April). Reprinted in Gordon, Robert J. (ed.), Milton Friedmans Monetary
Framework, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Friedman, Milton (Leube, Kurt R., ed.) (1987), The Essence of Friedman, Stanford, Hoover Institution
Stanford University.
Friedman, Milton and Schwartz, Anna J. (1963), A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960,
Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Friedman, Milton and Schwartz, Anna J. (1982), Monetary Trends in the United States and the United
Kingdom, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Fudenberg, Drew and Tirole, Jean (1991), Game Theory, Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press.
Goff, Brian (1996), Regulation and Macroeconomic Performance, Boston, Kluwer Academic
Publishers.
Gordon, Richard L. (1994), Regulation and Economic Analysis, A Critique over Two Centuries,
Boston and Dordrecht, Kluwer Academic Publishing.
Gordon, Robert Aaron, and Klein, L.R. (eds) (1965), Readings in Business Cycles, Homewood,
Richard D. Irwin.
Gordon, Robert J. (1990), What is New-Keynesian Economics?, 28 Journal of Economic Literature,
(September), 1125-1171.
Gordon, Robert J. (1993), Macroeconomics, 6th edn, Glenview, Scott-Foresman.
Greenwald, Bruce and Stiglitz, Joseph (1993), New and Old Keynesians, 7 Journal of Economic
Perspectives, (Winter), 23-44.
Haberler, Gottfried (ed.) (1944), Readings in Business Cycle Theory, Homewood, Richard D. Irwin.
Haberler, Gottfried (1957), Prosperity and Depression: A Theoretical Analysis of Cyclical
Movements, new and revised (fourth) edition, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press, 1964.
(First three editions 1937, 1939, and 1941 Geneva, League of Nations.
Hahn, Frank and Solow, Robert M. (1995), A Critical Essay in Modern Macroeconomic Theory,
Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press.
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1945). The Uses of Knowledge in Society, 35 American Economic Review,
(September), 519-530. Reprinted in Hayek (1948), 77-91 and Hayek (1984), 211-224.
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1948), Individualism and Economic Order, Chicago, Ill., University of Chicago
Press.
Hayek, Friedrich A. (Nishiyama, Chiaki and Leube, Kurt R., eds) (1984), The Essence of Hayek,
Stanford, Hoover Institution Stanford University.
Hicks, John R. (1937), Mr. Keynes and the Classics, 5 Econometrica, (April), 147-159. Reprinted
in Fellner and Haley (1951), 461-476 and Hicks, J.R. (1982), Money Interest and Wages,
Collected Essays on Economic Theory, vol. II, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press and
Oxford, Basil Blackwell, 100-115.
Hicks, J.R. (1950), A Contribution to the Theory of the Trade Cycle, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Houthakker, H.S. (1957), Can Speculators Forecast Prices?, 39 The Review of Economics and
Statistics, (May), 143-151.
Hume, David (1985), Essays: Moral, Political, and Literary, Indianapolis, Liberty Classics.
Kelman, Mark (1993), Could Lawyers Stop Recessions? Speculations on Law and Macroeconomics,
45 Stanford Law Review, (May), 1215-1310.
690 Law and Macroeconomics 0620
Keynes, John Maynard (1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, New York,
Harcourt Brace and London, Macmillan and Company. (Available in the Royal Economics Society
collected works series.)
Kindleberger, Charles P. (1986), The World in Depression, 1929-1939, Berkeley, University of
California Press.
King, Robert G. (1993), Will the New Keynesian Macroeconomics Resurrect the IS-LM Model?, 7
Journal of Economic Perspectives, (Winter), 67-82.
Klevorick, Alvin K. (1991), Directions and Trends in Industrial Economics: A Review Essay on the
Handbook of Industrial Organization, in Brookings Papers on Economic Activity:
Microeconomics 1991, 241-280 (Comments, 265-279).
Kreps, David M. (1990), A Course in Microeconomic Theory, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Krouse, Clement G. (1990), Theory of Industrial Competition, Cambridge, MA, Basil Blackwell.
Kuhn, Thomas (1970), The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, 2nd edn, enlarged, Chicago, University
of Chicago Press.
Layard, Richard, Nickell, Stephen and Jackman, R. (1991), Unemployment: Macroeconomic
Performance and the Labor Market, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Leijonhufvud, Axel (1968), On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes, A Study in
Monetary Theory, New York, Oxford University Press.
Lindbeck, Assar (1993), Unemployment and Macroeconomics, Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press
Lindbeck, Assar and Snower, Dennis (1988), The Insider-Outsider Theory of Employment and
Unemployment, Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press.
Lipsey, Richard G. (1960), The Relationship between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of
Money Wages in the United Kingdom 1862-1957: A Further Analysis, 27 Economica,
(February), 1-31. Reprinted in Gordon and Klein (1965), 457-487.
Lucas, Robert, E., Jr (1972a), Econometric Testing of the Natural Rate Hypothesis, in Eckstein, Otto
(ed.), The Econometrics of Price Determination Conference, Washington, DC, U.S. Federal
Reserve System Board of Governors, 50-59. Reprinted in Lucas (1981), 90-103.
Lucas, Robert, E., Jr (1972b), Expectations and the Neutrality of Money, 4:2 Journal of Economic
Theory, (April), 103-124. Reprinted in Lucas (1981), 66-89.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr (1973), Some International Evidence on Output-Inflation Tradeoffs,63 American
Economic Review, (June), 326-334. Reprinted in Lucas (1981), 131-145.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr (1975), An Equilibrium Model of the Business Cycle, 83 Journal of Political
Economy, (December), 1113-1144. Reprinted in Lucas (1981), 179-214.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr (1976), Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique, in Brunner, Karl and
Meltzer, Allan (eds), The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, Carnegie-Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy, vol. 1, 19-46. Reprinted in Lucas (1981), 104-130.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr (1977), Understanding Business Cycles, in Brunner, Karl and Meltzer, Allan
(eds), Stabilization of the Domestic and International Economy, Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, 7-29. Reprinted in Lucas, (1981), 215-239.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr (1981a), Studies in Business Cycle Theory, Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr (1981b), Tobin and Monetarism: A Review Article, 19 Journal of Economic
Literature, (June), 558-567.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr (1987), Models of Business Cycles, Oxford, Basil Blackwell.
0620 Law and Macroeconomics 691
Lucas, Robert E., Jr and Sargent, Thomas J. (eds) (1981), Rational Expectations and Practice,
Minneapolis, Minn., University of Minnesota Press.
Lutz, Friedrich A. and Mints, Lloyd W. (eds) (1951), Readings in Monetary Theory, Philadelphia,
Blakiston (subsequently Homewood, Richard D. Irwin).
McChesney, Fred S. and Shughard, William F., II (eds) (1995), The Causes and Consequences of
Antitrust, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Mankiw, N. Gregory (1985), Small Menu Costs and Large Business Cycles: A Macroeconomic Model
of Monopoly, 100 Quarterly Journal of Economics, (May), 529-537. Reprinted in Mankiw and
Romer (1991), vol. 1, 29-42.
Mankiw, N. Gregory (1989), Real Business Cycles: A New Keynesian Perspective, 3 Journal of
Economic Perspectives, (Summer), 79-90.
Mankiw, N. Gregory (1990), A Quick Refresher Course in Macroeconomics, 28 Journal of
Economic Literature, (December), 1645-1660.
Mankiw, N. Gregory and Romer, David (eds) (1991), New Keynesian Economics, 2 vol., Cambridge,
MA, The MIT Press.
Margo, Robert A. (1993), Employment and Unemployment in the 1930s, 7 Journal of Economic
Perspectives, (Spring), 41-59.
Mas-Colell, Andreu, Whinston, Michael D. and Green, Jerry R. (1995), Microeconomic Theory, New
York, Oxford University Press.
Mason, Edward S. (1957), Economic Concentration and the Monopoly Problem. Cambridge, MA,
Harvard University Press.
Mason, Edward S. (1982), The Harvard Department of Economics from the Beginning to World War
II, 97 Quarterly Journal of Economics, (August), 383-433.
Means, Gardiner (1939), The Structure of the American Economy, Washington, National Resources
Council.
Means, Gardiner (1972), The Administered-Price Thesis Reconfirmed, 62 American Economic
Review, (June), 292-306.
Miller, J. Preston (ed.) (1994), The Rational Expectations Revolution: Readings from the Front Line,
Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press.
Mises, Ludwig von (1966), Human Action: A Treatise on Economics. 3rd rev. edn, Chicago, Henry
Regnery Company. (Now published by Contemporary Books Inc., Chicago)
Modigliani, Franco (1944), Liquidity Preference and the Theory of Interest and Money, 12
Econometrica, (January), 45-88. Reprinted in Lutz and Mints (1951), 186-239.
Okun, Arthur (1975), Inflation: Its Mechanics and Welfare Costs, Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity #2, 351-401. Reprinted in Mankiw and Romer (1991), vol. 2, 327-375.
Patinkin, Don (1965), Money, Interest and Prices, 2nd edn, New York, Harper and Row. (Available
minus appendixes from MIT Press)
Peltzman, Sam (1991), The Handbook of Industrial Organization: A Review Article, 99 Journal
of Political Economy, 201-217.
Phillips, A.W. (1950), Mechanical Models in Economic Dynamics,17 Economica NS, (#67 August),
283-305.
Phillips, A.W. (1954), Stabilization Policy in a Closed Economy, 64 Economic Journal, (June),
290-323.
Phillips, A.W. (1956), Some Notes on the Estimation of the Time-Forms of Reactions in
Interdependent Dynamic Systems, 23 Economica NS, (#90 May), 99-113.
Phillips, A.W. (1957), Stabilization Policy and the Time Form of Lagged Responses, 47 Economic
Journal, (June), 265-277. Reprinted in Gordon and Klein (1965), 66-79.
692 Law and Macroeconomics 0620
Phillips, A.W. (1958), The Relation Between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage
Rates in the United Kingdom, 1861-1957', 25 Economica NS, (Issue # 100 November), 283-299.
Plosser, Charles L. (1989), Understanding Real Business Cycles, 3 Journal of Economic
Perspectives, (Summer), 51-77.
Posner, Richard A. (1976). Antitrust Law, An Economic Perspective, Chicago, University of Chicago
Press.
Romer, Christina D. (1993), The Nation in Depression, 7 Journal of Economic Perspectives,
(Spring), 19-39.
Romer, David (1993), The New Keynesian Synthesis,7 Journal of Economic Perspectives, (Winter),
5-22.
Samuelson, Paul A. (1939), Interactions between the Multiplier Analysis and the Principle of
Acceleration, 21 Review of Economic Statistics, (May), 75-78. Reprinted in Haberler (1944),
261-269 and Samuelson (1966), vol. 2, 1107-1110.
Samuelson, Paul A. (Stiglitz, Joseph E., ed.) (1966), The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A.
Samuelson, , 2 vols, Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press.
Samuelson, Paul A. (Merton, Robert C., ed.) (1972), The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A.
Samuelson, , vol. 3, Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press.
Samuelson, Paul A. (Nagatani, Hiroaki and Crowley, Kate, eds) (1977), The Collected Scientific
Papers of Paul A. Samuelson, vol. 4, Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press.
Samuelson, Paul A. (Crowley, Kate, ed.) (1986), The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A.
Samuelson, vol. 5, Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press.
Samuelson, Paul A. and Solow, Robert M. (1960), Analytic Aspects of Antiinflation Policy, 50
American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, (May), 177-194. Reprinted in Samuelson
(1966), vol. 2, 1336-1353.
Sargent, Thomas J. (1973), Rational Expectations, the Real Rate of Interest and the Natural Rate of
Unemployment, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 429-480. Reprinted in Lucas and
Sargent (1981), 159-198.
Sargent, Thomas J. (1976a), A Classical Macroeconomic Model for the United States, 84 Journal of
Political Economy, 207-237. Reprinted in Lucas and Sargent (1981), 521-551.
Sargent, Thomas J. (1976b), The Observational Equivalence of Natural and Unnatural Rate Theories
of Macroeconomics, 84 Journal of Political Economy, 631-640. Reprinted in Lucas and Sargent
(1981), 553-562.
Sargent, Thomas and Wallace, Neil (1975), Rational Expectations, The Optimal Monetary
Instrument and the Optimal Money Supply Rule, 83 Journal of Political Economy, (April),
241-254. Reprinted in Lucas and Sargent (1981), 215-228.
Sargent, Thomas and Wallace, Neil (1976), Rational Expectations and the Theory of Economic
Policy, 2 Journal of Monetary Economics (previously Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Studies in Monetary Economics 2). Reprinted in Lucas and Sargent (1981), 199-213.
Sawyer, Malcolm C. (1991), Post-Keynesian Macroeconomics, in Greenaway, David, Blarney,
Michael and Stewart, Ian (eds), Companion to Contemporary Economics, London, Routledge,
184-206.
Scherer, F.M. and Ross, David (1990), Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, 3rd
edn Boston, Houghton-Mifflin Co.
Schmalensee, Richard and Willig, Robert D. (eds) (1989), Handbook of Industrial Organization, 2
vols, Amsterdam, North-Holland (Elsevier).
Slutsky, Eugen (1937), The Summation of Random Causes as the Source of Cyclic Processes, 5
Econometrica, (April), 105-146.
0620 Law and Macroeconomics 693
Smithies, Arthur and Butters, J. Keith (eds) (1955), Readings in Fiscal Policy, Homewood, Richard
D. Irwin.
Snowdon, Brian, Vane, Howard, and Wynarczyk, Peter (1995), A Modern Guide to Macroeconomics:
An Introduction to Competing Schools of Thought, Aldershot, Edward Elgar.
Spulber, Daniel F. (1989), Regulation and Markets, Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press.
Stadler, George W. (1994), Real Business Cycles, 32 Journal of Economic Literature, (December),
1750-1783.
Stigler, George J. (1988a), Memoirs of an Unregulated Economist, New York, Basic Books.
Stigler, George J. (ed.) (1988b), Chicago Studies in Political Economy, Chicago, University of
Chicago Press.
Temin, Peter (1989), Lessons from the Great Depression: The Lionel Robbins Lectures for 1989,
Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press.
Temin, Peter (1993), Transmission of the Great Depression, 7 Journal of Economic Perspectives,
87-102.
Tirole, Jean (1988), The Theory of Industrial Organization, Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press.
Tobin, James (1993), Price Flexibility and Output Stability: An Old Keynesian View, 7 Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 45-65.
Viscusi, W. Kip, Vernon, John M. and Harrington, Joseph E., Jr (1995), Economics of Regulation and
Antitrust, Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press.
Woglom, Geoffrey (1988), Modern Macroeconomics, Glenview, Scott, Foresman.
0630
OTHER SOCIOLOGICAL APPROACHES
Ian R. Macneil
Wigmore Professor of Law
Northwestern University
Copyright 1999 Ian R. Macneil
Abstract
1. Introduction
Any comparison between law and economics and other sociological approaches
is complicated by the fact that there is neither a single law and economics
approach nor a single noneconomic sociological approach to law. Moreover,
when law and economics takes a serious empirical turn it may for all practical
purposes be indistinguishable from empirical noneconomic sociology (see
Sections 10 and 11). To deal with these problems of diversity and to make
comparison feasible in the small compass of this part, I shall focus on what may
be called the Posnerian approach to law and economics (see Section 5). (There
is a danger in this, as it is all too easy improperly to equate law and economics
with the Chicago School, and particularly Posnerian, economics, see Donohue,
1997. There is, however, no intention of doing so here.) On the sociological
side I shall range somewhat more broadly (see Section B).
Part A treats a number of aspects of law and economics important to the
comparisons to be made to other sociological approaches: (1) the fundaments
694
0630 Other Sociological Approaches 695
of economic behavior; (2) the many worlds of law and economics; (3) the unity
of law and economics; and (4) Posnerian law and economics.
Part B describes other American sociological approaches to law: (1)
case-law research as a sociological approach to law; (2) approaches based on
particular theories; (3) empirical sociological approaches generally and as
compared with law and economics; and (4) empiricism as the meeting ground.
Finally, Part C considers law and economics and other sociological
approaches as competitors.
In spite of the dominance of rational choice theory, any given work in law and
economics may differ from another in at least any of the following somewhat
overlapping respects:
In spite of the foregoing, three factors bring considerable unity to law and
economics.
First is the centrality of rational choice theory (see Section 2) with its
foundation in the individual. Second, the field remains an area dominated by
theoretical and deductive, rather than empirical and inductive, analysis,
although the latter seems to be growing in importance. See Donohue (1997);
Shelanski and Klein (1995). Third, at least in the United States, there is a
dominant school of law and economics, epitomized by the work of Richard
Posner (see generally Posner, 1992), to which I now turn.
The Posnerian school falls at the following locations on the spectra set out in
Subsection 3:
698 Other Sociological Approaches 0630
For an extensive treatment of law and the social sciences see Lipson and
Wheeler (1986); respecting law and sociology see Arnaud et al. (1993).
0630 Other Sociological Approaches 699
6. Introduction
The term case-law research is used here to mean research aimed at finding
out what judicial and/or administrative decision-makers have done respecting
particular issues. (Case-law research may be and often is, of course, conducted
in connection with more formal approaches of various kinds, such as law and
economics and various critical theories. The discussion following is limited
largely to case-law research not so connected, although much of what is said
applies to such instances as well.)
It is seldom, if ever, recognized in academia that - at least as conducted in
the United States - ordinary case-law research is a form of sociological study
of law. This omission calls for explanation given that such research is by far the
most common form of American legal study - both within and without the
academy. In spite of the proliferation of academic and quasi-academic journals
it may safely be assumed that the majority of such research is done in the day-
to-day world of lawyers and judges, administrators and legislators, and their
various staff members. Nonetheless, even with the exclusion of such work of
the real world, academic case-law research, that in law reviews, other legal
periodicals, and monographs of various kinds overwhelms in volume all the
more formal scholarly approaches put together.
In the light of this dominance, it is worth pausing to consider what
case-law research is in the American context, what are its advantages and
disadvantages as a form of sociology, and the general ignoring of such work as
a sociological approach.
Thick description moves social interpretation away from a search for abstractions
that attempt to explain complex patterns of actions in terms of a minimum of
rationally organized principles related to a general theory. It seeks rather a
portrayal of complexity in all its ambiguity and richness. Geertz remarks that the
study of mankind often involves substituting complex pictures of social phenomena
for simple ones while trying to keep the persuasive character of the earlier simpler
ones. (Geertz, 1973, pp. 33-34)
The work of Childres and Spitz (1972) on the parol evidence rule illustrates
how purposive case-law analysis can result in thick description, as does
Feinman (1995). Childres and Spitz examined a large sample of cases applying
a rule stated by the courts as unitary. From the facts of the cases, as distinct
from the words of the opinions, Childres and Spitz concluded that in fact there
were three markedly different rules, depending upon whether the contract in
question was a formal contract, an informal contract, or involved an abuse of
the bargaining process. (In quite rare instances work of this kind purports to
apply statistical principles.)
An important characteristic of the bulk of case-law research is that it is
atheoretical. The researcher typically is interested in finding out what is going
on and then drawing various conclusions respecting such things as what the
law is in terms of formal rules (favorite of law students), what it is in terms of
actual application, what policies are or are not being implemented, and how all
these things might be changed for the better as the particular researcher views
the world. (Only when the research is conducted in the context of a particular
theory, for example law and economics, can it be said to be theoretical in
nature.)
is of this nature (see Wahl, 1998, for a survey of all of the nearly 11,000
Southern appellate cases involving slavery). The two motivations for research
can easily merge in light of the impact of law on party behavior, as Mnookin
and Kornhausers (1979) phrase bargaining in the shadow of the law
suggests.
- nothing more than a way of distilling general rules, as the maddening habits
of most law students bring home to every American law teacher. To the degree
this is true, case-law research is no more sociology that would be reading a civil
code.
The consequences of non-recognition of case-law research as part of the
world of law and sociology are quite serious. Probably the most important is the
exclusion of a vast body of information as being essentially unworthy in
systematic sociological investigation. Nonetheless, flawed though it is,
information derived from case-law research is far from useless. This is
particularly so because of the close relation between academic case-law research
and that in the real world of the law. Another consequence is that such
non-recognition exacerbates the separation of academic scholarly work from the
work of the legal profession and legal institutions (see Edwards, 1992). Yet
another is that it distorts the perceptions of the relationships between competing
approaches to the law (see Section 5). Closely related to this is the present day
derogation of such work in American law schools. Even the highest quality of
original but straightforward case-law research is unlikely to yield tenure in elite
American law schools, or perhaps even to generate summer-research grants.
note that a lot of the European sociologists of law (of course, also with
exceptions) strive for a major theoretical image. (For examples see Section 6.)
Again like law and economics, in such theory-driven approaches the
positive truth of the basic theory, if any is claimed, is assumed rather than
proved empirically. Indeed, it is in the nature of such theories that they cannot
be proved empirically in anything remotely close to scientific proof. (Many if
not most rational choice theorists would probably argue that the positive nature
of rational choice theory has been proved repeatedly, and needs no further
proof. But what in fact has been proved repeatedly is that - at best - with proper
empirical bases it can produce relatively positive conclusions respecting
particular applications. Even so, as suggested in Section 10, it is probably the
empirical base that supplies whatever positivism exists, rather than the theory.)
These theory-driven sociological approaches, at least American versions,
tend to be also like law and economics in that systematic empirical work is
likely to be thin on the ground. For example, critical empirical studies seem to
come more from individuals like Richard Abel (1989, Abel and Lewis,
1988-89), who is related to the critical legal studies movement than from those
commonly viewed as at its center, such as Duncan Kennedy, Mark Tushnet or
Roberto Unger (to the extent it can be said to have a center).
Nonetheless, these theory-driven sociological approaches differ from law
and economics in a number of respects.
First, their analysis is almost always founded less on individual behavior
than on behavior of groups identified by such factors as class (in the case of
Marxian analysis and often critical legal studies), race, gender, and sexual
orientation.
Second, the focus of analysis is typically on power relations in which power
respecting material affairs as such - the principal focus of law and economics
- may or may not be a principal concern. Power respecting ideology and
culture-formation are of particular interest to many scholars of theory-driven
sociological approaches.
Third, within particular subject areas competing theories exist, thereby
multiplying diversity of approaches.
Fourth, although all these theory-driven sociological approaches are
related, at least in the United States, to groupings with significant
socio-political power in the nonacademic world, at the present time they all
remain relatively marginal in American law schools. Their heaviest impact in
the latter is probably collectively in terms of fostering academic atmospheres
which may, for lack of a better description, be described as politically correct.
In particular, neither collectively nor separately have they achieved the power
position, at least in American law schools, of the law and economics
movement.
The foregoing non-mainstream attribute is related to a fifth characteristic:
these approaches are all related to particular social causes. (One need not,
0630 Other Sociological Approaches 705
however, go as far as Posner, 1995, p. 269, who said: Suspicion persists that
critical legal studies owes a lot more to visceral left-wing political preferences
than to any body of theory.) None of the causes they represent have, however,
been able to achieve more than limited acceptance either within or without
academia as compared to the prevailing socioeconomic patterns of modern
capitalist-consumer society. To a degree this is true also of law and economics.
The latter has nonetheless been markedly more successful in achieving standing
and power for its advocates, at least in American law schools, than have all the
theory-driven sociological approaches combined.
Van Loon, Delrue and van Wambeke (1995, p. 380) have pointed to the
greater emphasis on induction, on empiricism, and on methodology in the
United States compared with Europe. They went on: The American scholars
- of course, with exceptions - tend to build theory inductively, from the bottom
up, driven by data, policy concerns and empirical observations. (see also
Posner, 1995, pp. 272-273). Van Loons word theory needs to be treated
gingerly. The theory produced by or related to such work, in America at least,
is not macrotheory of the type I have called theory-driven law and sociology.
Rather it tends, at most, to be what Cotterell calls middle-range theory, usually
concerned with analyzing the causal effects of legal change on wider social
change or with specifying the social mechanisms by which law can bring about
or hinder social change Cotterell (1995, p. 352).
Rubin has made these points more specifically in terms of a particular field,
contracts:
American sociology tends to be heavily empirical, but law schools lack the
intellectual infrastructure to carry out sustained empirical research. Unlike
economics, no dominant theoretical approach has emerged in sociology, and the
theories of Americas leading theoreticians such as Talcott Parsons and Herbert
Garfinkel proved difficult for contracts scholars lacking sociological training to
apply. The same is true for German social theory, which may represent a more
promising approach. While jurisprudence has been receptive to Habermas and
Gadamer, contract scholarship has tended to overlook the more applicable work of
their contemporaries such as Niklas Luhmann, Gunther Teubner, and Claus Offe.
The result, once again, was the delayed development of a theory for understanding
and evaluating the contractual process itself, as opposed to the judicial rules that
are applied when that process goes awry. (Rubin, 1995, pp. 113-114)
706 Other Sociological Approaches 0630
teaching interests, with about two and half times as many members listing
criminology in the latter category as in the former.)
As with law and economics the empiricism of other sociological
approaches may range from the most casual to the most systematic. The more
systematic it is the more it is likely to be recognized as a sociological approach.
thinking about the way exchange occurs in relations (see Macneil, 1981).
Thus noneconomic empirical sociological approaches deal with transaction
costs. Unlike Posnernian law and economics, such treatment is typically
from relational perspectives, and quite likely occurs without calling the
subject studied transaction costs.
e. Relations, recognition as such: Noneconomic sociological approaches by
definition focus on relations of all kinds and are thus antithetical to
Posnernian law and economics with its focus on individuals whose only
relationship is competitive.
f. Empiricism: This is the core of this approach, and is in sharp contrast to
Posnernian law and economics, where it is typically slighted.
g. Distributional effects: Likely to be considered where viewed as pertinent
and significant to the subject, and thus once again sharply at odds with
Posnernian law and economics.
h. Individualism: attitudes towards: Nothing in the nature of empirical
noneconomic approaches favors or disfavors individualism, and it is thus
theoretically more neutral than Posnernian law and economics on this
score. But see the discussion of attitudes towards market-solutions below;
similar things could be said about individualism.
Noneconomic empirical sociologists are less likely than Posnerians to
consider large organizations to be individuals for the purpose of
investigation.
i. Market-solutions: attitudes towards: Nothing in the empirical approach as
such favors either market or nonmarket solutions, and it is thus
theoretically more neutral than Posnernian law and economics on this
score. Nonetheless empiricists with a strong bent towards market solutions
are likely to end up in the law and economics camp, empirical side, rather
than in noneconomic sociology. This is particularly so of American legal
educators, given the power in American law schools of law and economics,
especially Posnernian law and economics, see Posner (1995). Thus
American empirical sociological approaches are more likely to be
conducted by individuals who range from having relatively neutral views
about market-solutions to those who heavily favor governmental and other
regulatory solutions.
j. Politico-legal goals: There is nothing in the nature of noneconomic
empirical sociological approaches that precludes right wing political
biases. Nonetheless, in the American context at least, those engaging in
such approaches are probably generally thought of as political liberals
ranging from middle to leftish, but not radicals in the various critical
camps mentioned in Section 8.
k. Power: In contrast to Posnernian law and economics, power may be
recognized as an important factor either explicitly or implicitly.
0630 Other Sociological Approaches 709
Empirical work apart from case-law research has been mentioned respecting
all three of the major sociological approaches treated in this part: law and
economics, other theory-driven sociology, and other nontheory-driven empirical
sociology. (This is not to suggest that any social investigation can ever be free
of ideology and unexpressed theories.)
Empirical work is where all approaches can meet in equal competition. Or
to put it in another way, where empirical work is a central focus of study the
approach behind it may be singularly unimportant. Consider, for example,
Ellicksons investigation of the ways in which farmers and ranchers in Shasta
County, California work out animal trespass disputes. Ellickson used social
science methods in his study, focusing on a local case study (a narrow but deep
wedge of location and time), gathering demographic and documentary
evidence, and conducting extensive field interviews with a range of
participants. He then used this finely detailed, highly localized data as a basis
for theorizing about a broader slice of reality (Larson , 1995, p. 229, citing
Ellickson, 1986, pp. 627-628; see also Ellickson, 1991).
Ellickson concluded that high transaction costs were such a barrier to legal
recourse that neighbors instead had worked out their problems in a neighborly
fashion, developing a set of customary norms that became their Order Without
Law Larson (1995, p. 232 n. 278). As noted, this investigation was
conducted in terms of transaction costs by its author, a devoted law and
economist. See Ellickson (1993). Moreover, he keyed his work to Coases
theory about social costs, Coase (1960), a Posnerian Bible until Coase
explained what he really meant: what matters is not what happens theoretically
when there are no transaction costs, but what happens in reality when there are.
Coase (1993).
To those of genuinely empirical bent, what counts about Ellicksons Shasta
County study is not its origin in the mind of a law and economist or what it
may or may not show about rational choice theory. What matters is the quality
of his empirical work and the knowledge of human behavior that can be derived
therefrom.
This is equally true of sociologists proceeding from other viewpoints. To
those of genuinely empirical bent, what counts about the studies of van Loon,
Delrue and van Wambeke of litigation, for example, is not their origin in the
minds of Weberian-Durkheimians or what they may show about
Weberian-Durkheimian theory. What counts is the quality of their empirical
work and the knowledge of human behavior that can be derived therefrom.
Various authors have talked about the coming together of law and
economics and sociology - Campbell (1996), De Geest (1995), Posner (1995) -
as well as economics and sociology more generally - Baron and Hannan (1994).
Posner, for example, urges the erasure of the remaining disciplinary
710 Other Sociological Approaches 0630
boundaries that are retarding the complete merger of sociology with the other
scholarly disciplines that study law (Posner, p. 266).
If such a merger is in prospect the question is how they come together, and
here there are great variations. It is clear enough that Posner means a merger
along the lines of the Norman conquest of the Anglo-Saxons, with Posnerian
law and economics in the role of the Normans. (Just as Norman England was
a merger and not genocide, so too Posner would leave something of
noneconomic sociology intact, such as the impact of social class on
economically inexplicable behavior, see (Posner, 1995, p. 278.) De Geest, on
the other hand, sees law and economics as already a combination of economics,
sociology, psychology and other sciences, a pattern very much at odds with
Posnerian law and economics.
I too see a possible merger in the offing, one closer to De Geests than to
Posners position. What is suggested here is that empirical studies of law
themselves may be in the process of establishing a field of study that essentially
transcends the economic and noneconomic boundaries. In that field the
competition will be over empirical quality with theoretical approaches playing
only a secondary role. Out of such an eclectic body of research could come an
eclectic social science in which a wide variety of theories all were viewed as
valuable analytical tools, but with none having a monopoly on whatever limited
positivism is possible in social investigation. For a suggestion of a merger along
somewhat similar lines relating to crime, see Panther (1995, pp. 372-375).
There can be little doubt that much competition exists among the proponents
of these various approaches for prominence in the study of law. Richard Posner
has proclaimed more or less total victory in this competition for law and
economics, at least insofar as American legal studies are concerned (Posner,
1995).
12. Victory?
It would be foolish to deny that law and economics has become the most
powerful single monofocused discipline in American legal studies. Nonetheless,
the victory is neither as complete nor as satisfactory from a Posnerian
standpoint as might appear from reading Posners account. Before taking up
more serious aspects, it might be noted that although Posner professed to be
unaware that sociology of law is commonly taught in American law schools
(Posner, 1995, p. 275), half again as many names are listed as teaching Law
0630 Other Sociological Approaches 711
and the Social Sciences as Law and Economics in AALS (1995, pp. 1153-1154,
1158-1160). It is true that the former category is a potpourri. It even includes
some teachers, for example, Guido Calabresi, who prefer their law and
economics teaching to be so categorized rather than under the more specialized
heading. Nonetheless, a riffle through the entries for some of the teachers so
listed suggests that some form or aspect of law and sociology is taught in
American law schools a good deal more than Posner suggests. (In terms of
expression of law teacher interests the picture in Britain is dramatically
opposite from Posners view. Only 5 law teachers identify an interest in law and
economics, compared to 14 for sociology of law and 7 for socio-legal studies.
SPTL (1996, pp. 130, 135, 136).) I turn now to more significant tests of
success.
First, when academic case-law research of the type described in Section 7
is counted as a noneconomic sociological approach, law and economics falls
into a very distant second place. Moreover, academic case-law research has a
mighty sibling in the day-to-day work of bench and bar. Although law and
economics may dominate a few areas of legal practice, most notably antitrust
and restrictive practices, and may, as Posner claims, have had an effect on the
deregulatory movement, it is a long, long way from dominating or even playing
a major role in most areas of the law. There are undoubtedly a growing number
of judges relatively literate in law and economics. That does not, however,
mean that they are necessarily converts who view economic analysis as a
primary, much less the primary, tool of their trade. (For a critical discussion of
the relationship between theoretical studies like law and economics and the
legal profession, see Edwards, 1992.)
Second, as noted in Section 3, there are many worlds of law and
economics, a field not originated by Posner. Nor, in spite of Posners prolific
work and the dominance of Posnerian thinking, by any stretch of the
imagination has Posnerian law and economics ever occupied the entire field of
law and economics. Furthermore, even apart from its diverse origins, the
centrifugal forces afflicting any maturing ideology seem to be well and truly
loose in law and economics. Moreover, other theories, in particular game
theory, have come muscling into law and economics. Game theory proceeds
from the individualistic benefit/cost concept as does law and economics.
Nonetheless, game theory, with its stress on asymmetric information and
strategic behavior, brings uncertainties to the picture utterly inconsistent with
the kinds of claims to positivism often made on behalf of law and economics.
([T]he strong predictions of the price theoretic models quickly degenerate into
a fragmented array of models whose predictions are highly dependent on the
nature of the initial assumptions, Donohue, 1997).
An illustration of the centrifugal forces affecting law and economics comes
from the institutional school of which Oliver Williamson is the leading voice.
712 Other Sociological Approaches 0630
Posner (1) has not understood the Coasian message (or does not like what he
hears), (2) misconstrues transaction costs economics, (3) misconstrues game theory,
(4) has a truncated understanding of bounded rationality, the economics of
information, and maximizing, and (5) mischaracterizes empirical research in
transaction cost economics. (Williamson, 1993b, p. 99, replying to Posners attack
on Williamson, 1993a. Such comments hardly augur well for a unified law and
economics under the Posnerian banner)
The presence of these forces swirling around Posnerian law and economics goes
blithely unrecognized in Posners mention of Guido Calabresi as one of the six
law and economics academics on the federal Courts of Appeal (Posner, 1995,
p. 281, n. 30). Calabresi, who with Coase has legitimate claim to be the
co-founder of law and economics, never has been in the Posnerian school.
Moreover, four years before this citation of his name appeared, Calabresi
specifically and vigorously rejected several of the most fundamental principles
underlying Posnerian law and economics (Calabresi, 1991).
Given these divergent forces, whatever claim may be made for a victory of
economic analysis over other sociological approaches does not, as Posner
clearly would like us to think, support a claim of such victory for Posnerian law
and economics.
Third, and perhaps most important respecting any claim of a Posnerian
victory, is the impact of empiricism on the relationship between law and
economics and other sociological approaches. As suggested in Section 11, what
matters about empirical work is its quality, not the particular intellectual camp
from whence it comes, for example, Ellicksons Shasta County study
(Ellickson, 1986). Ellickson analyzed the outcome from the standpoint of
transaction cost economics. The social facts as found by Ellickson, however,
equally vindicate relational contract theory in which transaction costs are
viewed as too narrow a social concept (Macneil, 1981). Thus, in terms of the
empirical work itself, Ellicksons work is just as much a part of the
noneconomic sociological approach of relational contract as it is a part of law
and economics. Ellicksons fine work turns out not to be victory of law and
economics over a noneconomic sociological approach, but a victory for
empiricism.
The dangers to Posnerian orthodoxy, or even to the minimum of economics
orthodoxy, of high quality empirical work by law and economists should be
obvious. Such work focusing on transaction costs, and/or taking into adequate
account assymetric information and the possibilities of strategic bargaining,
may come perilously close to demonstrating the validity of noneconomic
approaches with their emphasis on complex social worlds. It could thus lead to
what Posner (1995, p. 266) called an erasure of the remaining disciplinary
0630 Other Sociological Approaches 713
13. The Causes of the Relative Success of Law and Economics in America
Posner attributes his claimed victory of law and economics to the following:
Max Webers bequest to sociology of a useless methodology, idem. pp.
267-268); insofar as criminology is concerned a discredited approach to
criminality and its control (p. 270); the lack of theoretical and empirical [sic!]
ambition of American sociology of law compared with law and economics (p.
272); a lack of normative punch compared to law and economics (p. 273); the
failure of law and sociology to retool with the methods of a rival discipline,
that is, law and economics (p. 274), prevented by such factors as the
left-liberal bent of law and sociologists who perceive law and economics as
being politically conservative, reluctance to accept the knowledge-claims of
other disciplines, and professional envy (pp. 274-275).
Whatever one may think of the merits of Posners factors purporting to
foster the relative success of law and economics included, his list is far from
complete. Other factors are not only important, but might well be thought to be
substantially more important than those listed.
Perhaps the most important factor Posner omits is the political climate
developing in America (and elsewhere) as law and economics was getting its
foothold in American law schools. Reactions against the State from right and
left achieved national prominence with the Republican nomination of Barry
Goldwater in 1964 and the anti-war movement of the late 1960s and early
1970s. Opposition to the bureaucratic welfare state legacies of the New Deal,
Fair Deal, and Great Society increased during the period until it culminated in
the presidency of Ronald Reagan in 1980. Anti-regulation, pro-market
positions such as those of Alfred Kahn respecting the airlines became
politically respectable in a way that they had not been since the days of the
Hoover administration. Nor was this confined to the far right or even the right.
On the international scene the liberal establishment, heavily eastern and
Republican, long had been supporters of free trade. It is hardly surprising that
law and economics, particularly of the ideological Posnerian variety, thrived in
such an atmosphere. Nor is it surprising that sociological approaches more
likely to be neutral or favorable towards regulation were less likely to thrive.
(Interestingly enough, Mrs Thatchers 1979 triumph seems to have largely
failed to produce a similar pattern in British academia; perhaps this in part
714 Other Sociological Approaches 0630
reflected that, unlike Ronald Reagan, she never enjoyed the support of much
more than 40 percent of the electorate.)
Even the most casual observation of American law schools, particularly the
more elite law schools, reveals how responsive their curricula and research are
to what is going on in the outside world. The 1940s saw a proliferation of law
school activity in areas like labor law (collective bargaining and unfair labor
practices) and administrative law reflecting the the New Deal. Comparative and
public international law blossomed in the postwar Cold War era with
Americas new world role. Law and poverty and civil rights courses came with
the Lyndon Johnsons Great Society. Courses and studies relating in a wide
variety of ways to international trade have blossomed as its importance to the
American economy have become more and more widely recognized. It is hardly
surprising that a market-oriented and often right-wing subject like law and
economics thrived in the 1970s and thereafter. Indeed it would have been
simply amazing had it not.
A second factor in the relative success of law and economics undoubtedly
has to do with the speed and simplicity of effort required for various kinds of
intellectual work. For example, case-law research and empirical studies based
on published statistical information can be done in a library with far greater
speed and simplicity of effort than empirical studies can be done in the field.
This is almost certainly the primary reason that the empirical studies
envisioned by the early American realists, and sometimes conducted on a pilot
basis, caught on in American law schools only to a extremely limited degree.
Theoretical law and economics can in turn be done with far greater speed and
simplicity of effort than can be case-law and other library-based research.
None of the foregoing is to make any judgment whatever about the
intellectual challenge or difficulty of the different kinds of enterprise. It is
simply that most thought-experiments based on hypothetical situations can
typically be done faster than activities requiring fact-gathering, and that library
fact-gathering can typically be done faster than field fact-gathering. Thus
theoretical law and economics is in cost terms at a significant advantage in
competition with case-law research. It is at an even greater advantage in
competition with empirical approaches, particularly field studies. In an
academic world increasingly focussed on publish-or-perish this has made law
and economics singularly attractive to those with real or imagined ability to
carry out such analysis. This is especially true in any law school where
article-counting is an important aspect of promotion and tenure.
The big challenge to law and economics on this score will come to
whatever degree it shifts towards empiricism and particularly towards the more
time-intensive forms of field study such as that of Ellickson in Shasta County.
To whatever degree law and economics shifts in this direction its competitive
advantage will tend to disappear.
0630 Other Sociological Approaches 715
A third important factor in the relative success of the law and economics
movement has been its considerable financing from sources with pro-market,
and often right-wing, ideologies, of which the Olin Foundation stands out. This
financing included particularly a major effort to proselytize law teachers.
Starting in the late 1960s Henry Manne, a Chicago School enthusiast,
organized a well-financed and most attractive summer program, first at the
University of Rochester and later at the University of Miami. A very substantial
number of law teachers were both taught the basics of law and economics and
propagandized about its merits by this program. (It was nicknamed Pareto in
the Pines and after its move south, Pareto in the Palms.) Manne continued such
well-funded programs and others after moving to Emory University in 1980
and later founding a law and economics law school at George Mason
University. Nothing on a remotely comparable scale has ever been available to
provide financial support for noneconomic sociological training and
propaganda.
D. Conclusion
In conclusion, the great and probably unbridgeable gulf between various other
sociological approaches and Posnerian law and economics is much smaller
respecting other varieties of law and economics, particularly institutional law
and economics. These smaller gaps are likely to become smaller yet to whatever
extent both law and economics and other sociological approaches move in the
direction of empirical studies.
Acknowledgements
Abel, Richard L. (1989), American Lawyers, New York, NY, Oxford University Press.
Abel, Richard L. and Lewis, Phillip S.C. (1988-89), Lawyers in Society, 3 vols, Berkeley, CA,
University of California Press.
Arnaud, Andr-Jean, et al. (1993), Dictionaire Encylopdique de Thorie et de Sociologie du Droit,
Paris, Libraire Gnrale de Droit et de Jurisprudence.
Arriola, Elvia R. (1994), Gendered Inequality: Lesbians, Gays and Feminist Legal Theory, 9
Berkeley Womens Law Journal, 103 ff.
Association of American Law Schools (AALS) (1995), The AALS Directory of Law Teachers
1995-96, St Paul, MN, West Publishing Company.
Baron, James N. And Hannan, Michael T. (1994), The Impact of Economics on Contemporary
Sociology, 32 Journal of Economic Literature, 1111-1146.
Black, Donald (1989), Sociological Justice, New York, NY, Oxford University Press
Calabresi, Guido (1991), The Pointlessness of Pareto: Carrying Coase Further, 100 Yale Law
Journal, 1211-1237
Campbell, David A. (1996), On What is Valuable in Law and Economics, 8 Otago Law Review,
489-514
Campbell, David A. ( 1997), Law and Economics and its Relationship to Sociology, in Tomasic, R.,
The Sociology of Law, 2nd edn, London, Sage
Childres, Robert and Spitz, Steven J. (1972), Status in the Law of Contracts, 47 New York University
Law Review, 1-31.
Coase, Ronald (1960), The Problem of Social Cost, 3 Journal of Law and Economics, 1-44
Coase, Ronald (1993), Coase on Posner on Coase, 149 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical
Economics, 96-98.
Cotterell, Roger (1995), Sociological Interpretations of Legal Development, 2 European Journal of
Law and Economics, 347-359.
Crenshaw, Kimberle Williams, Gotanda, Neil, Peller, Gary and Thomas, Kendall (1995), Critical Race
Theory: The Key Writings that Formed the Movement, New York, NY, The New Press.
Decoste, F.C., Munro, K.M. and MacPherson, Lillian (1991), Feminist Legal Literature: An
Annotated Bibliography, New York, Garland Pub.
De Geest, Gerrit (1995), Toward an Integration of Economic and Sociological Approaches?, 2
European Journal of Law and Economics, 301-308.
Delgado, Richard, and Stefancic, Jean (1993), Critical Race Theory: An Annotated Bibliography, 79
Virigina Law Review, 461
Donohue, John J. III (1997), The Path of Law and Economics, forthcoming.
Edwards, Harry T. (1992), The Growing Disjunction between Legal Education and the Legal
Profession, 91 Michigan Law Review, 34-78.
Ellickson, Robert C. (1986), Of Coase and Cattle: Dispute Resolution Among Neighbors in Shasta
County, 38 Stanford Law Review, 623-680
Ellickson, Robert C. (1991), Order Without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes, Cambridge, MA,
Harvard University Press.
Ellickson, Robert C. (1993), Property in Land, 102 Yale Law Journal, 1315-1400.
Eskridge, William N. (1994), Gaylegal Narratives, 40 Stanford Law Review, 607.
0630 Other Sociological Approaches 717
Feinman, Jay M. (1995), Economic Negligence, Liability of Professionals and Businesses to Third
Parties for Economic Loss, Boston, MA, Little, Brown & Co.
Friedman, Lawrence M. (1986), The Law and Society Movement, 38 Stanford Law Review, 763-780
Frasco, Gregg, (1991), Exclusive Dealing: A Comprehensive Case Study, Lanham, MD, University
Press of America.
Geertz, Clifford (1973), The Interpretation of Cultures: Selected Essays, New York, NY Basic Books.
George, Paul M. and McGlamery, Susan (1991), Women and Legal Scholarship: A Bibliography, 77
Iowa Law Review, 87 ff.
Holzhauer, Rudi W. and Teijl, Rob (1995), Comment on Francis van Loon, Stephane Delrue, and
Wim van Wambeke, Sociological Research on Litigation: Perspectives and Examples, 2
European Journal of Law and Economics, 387-392.
Kaufmann, Patrick J. and Stern, Louis W. (1988), Relational Exchange Norms, Perceptions of
Unfairness and Retained Hostility in Commercial Litigation, 32 Journal of Conflict Resolution,
534-552.
Kelman, Mark (1987), A Guide to Critical Legal Studies, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Larson, Jane E. (1995), Free Markets Deep in the Heart of Texas, 84 Georgetown Law Journal,
179-260.
Lipson, Leon and Wheeler, Stanton (eds) (1986), Law and the Social Sciences, New York, NY,
Russell Sage Foundation.
Llewellyn, Karl N. (1960), The Common Law Tradition: Deciding Appeals, Boston, MA, Little
Brown.
Macneil, Ian R. (1981), Economic Analysis of Contractual Relations: Its Shortfalls and the Need for
a "Rich Classificatory Apparatus, 75 Northwestern University Law Review, 1018-1063.
Mnookin, Robert H. and Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1979), Bargaining in the Shadow of the Law: The
Case of Divorce, 88 Yale Law Journal, 950-997.
Panther, Stephan M. (1995), The Economics of Crime and Criminal Law: An Antithesis to
Sociological Theories?, 2 European Journal of Law and Economics, 365-378.
Posner, Richard A. (1992), Economic Analysis of Law, 4th edn, Boston, MA, Little Brown.
Posner, Richard A. (1993), The New Institutional Economics Meets Law and Economics, 149
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 73-87.
Posner, Richard A. (1995), The Sociology of the Sociology of Law: A View from Economics, 2
European Journal of Law and Economics, 265-284.
Robson, Ruthan (1992), Lesbian (Out)law: Survival Under the Rule of Law, Ithaca, NY, Firebrand
Books.
Robson, Ruthan and Duberman, Martin (eds) (1997), Gay Men, Lesbians, and the Law, New York,
NY, Chelsea House.
Rubin, Edward L. (1995), The Nonjudicial Life of Contract: Beyond the Shadow of the Law, 90
Northwestern University Law Review, 107-131.
Schlegel, John Henry (1995), American Legal Realism and Empirical Social Science, Chapel Hill,
NC, University of North Carolina Press.
Schlegel, John Henry (1980), American Legal Realism and Empirical Social Science: From the Yale
Experience, 28 Buffalo Law Review, 459-586.
718 Other Sociological Approaches 0630
Shelanski, Howard A. and Klein, Peter G. (1995), Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Economics:
A Review and Assessment, 11 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 335-361.
Society of Public Teachers of Law (SPTL) (1996), Directory of Members 1997, Butterworths.
Socio-Legal Studies Association (SLSA) (1996), Directory of Members 1996, Butterworths.
Symposium (1993), Can Feminists Use the Law to Effect Social Change in the 1990s?, 87
Northwestern University Law Review, 1252.
Twining, William L. (1974), Law and Social Science: The Method of Detail, New Society, June 27,
1974, 758-761.
van Loon, Francis and Langerwerf, Etienne (1990), Socioeconomic Development and the Evolution
of Litigation Rates of Civil Courts in Belgium, 1835-1980, 24 Law and Society Review, 285-298.
van Loon, Francis and Wouters, Yolande (1992), Civil Litigation in Belgium: The Reconstruction of
the Pyramid of Legal Disputes: A Preliminary Report, 20-21 Droit et Socit, 199-210.
van Loon, Francis, Delrue, Stephane and Van Wambeke, Wim (1995), Sociological Research on
Litigation: Perspectives and Examples, 2 European Journal of Law and Economics, 379-385.
Wahl, Jenny Bourne (1998), The Bondsmans Burden: An Economic Analysis of the Common Law
of Southern Slavery, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1993a), The Evolving Science of Organization, 149 Journal of Institutional
and Theoretical Economics, 36-63.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1993b), Transaction Cost Economics Meets Posnerian Law and Economics,
149 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 99-118.
0640
THE LAW AND ECONOMICS OF
ANTHROPOLOGY
Robert Cooter
University of California at Berkeley
Copyright 1999 Robert Cooter
Abstract
I briefly review the classics of legal anthropology and discuss the economic
analysis relevant to it.
JEL classification: K00
Keywords: Law, Economics, Anthropology, Property, Social Norms
Just look along the road, and tell me if you can see either of [the messengers].
I see nobody on the road, said Alice.
I only wish I had such eyes, the King remarked in a fretful tone. To be able
to see Nobody! And at that distance too! Why, its as much as I can do to see
real people, by this light! (Lewis Carrolls Through the Looking-Glass,
Chapter 7)
1. Legal Anthropology
719
720 The Law and Economics of Anthropology 0640
2. Economic Analysis
I now turn to the smattering of articles on anthropology that fit within the
modern law and economics movement. In an earlier review Brenner (1983),
stresses population growth as the destabilizing influence that causes innovation
and economic development in tribes. Only a few papers in law and economics
concern law among tribal people. Perhaps the most discussed is the paper by
Demsetz (1967) which proposes a simple theory of the origins of property.
Demsetz reasoned that private property emerges from a prior rule permitting
open access to resources, and this event should occur at the point in history
when the benefits of the change exceed the costs. He observed that when
everyone has open access to a resource, over-exploitation produces a
dead-weight loss, as with over-fishing on the high seas. In contrast, private
ownership can eliminate this dead-weight loss, but, unlike open-access, private
property requires costly definition and enforcement of ownership rights. So
Demsetz predicts that privatization will occur when the dead-weight loss of
open access exceeds the transaction costs of exclusion by private property
rights.
For evidence in favor of this theory, Demsetz relies upon secondary sources,
notably concerning the fur trade among North American Indian tribes. More
careful examination proves that Demsetz got some important facts wrong.
Tribal people live among kin with extensive, complicated obligations to each
other, including obligations about using land. These obligations create a very
different legal regime from open access. So the characteristic movement in
tribal property law is not from open access to private ownership. Rather, new
customary rights in property continually evolve from old customary rights in
property (Cooter, 1991). Tradition persists by continually inventing new things.
Economists often contrast individual and group ownership, but these labels
are too imprecise to fit customary law. Research on property rights has revealed
variety and detail in the political arrangements by which small groups manage
their assets (Eggertsson, 1992; Ellickson, 1993; McCloskey, 1975a, 1975b;
Ostrom, 1990). Even without individual ownership, small groups of people
living intimate lives seldom suffer the political paralysis that causes deadweight
losses like the infamous tragedy of the commons.
Note that the Demsetz paper reveals a characteristic weakness of
anthropological work among law and economics scholars: they lack intuition
because they have never done field research. For an early exception in property
law, see Trebilcock (1981).
722 The Law and Economics of Anthropology 0640
In another paper with high ambition, Posner (1980) interprets the behavior
of tribes as a response to missing insurance markets. The combination of the
hazards of primitive life and the absence of insurance, according to this view,
causes people to form long-run relationships and redistribute wealth. Like
Demsetz, this paper contributes to anthropology by raising the level of
generality in formulating familiar trade-offs.
Risk-reduction is important to cases where customary law allows relatively
open access to a resource, such as summer grazing land in Mongolia.
Variations in weather impose risks on people living off the land. A customary
rule of open access enables people to relocate quickly from one micro-climate
to another, thus reducing climatic risk (Cooter, 1995; McCloskey, 1976;
Nugent and Sanchez, 1993). Open-access, however, discourages investments
to improve the land. So the trade-off is between dead-weight loss and
risk-spreading, not the trade-off between dead-weight loss and transaction costs
of exclusion as proposed by Demsetz.
3. Social Norms
4. Conclusion
Akerlof, George A. (1980), A Theory of Social Custom, of Which Unemployment may be one
Consequence, 94 Quarterly Journal of Economics, 719-775.
Akerlof, George A. (1985), Discriminatory, Status-based Wages among Tradition Oriented,
Stochastically Trading Coconut Producers, 93 Journal of Political Economy, 265-276.
Anderson, Terry L. and McChesney, Fred S. (1994), Raid or Trade? An Economic Model of
India-White Relations, 37 Law and Economics, 39-74.
Audain, Linz (1995), Critical Cultural Law and Economics, the Culture of Deindividualization, the
Paradox of Blackness, 70 Indiana Law Review, 709 ff.
Bernstein, Lisa (1992), Opting Out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the
Diamond Industry, 21 Journal of Legal Studies, 115-157.
Bernstein, Lisa (1996), Merchant Law in a Merchant Court: Rethinking the Codes Search for
Immanent Business Norms, 114 University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 1643-1696.
Bohannan, Paul (1957), Justice and Judgement Among the Tiv, London.
Brenner, Reuven (1983), Trust, Population, and Wealth; or, Why did Cain Kill Abel?, in History -
the Human Gamble, Chicago, IL, University of Chicago Press, 62-104. Reprinted in Spanish
edition: Fondo de Cultura Economics, Mexico - Spain, 1989.
0640 The Law and Economics of Anthropology 725
Collier, Jane (1973), Law and Social Change in Zinacantan, Stanford, CA, Stanford University Press.
Comaroff, John L. (1992), The Discourse of Rights in Colonial South Africa: Subjectivity,
Sovereignty, Modernity, Vol. I (with J. Comaroff), Chicago, IL, University of Chicago Press.
Comaroff, John L. and Roberts, Simon (1981), Rules and Processes: The Cultural Logic of Dispute
in an African Context, Chicago, IL, University of Chicago Press.
Conley, John M. and OBarr, William M. (1993), Legal Anthropology Comes Home: A Brief History
of the Ethnographic Study of Law, 27 Loyola Law Review, 41-64.
Cooter, Robert D. (1991), Inventing Market Property: The Land Courts of Papua New Guinea, 25
Law and Society Review, 759-801.
Cooter, Robert D. (1994), Structural Adjudication and the New Law Merchant: A Model of
Decentralized Law, 14 International Review of Law and Economics, 215-231.
Cooter, Robert D. (1995), Mongolia: Avoiding Tragedy in the Worlds Largest Commons, Olin
Working Paper in Law and Economics, Boalt Hall School of Law, Berkeley.
Cooter, Robert D. and Landa, Janet T. (1984), Personal versus Impersonal Trade: The Size of Trading
Groups and Contract Law, 4 International Review of Law and Economics, 15-22.
Cornell, Stephen and Kalt, Joseph P. (1993), Where does Economic Development Really Come From?
Constitutional Rule Among the Modern Sioux and Apache, 93 Faculty Research Working
Papers, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, 30 ff.
Dalton, George (1967), Tribal and Peasant Economies, Austin, University of Texas Press.
De Soto, Hernando (1989), The Other Path, New York, Harper and Row.
Demsetz, Harold (1967), Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 62 American Economic Review,
347-359.
Eggertsson, Thrainn (1992), Analyzing Institutional Successes and Failures: A Millenium of Common
Mountain Pastures in Iceland, 12 International Review of Law and Economics, 423-437.
Ellickson, Robert C. (1991), Order Without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes, Cambridge, MA,
Harvard University Press.
Ellickson, Robert C. (1993), Property in Land, Yale Law Journal.
Fikentscher, Wolfgang (1995), Modes of Thought: A Study in the Anthropology of Law and Religion,
Tubingen, J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck).
Frank, Robert H. (1988), Passions Within Reason: The Strategic Role of the Emotions.
Fudenberg, Drew and Maskin, Eric (1986), The Folk Theorem in Repeated Games with Discounting
or with Incomplete Information, 54 Econometrica, 533-554.
Geertz, Clifford (1983), The Way We Think Now: Toward an Ethnography of Modern Thought,
Local Knowledge.
Gluckman, Max (1965), The Ideas in Barotse Juriprudence, New Haven, Yale University Press.
Greenhouse, Carol J. (1986), Praying for Justice: Faith, Order, and Community in an American
Town, NY, Cornell Univesity Press.
Greif, Avner (1993), Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghiribi
Traders Coation, 83 American Economic Review, 525-548.
Gruter, Magaret (1991), Law and the Mind: Biological Origins of Human Behavior, Newbury Park,
California, Sage.
726 The Law and Economics of Anthropology 0640
Gruter, Magaret and Masters, Roger (1992), The Sense of Justice: Biological Foundations of Law,
Newbury Park, California, Sage.
Harris, M. (1968), The Rise of Anthropological Theory, New York.
Hayek, Friedrich A. von (1976), Planning and the Rule of Law, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Hirshleifer, Jack (1987), Evolutionary Models in Economics and Law: Cooperation versus Conflict
Stategies, 9 Economic Behavior in Adversity.
Kuppe, Rene and Potz, Richard (1994), Law and Anthropology: International Yearbook for Legal
Anthropology, Dordrecht/Boston/London, Martinus Nijhoff Publishers.
Kuran, Timur (1995), Islamic Economics and the Islamic Subeconomy, 9 Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 155-173.
Landa, Janet T. (1981), A Theory of the Ethnically Homogeneous Middleman Group: An Institutional
Alternative to Contract Law, 10 Journal of Legal Studies, 349-362.
Leoni, Bruno (1991), Freedom and the Law, Indianapolis, Liberty Fund.
Levmore, Saul (1995), Rethinking Group Responsibility and Strategic Threats in Biblical Text and
Modern Law, 71 Chicago-Kent Law Review, 85 ff.
Llewellyn, Karl N. and Hoebel, Adamson E. (1941), The Cheyenne Way: Conflict and Case Law in
Primitive Jurisprudence, University of Oklahoma Press.
Macaulay, Stewart (1963), Non-Contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study, 25
American Sociological Review, 55-70. Reprinted in Goldberg, Victor P. (ed.), Readings in the
Economics of Contract Law, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1989, 4-15.
Malinowski, Bonislaw (1926), Crime and Custom in Savage Society, New York.
McAdams, Richard H. (1995), Cooperation and Conflict: The Economics of Group Status Production
and Race Discrimination, Harvard Law Review.
McChesney, Fred S. (1990), Government as Definer of Property Rights: Indian Land Ownership,
Ethnic Externalities, and Bureaucratic Budgets, 19 Journal of Legal Studies, 297-335.
McCloskey, D.N. (1975a), The Economics of Enclosure, in Parker, W.N. and Jones, E.L. (eds),
European Peasants and Their Markets, ASIN.
McCloskey, D.N. (1975b), The Persistence of English Common Fields, in Parker, W.N. and Jones,
E.L. (eds), European Peasants and Their Markets, ASIN.
McCloskey, Donald N. (1976), English Open Fields as Behavior Towards Risk, in Unselding, Paul
(ed.), Research in Economic History 1, Greenwich, CT, JAI Press.
Milgrom, Paul R., North, D. and Weingast, B. (1990), The Role of Institutions in the Revival of
Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs, 2 Economic and Politics,
1-23.
Miller, Geoffrey P. (1992), The Culture of Capital: Comments on Conley and OBarr, 71 North
Carolina Law Review, 201 ff.
Miller, Geoffrey P. (1993a), Ritual and Regulation: A Legal Economic Interpretation of Selected
Biblical Texts, 22 Journal of Legal Studies, 477-501.
Miller, Geoffrey P. (1993b), Contracts of Genesis, 22 Journal of Legal Studies, 15-45.
Miller, Geoffrey P. (1994), The Legal-Economic Analysis of Comparative Civil Procedure, the
Legal-Economic Approach to Biblical Interpretation,150 American Journal of Comparative Law
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 755 ff.
Miller, Geoffrey P. (1995), Verbal Feud in the Hebrew Bible: Judges 3:12-30 and 19-21, Journal of
Near Eastern Studies.
0640 The Law and Economics of Anthropology 727
Miller, Geoffrey P. (1996a), Ancient Law: the New Learning (tentative title) (1996) Constitutionalist:
A Legal-Economic Interpretation of Exodus 17:8-16 and Related Texts, 70 Chicago-Kent Law
Review, 1829 ff. To be republished in Lindgren, James, Miller, Geoffrey et al. (eds).
Miller, Geoffrey P. (1996b), The Song of Deborah: A Legal-Economic Analysis, 144 University of
Pennsylvania Law Review, 2293 ff.
Moore, Sally Falk (1986), Social Facts and Fabrications: Customary Law in Kilimanjaro
1880-1980, New York, Cambridge University Press.
Nader, Laura (1990), Harmony Ideology: Justice and Control in a Zapotec Mountain Village,
Stanford, CA, Stanford University Press.
Nugent, Jeffrey B. and Nical Sanchez (1993), Tribes, Chiefs, and Transhumance: A Comparative
Institutional Analysis, 87 Economic Development and Cultural Change, 113 ff.
Ortner, Sherry (1984), Theory in Anthropology Since the Sixities, 26 Comparative Studies in Society
and History, 125-166.
Ostrom, Elinor (1990), Governing the Commons: Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Plattner, Stuart (1989), Economic Anthropology, Stanford, Hoover Institute Press, Stanford University.
Posner, Eric A. (1995), The Regulation of Groups: The Influence of Legal and Nonlegal Santions on
Collective Action, 63 University of Chicago Law Review, 113-197.
Posner, Eric A. (1996), Law, Economics and Inefficient Norms, 145 University of Pennsylvania Law
Review, 1697-1744.
Posner, Richard A. (1980), A Theory of Primitive Society, with Special Reference to Law,23 Journal
of Law and Economics, 1-25.
Pospisil (1958), Kapauku Papuans and Their Law, New Haven, Published for the Dept. of
Anthropology, Yale University.
Sierra, Maria Teresa (1995), Indian Rights and Customary Law in Mexico: A Study of the Nahuas in
the Sierra de Puebla, 29 Law and Society Review, 227-254.
Taylor, Michael (1987), The Possibility of Cooperation, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Trebilcock, Michael J. (1981), Communal Property Rights: The Papua New Guinea Experience,
University of Toronto Law Journal.
Ullman-Margalit, Edna (1977), The Emergence of Norms, Oxford, Clarendon Press.
Williams, Robert, A., Jr (1994), Linking Arms Together: Multicultural Constitutionalism in a North
American Indigenous Vision of Law and Peace', 82 California Law Review, 981-1049.
Winn, Jane Kaufman (1994), 'Informal Financial Practices of Small Business in Taiwan', 28 Law and
Society Review, 193-241.
0650
NEW ECONOMIC HISTORY AND LAW AND
ECONOMICS
Alexander J. Field
Professor of Economics at Santa Clara University
Copyright 1999 Alexander J. Field
Abstract
This chapter reviews the contributions of the new economic history in light of
their relationship to the study of law and economics. After reviewing the
progress of the subdiscipline over the past century, and comparing the
approaches of new and old economic historians, the chapter provides an
overview of some of the most important controversies in the field and offers a
bibliography with references to the relevant literature.
JEL classification: K0, N0.
Keywords: New Economic History, Law and Economics, German Historical
School
1. Introduction
The purpose of this chapter is to give readers a broad overview of the new
economic history and its relationship to the study of law and economics. The
emphasis is not primarily on contributions specifically concerned with law and
institutional structure as explananda per se - such matters are treated elsewhere
in these volumes. Rather the focus is on what the field of the new economic
history is, what its relationship is to the old economic history, and how its
methodology and concerns relate to those of the economics discipline on the
one hand and the study of law and economics on the other.
To understand the relationship between law and economics and the new
economic history, it is important to understand what the new economic history
is (or was, since it is hardly new anymore) and what it reacted against.
Economic history began its life as a specialized social science subdiscipline
with close links to legal and institutional scholarship, and considerable shared
interest in documenting rule variation and its independent causal influence on
economic life. Receptivity to that methodological stance waned during the
heyday of the new economic history, although there is evidence in recent years
that it is beginning to wax again.
728
0650 New Economic History and Law and Economics 729
The new economic history was born in the United States in the late 1950s
and early 1960s, and has subsequently come to have increasing influence in
Europe and the rest of the world as well. Prior to the late 1950s scholarship in
the area of economic history had a strong institutional, legal, and arguably
statistical focus, but was largely agnostic when it came to the desirability of
applying formal economic theory to historical inquiry. Attitudes toward theory
changed with the advent of the new economic history, and with these came
differences in how old and new economic historians defined their tasks. A
strand of continuity over the last century has been a subject of concern in the
history of growth and development. In this context, economic history is
distinguishable from the history of economic thought, a branch of intellectual
history.
The first professor of economic history in the United States, William J. Ashley,
assumed his position at Harvard University in 1892, seven years after the
founding of the American Economic Association and eight years after the
establishment of the American Historical Association. The initial memberships
of both of these associations were heavily influenced by ideals and scholarship
developing within German universities, which led the world in doctoral
instruction at the end of the nineteenth century. Indeed, up until the 1880s it
was impossible to obtain a PhD in the United States; the first American
programs were established at Johns Hopkins University and Clark University
at the end of the century.
The German tradition of economic scholarship, associated with such
scholars as Wilhelm Roscher, Gustav von Schmoller, Karl Knies and Werner
Sombart, emphasized inductive generalizations reached through the careful
study of primary materials, and defined itself in opposition to the more abstract
deductive approach popularized in England by David Ricardo and others.
German economic scholarship was dynamic and developmental, in that it
sought to delineate and understand how economic categories changed and
evolved over time, leading to various stage theories, or at least typologies of
economic progress. The ambitions of German historical economists were hardly
modest: they looked forward to a victory over the English approach as complete
as had been Adam Smiths over Mercantilist doctrine (Gay, 1941, p. 10).
This ambition was overreaching, a conclusion announced as early as 1901
by Thorstein Veblen and affirmed consistently by scholars thereafter (Veblen,
1901). Neither the extensive description of legal and institutional environments
nor the development of stage theories of economic development would halt the
elaboration, development and growing influence of partial and general
equilibrium analysis known generically as neoclassical economics. But the
730 New Economic History and Law and Economics 0650
One can appreciate the old economic history perspective on the tasks of
economic history in this excerpt from a paper published in 1913 by Guy
Callender in the American Historical Review. Callender, then professor of
economic history at Yale, began by contrasting the lack of interest in economic
history he experienced that year at the annual meeting of the American
Economic Association with that displayed by historians at their conclave. He
noted that relative interest levels in the two disciplines appeared to have
reversed over the previous two decades and went on to reaffirm the
indebtedness of economic history to the German historical tradition, as well as
the primacy of institutional analysis as the starting point for economic inquiry:
economic history owes its existence to [the historical school] Economic
science ought to be primarily a theory of development and not merely an
explanation of the way in which human beings produce wealth and share it as
income under a given set of social conditions.
Callenders vision of economic history as a fundamentally empirical
science, concerned with growth and development, recognizing that institutions
have consequences for economic performance and may change over time in
ways we should try and understand, is a statement of the tasks of economic
history that continues to have relevance today. But only parts of it would have
found favor at the height of the new economic history revolution. Although new
economic historians were as concerned as was Callender with understanding
growth and development, institutional variation was not the first thing they
turned to in accounting for it.
A second arguable area of continuity among old and new economic history
has been an emphasis on the use of statistics to measure economically
important magnitudes. Sir John Clapham, in his inaugural lecture for the first
chair in economic history at Cambridge University in England proclaimed it
the obvious business of an economic historian to be a measurer above other
historians (cited in McCloskey, 1987, p. 41; from Clapham 1930, p. 68), and
most new economic historians would embrace the sentiment. The continuity is
arguable, however, because old economic historians interest in statistics was
often limited to documenting the historical record.
New economic historians have been interested in doing more than just
clarifying the record per se: they have yearned to verify conjectures, to test
hypotheses. New economic historians have been more likely to say, well, if
this is true, then that must be true. Lets go look at the data and see if it is.
They have also been armed with more powerful statistical techniques - in
particular multiple regression - and much cheaper computational tools than
were available to their predecessors. And they have approached with
enthusiasm the task of teasing out relationships and possible causal connections
from the experiments provided by history in what of course has had to remain
a nonexperimental science.
732 New Economic History and Law and Economics 0650
Another reason the continuity is arguable is that in the first half of the
twentieth century the most dedicated analyzers of quantitative historical data
were not economic historians per se but rather students of business cycles
associated with the National Bureau of Economic Research. Wesley Mitchell,
Arthur Burns and Simon Kuznets were certainly sympathetic to the study of
economic history, but it was not their primary professional identification. This
anomaly led Carter Goodrich to wonder, on the eve (or morning?) of the
revolution in 1960, whether economic history [was] one subject or two? He
commented that the study of business cycles and conventional economic
history are for the most part carried on in separate compartments and that
twice during the present century a vigorous body of research concerned
with economic changes over time [has] developed largely in isolation from
conventional economic history. (The first was the study of business cycles, the
second the resurgence in the 1950s in interest in economic growth.) In each
case the new work was quantitative in method, and the result was the
phenomenon of two separate bodies of scholarship - the one written in prose
and calling itself economic history, the other written mainly in figures and
calling itself by another name (Goodrich, 1960, p. 531).
Goodrich concluded by asking plaintively whether If these are tasks that
can be done better by scholars operating under another banner, is there any
remaining purpose for us to serve? The partial isolation of the field from work
relevant to its main concerns was something that new economic historians
wished to remedy, and it is one area in which there has been partial success.
A final area of continuity between the German and English/American
traditions was in the commitment to describing and communicating to students
the important and essential features of legal and institutional environments,
even as this commitment received less and less affirmation from mainstream
economists. Here one finds the weakest link between old and new economic
history - a point of obvious relevance to scholars in the law and economics area.
Both old and new historians have sought to understand and explain growth.
Old economic historians, and institutional economists such as John R.
Commons, were interested in institutions, not so much in and of themselves,
as for the insight they might offer into variations in economic performance.
Nevertheless, for old economic historians, one started with the institutions, and
in that sense they were primary (Redlich, 1965, p. 482).
It is fair to say that throughout the first four decades of the twentieth century,
American scholarship proceeded very much in the shadow of Europe. The
0650 New Economic History and Law and Economics 733
outbreak of the World War Two in Europe created conditions under which the
modern American university would blossom, both because of the interruptions
of contacts and scholarly materials from overseas and because of the exodus of
scholars (and scholars to be) from the war-torn continent. The latter migration,
which brought to the United States such luminaries as Alexander Gerschenkron
and Simon Kuznets, enriched economic history in the United States as it did
other scholarly fields, and the increased difficulty of maintaining scholarly
contact with Europe helped lead to the establishment in 1940 of a US based
Economic History Association (EHA).
Although an Economic History Society (EHS) had existed in England since
1926, and been supported by American scholars, there were concerns that the
EHS was partial to European topics and thus intermittent pressures for a new
association on the western side of the Atlantic. The war catalyzed these
concerns, and the establishment of the EHA along with its journal, the Journal
of Economic History, announced and ratified at meetings of both the American
Economics and the American Historical Associations in 1940, fleshed out the
thesis against which the antithesis of the new economic history would be
opposed (Lamoreaux, 1998).
Two other developments should be noted in order fully to appreciate the
historical setting in the United States in the late 1950s and early 1960s, within
which the new economic history strode brashly forward. The first was the
establishment, also in 1940, with Rockefeller Foundation support, of the
Committee on Research in Economic History, administered for the first 10
years through the Social Science Research Council, and incorporated separately
thereafter. (The other, dealt with subsequently, was the rapid growth after 1957
of the American university system, the consequence of demographic trends and
the launching of Sputnik.) The purpose of the Rockefeller grant was quite
simply to develop the field of economic history. To do this the committee
supported studies of the role of government and its relationship to economic
development, of entrepreneurship within the private sector, of the banking
system and its role in mobilizing capital and facilitating interregional and
intersectoral intermediation, and of historical statistics (Cole, 1953, p. 79).
The latter initiative is probably least well known yet illustrates how interest
in statistical data does represent at least a weak strand of continuity between the
concerns of the old and new economic history. CREH funding partially
supported the preparation of the first edition of Historical Statistics of the
United States, published by the Federal governments Bureau of the Census in
1949 (Cole, 1953). This publication and its successors both reflect and have
served as a starting point for much research in US economic history, providing
authoritative statistical series extending far beyond those available in current
editions of the Statistical Abstract of the United States or Economic Report of
the President. A second edition of Historical Statistics appeared in 1960, with
734 New Economic History and Law and Economics 0650
data through 1957, and a Bicentennial edition in 1975, with data through 1970.
A new millennial edition is now under preparation by a consortium of
economic scholars in universities (because of budget cutbacks the United States
Census Bureau has been unwilling to fund a revision) and is scheduled to be
published in both print and electronic editions by Cambridge University Press
in the year 2000.
The other CREH initiatives, particularly those in the areas of institutional
structure, strengthened old economic history traditions that new economic
historians would enthusiastically reject. The committees grants in the
institutional area reflected a view that governments of American states had, in
the early history of the republic, played an influential role in fostering economic
development and that the increased federal role evident in the New Deal should
be understood as a change in the locus of regulatory influence and government
action to improve economic performance, not wholesale abandonment of a
laissez faire past. CREH funding supported the well-known works by Oscar and
Mary Handlin on the role of government in Massachusetts (Handlin and
Handlin, 1969), as well as Louis Hartzs 1955 treatise on government in
Pennsylvania, The Liberal Tradition in America. Less familiar are CREH
funded studies of Georgia (Heath, 1954) and Missouri (Primm, 1954).
The intellectual framework underlying these grants was the old economic
history belief in the need for an intellectual division of labor between scholars
who would describe the institutional setting within which economic activity
(and the processes that led to its change over time) took place, and those who
would model and study behavior within such settings. The position of economic
historians within economics departments had traditionally reflected this
division of labor, but it was and continued to be an awkward division because
the intellectual tools needed to do the former well were different from those
required to excel at the latter. Analyzing economic behavior within an
institutional framework required tools of great analytical sophistication whereas
studies of an evolving institutional environment required sensitivity to context,
nuance and skills in the interpretation of documentary materials, all more likely
to be found in humanities as opposed to mathematics or statistics departments.
It was this divergence of traditions and methodologies, particularly with
respect to the use of formal economic theory in historical analysis, that the new
economic historians would ultimately try to bridge. Fogel (1965, p. 95) argued
in 1965 that the new economic history represents a reunification of economic
history with economic theory and thus brings to an end the century old split
between these two branches of economics. The new economic historians
possessed stronger training in statistical methods and econometrics than did
their predecessors. But the emphasis on the use of statistics for measurement
was not, as has been noted, entirely new. In that sense the term Cliometrics
(from Clio, the muse of history), sometimes used synonymously for the new
0650 New Economic History and Law and Economics 735
such as social psychology, for inspiration (McClelland et al., 1953). Thus the
two main CREH initiatives had relatively little influence on scholars interested
in historical economics who also had some systematic exposure to formal
economics.
Establishment of the Research Center in Entrepreneurial History did,
however, lead to the establishment of a second American journal in the area,
Explorations in Entrepreneurial History, a journal that would be renamed
Explorations in Economic History in 1969, presumably to distance itself
somewhat from its intellectual origins and broaden its appeal. (A third
American outlet, an annual, Research in Economic History, began publication
in 1979.)
The final factors reinforcing the growth of the new economic history were
US demographic trends and the launching in October of 1957 of Sputnik. The
Soviet scientific and propaganda triumph led to a great deal of national soul
searching and a substantial increase of US funding for scientific, including
social scientific research. Although the baby boom in the US peaked in that
year, the enormous number of children born after World War Two and their
eventual demands for higher education, contributed, along with Sputnik, to a
golden age for American academicians between 1957 and 1969. These were
years of great expansion in the capacity of the American University system as
undergraduate enrollments soared and faculty shortages developed. New and
expanded graduate training programs designed to address these shortages
served in the short run only to worsen them as they added their own demand
for new faculty to an already undersupplied pool (the phenomenon can be
understood in economic terms as a capital stock adjustment phenomenon). The
real income of scholars and funds available for research increased over these
years until the expanded graduate programs eventually flooded the faculty
market as the 1970s began, and the macroeconomic legacy of the Vietnam war
led to more moderate levels of support for scientific research (Field, 1987a).
The new economic history defined itself and made its greatest impact during
these golden years. What the insurgents promised was an extension of the
revolution in method then sweeping the economics profession as a whole, a
revolution that emphasized much greater use of analytical, mathematical and
statistical methods, to economic history. The old intellectual guideposts were
vigorously attacked. In particular, two pillars of the CREH initiatives and the
traditional economic history - (1) the emphasis on description of institutional
or legal structures as the first step in understanding the process of development
and (2) the study of entrepreneurial behavior within those structures - was, if
not rejected, at least very substantially reduced in the attention devoted to it.
0650 New Economic History and Law and Economics 737
In summary, it is my conviction that we need to sweep out the door a good deal of
the old economic history, to improve the quality of the new economic history, and
it is incumbent upon economists to cast a skeptical eye upon the research produced
by their economic history colleagues to see that it lives up to standards which they
would expect in other areas of economics. (North, 1965, p. 91)
The Nobel prize in economics was first awarded in 1969, and a review of
recipients with work touching on economic history, law and economics, and
their relationship provides perspective on the recent evolution of these
disciplines. Simon Kuznets was the first of five honorees with such
connections. Although Kuznets, who received the award in 1971, did not
consider himself primarily a new economic historian, he trained many of its
pioneers (such as Robert Fogel and Stanley Engerman) and his development of
national income accounting reflected the new economic historys passion for
measurement. Kuznets work laid the foundation for modern empirical
macroeconomics and macroeconomic history, even though, as noted by
Goodrich above, the National Bureau tradition proceeded largely independently
from economic history.
Five years later (1976) Milton Friedman received the award. From the
standpoint of economic history, his greatest contribution has been in the area
of monetary history, in particular the monumental 1963 work coauthored with
Anna Schwartz, A Monetary History of the United States (Friedman and
Schwartz, 1963). Friedmans work, and the reaction to it, played an important
role in seating the study of cyclical macroeconomic phenomena squarely within
the purview of economic history. Part of the success here, however, is
attributable to a shift toward a more contemporary focus on policy issues by the
National Bureau under the leadership of Martin Feldstein, with the
consequence that historical studies of business cycles no longer play as central
a role in the Bureaus agenda.
Fifteen years later, in 1991, Ronald Coase won the prize. Coase is a pivotal
figure in the development of industrial organization as well as law and
economics, and his contributions are discussed in detail elsewhere in these
volumes. To the extent that economic historians have developed a more
sophisticated approach to economic and legal institutions, his ideas have been
742 New Economic History and Law and Economics 0650
important. Yet for reasons having to do with the sociology of the profession, his
overall influence on economic history has been curiously weak. This is because
scholars who start out self-identifying as economic historians, but become
interested and proficient in a Coasian type of analysis, generally begin
publishing in law reviews or law and economics journals. There is little bias
against an historical perspective in law; indeed one might argue that such a
perspective is essential, and thus the barriers to exit in this direction are weak.
Finally, in 1993, two pioneers of the new economic history, Robert Fogel
and Douglass North, received the prize. Fogel was a central player in two of the
defining intellectual debates of the Cliometrics revolution, the study of how
indispensable were the American railroads and, in a book coauthored with
Stanley Engerman in 1974, Time on the Cross, the economics of slavery. This
latter work, which attempted to turn upside down much received wisdom about
how efficient the slave plantation system had been, and how well slaves were
housed, fed, clothed and treated, engendered enormous controversy within the
profession. In the last two decades, Fogel has pioneered in the use of historical
demographic data to study variations and changes in the standard of living.
Douglass North made important empirical contributions to the economic
history of the antebellum period, in particular his study of the US as an export-
led economy from 1790 to 1860 (North, 1961). But his greatest professional
success has been in trying to fill the gap left by the new economic historys
attack on the older legal/institutional tradition. For many scholars outside of the
profession, North is the new economic history. But there is a real question as
to how central Norths institutional work is to the new economic history or
what exactly law and economics scholars should draw from it. How to
reintegrate institutions with historical analysis without reembracing the errors
of the old economic history? As noted, in his 1973 work with Robert Paul
Thomas, instead of making the study of the institutional framework the starting
point of analysis, North struggled bravely to avoid appeals to ad hoc
explanations, and instead to develop endogenous theories of institutions: that
is, August 17, 1999 theories that would explain within a general (not historical
or case-specific) framework, how and why institutions varied over time and
space. The problem with such an approach is this. If we take the fundamental
task of economic history to be understanding and explaining economic
performance over time, then an interest in institutions - by old or new economic
historians - is ultimately relevant only to the degree that it can shed light on
such performance. To the extent that institutions are made endogenous -
determined within the context of a general theory by more fundamental factors
such as technology or demography, they cannot play an independent role in
accounting for variation in performance.
These are the dimensions of the intellectual box that North - and scholars
in many other disciplines - have struggled mightily to escape from. In a 1971
book coauthored with Lance Davis, Davis and North were willing to take the
0650 New Economic History and Law and Economics 743
initial constitutional setup as given, but then went on to describe how private
groups motivated by self interest seized profitable opportunities to make
institutional innovations. Ex post one can certainly find many cases where such
a perspective makes good narrative history. But whether Davis and North
actually succeed in developing a general theory, an explanatory framework
that leads to refutable hypotheses, remains questionable. This was the view of
Olmstead and Goldberg (1975), who also pointed out that many of the factors
(such as public opinion) that North and Davis took as exogenous environmental
factors, could in fact also be affected by expenditures of resources by private
groups.
In the previously discussed The Rise of the Western World, coauthored with
Robert Paul Thomas (North and Thomas, 1973), North tried to make
endogenous the entire institutional structure of Western Europe, accounting for
the breakdown of feudalism and the rise of modern economic and political
institutions with reference only to more fundamental factors, such as
demographic change and, to a lesser degree, new technology. The key
component of their analysis is the labor to land ratio, whose rise, caused by
population growth, is supposed to account for the demise of feudalism. But
feudalism in western Europe broke down both as population rose, prior to the
Black Death, and when population fell, after the plague. Moreover, falling
population appears to have been associated with a recrudescence of feudalism
in Eastern Europe, and it was precisely the scarcity of labor that Evsey Domar
has used to explain the initiation and persistence of coerced labor regimes, both
in Eastern Europe, and in the American South (Domar, 1970). Looked at
objectively, one extracts from the work a theory that says that rising labor to
land ratios lead to breakdowns of coerced labor regimes, except when they do
not.
In later work, North (1981, 1990) has made valiant attempts to respond to
such criticisms, but as one reads his contributions, one cannot help but continue
to ask how much of the explanation represents ex post rationalization for
what has happened. One continues to be troubled by the paucity of testable
hypotheses, as compared, for example, with his earlier empirical studies of the
US as a (cotton) export led economy prior to the Civil War (North, 1961). That
theory generated predictions that other scholars such as Fishlow (1965b) could
then test (in a way not favorable to the North hypothesis) but in the process our
understanding of antebellum economic history advanced.
Northian institutional economic history tends to be neither quantitatively
empirical nor, because of its sweep, informed by detailed knowledge of law in
its particulars. In contrast, scholars in the law and economics area must possess
such understanding. In the United States, a minimum familiarity with the law
of property, contracts, civil procedure and torts (at least at the level it is taught
in a typical first year law school curriculum) as well as some Constitutional
Law is in general a precondition for success in the field. Particularly in
744 New Economic History and Law and Economics 0650
countries with an Anglo Saxon tradition, legal research and historical archival
research have important similarities: the role of precedent (stare decisis) means
that history matters (although in legal research the archives are more likely
to be computer searchable).
Legal scholarship, in general, has a solid grounding in the history and
historiography of the law, as reflected for example in the enormous footnote
apparatus of a typical law review article. Empirical economics and economic
history, in general, have a firm grounding in the statistical record. Northian
institutional economic history, written almost exclusively from secondary
sources, often lacks much of either. Armchair economic theorists, and North,
have a fondness for stylized facts but stylized facts are sometimes simply
wrong, and someone has to be responsible for trying to ensure that the
generalizations are reasonable. It falls to economic (and legal) historians to be
at least as concerned with accurately characterizing the stylized facts as
explaining them.
North, as we have seen, has been a continuing proponent of revitalizing
economic history through the introduction of the perspectives of economic
theory, and the urge to generalize in his work often militates against detailed
immersion in the particulars of a topic. But importing even a little bit of the
attitude toward data of theoretical economists into historical, let alone legal or
institutional scholarship, creates real problems. In an effort which has been
relatively exceptional in recent years, however, Wallis and North (1986) did try
empirically to estimate the size of the transactions economy: that part of
economic activity devoted to negotiating and transactions among individuals,
as opposed simply to producing the goods or nontransactions services (like
haircuts).
In reflecting on Norths contributions, one is struck by the extent to which
the interface between law and economics and economic history might benefit
from more contributions such as McCurdy (1978). This article, although
published in the Journal of Economic History, displays the legal historians
knowledge of constitutional and statutory law and attention to detail sometimes
lacking in Norths grand excursions. I mention McCurdys article first because
it is relatively obscure and second because it deals with private actions to
achieve institutional change - in this case those of American corporations such
as Singer to eliminate state created obstacles to interstate trade, and in so doing
help forge a national market. Such actions in response to opportunities for gain
are of course the main subject of Davis and North.
When all is said and done, however, North deserves credit for the
indefatigable way in which he has worked successfully to reinject a concern
with legal and institutional arrangement back in to the new economic history.
What can law and economics scholars learn from Norths sweeping forays into
institutional and economic history? Probably not too much about law and
0650 New Economic History and Law and Economics 745
economics. But his work can open up for them a better understanding of the
broad macroeconomic concerns about growth and development that are second
nature to practicing economic historians and remain at the core of the
discipline. Interested readers should consult Norths numerous publications (see
bibliography) as well as surveys such as Libecap, (1978, 1986).
Returning to Fogel, the publication of Time on the Cross in 1974
engendered enormous publicity and an equally massive intellectual reaction
(see David et al., 1976). Looking back from the perspective of the late 1990s,
the controversy over slavery in the 1970s, which continued a conversation
begun by Conrad and Meyer in 1958, was in a very real sense the beginning of
the end of the new economic history as a revolutionary movement (Conrad and
Meyer, 1958). There have been few contributions in the last two decades that
have engendered anywhere near as much heat, with the possible exception of
relatively recent work on technological lock-in (Arthur 1994; David, 1985).
This reduction in heat has not been entirely regrettable. Some of the
criticisms of the old economic history evidenced more bluster than substance,
and when the dust settled and these critiques were subject to more dispassionate
analysis, were found to have weak intellectual foundations. Although there
were a few more displays of revolutionary rhetoric in the late 1970s, the field
began to exhibit more intellectual maturity. The sense of superiority that
economic historians trained as economists maintained vis vis their colleagues
trained as historians began to weaken, and a rapprochement of sorts took place
at least with those historians who remained active in the Economic History
Association because of their interest in the application of social science
methods to history.
Although mathematical symbols and econometric results continue to appear
frequently within the pages of economic history articles, text and narrative hold
their own as important parts of the exercise in persuasion. And so an uneasy
methodological truce has been reestablished, with economic history in the late
twentieth century perhaps now poised to provide object lessons both to
historians and to economists about how to conduct empirically based,
analytically sophisticated inquiries into social phenomena.
But the fundamental issue of the role of legal and institutional analysis
within economics and the role of economic historians in addressing such
phenomena remains unresolved. The finesses simply have not been successful.
Perhaps the scholar who came closest to striking the right balance in recent
decades was Jonathan Hughes. Hughes, although a new economic historian,
was always something of a maverick, publishing entrepreneurial history when
it was no longer fashionable, and, when it was no longer fashionable,
continuing to treat the institutional environment as consequential and at least
partially exogenous, and thus deserving of detailed attention in its own right
(Hughes, 1966, 1977). His approach to institutions can also be appreciated by
746 New Economic History and Law and Economics 0650
The best current overview of the contributions of the new economic history to
the economic history in the United States is Atack and Pasell (1994). This is
the second edition of a volume that appeared first in 1979 as Lee and Passell.
The second edition is more comprehensive and balanced; the first, for example,
devoted almost a third of its text to slavery, reflecting the extent to which that
topic dominated discussion in the 1970s. For a survey of the state of the art in
economic history circa 1972, readers should consult Davis, Easterlin and
Parker, 1972. For a textbook on American topics with a somewhat more
chronological approach, see Hughes (1990). Although this essay focuses largely
on American topics, readers interested in what the new economic history has
accomplished for the historiography of British growth should consult Floud and
McCloskey (1994). For a modern survey of the role of technological change in
economic development, see Mokyr (1990). For membership lists, online book
reviews, sample syllabi, discussion groups, and more, consult the website
maintained by the Cliometrics society at http://cs.muohio.edu. The Cliometrics
association also publishes a newsletter, which in recent years has printed
interviews with new economic history pioneers.
Identifying the significant post-slavery controversy developments in US
economic history is difficult. Southern agriculture has continued to figure, with
important books by Ransom and Sutch (1977) and Wright (1978, 1986).
Ransom and Sutch (1977) and Wright (1986) both focus on the post bellum
period, as do Alston and Ferrie (1985). The greater interest in post Civil War
topics was reinforced by the publication in 1977 of Alfred Chandlers The
Visible Hand. The book was influential not only because of its masterful
reinterpretation of the dependence of the rise of the modern business enterprise
on new communication and transportation technologies (the telegraph and the
railroad), not only for the stimulus it has given to the study of post Civil War
topics, but also because it was significant in reintegrating the sophisticated
study of business history into the agenda of economic history (Field, 1987a;
Temin, 1991; Lamoreaux and Raff, 1995; Lamoreaux, Raff and Temin, 1998).
The 1980s also saw an emphasis on the systematic analysis of height by age
data to shed new light on variations in standards of living across time and
space. This has been part of a broader increase in the interests of new economic
historians in historical demography (Steckel, 1995). Another notable
development has been increased interest in the phenomenon of technological
lock-in - the idea that economies might be subject to technological hysterisis
0650 New Economic History and Law and Economics 747
and thus path-dependent. The argument is that accidents of the past can matter,
determining everything from the shape of a dollar bill to our dependence on
internal rather than external combustion (steam) engines for road transport
(David, 1985; Arthur, 1994). While this literature has developed largely out of
an interest in technological trajectories, it has great potential relevance for the
study of legal structure and institutions. Indeed, since there is broader variation
in legal structures at moments in time than there is in technological practice,
lock-in effects might be more significant in the analysis of law than in
technology per se. This is largely an unexplored area (Field, 1991), however,
and the empirical significance of technological lock-in remains under debate
(Liebowitz and Margolis, 1990), although it has figured heavily in the 1998
Department of Justice antitrust proceeedings against the Microsoft corporation.
Other major trends in the 1980s and 1990s have included an emphasis on
what might be called applied labor economics using older data - with analysis
applied to everything from the traffic in indentured servants in the colonial
period (Galenson, 1981) to the earnings of women (Goldin, 1990). But
macroeconomics has not been entirely eclipsed, particularly in studies of the
Great Depression. Its history remains in an unsettled state, but not for want of
attention, with a new international perspective (Eichengreen, 1992; Temin,
1989), which emphasizes the deflationary consequences of failure to abandon
gold as well as new work by Field (1992) and Romer (1992) exploring internal
reasons why the depression in the United States was so long and a number of
contributions focusing on the role of financial structure (see Calomiris, 1993
for a review of recent research on financial aspects of the downturn).
In other work Romer has questioned the conventional wisdom that the post-
World War Two period has in fact been less volatile than prior periods.
Romers methodology was thought provoking, but the contribution is notable
also because it signals the degree to which, whether on the microeconomic or
macroeconomic side, the great unexplored frontier for economic historians lies
in the post-World War Two period. It is symptomatic that the Atack and Passell
survey stops in 1940, and the postwar sections in standard economic history
texts tend to be relatively weak. When the new economic history began in the
late 1950s, the end of the World War Two was barely a decade in the past, and
consequently it was hard to think of the postwar period in historical terms.
More than half a century has now elapsed since 1945, a half century that will
benefit in the future from the detailed attentions of economic historians. Such
work will likely cause us increasingly to rethink interpretations of prior periods.
748 New Economic History and Law and Economics 0650
7. Conclusion
Scholars in law and economics should read economic history not so much
because of what it will teach them about law, but because of what it can teach
them about economies. In spite of all the methodological writing about the
differences between old and new economic history, one constant throughout the
century during which the subdiscipline of economic history has had a distinct
existence has been an empirical concern with the process of economic growth
and development. This theme unifies the practitioners of the German historical
school, with their tastes for inductively developing stage theories of growth,
through the old economic history up through and continuing with the new
economic history. The general understanding of the trajectories of growth and
development, and the creative use of the framework of economic theory to
account for these are valuable complements to the knowledge base typically
possessed by the law and economics scholar. So too is the consistent approach
to data and measurement - particularly because the study of law and economics,
with the possible exception of studies of criminal law, is not in general
empirically quantitative.
The contributions of the new economic history to legal analysis per se are
less clear, with the possible exception of recent work on lock in. First of all, law
and economics scholars will already be familiar with much of it, because
individuals who may have begun in economic history have mastered the body
of knowledge possessed by law and economic scholars and have consequently
published in Journal of Law and Economics or various Law Reviews. A search
of the Econ Lit database (published for the American Economic Association by
Silver Platter) for economic history and law brings up over a thouand citations,
but most of them are not in economic history journals.
Law and economics researchers interested in institutional and legal
structure per se may actually find more of interest in the writings of old
economic historians. But for economic historians, the interest in law and
institutions has, at least in principle, always been instrumental - the payoff
comes in understanding how variation in such structures may affect
performance. Naturally, time in the classroom and time in the library is limited
and old economic historians can be faulted for sometimes appearing to lose
steam after describing the changing institutional structure, perhaps assuming
that the connections with economic performance were obvious. They are not.
On the other hand, new economic historians have often ignored the
institutional structure or tried to make it endogenous. It is in understanding the
links between legal and institutional structure and performance that lie the
greatest challenges to scholars in law and economics and economic history.
0650 New Economic History and Law and Economics 749
Acknowledgments
I would like to thank Peter Temin, Gavin Wright and an anonymous referee for
their helpful comments.
Alston, Lee J. and Ferrie, Joseph P. (1985), Labor Costs, Paternalism and Loyalty in Southern
Agriculture: A Constraint on the Growth of the Welfare State, 45 Journal of Economic History,
95-117.
Arthur, Brain (1994), Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy, Ann Arbor,
University of Michigan Press.
Ashley, W.J. (1893), On the Study of Economic History, 17 Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Ashton, T.S. (1946), The Relation of Economic History to Economic Theory, Economica NS May
1946, reprinted in the Study of Economic History, edited by N.B. Harte, London, Frank Cass,
1971, 161-80
Atack, Jeremy and Passell, Peter (1994), A New Economic View of American History, 2nd edn, New
York, W.W. Norton.
Callender, Guy S. (1913), The Position of American Economic History, 19 American Historical
Review, 80-97.
Calomiris, Charles (1993), Financial Factors in the Great Depression, 7 Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 61-85.
Chandler, Alfred (1977), The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business,
Cambridge, Harvard University Press.
Clapham, J.H. (1930), Economic History as a Discipline, V Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences,
New York, Macmillan.
Cochran, Thomas C. (1959), Recent Contributions to Economic History: The United States, The
Twentieth Century, 19 Journal of Economic History, 64-75.
Cole, Arthur H. (1953), Committee on Research in Economic History: A Description of its Purposes,
Activities, and Organization, 13 Journal of Economic History, 79-87.
Conrad, Alfred and Meyer, John (1958), The Economics if Slavery in the Antebellum South, 66
Journal of Political Economy.
David, Paul A. (1985), Clio and the Economics of QWERTY, 75 American Economic Review,
332-337.
David, Paul A. et al. (1976), Reckoning with Slavery : A Critical Study in the Quantitative History
of American Negro Slavery, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
750 New Economic History and Law and Economics 0650
Davis, Lance E. and North, Douglass C. (1971), Institutional Change and American Economic
Growth, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Davis, Lance E., Easterlin, Richard and Parker, William (1972), American Economic History: An
Economists History of the United States, New York, Harper and Row.
Domar, Evsey (1970), The Causes of Slavery and Serfdom, A Hypothesis, 30 Journal of Economic
History, 18-32.
Eichengreen, Barry (1992), Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression,
1919-1939, New York, Oxford University Press.
Engerman, Stanley L. (1992), Coerced and Free Labor: Property Rights and the Development of the
Labor Force, 29 Explorations in Economic History, 1-29.
Field, Alexander J. (1981), The Problem with Neoclassical Institutional Economics: A Critique with
Reference to the North-Thomas Model of Pre-1500 Europe, 18 Explorations in Economic
History, 174-198.
Field, Alexander J. (1987a), The Future of Economic History, in Field, A.J. (ed.), The Future of
Economic History, Boston, Kluwer-Nijhoff.
Field, Alexander J. (1987b), Modern Business Innovation as a Capital Saving Innovation, 47 Journal
of Economic History, 473-485.
Field, Alexander J. (1991), Do Legal Systems Matter?, 28 Explorations in Economic History, 1-35.
Field, Alexander J. (1992), Uncontrolled Land Development and the Duration of the Depression in the
United States, 52 Journal of Economic History, 785-805.
Fishlow, Albert (1965a), American Railroads and the Transformation of the Antebellum Economy,
Cambridge, Harvard University Press.
Fishlow, Albert (1965b), Antebellum Interregional Trade Reconsidered, in Andreano, Ralph (ed.),
New Views in American Economic Development, Cambridge, Harvard University Press.
Fishlow, Albert and Fogel, Robert, (1971), Quantitative Economic History: An Interim Evaluation -
Past Trends and Present Tendencies, 31 Journal of Economic History, 15-42.
Floud, Roderick (1994), The Economic History of Britain Since 1700 , 2nd edn, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
Floud, Roderick and McCloskey, Donald (1994), The Economic History of Britain Since 1700, 2nd
edn, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Fogel, Robert, William (1964), Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric
History, Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University Press.
Fogel, Robert, William (1965), The Reunification of Economic History with Economic Theory, 55
American Economic Review, 92-98.
Fogel, Robert, William and Stanley Engerman (1974), Time on the Cross: The Economics of
American Negro Slavery, Boston, Little Brown.
Friedman, Milton and Schwartz, Anna J. (1963), A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960,
Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Galenson, David (1981), White Servitude in colonial America: An Economic Analysis, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
Gay, Edwin F. (1941) The Task of Economic History, 1 Journal of Economic History, 9-16.
Goldin, Claudia, Dale (1990), Understanding the Gender Gap: An Economic History of American
Women, New York, Oxford University Press.
0650 New Economic History and Law and Economics 751
Goodrich, Carter (1959), Recent Contributions to Economic History: The United States, 1789-1860,
19 Journal of Economic History, 25-43.
Goodrich, Carter (1960), Economic History: One Field or Two?, 20 Journal of Economic History,
531-538.
Gras, N.S.B. (1930), Economic History in the United States, Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences,
New York, Macmillan.
Handlin, Oscar and Handlin, Mary Flug (1969), Commonwealth: A Study of the Role of Government
in the American Economy: Massachusetts, 1774-186 (rev. Edn), Cambridge, MA, Belknap Press
of Harvard University Press.
Heath, Milton Sydney (1954), Constructive Liberalism, the Role of the State in Economic
Developments in Georgia to 1860, Cambridge, Harvard University Press.
Heaton, Herbert (1941), The Early History of the Economic History Association, 1 Journal of
Economic History, 107-109.
Higgs, Robert (1985), Crisis, Bigger Government, and Ideological Change: Two Hypotheses on the
Ratchet Phenomenon, 22 Explorations in Economic History, 1-28.
Hughes, Jonathan (1966), The Vital Few; American Economic Progress and its Protagonists, Boston,
Houghton Mifflin.
Hughes, Jonathan (1977), The Governmental Habit: Economic Controls from Colonial Times to the
Present, New York, Basic Books.
Hughes, Jonathan (1990), American Economic History, 3rd edn, Glenview, Scott Foresman.
Kuznets, Simon (1941), Statistics and Economic History, 1 Journal of Economic History.
Kuznets, Simon (1957), Summary of Discussion and Postscript, 17 Journal of Economic History,
545-553.
Lamoreaux, Naomi (1998), Economic History and the Cliometric Revolution, in Molho, Anthony
and Wood, Gordon (eds), Imagined Histories: American Historians Interpret the Past, Princeton,
Princeton University Press.
Lamoreaux, Naomi and Raff, Daniel M.G. (1995), Information and Coordination: Historical
Perspectives on the Organization of Enterprise, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Lamoreaux, Naomi, Raff, Daniel M.G. and Temin, Peter (1998), Learning by Doing in Markets,
Firms and Countries, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Landes, William (1997), The Art of Law and Economics: An Autobiographical Essay, American
Economist, 31-42.
Lee, Susan and Passell, Peter (1979), A New Economic View of American History, New York, W.W.
Norton.
Libecap, Gary D. (1978), Economic Variables and the Development of the Law, 38 Journal of
Economic History, 338-362.
Libecap, Gary D. (1986), Property Rights in Economic History: Implications for Research, 23
Explorations in Economic History, 227-252.
Liebowitz, Stanley J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1990), The Fable of the Keys, 31 Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-25.
McClelland, David C. et al. (1953), The Achievement Motive, New York, Appleton-Century-Crofts.
McCloskey, D.N. (1976), Does the Past Have Useful Economics?, 14 Journal of Economic
Literature, 434-461.
McCloskey, D.N. (1978), The Achievements of the Cliometric School, 38 Journal of Economic
History, 13-28.
McCloskey, D.N. (1987), Econometric History, London, Macmillan.
752 New Economic History and Law and Economics 0650
McCurdy, Charles W. (1978), American Law and the Marketing Structure of the Large Corporation,
1875-1890, 38 Journal of Economic History, 631-649.
Mokyr, Joel (1990), The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress, Oxford,
Oxford University Press.
North, Douglass C. (1961), The Economic Growth of the United States, 1790-1860, Englewood
Clifffs, Prentice Hall.
North, Douglass C. (1965), The State of Economic History, 55 American Economic Review, 86-91.
North, Douglass C. and Lance Davis (1971), Institutional Change and American Economic Growth,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass C. (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History, New York, Norton.
North, Douglass C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass C. and Thomas, Robert Paul (1973), The Rise of the Western World, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass C. and Weingast, Barry (1989), Constitutions and Commitment: Evolution of
Institutions Governing Public Choice, 49 Journal of Economic History, 803-832.
Olmstead, Alan and Goldberg, Victor P. (1975), Institutional Change and American Economic
Growth, 12 Explorations in Economic History, 193-210.
Parker, William (1971), From Old to New to Old in Economic History, 31 Journal of Economic
History, 3-14.
Primm, James Neal (1954), Economic Policy in the Development of a Western State, Missouri,
1920-1860, Cambridge, Harvard University Press.
Ransom, Roger and Sutch, Richard (1977), One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of
Emancipation, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Redlich, Fritz (1965), New and Traditional Approaches to Economic History and their
Interdependence, 25 Journal of Economic History, 480-495.
Romer, Christina (1986), Is the Stabilization of the Postwar Economy a Figment of the Data?, 76
American Economic Review, 314-334.
Romer, Christina (1992), What Ended the Great Depression?, 52 Journal of Economic History, 757-
784.
Solow, Robert (1985), Economic History and Economics, 75 American Economic Review, 328-331.
Temin, Peter (1969), The Jacksonian Economy, New York, W.W. Norton.
Temin, Peter (1989), Lessons from the Great Depression, Cambridge, MIT Press.
Temin, Peter (ed.) (1991), Inside the Business Enterprise: Historical Perspectives on the Use of
Information, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Umbeck, John (1977), The California Gold Rush: A Study of Emerging Property Rights, 14
Explorations in Economic History, 197-226.
Usher, Abbot Payson (1949), The Significance of Modern Empiricism for History and Economics,
9 Journal of Economic History, 137-155.
Steckel, Richard (1995), Stature and the Standard of Living, 33 Journal of Economic Literature,
1903-1940.
Swedberg, Richard (ed.) (1991), Joseph A. Schumpeter: The Economics and Sociology of Capitalism,
Princeton, Princeton University Press.
0650 New Economic History and Law and Economics 753
Abstract
In the 1970s, just as the Chicago school of law and economics (0200, 0500) was
moving beyond the relatively narrow doctrinal areas in which it had earlier
been cabined, another movement, antithetical to the free market conservatism
of the Chicago school and the kindred though distinct Virginia school (0610),
arose in American law schools. This movement, critical legal studies (CLS),
was launched as a theoretical school in substantial part through writings by
Roberto Unger (1975) and Duncan Kennedy (1976, 1979) of Harvard Law
School, and was institutionalized through the Conference on Critical Legal
Studies, begun in 1977.
CLS drew much of its inspiration and many of its adherents from the rise
in the 1960s in the United States and Europe of an egalitarian, anti-statist New
Left politics. Though partisans of both the Chicago school and CLS tended to
share a jaundiced view of the liberal centrist, New Deal/Great Society,
welfare/warfare state, their diagnoses of what was wrong with that state and
the social order in which it was embedded were profoundly different. Where
Chicago school academics saw inattention to the price mechanism and upheld
an idealized common law that harkened back to the visions of late nineteenth-
century laissez-faire legal theorists, CLS academics saw a troubling adherence
to routine, hierarchy, and rationalized violence in the liberal order.
754
0660 Critical Legal Studies 755
The sharply different political visions of CLS and Chicago law and
economics, along with differences in cultural politics between typical partisans
of the movements, reflected in matters such as hairstyle and dress, did not in
themselves determine that there would be intellectual engagement between CLS
and law and economics. But they foreshadowed that any engagement would
likely be a conflictual one, and that once CLS arose as a distinct and assertive
movement, the publication of an early article on legal form by Duncan Kennedy
(1973) in the then-new Chicago school Journal of Legal Studies (0100) would
not be followed by further articles by CLS advocates in the law and economics
journals.
Beyond the general political divisions between them, the shared
jurisprudential ambition of both CLS and Chicago law and economics to decode
and translate the law according to their own distinctive methodologies - to, as
it were, provide a Rosetta Stone for law - has been a crucial additional factor
that has led to persistent conflict between CLS and law and economics. That
conflict can be traced back to the underlying tension between the law and
economics commitment to understanding law centrally in terms of economics
and the CLS commitment to understanding law centrally in terms of
politically-charged, deep-rooted yet also contingent patterns of contradiction.
This chapter essay will focus on the relationship between CLS as an
intellectual movement in American law schools, one with the general approach
to interpreting law noted above, and law and economics, in both Chicago and
other forms. It does not deal with critical or leftist legal academic movements
in general, such as Law and Society, that may have some interest in law and
economics; nor does it deal with European scholarship that denominates itself
as critical and that has some relationship to American CLS, but that is more
closely connected outside the UK to a European tradition of contrasting formal
approaches to social, or welfare state, approaches to law (see, for example,
Wilhemsson, 1993 on critical contract law) and in the UK to a class-oriented
analysis drawing on Marxism (see, for example, Fitzpatrick and Hunt, 1987).
The intellectual engagement between CLS and law and economics over the
last twenty years has not mediated the contradiction between the CLS and law
and economics views of law. At least two major reasons for the impasse can be
offered. First, the engagement has overwhelmingly consisted of CLS analyses
of law and economics, and the relative absence of back-and-forth exchange has
made change in the terms of the debate difficult. Second, there has been a
question as to whether advocates of law and economics and CLS believe there
is any substantial value in appropriating at least some aspects of the other
movements approach; in the absence of such a belief, attempts from either
CLS or law and economics to mediate the basic tension between the movements
are unlikely.
756 Critical Legal Studies 0660
The relative dearth of law and economics attention to CLS can be taken as
reflective of law and economics supporters by and large viewing CLS as a
movement that, whatever its merits as jurisprudence, has little or nothing to
contribute to the law and economics project of relating economic reasoning to
law. On the CLS side, the situation has been more complex. To interpret the
CLS treatment of law and economics as a justification for a dismissive stance
toward the genre by the legal left is oversimple, since that interpretation misses
the substantial degree of attraction to as well as repulsion from law and
economics in CLS work.
The two major figures in the CLS engagement with law and economics,
Duncan Kennedy and Mark Kelman, have been substantially involved in doing
what can be termed CLS law and economics, that is, law and economics from
a CLS perspective (Kelman, 1979a, 1991a, 1993; Kennedy, 1987, 1992, 1994),
as well as in critically analyzing non-CLS law and economics (Kelman, 1979a,
1979b, 1980, 1983, 1984, 1985, 1987a, 1987b, 1988; Kennedy, 1981a, 1981b,
1982, 1985; Kennedy and Michelman, 1980). Nevertheless, their work,
especially their more theoretically aggressive work, and that of other CLS
supporters has been more widely viewed as a powerful criticism of prevailing
assumptions and practices in law and economics than as a charter for an
alternative, radical law and economics. Though Kennedys and Kelmans own
practice contains an implicit defense of the value of doing radical law and
economics and suggests certain contours that it can take, CLS law and
economics is at this point a developing rather than a fully developed genre. Its
future prospects will depend in part on whether CLS supporters can provide a
persuasive rationale for how CLS analysis can aid in doing law and economics,
as well as more examples of CLS law and economics.
The major theme in CLS analysis of law and economics, which is closely
parallel to the major theme in CLS analysis of law more generally, can be
readily summarized: law and economics, though typically couched as an
apolitical, technical exercise, is in fact an intensely political project. Arguments
in law and economics both rely upon and themselves embody controversial
political judgments. Law and economics argument, like legal argument, is
ideological; both genres are structured by intractable though not immutable
political contradictions. The dream of a meaningful technical efficiency
discourse purged of political contradiction is a chimerical nightmare, both
because it is false and because adherence to it tends to move political argument
rightward to a band between pragmatic, technocratic centrism and free-market
libertarianism. (How this rightward tendency operates and whether it is
0660 Critical Legal Studies 757
In modern law and economics (and economics more generally), efficiency is the
central concept, the means by which normative evaluation and technical,
value-free analysis are reconciled and brought together. That is, efficiency is
the master device for mediating the fact-value antinomy (Unger, 1975) that
pervades the social order in which law and economics is embedded. This CLS
understanding of the linchpin role of efficiency in contemporary economic
argument, which is differently expressed but hardly different in substance from
that within mainstream law and economics, has naturally led to CLS
scholarship that critically analyzes the notion of efficiency. The CLS article
that focuses most directly and thoroughly on that theme is Duncan Kennedys
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Entitlement Problems (1981a); early work of
Kelmans on the Coase Theorem (1979b, 1980) and ambivalence and regret in
consumers (1979a) makes related points, and complements and extends the
discussion in Cost-Benefit Analysis of some topics, such as offer-asking price
disparities.
Kennedys general claim in Cost-Benefit Analysis is that efficiency claims
lack the objectivity, coherence and autonomy from political value judgments
that liberal law and economics (and presumably conservative law and
economics as well, which he does not focus on) demands from them. After an
historical review contending that efficiency arguments based on internalizing
externalities became the mainstay of postwar liberal law reform movements in
areas such as products liability, he describes how liberal law and economics
responded creatively to Coases criticism of Pigous externalities analysis by
broadening externalities to include psychic costs (such as unhappiness of New
Jersey suburbanites at the destruction of Alaskan wilderness) that high
transaction costs prevented from being recognized, but that should be
recognized under liberal law and economics version of Coasean analysis.
Kennedy goes on to argue that proponents of liberal law and economics have
760 Critical Legal Studies 0660
Dilemma and Coasean bargaining to achieve a surplus, that are generally seen
as having very different meanings; the substantive claim is that efficiency
discourse operates to repress awareness of contradiction by setting up two
different stories with presumably different logical groundings, although these
logical twists are actually the same. Though the articles focus on the formal
link between Coasean bargaining and the Prisoners Dilemma suggests that its
objective is the traditional CLS one of debunking scientic pretension in law and
economics, the overall argument, like that in Brattons article, assumes and
operates from the premise that there are meaningful political contradictions
within the efficiency idea.
In developing further CLS analyses of contradictions within efficiency,
there is relevant material to be drawn from Kelmans early arguments about
psychological division in Choice and Utility (1979a). Kelmans strategy was
to debunk neoclassical theory that overlooked ambivalence and regret, but one
could now point to economic approaches advanced since 1979, such as regret
theory, that incorporate at least part of his argument and that are in
politically-salient tension with subjective expected utility theory. Or (riskily for
noneconomists, but CLS scholars accustomed to taking intellectual risks should
not, one trusts, be paralyzed by this one) one could propose new law and
economics models that are at least plausible in the terms of efficiency discourse
and are also in self-conscious political tension with other, prevailing models.
Another significant source for the developing CLS argument about
persistent contradiction within efficiency comes from work by mainstream law
and economics scholars that has arguably though not necessarily been
influenced by CLS. Cooter (1982) notes the sharp contrast between the
optimistic Coase Theorem and a pessimistic Hobbes Theorem that assumes
strategic behavior will block desirable bargains. Neither approach to achieving
efficiency is analytically preferable; rather, as Cooter notes, values and
assumptions about human nature are at stake in any effort to mediate between
them. A similar, somewhat broader point, is made by Hovenkamp (1992), who
analyzes the inconsistent views of human nature and rationality in the Coase
Theorem, price theory, and Arrows Theorem/social choice theory, which all
enjoy high standing within orthodox efficiency analysis despite their
contradictory features. Ian Ayres makes good observations on the politically
significant contrast between game theory and price theory as approaches to
efficiency, and the likely political correlates of the ascendancy of game theory
(Ayres, 1990). Ayres own game theoretic work, though it avoids assertive
claims about contradiction, persistently deploys efficiency arguments in a
fashion that flips Chicago orthodoxy. For example, Ayres and Talley (1995)
argue that liability rules generate higher welfare than property rules under
certain assumptions, an argument that flips the Chicago law and economics
case for property rules in low transaction cost situations. Interestingly, Louis
0660 Critical Legal Studies 763
entitlement to pollute, it is much less likely, even with costless bargaining, that
the neighbors will value freedom from pollution enough to bribe the
manaufacturer not to pollute. Second, the Theorem works (that is, is
counterintuitive rather than simply a truism) because it points out typically
unsuspected opportunities to bargain, such as between the rancher and the
farmer in Coases original example. Kelman criticizes the Theorems implicit
support for making bargaining ubiquitous in strong terms: The real substantive
vision of the Coase Theorem, its real cultural contribution, is to a particular
worldview that seems to me both a distorted description and a horrifying
covert ideal (Kelman, 1985, p. 1046).
In contrast, Schlag (1986) describes the Coase Theorem not as a charter for
bargaining and commodification but rather as a potentially radical vehicle for
the critique of legal concepts; he suggests that this critique can begin by
substituting conceptualization for choice of liability rule in statements of the
Theorem. His second take on the Theorem, and the transaction costs analysis
associated with it, is less optimistic; he argues that transaction costs analysis
has fallen prey to the same limitations and rigidities that were criticized by
Coase in Pigouvian externalities analysis (Schlag, 1989).
Recently Eastman (1996a) has translated the Coase Theorem into
game-theoretic terms. He argues that what distinguishes the Theorem from
standard game-theoretic analyses is a Coasean assumption of payoff mutability,
under which people engage in promises and threats in an effort to enhance their
positions. Understanding the Coase Theorem in terms of this everything is up
for grabs assumption leads to quite different implications for law than those
associated with standard interpretations of the Theorem. While the
conventional wisdom associated with the Theorem supports bargaining and
worries only about strategic behavior as an obstacle to desirable agreements, the
game-theoretic understanding points out the significance of undesirable threat
bargaining, and suggests a potential value for legal regulation that inhibits
opportunities for threat bargaining.
CLS scholarship from its inception has had a distinctive concern with the form
in which academic and judicial arguments are made. In law and economics,
that CLS concern has focused on arguments and interpretations that are
ideological but are made in a fashion that suggests they are scientifically
grounded in foundational logic or hard data. Through unmasking claims to
scientific status, CLS advocates have hoped to bring political division to the
disciplines surface and possibly to move liberals to the left.
Kennedys first major published article on law and economics, Are
Property and Contract Efficient?, written with Frank Michelman (Kennedy
0660 Critical Legal Studies 765
Given the stark oppositions Kennedy and Michelman employ (for example,
between private property and forced sharing for needs, their article has a
radical flavor, rather than the liberal flavor that would have been created by an
argument that there is no necessary inefficiency associated with, say, Swedish
social democracy compared to the less egalitarian American order. But because
they do not challenge the efficiency criterion as incoherent and necessarily
beset by political tensions, their article can be and has been (Kelman, 1987a)
characterized as a criticism of an unwarranted conservative tilt in law and
766 Critical Legal Studies 0660
To the extent CLS scholarship comes down in favor of the use of law and
economics in some form, there is an issue, which CLS work to date has not
dwelt on, as to the basis on which one might justify that stance. Kennedy (1992,
p. 1314) makes a brief, ambivalent defense of the rhetoric of cost/benefit
analysis: It is more authentic for me, than the voice of role-reversed male
sensitivity ... This is so even though I am constituted in ways I dont like, and
think are dangerous, by this very language (it speaks me) and wish it were
a different, better vehicle. One can, as Eastman (1996c) does, simply
rationalize law and economics as a storytelling project that is not necessarily
worse than other, less logistic, types of storytelling. But this elides the issue, a
sensitive one on the (post)modern, self-consciously non-foundationalist left, of
whether one believes that through the logistic storytelling of law and economics
one is discovering things about how the world works, or at least about how
certain human communities organize their concepts. The issue is not significant
to the extent CLS is not engaged in doing law and economics, but becomes a
probably unavoidable, if perhaps annoying, issue for a
philosophically-reflective CLS movement, some of whose supporters are
committed to some kind of law and economics.
7. CLS Law and Economics: The Distributive Turn and The Ideological
Turn
CLS work relating to law and economics is by no means limited to the broad
subjects treated thus far. Although this review essay focuses on themes in CLS
scholarship on law and economics that cut across particular areas of law,
arguably the most significant work in terms of the long-term viability of the
CLS engagement with law and economics is discipline-specific work in
corporate law, labor law, housing law and other areas.
An area in which a substantial body of CLS law and economics has
developed is housing law and policy (Aoki, 1993; Ford, 1994; Fox, 1991;
Keller, 1988; Kennedy, 1987, 1994; Kennedy and Specht, 1994; Kinning,
1993; Kolodney, 1991; McUsic, 1988). That work has considerable diversity
in approach, ranging as it does from Kolodneys use of tipping models to
analyze gentrification (1991) to Kinnings empirical survey of selective code
enforcement in Minneapolis (1993) to Kellers proposal for a tort remedy for
breaches of landlord duty (1988) to Fords mixture of economic analysis,
critical legal theory, critical race theory, and aspirational proposals for
combatting segregation (1994). But for all these differences in approach, the
housing literature constitutes a collective whole that is identifiably CLS law and
economics in its simultaneous commitment to economic analysis and to critical
analysis of the politics of law.
770 Critical Legal Studies 0660
Although housing law stands out for its overall body of CLS law and
economics, there are other areas of law in which CLS scholarship has fruitfully
engaged law and economics, among them antitrust (Peritz 1984, 1989, 1990),
debtor-creditor (Carlson, 1992, 1994), labor and employment (Klare, 1988;
Stone, 1991), contract (Kennedy, 1976, 1982), discrimination (Kelman, 1991a),
critical race theory (Audain, 1995), transitional economies (Alexander, 1994;
David Kennedy, 1991), property (Alexander, 1982), tort (Kennedy, 1982;
Kelman, 1988), international law (David Kennedy, 1994), and tax (Heller,
1979). Also worthy of note is work that, although done by writers not
necessarily identified with CLS, applies a critical approach of identifying
contradiction and parsing the politics of legal and economic argument:
Brattons work in corporate law (Bratton 1984, 1989a, 1989b, 1995) is
especially noteworthy in this regard, and one could also note Millons (1990)
work on corporate law and Harrisons (1995) on contract law. A final category
of work worth noting is scholarship by certain founding figures in CLS whose
interests were centered around the application of social science to law, not
through law and economics but through empirical sociology in the radical
Weberian tradition (see, for example, Richard Abel, 1982, on tort law and
David Trubek, 1984 on the use of empirical methods in CLS). Though their
work is more in keeping with the Law and Society movement than with CLS
as it developed through the theorizing of Unger and Kennedy, some work in
this line, such as Trubeks, deals with both CLS and social science, if not law
and economics in particular.
A considerable amount of CLS scholarship is historical, and some of that
work deals with law and economics. For example, in Essays on the Fetishism
of Commodities (1985), Kennedy carries out an historical analysis of the role
of law in classical economics, Marxs discussion of commodity fetishism and
neoclassical economics and argues that a realist understanding of law
destabilizes the sense of law as a coherent block that appears in classical
economics, in Marxs response to it, and in neoclassical economics effort to
overcome and partially acknowledge Marxs critique. In a more contemporary
context, Bratton (1989a) provides an historical examination of theories of the
firm.
Finally, some CLS scholars, such as Unger, have had a particular concern
with philosophy, or with the work of particular philosophers. On occasion, such
concerns have intersected with the analysis of law and economics in CLS work.
Work by David Carlson criticizing Chicago work on bankruptcy in the course
of analyzing Rawls political philosophy, and arguing that the notion of the
perfect market embodies in Derridean terms an incoherent philosophy of
presence that both presupposes and negates the idea of an opportunity cost
(Carlson, 1993), exemplify this intersection. A further subtheme in the CLS
critique of law and economics that is to some degree related to the concern with
analyzing the work of particular philosophers involves personalizing the
critique, by focusing specifically on the work of Richard Posner (see, for
0660 Critical Legal Studies 771
example, Balkin, 1987; Minda, 1978; for a good example of such work by an
author less identified with CLS, see also West, 1986).
CLS scholarship has focused its attention on law and economics, instead of the
economic discourse from which law and economics draws. One can certainly
understand the reasons that have led legal critics to engage in a critique of the
work of legal economists such as Posner rather than of economists more
generally. But given that economics, for all the formidable and specialized
analytical talent of many in the discipline, operates under social scientific
rhetorical constraints that inhibit the critical analysis of how economic
arguments are constructed and achieve their effects, there is a significant gap
that CLS can help fill. The critique of law and economics is also the critique
of economics, and there is a relative openness in law reviews, much of it won
by CLS efforts over the years, to the kind of serious critical analysis of patterns
of argument that is not currently cognizable within the conventions of social
science publication. What follows are preliminary observations on the kind of
critique of economic argument that CLS is particularly qualified to make.
These observations are followed by an analysis of the contents of a recent issue
of the American Economic Review, designed to show how a critical theory of
the ideological structuring of economic argument can be hooked up to current
practice in the field. Finally, the analysis of the ideological nature of economic
discourse will be drawn on for a brief how to guide for creating critical law
and economics.
On economic arguments: A starting point of CLS theory on this point is that
economic discourse is ideological. What does that mean? Just as legal discourse
is largely constituted by liberal and conservative argument bites, economic
discourse largely consists of similar ideological argument bites, more logically
elaborate than in law, that are associated with economic models. Public
goods, externalities, and underconsumption are a few terms evoking
argument bites and models that are typically though by no means necessarily
liberal (asymmetric information, adverse selection and relational
contracting are others); rational expectations, monetarism and supply side
evoke typically conservative argument bites/models (also transaction costs,
Coase Theorem contract law).
How does economic argument work? One tries to make a connection
between analytical logic and a real world situation. Typically, what makes the
connection interesting is that it has ideological, liberal-conservative
significance. Empirical economics is also ideological; what makes an empirical
772 Critical Legal Studies 0660
Rat race equilibria reduce access to powerful positions for those unwilling to
tolerate excessive work hours early in their careers. This selection process may have
the effect, although not the intent, of keeping a disproportionate number of qualified
women out of leadership positions in business and professional organizations. (p.
347)
underwork equilibrium? Suppose the partners in a law firm believe that success
depends on identifying future partners who will fit in well into their white shoe
club, and weeding out associates who will not. Type 1 attorneys are the
clubbable ones, while Type 2 are the overly aggressive, unclubbable ones,
who generate more short-term billings from their high hours, but who are not
desirable as rainmakers or future members of the partnership. Of course,
knowing the partners preferences, Type 2 associates have an incentive to
disguise their status by not working longer hours. But by establishing a firm
culture with a sufficiently white shoe atmosphere and low work hours ceilings,
the partners can drive out the Type 2 attorneys by making the firm an
uncomfortable place for them to work. The result is an inefficient underwork
equilibrium.
Readers may differ in their evaluation of the relative plausibility of the Rat
Race and Reverse Rat Race stories. In my view, the authors rat race story
seems like a much convincing evocation of contemporary Wall Street law firms
than the flipped story, but that is of course not a matter of the logic of adverse
selection tilting one way or another but of contingent, empirical factors. The
point here is not to insist on one story or the other, but to support the critical
intuition that the logical apparatus of the adverse selection model does not in
itself carry the day for a particular political moral.
Rat Race Redux illustrates the complexities of telling an economic story
that resonates in critical terms. The article accomplishes the considerable feat
of telling a clever story with a potentially radical moral while using standard
economic assumptions. But in relation to the adverse selection model, the lower
work preference attorneys whom the partners are trying to ferret out are like the
lemons in Akerlofs used-car story - not people one necessarily feels empathy
or support for. The adverse selection story of Rat Race Redux is technically
prettier than the simpler, keeping up with the Joneses Prisoners Dilemma
story of competition for material goods leading people to work excessively long
hours that Schor (1991) tells. But Schors Dilemma story accords more readily
with the spirit of the case for reducing work hours than the adverse selection
story of attorneys trying to disguise their low work hours preferences. Both
stories are good liberal law and economics stories that can be made radical by
being told with attention to thir ideological context; whether one values the
greater technical elegance of the Rat Race Redux adverse selection argument
or the closer connection to critical feeling in the Overworked American
Prisoners Dilemma argument is a matter of aesthetic and political judgment.
The CLS law and economics analysis just carried out for Rat Race Redux
can be compressed into a brief description of the articles story, its ideology, its
legal implications, and possibilities for reversing or flipping the storys moral.
What follows is a concise analysis of Rat Race Redux and of all the remaining
papers in the issue of AER in which in appears.
0660 Critical Legal Studies 775
(1) Rat Race Redux: Adverse Selection in the Determination of Work Hours in
Law Firms, Renee M. Landers, James B. Rebitzer and Lowell J. Taylor, AER,
Vol. 86 (1996): 329-348.
The story: Adverse selection/asymmetric information. Adverse selection may
lead to an inefficiently high number of hours worked, with firms setting a very
high hours standard to drive out asssociates who pretend to be interested in
working long hours to win the favor of partners.
The storys ideology: Liberal/radical.
Legal implications: Cut work hours.
Possibilities for flipping the model: Adverse selection may lead to an
inefficiently low level of hours worked, given an incentive of associates to
pretend to be clubbable to win the favor of partners.
(3) The Gender Gap, Fertility, and Growth, Oded Galil and David N. Weil,
AER, Vol. 86 (1996): 374-387.
The story: Assuming that men have an advantage in brawn while the sexes
are equal in brains, an increase in capital per worker will raise womens
relative wages, which in turn will decrease fertility, which in turn will increase
776 Critical Legal Studies 0660
capital per worker. Thus, a positive feedback loop exists; further, technology
is a way to escape high fertility/low capital equilibria.
The storys ideology: Conservative.
Legal implications: The gender gap will likely narrow without legal
intervention, which reduces the case for such intervention.
Possibilities for flipping the model: The optimistic invisible hand story of
increasing growth and gender equality that is told here depends on a model that
employs a simple brains vs. brawn dichotomy. Alternative models that
employ different dichotomies - for example, models in which higher capital
levels increase returns to very high levels of work hours as opposed to moderate
hours, or to mathematical as opposed to verbal skills - could be used to suggest
that economic growth without legal and political activism by and for women is
likely to generate an increasing rather than a diminishing gender gap.
(5) The Swing Voters Curse, Timothy J. Fedderson and Wolfgang Posendorfer,
AER, Vol. 86 (1996): 408-424.
The story: Winners curse/asymmetric information. Abstention from voting can
be rational for less-informed voters, because they have an interest in allowing
voters who know which candidate is preferable to control the result.
The storys ideology: Conservative.
Legal implications: Efforts to create higher turnout through, for example,
mandatory voting laws are misconceived, as are efforts to reduce the difference
0660 Critical Legal Studies 777
(6) How do Senators Vote? Disentangling the Role of Voter Peferences, Party
Affiliation, and Senator Ideology, Steven D. Levitt, AER, Vol. 86 (1996):
425-441.
The story: The liberalism or conservatism of senatorial voting, as measured by
ADA score, is more dependent on the senators own ideology than on other
factors such as party affiliation and degree of constituency liberalism.
The storys ideology: Unclear.
Legal implications: Unclear.
Possibilities for flipping the model: This is a methodological article that studies
liberal-conservative politics but does not itself have a clear liberal-conservative
significance. The model assumes that the senators ideology is the residual
influence, which is certainly debatable - what about error in measuring other
variables, or unmeasured potential influences such as the economic interests of
the senators constituency? But the articles modeling of the centrality of
ideology does not have a clear methodological politics; the model could accord
either with a new left/CLS belief in the value as well as the inevitability of
ideology and ideological debate, or with a new right/public choice belief in
representatives ideology as rent-seeking.
(8) Avoidable Cost: Ride a Double Auction Roller Coaster, Mark H. Van
Boening and Nathaniel Wilcox, AER, Vol. 86 (1996): 461-477.
The story: Double auction markets such as those employed on stock exchanges
are usually supported as efficient, but in a situation characterized by high
avoidable costs (that is, high costs for any level of production above zero, as
with flying a plane), experiments indicate that double auctions may well be
inefficient. There, cooperative institutions may well have a role in creating
efficient outcomes.
The storys ideology: Liberal.
Legal implications: For regulators to impose double auction markets is not
necessarily a good idea; sometimes cooperative institutions may work better.
Possibilities for flipping the model: Although the overall point about the failure
of a competitive market is a liberal one, in the regulatory context the message
may be opposed to certain antitrust initiatives assocated with political liberals.
More broadly, the conservative flip on this type of experimental economic work
would involve looking at an institutional situation in which the prevailing
(liberal) assumption is that free-rider problems or other market failures will
prevent an efficient solution from being achieved in the absence of regulation,
and showing experimentally that, at least in a significant category of these
situations, efficient solutions will in fact be reached without regulation.
0660 Critical Legal Studies 779
(13) Entry, Exit, Growth, and Innovation over the Product Life Cycle, Steven
Klepper, AER, Vol. 86 (1996): 562-583.
The story: The idea is to explain a pattern in which product markets are
characterized by an initial phase with innovative products and competing
designs to a later stage in which a dominant design emerges, market shares
stabilize, and larger firms predominate. The model assumes that the ability to
appropriate returns from process R&D (that is, production-oriented rather than
new product-oriented R&D) depends on firm size, which leads to large firms
and a shutout of new entrants.
The storys ideology: Conservative.
Legal implications: An anti-regulation, hands-off message is the logical
accompaniment of this type of economic storytelling.
Possibilities for flipping the model: This is economics in the conservative genre
of providing a more or less sunny explanation of why things are the way they
are, or at least seem to be. The corresponding liberal genre would explain the
product life cycle in a less sunny fashion, perhaps by using monopoly power
rather than process R&D as the driving assumption in the model. Either way,
the aesthetics of the exercise depend on whether the particular simple
conditions of the model seem to determine the situation in a persuasive,
interesting fashion.
A theoretical law and economics story may begin with a logical puzzle or it
may begin with a question about a rule, an institution or peoples actions. But
whether the initial kernel is a real world situation or a logical model, the
point of the storytelling exercise, as suggested by the foregoing review of
current economic articles, is to hook up logic with some significant situation
in a politically significant fashion. Or, to put the how-to process for doing law
and economics in outline form:
Since the linking of logic, situation, and moral in law and economics
storytelling/model building involves a substantial degree of creativity, it is not
possible to produce a law and economics story in the same way that one can
produce results using the formula for quadratic equations. A major premise of
CLS law and economics is that one has a high level of freedom in hooking up
logical models and salient real world situations. That freedom to choose a
particular phenomenon out of all the ones in the world to which the model
might be applicable makes hash out of any claim that the logic has now been
shown to have determinate real-world implications. The inventive researcher
trying to think of an application for the model is in effect rummaging through
a huge number of potential real-world situations, very likely without being
aware of how many she is implicitly considering and rejecting. When she finds
a phenomenon for which there is a feeling of match or fit, the connection she
draws between the logic and the phenomenon may be convincing to her and to
her readers. But she has not proven that the connection is something other than
fortuitous, and she and her readers, no matter how plausible they find the
connection, should carry more than a twinge of doubt about it, given the
0660 Critical Legal Studies 783
12. Conclusion
Abel, Richard L. (1982), A Socialist Approach to Risk, 41 Maryland Law Review, 695 ff.
Alexander, Gregory S. (1982), The Concept of Property in Private and Constitutional Law: The
Ideology of the Scientific Turn in Legal Analysis, 82 Columbia Law Review, 1545-1599.
Alexander, Gregory S. (1988), Takings, Narratives and Power, 88 Columbia Law Review, 1752 ff.
Alexander, Gregory S. (1997), Commodity and Propriety: Competing Visions of Property in
American Legal Thought, 1776-1970, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Alexander, Gregory S. (ed.) (1994), A Fourth Way?: Privatization, Property, and the Emergence of
New Market Economies, New York, Routledge.
Aoki, Keith (1993), Race, Space and Place: The Relation Between Architectual Modernism,
Post-Modernism, Urban Planning and Gentrification, 22 Fordham Urban Law Journal, 699 ff.
Audain, Linz (1992), Ctritical Legal Studies, Feminism, Law and Economics, and the Veil of
Intellectual Tolerance: A Tentative Plea for Cross-Jurisprudential Dialogue, 20 Hofstra Law
Review, 1017 ff.
Audain, Linz (1995), Critical Cultural Law and Economics, the Culture of Deindividualization, the
Paradox of Blackness, 70 Indiana Law Journal, 711 ff.
Baker, C. Edwin (1975), The Ideology of the Economic Analysis of Law, 5 Philosophy and Public
Affairs, 3-48.
Baker, Tom (1996), On the Genealogy of Moral Hazard, 75 Texas Law Review, 237-292.
Balkin, J.M. (1986), Learning Nothing and Forgetting Nothing: Richard Epstein and the Takings
Clause, 18 Urban Law, 707 ff.
Balkin, J.M. (1987), Too Good to be True: The Positive Economic Theory of Law, 87 Columbia Law
Review, 1447 ff.
Black, Kreider and Sullivan, C.L.S. (1988), Economic Realism and the Theory of the Firm, Miami.
Bratton, William W., Jr (1984), The Interpretation of Contracts Governing Corporate Debt
Relationships, 5 Cardozo Law Review, 371 ff.
Bratton, William W., Jr (1989a), Corporate Debt Relationships: Legal Theory in a Time of
Restructuring, 1989 Duke Law Journal, 92 ff.
Bratton, William W., Jr (1989b), The New Economic Theory of the Firm: Critical Perspectives from
History, 41 Stanford Law Review, 1471-1527.
Bratton, William W., Jr (1992), The Economic Structure of the Post-Contractual Corporation, 87
Northwestern Law Review, 180 ff.
Bratton, William W., Jr (1995), Game Theory and the Restoration of Honor to Corporate Laws Duty
of Loyalty, in Mitchell, Lawrence E. (ed.), Progressive Corporation Law, Boulder, Westview
Press.
Carlson, David Gray (1986), Reforming the Efficiency Criterion: Comments on Some Recent
Suggestions, 8 Cardozo Law Review, 39 ff.
Carlson, David Gray (1992), Bankruptcy Theory and the Creditors Bargain, 61 University of
Cincinnati Law Review, 453 ff.
Carlson, David Gray (1993), On the Margins of Microeconomics, 14 Cardozo Law Review, 1867 ff.
Carlson, David Gray (1994), The Politics of Article 9: On the Efficiency of Secured Lending, 80
786 Critical Legal Studies 0660
Kelman, Mark G. (1979a), Choice and Utility, Wisconsin Law Review, 769-797.
Kelman, Mark G. (1979b), Consumption Theory, Production Theory and Ideology in the Coase
Theorem, 52 Southern California Law Review, 669-698.
Kelman, Mark G. (1980), Spitzer and Hoffman on Coase: A Brief Rejoinder, 53 Southern California
Law Review, 1215-1223.
Kelman, Mark G. (1983), Misunderstanding Social Life: A Critique of the Core Premises of Law and
Economics, 33 Journal of Legal Education, 274-284.
Kelman, Mark G. (1984), Trashing, 36 Stanford Law Review, 293-348.
Kelman, Mark G. (1985), Comment on Hoffman and Spitzers Experimental Law and Economics,
85 Columbia Law Review, 1037-1047.
Kelman, Mark G. (1986), Taking Takings Seriously: An Essay for Centrists, 74 California Law
Review, 1829 ff.
Kelman, Mark G. (1987a), A Guide to Critical Legal Studies, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press.
Kelman, Mark G. (1987b), The Necessary Myth of Objective Causation Judgments in Liberal Political
Theory, 63 Chicago-Kent Law Review, 579-637.
Kelman, Mark G. (1988), On Democracy-Bashing: A Skeptical Look at the Theoretical and
Empirical Practice of the Public Choice Movement, 74 Virginia Law Review, 199-273.
Kelman, Mark G. (1991a), Concepts of Discrimination in General Ability Job Testing, 104
Harvard Law Review, 1157 ff.
Kelman, Mark G. (1991b), Emerging Centrist Liberalism, 43 Florida Law Review, 417 ff.
Kelman, Mark G. (1993), Could Lawyers Stop Recessions?: Speculations on Law and
Macroeconomics, 45 Stanford Law Review, 1215 ff.
Kennedy, David (1991), Turning to Market Democracy: A Tale of Two Architectures, 32 Harvard
International Law Journal, 373 ff.
Kennedy, David (1994), The International Style in Postwar Law and Policy: John Jackson and the
Field of International Economic Law, Utah Law Review, 7 ff.
Kennedy, Duncan (1973), Legal Formality, 2 Journal of Legal Studies, 351-398.
Kennedy, Duncan (1976), Form and Substance in Private Law Adjudication, 89 Harvard Law
Review, 1685-1778. Reprinted in Kronman, Anthony T. and Posner, Richard A. (eds), The
Economics of Contract Law, Boston, Little Brown, 1979, 100-107.
Kennedy, Duncan (1979), The Structure of Blackstones Commentaries, 28 Buffalo Law Review, 205
ff.
Kennedy, Duncan (1981a), Cost-Benefit Analysis of Entitlement Problems: A Critique, 33 Stanford
Law Review, 387-445.
Kennedy, Duncan (1981b), Cost-Reduction Theory as Legitimation, 90 Yale Law Journal,
1275-1283.
Kennedy, Duncan (1982), Distributive and Paternalist Motives in Contract and Tort Law, with Special
Reference to Compulsory Terms and Unequal Bargaining Power, 41 Maryland Law Review, 563
ff.
Kennedy, Duncan (1985), The Role of Law in Economic Thought: Essays on the Fetishism of
Commodities, 34 American University Law Review, 939 ff.
Kennedy, Duncan (1987), The Effect of the Warranty of Habitability on Low Income Housing:
Milking and Class Violence, 15 Florida State University Law Review, 485 ff.
788 Critical Legal Studies 0660
Kennedy, Duncan (1991), The Stakes of Law, or Hale and Foucault!, 15 Legal Studies, 327 ff.
Kennedy, Duncan (1992), Sexy Dressing, 26 New England Law Review, 1309 ff. Sexy Dressing,
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press (1994b)
Kennedy, Duncan (1994), Neither the Market Nor the State: Housing Privatization Issues, in
Alexander, Gregory S. (ed.), A Fourth Way?: Privatization, Property, and the Emergence of New
Market Economies, New York: Routledge.
Kennedy, Duncan and Michelman, Frank I. (1980), Are Property and Contract Efficient?, 8 Hofstra
Law Review, 711 ff.
Kennedy, Duncan and Specht, Leopold (1994), Housing Cooperatives as a Mode of Privatization, in
Alexander, Gregory S. (ed.), A Fourth Way?: Privatization, Property, and the Emergence of New
Market Economies, New York: Routledge.
Kinning, Robin (1993), Selective Housing Code Enforcement and Low-Income Housing Policy:
Minneapolis Case Study, 21 Fordham Urban Law Journal, 159 ff.
Klare, Karl (1988), Workplace Democracy and Market Reconstruction: An Agenda for Legal Reform,
38 Catholic University Law Review, 1 ff.
Kolodney, Lawrence K. (1991), Eviction Free Zones: The Economics of Legal Bricolage in the Fight
Against Displacement, 18 Fordham Urban Law Journal, 502 ff.
Levinson, Sanford (1991), Strolling Down the Path of the Law (and Toward Critical Legal Studies?):
The Jurisprudence of Richard Posner (Book Review of the Problems of Jurisprudence), 91
Columbia Law Review, 1221-1252.
McUsic, Molly (1988), Note, Reassessing Rent Control: Its Economic Impact in a Gentrifying Housing
Market, 101 Harvard Law Review, 1835 ff.
Millon, David (1990), Theories of the Corporation, Duke Law Journal, 201 ff.
Minda, Gary (1978), The Lawyer-Economist at Chicago: Richard A. Posner and the Economic
Analysis of Law, 39 Ohio State Law Journal, 439 ff.
Minda, Gary (1989), The Law and Economics and Critical Legal Studies Movement in American
Law, in Mercuro, Nicholas (ed.), Law and Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers,
87-122.
Peller, Gary (1985), The Metaphysics of American Law, 73 California Law Review, 1151 ff.
Peritz, Rudolph J. (1984), The Predicament of Antitrust Jurisprudence: Economics and the
Monopolization of Price Discrimination, Duke Law Journal, 1205-1295.
Peritz, Rudolph J. (1989), The Rule of Reason in Antitrust Law: Property Logic in Restraint of
Competition, 40 Hastings Law Journal, 285-342.
Peritz, Rudolph J. (1990), A Counter-History of Antitrust Law, Duke Law Journal, 263 ff.
Schlag, Pierre (1986), An Appreciative Comment on Coases the Problem of Social Cost: A View from
the Left, Wisconsin Law Review, 919-962.
Schlag, Pierre (1989), The Problem of Transaction Costs, 62 Southern California Law Review,
1661-1699.
Schwartzstein, Linda A. (1992), Austrian Economics and the Current Debate between Critical Legal
Studies and Law and Economics, 20 Hofstra Law Review, 1105 ff.
Singer, Joseph W. (1984), The Player and the Cards: Nihilism and Legal Theory, 94 Yale Law
Journal, 1 ff.
Spann, Girardeau A. (1988), A Critical Legal Studies Perspective on Contract Law and Practice,
Annual Survey of American Law, 223-292.
0660 Critical Legal Studies 789
Stone, Katherine Van Wezel (1991), Employees as Stakeholders Under State Nonshareholder
Constituency Statutes, 21 Stetson Law Review, 45 ff.
Trubek, David (1984), Where the Action is: Critical Legal Studies and Empiricism, 36 Stanford Law
Review, 575 ff.
Tushnet, Mark (1991), Critical Legal Studies: A Political History, 100(5) Yale Law Journal,
1515-1544.
Unger, Roberto Mangabeira (1975), Knowledge and Politics, New York, Free Press.
Van Wezel Stone, Katherine (1991), Employees as Stakeholders Under State Nonshareholder
Constituency Statutes, 21 Stetson Law Review, 45 ff.
Vracar, K. Stevan (1994), Preispitivanja pravne metodologije: Nagovestaji drzavno-pravnog
integralizma (Reexamination of the Legal Methodology: Indications of State-Legal Integralism),
Belgrade, Naucna knjiga.
West, Robin (1986), Submission, Choice, and Ethics: A Rejoinder to Judge Posner, 99 Harvard Law
Review, 1449-1456.
West, Robin (1989), Taking Preferences Seriously, Tulane.
Wilhelmsson, Thomas (ed.) (1993), Perspectives of Critical Contract Law, Aldershot, Dartmouth.
Other References
American Economic Review (1996), 86(2) (all articles).
Ayres, Ian (1990), Playing Games with the Law, 42 Stanford Law Review, 1291 ff.
Ayres, Ian and Talley, Eric (1995), Solomonic Bargaining: Dividing a Legal Entitlement to Facilitate
Coasean Trade, 104 Yale Law Journal, 1027 ff.
Calabresi, Guido (1970), The Cost of Accidents: A Legal and Economic Analysis, New Haven, CT,
Yale University Press.
Cooter, Robert (1982), The Cost of Coase, 11 Journal of Legal Studies, 1 ff.
Hovenkamp, Herbert (1992), Rationality in Law and Economics, 60 George Washington Law
Review, 293 ff.
Markovits, Richard S. (1984), Duncans Do-nots: Cost-Benefit Analysis and the Determination of
Legal Entitlements, 36 Stanford Law Review, 1169 ff.
Schor, Juliet (1991), The Overworked American, New York, Basic Books.
Posner, Richard A. (1972), The Economic Analysis of Law, Boston, Little Brown.
0710
RATIONAL CHOICE THEORY IN LAW AND
ECONOMICS
Thomas S. Ulen
Alumni Distinguished Professor of Law, College of Law, University of
Illinois at Urbana-Champaign and Professor, University of Illinois Institute
of Government and Public Affairs
Copyright 1999 Thomas S. Ulen
Abstract
The great appeal of law and economics has been its use of a coherent theory
of human decision making (rational choice theory) to examine legal rules
and institutions. While the innovations and accomplishments of that theory
in the analysis of the law have been many and important, there has been a
great deal of dissatisfaction among more traditional legal scholars with the
rational-choice foundation of law and economics. This chapter, first,
explains rational choice theory and its importance in the economic analysis
of law; second, summarizes some of the literature from economics, cognitive
psychology, and other disciplines that have been critical of rational choice
theory; and, third, speculates on the impact of those criticisms on the
economic analysis of law.
JEL classification: K00
Keywords: Rationality, Bargaining, Human Decision Making,
Methodological Criticism
1. Introduction
When law and economics was a new field in the legal curriculum and just
becoming a regular part of academic legal discourse, the use of
microeconomic theory to discuss traditional legal topics aroused interest but
also suspicion and hostility. Prominent among the reasons for this suspicion
and hostility was the feeling that the economists account of human decision
making - rational choice theory - was so deeply flawed that conclusions
derived from that account ought to be taken with a very large grain of salt, if
not rejected outright. To take one example, the economic theory of the
decision to commit a crime asserted that the potential criminal evaluated the
expected costs and expected benefits of the criminal act and committed the
crime only if the expected benefits exceeded the expected costs.
790
0710 Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics 791
Rational choice theory is at the heart of modern economic theory and in the
disciplines contiguous to economics, such as some parts of political science,
decision theory, sociology, history and law, that have adopted the theory as
their model of decision making. In this section I define rational choice, show
how it is used in economics and describe its use in other disciplines and
suggest why traditional scholars in those other disciplines find problems
with rational choice theory.
There is no widely accepted definition of rational choice theory, but there are
two important senses in which the term is used. The first is an informal
sense: choice is said to be rational when it is deliberative and consistent. The
decision maker has thought about what he or she will do and can give a
reasoned justification for the choice. And taking choices over time or
focusing on their choices about particular things, such as food or class
choices in college, one expects rationality to lead to consistent (and
relatively stable) choices. That is, one expects that there will be no wild and
inexplicable swings in the objects of their choices and that the means chosen
to effectuate the goals of the decision maker will be reasonably well-suited to
the attainment of those goals (Nozick, 1993)
792 Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics 0710
a house, there are many people who have made these purchases, so that
there is the possibility of learning from others about the pitfalls of those rare
transactions. Nonetheless, the general point bears making that market
choices are more problematic for individuals, the rarer they are. Related to
this matter is the fact that many non-market choices are so infrequent that
people do not have repeated opportunities to learn and to make corrections.
Love and marriage are examples. Even though one might consult others for
their experiences with these infrequent decisions, each individuals
circumstances with respect to many of these non-market choices are so
highly particularized that the others experiences may not be an appropriate
guide to ones own best course of action.
Second, as already noted, market choices are mediated through a
common medium - money - that makes commensurability easier. We do not
have problems of comparing apples and oranges in many market
transactions because the choices almost always involve the purchasers
giving up money. Because the purchaser knows or could know the market
price of other goods and services or can compute an opportunity cost, he or
she can make a fairly accurate estimate of the comparative worth of very
different courses of action, such as whether to purchase or lease a new car or
whether to spend another year in school or get a job. By contrast,
non-market choices usually do not involved a common measuring rod like
money. Therefore, making comparisons across non-market alternatives or
between a market and a non-market alternative may be very difficult. How
does one compare the profound experience of parenthood with the cost of an
exotic vacation?
Third, there are problems of transparency in non-market choices. Market
choices involve relatively straightforward comparisons, save when they are
complex and reserved for specialists, as in some complicated options
valuations. There is, frequently, a single best (an optimal) decision. But
many non-market choices are simply difficult to understand and have a
variety of suitable outcomes. Consider the decision of whether or not to
invite a friend to travel a long distance with one. There is no correct
answer to the question and there are lots of nuanced meanings, including
misunderstandings, that may be read into the question and its answer.
Taken together, these issues of frequency, commensurability and
transparency may suggest why rational choice theory is widely accepted as
an explanation of market choices but has difficulties in acceptance as a
model of non-market choices (Ulen, 1998).
0710 Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics 797
The most important, but not the only, characteristic of law and economics is
its use of rational choice theory to examine legal decisions. In this section I
describe the general reasons why rational choice theory may be appropriate
for the description and prediction of legal decision making and give
examples of the use of the theory in the analysis of private law rules of
contract and tort law and in the analysis of criminal law.
I shall here give only a few broad examples of rational choice theory in
private law, rather than an exhaustive survey. One particular omission
deserves mention. I shall have nothing to say about the Coase Theorem, the
most famous example of the economic analysis of law and a superb example
of rational choice theory in private law decision making, on the grounds that
this Encyclopedia covers that theorem extensively elsewhere. Here I merely
note that the bargaining behavior that the Coase Theorem posits will occur
in the absence of transaction costs precisely because the parties are rational
calculators in the manner assumed by rational choice theory.
Notwithstanding the fact that I have not discussed the Coase Theorem, in
Part C below I shall describe some criticisms of the assumptions of that
theorem and then in Part D I shall some implications for the theorem of
those criticisms. Here I shall give examples of rational choice theory as it
informs the economic analysis of contract law and tort law.
results that are difficult to reconcile with rational choice theory. The
experiments have questioned implications of that theory with regard to at
least four different areas. First, subjects in carefully-designed experiments
seem to reject mutually beneficial exchanges when they believe that the
proposed division of the cooperative surplus violates widely-accepted norms
of fairness. Rational choice theory predicts that this will not happen. Second,
subjects in another series of experiments in which there are several stages of
bargaining involved do not devise rational strategies. Third, most decision
makers have cognitive limitations that cause systematic deviations in their
behavior away from that predicted by the theory of rational choice. For
instance, those engaged in a common-value auction fall prey to the
winners curse; and people cling to the status quo, even though an
alternative likely has much greater value. Fourth, experiments have shown
that people do not make decisions about uncertain outcomes in the way that
the theory of rational choice predicts.
I shall briefly summarize some of these results in this section before
turning in Part D to a discussion of the important implications of this
literature for the rational-choice-based economic analysis of the law.
8. Rational Bargaining
Rational choice theory makes two broad claims about bargaining. One is that
whenever there is a cooperative surplus greater than the transactions costs of
splitting that surplus, parties will find a means of dividing the surplus. The
second is that there are certain situations in which people will not fully
participate in bargaining behavior, such as in the provision of and payment
for public goods. Experimental evidence questions both of these claims.
People apparently willingly cooperate in circumstances in which rational
choice theory predicts that they will not cooperate and they frequently do not
bargain in circumstances in which the theory predicts that they will.
predict that with repeated plays the rate of contribution to the group
exchange would decline (perhaps because the players would come to
understand the disadvantages of contribution and the advantages of free
riding). And that is what the experimenters found. (There is some
controversy about whether the decline is rapid or gradual, but there is
agreement that there is decline.) Were the reasons for the decline those
given by rational choice theory? Plausible as the theorys conjecture sounds,
it is not supported by the experimental results. The 40-60 percent
cooperation rate of the earlier experiment is found to hold on the first trial of
the game even for experienced players - that is, even for those players who
have participated in other multiple-play public-goods experiments in which
the contribution rate fell with repeated plays. Andreoni confirmed this
surprising result in the following way. He assembled a group to play the
public-goods experiment and announced the usual rules of the game and,
further, that the game would be played for ten trials. He found, as expected,
that the contribution rate declined over the course of those trials. At the end
of the ten trials, he announced that the same players would play the game for
an additional ten trials. When the game was re-started for the second run of
ten trials, the participation rate rose back to the 40-60 percent range before
declining again. (Andreoni, 1988)
These experimental results present a puzzle for rational choice theory:
why do people cooperate when there appears to be a rational basis for not
cooperating? One possibility is that people start any given interaction from
the presumption that it is better to cooperate than not; they continue to
cooperate until the evidence shows this to be ill-advised; and then they quit
cooperating.
effect that suggests that bargains will not necessarily take place under the
ideal conditions posited by rational choice theory. The reason is the presence
of what is called an endowment effect or status quo bias. Thaler defines
that effect as the fact that people often demand much more to give up an
object than they would be willing to pay to acquire it. (Thaler, 1992, p. 63).
The closely related status quo bias may be defined as a general preference
for the current state of holdings over any alternative (Korobkin, 1994;
Samuelson and Zeckhauser, 1988).
The endowment effect surfaced in laboratory experiments (Thaler, 1992;
Korobkin, 1998). Experimenters intent on testing propositions about
bargaining typically gave half the subjects something of value (for example,
a lottery ticket, ballpoint pens, or a coffee mug) and the other half a sum of
money. One member of each group was paired with a member of the other
group. The pairs were then given an opportunity to exchange; the roles were
then re-assigned and the participants again had an opportunity to exchange.
This reversal of roles was done a number of times with the understanding
that only one of the attempted exchanges would actually be executed by the
experimenters. The subjects were given ample opportunity to learn the rules
of the game.
The purpose of the experiments was to test two propositions about
exchange suggested by rational choice theory. First was the proposition that
when there are no impediments to exchange, goods and services will move
to those who value them the most. Because there were no impediments in
the experiments, the tickets, ballpoint pens and coffee mugs should end up
in the hands of those who valued them the most. Sometimes that would be
the subject to whom the items had been originally given and sometimes it
would be to the person to whom cash had been given. Because the
investigators did not know beforehand what the tastes and preferences of the
subjects were, their prediction was that approximately half of the pairs
would engage in an exchange.
Second was a proposition about the prices at which the exchanges would
take place. Because of the role reversals and the repetition of the possible
exchanges, each subject found herself alternately in the role of seller and
buyer of the same object. The prediction of the experimenters was that the
prices asked by subjects in their role as sellers ought to be roughly the same
as the prices bid by them in their role as buyers.
The experiments confirmed neither of these propositions. First, far fewer
transactions took place than the theory predicted - approximately half those
anticipated. Second, the prices asked by those who were willing to sell and
those bid by those who were willing to buy were not in equilibrium. The
ratio of the median selling price and the median buying price was
806 Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics 0710
The rational choice theory of decision making under uncertainty posits that
decision makers attempt to maximize their expected utility by combining
three elements: their attitudes toward risk (risk neutrality, risk preferring, or,
the most commonly-assumed attitude, risk aversion); their stable,
well-ordered preferences for the possible outcomes; and estimates of the
likelihood of the various possible outcomes. But some recent experimental
results suggest that this is not an accurate description of how many people
make decisions about uncertain outcomes.
appealing as does the axiom of transitivity, but it turns out that the
independence axiom is sometimes violated in decision making under
uncertainty (Machina, 1990). The preference-reversal phenomenon would
clearly be a violation of this axiom.
As we have seen, law and economics has premised much of its scholarship
on rational choice theory. Therefore, the implications of the literature
critical of that theory for law and economics are profound. In this part I want
to focus on four of those implications - on the relationship between
transactions costs and the law, on the choice between mandatory and default
rules in the law, on the best means of dealing with risky decisions by
consumers and on some issues in tort law.
810 Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics 0710
The most famous piece of scholarship in law and economics is The Problem
of Social Cost by Professor Ronald Coase (1960). The broad inquiry to
which that article is addressed is this: when may society rely upon
bargaining to achieve the efficient use of resources and when may it not?
That inquiry then leads to a discussion of how the law should be structured
so as to encourage efficient resource use in those circumstances in which it
is inappropriate to rely upon bargaining. The Coase Theorem says that when
there are no impediments to exchange (that is, when transaction costs are
zero), the efficient use of resources will result, regardless of the assignment
of property rights. Appropriate legal policy depends on being able to identify
impediments to exchange and to specify correctives when those impediments
are significant. Law and economics scholarship has concentrated on search,
bargaining and enforcement costs as the elements of transaction costs and
has sought to identify the objective characteristics of transactions (for
example, the number of people involved, whether the transaction is for a
fungible or a unique item and so on) that cause these three elements of the
costs of exchange to be high.
The literature reported in Section 8 has two important implications for
the standard view of the Coase Theorem. First, the reported results on
cooperation and fairness suggest that people are far more ready to cooperate
and that they have a much stronger sense of what is an equitable outcome
than rational choice theory predicts. These conclusions point in two very
different directions on the Coase Theorem. On the one hand, the broad
willingness to cooperate (as revealed in the public goods experiments)
suggests that voluntary exchange may be able to achieve an efficient
allocation in a broader range of circumstances than those of zero transaction
costs and, further, that the need to intervene in private decision making to
enhance efficiency, even when transaction costs are positive and significant,
may be less than previously thought. For example, if people appear to be
more willing to contribute to the provision of public goods than rational
choice theory predicts, then there may be less need for the compulsory public
subsidization of those goods or the level of subsidization can be less
extensive. There are implications, too, regarding the need for or the most
appropriate structure of environmental regulations - for example, people
may be more willing to bestow the external benefits of
environmentally-conscious activity than previously supposed.
On the other hand, the finding of the experimental literature that people
appear to be extremely sensitive to the equitable distribution of resources
suggests that more intervention in private decision making may be justifiable
than previously thought. This is because the experiments suggest that people
0710 Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics 811
may be so sensitive to fairness issues that they would rather not cooperate
than cooperate on terms that they consider to be excessively one-sided. This
is a cause for the failure of bargaining that has not heretofore been given
much weight. Even when transaction costs are very low, some otherwise
efficient exchanges will not take place because some of the participants do
not like the proposed division of the cooperative surplus. The experimental
findings provide an efficiency justification for legal intervention in private
decision making in order to prevent over-reaching by one of the parties that
might forestall an otherwise efficiency-enhancing exchange.
The second major implication for the Coase Theorem of the criticisms
reported in Section 8 arises from the endowment effect (or status quo bias).
Recall that that effect suggested two anomalies in bargaining behavior: first,
when transaction costs were very low, people were far more reluctant to
transact than rational choice theory predicted and, second, subjects typically
demanded twice as much to sell something they owned as they were willing
to pay in order to acquire it. The troubling implication of those findings is
that there may be cases in which there is no such thing as a uniquely
efficient assignment of rights. Where society initially assigns an entitlement
is where it is likely to remain; we should be far less sanguine about
entitlements moving to their highest-valued use, even when transaction costs
are zero, than we have been heretofore. (Indeed, status quo bias makes the
notion of highest valuing use less clear.)
11. Default and Mandatory Rules and the Criticisms of Rational Choice
Theory
If one assumes, as does law and economics, that the law can increase the
efficient use of resources by creating rules of conduct that correct for market
failures, two issues that must be resolved are, first, the specification of a rule
or standard and, second, whether that rule or standard is mandatory or may
be waived by those affected. One of the areas of the law in which this issue
has been central is corporation law. There the debate has been between those
who favor non-waivable mandatory rules of corporate conduct and those
who favor allowing corporations to opt out of some rules. Consider, for
example, insider trading. Everyone admits that there are potential
inefficiencies from allowing insider trading, although there are
disagreements about the extent and likelihood of these inefficiencies. Most
commentators, therefore, agree that there ought to be some legal regulation
of the practice. However, there is disagreement about whether this regulation
should take the form of a prohibition or merely a default rule from which
those corporations that so choose might wish to opt out. Those who favor
812 Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics 0710
making the prohibition waivable argue that some corporations might wish to
offer their managers partial compensation in the form of allowing them to
trade on the basis of the inside information that they acquire in the course of
working for the corporation. If that method of compensation is more
efficient than the alternatives, then, the argument goes, those corporations
and their managers ought to be allowed to opt out of the default rule. The
other side argues that both private and public difficulties in policing the
behavior of managers make the realization of those efficiencies illusory.
Thus, they argue, the prohibition of insider trading should be non-waivable.
How are the findings of Part C relevant to this issue? Status-quo bias
suggests that people will not make changes away from a default position
unless the expected benefits from so doing substantially exceed the expected
costs. That is, the default position has a strong anchoring effect. With
respect to insider trading rules, the presence of status-quo bias might
indicate that even if the prohibition on insider trading was waivable, very
few corporations would take advantage of that waivability.
There is another relevant implication of status-quo bias. If most people
are reluctant to leave the status quo, whatever that is, then the law ought to
establish the starting position (that is, establish the status quo) at an efficient
point. In the case of insider trading that might suggest that the appropriate
starting point is a prohibition of the practice, not the freedom to engage in
the practice unless ones employer has forbidden it. This sort of
consideration no doubt has other applications in the law well beyond
corporation law. For instance, it may say something about whether society
should make the status quo one in which addictive drugs are legal or one in
which they are illegal but one may (explicitly or implicitly) opt out of this
illegality. (For the implications of status quo bias for a broad range of
contract issues, see Korobkin, 1998.)
The regulation of risk is a topic upon which there is very large and growing
literature and about which there is a surprising lack of consensus. Many are
convinced that the panoply of regulations dealing with risky behavior is not
well conceived and the criticisms of rational choice under uncertainty
contribute to an understanding of this position. Recall that, broadly
speaking, people do not seem to do a very good job of appraising risky
outcomes. For example, they tend to overestimate the value of
low-probability, high-payoff gambles. And because of status-quo bias, they
prefer a known, high risk to an unknown, low risk. These imperfections in
the way people deal with risk may motivate them to demand legislative
regulation of risk that reflects their own, not entirely coherent, views. For
0710 Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics 813
example, on an average day in the United States 30 people are killed on the
job, 56 are killed in accidents in the home, 133 die in automobile accidents
and 4,000 die from cancer. Of those who die each day from cancer, 30
percent of those deaths are attributable to tobacco; 4 percent are attributable
to cancers arising from occupational hazards; 1 percent to medical
treatment; and 2 percent to air and water pollution (Breyer, 1993). All other
things equal, these figures would suggest two predictions about current
regulations designed to minimize the harms from risky activities: first, that a
large amount of effort ought to be directed at reducing the risk of cancer and
second, that a large portion of the cancer-reducing effort ought to be directed
at tobacco-related cancers. Neither prediction is correct. Rather, the risk
regulation of the United States government has a willy-nilly aspect with
little rational regard for the value of the good it might be doing. For
instance, there is no single implicit value of a life saved that is used by the
federal government in regulating risk. Rather, the governments regulations
imply that the value of a life saved ranges from $10,000 to $1 billion
(Viscusi, 1992).
Just bringing coherence to risk regulation would be a substantial
improvement in the efficient allocation of governmental resources. But the
experiments on decision making under uncertainty described in Section 8
suggest an important new way of looking at the regulation of risk.
Heretofore, much government risk regulation has been premised on the
belief that individuals make errors in dealing with risk because they do not
have correct information. If they had that information, they would make the
appropriate maximizing decision. Thus, the governments role ought
principally to be to disseminate accurate information to assist individuals
and organizations in their decision making. But the material on
intertemporal choice in Part C suggests that even if they had the appropriate
information, some people would not make the right decision about risky
activities.
How these insights should translate into a reform of risk regulation is a
very broad issue. Here I want only to suggest that they might lead to
principled justifications for far more paternalistic policies than those that
rational choice theory typically recommends. For instance, where rational
choice theory might suggest that the comparison of the costs and benefits of
wearing motorcycle helmets ought to be left to motorcyclists so long as they
are well-informed about the true costs and benefits, the findings about
mistakes in intertemporal choice and in the assessment of risk imply that
motorcyclists will always underestimate the benefits of wearing helmets and
that, therefore, the best regulation for minimizing head injuries among
motorcyclists may be one mandating helmet-wearing. These are significant
differences in policy and we must wait on further empirical work to clarify
the extent of the cognitive errors and the various policy choices before us.
814 Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics 0710
13.1 The Choice Between Statutory Regulation and the Risk-Utility Test
There are two important points to be made about the efficiency of negligence
and of strict liability. First, within negligence there are two very different
means of determining whether someone had complied with a legal duty of
care. In one set of circumstances compliance is determined by comparing the
victims or injurers actions with a clear rule - for example, a speed limit or
manufacturing standard proposed by an administrative agency (or possibly
by some respected private standard-setting group). This sort of negligence
(negligence per se) is relatively easy for the court to determine and easy for
potential injurers and victims to perceive and to follow. No sophisticated
calculations are required and, therefore, the demands on the cognitive
abilities of the potential victim and injurer are not large.
The other, more common form of negligence delegates to potential
injurers and potential victims the determination of the appropriate amount of
care to take. There is no hard-and-fast rule specifying the suitable amount of
precaution; rather, each potential victim and potential injurer calculates
what is appropriate in the understanding that, in the event of an accident, a
court may check those calculations to see if they have been done reasonably.
This standard of due care is frequently determined according to a
risk-utility test or the Hand Test. The court assumes that the parties who
may injure or be injured compare the costs of precaution with the benefits of
0710 Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics 815
any non-obvious dangers; consumers can reduce the expected social costs of
accidents by taking care in the use of the product, by following the
manufacturers instructions, by using the product in a manner that it was
intended that it be used and so on. But suppose that we make one more
assumption - namely, that producers have much greater facility in making
decisions about uncertain outcomes than do consumer because consumers
are prone to the sort of miscalculations that we noted in Part C. We might
now doubt that precaution is truly bilateral. Perfectly rational consumers
might be able to calculate the appropriate level of risk and the expected level
of accident costs, given different levels of precaution, but these are not, by
assumption, perfectly rational consumers. They will make errors;
importantly, they will make more and more costly errors than will
producers. If so, then a situation that assumed the affected parties to be
rational and that precaution was bilateral becomes one in which only one of
the parties is reliably rational and there is, therefore, unilateral precaution.
This makes out an argument for treating at least some product-related
accidents under the strict liability rule. To put the point more generally, I am
suggesting that the recognition that there may be cognitive limitations
among potential victims and injurers should alter the search for the
appropriate liability standard from one in which the law looks for the
least-cost avoider to one in which the law looks for the least-cost decision
maker or least irrational party.
14. Conclusion
We have seen how important rational choice theory is to law and economics.
But we have also seen that there is an increasing body of experimental work
that questions some of the assumptions of that theory. We must amend the
rational-choice model, but precisely how we should amend the model is not
yet clear. I want to conclude with a cautionary statement about the crucial
questions that must be addressed in undertaking these emendations in
rational choice theory and in drawing conclusions about law on the basis of
these emendations.
Some may mistakenly think that we are put to a stark choice between, on
the one hand, rational choice theory and, on the other hand, the extreme
position that no coherent theory of human decision making is possible. That
is a dangerous illusion. A synthesis is possible and is, I believe, coming. But
it is not yet here and until it is, we must remain uncomfortably in the middle
- somewhat skeptical about rational choice theory but not so skeptical that
we abandon that theory. To see the dangers of moving too far, too fast in the
application of Part Cs findings, consider the experiments that suggest that
cooperation in the provision of a public good is much more likely than
0710 Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics 817
rational choice theory predicts. This is, so far, merely suggestive; it is not a
complete guide to behavior. Therefore, no one could responsibly use these
experiments as a warrant for cutting the public subsidies for basic research
and public television or for laxer enforcement of the intellectual property
laws. Before we make policy pronouncements on the basis of these
anomalies, we need to know much more. The implication of some of the
experimenters is that their findings apply to all decision makers in all
circumstances. But that seems highly unlikely. Surely there are important
differences among circumstances and among people. There may be some
people who always obey the predictions of rational choice theory; there may
be some circumstances in which no one obeys those predictions. And there
may be more subtle differences. For example, are there systematic
differences in the dispensation to cooperate by age and gender? Are there
objective circumstances about the manner in which the cooperation is
solicited (for example, how long the people have known each other and
whether they are allowed to communicate) that lead to a greater likelihood
of cooperation? How robust is the finding that repeated playing leads to a
diminution of the propensity to cooperate? These and many more questions
need to be addressed.
Some day, perhaps soon, we shall have a complete account of human
decision making than that provided by rational choice theory. And when we
do, that account will greatly enhance our understanding of the law and our
ability to draft the law for desirable ends.
Acknowledgements
The author would like to thank an anonymous referee for helpful comments.
Andreoni, James (1988), Why Free Ride? Strategies and Learning in Public Goods Experiments,
38 Journal of Public Economics, 291-305.
Becker, Gary (1962), Irrational Behavior and Economic Theory, 70 Journal of Political
Economy, 1-13.
Becker, Gary (1968) Crime and Punishment: an Economic Approach, 76 Journal of Political
Economy, 169-217.
Breyer, Stephen (1993), Breaking the Vicious Circle, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Coase, Ronald A. (1960), The Problem of Social Cost, 3 Journal of Law and Economics, 1-28.
818 Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics 0710
Cooter, Robert D. and Ulen, Thomas S. (1997), Law and Economics, (2nd edn), Reading, MA,
Addison-Wesley-Longman.
Dixit, Avinash and Nalebuff, Barry (1991), Thinking Strategically, New York, W.W. Norton &
Co.
Grether, David and Plott, Charles (1979), Economic Theory of Choice and the Preference Reversal
Phenomenon, 69 American Economic Review, 623-638.
Guth, Werner, Schmittberger, Rolf and Schwarze, Bernd (1982), An Experimental Analysis of
Ultimatum Bargaining, 3 Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 367- 383.
Kahneman, Daniel, Knetsch, Jack and Thaler, Richard (1986), Fairness as a Constraint on Profit
Seeking: Entitlements in the Market, 76 American Economic Review, 728-741.
Korobkin, Russell (1994), Policymaking and the Offer/Ask Price Gap: Toward a Theory of
Efficient Entitlement Allocation, 46 Stanford Law Review, 663-708.
Korobkin, Russell (1998), The Status Quo Bias and Contract Default Rules, 83 Cornell Law
Review, 608-687.
Lichtenstein, Sarah and Slovic, Paul (1971), Reversals of Preference between Bids and Choices in
Gambling Decisions, 89 Journal of Experimental Psychology, 46-61.
Liebenstein, Harvey (1950), Bandwagon, Snob and Veblen Effects in the Theory of Consumers
Demand, 64 Quarterly Journal of Economics, 183-201.
Loewenstein, George and Elster, John (eds) (1992), Choice Over Time, New York, Russell Sage
Foundation.
Machina, Mark (1990), Expected Utility Hypothesis, in John Eatwell, Milgate, Murray and
Newman, Peter (eds), The New Palgrave: Utility and Probability, London, Macmillan
Publishing.
Marwell, Gerald and Ames, Ruth (1981), Economists Free Ride, Does Anyone Else?, 15 Journal
of Public Economics, 295-310.
Nozick, Robert (1993), The Nature of Rationality, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Plous, Scott (1993), The Psychology of Judgment and Decision Making, New York,
McGraw-Hill.
Posner, Richard A. (1998), Economic Analysis of Law, (4th edn), Boston, MA, Aspen Publishing
Co.
Samuelson, William and Zeckhauser, Richard (1988), Status Quo Bias in Decision Making, 1
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 7-17.
Shefrin, Hersh and Thaler, Richard (1988), The Behavioral Life-cycle Hypothesis, 26 Economic
Inquiry, 609-643.
Thaler, Richard (1992), The Winners Curse, New York, W.W. Norton & Co.
Ulen, Thomas S. (1994), Rational Choice Theory and the Economic Analysis of Law, 19 Law and
Social Inquiry, 487-522.
Ulen, Thomas S. (1998), The Growing Pains of Behavioral Law and Economics, Vanderbilt Law
Review (forthcoming).
Viscusi, W. Kip (1992), Fatal Tradeoffs: Public and Private Responsibilities for Risk, New York,
Oxford University Press.
Wilson, James Q. and Abrahamse, Alan (1992), Does Crime Pay?, 9 Justice Quarterly, 359-377.
0720
THE ENDOWMENT EFFECT
Christopher Curran
Associate Professor, Emory University
Copyright 1999 Christopher Curran
Abstract
This chapter reviews the literature on the endowment effect that challenges the
validity of using neoclassical economic theory to evaluate legal issues. While
a consensus does not yet exist, much of the research suggests that the
endowment effect phenomena does not offer as much of a challenge to
neoclassical economic theory as was once thought.
JEL classification: D0, D6
Keywords: Endowment Effect, Experimental Economics
1. Introduction
This essay discusses the issue of whether the results of recent experimental
research on consumer behavior undermines the conclusions of neoclassical
economics enough to render arguments based on that theory incorrect. This
entry is not a thorough review of the rich experimental economics literature
(see Kahneman, Knetsch and Thaler, 1991) for summary of much of this
research and Conlisk, 1996, for a statement of the case for using the notion of
bounded rationality in economics). Instead, we focus on the possibility that the
phenomena known as the endowment effect may provide evidence that
questions the applicability of some of the basic assumptions made by
economists about consumer rationality. After describing the endowment effect
and some of the theories used to take account of this effect, we recount how
some law and economics scholars use the endowment effect in their analyses.
The endowment effect arises when consumers willingness to accept (WTA) for
a good is greater than their willingness to pay (WTP) for it. While economists
have long recognized that an income effect may make cause the WTA to be
819
820 The Endowment Effect 0720
greater than the WTP, they accepted the conclusion by Willig (1976) that these
differences should be small. While psychologists had noted a difference
between the WTP and WTA as early as the 1960s (see Coombs, Bezembinder,
and Goode, 1967, and Slovic and Lichtenstein, 1968), economists only began
to focus on the issue after observing this difference when using surveys to
measure the value of environmental projects. When the economists asked
consumers about both their WTP and their WTA in these surveys, they found
that the reported WTA is much larger than the reported WTP - much larger
than Willigs predictions suggest. Using students as subjects and goods such as
coffee mugs, candy bars and trees as the commodities, experimental economists
have been able to find evidence that their subjects often have a WTA that is
substantially greater than their WTP (see, for example, Bishop, Heberlein and
Kealy, 1983; Knetsch, 1984; Knetsch and Borcherding, 1979; Knetsch and
Sinden, 1984; Brookshire and Coursey, 1987; Samuelson and Zeckhauser,
1988; Quattrone and Tversky, 1988; Donohue, 1989; Harless, 1989; Knetsch,
1989; Kahneman, Knetsch and Thaler, 1990; Ortona and Scacciati, 1992;
Boyce et al., 1992; Shogren et al., 1994; Loewenstein and Adler, 1995; Sileo,
1995; Pratt and Zeckhauser, 1996, for evidence about, explanations of and
implications of the endowment effect; Hoffman and Spitzer, 1993, offer an
excellent summary of the results of both the empirical and theoretical research).
The formats used these experiments follow a regular pattern. The experimental
researchers randomly split the subjects into two groups. They give each of the
members of one group some object - say a coffee mug or a candy bar - and then
offer to buy the object back from them using some truth-revealing mechanism.
The researchers then give the members of the other group money and then
allow the subjects to purchase the object offered to the first group, again using
a truth-revealing mechanism. (There are a large number of variations on the
structure of the various experiments; see these studies or Hoffman and Spitzer,
1993, for more details of the different experiments.) The researchers report
potentially conflicting evidence indicating (1) that the endowment effect is
persistent and substantive, (2) that the endowment effect, while evident
initially, tends to disappear over time and (3) that there is no difference in the
WTP and the WTA.
0720 The Endowment Effect 821
Studies that find evidence of the endowment effect suggest that consumers may
have a greater preference for the status quo than what the assumption of
rationality implies. Several criticisms have been leveled at the studies that find
evidence of an endowment effect. For instance, some authors reject the use of
hypothetical questions and experiments involving small amounts of money as
revealing little about a subjects actual behavior in the market place (see
Hoffman and Spitzer, 1993, p. 69, n. 23). Other authors question whether the
subjects really understand what they are being asked and whether the effect will
remain after repeated experiments. Unfortunately, the evidence on these points
is mixed; while some studies find evidence that the WTP is equal to the WTA
in experiments involving simple securities (see Kahneman, Knetsch and
Thaler, 1990, pp. 1329-1330; Harless, 1989), other studies reach the opposite
conclusion for simple securities (see, for instance, Knez, Smith and Williams,
1985) and for more complicated securities involving risk (see, for instance,
McClelland and Schulze, 1991).
5. Prospect Theory
Figure 1
The Value Function Proposed in Prospect Theory
Figure 2 illustrates how prospect theory might explain the endowment effect.
We start with an individual owning quantity A of some good and ask how
much he would be willing to pay to acquire the larger quantity B. Thus, the
vertical distance between points D and C represents the WTP of this individual
to acquire (B - A) units of the good. Now we compare this situation with the
case where the individual already owns B units of the goods and is offered the
opportunity to sell (B - A) units of the good. Since the individual actually owns
B units of the good, we begin at point E (shown in this case to be valued higher
than when the individual did not actually own the good, though it is not
necessarily of higher value) and move to point F. Thus, the vertical distance
between E and F is the individuals WTA, which in this case is greater than his
WTP. The key point is that potential losses have a greater impact on the
individuals value than do potential gains.
some good X and wealth. Consider an individuals WTP to move from point
A where he has X0 of good X to point B where he has the same wealth and X1
of good X.
Figure 2
A Prospect Theory Explanation of the Endowment Effect
Since the individual is indifferent between being at point A and point C, the
vertical distance between points B and C measures how much this individual
is willing to pay to move to point B. Now consider how much this individual
is willing to accept to move from point B to point A. Since the individual is
indifferent between being at points B and D, the vertical distance between A
and D measures his willingness to accept the move from point B to A. Figure
3 shows the case where the individuals WTA is greater than his WTP. As
Hanemann (1991) proves, the size of this difference depends on the elasticity
of substitution of the indifference curves - the more inelastic the indifference
curves are, the larger is the spread between the WTA and the WTP. Put another
way, the less substitutable a good is with money, the larger will be the
endowment effect. More importantly, if Hanemanns hypothesis is correct, the
endowment effect observed by experimental economists does not imply that the
neoclassical analysis of welfare economics is fatally flawed. Shogren et al.
(1994) report the results of experiments that lend support to Hanemanns
hypothesis.
824 The Endowment Effect 0720
Scholars in law and economics have given the endowment effect a mixed
reception. Some authors such as Knetsch and Borcherding (1979), Hovenkamp
(1991), Hoffman and Spitzer (1993) and Fischel (1995) accept the endowment
effect as a real phenomena with serious implications for the study of legal
issues while others such as Curran and Rubin (1995), while analyzing the
implications of the endowment effect, seem to doubt its existence. A majority
of legal scholars ignore the existence of an endowment effect.
Hovenkamp (1991) claims that the endowment effect has very significant
implications for the study of law and economics because it potentially
undermines the validity of traditional results from welfare economics. As
Hovenkamp argues, the equality of WTP and WTA is central to the
construction
of demand curves, the estimation of consumers surplus, the use of cost-benefits
analyses and the use of indifference curves. He carries the argument further
when he suggests that, when the endowment effect exists, the person has no
indifference curve. (Hovenkamp, 1991, p. 226). Thus, he concludes that an
endowment effect that is substantial and ubiquitous could make [the tools of
welfare economics] virtually useless. (Hovenkamp, 1991, p. 227).
Figure 3
Hanemanns Explanation of the Endowment Effect
0720 The Endowment Effect 825
One of the practical difficulties of using WTA as a measure of value when the
WTA and WTP measures differ is the fact that no one ever observes WTA.
Clearly, market prices are an accurate measure of the WTP of the purchaser
and the WTA of the seller; they provide little information about the buyers
WTA once he is the owner. This measurement problem is especially important
in thin markets where there are few substitutes for the good or where a good
cannot be bought and sold. A piece of land that has sentimental value for the
current owner is an example of a good with few substitutes while environmental
goods like clear air and water are examples of goods that have no recognizable
markets. Hovenkamp (1991, pp. 238-243) recognizes this difficulty with using
WTA as a measure of value. He suggests, however, the fact that economic
theory offers policymakers little aid in measuring WTA does not mean that they
cannot use the concept. He suggests that policymakers should turn to
psychologists and sociologists for aid in measuring WTA. Researchers in these
fields, Hovenkamp contends, have many tools - surveys, questionnaires,
interviews and tests - that would help in the measurement of WTA. Gathering
this information is costly. When costs become prohibitive, Hovenkamp suggests
that policymakers resort to generalizations. As an example of such a
generalization, Hovenkamp (1991, p. 243) suggests the fact that biological
organisms have a common set of survival needs and perhaps a common set of
minimal needs for social productivity implies that policymakers can assume
that goods such as these have a WTA that is systematically greater than their
WTP. Economists aware of the problems of rent-seeking common to
governments - and well-documented in the public choice literature - probably
will not share Hovenkamps faith in the ability of policymakers to correctly
identify what goods belong to the common set of survival needs.
The fact that Hovenkamp rejects neoclassical economic theory presents him
with a logical problem - what, if any, parts of the economic model can he use
in his analysis? Clearly, Hovenkamp offers a theory that purports to
differentiate among the various Pareto optimal points. However, Hovenkamp
(1991, p. 230) does not explain what he means by Pareto optimality in a
world where indifference curves do not exist. Hovenkamp does not resolve this
logical problem by constructing a completely new model of human behavior to
replace the neoclassical economic model. Instead, he assumes that consumers
WTA is larger than their WTP and then borrows concepts from the neoclassical
model when he needs them. While Curran and Rubin (1995) temper their
0720 The Endowment Effect 827
analysis with expressions of concern, they also mix the results of neoclassical
welfare economics in their criticism of Hovenkamp (for which Fischel, 1995,
p. 200, criticizes them).
Many may not find Fischels assurances that the members of the various
constitutional conventions considered and correctly solved the WTP/WTA
disparity issue satisfactorily. The dilemma facing society is that in deciding
whether to pursue a project, policymakers need to determine if the project is
potentially Pareto improving. To make this determination, they have to estimate
the costs of the project where these costs include the losses in value sustained
by property owners affected by the project. Currently, in the United States
courts use the market value of the property - that is, the WTP - plus some
amount to cover any losses to the owner due to inconvenience. The advantage
of using the WTP is that it is generally inexpensive to measure and avoids the
828 The Endowment Effect 0720
18. Conclusion
would seem rash to toss out all of neoclassical economic theory based solely on
the evidence offered by the endowment effect.
Alchian, Armen A. (1953), The Meaning of Utility Measurement, 43 American Economic Review,
26 ff.
Armentano, Dominick T. (1987), Comment: Efficiency, Liberty and Antitrust Policy, in Dorn, James
A. and Manne, Henry G. (eds), Economic Liberties and the Judiciary, Fairfax, George Mason
University Press, 309-316.
Baker, C. Edwin (1978), Counting Preferences in Collective Choice Situations, 25 UCLA Law
Review.
Beavis, Brian and Rowley, Charles K. (1983), Evaluating Choice: A Note, 3 International Review
of Law and Economics, 79-83.
Bishop, Richard, Heberlein, Thomas and Kealy, Mary Jo (1983), Contingent Valuation of
Environmental Assets: Comparisons with a Simulated Market, 23 Natural Resources Journal,
619-648.
Boyce, Rebecca R., Brown, Thomas C., McClelland, Gary H., Peterson, George L. and Schulze,
William D. (1992), An Experimental Examination of Intrinsic Values as a Source of the
WTA-WTP Disparity, 82 American Economic Review, 1366-1373.
Brinig, Margaret F. and Crafton, Steven M. (1994), Marriage and Opportunism, 23 Journal of Legal
Studies, 869-894.
Bromley, Daniel W. (1990), The Ideology of Efficiency: Searching for a Theory of Policy Analysis,
19 Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 86-107.
Brookshire, David S. and Coursey, Don L. (1987), Measuring the Value of a Public Good: An
Empirical Comparison of Elicitation Procedures, 77 American Economic Review, 554-566.
Bruce, Christopher J. (1984), Testing the Hypothesis of Common Law Efficiency: The Doctrine of
Informed Consent, 6 Research in Law and Economics, 227-265.
Buchanan, James M. (1962), The Relevance of Pareto Optimality, 6 Journal of Conflict Resolution,
341-354.
Calabresi, Guido (1991), The Pointlessness of Pareto: Carrying Coase Further, 100 Yale Law
Journal, 1211-1237.
Centi, Jean-Pierre (1987), Quel critre defficience pour lanalyse conomique du droit (Which
Efficiency Criterion for Economic Analysis of Law), 2 Revue de la Recherche Juridique.
Coleman, Jules L. (1980), Efficiency, Exchange and Auction: Philosophic Aspects of the Economic
Approach to Law, 68 California Law Review, 221-249.
Coleman, Jules L. (1980), Efficiency, Utility and Wealth Maximization, 8 Hofstra Law Review,
509-551.
Coombs, C.H., Bezembinder, T.G. and Goode, F.M. (1967), Testing Expectation Theories of Decision
Making without Measuring Utility or Subjective Probability, 4 Journal of Mathematical
Psychology, 72-103.
Cooter, Robert D. (1989), The Best Right Laws: Value Foundations of the Economic Analysis of
Law, in Levit, Nancy and Hayman, Robert (eds), Jurisprudence: Contemporary Readings,
Problems and Narratives, St Pauls, West, 1994.
830 The Endowment Effect 0720
Cotter, Thomas F. (1996), Legal Pragmatism and the Law and Economics Movement, 84
Georgetown Law Journal, 2071-2141.
Curran, Christophe and Rubin, Paul H. (1995), The Endowment Effect and Income Transfers, 17
Research in Law and Economics, 207-217.
Demsetz, Harold (1969), Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint, 12 Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-22.
Dnes, Anthony W. (1984), Joint Production, National Income Definitions and Pricing in Linear
Environmental Models, 18(4) Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 247-253.
Dobbs, I. (1981), Externality, Efficiency and the Pareto Principle, 1 International Review of Law and
Economics, 167-181.
Egger, J.B. (1979), Efficiency is not a Substitute for Ethics, in Rizzo, Mario J. (ed.), Time,
Uncertainty and Disequilibrium, Lexington, MA, Lexington Books, 117-125.
Fischel, William A. (1991), Exploring the Kozinski Paradox: Why is More Efficient Regulation a
Taking of Property?, 67(3) Chicago-Kent Law Review, 865-912.
Fischel, William A. (1995), The Offer/Ask Disparity and Just Compensation for Takings: A
Constitutional Choice Perspective, 15 International Review of Law and Economics, 187-203.
Fischel, William A. and Shapiro, Perry (1988), Takings, Insurance and Michelman: Comments on
Economic Interpretations of Just Compensation Law, 17 Journal of Legal Studies, 269-293.
Reprinted in Ellickson, Robert; Rose, Carol and Ackerman, Bruce (eds), Perspectives on Property
Law, 2nd edn, 514-530, Boston, Little Brown, 1995.
Friedman, David D. (1988), Does Altruism Produce Efficient Outcomes? Marshall versus Kaldor, 17
Journal of Legal Studies, 1-13.
Frisch, R. (1959), On Welfare Theory and Pareto Regions, 9 International Economic Review, 39-92.
Gaertner, W. and Pattanaik, P.K. (eds) (1988), Distributive Justice and Inequality: A Selection of
Papers Given at a Conference, Berlin May 1986, New York, Springer.
Gantner, Manfred (1993), Anmerkungen zur Universittsreform aus finanzwissenschaflticher Sicht
(Notes on Reforming Universities from a Public Finance Perspective), in Strasser, R. (ed.),
Beitrge zum Universittsrecht, Vienna, 119-139.
Gilson, Ronald J. and Kraakman, Reinier H. (1984), The Mechanisms of Market Efficiency, 70
Virginia Law Review, 549-644.
Glasner, David (1982), On the Difference Between Wealth and Liberty, 2 International Review of
Law and Economics, 227-233.
Goldberg, Victor P. (1984), Readings in the Economics of Contract Law, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press. Reprinted in Feiwel, George (ed.), Issues in Contemporary Microeconomics,
Macmillan Press, 395-402.
Grant, Robin F. (1989), Judge Richard Posners Wealth Maximization Principle: Another Form of
Utilitarianism?, 10 Cardozo Law Review, 815-845.
Hammond (1982), The Economics of Justice and the Criterion of Wealth Maximization (Book
Review), 91 Yale Law Journal, 1493-1507.
Hanemann, W. Michael (1991), Willingness to Pay and Willingness to Accept: How Much Can They
Differ?, 81 American Economic Review, 635-647.
Hanks, John L. (1986), On a Just Measure of the Efficiency of Law and Governmental Politics, 8
Cardozo Law Review, 1-38.
0720 The Endowment Effect 831
Harless, David W. (1989), More Laboratory Evidence on the Disparity Between Willingness to Pay
and Compensation Demanded, 11 Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 359-379.
Hayashida, Seimei (1991), Koritsusei tai Ihosei: Minji Iho no Keizairiron (Efficiency vs.
Unlawfulness: An Economic Theory of the Unlawfulness in the Civil Law in Japan), 41 Hokudai
Hogaku Ronshu (Hokkaido Law Review), 1364-1450.
Heiner, Ronald A. (1983), The Origin of Predictable Behavior, 73 American Economic Review,
560-595.
Hochman, Harold M. and Peterson, George E. (eds) (1974), Redistribution through Public Choice,
New York, Columbia University Press.
Hoffman, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1993), Willingness to Pay vs. Willingness to Accept:
Legal and Economic Implications, 71 Washington University Law Quarterly, 59-114.
Hovenkamp, Herbert J. (1990a), Exchange on Public Choice, 57 University of Chicago Law Review,
840-843.
Hovenkamp, Herbert J. (1990b), Legislation, Well-Being and Public Choice, 57 University of
Chicago Law Review, 63-116.
Hovenkamp, Herbert J. (1991), Legal Policy and the Endowment Effect,20 Journal of Legal Studies,
225-247.
Johnsen, D. Bruce (1986), Wealth is Value, 15 Journal of Legal Studies, 263-288.
Jones, Peter and Sugden, Robert (1982), Evaluating Choice, 2 International Review of Law and
Economics, 47-65.
Jones, Peter and Sugden, Robert (1983), Evaluating Choice: A Reply, 3 International Review of Law
and Economics, 85-87.
Juhnjuhnwala, Bharat (1974), Kaldor-Hicks-Scitovsky Criteria: A Postmortem, 40 Southern
Economic Journal, 493-496.
Kahan, Marcel (1992), Securities Laws and the Social Costs of Inaccurate Stock Prices , Duke Law
Journal, 977-1044.
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos (1979), Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under
Risk, 47 Econometrica, 263-291.
Kahneman, Daniel, Knetsch, Jack and Thaler, Richard H. (1990), Experimental Tests of the
Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem, 98 Journal of Political Economy, 1325-1348.
Kahneman, Daniel, Knetsch, Jack and Thaler, Richard H. (1991), Anomalies: The Endowment Effect,
Loss Aversion and Status Quo Bias, 5 Journal of Economic Perspectives, 193-206.
Kaldor, N. (1939), Welfare Propositions of Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility, 49
Economic Journal, 549-552.
Keenan, Donald C. (1981), Value Maximization and Welfare Theory, 10 Journal of Legal Studies,
409-419.
Kennedy, Duncan (1981), Cost-Benefit of Entitlement Problems: A Critique, 33 Stanford Law
Review, 387-445.
Kirchner, Christian (1991), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin, Springer-Verlag.
Knetsch, Jack L. (1984), Legal Rules and the Basis for Evaluating Economic Losses, 4 International
Review of Law and Economics, 5-13.
Knetsch, Jack L. (1989), The Endowment Effect and Evidence of Nonreversible Indifference Curves,
79 American Economic Review, 1277-1284.
832 The Endowment Effect 0720
Knetsch, Jack L. (1990), Environmental Policy Implications of Disparities between Willingness to Pay
and Compensation Demanded Measures of Values, 18 Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management, 227-237.
Knetsch, Jack L. and Borcherding, Thomas (1979), Expropriation of Private Property and the Basis
for Compensation, 29 University of Toronto Law Journal, 237-252.
Knetsch, Jack L. and Sinden, J.A. (1984), Willingness to Pay and Compensation Demanded:
Experimental Evidence of an Unexpected Disparity in Measures of Value, 99 Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 507-521.
Knez, Peter, Smith, Vernon L. and Williams, Arlington W. (1985), Individual Rationality, Market
Rationality and Value Estimation, 75 American Economic Review, 397-402.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1980), A Guide to the Perplexed Claims of Efficiency in the Law, 8 Hofstra
Law Review, 591-639.
Kraakman, Reinier H. (1988), Taking Discounts Seriously: The Implications of Discounted Share
Prices as an Acquisition Motive, 88 Columbia Law Review, 891-941.
Kronman, Anthony T. (1980), Wealth Maximization as a Normative Principle, 9 Journal of Legal
Studies, 227-242.
Kbler, Friedrich (1990), Effizienz als Rechtsprinzip - berlegungen zum rechtspraktischen Gebrauch
konomischer Argumente (Efficiency as Legal Principle - Considerations for the Legal Practice Use
of Economic Arguments), in Baur, Jrgen F., Hopt, Klaus J. and Mailnder (eds), Festschrift fr
Ernst Steindorff, Berlin, De Gruyter, 687-704.
Lande, Robert H. (1982), Wealth Transfers as the Original and Primary Concern of Antitrust: The
Efficiency Interpretation Challenged, 34 Hastings Law Journal, 67-151.
Lee, Dwight R. and McKenzie, Richard B. (1990), Second Thoughts on the Public-Good Justification
for Government Poverty Programs, 19 Journal of Legal Studies, 189-202.
Lemley, Mark A. (1997), The Economics of Improvement in Intellectual Property Law, 75 Texas
Law Review, 989-0.
Lipsey, Richard G. and Lancaster, K. (1956), On the General Theory of the Second Best, 24 Review
of Economic Studies, 11-32.
Loewenstein, George and Adler, Daniel (1995), A Bias in the Prediction of Tastes, 105 Economic
Journal, 929-937.
Macey, Jonathan R. and Miller, Geoffrey P. (1990), Good Finance, Bad Economics: An Analysis of
the Fraud-on-the-Market Theory, 42 Stanford Law Review, 1059-1092.
Margolis, Stephen E. (1987), Two Definitions of Efficiency in Law and Economics, 16 Journal of
Legal Studies, 471-482.
Markovits, Richard S. (1975), A Basic Structure for Microeconomic Policy Analysis in our
Worse-Than-Second-Best World: A Proposal and Related Critique of the Chicago Approach to the
Study of Law and Economics, Wisconsin Law Review, 950-1080.
Markovits, Richard S. (1980), Legal Analysis and the Economic Analysis of Allocative Efficiency,
8 Hofstra Law Review, 811-903.
McClelland, Gary H. and Schulze, William D. (1991), The Disparity Between Willingness to Pay
Versus Willingness to Accept as a Framing Effect, in Brown, Donald R. and Smith, J.E. Keith
(eds), Frontiers of Mathematical Psychology: Essays in Honor of Clyde Coombs, New York,
Springer-Verlag, 166-192.
Medema, Steven G. (1993), Is There Life Beyond Efficiency? Elements of a Social Law and
Economics, 51 Review of Social Economy, 138-153.
0720 The Endowment Effect 833
Medema, Steven G. and Samuels, Warren J. (1997), Ronald Coase and Coasean Economics: Some
Questions, Conjectures and Implications, in Samuels, Warren J., Medema, Steven G. and Schmid,
A. Allan (eds), The Economy as a Process of Valuation, Aldershot, Edward Elgar.
Miller, Geoffrey P. (1987), Economic Efficiency and the Lockean Proviso, 10 Harvard Journal of
Law and Public Policy, 401 ff.
Milovanovic Milic (1994), Privatizacija i ekonomska efikasnost (Privatization and Economic
Efficiency), 1-2 Ekonomska Misao, 1-20.
Mishan, Ezra J. (1967), Pareto Optimality and the Law, 19 Oxford Economic Papers, 255-287.
ODriscoll, Gerald P., Jr (1980), Justice, Efficiency and the Economic Analysis of Law: A Comment
on Fried, 9 Journal of Legal Studies, 355-366.
Olson, Mancur (1987), Why Some Welfare-State Redistribution to the Poor is a Great Idea, in
Rowley, Charles K. (ed.), Democracy and Public Choice: Essays in Honor of Gordon Tullock,
Oxford, Blackwell, 191-222.
Ortona, Guido and Scacciati, Francesco (1992), New Experiments on the Endowment Effect, 13
Journal of Economic Psychology, 277-296.
Paz-Ares, Cndido (1993), Principio de Eficiencia y Derecho privado (Efficiency and Private Law),
in AA. VV., Derecho, Moral y Eficiencia, III, Jornadas de Filosofa del Derecho, Palma de
Mallorca, Revisado en Estudios en homenaje a M. Brocheta Pont, Valencia 1995, III pp.
Posner, Richard A. (1980), The Ethical and Political Basis of the Efficiency Norm in Common Law
Adjudication, 8 Hofstra Law Review, 487-507.
Pratt, John W. and Zeckhauser, Richard J. (1996), Willingness to Pay and the Distribution of Risk and
Wealth, 104 Journal of Political Economy, 747-763.
Quattrone, George A. and Tversky, Amos (1988), Contrasting Rational and Psychological Analyses
of Political Choice, 82 American Political Science Review, 719-736.
Radin, Margaret J. (1982), Property and Personhood, 34 Stanford Law Review, 957-1015.
Rizzo, Mario J. (1980), The Mirage of Efficiency, 8 Hofstra Law Review, 641-658.
Rothbard, Murray N. (1979), Comment: The Myth of Efficiency, in Rizzo, Mario J. (ed.), Time,
Uncertainty and Disequilibrium, Lexington, MA, Lexington Books, 91-95.
Rowley, Charles K. and Peacock, Alan T. (1975), Welfare Economics: A Liberal Restatement,
London, Martin Robertson, 198 p.
Rowley, Charles K. and Walker, Martin (1979), Pareto-Optimality and Gains-From-Trade: A Public
Choice Interpretation, 34 Public Choice, 123-127.
Rozen, Marvin E. (1985), Maximizing Behavior: Reconciling Neoclassical and X-Efficiency
Approaches, 19 Journal of Economic Issues, 661-685.
Ryssdal, Stray A.C. (1995), Legal Realism and Economics as Behavior - A Scandinavian Look at the
Economic Analysis of Law, Oslo, Juridisk Forlag AS, Nerenius & Santrus Frlag AB Gad Jura
AS.
Sager, Lawrence G. (1980), Pareto Superiority, Consent and Justice,8 Hofstra Law Review, 913-937.
Samuels, Warren J. and Mercuro, Nicholas (1984), Posnerian Law and Economics on the Bench, 4
International Review of Law and Economics, 107-130.
Samuels, Warren J. and Mercuro, Nicholas (1986), Wealth Maximalization and Judicial
Decision-Making: The Issues Further Clarified, 6 International Review of Law and Economics,
133-137.
834 The Endowment Effect 0720
Samuelson, W. and Zeckhauser, R. (1988), Status Quo Bias in Decision Making, 1 Journal of Risk
and Uncertainty, 7-60.
Schwarzer, Stephan (1985), Wirtschaftsrecht und konomische Effizienz (Commercial Law and
Economic Efficiency), Wirtschaftspolitische Bltter, 26-31.
Scitovski, T. (1951), The State of the Welfare Economics, 41 American Economic Review.
Shavell, Steven (1981), A Note on Efficiency vs. Distributional Equity in Legal Rulemaking: Should
Distributional Equity Matter Given Optimal Income Taxation?, 71 American Economic Review.
Papers and Proceedings, 414-418.
Shaviro, Daniel N. (1990), Exchange on Public Choice, 57 University of Chicago Law Review,
834-843.
Shogren, Jason F., Shin, Seung Y., Hayes, Dermot J. and Kleibenstein, James B. (1994), Resolving
Difference in Willingness to Pay and Willingness to Accept, 84 American Economic Review,
255-270.
Sileo, Patrick W. (1995), Intransitivity of Indifference, Strong Monotonicity and the Endowment
Effect, 66 Journal of Economic Theory, 198-223.
Slovic, P. and Lichtenstein, S. (1968), Relative Importance of Probabilities and Payoffs in Risk
Taking, 78 Journal of Experimental Psychology, 1-18.
Smith, Vernon (1991), Rational Choice: The Contrast Between Economics and Psychology, 99
Journal of Political Economy, 877-897.
Stigler, George J. (1970), Directors Law of Public Income Redistribution, 13 Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-10.
Stigler, George J. (1976), The Xistence of X-Efficiency, 66 American Economic Review, 213-216.
Stigler, George J. (1978), Wealth and Possibly Liberty, 7 Journal of Legal Studies, 213-217.
Stout, Lynn A. (1996), Insurance or Gambling? Derivatives Trading in a World of Risk and
Uncertainty, 39 Brookings Review.
Stout, Lynn A. (1997a), How Efficient Markets Undervalue Stocks: CAPM and ECMH in A World
of Uncertainty and Disagreement, 18 Cardozo Law Review.
Stout, Lynn A. (1997b), ATechnology, Transactions Costs and Investor Welfare: Is a Motley Fool
Born Every Minute?, 75 Washington University Law Quarterly.
Symposium (1980), Symposium on Efficiency as a Legal Concern, 8 Hofstra Law Review, 485-972.
Thaler, Richard (1980), Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice, 1 Journal of Economic
Behavior and Organization, 39-60.
Tullock, Gordon (1971), Subsidized Housing in a Competitive Market: Comment, 61 American
Economic Review, 218-219.
Tullock, Gordon (1980), Two Kinds of Legal Efficiency, 8 Hofstra Law Review, 659 ff.
Tullock, Gordon (1983), Economics of Income Redistribution, Boston, Kluwer-Nijhoff, 208 p.
Tullock, Gordon (1986), The Economics of Wealth and Poverty, New York, Columbia University
Press, 210 p.
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel (1991), Loss Aversion in Riskless Choice: A
Reference-Dependent Model, 106 Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1039-1061.
Tversky, Amos and Wakker, Peter (1995), Risk Attitudes and Decision Weights, 63 Econometrica,
1255-1280.
0720 The Endowment Effect 835
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1981), Wealth Maximization, Law and Ethics - on the Limits of Economic
Efficiency, 1 International Review of Law and Economics, 5-28.
Vukotic Veselin (1993), Privatizacija, Pravicnost i Efikasnost (Privatization, Justice and Efficiency),
1-2 Ekonomist, 81-88.
Wang, William K.S. (1986), Some Arguments that the Stock Market is not Efficient, 19 U.C. Davis
Law Review, 341-402.
Wetzstein, Michael E. and Centner, Terence J. (1992), Regulating Agricultural Contamination of
Groundwater Through Strict Liability and Negligence Legislation, 22 Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management, 1-11.
Other References
de Alessi, Louis (1960), Implications of Property Rights for Government Investment Choices, 59
American Economic Review, 13-24.
Calfee, John E. and Rubin, Paul H. (1992), Some Implications of Damage Payments for Nonpecuniary
Losses, 21 Journal of Legal Studies, 371-409.
Conlisk, John (1996), Why Bounded Rationality?, 34 Journal of Economic Literature, 669-700.
Donohue, John J. III (1989), Diverting the Coasean River: Incentive Schemes to Reduce
Unemployment Spells, 99 Yale Law Yournal, 549-609.
Willig, Robert D. (1976), Consumer Surplus Without Apology,66 American Economic Association,
589-597.
0730
THE COASE THEOREM
Steven G. Medema
Associate Professor of Economics, University of Colorado at Denver
Richard O. Zerbe, Jr
University of Washington, Graduate School of Public Affairs
Copyright 1999 Steven G. Medema and Richard O. Zerbe, Jr
Abstract
1. Introduction
Ronald Coases seminal essay, The Problem of Social Cost (1960), is one of
the most cited articles in the economics and legal literatures, and much of this
attention is owed to a proposition that has come to be known as the Coase
Theorem. While the Coase Theorem is by no means the only idea contained
within that essay, it has captured the attention and interest of economists and
legal scholars as have few other ideas. (For useful treatments of The Problem
of Social Cost as a whole, see Zerbe, 1976; Schlag, 1986; and Medema,
1996a; for context, see Coase, 1937, 1959.) Coase argued that, from an
economic perspective, the goal of the legal system should be to establish a
pattern of rights such that economic efficiency is attained. The legal system
836
0730 The Coase Theorem 837
affects transactions costs and the goal of such a system is to minimize harm or
costs, broadly conceived (Coase, 1960, p. 2). With this in mind Coase (1960,
pp. 2-15) demonstrates the importance of transaction costs by considering the
nature of bargaining or of contracts that could be struck by using an example
of crop damage caused by straying cattle. He noted that negotiations among
affected parties would result in an efficient and invariant outcome under the
standard assumptions of competitive markets (especially, that the costs of
transacting are zero), as long as rights are well-defined. Specifically, it is
necessary to know whether the damaging business is liable or not for damage
caused since without the establishment of this initial delimitation of rights there
can be no market transactions to transfer and recombine them. But the ultimate
result (which maximizes the value of production) is independent of the legal
position if the pricing system is assumed to work without cost (Coase, 1960, p.
8).
This is as close as Coase comes in his essay to stating what has come to be
known as the Coase Theorem.
2. Theorem(s)
Although Coase had set forth this idea already in The Federal
Communications Commission (Coase, 1959, p. 27), the first formal statement
of the Coase Theorem did not come until 1966, when George Stigler (1966, p.
113) offered that The Coase theorem ... asserts that under perfect competition
private and social costs will be equal. Subsequently, the Theorem has been
stated in numerous ways, including:
If transaction costs are zero the structure of the law does not matter because
efficiency will result in any case (Polinsky, 1974, p. 1665).
838 The Coase Theorem 0730
if there were (a) no wealth effects on demand, (b) no transaction costs and (c) rights
to pollute or control pollution, the allocative solution would be invariant and
optimal, regardless of the initial assignment of rights. (Frech, 1979, p. 254)
In a world of zero transaction costs, the allocation of resources will be efficient, and
invariant with respect to legal rules of liability, income effects aside (Zerbe, 1980,
p. 84).
a change in a liability rule will leave the agents production and consumption
decisions both unchanged and economically efficient within the following (implicit)
framework: (a) two agents to each externality bargain, (b) perfect knowledge of one
anothers (convex) production and profit or utility functions, (c) competitive
markets, (d) zero transactions costs, (e) costless court system, (f) profit-maximizing
producers and expected utility-maximizing consumers, (g) no wealth effects, (h)
agents will strike mutually advantageous bargains in the absence of transactions
costs. (Hoffman and Spitzer, 1982, p. 73)
when parties can bargain together and settle their disagreements by cooperation,
their behavior will be efficient regardless of the underlying rule of law. (Cooter and
Ulen, 1988, p. 105)
a change in [law] affects neither the efficiency of contracts nor the distribution of
wealth between the parties. (Schwab, 1988, p. 242)
3. Implications
The Theorem has never been formally proved. Arguments regarding its
correctness or incorrectness generally consist of attempts to demonstrate that
it does or does not hold in a particular context or under a certain set of
assumptions. Of particular import here is the framework within which the
reallocations of rights contemplated by the Theorem are assumed to take place.
Two basic frameworks can be identified: the quasi-competitive framework,
within which all relevant markets are assumed to be perfectly competitive and
840 The Coase Theorem 0730
Most of the analysis of the Theorem has taken place within the
quasi-competitive framework, under which are two different types of treatment.
First, there are discussions of small numbers externality negotiations within a
more broad competitive context of full information, no strategic behavior,
agents operating within competitive markets, and so on, with the result that
parties strike mutually-beneficial bargains when they are available. This is
analogous to the standard Edgeworth box analysis and is the environment
contemplated by Coase in The Problem of Social Cost. The second type of
treatment actually assumes competitive markets in externality rights and
analyzes the Theorem on that basis. In the latter case, the first optimality
theorem of welfare economics suggests that the Coase Theorem is correct
(Arrow, 1969).
4.1 Rents
One of the earliest but merely technical arguments raised against the Theorem
is that it cannot hold under perfectly competitive conditions in the long run
because it presupposes rents that may not exist. To consider the objection
suppose that both the polluter and the victim are in a zero-profit, long-run
equilibrium position. (For expositional simplicity, in the following discussion
we will refer to the parties as polluters and victims. The analysis, of course,
generalizes to all manner of externalities.) Then, the assignment of liability to
the polluter will force the polluter to cease operations, since it lacks the
resources with which to make liability payments to the victim. Similarly, if the
victim is made liable, it will exit the market because it lacks the resources to
bribe the polluter to reduce its harmful activity. Thus, it is argued, the Coase
Theorem will only hold in the presence of non-transferable resources giving
rise to Ricardian rents (Wellisz, 1964, p. 351). It has been further argued that
even the prior existence of rents would not ensure the validity of the Coase
Theorem: the rents must be sufficient to support the externality - that is,
sufficient to allow the polluter to pay damages (if he is liable) or the victim to
pay the bribe (if the victim is liable); otherwise, a change in the direction of
liability will cause the party bearing the cost of the externality to exit the
industry (Tybout, 1972; Shapiro, 1974). Let us analyze these claims.
Suppose that the polluter is not earning rents and that he is liable for
damage caused. Then, the polluter will be forced to go out of business in the
long run, as he does not have the resources necessary to pay damages. This
0730 The Coase Theorem 841
result is efficient since the externality existed inefficiently in the first place: the
polluter was able to inflict damages on the victim only because he did not bear
the full social cost of his actions. If the polluter is not liable for damages, the
victims would be willing to offer a bribe up to the amount of damage to induce
the polluter to cease operations, a bribe which the polluter would be willing to
accept since it was not earning any rents in the first place. Thus, whether the
polluter or the victim is earning no rents, we get the same, efficient, result
regardless of the assignment of rights.
If neither party is earning rents sufficient to support the externality, the
externality would not exist in the first place; the appearance of the externality
would immediately drive the victim out of business and the externality would
cease to exist. (See Wellisz, 1964, p. 350; Crain, Saurman, and Tollison, 1978
and Zerbe, 1980, pp. 89-90; 99.) Thus rents must exist for negotiation over
rights to even be in the realm of possibility; that is, they are prior to the Coase
Theorem analysis. But once they are satisfied, an efficient and invariant result
will obtain.
The one case in which rents are not necessary is for externalities that are
industry-wide in their emission and public bads in their effects (so that all firms
in an industry are affected). Here, assuming that all firms are harmed equally
(in terms of the effect on marginal and average costs), the externality acts in a
manner analogous to an increase in input prices, causing an increase in
marginal and average cost, a reduction in supply, and an increase in market
price. The result will be invariant under alternative rules of liability.
the long-run inefficiency will be cured through the same type of bargaining
transactions that were employed to resolve the short-run inefficiencies caused
by the externality (Calabresi, 1968, p. 67). That is, available gains from
exchange will be exploited in the long run just as they are in the short run.
Second, following Nutter (1968), any long-run misallocation will be cured by
a single owner who will enter the market in order to exploit the potential for
gain. Third, the above argument assumes the existence of a single efficient
long-run equilibrium point (and thus that efficiency implies invariance), when,
in fact, such need not exist. Here, the long-run equilibria are both efficient and
thus the subsequent corrective negotiations or entrepreneurial actions are
unnecessary. That is, long-run entry effects do not invalidate the efficiency
argument.
The more difficult issue is that of invariance. While the above argument
against invariance would appear to be straightforward, consider the following
counter-argument. Suppose that ranchers are liable for damage done by their
cattle. The flow of liability payments will then be capitalized into the value of
farmland that adjoins ranching property and there will be no incentive for entry
into farming in order to secure the bribe. In analogous fashion, any bribes that
result from farmer liability will be capitalized into the value of ranchland that
adjoins farms and there will be no incentive to enter ranching. Given this, the
long-run entry effects that are said to invalidate the invariance proposition will
not occur (Demsetz, 1972a; Frech, 1979).
The key to distinguishing between these competing claims regarding
invariance has been provided by Holderness (1989), who pointed out that
invariance turns on the issue of whether rights are assigned to open or closed
classes of individuals or entities. An open class is defined as one into which
entry is unrestricted, while a closed class is one which can be entered only if the
right is purchased from a current class member (see also Demsetz, 1972b,
229-231). Consider first the assignment of rights within closed classes.
Landowners constitute a closed class since one can become a landowner only
by purchasing the land and the attendant bundle of rights from a current
landowner. The assignment of rights to one class of owners creates at once a
windfall gain for those having the right and a windfall loss for those not having
it. However, in a competitive system these windfall gains and losses are
immediately capitalized into the value of the land so that both types of land
yield a normal rate of return. Since the rate of return for each of these types of
land is unaffected by the assignment of rights, there are no incentives for entry
or exit. Thus, the invariance proposition holds for closed classes (Holderness,
1989, pp. 183-184).
The invariance claim does not hold for open classes, however.
Holdnernesss separation of open from closed classes calls attention since to a
broad category of spurious objections all based on incomplete property right
specification. Here, those who are not parties to the lawsuit through which the
0730 The Coase Theorem 843
initial assignment of rights is generated can acquire that right costlessly merely
by entering and this valuable right will not be capitalized into the price of any
resource. Entry will indeed result (Holderness, 1989, p. 185). Similarly, the
absence of a right reduces the returns to that activity, thereby inducing exit. The
asymmetric entry/exit effects across alternative assignments of rights will thus
result in different long-run outputs under alternative assignments of rights,
thereby negating the invariance proposition.
This distinction illuminates the divergent results obtained by many of those
offering support for or claiming to refute the invariance proposition. Those who
have found the invariance proposition to be valid in this (the entry issue)
context have either explicitly or implicitly assumed or worked with examples
constituting closed classes. On the other hand, those finding against invariance
have analyzed the problem in open-class contexts - primarily situations with
two industries where entry is possible. The invariance proposition is applicable
to closed class situations, such as externalities affecting land values, but is
inapplicable to tort situations, such as accident law, where there is free entry
into one or both classes and to assignments of rights which cover all (current
and future) entrants into an industry.
The open class case, however, would seem to violate an underlying
assumption of the Coase Theorem - fully-specified property rights. That is,
rights in open classes are not delimited to the extent necessary to make market
transactions possible; potential entrants are able to secure a valuable right
without paying for it. This is consistent with Barzels (1989, p. 2) definition of
property rights as the powers to consume, obtain income from and alienate ...
assets and Allens (1995, p. 2) definition of an economic property right as
ones ability, without penalty, to exercise a choice over a good, service, or
person (emphasis in original). In fact, the assumption of zero transaction costs
is said by some to mean that rights are fully specified (see Cheung, 1992; Allen,
1991, 1995) and the discussion in section 6, below). As such, the issue of
incompletely specified rights, or open classes, goes to the issue of relevance
rather than correctness.
so that CB = C(qA, qB), where the pollution damage owing to firm As output
increases the costs of firm B.
With a non-separable cost function there is neither efficiency nor
invariance. With a non-separable cost function, the level of pollution damage
to B is a function not just of As output, but of Bs output as well and thus a
given level of output by A causes B more harm (that is, causes a greater
increase in Bs costs) the more output B produces. In such a situation, the
victim can and does contribute to its own damage without having to bear the
cost, since it is fully compensated for all damage. As a result, the victim has no
incentive to mitigate damages and produces an inefficiently high level of
output. Moreover, the damage liability associated with this imposes a higher
than optimal cost on the polluter, causing it to restrict its output below the
optimal level (Marchand and Russell, 1973, pp. 613-615).
However, if both activities are controlled by a single owner, the result will
be efficient and invariant regardless of the initial assignment of rights and
irrespective of whether the victims cost function is separable or non-separable
(Marchand and Russell, 1973, pp. 614-616). Moreover, one can imagine a
contract between owners that mimics the effect of single ownership assuming
costs of monitoring and negotiation are zero. This demonstration is sufficient
to negate the nonseparability critique, since the inefficiency contemplated will
be exploited through merger, which can be achieved costlessly, or by an
entrepreneur (see, for example, Nutter, 1968; Coelho, 1975 and Zerbe, 1980,
pp. 87-88). Marchand and Russell (1975) have responded to this criticism by
invoking difficulties in carrying out a merger - that is, by introducing
transaction costs. But introducing transaction costs is no argument against the
correctness of the Coase Theorem. A further argument that can be raised
against the nonseparabilities critique is that it violates the assumption of
fully-specified property rights (at least in the sense of Allen, 1991, 1995), since
the victim is able to procure revenues from the polluter without giving up
anything in return.
Figure 1
Panel A Panel B
Here, qB is the output of firm B, the victim and Z is the level of the
externality. The analysis turns on the effect of increasing pollution damage on
the victims output. Panel (b) illustrates a situation of increasing marginal
damage from pollution (given by the reduction in the victims output due to the
externality) with the recognition that, beyond some point (Z0), marginal damage
will be zero (Starrett, 1972, pp. 189-190).
The import of this for the Coase Theorem is as follows. Suppose that the
polluters (As) profit-maximizing level of pollution in the absence of the legal
rule is some level Z1 > Z0. With this level of pollution, B will produce no output.
If the A has the right to pollute, the point Z = Z1, qB = 0 is the starting point for
negotiation over the level of pollution. The minimum payment that the polluter
is willing to accept to reduce pollution is the reduction in profits that would
accompany the reduction in pollution. However, at (and around) Z1, there is no
benefit to the victim from a one unit reduction in pollution; the victims output
(qB) would remain at zero with this one unit reduction in pollution. Thus, the
victim would not be willing to offer a bribe payment to induce the polluter to
reduce its pollution by one unit (to Z1 ! 1 units) - it is a cost with no attending
benefit. Thus, the equilibrium when the polluter has the right to pollute will be
at a pollution level Z = Z1 and an output level for the victim of qB = 0, a result
which is due to the nonconvexity.
On the other hand, if the victim has the right to be free from pollution, the
baseline from which negotiation begins is Z = 0. The victim will be willing to
accept any bribe to allow positive levels of the pollution if the bribe is in excess
of the lost profits due to pollution damage (or reduction in q B). Thus, the parties
will be able to negotiate to an efficient result along standard Coasean lines, but
the final result will not (except by accident) be Z = Z1 and qB = 0. Thus, the
846 The Coase Theorem 0730
its efficiency. That is, alternative assignments of rights can have differential
effects on the structure of demands for consumer goods. Since different
assignments of rights result in different distributions of income, the
composition of demands - and hence equilibrium prices and quantities across
markets - will vary with alternative assignments of rights. For example,
suppose that an economy produces only beef and fish and that fertilizer runoff
used to produce grass, an input into beef production reduces fish production.
Those that produce beef prefer to eat beef and those that produce fish prefer
fish. A change in the liability rule from one in which beef producers are liable
to one in which they are not will increase the income of beef producers and
reduce the income of fish producers. This will then increase the demand for
beef and reduce the demand for fish; thus, the relative production of beef and
fish will not be invariant to the liability rule. This objection to the strong
version of the Theorem is well recognized. But, we shall see that even this
objection presupposes incomplete property rights.
Differences Between WTP and WTA A change in the law can change the sense
of ownership and thus change the measure of value from the WTP to WTA or
vice versa. Following Willig (1976), economists have tended to assume that any
differences between willingness to accept (WTA) and willingness to pay (WTP)
owing to a price change are small. This is now recognized as untrue in
important cases. For environmental goods, researchers have demonstrated
repeatedly that WTA questionnaires generate values from two to nineteen times
greater than those elicited by WTP questions (Levy and Friedman, 1994, p.
495, n. 6; Hoffman and Spitzer, 1993, pp. 69-85). There are three reasons for
the difference: income effects, substitution possibilities and loss aversion.
(Hoffman and Spitzer, 1993) present an excellent survey of the WTA v. WTP
issue, much of the evidence regarding which comes from the experimental
literature. The present discussion touches on what we believe to be the most
significant of these arguments.)
Let us first consider the implications of income effects. If most people
experience diminishing marginal utility of income, the utility loss resulting
from a reduction in income of a certain amount is greater than the utility gain
associated with an increase in income of the same amount. Thus, if individuals
bargain over utility, rather than over wealth per se, we would expect to see
differences between WTA and WTP and thus negotiated solutions that vary
with the initial assignment of rights (Hovenkamp, 1990). This is an income
effect. For example (and assuming that A, the polluter, is a firm, so that wealth
effects are irrelevant for it), if B (an individual) has the right to be free from
pollution, then the amount of pollution generated will be a function of the
payment that he is willing to accept to avoid pollution. If B does not have the
right to be free from pollution (that is, A has the right to pollute), then the
amount of pollution generated will be a function of the amount that B is willing
to pay to avoid pollution. Since the maximum amount a person is willing to pay
848 The Coase Theorem 0730
Perhaps the most intriguing case is one suggested by the recent literature in
which legal ownership is different from psychological ownership (Zerbe,
1998a, 1998b). Evidence suggests that a sense of ownership attends certain
environmental goods even if there is no individual ownership. A decision to cut
down the last remaining stand of privately owned redwood trees, the Headwater
Grove, may create a sense of loss among some that are non-owners of the
grove. This loss is correctly measured by the WTA. If, however, a decision to
measure the value of the grove is based on legal ownership the value to the
public will be based on the WTP for preservation. Since for a normal good the
WTP will be less than the WTA, the grove may be cut when it should not.
Property rights are fully specified in this example so that it would appear to
violate the strong version of the Theorem.
However, Zerbe (1998a, 1998b) has noted that, although property rights in
this case are fully specified, they are inefficiently specified. He argues that
efficiency requires that the legal measure of property and damage correspond
to psychological reference points. (Posners rule (1992, p. 52) for the
allocation of rights is a subsidiary of this theorem. This rule is that where one
class of claimants values the right more than other classes, efficiency requires
that the right should go to the claimants that value it the most.) If there is not
a correspondence between psychological and legal property rights, the use of
WTP and WTA based on legal criteria can impose net losses. Imagine that a
party, George, believes he owns a right or a property, M and that another party,
Ronald, also believes that George owns property M. They discover that the law,
however, holds that party George, not Ronald, owns M. Ronald suffers a loss
of M psychologically and therefore economically, while George gains M. Since
losses are, on the average, worth more than equivalent gains (due to income,
substitution effects and loss aversion), on the average George will gain less than
what Ronald loses. This is perfectly general, so that the application of law to
affect a legal ownership different from psychological ownership must, on
average, impose net losses. (This is true as long as Ronald and George may be
regarded as equivalent in the sense that on average one does not have a greater
income than the other or does not differ in some other relevant characteristic.
Underlying this proof is the notion that we cannot speak of it being efficient to
change preferences to be in accord with the law since this violates the proper
context for benefit cost analysis - which requires that preferences be taken as
they lie - and the very concept of efficiency. In any event benefit cost can not
evaluate the advantages of a change in preferences since this does not take
preferences as they lie.) Similarly, if one class of claimant psychologically
possesses property so that its removal is felt as a psychological loss, as
compared with a rival claimant who has a lesser psychological claim or no
claim, efficiency requires that the law grant the right to the psychological
possessor. But, in a zero transactions cost world this sort of inefficiency would
0730 The Coase Theorem 851
not arise since the law would be made to correspond with the psychological
sense of ownership.
While the vast majority of the literature debating the validity of the Coase
Theorem employs the quasi-competitive framework, a number of commentators
have addressed the Theorem from a game-theoretic bargaining perspective,
arguing that that the quasi-competitive framework is not appropriate or relevant
for Coase Theorem-like bargains over rights owing to the small number of
parties contemplated and the potential for strategic behavior. (See, for example,
Davis and Whinston, 1962; Samuelson, 1966, p. 1141; Shoup 1971, p. 310;
Regan 1972, p. 428; Cooter, 1982, pp. 16-17.) By placing the Theorem in a
small numbers context but yet ignoring the potential for strategic behavior, it
is presumed that the contemplated agreements can and will be reached because
it is in the joint interest of the parties to do so (Samuelson, 1985, p. 322). Yet,
this fails to consider the possibility that what is rational for the group may not
be rational for the individual and constitutes, in essence, an a priori argument
for the Theorem (Regan, 1972, pp. 429-431).
Several commentators (for example, Davis and Whinston, 1965; Arrow,
1979; Aivazian and Callen, 1981; Samuelson, 1985 and Aivazian, Callen and
Lipnowski, 1987) have suggested that the Coase Theorem, as envisioned by its
proponents at least, lends itself quite naturally to the theory of cooperative
games. It can be demonstrated that the Coase Theorem will always hold in a
two-person cooperative game. However, this result is not particularly
comforting since, by setting the problem in the context of a two-person
cooperative game, efficiency is assured by definition (although there is no
guarantee of invariance), making this more along the lines of an illustration of
the Coase Theorem rather than a proof (Schweizer, 1988, pp. 246, 254). In fact,
much of the quasi-competitive literature (especially the two-person analysis)
can, without too much injustice, be described as cooperative game analysis. The
situation is complicated when the cooperative game involves more than two
players. While it has been suggested that the Theorem may not hold in such a
context (Aivazian and Callen, 1981), this claim has been shown to be incorrect
(Coase, 1981; De Bornier, 1986).
(a) Implication One: The Baseline Problem When victims are liable, the firm
can influence the level of the bribe that it receives by making an upward
adjustment in pollution emission at the time that the baseline level of pollution
(against which subsidized/bribe-induced pollution reductions will be measured)
is set or by choosing not to take cost-justified precautions. That is, the level of
pollution on which the bribe is based may differ from the level of pollution that
would have been emitted if the polluter was liable. The source of this incentive
is the inability of the victim to ascertain with certainty the true baseline level
of pollution. Moreover, disagreements over the baseline level of pollution may
result in the failure to consummate bargains when the victim is liable.
Conversely, if polluters are known to be liable for damages, then, in the absence
of full information about actual damages and measures taken by the victim to
0730 The Coase Theorem 853
mitigate damages, the victims moral hazard will result in too few resources
being devoted to precaution/mitigation by the victim and too many resources
being devoted to abatement by the polluter (Kamien, Schwartz and Dolbear,
1966; Tybout, 1972; Harris, 1990). With endogenous liability assignment,
however, the moral hazard problems disappear, since a party does not know
with certainty whether or not it will be forced to bear the costs of the
externality. Thus each party will act efficiently to minimize expected costs by
engaging in the appropriate level of precaution/preventive activity (Harris,
1990, pp. 701-702).
garners for it an amount not in excess of the other partys rents. Thus, the only
differential impact of alternative legal rules will be on the distribution of rents;
the final allocation of resources will be unaffected (Boyd and Mohring, 1971;
Demsetz, 1972a; Feldman, 1974).
(c) Implication Three: Private Information While Davis and Whinston (1965,
p. 118) argued early on that information would be revealed through the
bargaining process, the application of more complex strategic thinking suggests
that private information, if revealed, may be used against ones self and thus
adversely affect ones payoff. Given this, agents have an incentive to conceal
information (through silence or lies) and to expend resources both to protect the
value of their own private information and to acquire information from/about
others. These costs and resultant delays and/or failures to consummate
mutually-beneficial bargains, are likely to preclude the attainment of efficient
negotiated solutions where information is asymmetrically distributed (Cooter,
1982; Sutton, 1986; Farrell, 1987). Cooter (1982, pp. 17-18) even goes so far
as to argue that an equally strong case can be made that parties will never agree
on the distribution of the surplus, even when transaction costs are zero, a
proposition that he labels the Hobbes Theorem. However, he maintains that
the ever-present strategic element is not as insurmountable as the Hobbes
Theorem implies, nor as inconsequential as the Coase Theorem implies; in
fact, he argues, gains from trade in bargaining situations are realized more
often than not (Cooter, 1982, p. 19). Cento Veljanovski (1982, p. 60) offers a
theorem similar to Cooters Hobbes Theorem - the Johansen theorem, which
holds that [d]irect bargaining has an inherent tendency to dissipate the
gains-from-trade through strategic behaviour (see Johansen, 1979, pp.
515-520). Unlike Cooter, however, Veljanovski maintains that in a world of
zero transaction costs the dissipation of gains is likely to be the more common
outcome.
A number of commentators have demonstrated the potential for both
agreement and non-agreement when information is imperfect. If neither partys
utility function is a function of the others private information, then an efficient
result will be reached. However, if either partys utility function is a function
of the others private information, then there is no guarantee that an efficient
result will be reached (Schweizer, 1988, pp. 259-263). (See also Arrow, 1979,
pp. 29-31; Cooter, 1982, pp. 20-24; Samuelson, 1985; Illing, 1992). Our
discussion here will draw primarily from Cooters analysis. Arrow and
Samuelson reach conclusions very similar to Cooter, using the assumption that
the parties are uncertain about each others utility functions. For example,
Cooter (1982, pp. 20-24) points out that uncertainty regarding the opponents
response causes each player to form a rational expectation of this response in
the sense of formulating a subjective probability distribution over his
opponents moves. Given this rational expectation regarding his opponents
strategy, each player chooses for himself the strategy that maximizes his
0730 The Coase Theorem 855
expected utility based on a comparison of the greater share of the gains from
taking a harder line in bargaining with the higher probability that this harder
line will prevent an agreement from being reached. The problem is that, while
each player will be playing the strategy that is optimal against the distribution
of his opponents possible strategies, this strategy is not necessarily optimal
against the particular strategy played by the opponent. The outcome will be
inefficient when players err in their predictions of the moves made by their
opponents (Cooter, 1982, pp. 20, 23; Arrow, 1979, p. 31). In fact, Cooter
contends that zero transaction (communication) costs actually decreases the
possibility of reaching an agreement, in that it facilitates the transmission of
threats and other strategic communications (Cooter, 1982, pp. 23), although,
as Arrow (1979) has demonstrated, it is possible to design a collective decision
rule that will induce a truthful revelation of preferences.
If the situation involves large bargaining groups, two more potential
difficulties arise. First, individuals will have an incentive to free ride and thus
the ability of the group to pay a bribe sufficient to induce the socially optimal
level of output/pollution will be greatly reduced. Second, if there are differential
damage effects across victims, we may observe the rise of coalitions within the
victim group (for example, by level of damage), each applying pressure to
encourage the result that best suits its interests. The greater is the number of
coalitions, the smaller is the likelihood that the optimal solution will be reached
(Wellisz, 1964, p. 354). However, as the number of parties approaches infinity
(with large numbers of right-holders and large numbers of rights-seekers), the
bargaining solution here will approach the efficient result of competitive
equilibrium (Samuelson, 1985, p. 338).
In sum, the likelihood of incomplete information gives us little reason to
believe that the Coase Theorem is correct when specified in a noncooperative
bargaining context. But while the game-theoretic critiques of the Coase
Theorem are suggestive of its demise, they have not gone unchallenged, largely
on the grounds that it is incorrect to place the Theorem in such a context. At
issue is what is meant by a world of zero transaction costs, to which we now
turn.
Perhaps the most sticky issue in the debate over the Coase Theorem is the
meaning given to the assumption of zero transaction costs. Indeed, the very
concept of transaction costs has been so vague and ill-defined that Stanley
Fischer (1977, p. 322, n. 5) was once led to remark that almost anything can
be rationalized by invoking suitably specified transaction costs. Coases (1960,
p. 15) definition of transaction costs encompasses those costs associated with
search, negotiation, monitoring and enforcement, which, as Dahlman (1979,
856 The Coase Theorem 0730
C. Relevance
A further facet of the extensive debate over the Coase Theorem has been the
attempt to verify its predictions experimentally and empirically. Hovenkamp
(1990, p. 794) has recently pointed out that [c]onducting empirical tests of the
Coase theorem is like conducting empirical tests of the Pythagorean theorem.
Given the theorems assumptions, the results flow out as a matter of logical
necessity. This is true; as such and given the impossibility of satisfying the
zero transaction costs assumption in the world in which we live, the
experimental and empirical tests go to the issues of relevance and applicability,
rather than to the Theorems correctness. In doing so, they begin to address the
potential difficulties for the Theorem that are raised by the challenges discussed
above, such as the effects of imperfect information, the potential for strategic
behavior, nonconvexities and the presence of income or taste and preference
effects.
7. Experimental Tests
The experimental tests of the Coase Theorem are among the most interesting
of the various tests, since they offer the potential to mimic as closely as possible
the conditions of zero transaction costs. At the same time, they can begin to
capture the effects of factors such as imperfect information and isolate the
import of these effects vis--vis situations in which they are absent.
remedies because of the high probability that the parties will bargain to the
efficient result (Hoffman and Spitzer, 1986, pp. 163-168). (See Calabresi and
Melamed, 1972. For discussions of the relative efficacy of property rules and
liability rules when transaction costs are positive, see also Polinsky, 1979;
1980; Ayres and Talley, 1995a, 1995b; Kaplow and Shavell, 1995, 1996.)
In making these claims, Hoffman and Spitzer clearly go too far. It is one
thing to show that the Coase Theorem is largely confirmed in a laboratory
setting that attempts more or less to mimic the zero transaction costs world, but
it is quite another to say that the results thus generated establish a presumption
in favor of the Coase Theorem for efficiently resolving real-world externality
problems with twenty or fewer parties. (It should be noted that the parties will
always reach an efficient point, in the Pareto sense. That is, even if transaction
costs are so large as to preclude rights transfers, that result is Pareto efficient,
given transaction costs. See, for example, Samuels (1974), Buchanan (1983)
and Calabresi (1991). However, the efficient result to which Hoffman and
Spitzers presumption refers is the Pigouvian social optimum, which is
equivalent to the Pareto optimal outcome when transaction costs are zero.)
What may be established is that up to twenty-party externalities will be resolved
efficiently through negotiations in many and perhaps even most, instances
where transaction costs are very low and the stakes are very small. But
transaction costs consist of far more than factors introduced by a twenty-second
tasting of a foul liquid or adding parties to a bargain, particularly when the
group consists of more-or-less homogeneous college students. The
emphysema-ridden residents of the neighborhood are likely to have a far
different view of pollution externalities than would others who are not so
affected; the light sleepers are likely to look far differently at the neighborhood
kennel than are the deep sleepers and so on. And how many groups are absent
one or two members who are likely to impede any negotiated settlement? All
of this is to say nothing of the information and coordination problems that may
attend complicated real-world bargains. In sum, Hoffman and Spitzer develop
some very nice results offering rather strong support for the Theorem when the
conditions it assumes are nearly met. However, to move from this to claims of
widespread applicability and presumptions in favor of the Theorem in
real-world cases is a somewhat different matter, one requiring far more caution
and future study than is implied by the authors.
Even when transaction costs are negligible, then, there does not seem to be
much room for confidence in the generation of an invariant outcome when
consumers are party to an externality.
such as to weigh heavily against the attainment of efficient results. By the same
token, however, these experiments go much more to the application of the
insights of the Coase Theorem than to the testing of the Theorem per se, in that
they introduce a variety of factors that are assumed away by the Theorems
assumption of zero transaction costs. Thus, earlier work, such as that by
Hoffman and Spitzer, speaks favorably to the Coase Theorem on its own terms,
while Schwabs results are rather pessimistic about the ability of parties to
bargain to efficient results in more natural settings. However, Schwabs results
take on a better cast when evaluated in light of what he calls the weak
efficiency hypothesis, which says that the law will not affect the rate at which
efficient bargains are consummated. (This is not to be confused with the weak
version of the Coase Theorem, noted above, which asserts efficiency but not
invariance.) The form of the contract presumption does not have a significant
effect on the inclusion of stay clauses or go clauses, nor on the efficiency of the
contracts (Schwab, 1988, pp. 252-253).
8. Empirical Studies
There have been three studies that more or less take Coases farmer-rancher
example into the real world to look at the ability of parties to negotiate efficient
solutions to animal trespass problems.
divorce rules (Peters, 1986, p. 449) and the labor force participation rates of
married women in such states are higher, which, she argues, may represent an
attempt by married women to self-insure against the possibility of becoming
divorced without compensation (Peters, 1986, pp. 448-449, 451-452). Thus,
both the divorce rates and the distribution of compensation are consistent with
the Coase Theorem. However, a number of subsequent studies find that the
evidence tends to support the conclusion that divorce rates are in fact higher in
unilateral divorce states than in mutual consent states. (See, for example, Allen,
1992; Zelder, 1993a, 1993b; Brinig and Buckley, 1995; Friedberg, 1995,
which also contain numerous citations to literature on both sides of the
argument.) Within this debate, each side claims that the others empirical work
contains errors or biases that influence the results (see, for example, Peters,
1986, 1992; Allen, 1992).
Even if one is willing to accept the result that divorce rates are not impacted
by the legal rules governing divorce, it remains to ascertain whether these
results actually reflect the working of Coase Theorem-type mechanisms. There
is plenty of reason to suggest that the answer is no, or at least not
necessarily. First, there is no evidence to suggest that unilateral divorces are
undertaken only when they are efficient. Rather, Peters infers that the efficiency
proposition holds based on a questionable claim that transaction costs are low
and the fact that the data confirm the models invariance and distribution
predictions. (For contrasting views on the potential magnitude of transaction
costs here, see Peters (1992, p. 690) and Allen (1992, p. 684). Allen (1992,
1995) goes so far as to argue that, by working an uncompensated transfer of
wealth from wives to husbands, the move to no-fault divorce violates the zero
transaction costs/fully-specified rights condition assumed by the Theorem and
thus that the rise in the divorce rate does not constitute a legitimate argument
against the Theorem.) Furthermore, Peters fails to account for the fact that the
Theorem predicts not just an invariant divorce rate, but an invariant allocation
of household resources as well - just as the farmer-rancher example predicts an
invariant allocation of resources devoted to farming and ranching. The fact that
female labor force participation is higher in states with unilateral divorce rules
thus speaks loudly against the claim of invariance.
reasons including, inter alia, precedent and reputation; (iv) cases that involve
an issue that is not easily negotiated over, such as a fundamental value; and
(v) the high transaction costs associated with settlement as compared to going
to trial - factors that lie outside of the bounds of the Coase Theorem. However,
the high proportion of settlements does not imply that the parties have
bargained to the Pareto optimal result contemplated by the Coase Theorem.
There is no way to infer from the settlement data whether the parties have
bargained to the socially optimal result contemplated within a zero transaction
costs world, or if they simply have realized some of the potential gains from
negotiation but hit a point where the transaction costs from further negotiation
exceed the expected gains and choose to settle at a suboptimal outcome
because this settlement, although not optimal, is still better than going to trial.
the differential bonus collection rates among the groups violates the allocative
invariance prediction of the Theorem (Donohue, 1989a, pp. 569-577). Finally,
there was no significant difference in wages across the WPG and EPG hirees,
so that aggregate (wages plus bonus) compensation was higher for WPG
workers than for EPG workers, in violation of the invariant distribution
prediction of the Theorem. That is, it appears that workers did not bargain with
employers over the wage or the bonus as a result of this program (Donohue,
1989a, pp. 586-590).
Donohue (1989a, pp. 591-601) asserts that transaction costs are extremely
low here and thus that the Theorem fails in a case most favorable to its success.
He offers two possible explanations for why the experiment failed to satisfy the
predictions of the Coase Theorem, each of which goes to the issue of individual
behavior/decision making in the context of such bargains. One possibility, to
which Donohue lends a great deal of support, is ignorance on the part of
workers, who seemed not even to realize that bargaining was possible and may
not have understood that the bonuses could aid them in gaining employment.
Moreover, there may have been an authoritarian effect which caused the
workers to believe that the bonus was in effect inalienable - that the party
designated to receive the bonus was in fact entitled to its full value, an effect
that would also discourage the type of bargains envisioned by the Theorem
(Donohue, 1989a, pp. 600-602).
Donohues conclusions regarding the implications of the Illinois experiment
for the Coase Theorems applicability have been challenged by Ellickson
(1989) and Lindgren (1990), both of whom contend that Donohue greatly
underestimates the effect of transaction costs within this experiment. Acquiring
this so-called free money actually involves a substantial number of steps (and
even more for employers than for workers), the aggregate effect of which is to
make the process rather costly, relative to the size of the bonus. Lindgren
(1990, pp. 581-582, 585), for example, lists the steps that participants in the
WPG and EPG programs must go through in order to collect bonuses and offers
several reasons why one would not anticipate an invariant distribution of
income, or bargaining over the bonuses. In fact, Lindgren (1990, p. 583)
suggests that the results do in fact match the predictions of the Coase Theorem
(see also Ellickson, 1989, p. 625).
First, because costs are high relative to the bonuses, the insights underlying
the Coase Theorem would lead one to predict that many workers or employers
who are eligible for bonuses would not collect them. The Illinois study
confirmed this prediction. Second, because costs are higher for employers than
for workers, the insights of the Coase Theorem would lead one to predict that
more workers in the worker-bonus group would be influenced to participate in
the program, obtain work quickly and collect the bonuses. Again, the Illinois
study confirmed these predictions (Lindgren, 1990, p. 583).
0730 The Coase Theorem 871
Indeed, if transaction costs were zero, the entire premise of the experiment
would disappear, since job search is a positive transaction cost phenomenon
(Lindgren, 1990, p. 578). Finally, the presence of stigma and institutional
rigidity effects would lead one to predict minimal bargaining over wages and
bonuses (in an amount different from the control group), a result again
supported by the Illinois experiment. In fact, Ellickson finds the results of the
Illinois experiment very consistent with his own study of Shasta County - that
people often tend to rely on norms rather than legal rules to govern their
behavior, particularly when the stakes are low and there is an expectation of a
continuing relationship, as among neighbors in Shasta County and between
employers and employees in the Illinois experiment (Ellickson, 1989, pp.
627-628).
or on farms employing wage labor, nor is there evidence that the market values
of land under tenant cultivation are lower than the values of land under owner
cultivation (Cheung, 1969a, pp. 56-61, 1980, p. 42). And, while it has been
argued that, under share tenancy, certain types of activities - such as
improvements to farms - would be contracted inadequately or not at all, Cheung
(1980, p. 43) finds that these are precisely the activities stated in every written
contract that I could find. All of this evidence suggests quite strongly that
charges that share tenancy is less efficient that other cultivation arrangements
cannot easily be sustained.
Even though the theory assumes zero transaction costs where transaction
costs are actually positive, it is able to explain much of the observed farming
behavior (Cheung, 1969a, p. 159). In this situation of well-defined property
rights, transaction costs are not so high as to affect resource use at the margin,
but, rather, affect the choice among alternative contractual arrangements - the
use of alternative methods of cultivation reflecting the tradeoff between
coordination costs and risk, each of which varies across alternative contractual
arrangements (Cheung, 1980, p. 44). (For a related discussion, see Cheung,
1969b.) While Cheungs evidence does not conclusively demonstrate the
optimality of share contracts, it certainly does lend strong support for the claim
that, at a minimum, share contracting is no less efficient than other available
contractual arrangements and thus that, under the appropriate (and not
unrealistic) conditions, the mechanisms of the Coase Theorem can lead to a
satisfactory resolution of externality problems through the market.
The other early study by Cheung of the working of Coase Theorem-type
mechanisms is The Fable of the Bees ... (1973), a study which responds to
Meades (1952) classic discussion of the positive reciprocal externalities that
exist between beekeepers and the owners of apple orchards: apple blossoms
provide valuable services to beekeepers, whose bees feed on them, while, at the
same time, bees provide valuable pollination services to the apple-orchard
owner. While Meade argued that a system of taxes and subsidies can and must,
be imposed in order to achieve efficiency, contractual arrangements between
farmers and beekeepers have long been routine in the US and the existence of
a market for nectar and for pollination services can be readily observed in the
state of Washington, the location of Cheungs study - in some cases merely by
consulting the yellow pages of the telephone directory (Cheung, 1973, p. 19).
The question, of course, is whether these markets generate an efficient
allocation of resources. Cheung (1973, pp. 24-28) argued that a presumption
can be established in the affirmative, since available data provides substantial
support for the competitive nature of the market.
How is it that in this externality situation the market avoids the failure
pointed to by Meade? To begin with, transaction costs are very low here. Since
the value of resources devoted to pollination and nectar extraction is
0730 The Coase Theorem 873
insignificant and farmers could easily and cheaply keep bees themselves (and
sometimes do so), the gains from contracting with beekeepers are extremely
small, which, in turn, suggests that contracting costs are minimal (Cheung,
1980, pp. 46-48). There is also a well-developed system of contractual relations
between beekeepers and farmers, so well-developed, in fact, that, while written
contracts (sometimes as simple as postcards) are used to secure an initial
arrangement among the parties, oral agreements are standard for subsequent
relations. Furthermore, these oral contracts are rarely breached, owing to the
presence of extra-legal constraints in the form of sanctions against those who
do not honor their contracts (Cheung, 1973, p. 29). Yet, in spite of the
informality of these contracts, they tend to be quite comprehensive, specifying
the number and strength of the [bee] colonies, the rental fee per hive, the terms
of delivery and removal of hives, the protection of bees from pesticide sprays
and the strategic placing of hives. And, where hives are placed merely for
honey-generating purposes (that is, no pollination is involved), prices (often
paid in honey) are not necessarily fixed - being allowed to vary with the honey
yield (Cheung, 1973, p. 29). All of these various pieces of evidence lead
Cheung to conclude that, contrary to Meades story, the allocation of hives and
nectar flows approximates that of a smoothly functioning market wherein
resources are efficiently allocated (Cheung, 1980, p. 50).
This having been said, Cheung notes that there are two factors which could
potentially complicate these arrangements (relative to standard lease contracts),
both of which relate to other levels of external effects. First, there are potential
spillovers from one farmer contracting for pollination services, which could
potentially lead neighbors to take strategic advantage by employing fewer hives
themselves. Second, the use of pesticide sprays by one farmer may result in
damage to the bees kept on nearby farms. But both of these issues are dealt with
through either custom or explicit contracting (such as the payment of risk
premiums for potential exposure to pesticides), depending on the
circumstances. The reliance on customs here is an interesting parallel to
Ellickson (1986, 1991), discussed above.
It should be obvious that it is not possible to confirm or refute the efficiency
claims made by Cheung and, given this, the results cannot be said to show the
applicability of the Theorem (here, the Stigler, 1966, version) per se. Yet, they
offer important evidence that markets can successfully (if not fully efficiently)
deal with potential externality problems under the appropriate conditions.
874 The Coase Theorem 0730
D. Importance
The importance of the Theorem lies not in whether it is correct, but in the
detailed nature of the assumptions required to make it correct-in that is the
nature of transactions costs. The interesting question about the Theorem then
is the nature of the transactions costs associated with those situations in which
the theorem is thought to not be correct. The legacy of the Theorem lies in the
subsequent work attempting to detail the nature of transaction costs and their
effect on the workings of the economic system. The richness and variety of
types of economic arrangements can now be seen in the richness and variety of
transaction costs and in mechanisms for reducing them.
In this sense the importance of the Coase Theorem lies not in its supposed
correctness or incorrectness and the corresponding policy relevance or lack
thereof, but, rather, in the positive transactions cost propositions that flow from
it. These include both normative and positive propositions. Examples are
Posners (1992, p. 52) normative suggestion that at law [s]ince transactions are
never costless in the real world, efficiency is promoted by assigning the legal
right to the party who would buy it ... if it were assigned initially to the other
party and the positive prediction of Lesser, Dobbs and Zerbe (1997) that suits
at law in situations where negotiation costs are low will involve considerations
of distribution not efficiency.
The Coase Theorem has helped to give rise to an extensive body of work,
much of it summarized by Eggertsson (1990), concerned with economic
behavior and institutions and to a more detailed and useful sense of what is
meant by property. The Coase Theorem has made clearer the relationship
between transactions cost and property rights and in doing so has begun to give
a much stronger basis for understanding how legal regimes change in response
to changes in constraints (North, 1981). One can now define the strength of
property rights in terms of lower transaction costs for the exclusion, exchange
and use of property.
In part of the economics literature at least (Eggertsson, 1990) the
transactions cost approach has replaced the market failure model of public
intervention that is expressed by Weimer and Vining (1992, p. 30):
Here is a later example of government service: lighthouses. These save lives and
cargoes; but lighthouse keepers cannot reach out to collect fees from skippers. So,
says the advanced treatise, we have a divergence between private advantage and
money cost ... and true social advantage and cost ... Philosophers and statesmen
have always recognized the necessary role of government in such cases of
external-economy divergence between private and social advantage.
10. Conclusion
In light of the foregoing discussion, three things can be said about the Coase
Theorem. First, it is correct, in the sense that it has withstood all of the
challenges mounted against it to date. Efficiency will obtain, regardless of the
initial assignment of rights and the result will be invariant keeping in mind that
even income effects are irrelevant if one accepts the Barzel/Allen definition of
zero transaction costs. Second, the Theorem, although correct, is unrealistic,
as Coase recognized (see Coase 1960, p. 15, 1981, p. 187, 1988a, pp. 174-179).
The latter point, of course, should have been obvious from the beginning, which
876 The Coase Theorem 0730
raises the question as to why the debate over the Theorem has been so intense.
A small part of the answer, within the economics profession at least, may lie
in the interesting theoretical puzzle that the Theorem poses. Dwarfing this,
however, is the normative debate that, implicitly or explicitly, pervades nearly
all aspects of the Theorems discussion.
Three prescriptions for legal-economic policy are said to flow from the
Coase Theorem.
But the Coase Theorem says none of these things. The Theorem is a positive
statement with no normative implications; it is an is statement, not an ought
statement. Each of the above propositions rests on the assumption that
efficiency is the goal of legal-economic policy. But the Coase Theorem goes
merely to the presence of absence of efficiency; it does not tell us that it is all
that matters or even that it matters at all. It is this normative leap that seems
to underlie most of the hostility to the Coase Theorem - and, by extension, to
law and economics generally. (See, for example, Baker, 1975; Kelman, 1979;
the Symposium on Efficiency as a Legal Concern, 1980; A Response to the
Efficiency Symposium, 1980; Schlag, 1986; Gjerdingen, 1986; Johnston, 1990
and Crespi, 1991.) For a response to these types of criticisms see Zerbe (1998a).
Compounding the hostility to the normative use of the Coase Theorem are the
use of incorrect definitions of economic efficiency by proponents of law and
economics (Zerbe, 1998b).
Furthermore, even if one takes efficiency to be the goal of legal-economic
policy, the Coase Theorem does nothing to establish the sanctity of property
and contract or the superiority of the market over Pigouvian remedies, owing
to the ubiquitous nature of transaction costs. If coordination is costless, the
market will optimally allocate rights and resources, but so too will Pigouvian
remedies. On the other hand, the Pigouvians fare no better in this debate since,
after waving away the Coase Theorem on the grounds that transaction costs are
positive, they tend to immediately fall back on the demonstration that
Pigouvian remedies generate socially optimal outcomes, using models in which
0730 The Coase Theorem 877
government is assumed to operate with full information and without cost. (But
see Baumol, 1972, for a more judicious evaluation of Pigouvian remedies.)
Here, we come to the true import of the Coase Theorem. The Theorem is
not, in the end, about markets or about costless bargaining; rather, it is about
the costs of coordination. If coordination is costless, markets function perfectly;
but so does government. If coordination is costly, markets function imperfectly;
but so does government. The task for legal-economic policy thus becomes that
of ascertaining the magnitude and influence of these costs and the resulting
implications for alternative institutional-policy arrangements. The true and
valuable legacy of the Theorem is all of the subsequent work on transactions
costs that explore the costs of coordination under different regimes and in
different situations. Like the Coase Theorem itself, this, too, is without direct
normative implications. However, it has led to certain normative claims, as
noted above. One, from an analytical perspective, is that the received
conception of externalities should be abandoned. Another, this time from a
policy perspective, is that judgments as to the appropriate form of government
intervention should be made on the basis of what institutional arrangement
produces the lowest combination of coordination costs. In this regard, it is
interesting to note that much of the normative debate and the propositions we
noted above in that regard can be turned into a series of positive predictions
about which arrangements will promote economic efficiency. Where the
affected parties could reach a solution through negotiation but choose litigation
or regulation, the real issue is likely to be who is to be assigned property rights
rather than how to realize gains from trade (see, for example, Lesser, Dobbs
and Zerbe, 1997).
Finally, the meaningfulness of the Coase Theorem must be understood in
epistemological terms. The correctness of the Theorem is a matter of logical
validity; in general, the Theorem is a conclusion derived from premises and the
role of the assumptions constituting its premises is to rule out of consideration
all those variables which would prevent the derivation of the conclusion as a
matter of logic. The validity of the Theorem, therefore, is a function of the
assumptions defining away certain limiting conditions. The empirical truth of
the Theorem - its descriptive accuracy - is a separate matter from its logical
validity. The Theorem considered empirically is a tendency statement, a
statement that under certain conditions such and such behavior and allocative
and so on results can be expected; that is, a law in the Marshallian sense.
However, the logical and empirical aspects are closely related to one another
in that changing the assumptional conditions of the Theorem is tantamount to
changing the conditions in terms of which the Theorem is a tendency
statement. The Theorem is a tendency or probability statement in a further
empirical sense, to wit: the experimental literature indicates that the results
expected on the basis of certain specifications of the Theorem are realized
something less than one hundred percent of the time.
878 The Coase Theorem 0730
Given the foregoing, it becomes clear that much of the literature on the
Coase Theorem not only overreaches in terms of the normative implications
more or less improperly drawn from the Theorem, but fails to specify the
meaningfulness of the Theorem in such terms - readily leading to practices
which make claims for and take the Theorem far beyond what logicality and
empiricism permit.
Acknowledgments
The authors would like to thank Douglas Allen, James Buchanan, Robert
Cooter, Robert Ellickson, Elizabeth Hoffman, Richard Posner, Warren Samuels
and participants in the Workshop in the History of Economic Thought and
Methodology at Michigan State University for comments and suggestions on
previous drafts of this chapter and for helping to clarify our thinking on certain
points raised herein. The excellent research assistance of Mary Therese Cogeos
is also gratefully acknowledged. Of course, the authors are solely responsible
for any remaining errors.
Aivazian, Varouj A. and Callen, Jeffrey L. (1980), Uncertain Externalities, Liability Rules and
Resource Allocation: Comment, 70 American Economic Review, 1058-1059.
Aivazian, Varouj A. and Callen, Jeffrey L. (1981), The Coase Theorem and the Empty Core, 24
Journal of Law and Economics, 175-181.
Aivazian, Varouj A., Callen, Jeffrey L. and Lipnowski, Irwin F. (1987), The Coase Theorem and
Coalitional Stability, 54 Economica, 517-520.
Allen, Douglas W. (1991), What are Transaction Costs?, 14 Research in Law and Economics, 1-18.
Allen, Douglas W. (1992), Marriage and Divorce: Comment, 82 American Economic Review,
679-685.
Allen, Douglas W. (1995), Property Rights, Transaction Costs and Coase: One More Time, in
Medema, Steven G. (ed.), Coasean Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1969), The Organization of Economic Activity: Issues Pertinent to the Choice of
Market versus Nonmarket Allocation, in X (ed.), Joint Economic Committee, 91st Congress of
the United States, 1st Session.
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1979), The Property Rights Doctrine and Demand Revelation under Incomplete
Information, in Boskin, Michael J. (ed.), Economics and Human Welfare: Essays in Honor of
Tibor Scitovsky, New York, Academic Press, 23-39.
Ayres, Ian and Talley, Eric (1995a), Distinguishing Between Consensual and Nonconsensual
Advantages of Liability Rules, 105 Yale Law Journal, 235-253.
Ayres, Ian and Talley, Eric (1995b), Solomonic Bargaining: Dividing a Legal Entitlement to Facilitate
Coasean Trade, 104 Yale Law Journal, 1027-1117.
0730 The Coase Theorem 879
Azqueta, Diego (1993), The Coase Theorem and Environmental Economics: A Survey of Some
Unsettled Issues, 10 Revista Espaola de Economia, 59-71.
Baker, C. Edwin (1975), The Ideology of the Economic Analysis of Law, 5 Philosophy and Public
Affairs, 3-48.
Barzel, Yoram (1989), Economic Analysis of Property Rights, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press, 122 p.
Baumol, William J. (1972), On Taxation and the Control of Externalities, 62 American Economic
Review, 307-322.
Besen, Stanley M., Manning, Willard G., Jr and Mitchell, Bridger M. (1978), Copyright Liability for
Cable Television: Compulsory Licensing and the Coase Theorem, 21 Journal of Law and
Economics, 67-95.
Bigelow, John Payne (1993), Inducing Efficiency: Externalities, Missing Markets and the Coase
Theorem, 34 International Economic Review, 335-346.
Boettke, Peter J. (1989), Information and the Coase Theorem: Comment, 3 Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 195-198.
Boitani, Andrea and Grillo, Michele (1992), Some Reflections on Externalities, Coase Theorem and
the Endogenous Determination of Property Rights, 43 Metroeconomica, 309-326.
Boyd, J.H. and Mohring, H. (1971), Externalities: Direct Interaction vs. Asset Utilization
Frameworks, 38 Economica, 347-361.
Bramhall, David F. and Mills, Edwin S. (1966), A Note on the Asymmetry Between Fees and
Payments, 2 Water Resources Research, 615-616.
Brinig, Margaret F. and Buckley, Francis H. (1995), Divorce, Legal Rules and Free Spirits, Mimeo,
George Mason University School of Law.
Buchanan, James M. (1973a), The Institutional Structure of Externality, 28 Public Choice, 69-82.
Buchanan, James M. (1973b), The Coase Theorem and the Theory of the State, 13 Natural
Resources Journal, 579-594.
Buchanan, James M. (1983), Rights, Efficiency and Exchange: The Irrelevance of Transaction Costs,
in Neumann, M. (ed.), Ansprache, Eigentums- und Verfagngsrechte, Schriften des Vereins far
Socialpolitik, Berlin, Duncker and Humblot, 9-24. Reprinted in Liberty, Market and State,
Harvester Press, 1986, 97-107. Reprinted in Medema, S.G. (ed.) (1995), The Legacy of Ronald
Coase in Economic Analysis, Volume II, Chapter 8, 175-190, Aldershot: Edward Elgar.
Buchanan, James M. and Faith, Roger L. (1981), Entrepreneurship and the Internalization of
Externalities, 24 Journal of Law and Economics, 95-111.
Buchanan, James M. and Stubblebine, W. Craig (1962), Externality, 29 Economica, 371-384.
Burrows, Paul (1970), On External Costs and the Visible Arm of Law, 22 Oxford Economic Papers,
39-56.
Calabresi, Guido (1965), The Decision for Accidents: An Approach to Non-Fault Allocation for
Costs, 78 Harvard Law Review, 713-745.
Calabresi, Guido (1968), Transaction Costs, Resource Allocation and Liability Rules: A Comment,
11 Journal of Law and Economics, 67-73.
Calabresi, Guido (1991), The Pointlessness of Pareto: Carrying Coase Further, 100 Yale Law
Journal, 1211-1237.
880 The Coase Theorem 0730
Calabresi, Guido and Melamed, A. Douglas (1972), Property Rules, Liability Rules and Inalienability:
One View of the Cathedral, 85 Harvard Law Review, 1089-1128. Reprinted in Ackerman, Bruce
A. (ed.), Economic Foundations of Property Law, Boston, Little Brown, 1975, 31-48.
Campbell, David (1996), On What is Valuable in Law and Economics, 8 Otago Law Review,
489-514.
Canterbery, E. Ray and Marvasti, A. (1992), The Coase Theorem as a Negative Externality, 26
Journal of Economic Issues, 1179-1189.
Chapman, Bruce (1982), Individual Rights and Collective Rationality: Some Implications for
Economic Analysis of Law, 10 Hofstra Law Review, 455-481.
Chari, V. and Jones, L.R. (1991), A Reconsideration of the Problem of Social Cost: Free Riders and
Monopolists, July, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Staff Report, 59 ff.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1969a), The Theory of Share Tenancy, Chicago, IL, University of Chicago
Press, 188 p.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1969b), Transaction Costs, Risk Aversion and the Choice of Contractual
Arrangements, 12 Journal of Law and Economics, 23-42.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1970), The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of a Non-exclusive
Resource, 13 Journal of Law and Economics, 49-70.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1973), The Fable of the Bees: An Economic Investigation, 16 Journal of Law
and Economics, 11-33.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1974), A Theory of Price Control, 17 Journal of Law and Economics, 53-71.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1978), The Myth of Social Costs: A Critique of Welfare Economics and the
Implications for Public Policy, London, Institute of Economic Affairs, 93 p.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1980), The Myth of Social Cost, San Francisco, Cato Institute.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1983), The Contractual Nature of the Firm, 26 Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-21.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1992), On the New Institutional Economics, in Werin, Lars and Wijkander,
Hans (eds), Contract Economics, Oxford, Basil Blackwell, 48-65.
Coase, Ronald H. (1937), The Nature of the Firm, 4 Economica, 368-405.
Coase, Ronald H. (1959), The Federal Communications Commission, 2 Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-40.
Coase, Ronald H. (1960), The Problem of Social Cost, 3 Journal of Law and Economics, 1-44.
Reprinted in Ackermann, Bruce A. (1975), Economic Foundations of Property Law, Boston,
Little Brown, 17-22. Reprinted in Medema, Steven G. (1995), The Legacy of Ronald Coase in
Economic Analysis, Vol. 2, Aldershot, Edward Elgar Publishing, 5-48. Reprinted in Coase, Ronald
H. (1988), The Firm, the Market and the Law, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Coase, Ronald H. (1974a), The Lighthouse in Economics, 23 Journal of Law and Economics,
357-376.
Coase, Ronald H. (1974b), The Choice of the Institutional Framework: A Comment, 17 Journal of
Law and Economics, 493-496.
Coase, Ronald H. (1981), The Coase Theorem and the Empty Core: A Comment, 24 Journal of Law
and Economics, 183-187.
Coase, Ronald H. (1988a), The Firm, the Market and the Law, Chicago, IL, University of Chicago
Press, 217 p.
0730 The Coase Theorem 881
Coase, Ronald H. (1988b), Blackmail (The 1987 McCorkle Lecture), 74 Virginia Law Review,
655-676.
Coase, Ronald H. (1991), The Institutional Structure of Production, in Coase, Ronald H. (ed.), Essays
on Economics and Economists, Chicago, IL, University of Chicago Press.
Coase, Ronald H. (1993), Law and Economics at Chicago, 36 Journal of Law and Economics,
239-254.
Coelho, Philip R.P. (1975), Externalities, Separability and Resource Allocation: Comment, 65
American Economic Review, 721-723.
Cohen, David and Knetsch, Jack (1992), Judicial Choice and Disparities Between Measures of
Economic Values, 30 Osgoode Hall Law Journal, 131 ff.
Cooter, Robert D. (1980), How the Law Circumvents Starrets Nonconvexity, 22 Journal of
Economic Theory, 499-504.
Cooter, Robert D. (1982), The Cost of Coase, 11 Journal of Legal Studies, 1-33. Reprinted in
Donahue, Charles Jr, Kauper, Thomas E. and Martin, Peter W. (eds) (1992), Property: An
Introduction to the Concept and the Institution. Reprinted in Ackerman, Bruce, Ellickson, Robert
and Rose, Carol (eds) (1995), Foundations of Property Law. Reprinted in Medema, Steven G.
(ed.) (1995), The Legacy of Ronald Coase in Economic Analysis, Aldershot, Edward Elgar
Publishing, 96-128.
Cooter, Robert D. (1987), The Coase Theorem, in Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray and Newman,
Peter (eds), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, London, Macmillan, 457-460.
Reprinted in The New Palgrave World of Economics (forthcoming).
Cooter, Robert D. (1989), The Coase Theorem, in Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray and Newman,
Peter (eds), The New Palgrave: Allocation, Information and Markets, New York, W.W. Norton,
64-70.
Cooter, Robert D. and Ulen, Thomas S. (1988), Law and Economics, Glenview, IL, Scott, Foresman
and Company.
Cooter, Robert D., Marks, Stephen and Mnookin, Robert H. (1982), Bargaining in the Shadow of the
Law: A Testable Model of Strategic Behavior, 11 Journal of Legal Studies, 225-251.
Cotter, Thomas F. (1995), Owning What Doesnt Exist, Where it Doesnt Exist: Rethinking Two
Doctrines from the Common Law of Trademarks, 3 University of Illinois Law Review, 487-541.
Cotter, Thomas F. (1996), Legal Pragmatism and the Law and Economics Movement, 84
Georgetown Law Journal, 2071-2141.
Coursey, Don L. and Stanley, L.R. (1988), Pretrial Bargaining Behavior within the Shadow of the
Law: Theory and Experimental Evidence, 8 International Review of Law and Economics,
161-179.
Coursey, Don L., Hoffman, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1987), Fear and Loathing in the Coase
Theorem: Experimental Tests Involving Physical Discomfort, 16 Journal of Legal Studies,
217-248.
Crain, W. Mark, Saurman, David S. and Tollison, Robert D. (1978), The Coase Theorem and Quasi
Rents: Correcting the Record, 6 Public Finance Quarterly, 259-262.
Crespi, Gregory Scott (1991), The Mid-Life Crisis of the Law and Economics Movement: Confronting
the Problems of Nonfalsifiability and Normative Bias, 67 Notre Dame Law Review, 231-252.
882 The Coase Theorem 0730
dArge, Ralph C. (1973), Coase Theorem Symposium, 13 Natural Resources Journal, 557-560.
Dahlman, Carl J. (1979), The Problem of Externality, 22 Journal of Law and Economics, 141-162.
Daly, George (1974), The Coase Theorem: Assumptions, Applications and Ambiguities, 12
Economic Inquiry, 203-213.
Daly, George and Giertz, J. Fred (1975), Externalities, Extortion and Efficiency, 65 American
Economic Review, 997-1001.
Davis, Otto A. and Whinston Andrew B. (1962), Externalities, Welfare and the Theory of Games, 70
Journal of Political Economy, 241-262.
Davis, Otto A. and Whinston Andrew B. (1965), Some Notes on Equating Private and Social Cost,
32 Southern Economic Journal, 113-126.
De Bornier, Jean Magnan (1986), The Coase Theorem and the Empty Core: A Re-examination, 6
International Review of Law and Economics, 265-271.
Demsetz, Harold (1971), Theoretical Efficiency in Pollution Control: Comments on Comments, 9
Western Economic Journal, 444-446.
Demsetz, Harold (1972a), When Does the Rule of Liability Matter?, 1 Journal of Legal Studies,
13-28.
Demsetz, Harold (1972b), Wealth Distribution and the Ownership of Rights, 1 Journal of Legal
Studies, 223-232.
Demsetz, Harold (1978), On Extortion: A Reply, 68 American Economic Review, 417-418.
DeSerpa, Allan C. (1977), The Coase Theorem: A Diagrammatic Presentation,15 Economic Inquiry,
600-604.
DeSerpa, Allan C. (1992), The Pure Economics of the Coase Theorem, 18 Eastern Economic
Journal, 287-304.
Dick, Daniel T. (1976), The Voluntary Approach to Externality Problems: A Survey of the Critics,
2 Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 185-195.
Dolbear, F. Trenery, Jr (1967), On the Theory of Optimum Externality, 57 American Economic
Review, 90-103.
Dolbear, F. Trenery, Jr (1974), Externalities as Commodities: Comment, 64 American Economic
Review, 341-343.
Donohue, John J. III (1988), Law and Economics: The Road not Taken, 22 Law and Society Review,
903-926.
Donohue, John J. III (1989a), Diverting the Coasian River: Incentive Schemes to Reduce
Unemployment Spells, 99 Yale Law Journal, 549-609.
Donohue, John J. III (1989b), Reply to Professors Ellickson and Stigler, 99 Yale Law Journal,
635-636.
Eggertsson, Thrainn (1990), Economic Behaviour and Institutions, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press, 385 p.
Ellickson, Robert C. (1986), Of Coase and Cattle: Dispute Resolution among Neighbors in Shasta
County, 38 Stanford Law Review, 623-687. Reprinted in 18 Land Use and Environment Law
Review, 1987, 79-143.
Ellickson, Robert C. (1989), The Case for Coase and Against Coaseanism, 99 Yale Law Journal,
611-630.
Ellickson, Robert C. (1991), Order Without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes, Cambridge, MA,
Harvard University Press.
0730 The Coase Theorem 883
Endres, Alfred (1976), Das Coase-Theorem bei langfristiger Betrachtung (The Coase Theorem in a
Long Term Perspective), 27 Jahrbuch fr Sozialwissenschaft, 430-433.
Endres, Alfred (1977), Die Coase-Kontroverse (The Coase Controversy),133 Journal of Institutional
and Theoretical Economics, 637-651.
Farrell, Joseph (1987), Information and the Coase Theorem, 1 Journal of Economic Perspectives,
113-129.
Farrell, Joseph (1990), Information and the Coase Theorem, in Baker, Samuel H. and Elliot,
Catherine S. (eds), Readings in public Sector Economics, Lexington, MA and Toronto, D.C.,
Heath and Company, 165-174.
Faure, Michael G. (1986), Commentaar bij de Paper van Dr.Jan C. Bongaerts: Coase en
Produktenaansprakelijkheid (Comment on the paper of Dr. Jan C. Bongaerts: Coase and Product
Liability), in Van Den Bergh, Roger (ed.), Verslagboek Eerste Werkvergadering Recht en
Economie, Antwerpen, Handelshogeschool, 31-37.
Feldman, Robert (1974), Liability Rules and the Transfer of Economic Rents, 3 Journal of Legal
Studies, 499-508.
Fischel, William A. (1978), A Property Rights Approach to Municipal Zoning, 54 Land Economics,
54-81. Reprinted in Beaton, Patrick W. (ed.) (1983), Municipal Expenditures, Revenues and
Services, New Brunswick, Rutgers University Center for Urban Policy Research.
Fischel, William A. (1985), The Economics of Zoning Laws: A Property Rights Approach to
American Land Use Controls, Baltimore, MD, John Hopkins University Press, 372 p.
Fischer, Stanley (1977), Long Term Contracting, Sticky Prices and Monetary Policy, 3 Journal of
Monetary Economics, 317-323.
Frank, Robert H. (1991), Microeconomics and Behavior, New York, London, Montreal and Sydney,
McGraw Hill, 694 p.
Frech, H. Edward III (1973), Pricing of Pollution: The Coase Theorem in the Long Run, 4 Bell
Journal of Economics and Management Science, 316-319.
Frech, H. Edward III (1973), Biological Externalities and Evolution: A Comment, 39 Journal of
Theoretical Biology, 669-672.
Frech, H. Edward III (1979), The Extended Coase Theorem and Long Run Equilibrium: The
Non-Equivalence of Liability Rules and Property Rights, 27 Economic Inquiry, 254-268.
Frey, Bruno S. (1993), Review of: Environment and Economy: Property Rights and Public Policy,
31 Journal of Economic Literature, 1442-1443.
Friedberg, Leora (1995), Did No-Fault Divorce Raise Divorce Rates? Evidence from Panel Data,
Working Paper, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Furubotn, Eirik G. (1995), Income Transfers, Entrepreneurial Effort and the Coase Theorem: The Case
for Efficiency Reconsidered, 2 European Journal of Law and Economics, 99-118.
Ghosh, Shubha (1997), Takings, the Exit Option and Just Compensation, 17 International Review
of Law and Economics, 157-176.
Gifford, Adam, Jr (1974), Externalities and the Coase Theorem: A Graphical Analysis, 14 Quarterly
Review of Economics and Business, 7-21.
Gifford, Adam, Jr (1975), Externalities, Liability, Separability and Resource Allocation: Comment,
65 American Economic Review, 724-727.
884 The Coase Theorem 0730
Gifford, Adam, Jr and Stone, Courtney C. (1973), Externalities, Liability and the Coase Theorem: A
Mathematical Analysis, 11 Western Economic Journal, 260-269.
Gjerdingen, Donald H. (1983), The Coase Theorem and the Psychology of Common Law Thought,
56 Southern California Law Review, 711-760.
Gjerdingen, Donald H. (1986), The Politics of the Coase Theorem and its Relationship to Modern
Legal Thought, 35 Buffalo Law Review, 871-935.
Glanter, Marc (1983), Reading the Landscape of Disputes: What we Know and Dont Know (and
Think we Dont Know) about Our Allegedly Contentious and Litigious Society, 31 UCLA Law
Review, 4-71.
Goldberg, Victor P. (1974), Institutional Change and the Quasi-Invisible Hand, 17 Journal of Law
and Economics, 461-492. Reprinted in Goldberg, Victor P. (ed.) (1989), Readings in the
Economics of Contract Law, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 169-173.
Gould, J.R. (1973), Meade on External Economies: Should the Beneficiaries be Taxed?, 16 Journal
of Law and Economics, 53-66.
Gould, J.R. (1975), Mohring and Boyds Objection to the Coase Theorem: A Note, 42 Economica,
203-206.
Grady, Mark F. (1988), Common Law Control of Strategic Behavior: The Railroad and the Farmer,
17 Journal of Legal Studies, 15-42.
Greenwood, Peter H. and Ingene, Charles A. (1978), Uncertain Externalities, Liability Rules and
Resources Allocation, 68 American Economic Review, 300-310.
Greenwood, Peter H. and Ingene, Charles A. (1980), Reply, 70 American Economic Review,
1060-1063.
Greenwood, Peter H., Ingene, Charles A. and Horsfied, James (1975), Externalities, Separability and
Resource Allocation, 65 American Economic Review, 728-729.
Guellec, Dominique (1995), Externalites et Asymetries dInformation dans un Modele de Croissance
(With English summary) (Externalities and Information Asymmetry in a Model of Growth), 46(3)
Revue Economique, 837-846.
Hamilton, Jonathan H., Sheshinski, Eytan and Slutsky, Steven M. (1989), Production Externalities and
Long-run Equilibria: Bargaining and Pigovian Taxation, 27 Economic Inquiry, 453-471.
Hanemann, W. Michael (1991), Willingness to Pay and Willingness to Accept: How Much Can They
Differ?, 81 American Economic Review, 635-647.
Hanley, Nick and Sumner, Charles (1995), Bargaining Over Common Property Resources: Applying
the Coase Theorem to Red Deer in the Scottish Highlands, 43 Journal of Environmental
Management, 87-95.
Hansmann, Henry B. (1977), The Coase Proposition, Information Constraints and Long-Run
Equilibrium: Comment, 67 American Economic Review, 459-461.
Harris, Frederick H. (1990), Economic Negligence, Moral Hazard and the Coase Theorem, 56(3)
Southern Economic Journal, 698-704.
Harrison, Glenn W. and McKee, Michael (1985), Experimental Evaluation of the Coase Theorem,
28 Journal of Law and Economics, 653-670.
Harrison, Glenn W., Hoffman, Elizabeth, Rustrom, E.E. and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1987), Coasian
Solutions to the Externality Problem in Experimental Markets, 97 Economic Journal, 388-402.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1991), Ronald H. Coase: Nobel Oikonomikon 1991, 68 Epikentra, 77-84.
0730 The Coase Theorem 885
Head, John G. (1974), Public Policies and Pollution Problems, 33 Finanzarchiv, 1-29.
Hellner, Jan (1978), Rttsekonomi, avbestllning och Coase-teorem (Law and Economics,
Cancellation and Coase Theorem), 24 Juridiska Freningen i Lund, 101 p.
Hoffman, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1982), The Coase Theorem: Some Experimental Tests,
25 Journal of Law and Economics, 73-98.
Hoffman, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1985), Entitlements, Rights and Fairness: An
Experimental Examination of Subjects Concepts of Distributive Justice, 14 Journal of Legal
Studies, 259-297.
Hoffman, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1986), Experimental Tests of the Coase Theorem with
Large Bargaining Groups, 15 Journal of Legal Studies, 149-171.
Hoffman, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1993), Willingness to Pay vs. Willingness to Accept:
Legal and Economic Implications, 71 Washington University Law Quarterly, 59-114.
Hoffman, Philip T. (1989), Institutions and Agriculture in Old Regime France, 145 Journal of
Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 166-181.
Holderness, Clifford G. (1989), The Assignment of Rights, Entry Effects and the Allocation of
Resources, 18 Journal of Legal Studies, 181-189.
Homa, M. (1974), Tentative Note on Liability Rules under the Coase System, 24 Osaka Economic
Papers, 86-97.
Hovenkamp, Herbert J. (1990), Marginal Utility and the Coase Theorem, 75 Cornell Law Review,
783-810.
Hsiung, Bingyuang (1993), The Scale of the Market and the Scale of the Heart: Reconciling Coase and
Buchanan on the Coase Theorem (In Chinese, with English summary), 21 Academia Economic
Papers, 331-356.
Illing, Gerhard (1992), Private Information as Transaction Costs: The Coase Theorem Revisited, 148
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 558-576.
Inada, Ken I. and Kuga, Kigoshi (1973), Limitations of the Coase Theorem on Liability Rules,
6 Journal of Economic Theory, 606-613.
Jaffe, Jeffrey F. (1975), The Coase Theorem: A Reexamination Comment, 89 Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 660-661.
Johansen, L. (1979), The Bargaining Society and the Inefficiency of Bargaining, 32 Kyklos, 497-521.
Johnson, David B. (1973), Meade, Bees and Externalities, 16 Journal of Law and Economics, 35-52.
Johnston, Jason Scott (1990), Law, Economics and Post-Realist Explanation, 24 Law and Society
Review, 1217-1254.
Jung, Chulho et al. (1995), The Coase Theorem in a Rent Seeking Society, 15 International Review
of Law and Economics, 259-268.
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos (1979), Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under
Risk, 47 Econometrica, 263-291.
Kahneman, Daniel, Knetsch, Jack L. and Thaler, Richard H. (1990), Experimental Tests of the
Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem, 98 Journal of Political Economy, 1325-1348.
Reprinted in Thaler, Richard H. (ed.) (1991),Quasi Rational Economics, New York, Russell Sage
Foundation, 167-188.
Kamien, M.I., Schwartz, Nancy L. and Dolbear, F. Trenery, Jr (1966), Asymmetry Between Bribes
and Charges, 2 Water Resources Research, 147-157.
886 The Coase Theorem 0730
Kaplow, Louis and Shavell, Steven (1995), Do Liability Rules Facilitate Bargaining? A Reply to
Ayres and Talley, 105 Yale Law Journal, 221-233.
Kaplow, Louis and Shavell, Steven (1996), Property Rules versus Liability Rules: An Economic
Analysis, 109 Harvard Law Review, 713-790.
Kelman, Mark G. (1979), Consumption Theory, Production Theory and Ideology in the Coase
Theorem, 52 Southern California Law Review, 669-698.
Kelman, Mark G. (1980), Spitzer and Hoffman on Coase: A Brief Rejoinder, 53 Southern California
Law Review, 1215-1223.
Kelman, Mark G. (1985), Comment (on Hoffman and Spitzers Experimental Law and Economics),
85 Columbia Law Review, 1037-1047.
Kessel, Reuben A. (1974), Transfused Blood, Serum Hepatitis and the Coase Theorem, 17 Journal
of Law and Economics, 265-289.
Kneese, Allan V. and Maller, Koran G. (1973), Bribes and Charges in Pollution Control: An Aspect
of the Coase Controversy, 13 Natural Resources Journal, 677-704.
Labus Miroljub (1995), Osnovi Ekonomije: Savremene Teorije i Primena (Foundation Economics:
Contemporary Theories and Application), Jugoslovenska knjiga, Belgrade.
Ledebut, L.C. (1967), The Problem of Social Cost, 26 American Journal of Economics and
Sociology, 399-415.
Lesser, Jonathan A., Dobbs, Daniel and Zerbe, Richard O., Jr (1997), Environmental Economics,
Boston, Addison Wesley.
Levy, Daniel S. and Friedman, David D. (1994), The Revenge of the Redwoods? Reconsidering
Property Rights and the Economic Allocation of Natural Resources, 61 University of Chicago
Law Review, 493-526.
Liebermann, Yehoshua (1981), The Coase Theorem in Jewish Law, 10 Journal of Legal Studies,
293-303.
Liebhafsky, Harold H. (1973), The Problem of Social Cost: An Alternative Approach, 13 Natural
Resources Journal, 615-676.
Lindgren, James (1989), Blackmail: On Waste, Morals and Ronald Coase, 36 UCLA Law Review,
597-608.
Lindgren, James (1990), Ol Man River, ... He Keeps on Rollin Along: A Reply to Donohues
Diverting the Coasean River, 78 Georgetown Law Journal, 577-591.
Littlechild, Stephen C. (1978), The Problem of Social Cost, in Spadaro, Louis M. (ed.), New
Directions in Austrian Economics, Kansas City, Sheed. Andres & McMeel, 77-93.
Macey, Jonathan R. (1988), Transaction Costs and the Normative Elements of the Public Choice
Model: An Application to Constitutional Theory, 74 Virginia Law Review, 471-518.
Magnan De Bornier, Jean (1986), The Coase Theorem and the Empty Core: A Re-examination, 6
International Review of Law and Economics, 265-271.
Mailath, George J. and Postlewaite, Andrew (1990), Asymmetric Information Bargaining Problems
with Many Agents, 57 Review of Economic Studies, 351-367.
Majone, Giandomenico (1995), The Development of Social Regulation in the European Community:
Policy Externalities, Transaction Costs, Motivational Factors, 50 Aussenwirtschaft, 79-109.
Maloney, Michael T. (1977), The Coase Theorem and Long Run Industry Equilibrium: Note, 17
Quarterly Review of Economics and Business, 113-118.
Marchand, James R. and Russell, Keith P. (1973), Externalities, Liability, Separability and Resource
Allocation, 63 American Economic Review, 611-620.
0730 The Coase Theorem 887
Marchand, James R. and Russell, Keith P. (1975), Externalities, Liability, Separability and Resource
Allocation: Reply, 65 American Economic Review, 730-732.
Martins, Manuel Victor (1992), Ronald Coase: Na Fronteira de Economia e do Direito, 2 Sub Judice,
29-30.
McEwin, R. Ian (1981), Liability Rules, Insurance and the Coase Theorem, 6 Australian Journal of
Management, 103-117.
Meade, James E. (1952), External Economies and Diseconomies in a Competitive Situation, 62
Economic Journal, 54-67.
Medema, Steven G. (1994), Ronald H. Coase, London, Macmillan.
Medema, Steven G. (1995a), Through A Glass Darkly, or Just Wearing Dark Glasses? Posin, Coase
and the Coase Theorem, 62 Tennessee Law Review, 1041-1056.
Medema, Steven G. (1995b), The Legacy of Ronald Coase in Economic Analysis. 2 vols, Aldershot,
Edward Elgar.
Medema, Steven G. (1996a), The Coase Theorem, in Coopera and Argyris (eds), The Encyclopedia
of Managerial Economics, Oxford, Basil Blackwell.
Medema, Steven G. (1996b), Comment: The Coase Theorem, Rent Seeking and the Forgotten
Footnote, 17 International Review of Law and Economics, 177-178.
Medema, Steven G. (1996), Of Pangloss, Pigouvians and Pragmatism: Ronald Coase on Social Cost
Analysis, 18 Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 96-114.
Medema, Steven G. (1997a), The Trial of Homo Economicus: What Law and Economics Tells Us
about the Future of Economic Imperialism, 27 New Economics and its Writing: History of
Political Economy Annual Supplement, forthcoming.
Medema, Steven G. (1997b), The Coase Theorem, Rent Seeking and the Forgotten Footnote, 17
International Review of Law and Economics, 177-178.
Meran, Georg and Wolfstetter, Elmar (1987), Optimal Risk Shifting vs Efficient Employment in
Illyria: The Labor Managed Firm under Asymmetric Information, 11 Journal of Comparative
Economics, 163-179.
Miceli, Thomas J. and Sirmans, C.F. (1995), The Economics of Land Transfer and Title Insurance,
10 Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 81-88.
Mishan, Ezra J. (1965), Reflections on Recent Developments in the Concept of External Effects, 31
Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 3-34.
Mishan, Ezra J. (1967), Pareto Optimality and the Law, 19 Oxford Economic Papers, 255-287.
Mishan, Ezra J. (1971), The Post-war Literature on Externalities: An Interpretative Essay, 9 Journal
of Economic Literature, 1-28.
Mishan, Ezra J. (1974), The Economics of Disamenity, 14 Natural Resources Journal, 55-86.
Mnookin, Robert H. and Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1979), Bargaining in the Shadow of the Law: The
Case of Divorce, 88 Yale Law Journal, 950-997.
More, Daniel (197), The Coase Theorem and the Reciprocal Nature of Land-Use Conflicts in Pollution
Cases, 4 Studies in Law, Tel Aviv University, 84-114.
Mumey, George A. (1971), The Coase Theorem: A Reexamination, 85 Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 718-723.
Ng, Yew Kwang (1971), Recent Developments in the Theory of Externality and the Pigovian
Solution, 47 Economic Record, 169-185.
Ng, Yew Kwang (1975), Coases Theorem and First-party Priority Rule: Reply, 51 Economic
Record, 272-274.
888 The Coase Theorem 0730
Ng, Yew Kwang (1977), Again on Externalities and Liability Rules: A Reply, 53 Economic Record,
542-544.
North, Douglass C. (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History, New York, W.W. Norton.
Norton, Seth W. (1987), The Coase Theorem and Suboptimization in Marketing Channels, 6
Marketing Science, 268-285.
Nutter, Warren G. (1968), The Coase Theorem on Social Cost: A Footnote, 11 Journal of Law and
Economics, 503-507.
Ogus, Anthony I. (1991), Comment (on Staaf and Yandle, Collective and Private Choice;
Constitutions, Statutes and the Common Law), in Weigel, Wolfgang (ed.), Economic Analysis
of Law - A Collection of Applications, Vienna, sterreichischer Wirtschaftsverlag, 267-269.
Parisi, Francesco (1991), Interpretazione Giuridica ed Analisi Economica - Il Teorema di Coase Trenta
Anni Dopo (Legal Interpretation and Economic Analysis - The Coase Theorem Thirty Years
Later), Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato, 643-676.
Parisi, Francesco (1995), Private Property and Social Costs, 2(2) European Journal of Law and
Economics, 149-173.
Pejovich, Svetozar (1995), Economic analysis of institutions and systems, International Studies in
Economics and Econometrics, vol. 33. Dordrecht and Boston: Kluwer Academic, 231 p.
Peters, H. Elizabeth (1986), Marriage and Divorce: Informational Constraints and Private
Contracting, 76 American Economic Review, 437-454.
Peters, H. Elizabeth (1992), Marriage and Divorce: Reply, 82 American Economic Review, 686-693.
Polinsky, A. Mitchell (1974), Economic Analysis as a Potentially Defective Product: A Buyers Guide
to Posners Economic Analysis of Law, 87 Harvard Law Review, 1655-1681.
Polinsky, A. Mitchell (1979), Controlling Externalities and Protecting Entitlements: Property Right,
Liability Rule and Tax-Subsidy Approaches, 8 Journal of Legal Studies, 1-48.
Polinsky, A. Mitchell (1980), Resolving Nuisance Disputes: The Simple Economics of Injunctive and
Damage Remedies, 33 Stanford Law Review, 1075-1112.
Posin, Daniel Q. (1979), The Coase Theorem: Through a Glass Darkly, 61 Tennessee Law Review,
868 ff.
Posin, Daniel Q. (1990), The Coase Theorem: If Pigs Could Fly, 37 Wayne Law Review, 89-120.
Posin, Daniel Q. (1991), Bringing Home the Bacon: A Response to Critics, 38 Wayne Law Review,
107 ff.
Posin, Daniel Q. (1995), Risk and the Error of the Coase Theorem, 62 Tennessee Law Review,
1057-1071.
Posin, Daniel Q. (1996), Silicone Breast Implant Litigation and My Father-in-Law: A Neo-Coasean
Analysis, 70 Tulane Law Review, 2565-2582.
Posner, Richard A. (1983), Utilitarianism, Economics and Social Theory, in Posner, Richard A., The
Economics of Justice, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press, 48-87.
Posner, Richard A. (1992), Economic Analysis of Law, 4th edn, Boston, Little Brown and Co.
0730 The Coase Theorem 889
Prudencio, Yves C. (1982), The Voluntary Approach to Externality Problems: An Experimental Test,
9 Journal of Environmental Economy and Management, 213-228.
Quirk, James P. (1987), Intermediate Microeconomics, 3rd edn, Chicago, Henley on Thames, Sydney
and Toronto, Science Research Associates, 485 p.
Randall, Alan (1983), The Problem of Market Failure, 23 Natural Resources Journal, 131-148.
Randall, Allan (1972), Market Solutions to Externality Problems: Theory and Practice, 54 American
Journal of Agricultural Economics, 175-183.
Randall, Allan (1974), Coasian Externality Theory in a Policy Context, 14 Natural Resources
Journal, 35-54.
Regan, Donald H. (1972), The Problem of Social Cost Revisited, 15 Journal of Law and Economics,
427-437.
Roberts, John (1991), Review of: Managerial Dilemmas: The Political Economy of Hierarchy, 32
Journal of Economic Literature, 159-161.
Ryssdal, Stray A.C. (1995), Legal Realism and Economics as Behavior - A Scandinavian Look at the
Economic Analysis of Law, Oslo, Juridisk Forlag AS, Nerenius & Santrus Frlag AB Gad Jura
AS.
Ryssdal, Stray A.C. (1995), An Economic Analysis of Civil Suits and Appeals, Oslo, Juridisk Forlag
AS, Nerenius & Santrus Frlag AB Gad Jura AS.
Samuels, Warren J. (1974), The Coase Theorem and the Study of Law and Economics, 14 Natural
Resources Journal, 1-33.
Samuelson, Paul A. (1954), The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure, 36 Review of Economics and
Statistics, 386-389.
Samuelson, Paul A. (1964), Economics: An Introductory Analysis, 6th edn, New York, McGraw-Hill.
Samuelson, Paul A. (1966), Modern Economic Realities and Individualism, in Stiglitz, Joseph E.
(ed.), The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A. Samuelson, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press,
1407-1418.
Samuelson, William (1985), A Comment on the Coase Theorem, in Roth, Alvin E. (ed.),
Game-Theoretic Models of Bargaining, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 321-339.
Saraydar, Edward (1983), Bargaining Power, Dissimulation and the Coase Theorem, 139 Journal
of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 599-611.
Schap, David (1986), The Nonequivalence of Property Rules and Liability Rules, 6 International
Review of Law and Economics, 125-132.
Schlag, Pierre (1986), An Appreciative Comment on Coases the Problem of Social Cost: A View from
the Left, 1986 Wisconsin Law Review, 919-962.
Schlag, Pierre (1989), The Problem of Transaction Costs, 62 Southern California Law Review,
1661-1699.
Schulze, William D. and dArge, Ralph C. (1974), The Coase Proposition, Information Costs and
Long-run Equilibrium, 64 American Economic Review, 763-772.
Schulze, William D. and dArge, Ralph C. (1977), The Coase Proposition, Information Constraints
and Long-Run Equilibrium: Reply, 67 American Economic Review, 462-463.
Schwab, Stewart J. (1987), Collective Bargaining and the Coase Theorem, 72 Cornell Law Review,
245-287.
890 The Coase Theorem 0730
Stigler, George J. (1966), The Theory of Price, 3rd edn, New York, Macmillan.
Stigler, George J. (1989), Two Notes on the Coase Theorem, 99 Yale Law Journal, 631-633.
Sumner, Charles (1993), Red Deer Management Problems in Strathyre Forest: Ecology, Economics
and Land Use, MSc dissertation, Department of Environmental Science, University of Stirling.
Sutton, John (1986), Noncooperative Bargaining Theory: An Introduction, 53 Review of Economic
Studies, 709-724.
Swan, Peter L. (1975), The Coase Theorem and Sequential Pareto Optimality, 51 Economic
Record, 268-271.
Thaler, Richard H. (1980), Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice, 1 Journal of Economic
Behavior and Organization, 39-60.
Turvey, Ralph (1963), On Divergences Between Social Cost and Private Cost, 30 Economica,
309-313.
Tybout, Richard A. (1972), Pricing Pollution and Other Negative Externalities, 3 Bell Journal of
Economics, 252-266.
Tybout, Richard A. (1973), Pricing of Pollution: the Coase Theorem in the Long Run: Reply, 4 Bell
Journal of Economics, 320-321.
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1977), The Coase Theorem: The Says Law of Welfare Economics?, 53
Economic Record, 535-541.
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1982), The Coase Theorems and the Economic Theory of Markets and Law,
35 Kyklos, 53-74.
Ventura, Andrea (1990), Il Ruolo del Teorema di Coase nellAnalisi Economica del Diritto di G.
Calabresi (The Role of the Coase Theorem in G. Calabresis Economic Analysis of Law),
Economia Pubblica, 27-34.
Vogel, Kenneth R. (1987), The Coase Theorem and California Animal Trespass Law, 16 Journal of
Legal Studies, 149-187.
Walsh, Cliff (1975), First-Party-Priority Revisited, 51 Economic Record, 275-277.
Wegehenkel, Lothar (1980), Coase Theorem und Marktsystem (Coase Theorem and the Market
System), Tbingen, J.C.B. Mohr, 138 p.
Weimer, David L. and Vining, Aidan R. (1992), Policy Analysis: Concepts and Practice, 2nd edn,
Englewood Cliffs, NJ, Prentice-Hall.
Weld, John (1973), Coase, Social Cost and Stability: An Integrative Essay, 13 Natural Resources
Journal, 595-613.
Wellisz, Stanislaw (1964), On External Diseconomies and the Governement - Assisted Invisible Hand,
31 Economica, 345-362.
White, Barbara (1987), Coase and the Courts: Economics for the Common Man, 72 Iowa Law
Review, 577-635.
Willig, Robert D. (1976), Consumers Surplus Without Apology, 66 American Economic Review,
589-897.
Wohar, Mark (1988), Alternative Versions of the Coase Theorem and the Definition of Transaction
Costs, 27 Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics, 3-19.
Woj, Carolyn (1985), Property Rights Disputes: Current Fallacies and a New Approach, 14 Journal
of Legal Studies, 411-422.
X (1980), Symposium on Efficiency as a Legal Concern, 8 Hofstra Law Review, 485-972.
Zelder, Martin (1993a), The Economic Analysis of the Effect of No-Fault Divorce Law on the Divorce
Rate, 16 Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy, 241-267.
892 The Coase Theorem 0730
Zelder, Martin (1993b), Inefficient Dissolutions as a Consequence of Public Goods: The Case of
No-Fault Divorce, 22 Journal of Legal Studies, 503-520.
Zelder, Martin (1997), The Cost of Accosting: A Reconciliatory Survey of Proofs and Disproofs of the
Coase Theorem, in Medema, Steven G. (ed.),Coasean Economics, Kluwer, Academic Publishers.
Zerbe, Richard O., Jr (1976), The Problem of Social Cost: Fifteen Years Later, in Say, Lin, (ed.),
Theory and Measurement of Economic Externalities, New York, Academia Press, 29-36.
Zerbe, Richard O., Jr (1980), The Problem of Social Cost in Retrospect, 2 Research in Law and
Economics, 83-102.
Zerbe, Richard O., Jr (1998a), Is Benefit Cost Analysis Legal? Three Rules, 17 Journal of Policy
Analysis and Managment, forthcoming.
Zerbe, Richard O., Jr (1998b), A Foundation for Kaldor-Hicks Efficiency in Law and Economics: On
the Kindness of Strangers, Working Paper Graduate School of Public Affairs, University of
Washington.
Zerbe, Richard O., Jr (1998c), An Integration of Equity and Efficiency, 73 Washington Law Review,
forthcoming April 1998.
Zerbe, Richard O., Jr and McCurdy, Howard (1996), The Failure of Market Failure, Working Paper,
University of Washington..
Zerbe, Richard O., Jr and Urban, Nicole (1988), Including the Public Interest in Theories of
Regulation, 11 Research in Law and Economics, 1-23.
Zimbalist, Andrew (1994), Review of: Pay Dirt: The Business of Professional Team Sports, 32
Journal of Economic Literature, 167-168.
Zupan, Mark A. (1990), On Cream Skimming, Coase and the Sustainability of Natural Monopolies,
22 Applied Economics, 487-492.
Cases
Abstract
This chapter addresses the history, use and significance of the term transaction
costs. Few words in the economic language have been more abused or fought
over and this is shown to result from the emergence of two distinct definitions
and uses. The Neoclassical definition rests on the costs of trading across a
market, while the property rights definition centers on the costs of
establishing and enforcing property rights. In articulating these two separate
definitions and in demonstrating their relationship and separate uses, it is
hoped that more progress can be made in the field of transaction cost
economics.
JEL classification: K0, L0, L2, D0, D8
Keywords: Transaction Costs, Property Rights, Coase Theorem
1. Introduction
Transaction costs. Do another two words exist in the economic lexicon that
generate as much friction? Conceptually introduced in Coases 1937 paper The
Nature of the Firm as simply the cost of using the price mechanism (Coase,
1988, p. 38), the words transaction costs have evolved to the point where
some skeptics claim they include any cost that is convenient and elusive enough
to avoid critical examination (Niehans, 1987, p. 678). Advocates, on the other
hand, have hailed the recognition of these costs as revolutionary and as
important conceptually as marginalism and substitution (Cheung, 1983, p.
21).
The ambiguity that surrounds the concept of transaction costs stems, in
large part, from the existence of two literatures simultaneously claiming
ownership over the term. The property rights literature begins with Coase and
has consistently focused on the role transaction costs play in determining the
distribution of property rights, broadly defined as all laws, rules, social customs
and organizations that generate incentives for behavior. This literature has
called into question fundamental concepts like efficiency and the nature of
production. Though based in neoclassical economics, this literature has evolved
beyond the neoclassical model and has produced the new sub-fields of law and
economics, the new economic history and the new institutional economics.
893
894 Transaction Costs 0740
Though this field, through Coase, claims the discovery and rightful title to
transaction costs, ironically the words are conspicuously absent from many
of its titles. Indeed this literature is mostly responsible, though not solely, for
the plethora of terms that either substitute for or refine the notion of transaction
costs.
The neoclassical literature on transaction costs begins in the early 1950s,
although some might argue that it starts with Hicks (1935) or even Coase
(1937). This literature defines transaction costs more narrowly, generally
models them more explicitly and often analytically identical to transportation
charges or taxes. The correspondence with familiar costs carries over to the
types of issues examined, such as the effect of transaction costs on the volume
of trade, abilities to arbitrage, the bunching of transactions, intermediation and
the existence and efficiency of equilibrium - all standard neoclassical fare.
Sometimes this literature examines issues of property right determination, such
as the role of middlemen and the medium of exchange. In addition to the
different approach and definition, the conclusions are often opposite from the
property rights literature as well. This is especially true over questions of
efficiency and this has increased the level of belittling rhetoric between the two
camps. For example, it is common in the neoclassical literature, when reference
is made to the Coase Theorem - the cornerstone of the property rights literature
- to say the so-called Coase Theorem (See Niehans, 1987 p. 678, for an
example). The property rights literature is just as aggressive, claiming that the
neoclassical camp often wants their cake and eat it too. For example, early
criticisms over the monopoly model almost mocked the inconsistency of having
a monopolist know its demand curve at zero costs, yet find it prohibitively
costly to price discriminate (see Demsetz, 1969, or Barzel, 1977, for examples).
The likely cause of this dichotomous literature is twofold. First, there is the
early introduction of costly transacting by Coase (1937) in the explicit context
of institutional choice, at a time when the profession had little interest or ability
to grapple with the issue. As Coase (1972) noted, his 1937 paper on the firm
was often cited, but was little used. Second, there is Coases failure in 1937 to
define transaction costs with any precision, using instead the phrase the costs
of the price mechanism. At the same time, though Coase uses examples that
suggest more than just the market is involved in transaction costs, he ultimately
leaves the issue open for interpretation. As such, the property right literature
did not truly begin until 1960, with Coases publication of The Problem of
Social Cost. This latter article provided the necessary elaboration of Coases
1937 publication in order to tie many existing ideas together and to provide a
property rights research agenda (see Barzel and Kochin, 1992, or Medema,
forthcoming, for elaborations on this point). In the intervening years,
economists did what they could with the term transaction costs and the
neoclassical approach was born.
The purpose of this chapter is to provide a broad picture of transaction
costs: its history, definition, foundation, use, measurement and implications.
0740 Transaction Costs 895
In the beginning Coase created transaction costs. His critics might continue:
And the term was formless and void and darkness was over the surface of the
term. For the believers in the property right approach, however, Coase (1937)
is seminal. As an advanced undergraduate perplexed by economics ability to
conceptually organize the economy around prices, Coase was troubled that
there was no room for any form of direct cooperation or direction. In his words
we had a factor of production, management, whose function was to coordinate.
Why was it needed if the pricing system provided all the coordination
necessary? (1992, p. 715). His solution was to recognize that there are costs
of using the price mechanism. When prices allocate resources at a cost, then
they compete with other allocating mechanisms like firms and governments.
Coase argued that, at times, firms and direct management supersede the
market, while at other times market prices are used in directing goods and
services. Readers interested in the genesis and a detailed account of the history
of Coases first great work are directed to Williamson and Winter (1991).
In this simple argument a charitable reading finds some basic elements that
distinguish the property rights literature. First, all methods of allocating
resources have costs and benefits and no single mechanism works for free and
dominates all others - in modern language, all allocation mechanisms are
second best. Second, it is argued that rules, organizational forms and
methods of payments are subject to economic analysis. Although it has been
argued that Frank Knight (1921) indirectly made a similar case (see McManus,
1975; Barzel, 1987), Coase explicitly addressed this issue. And finally, Coase
implicitly argues that positive transaction costs were both necessary and
sufficient for an explanation of the firm.
Coase provides examples of what he meant by the costs of the price
mechanism: discovering what the prices are, negotiating and closing a contract;
and he hints at problems of enforcement, but he stops short of any definition.
In fact, throughout all of his writings, Coase never goes beyond providing
examples of transaction costs. Barzel and Kochin (1992, p. 25) have noted that
the discussion of transaction costs in that [1937] paper is brief and cryptic and
even the most sympathetic reader would have to agree. Though the words
896 Transaction Costs 0740
transaction costs are never used in his first work, Coase is still correct when,
in his Nobel address, he states that: What I think will be considered in the
future to have been the important contribution of this article is the explicit
introduction of transaction costs into economic analysis. (1992, p. 716).
It remains a strange fact of economic history that after the publication of
The Nature of the Firm, neither Coase, nor any other writer in the profession,
picked up the joint theme of transaction costs and property rights. Finally, in
The Federal Communications Commission, Coase (1959) returns to the theme
of the influence of transaction costs on property rights and this article provides
the motivation for The Problem of Social Cost (see Kitch (ed.), 1983, or
Stigler, 1988, for discussions of how Coase came to write his most famous
paper). Ironically, even Coase did not appreciate his accomplishment at the
time of writing:
I should add that in writing this article I had no such general aim in mind. I thought
that I was exposing the weaknesses of Pigous analysis of the divergence between
private and social products, an analysis generally accepted by economists and that
was all. It was only later and in part as a result of conversation with Steven Cheung
in the 1960s that I came to see the general significance for economic theory of what
I had written . . . (1992, p. 717)
(1975, 1979, 1985). This connection between transaction costs and property
rights is summarized in the Coase Theorem, which is defined as follows:
There are many attacks and defenses of the Coase Theorem, none of which
are dealt with here (see Shapiro, 1974, for an example of an attack, Allen,
1997, for a defense and Zerbe, 1980, for a survey). The point is that for all
property right approaches to transaction costs, the two concepts of property
rights and transaction costs are fundamentally interlinked. In fact, it will be
shown that they are two sides of the same coin and that this linkage
distinguishes the property right approach from the neoclassical approach to the
study of transaction costs.
existence of the state, but that they depend on custom, reciprocity and voluntary
restraints. This notion is now commonplace in the modern property rights
literature and is explicitly found in Ellickson (1991) and Landa (1994).
Although economic property rights are enhanced by the law, they are ultimately
use rights and the greater extent one can exercise these uses and bear the
consequences the greater are the property rights, regardless of the law. Property
rights are therefore defined as:
where the distribution of property rights has a broad meaning and includes
all sets of rules, governance structures and organizations. Hence, families,
firms, governments, non-profit institutions, contracts, are all viewed as sets of
property rights. Lawyers forming a partnership to split the residuals, a farmer
renting land from a landowner, or a judge deciding on a case, are all examples
of different allocations of property rights. Every distribution of property rights
has with it a set of production costs and a set of transaction costs. The
distribution of property rights that maximizes the gains from trade net of all
costs is the optimal distribution. This, in fact, is the grand hypothesis of
transaction cost economics under the property rights approach. An account of
transaction cost methodology is beyond the scope of this paper, but see
Williamson (1979, 1985) for detailed accounts.
A second characterization is the reluctance to infer any policy implications
from the analysis and to stress explanation. As stated earlier, this goes back to
Coases original idea that no single allocation mechanism dominates. Notions
of market failure lose meaning when there is no reason for prices to allocate
everything. One might as well refer to government failure or firm failure in
cases where prices do allocate.
This transaction cost approach dominates what is now called the New
Institutional Economics, so named because it provides a theoretical framework
and emphasis of testability to the institutional traditions of Veblen and
Commons. Oliver Williamson is considered the founder of this literature, both
in terms of vocabulary and content and he is one of the strongest proponents of
applying the notion of transaction costs ubiquitously. His notion of a
governance structure as a distribution of property rights providing appropriate
incentives to govern a relationship, is intended to apply within and outside
firms. Williamson (1971) is the first to note the role sunk costs can play in
causing contracting problems and incentives to vertically integrate. This idea
is popularized in Klein, Crawford and Alchian (1978) and in Klein and Leffler
(1981). The role of asset specificity and idiosyncratic capital is so attached to
the name of Williamson that for many, transaction costs means little else.
Although Williamsons understanding of the relationship between transaction
costs and property rights is consistent with what is presented here, he also
distinguishes between the property rights approach and the transaction cost
approach to organizational problems. For Williamson, a property rights
approach deals with grand private environmental rules, while the transaction
cost approach deals with private incomplete contracts (see Williamson, 1990
for a discussion).
0740 Transaction Costs 901
Although, Coase (1937) provides mostly market exchange examples and could
be argued as the founder of the neoclassical approach to transaction costs, it
could be better argued that this approach begins with Hicks (1935) publication
A Suggestion of Simplifying the Theory of Money, which predates Coase by
two years. In his paper, Hicks begins what is known as a transaction demand
for money, although he never calls it as such. For him, there are frictions in the
economy and these apply to buying and selling capital assets yielding positive
returns. When the returns were small, at the margin, relative to the costs of
trading, individuals rationally hold cash balances yielding no return. In his
words:
The most obvious sort of friction and undoubtedly one of the most important, is the
cost of transferring assets from one form to another. This is of exactly the same
character as the cost of transfer which acts as a certain impediment to change in all
parts of the economic system; it doubtless comprises subjective elements as well as
elements directly priced. Thus a person is deterred from investing money for short
periods, partly because of brokerage charges and stamp duties, partly because it is
not worth the bother. (1935, p. 6)
Since money is used to facilitate exchange and since an exchange that needs
facilitating must be subject to transaction costs, it is not surprising that those
concerned with money dealt with these costs. Indeed, Baumol (1952) and Tobin
(1956) elaborate on the transaction demand for money and again treat
transaction costs as the costs of trading. The first explicit statement of
transaction costs as the cost of trading comes from Demsetz (1964) where he
states that Transaction cost may be defined as the cost of exchanging
ownership titles (1988, p. 64). Although this type of definition refers to
property rights, transaction costs only arise when an exchange of property
rights takes place. This leads to the neoclassical definition of transaction costs:
Transaction Costs #2: the costs resulting from the transfer of property
rights.
In general, transaction costs are ubiquitous in market economies and can arise from
the transfer of any property right because parties to exchanges must find one
another, communicate and exchange information. There may be a necessity to
inspect and measure goods to be transferred, draw up contracts, consult with
lawyers or other experts and transfer title. Depending upon who provides these
services, transaction costs can take one of two forms, inputs or resources - including
time - by a buyer and/or a seller or a margin between the buying and selling price
of a commodity in a given market. (Stavins 1995, p. 134)
Definitional Squabbles
For the most part, these two streams of literatures - the property rights approach
and the neoclassical approach - flow independently. Those writing in the area
of property rights follow the line of reasoning laid by Coase, Cheung and
Williamson and use the broad notion of transaction costs. Those interested in
the neoclassical issues of volume of trade and equilibrium generally stick to an
Arrow-Debreu based general equilibrium model and use the narrow definition
of straight exchange costs.
The major exception is Harold Demsetz. Demsetz was an early contributor
to the theory of property rights and the role of enforcement costs in determining
the distribution of property rights (See Demsetz, 1964, 1967 and 1972).
Ironically though, he was also the first to articulate the neoclassical definition
of transaction costs (Demsetz, 1968). For Demsetz, transaction costs remain
the costs of coordinating resources through market arrangements (1995, p. 4)
and among property right economists he remains a staunch, though perhaps
lonely, proponent of this view. Demsetz (1964) is the first to deal with the
breadth of definition used for transaction costs. In Demsetz (1988) he
acknowledges that this is mostly a question of semantics, since his collection
of costs all fit under the rubric of governance costs or the property rights
definition. According to Demsetz, the clear meaning of transaction costs is the
904 Transaction Costs 0740
cost of transacting. To apply the term more broadly threatens to make the term
tautological and useless. This view is summarized by Schlag, an overly
expansive view of transaction costs threatens to make the Coase theorem
tautological. On the other hand, an overly restrictive view of transaction costs
can effectively invalidate the theorem (1989, p. 1675).
Demsetz (1988, pp. 144-150) argues that a broad definition of transaction
costs hinders any understanding of firms and markets. For example, Demsetz
(1995) argues that the definition of a firm and its internal organization are two
separate issues that have been confused since Coase. Demsetz defines the firm
as a production unit, created to exploit gains from specialization. Since markets
only transfer titles they complement firms and the Coasean notion of firms and
markets substituting for one another does not arise. This is exactly the opposite
way the property rights literature would define a firm (see Barzel, 1989, as an
example). Coase has always put emphasis on the formal relations within a firm
(for example, employer vs. employee) as a possible means of reducing
transaction costs. Alchian and Demsetz (1972), on the other hand, downplay
the role of authority within the firm. (See Medema, 1994 , for a discussion of
Coase vs. Alchian and Demsetz.)
Demsetz, de facto, takes a property rights approach to the internal
organization of the firm, however. Demsetz (1995) discusses several transaction
costs (definition #1) arguments for the firm without using the term, including:
shirking, Knightean uncertainty, reduction of coordination costs and the agency
problems from opportunism. Hence, in the end there is very little to quibble
over and the definition to be used depends on the problem being addressed.
Clearly, all of the costs mentioned by Demsetz fall under the umbrella of the
property right definition of transaction costs, where a broad transaction cost
definition is necessary in order to make clear that the Coase theorem does not
apply.
household wealth, because taxpayers are able to unravel any financing decisions
of governments.
In addition to these, there are a host of equivalence results regarding taxes,
the most famous being that it is irrelevant whether the consumer or the
producer is taxed, the result is the same in terms of both resource allocation and
incidence of tax paid. Furthermore, both ad valorem and per unit taxes are
equivalent in terms of resource allocation. Finally, in trade policy and again in
terms of resource allocation, it is well known that tariffs and quotas can have
identical effects.
All of these results are special cases of the Coase theorem because all taxes,
debt obligations, equity shares and other policy instruments are delineations of
property rights. A firm deciding on the optimal amount of debt versus equity
is essentially assigning property rights over the stream of expected profits,
including priority in case of unexpected shortfalls. A government deciding on
a choice between taxation and debt is simply transferring property rights over
time. In all of these cases, only a different distribution of property rights exists
and given the Coase theorem, this does not alter the allocation of resources -
when, as Coase stated, transaction costs are zero.
When transaction costs are not zero, these equivalence results do not occur.
For example, Barzel (1976) shows how the tax equivalent result is altered when
transaction costs are positive. When goods are complex bundles of commodities
they become difficult to define under tax legislation and some attributes are
possibly ignored. Under these conditions, taxes have the effect of altering the
relative price of the taxed and untaxed attributes and therefore alter the mix or
quality of the item that is produced. Lump sum taxes tend to increase the
quality of good, while per unit taxes tend to lower quality. The result is that
different forms of taxation can have vastly different effects on resource
allocation. Furthermore, differences in the ability to avoid taxation implies that
tax revenue is not neutral with respect to the location of the tax.
All these examples explain why the property rights approach requires a
broad definition of transaction costs. Given the Coase theorem and all of its
different manifestations, distributions of property rights are irrelevant. If we did
live in a world of zero transaction costs (definition # 1), then firms truly would
toss coins to decide debt levels, if indeed there were any firms, which would
also be decided by a coin toss. And so on for governments and all other
institutions. The importance of the Coase theorem then is that it points to
transaction costs as the necessary factor in any explanation of the distribution
of property rights. The definition of transaction costs, therefore, must be those
costs that cause the Coase theorem to not apply. This also seems to be the
reason why the neoclassical approach never analyzes questions of economic
organization outside of the choice of medium of exchange. They have selected
a definition of transaction costs that is too limited for this purpose. Many in the
906 Transaction Costs 0740
find each other, they have to communicate and to exchange information . . . goods
must be described, inspected, weighed and measured. Contracts are drawn up,
lawyers may be consulted, title is transferred and records have to be kept. In some
cases, compliance needs to be enforced through legal action and breach of contract
may lead to litigation. (1987, p. 676)
style.) Although the specific technologies are generally simple, they are usually
sufficient to complicate the analysis greatly.
Three general approaches are taken to model the transaction technology.
The first simply assumes that some general transaction function T(x) exists (see
Brennan and Copeland, 1988, for example). This function is often assumed to
depend on the volume of trade, cash flows, number of traders and other such
variables that reflect the size of the transaction. The second assumes that
transaction costs are fixed (see Leland, 1974; Mukherjee and Zabel, 1974;
Brennan, 1975; Goldsmith, 1976; Levy, 1978; or Mayshar, 1979, 1981; for
examples). Finally, proportional (or iceberg) transaction costs k(x) are
assumed, where k is a constant fraction and x again is a measure of the size of
transaction (see Gennotte and Jung, 1994, or Constantinides, 1986, for
examples). All of these technologies make their way into standard objective
functions for firms and households. Though the subsequent analysis is usually
complicated, the results are most often exactly analogous to the effects of
transportation charges. Typically, these analyses show that the presence of
transaction costs reduces the frequency and volume of trade.
a U (Wa )
1 a U (Wb )
where pa is the probability of fire in state a, U the individuals affine utility
function and W the wealth level in the two states. In the case of pure
uncertainty the probabilities are determined by nature.
However, if the behavior of the individual is not observable, the
probabilities are alterable by the individual and a transaction cost problem
arises. As has been noted above the transaction cost problem requires: (1) the
presence of uncertainty (here the probability of a fire) and (2) the ability of the
individual to change his behavior without costless detection. Since the firm
cannot observe behavior, this implies individuals all become careless, which
alters the marginal rate of substitution! The introduction of costly information
leads to preferences no longer being fixed and exogenous and this is an
example of a fundamental difference between the two types of models. (Arnott
and Stiglitz, 1988) explore the implications of shifting marginal rates of
substitution.)
The solution to this particular problem has the insurance company offering
an incomplete contract (an insurance contract with a deductible), which points
to a second difference. Namely the possible non-existence of explicit
transaction costs in equilibrium. The insurance company, by offering an
incentive compatible contract, does not engage in any form of direct
monitoring. Such monitoring is not necessary and many property right models
have no actual resources used to establish and maintain property rights in
equilibrium. In this case, the transaction costs are simply the lost gains from
trade that result from the incomplete contract.
As a second example, consider a variation on the principal-agent model first
introduced by Stiglitz (1974). In this model the effort of a risk-averse agent is
unobservable and so a contract is reached that trades off incentives for risk
avoidance. For example, consider the case of cropshare contracts, where a risk-
averse farmer contracts with a risk-neutral landowner (Allen and Lueck, 1995).
For a plot of land, output is q=(e + ?), where e is the unobservable labor effort
and ? is a random variable with mean 0 and variance s . Furthermore, assume
that the farmers income is Y = aq + and his utility is U=E(Y) + (r/2)Var(Y),
where r is a measure of risk aversion, a is the share of output and is a fixed
side payment. Finally, assume that the cost of effort to the farmer is c0 + c1e +
(c2/2)e2.
910 Transaction Costs 0740
For a given outputshare the effort which maximizes farmer utility is:
c1
e$ ( ) = ,
c2
which represents the behavior of the farmer and becomes a constraint to the
landowner designing the optimal contract. This incentive compatibility
constraint represents another example of a fundamental distinction in modeling
property right distributions - namely, the constraints often involve optimization
problems. The next stage in this particular problem involves the landowner
maximizing his expected income E ((1 ! a) ( + ) + ) subject to the incentive
constraint and a participation constraint.
Although the principal-agent model has been extended and broadly applied,
(see Dewatripont, 1989; Freixas, Guesnerie and Tirole, 1985; Holmstrom,
1979, 1982; or Shavell, 1979, for examples), it has recently fallen out of favor
for models where all parties are risk neutral (see Eswaran and Kotwal, 1985;
Grossman and Hart, 1986; Leffler and Rucker, 1991; and Allen and Lueck,
1992a, for examples). Holmstrom and Milgrom (1991) develop an explicit
principal-agent model where risk aversion is not required. The great advantage
of risk neutrality is that it allows for several margins over which transaction
cost behavior can take place. However, though there remains no single way to
model transaction costs in the property rights approach, the bottom line
remains that it does involve some fundamental differences from putting a T
in a cost function.
The empirical work in transaction cost economics is very large. On the property
rights side, studies have examined vertical integration (Anderson, 1988;
Fishback, 1986, 1992; Globerman, 1980; Globerman and Schwindt, 1986;
Joskow, 1985; Levy, 1985; Mahoney, 1992; Masten, 1984; Masten, Meehan
and Snyder, 1989, 1991; and Monteverde and Teece, 1982), long-term
contracts (Crocker and Masten, 1988; Joskow, 1985, 1987; Leffler and Rucker,
1991; Masten and Crocker, 1985), franchising and share contracts (Allen and
Lueck, 1992a, 1992b, 1993; Alston and Higgs, 1982; Alston, Datta and
Nugent, 1984; Datta, OHara and Nugent, 1986; Lafontaine, 1993; Williamson,
1976; Zupan, 1989a, 1989b), marriage (Allen, 1990, 1991; Brinig, 1990;
Brinig and Alexeev, 1993; Parkman, 1992), wildlife (Lueck, 1991), horse
racing (Hall, 1986), price adjustments (Crocker and Masten, 1991; Goldberg
and Erickson, 1987; Joskow, 1988b, 1990), economic history (North, 1981;
North and Weingast, 1989; and North, 1990), rate of return regulation (Crew
and Kleindorfer, 1985) and a host of other organizational issues (see Shelanski
0740 Transaction Costs 911
and Klein, 1995, for a more complete listing of references to the empirical
literature).
Studies in the neoclassical approach are also numerous and mostly focus on
asset arbitrage, the volume of trade, risk adjusted returns and the bundling of
transactions (see Demsetz, 1968; Fisher, 1994; Frenkel and Levich, 1975;
Litzenberger and Rolfo, 1984; Malkiel, 1966; Pesaran and Timmermann, 1994;
Phillips and Smith, 1980; Protopapadakis and Stoll, 1983; Schultz, 1983;
Smiley, 1976). It should be stressed that the empirical transaction cost literature
seriously tests hypotheses and therefore by its existence refutes the assertion
that transaction cost economics is tautological. However, most of property right
and neoclassical empirical studies are of the comparative static variety and
attempt to test transaction cost hypotheses using various proxies for asset
specificity, uncertainty, measurement costs, friction and other transaction cost
variables in reduced form equations. There are only two studies that have
attempted to measure the level of transaction costs.
The first and perhaps most ambitious of these is Wallis and North (1986),
who attempt to measure the entire transaction sector of the economy over 100
years. Understandably, the first problem they face is how to define transaction
costs. Their property rights background leads them to define transaction costs
as the resource costs of maintaining and operating the institutional framework
associated with capturing the gains from trade. In the end, however, they
simply separate resources devoted to transacting as their measure and in doing
so ironically come closer to a neoclassical definition. Although they
acknowledge the conceptual problems this definition has with respect to firms,
they settle for the following compromise:
We divide occupations into those that provide primarily transaction services to the
firm and, by elimination, those that provide primarily transformation services. The
wages of employees in these transaction occupations constitute our measure of the
transaction sector within firms. (1986, p. 100)
This compromise would require all protective services (police, courts and
so on) included in the non-transaction sector of the economy, which makes
Wallis and North so uncomfortable, they switch its classification (pp. 102-103).
The analysis of Wallis and North concludes that the transaction sector accounts
for a significant part of the economy and that this has grown from 25 percent
to 40 percent over the years 1870 to 1970.
Davis (1986), however, has pointed out that this estimate is not robust for
even small changes in the line that separates transactions from production.
In the end, the problem of definition seems overwhelming. Is a farmer a
manager/marketing agent, or a grain-growing field hand? All jobs have
elements of production and transaction in them and it seems an impossible task
912 Transaction Costs 0740
to separate them. This perhaps best explains why Wallis and North were both
the first and the last to tackle transaction costs on such a grand scale.
A more sophisticated treatment of measuring the costs of organization is
found in Masten, Meehan and Snyder (1991). They note that much of the
empirical literature proxies only the hazards of market exchange and ignores
the internal costs of governance. Reduced form estimates are unable to
distinguish between internal and external transaction costs.
Furthermore, attempts to directly measure transaction costs are subject to
the problems faced by Wallis and North. Finally, Masten, Meehan and Snyder
recognize the selection bias that occurs since the efficient organization structure
is chosen and the other choices are not observed. Their solution is to utilize
switching regression techniques and to adopt censured regression models used
in labor economics. From this technique they obtain actual dollar estimates of
organization costs and therefore can estimate the magnitude of individual
coefficients and not just their relative impact. Masten, Meehan and Snyder
apply this methodology to naval shipyard contracts and find that overall
organization costs amount to 14 percent of total costs. They estimate that if an
incorrect contractual agreements is chosen that this would lead to increases in
organizational costs of up to 70 percent.
9. Conclusion
Ackerlof, George A. (1970), The Market for Lemons: Qualitative Uncertainty and the Market
Mechanism, 84 Quarterly Journal of Economics, 488-500.
Aivazian, Varouj A. and Callen, Jeffrey L. (1980), Uncertain Externalities, Liability Rules and
Resource Allocation: Comment, 70 American Economic Review, 1058-1059.
Aivazian, Varouj A. and Callen, Jeffrey L. (1981), The Coase Theorem and the Empty Core, 24
Journal of Law and Economics, 175-181.
Aivazian, Varouj A., Callen, Jeffrey L. and Lipnowski, Irwin F. (1988), The Coase Theorem and
Coalitional Stability, 54 Economica, 517-520.
Aiyagari, S.R. and Gertler, M. (1991), Asset Returns with Transactions Costs and Uninsured
Individual Risk, 27 Journal of Monetary Economics, 311-331.
Alchian, Armen A. (1958), Private Property and the Relative Cost of Tenure, in Bradley, P. (ed.), The
Public Stake in Union Power, Charlottesville, VA, University Press of Virginia, 350-371.
Alchian, Armen A. (1961), Some Economics of Property Rights, Rand Paper, Rand Corporation.
Alchian, Armen A. (1965), Some Economics of Property Rights, 30 Il Politico, 816-829.
Alchian, Armen A. (1977), Why Money?, 9 Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 133-140.
Alchian, Armen A. (1979), Some Implications of Recognition of Property Right Transaction Costs,
in Brunner, K. (ed.), Economics and Social Institutions, Boston, 233-252.
Alchian, Armen A. and Allen, W. (1964), University Economics, Belmont, Wadsworth Publishing Co.
Alchian, Armen A. and Demsetz, Harold (1972), Production, Information Costs and Economic
Organization, 62 American Economic Review, 777-795.
Alchian, Armen A. and Kessel, R. (1962), Aspects of Labor Economics (Competition, Monopoly and
the Pursuit of Money), Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Alchian, Armen A. and Woodward, S. (1988), Review of Williamsons The Economic Institutions
of Capitalism, 26 Journal of Economic Literature, 65-79.
Alfaro Aguila-Real, Jess (1996), Los Costes de Transaccin (Transaction Costs), in Menndez,
Aurelio (ed.), Estudios Homenaje, Madrid, Tomo I, 131-162.
Allen, Douglas W. (1990), In Inquiry into the States Role in Marriage, 13 Journal of Economic
Behavior and Organization, 171-191.
Allen, Douglas W. (1991), What are Transaction Costs?, 14 Research in Law and Economics, 1-18.
914 Transaction Costs 0740
Allen, Douglas W. (1997), Property Rights, Transaction Costs and Coase: One More Time, in
Medema, Steven G. (ed.), Coasean Economics: Law and Economics and the New Institutional
Economics, Dordrecht, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 105-118.
Allen, Douglas W. and Lueck, Dean (1992a), Contract Choice in Modern Agriculture: Cash Rent
versus Cropshare, 35 Journal of Law and Economics, 397-426.
Allen, Douglas W. and Lueck, D. (1992b), The Back-Forty on a Handshake: Specific Assets,
Reputation and the Structure of Farmland Contracts, 8 Journal of Law, Economics and
Organization, 366-377.
Allen, Douglas W. and Lueck, D. (1993), Transaction Costs and the Design of Cropshare Contracts,
24 Rand Journal of Economics, 78-100.
Allen, Douglas W. and Lueck, D. (1995), Risk Preferences and the Economics of Contracts, 5
American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 447-451.
Alston, L. and Higgs, R. (1982), Contractual Mix in Southern Agricultre since the Civil War: Facts,
Hypotheses and Tests, 42 Journal of Economic History, 327-353.
Alston, L., Datta, S. and Nugent, J. (1984), Tenancy Choice in a Competitive Framework with
Transaction Costs, 92 Journal of Political Economy, 1121-1133.
Andersen, E. (1988), Transaction Costs as Determinants of Opportunism in Integrated and Independent
Sales Forces, 9 Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 242-264.
Anderson, Terry L. and Lueck, Dean (1992), Land Tenure and Agricultural Productivity on Indian
Reservations, 35 Journal of Law and Economics, 427-454.
Arnott, R. and Stiglitz, J. (1988), The Basic Analytics of Moral Hazard, 90(3) Scandinavian Journal
of Economics, 383-413.
Babic, Blagoje (1994), Prelaz u Tranziciji (Deception in Transition), Belgrade, Prometej.
Barzel, Yoram (1976), An Alternative Approach to the Analysis of Taxation, 84 Journal of Political
Economy, 1177-1197.
Barzel, Yoram (1977), Some Fallacies in the Interpretation of Information Costs, 20 Journal of Law
and Economics, 291-307.
Barzel, Yoram (1982), Measurement Cost and the Organisation of Markets, 25 Journal of Law and
Economics, 27-48.
Barzel, Yoram (1985), Transaction Costs: Are They Just Costs?, 141 Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics, 4-16.
Barzel, Y. (1987), Knights Moral Hazard Theory of Organization, 25 Economic Inquiry,
117-120.
Barzel, Yoram (1989), Economic Analysis of Property Rights, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press, 122 p.
Barzel, Yoram and Kochin, L. (1992), Ronald Coase on the Nature of Social Cost as a Key to the
Problem of the Firm, 94 Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 19-31.
Baumol, William J. (1952), The Transactions Demand for Cash: An Inventory Theoretic Approach,
66 Quarterly Journal of Economics, 545-556.
Bensaid, B., Lesne, J.P. and Pages, H. (1992), Derivative Asset Pricing with Transaction Costs, 2
Mathematical Finance, 63-86.
Bergstrom, T. (ed.) (1976), How to Discard Free Disposability - At No Cost, 3 Journal of
Mathematical Economics, 131-134.
Blackstone, W. (1803), Commentaries on the Laws of England, London, Strahan.
Bowers, James W. (1993), The Fantastic Wisconsylvania Zero-Bureaucratic-Cost School of
Bankruptcy Theory: A Comment, 91 Michigan Law Review, 1773-1792.
0740 Transaction Costs 915
Boyle, P.P. and Vorst, Ton (1992), Option Replication in Discrete Time with Transaction Costs, 47
Journal of Finance, 271-293.
Breeden, Charles H. and Toumanoff, Peter G. (1984), Transaction Costs and Economic Institutions,
in Leube, K.R. and Zlabinger, A.H. (eds), The Political Economy of Freedom, Mnchen,
Philosophia Verlag, 161-177.
Brennan, Michael J. (1975), The Optimal Number of Securities in a Risky Asset Portfolio when there
are Fixed Costs of Transaction: Theory and Some Empirical Results, 10 Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis, 483-496.
Brennan, Michael J. and Copeland, T.E. (1988), Stock Splits, Stock Prices and Transaction Costs, 22
Journal of Financial Economics, 83-101.
Brinig, Margaret F. (1990), Rings and Promises, 6 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization,
203-215.
Brinig, Margaret F. (1993), The Law and Economics of No-Fault Divorce, 27 Family Law Quarterly,
453-470.
Brinig, Margaret F. (1994), The Effect of Transactions Costs on the Market for Babies, 18 Seton Hall
Journal on Legislation, 553-579.
Brinig, Margaret F. and Alexeev, Michael V. (1991), Legal Rules, Bargaining and Transactions Costs:
The Case of Divorce, in Nagel, Stuart and Mills, Miriam K. (eds), Systematic Analysis in Dispute
Resolution, New York, Quorum Books, 91-105.
Brinig, Margaret F. and Alexeev, Michael V. (1993), Trading at Divorce: Preferences, Legal Rules
and Transaction Costs, 8 Ohio State Journal on Dispute Resolution, 279-297.
Brinig, Margaret F. and Alexeev, Michael V. (1995), Fraud in Courtship: Annulment and Divorce,
2 European Journal of Law and Economics, 45-63.
Brousseau, Eric (1993), Les Theories des Contrats: Une Revue, 103(1) Revue dEconomie Politique,
1-82.
Brousseau, Eric (1993), LEconomie des Contrats; Technologies de lInformation et Coordination
Interentreprises, Paris, Presses Universitaires de France (PUF).
Brousseau, Eric (1995), Contracts as Modular Mechanisms: Some Propositions for the Study of
Hybrid Forms, 2(3) International Journal of the Economics of Business, 409-439.
Brousseau, Eric and Bessy, Christian (1997a), Brevet, Protection et Diffusion des Connaissances: une
Relecture Neo-institutionnelle des Proprietes de la Regle de Droit (Patent, Protection and Diffusion
of Knowledge: A Neo Instititional Revision of the Characteristics of the Rule of Law), 79(S)
Revue dEconomie Industrielle, 233-254.
Brousseau, Eric and Bessy, Christian (1997b), Technology Licensing Contracts: Features and
Diversity, 14th Conference of the European Association of Law and Economics (EALE),
Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona, Spain.
Brousseau, Eric and Bessy, Christian (1997c), The Governance of Intellectual Property Rights:
Patents and Copyrights in France and in the US, Inaugural Conference for the International
Society for New Institutional Economics, The Present and Future of the New Institutional
Economics, Washington University, St. Louis, Missouri.
Campbell, David (1996), On What is Valuable in Law and Economics, 8 Otago Law Review,
489-514.
Centi, Jean-Pierre (1987), Quel Critre dEfficience pour lAnalyse Economique du Droit? (Which
Efficiency Criterion for Economic Analysis of Law), 2 Revue de la Recherche Juridique.
Centner, Terence J. (1985), Are FmHA Loans Entitlements Protected by the Due Process Clause?,
34 Drake Law Review, 389-427.
916 Transaction Costs 0740
Centner, Terence J. and Wetzstein, Michael E. (1987), Reducing Moral Hazard Associated with
Implied Warranties of Animal Health, 68 American Journal of Agricultural Economics,
143-150.
Centner, Terence J. and Wetzstein, Michael E. (1988), Reducing Moral Hazard Associated with
Implied Warranties of Animal Health: Reply, 70 American Journal of Agricultural Economics,
413-414.
Centner, Terence J. and White, F.C. (1987), FmHAs Efforts against Delinquent Borrowers: Property
Interests and Transaction Costs, 12 Western Journal of Agricultural Economics, 35-41.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1969), A Theory of Share Tenancy, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 188
p.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1970), The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of a Non-exclusive
Resource, 13 Journal of Law and Economics, 49-70.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1974), A Theory of Price Control, 17 Journal of Law and Economics, 53-71.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1978), The Myth of Social Costs: A Critique of Welfare Economics and the
Implications for Public Policy, London, Institute of Economic Affairs, 93 p.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1983), The Contractual Nature of the Firm, 26 Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-21.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1992), On the New Institutional Economics, in Werin, Lars and Wijkander,
Hans (eds), Contract Economics, Oxford, Blackwell, 48-65.
Chianale, Angelo (1992), Latto Pubblico: Contributo allo Studio dei Costi Transattivi (The
Document under the Seal of a Public Officer: Contribution to the Study of Transaction Costs),
Torino, Giappichelli.
Chisholm, Darlene C. (1997), Profit-Sharing Versus Fixed-Payment Contracts: Evidence From the
Motion Pictures Industry, 13 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 169-201.
Coase, Ronald H. (1937), The Nature of the Firm, 4 Economica, 386-405. Reprinted in Kronman,
Anthony T. and Posner, Richard A. (eds) (1979), The Economics of Contract Law, Boston, Little
Brown, 31-32.
Coase, Ronald H. (1959), The Federal Communications Commission, 2 Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-40.
Coase, Ronald H. (1960), The Problem of Social Cost, 3 Journal of Law and Economics, 1-44.
Reprinted in Ackermann, Bruce A. (1975), Economic Foundations of Property Law, Boston,
Little Brown, 17-22. Reprinted in Medema, Steven G. (1995), The Legacy of Ronald Coase in
Economic Analysis, Vol.2, Aldershot, Edward Elgar Publishing, 5-48. Reprinted in Coase, Ronald
H. (1988), The Firm, the Market and the Law, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Coase, R. (1972), Policy Issues and Research Opportunities in Industrial Organization, in Fuchs,
Victor (ed.), Economic Research: Retrospective and Prospect (Vol.3), NBER General Series no.
96, Cambridge National Bureau of Economic Research, 59-73.
Coase, Ronald H. (1988), The Firm, the Market and the Law, Chicago, University of Chicago Press,
217 p.
Coase, Ronald H. (1991), The Institutional Structure of Production, in Coase, Ronald H. (ed.),Essays
on Economics and Economists, Chicago, IL, University of Chicago Press.
Coase, Ronald H. (1992), The Institutional Structure of Production, 82(4) American Economic
Review, 713-719.
0740 Transaction Costs 917
Coelho Philip R.P. (1975), Externalities, Liability Separability and Resource Allocation: Comment,
65 American Economic Review, 721-723.
Cohen, Lloyd R. (1991), Holdouts and Free Riders, 20 Journal of Legal Studies, 351-362.
Constantinides, G.M. (1976), Optimal Portfolio Revision with Proportional Transaction Costs:
Extension to HARA Utility Functions and Exogenous Deterministic Income, 22 Management
Science, 921-923.
Constantinides, G.M. (1979), Mutiperiod Consumption and Investment Behavior with Convex
Transaction Costs, 25 Management Science, 1127-1137.
Constantinides, G.M. (1986), Capital Market Equilibrium with Transaction Costs, 94 Journal of
Political Economy, 842-862.
Cooter, Robert D. (1982), The Cost of Coase, 11 Journal of Legal Studies, 1-33. Reprinted in
Donahue, Charles Jr, Kauper, Thomas E. and Martin, Peter W. (1992), Property: An Introduction
to the Concept and the Institution. Reprinted in Ackerman, Bruce, Ellickson, Robert and Rose,
Carol (1995), Foundations of Property Law. Reprinted in Medema, Steven G. (ed.) (1995), The
Legacy of Ronald Coase in Economic Analysis, Aldershot, Edward Elgar Publishing, 96-128.
Copeland, T.E. and Galai, D. (1983), Information Effects on the Bid Ask Spread, 38 Journal of
Finance, 1457-1469.
Crew, M.A. and Kleindorfer, D.R. (1985), Governance Costs or Rate-of-Return Regulation, 141
Journal of Theoretical and Institutional Economics, 104-123.
Crocker, Keith J. and Masten, Scott E. (1988), Mitigating Contractual Hazards: Unilateral Options and
Contract Length, 19 Rand Journal of Economics, 327-343.
Crocker, Keith J. and Masten, Scott E. (1991), Pretia ex Machina? Prices and Process in Long-Term
Contracts, 34 Journal of Law and Economics, 69-99.
Datta, Samar, OHara, Donald and Nugent, Jeffrey (1986), Choice of Agricultural Tenancy in the
Presence of Transaction Costs, 62(2), Land Economics.
Davis, L. (1986), Comment, in Gallman (ed.), Long Term Factors in American Economic Growth,
Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 149-161.
Davis, M.H. and Norman, A.R. (1990), Portfolio Selection with Transaction Costs, 15 Mathematical
Operations Research, 676-713.
Demsetz, H. (1969), Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint, Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-22.
Demsetz, Harold (1964), The Exchange and Enforcement of Property Rights, 7 Journal of Law and
Economics, 11-26.
Demsetz, Harold (1967), Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 57 American Economic Review,
347-359. Reprinted in Demsetz, Harold (1988), Ownership, Control and the Firm: The
Organization of Economic Activity, Vol. I, Cambridge: Basil Blackwell, 104-116
Demsetz, Harold (1968), The Cost of Transacting, 82 Quarterly Journal of Economics, 33-53.
Demsetz, Harold (1972), When Does the Rule of Liability Matter?, 1 Journal of Legal Studies,
13-28.
Demsetz, Harold (1988), The Theory of the Firm Revisited, 4 Journal of Law, Economics and
Organization, 141-161.
Demsetz, Harold (1995), The Economics of the Business Firm, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press.
918 Transaction Costs 0740
Dermody, J.C. and Prisman, E.Z. (1993), No Arbitrage and Valuation in Markets with Realistic
Transaction Costs, 28 Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 65-80.
Dewatripont, Mathias (1989), Renegotiation and Information Revelation over Time: The Case of
Optimal Labor Contracts, 103 Quarterly Journal of Economics, 589-619.
Dnes, Antony W. (1992), Unfair Practices and Hostages in Franchise Contracts, 148 Journal of
Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 484-504.
Dnes, Antony W. (1993), A Case-Study Analysis of Franchise Contracts, 22 Journal of Legal
Studies, 367-393.
Dnes, Antony W. (1996), The Economic Analysis of Franchise Contracts, 152 Journal of
Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 297-324.
Donohue, John J. III (1989), Diverting the Coasian River: Incentive Schemes to Reduce
Unemployment Spells, 99 Yale Law Journal, 549-609.
Dudek, Daniel J. and Wiener, Jonathan Baert (1996), Joint Implementation, Transaction Costs and
Climate Change, Paris, OECD.
Dugger, William M. (1983), The Transaction Cost Analysis of O.E. Williamson: A New Synthesis?,
17 Journal of Economic Issues, 95-114.
Dumas, B. and Luciano, E. (1991), An Exact Solution to a Dynamic Portfolio Choice Problem under
Transactions Costs, 46 Journal of Finance, 577-595.
Edirisinghe, C., Naik, V. and Uppal, R. (1993), Optimal Replication of Options with Transactions
Costs and Trading Restrictions, 28 Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 117-138.
Eggertsson, Thrainn (1990a), Economic Behaviour and Institutions, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press, 385 p.
Eggertsson, Thrainn (1990b), The Role of Transaction Costs and Property Rights in Economic
Analysis, 34 European Economic Review, 450-457.
Ellickson, Robert C. (1991), Order Without Law: How Neighbours Settle Disputes, Cambridge, MA,
Harvard University Press.
Eppen, G. and Fama, Eugene F. (1969), Cash Balance and Simple Dynamic Portfolio Problems with
Proportional Costs, 10 International Economic Review, 119-133.
Eswaran, Mukesh and Kotwal, A. (1985), A Theory of Contractual Structure in Agriculture, 75
American Economic Review, 352-367.
Fischel, William A. (1980), Externalities and Zoning, 35 Public Choice, 37-43.
Fishback, Price V. (1986), Did Coal Miners Owe their Souls to the Company Store? Theory and
Evidence from the Early 1900s, 46 Journal of Economic History, 1011-1029.
Fishback, Price V. (1992), The Economics of Company Housing: Historical Perspectives from the
Coal Fields, 8 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 346-365.
Fisher, S. (1994), Asset Trading, Transaction Costs and the Equity Premium, 9 Journal of Applied
Econometrics, 571-594.
Foley, D.K. (1970), Economic Equilibrium with Costly Marketing, 2 Journal of Economic Theory,
276-291.
Frech, H. Edward III (1973), Pricing of Pollution: The Coase Theorem in the Long Run, 4(1) Bell
Journal of Economics, 316-319.
Frech, H. Edward III (1979), The Extended Coase Theorem and Long Run Equilibrium: The
Non-Equivalence of Liability Rules and Property Rights, 27(1) Economic Inquiry, 254-268.
Freixas, X., Guesnerie, Roger and Tirole, Jean (1985), Planning Under Incomplete Information and
the Ratchet Effect, 52 Review of Economic Studies, 173-191.
0740 Transaction Costs 919
Frenkel, Jacob A. and Levich, R.M. (1975), Covered Interest Arbitrage: Unexploited Profits, 83
Journal of Political Economy, 325-338.
Frey, Bruno S. (1985), Comment on Barzel, Transaction Costs: Are they Just Costs?, 141 Journal
of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 17-20.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1991), Thesmikes Analyseis sten Oikonomike: E Theoria ton Praxiakon
Dikaiomaton (Institutional Analyses in Economics: The Property Rights Theory), 4 Aissymnetes,
27-48.
Gennotte, G. and Jung, A. (1994), Investment Strategies under Transaction Costs: The Finite Horizon
Case, 40 Management Science, 385-404.
George, T.J., Kaul, G. and Nimalendran, M. (1994), Trading Volume and Transaction Costs in
Specialist Markets, 49 Journal of Finance, 1489-1505.
Globerman, S. (1980), Markets, Hierarchies and Innovation, 14 Journal of Economic Issues,
977-998.
Globerman, S. and Schwindt, R. (1986), The Organization of Vertically Related Transactions in the
Canadian Forest Products Industries, 7 Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,
199-212.
Glosten, L. and Milgrom, Paul R. (1985), Bid, Ask and Transaction Prices in a Specialist Market with
Heterogeneously Informed Traders, 14 Journal of Financial Economics, 71-100.
Goldberg, Victor P. (1989), Production Functions, Transactions, Costs and the New Institutonalism,
in Goldberg, Victor P. (ed.), Readings in the Economics of Contract Law, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press, 21-23. Reprinted in Feiwel, George (ed.), Issues in Contemporary
Microeconomics, Macmillan Press, 1985, 395-402.
Goldberg, Victor P. and Erickson, John R. (1987), Quantity and Price Adjustments in Long-Term
Contracts: A Case Study of Petroleum Coke, 30 Journal of Law and Economics, 369-398.
Goldsmith, D. (1976), Transaction Costs and the Theory of Portfolio Selection, 31 Journal of
Finance, 1127-1139.
Grossman, Sanford J. and Hart, Oliver D. (1986), The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of
Vertical and Lateral Integration, 94 Journal of Political Economy, 691-719.
Guia-Abiad, V. (1993), Borrower Transaction Costs and Credit Rationing in Rural Financial Markets:
The Philippine Case, 31 Developing Economies, 208-219.
Hahn, F.H. (1971), Equilibrium with Transaction Costs, 39 Econometrica, 417-439.
Hahn, F.H. (1973), On Transaction Costs, Inessential Sequence Economies and Money, 40 Review
of Economic Studies, 449-461.
Hall, Christopher D. (1986), Market Enforced Information Asymmetry: A Study of Claiming Races,
24 Economic Inquiry, 271-291.
Hansen, Robert G. and Thomas, Randall S. (1992), An Auction - Theoretic Analysis of Corporate
Auctioneers Liability Regimes, 4 Wisconsin Law Review.
Hart, D. and Kuhn, H. (1975), A Proof of Existence of Equilibrium Without the Free Disposal
Assumption, 2 Journal of Mathematical Economics, 335-343.
Hart, Oliver D. and Moore, John (1990), Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm, 98 Journal of
Political Economy, 1119-1158.
Heller, W. and Starr, R. (1976), Equilibrium with Non-convex Transaction Costs: Monetary and
Non-monetary Economies, 43 Review of Economic Studies, 195-215.
920 Transaction Costs 0740
Hennart, Jean-Franois, Anderson, E. and Anderson, Erin (1993), Countertrade and the Minimization
of Transaction Costs: An Empirical Examination, 9 Journal of Law, Economics and
Organization, 290-313.
Hess, James D. (1990), A Comparison of Alternative Approaches to Economic Organization:
Comment, 146 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 72-75.
Hicks, John R. (1935), A Suggestion for Simplifying the Theory of Money, 2 Economica, 1-19.
Hirshleifer, Jack (1973), Exchange Theory: The Missing Chapter, 11 Western Economic Journal,
129-146.
Holm, Hakan J. (1995), Computational Cost of Verifying Enforceable Contracts, 15 International
Review of Law and Economics, 127-140.
Holmstrom, B. (1979), Moral Hazard and Observability, 10 Bell Journal of Economics, 74-91.
Holmstrm, Bengt (1982), Moral Hazard in Teams, 13 Bell Journal of Economics, 324-340.
Holmstrm, Bengt and Milgrom, Paul R. (1991), Multitask Principal-Agent Analyses: Incentive
Contracts, Asset Ownership and Job Design, 7 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization,
24-52.
Holmstrm, Bengt and Milgrom, Paul R. (1994), The Firm as an Incentive System, 84 American
Economic Review, 972-991.
Huberman, Gur (1990), Dividend Neutrality with Transaction Costs, 63 Journal of Business,
93-107.
Hutter, Michael (1986), Transaction Cost and Communication, in Graf Von Der Schulenburg,
J.-Matthias and Skogh, Gran (eds), Law and Economics and The Economics of Legal
Regulation, Dordrecht, Kluwer, 113-129.
Hwang, Chun-Sin and Kan, Steven S. (1994), Principles of Economics, Cooperating for Mutual
Prosperity and Progress (in Chinese), Published by the authors and distributed by Shin Lu
Bookstore, Taipei.
Hwang, Chun-Sin and Kan, Steven S. (1995), Democracy and the Principle for the Division of Labor
in Government Organization (in Chinese), in Chien, Sechin Y.S. and Tai, Terence H. (eds),
Philosophy and Public Norms, Taipei, Academia Sinica, Sun Yat-sen Institute for Social Sciences
and Philosophy, 163-200.
Jensen, M. and Meckling, W. (1976), Theory of the Firm: Manegerial Behavior, Agency Costs and
Ownership Structure, 3 Journal of Financial Economics, 305-360.
Johnsen, D. Bruce (1992), The Incentive Effects of Soft Dollar Brokerage, in Lehn, Kenneth and
Kamphuis, Robert (eds), Modernizing US Securities Regulations: Economic and Legal
Perspectives, 511-519.
Johnsen, D. Bruce (1994), Property Rights to Investment Research: The Agency Costs of Soft Dollar
Brokerage, 11 Yale Journal on Regulation, 75-113.
Johnsen, D. Bruce (1995), The Quasi-Rent Structure of Corporate Enterprise: A Transaction Cost
Theory, 44 Emory Law Journal, 1277 ff.
Johnsen, D. Bruce, Habib, Michel A. and Naik, Narayan Y. (1998), Spin-offs and Information,
Journal of Financial Intermediation, forthcoming.
Joskow, Paul L. (1985), Vertical Integration and Long-Term Contracts: The Case of Coal-Burning
Electric Generating Plants, 1 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 33-80.
0740 Transaction Costs 921
Joskow, Paul L. (1987), Contract Duration and Relationship-Specific Investments: Empirical Evidence
from Coal Markets, 77 American Economic Review, 168-185.
Joskow, Paul L. (1988), Price Adjustment in Long-Term Contracts: The Case of Coal, 31 Journal
of Law and Economics, 47-83.
Joskow, Paul L. (1990), The Performance of Long-term Contracts: Further Evidence from Coal
Markets, 21 Rand Journal of Economics, 251-274.
Jouini, E. and Kallal, H. (1995), Martingales and Arbitrage in Securities Markets with Transaction
Costs, 66 Journal of Economic Theory, 178-197.
Jovanovic, Aleksandra (1993), Participativna Ekonomija: Uticaj Tipa Svojine na Ponasanje
(Efikasnost) Preduzeca (Participatory Economics: Influence of a Property Form on Behaviour
(Efficacy) of a Firm), Belgrade, Pravni fakultet.
Jovanovic, Aleksandra (1994), Transakcioni Troskovi Privatizacije (Transaction Costs of
Privatisation), 43(9-10) Pravni Zivot, 895-905.
Jovanovic, Aleksandra (1996), Ekonomski Efekti Nekih Ekonomskih Prava, in Svetislav, Taborosi
(ed.), Srbija u Tranziciji, Belgrade, Pravni fakultet, 113-125.
Jovanovic, Aleksandra, Hiber, Dragor (1996), Postupak Izvrsenja na Imovini Drustvenog Preduzeca
i Moralni Hazard (Execution Procedure on the Propery of a Social Enterprise and Moral Hazard),
in X (ed.), Svojina i Slobode - Aspekti Tranzicije, Belgrade, Institut ekonomskih nauka, 202-208.
Jovanovic, Aleksandra, Mijatovic Bosko (1996), Preduzece i Moralni Hazard (Firm and Moral
Hazard), 45(5-8) Pravni Zivot, 404-415.
Kamin, J.H. (1975), Optimal Portfolio Revision with a Proportional Transaction Cost, 21
Management Science, 1263-1271.
Kan, Steven S. (1993), Entrepreneurship, Transaction Costs and Subjectivist Economics,1(2) Journal
of Enterprising Culture, 159-182.
Kan, Steven S. and Hsiao, Ding-Way (1996), Contracts in Tsing Dynasty to Build Irrigation System
at Lan-Yang Plain: A Transaction Cost Analysis, 59 Journal of Agricultural Economics
(Chinese), 111-157.
Kan, Steven S. and Hwang, Chun-Sin (1994), Principles of Economics: Cooperating for Mutual
Prosperity and Progress (in Chinese), Published by the authors and distributed by Shin Lu
Bookstore, Taipei.
Kan, Steven S. and Hwang, Chun-Sin (1996), A Form of Government Organization from the
Perspective of Transaction Cost Economics, 7 Constitutional Political Economy, 197-220.
Kaplow, Louis and Shavell, Steven (1996), Property Rules versus Liability Rules: An Economic
Analysis, 109 Harvard Law Review, 713-790.
Kelman, Mark G. (1979), Consumption Theory, Production Theory and Ideology in the Coase
Theorem, 52 Southern California Law Review, 669-698.
Kitch, Edmund W. (ed.) (1983), The Fire of Truth: A Remembrance of Law and Economics at
Chicago, 1932-1970, 26 Journal of Law and Economics, 163-233.
Klein, Benjamin and Leffler, Keith B. (1981), The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual
Performance, 89 Journal of Political Economy, 615-641.
Klein, Benjamin, Crawford, Robert G. and Alchian, Armen A. (1978), Vertical Integration,
Appropriable Rents and the Competitive Contracting Process,21 Journal of Law and Economics,
297-326.
Knight, Frank (1921), Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, London, Houghton Mifflin Company.
922 Transaction Costs 0740
Masten, Scott E. and Crocker, Keith J. (1985), Efficient Adaptation in Long-Term Contracts:
Take-or-Pay Provisions for Natural Gas, 75 American Economic Review, 1083-1093.
Masten, Scott E., Meehan, James W., Jr and Snyder, Edward A. (1989), Vertical Integration in the
U.S. Auto Industry: A Note on the Influence of Transaction Specific Assets, 12 Journal of
Economic Behavior and Organization, 265-273.
Masten, Scott E., Meehan, James W., Jr and Snyder, Edward A. (1991), The Costs of Organization,
7 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 1-25.
Mayshar, J. (1979), Transaction Costs in a Model of Capital Market Equilibrium, 87 Journal of
Political Economy, 673-700.
Mayshar, J. (1981), Transaction Costs and the Pricing of Assets, 36 Journal of Finance, 583-597.
McKenzie, L. (1981), The Classical Theorems on Existence of Competitive Equilibrium, 49
Econometrica, 819-841.
McManus, J. (1975), The Cost of Alternative Economic Organizations, 8 Canadian Journal of
Economics, 334-350.
Medema, Steven G. (1994), Ronald H. Coase, London, Macmillan.
Medema, Steven G. (1995a), Through a Glass Darkly, or Just Wearing Dark Glasses? Posin, Coase
and the Coase Theorem, 62 Tennessee Law Review, 1041-1056.
Medema, Steven G. (1995b), The Legacy of Ronald Coase in Economic Analysis, 2 vols, Aldershot,
Edward Elgar.
Medema, Steven G. (1996a), Of Pangloss, Pigouvians and Pragmatism: Ronald Coase on Social Cost
Analysis, 18 Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 96-114.
Medema, Steven G. (1996b), Comment: The Coase Theorem, Rent Seeking and the Forgotten
Footnote, 16 International Review of Law and Economics.
Medema, Steven G. (forthcoming), The Coase Theorem, in Coopera and Argyris (eds), The
Encyclopedia of Managerial Economics, Oxford, Basil Blackwell.
Mehra, R. and Prescott, E. (1985), The equity Premium - A Puzzle, 15(2) Journal of Monetary
Economics, 145-161.
Milgrom, Paul R. and Roberts, Mark J. (1992), Economics, Organization and Management,
Englewood Cliffs, NJ, Prentice-Hall.
Milovanovic Milic (1994), Privatizacija i Ekonomska Efikasnost (Privatization and Economic
Efficiency), 1-2 Ekonomska Misao, 1-20.
Modigliani, Franco and Miller, Merton H. (1958), The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the
Theory of Investment, 48 American Economic Review, 261-297.
Monteverde, Kirk and Teece, David J. (1982), Appropriable Rents and Quasi-Vertical Integration,
25 Journal of Law and Economics, 321-328.
Mukherjee, R. and Zabel, E. (1974), Consumption and Portfolio Choices with Transaction Costs, in
Balch, McFadden and Wu (eds), Essays on Economic Behavior under Uncertainty, Amsterdam,
North-Holland.
Niehans, J. (1969), Money in a Static Theory of Optimal Payment Arrangements, 1 Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking, 706-726.
Niehans, J. (1971), Money and Barter in General Equilibrium with Transaction Costs, 61 American
Economic Review, 773-783.
Niehans, J. (1987), Transaction Costs, in Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray and Newman, Peter (eds),
The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, London, Macmillan, 676-679.
924 Transaction Costs 0740
North, Douglass C. (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History, New York, W.W. Norton.
North, Douglass C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass C. and Weingast, Barry R. (1989), Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution
of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth Century England, 49 Journal of
Economic History, 803-832.
Olson, A. (1987), Leaving Liablity Alone, Aug 12 Wall Street Journal, 18 ff.
Ott, Claus (1991), Vorvertragliche Aufklrungspflichten im Recht des Gter- und
Leistungsaustausches (Precontractual Obligation to Provide Information in the Law), in Ott, Claus
and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Probleme des Zivilrechts, Berlin, Springer,
142-162.
Parkman, Allen M. (1992), Unilateral Divorce and the Labor-Force Participation Rate of Married
Women Revisited, 82 American Economic Review, 671-678.
Pesaran, M.H. and Timmermann, A. (1994), Forecasting Stock Returns: An Examination of Stock
Market Trading in the Presence of Transacton Costs, 13 Journal of Forecasting, 335-367.
Phillips, S.M. and Smith, C.W., Jr (1980), Trading Costs for Listed Options: The Implications for
Market Efficiency, 8 Journal of Financial Economics, 179-201.
Protopapadakis, A. and Stoll, H.R. (1983), Spot and Futures Prices and the Law of One Price, 38
Journal of Finance, 1431-1455.
Provencher, Bill (1991), A Quantitative Analysis of Private Property Rights in Groundwater,
University of California, Davis, Ph.D. Dissertation.
Radner, Roy (1972), Existence of Equilibrium of Plans, Prices and Price Expectations in a Sequence
of Markets, 40 Econometrica, 289-303.
Repullo, R. (1988), The Core of an Economy with Transaction Costs, 40 Review of Economic
Studies, 447-458.
Ricardo, D. (1951), Funding System, in Straffa, P. (ed.), The Works and Correspondence of David
Ricardo, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Rothschild, Michael and Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1976), Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets:
An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect Information, 90 Quarterly Journal of Economics,
629-649.
Rubin, Paul H. (1990), Managing Business Transactions, New York, Free Press.
Ryssdal, Stray A.C. (1995), Legal Realism and Economics as Behavior - A Scandinavian Look at the
Economic Analysis of Law, Oslo, Juridisk Forlag.
Samuels, Warren J. (1974), The Coase Theorem and the Study of Law and Economics, 14 Natural
Resources Journal, 1-33.
Schlag, Pierre (1989), The Problem of Transaction Costs, 62 Southern California Law Review,
1661-1699.
Schmidtchen, Dieter (1989), Evolutorische Ordnungstheorie oder: die Transaktionskosten und das
Unternehmertum (The Theory of Evolutionary Order, or: Transaction Costs and
Entrepreneurship), Ordo: Jahrbuch fr die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, 161-182.
Schultz, P. (1983), Transaction Costs and the Small Firm Effect,12 Journal of Financial Economics,
81-88.
Shaffer, S. (1989), Structuring an Option to Facilitate Replication with Transaction Costs, 31
Economic Letters, 183-187.
0740 Transaction Costs 925
Shapiro, David L. (1974), Rent and the Coase Theorem, 7(1) Journal of Economic Theory, 125-128.
Shavell, Steven (1979), Risk Sharing and Incentives in the Principal and Agent Relationship, 10 Bell
Journal of Economics, 55-73.
Shelanski, H and Klein, P. (1995), Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Economics: A Review and
Assessment, 11 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 335-361.
Smiley, Robert H. (1976), Tender Offers, Transactions Costs and the Theory of the Firm, 58(1)
Review of Economics and Statistics, 22-32.
Starret, David A. (1973), Inefficiency and the Demand for Money in a Sequence Economy, 40
Review of Economic Studies, 437-448.
Stavins, R.N. (1995), Transaction Costs and Tradable Permits, 29 Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management, 133-148.
Stigler, George J. (1988), Memoirs of an Unregulated Economist, New York, Basic Books, 228 p.
Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1974), Incentives and Risk Sharing in Sharecropping, 61 Review of Economic
Studies, 219-256.
Stout, Lynn A. (1997), A Technology, Transactions Costs and Investor Welfare: Is a Motley Fool Born
Every Minute?, 75 Washington University Law Quarterly.
Tobin, James (1956), The Interest-Elasticity of Transactions Demand for Cash, 38(3) Review of
Economics and Statistics, 241-247.
Ulph, A.M. and Ulph, D.T. (1975), Transaction Costs in General Equilibrium Theory - A Survey, 42
Economica, 355-372.
Ulph, A.M. and Ulph, D.T. (1977), Efficiency, Inessentiality and `Debreu Property of Prices, in
Schwdiauer (ed.), Equlibrium and Disequilibrium in Economic Theory, Dordrecht, Reidel,
337-359.
Wagner, W. and Schulman, E. (1994), Passive Trading: Point and Counterpoint, 20 Journal of
Portfolio Management, 25-28.
Wallis, J. and North, C. (1986), Measuring the Transaction Sector in the American Economy,
1870-1970, in Gallman (ed.), Long Term Factors in American Economic Growth, Chicago,
University of Chicago Press, 95-148.
Wegehenkel, Lothar (1980), Transaktionskosten, Wirtschaftssystem und Unternehmertum
(Transaction Costs, Economic System and Entrepreneurship), Tbingen, Mohr, 77 p.
West, E.G. (1990), Adam Smith and Modern Economics, Hants, Edward Elgar.
Whincop, Michael J. (1996), Due Diligence in SME Fundraising: Reform Choices, Economics and
Empiricism, 20 University of New South Wales Law Journal, 433-464.
Whincop, Michael J. (1997), Nexuses of Contracts, the Authority of Corporate Agents and Doctrinal
Indeterminacy: From Formalism to Law-and-Economics, 20 University of New South Wales Law
Journal.
Wilcox, J.W. (1993), The Effect of Transaction Costs and Delay on Performance Drag, 49 Financial
Analysts Journal, 45-54.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1971), The Vertical Integration of Production: Market Failure Considerations,
61 American Economic Review, 112-123.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implication: A Study
in the Economics of Internal Organization, New York, Free Press, 286 p.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1976), Franchise Bidding for Natural Monopolies - in General and with Resect
to CATV, 7 Bell Journal of Economics, 73-104.
926 Transaction Costs 0740
Abstract
Public goods contrast with private goods. Pure public goods have the unique
characteristics of non-excludability and non-rivalry in consumption while
private goods are sold to those who can afford to pay the market price. The
under-supply equilibrium of a public goods provision is an important aspect of
the provision of public goods. The economic theory of clubs represents an
attempt to explain the under-supply equilibrium of a public goods provision. It
raises many different and controversial issues which impinge on government
policy in the public sector. In many respects, a club provision proffers an
alternative to a central government provision of local public goods. The salient
characteristic of a club, the excludability factor, may militate against an equal
and democratic distribution of the club good. At the level of voluntary clubs,
with which Buchanan was originally concerned, club theory can critically
appraise the efforts at achieving optimal membership of the club and the
maximum utility of club members. As the literature introduces increasing
problems with cooperation then it behoves law and economics scholars to
research and develop non-market and/or non-cooperative solutions to an
optimal provision of public goods.
JEL classification: D60, D71, K00.
Keywords: Free Rider, Pareto Optimality, Club Goods, Excludability and
Non-rivalry, Coase Theorem, Homogeneity
1. Introduction
Pure public goods as originally defined by Samuelson (1954) have the unique
characteristics of non-excludability and non-rivalry in consumption. Public
goods contrast with private goods; public goods are non-excludable and
non-rivalrous in consumption while private goods are sold to those who can
afford to pay the market price. The market price excludes some consumers
while the property of rivalrous consumption ensures that not all consumers who
can afford to pay the price, actually purchase the private good. The public
goods property of non-rivalry ensures that a provision of the good for consumer
A entails a provision for consumer B. Likewise, the property of
927
928 Public Goods and Club Goods 0750
There are, therefore, two salient properties pertaining to the provision of public
goods, namely, non-excludability in supply and non-rivalry in consumption.
The latter implies that inter-citizen consumption is mutually exclusive, that is,
the consumption by one citizen of the public good will not affect the
consumption level of any other citizen. Radio broadcasts, clean air or defence
spring to mind as examples of a non-rivalrous public good. Non-excludability
is the hallmark of a political system where the central government funding
0750 Public Goods and Club Goods 929
Excludable Non-Excludable
Excludable Non-Excludable
whether they like them or not a range of public goods, for example defence.
They further comment that it is entirely possible that the welfare of some
individuals might fall when a marginal unit of the public good is provided.
The Pareto optimality conditions would have to allow for subsidies for these
individuals to ensure that the marginal utility to tax price ratios for all
individuals are equal. The forced rider may influence the provision of the
public good. This could be extended to local goods and services where forced
riders may be involved in decision making.
Pigou (1920) had suggested that government intervention was necessary in
order to abate the externality problem. The transactions costs of grouping
concerned citizens together in order to resolve the externality problem was
prohibitive. Coase (1960) argued that in the absence of transaction costs,
concerned citizens could resolve the problem, independent of government.
Theorem 1, the Coase Theorem and the liability rules amend the public choice
analysis of the externality problem.
The apportionment of blame and the allocation of property rights, that is,
the right to clean air, the right to pollute, proffer an alternative, indeed a
complement, to the introduction of Pigovian taxes. The idea behind liability
rules was to apportion blame; an alternative to this procedure in tort law is to
establish optimal conditions which may prevent the accident or property rights
dispute occuring. The traditional response in public finance was either to
compensate the offended party or tax the offending party. This required an
apportionment of blame which may have induced unnecessary government
expenditure and rent-seeking activity. The costs incurred must be weighted
against an inter-citizen or club resolution of the initial dispute.
The costs of providing the public good must include the bargaining costs
attributable to the resolution of the ensuing debate on the amount of public
good supplied, if at all. The treatment of these bargaining costs are a cental
feature in Buchanan and Tullock (1962) whose framework was used by Loehr
and Sandler (1978) in considering the impact of bargaining costs in the
provision of public goods. They illustrate the net indirect costs imposed on
forced riders and the number of individuals required to reach agreement on
public provision. They further represents costs imposed upon a person who
bears some burden under all decision rules with the exception of unanimity.
In this case if the individual was a forced rider he would agree to the
decision only when adequately compensated, that is when net costs are zero
where the entire population is in agreement. Loehr and Sandler further
0750 Public Goods and Club Goods 933
comment that their cost function is downward sloping since the greater the
proportion of the population needed for agreement, the more likely persons
similiar to himself (but not identical to him) will be wooed by the early
proponents of the public action. A point may be reached where the need to
form larger and larger coalitions would force bargains between free riders and
forced riders. A particularly interesting point in Loehr and Sandler (p. 31) is
their comment that the cost curve need not end at zero when unanimity is
reached.
In other words, some free riders, they argue, may still exist, even where
everyone is in agreement on the policy. Summation of all individual cost
curves in their presentation creates a community cost curve which indicates that
more and more decisive groups would imply a higher cost in terms of effort and
bargaining. If the decisions have to be made at the point where community
costs are at a minimum then we are abandoning Pareto optimality. The solution
presented represents a second best solution. McNutt (1996) considered an
inter-citizen resolution by adapting an earlier argument in Turvey (1968, p.
310) who had argued that the traditional interpretation of an externality is
rather restrictive. How much group B suffers from As externality depends not
only on the scale of As diseconomy but also on the precise nature of As
activity and Bs reaction to it. For example, the victim in Pigous chimney
example could reduce the disutility by installing an indoor clothes-line.
The Pigouvian solution of reducing the amount of smoke contrasts with the
alternative solution of either building a higher chimney or using different
smokeless fuel. McNutt (1996) shows that by allowing an inter-citizen
resolution to a dispute, the cost may be less than the government cost. If
citizens can agree on the resolution of an externality problem, the cost to the
government of financing the inter-citizen solution may be less than a central
government solution. An inter-citizen resolution like the Coase theorem offers
an alternative to government action in the resolution of an externality problem.
One policy implication of this result applies to traffic congestion in large cities.
Rather than impose a tax on car owners who persist in driving to the city at
rush hour, car-users should be encouraged to resolve the externalities of long
tailbacks, car emissions and queues by acting collectively. Car pools with
special motorway lane access, such as the HOV (heavy occupancy lanes with
at least three passengers per vehicle) lanes in the US, would be socially more
efficient than allowing as many fee paying cars to enter the city limits; citizens
would prefer to incur the lower garage parking fee for the pooled car.
5. Tiebout-Oates World
Definition: define the sub-group S of citizens such that there is an issue i which
at least one member j of the group regards as an externality, then j 0 S is
defined as an internal member of the set S. The set S is a proper subset of the
set, C, of all individuals in the square.
If the rule is to maximise the utility of the sharing group then emphasis will
be in the directon of group B. Ironically the utility of the A group will decrease.
The dominance of the internal group secures a reduction in the amount of local
public good in order to maximise the utility of the sharing group, B. McNutt
(1996, pp. 198-199) called this the tulips paradox, that is, in the local
provision of a public good the presence of a decisive internal heterogeneous
group with identical tastes may reduce the supply of the local public good in
order to maximise the utility of the larger citizenry group.
7. A Buchanan-Ng Framework
There are two basic models across the literature on club theory, the Buchanan
(1965) within-club model and the more general Oakland (1972) total economy
model which will be developed in a later section. Buchanans model is the
classic treatment of clubs while the Oakland model is more general in
extending club theory to include heterogeneous members, discrimination,
variations in the utilisation of the public good and exclusion costs. Neither
model, however, guarantees Pareto optimality in the provision of local goods,
which ironically is the raison dtre of club theory as a methodological study
of the allocative efficiency of (impure) public goods.
The assumptions underpinning the Buchanan model include the following:
(i) individuals have identical tastes for both private and public goods; (ii) the
size of the club good (a swimming pool), hence its total cost, is fixed; and (iii)
equal sharing of costs. Mueller (1979) has argued that (iii) follows as an
assumption from (i). In a simple model Buchanan determines the optimal size
of the club membership. Mueller shows that with some algebraic manipulation,
by deducting each individuals share (equal shares) of the cost of providing the
good from private income to obtain net of public good income and
substituting this into an objective function with the amount of public good and
club size as explanatory variables, the Buchanan model obtains the Samuelson
condition for the efficient consumption of a public good.
The crucial assumption in the Buchanan model, and in club theory
generally, is the assumption of identical tastes and incomes. The Tiebout model
shows that it is inefficient to have individuals of differing tastes in the same
club. Intuitively, think of ten women golfers in a golf club of 25 players. The
result here is akin to Paulys (1967) result, obtained much earlier, that no stable
equilibrium will exist if the women golfers form a winning majority. This is
particularly the case if the number of women golfers increased and the threat
of exit by the male golfers becomes credible - they could leave and form an
alternative club. The dynamics of the situation would suggest that a small
membership size is optimal - in other words, there has to be a limited degree
0750 Public Goods and Club Goods 937
The presumption is that a voluntary provision of the public good will lead to a
suboptimal outcome. The general model further assumes the existence of a
private good and an impure public good, with the private good acting as a
numeraire. The members are heterogeneous, non-members are costlessly
excluded and club members determine their utilisation rate of the club good by
varying the number of visits (to the public park) and time spent at the club.
Optimal provision in this general model, within which both members and
non-members are considered in deriving the optimal conditions for a single
club, requires, according to Sandler and Tschirhart (1980, p. 1489) that the
marginal benefits from crowding reduction, resulting from increased provision,
equal the marginal costs of provision (MRT). This is analogous to the earlier
Pareto optimal condition (MRS = MRT) for public goods provision and not
unlike the conclusion extracted by Buchanan. The utilisation condition in the
general Oakland model requires an equal rate of utilisation for all members,
although total toll payments (for utilisation) vary between heterogeneous
members.
Oaklands model is identical to the Buchanan model under the following
conditions: (i) all members are homogeneous and each consumes the available
quantity (say) X of the public good, such that Xi = Xj; (ii) for the members S the
crowding function must be an identity mapping, that is C(S) = S, this reduces
the general Oakland utility function to the Buchanan function U(Y1,X1,S),
where S substitutes for C(S). The insertion of a crowding function into the
0750 Public Goods and Club Goods 939
utility function is one major difference between the models in club theory.
Sandler (1978) argued that by including a crowding function, crowding
externalities such as poor view can be considered, (a) increases in the provision
of the public good reduces crowding (dc/dc < 0) and (b) increases in member
use of the good increases crowding, that is (dc/dxi > 0). It has been argued that
the general model implicitly assumes cardinality of the utility function. Sandler
and Tschirhart (1980, p. 1490) in their review of club theory comment that
since the general model requires an ordering of the population based upon club
preferences, cardinality is implicit.
Cardinality may rule out particular functional forms of the utility function,
that may be otherwise appropriate for club analysis, for example the
transformation W = LogU. In practice, however, populations cannot be ordered;
this applied weakness in the Oakland model has been overcome by Hillman and
Swan (1979) who proposed an ordinal representation that does not require an
ordering of the population. Their model, a ceteris paribus type model,
maximises an arbitrary members utility subject to the constancy of other
members utility levels. Recall that Buchanans model maximised individual
utility U(Y, X, S) subject to a production:cost constraint F(Y, X, S) = O. The
Hillman and Swan (1979) result is akin to this basic Buchanan model when (i)
C(S) = S and (ii) F = U[Y, X, C(S)]. The (ii) condition is the Buchanan
constraint in the optimization procedure; an analogy requires that the Hillman
and Swan constraint be rewritten as F = U[Y1, X, C(S)] = O. This may be
unlikely but worthy of further research.
Both Tiebout (1956) and Oakland (1972) represent alternative frameworks
to the approach adopted by Buchanan (1965) in accounting for the
under-supply of public goods. Oakland looked at the degree of congestion while
the Tiebout model is an application of club theory to community size. A
Tiebout-Oakland public goods problem would manifest itself for those public
goods for which congestion begins at a certain size of community. As the
community gets larger, residential density increases (community congestion),
reducing the utility of everyone living in the community. Two factors which are
important in the context are: (i) that the total number of people may not be an
integral multiple of N, the number of workers, that is there may be a fixed
population as identified by Pauly (1967); and (ii) the number of communities
may be fixed. The one exception, alluded to by Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980),
is a frontier society.
If the communities are fixed, say, to two, an optimal provision of the public
good may involve an equal treatment, a result which in Atkinson and Stiglitz
(1980) yields a local minimum (maximum) solution with population shortage
(excess), hence social welfare could be increased by moving to an unequal
treatment. A similiar point was alluded to earlier in the discussion of the
marginal decision curve. However, the general theory of clubs with the property
of no discrimination of members assumes a group of homogeneous individuals.
940 Public Goods and Club Goods 0750
The Tiebout world has heterogeneous individuals sorting themselves out into
homogeneous populations with homogeneous tastes. Hence doctors and lawyers
live in the same neighbourhood and there are golfers in the golf club and
swimmers in the swimming club. Health and sports clubs have to acquire an
optimal mix of members in order to minimise crowding and queues. A sorting
mechanism has to be introduced such as a rota or a time schedule based on
membership age. But is the sorting optimal? In answering this question we
have to refer to the concept of homogeneity.
9. Homogeneity
In the literature there are at least two interpretations of homogeneity in the club
literature; first (i) Tiebouts (1956, p. 419) homogeneity as captured in his work
where he commented on restrictions due to employment opportunities are not
considered. In mixed communities doctors and lawyers do not have equal
incomes since the respective income depends on labour supply. Consequently
they are not perfect substitutes and the community needs both; the community
is better off if they have the same tastes. Secondly, an Atkinson-Stiglitz (1980,
p. 531) type homogeneity, which is a weaker version of the Tiebout
homogeneity and argues that individuals are [not] always better off forming
homogeneous communities with people of identical tastes. In their argument,
they consider a third public good produced as a compromise to a merged
community forming from the separate communities. In the merged case the
individual can enjoy the benefits of the economies of scale associated with three
public goods (equivalent to our average cost reductions in the Buchanan
model), but when these benefits are weighted against diminishing returns to
labour N (equivalent to the declining benefits in a Buchanan model), the
individual is better off.
An interesting dimension arises in the context of a heterogeneous
population which can be translated into different marginal valuations. If, for
example, the local authority does not tax the individuals according to their
respective valuations, by imposing an equal tax, there may not be an optimal
provision of the local public good in the merged community. Those who value
the public good less, are essentially subsidised by the high-value individuals
and receive a windfall gain in the provision of the good. The movement from
separate communities to a merged community is not a Pareto improvement.
Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980) arrive at a similar result, assuming no
diminishing returns to labour, in looking at positive benefits, that is everyones
taxes [are] cut. Whether the sorting is optimal or not depends clearly on the
assumptions of diminishing returns to labour, the existence of a windfall
provision to individuals with lower valuations and on the assumption of
homogeneity.
0750 Public Goods and Club Goods 941
Theorem 2: The Henry George Theorem states that if public expenditure is fixed and
population varies, the population that maximises consumption per capita is such that
rents equal the public good expenditure.
The Starrett (1988, p. 62) result which states that the supply of the public
good should equal the pseudo-land rent in the optimal spatial club is in many
respects similiar to the Henry George Theorem as derived by Atkinson and
942 Public Goods and Club Goods 0750
Stiglitz (1980, p. 525). Optimization on club size leads to the Starrett result. In
a Henry George world, each citizen had identical tastes, an assumption which
is imported by Buchanan into his original club model. Since club rivalry
involves spatial separation the marginal cost of rivalry is reflected in the
marginal premia on limited space. Starrett concludes that in our bare-bones
model this premia could be measured in terms of transport costs, [but]
differential land rents turns out to be the right measure in broader contexts (p.
62). The measure is right, relatively speaking, in that it secures an optimal club
size. The different approaches within the general theory of clubs highlight the
many different characteristics of a club and of a club good. The general theory
of clubs offer a solution to the optimal provision of public goods.
In this final section we look at some of the more interesting areas of research
within the public and club goods literature, areas of recent controversies indeed
which have arisen across the literature. Many of the issues have an important
bearing on the optimal provision of local public goods and consequently on
local public finance.
Porter (1977), mixed clubs can always be shown to be less desirable than
homogeneous clubs. It is the set of second best constraints that relegates the
mixed clubs to second place in the efficiency comparisons. A scale of
membership fees may (paradoxically) encourage the intense user of the good
to use it less and while her less frequent user revisits frequently.
more clients at the expense of other clubs. The set of strategies is a Nash
equilibrium if no club can charge (X, P) such as to make more profit, with the
zero conjectural variation assumptions. The strategy space (X, N) is abandoned
because the Nash equilibrium requires the assumption, deemed unlikely by
Scotchmer (1985, p. 27), that the other [clubs] will change their prices in
whatever manner necessary to maintain the clientiele.
The earlier profit-maximising club literature explored by Berglas (1976)
and Wooders (1980) had assumed that there was an efficient size sharing group
and the conclusion has been that provided entry forces profits to zero, a club
equilibrium will be efficient. However, these firms are competitive in the sense
of being a utility-taker, whereas Scotchmer (1985) departs from this in
arguing that firms take as fixed the strategies of other firms. It is essentially a
non-cooperative game and the equilibrium is cast as a Nash equilibrium. For
members the utility available in other clubs will change as membership
changes.
Adelstein, Richard P. and Edelson, Noel (1976), Subdivision Exactions and Congestion Externalities,
5 Journal of Legal Studies, 147-163.
Aronson, J. Richard and Schwartz, E. (1973), Financing Public Goods and the Distribution of
Population in a System of Local Government, June, National Tax Journal, 353-367.
Aronson, J. Richard (1978), Public Finance, New York, McGraw-Hill.
Atkinson, Anthony B. and Stiglitz, J.E. (1980), Lectures in Public Economics, Maidenhead,
McGraw-Hill.
0750 Public Goods and Club Goods 947
Becker, G. and Tomes, Nigel (1976), Child Endowments and the Quantity and Quality of Children,
84 Journal of Political Economy, 143-165.
Benson, Bruce L. (1994), Are Public Goods Really Common Pools: Considerations of the Evolution
of Policing and Highways in England, 39 Economic Inquiry, 249-271.
Berglas, Eitan (1976), On the Theory of Clubs, 66 American Economic Review, 116-121.
Berglas, Eitan and Pines, D. (1978), Clubs, Local Public Goods and Transportation Models: A
Synthesis, Foerder Institute, 32/78 Working Paper.
Bergstrom, T., Blume, L. and Varian, H.R. (1986), On the Private Provision of Public Goods, 29
Journal of Public Economics, 25-49.
Bonus, Holger (1980), Offentliche Gter und der ffentlichkeitsgrad Von Gtern (Public Goods and
the Publicness of Goods), 136 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 50-81.
Borcherding, Thomas E. (1978), Competition, Exclusion and the Optimal Supply of Public Goods,
21 Journal of Law and Economics, 111-132.
Bowen, H.R. (1943), The Interpretation of Voting in Allocation of Resources, 58 Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 27-48.
Brennan, J. and Flowers, Marilyn R. (1980), All Ng Up on Clubs: Some Notes on the Current Status
of Club Theory, 8(2) Public Finance Quarterly, 153-170.
Brown, C.V. and Jackson, P.M. (1990), Public Sector Economics, Oxford, Basil Blackwell.
Brubaker, Earl D. (1975), Free Ride, Free Revelation, or Golden Rule?, 18 Journal of Law and
Economics, 147-161.
Buchanan, James M. (1949), The Pure Theory of Government Finance: A Suggested Approach, 57
Journal of Political Economy, 496-505.
Buchanan, James M. (1965), An Economic Theory of Clubs, 32 Economica, 1-14.
Buchanan, James M. (1967), Public Goods in Theory and Practice: A Note on the
Minasian-Samuelson Discussion, 10 Journal of Law and Economics, 193-197.
Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon (1962), Calculus of Consent, Ann Arbor, University of
Michigan Press.
Cebula, R.J. (1979), A Survey of the Literature on the Migration of State and Local Government
Policies, 34 Public Finance, 69-82.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1973), The Fable of the Bees: An Economic Investigation, 16 Journal of Law
and Economics, 11-33.
Coase, Ronald H. (1960), The Problem of Social Cost, 3 Journal of Law and Economics, 1-44.
Reprinted in Ackermann, Bruce A. (1975), Economic Foundations of Property Law, Boston,
Little Brown, 17-22. Reprinted in Medema, Steven G. (1995), The Legacy of Ronald Coase in
Economic Analysis, Vol. 2, Aldershot, Edward Elgar Publishig, 5-48. Reprinted in Coase, Ronald
H. (1988), The Firm, the Market and the Law, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Coase, Ronald H. (1974), The Lighthouse in Economics, 23 Journal of Law and Economics,
357-376.
Cohen, Lloyd R. (1991), Holdouts and Free Riders, 20 Journal of Legal Studies, 351-362.
Cornes, Richard and Sandler, Todd (1986), The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods and Club
Goods, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 303 p.
De Geest, Gerrit (1992), The Provision of Public Goods in Apartment Buildings, 12 International
Review of Law and Economics, 299-315.
De Jasay, Anthony (1989), Social Contract, Free Ride: A Study on the Public Goods Problem,
Oxford, Oxford University Press, 256 p.
948 Public Goods and Club Goods 0750
Demsetz, Harold (1970a), The Private Production of Public Goods, 13 Journal of Law and
Economics, 293-306.
Demsetz, Harold (1970b), Reply to Professor Thompson, 16 Journal of Law and Economics,
413-415.
Demsetz, Harold (1973), Joint Supply and Price Discrimination, 16 Journal of Law and Economics,
389-405.
Dubin, Jeffrey A. and Navarro, Peter (1988), How Markets for Impure Public Goods Organize: The
Case of Household Refuse Collection,4 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 217-241.
Ekelund, Robert B., Jr and Hulett, Joe R. (1973), Joint Supply, the Taussig-Pigou Controversy and
the Competitive Provision of Public Goods, 16 Journal of Law and Economics, 369-387.
Evans, Andrew (1970), Private Good, Externality, Public Good, 17 Scottish Journal of Political
Economy, 79-89.
Frech, H. Edward III and Rochlin, Clifford B. (1979), Advertising as a Privately Supplied Public
Good, 27(2) Economic Inquiry, 414-418.
Frech, H. Edward III and Rochlin, Clifford B. (1982), A New Economic View of Advertising, 1
Journal of Advertising, 213-222.
Goldin, Kenneth D. (1977), Equal Access versus Selective Access: A Critique of Public Goods
Theory, 29 Public Choice, 53-71.
Green, Jerry R. (1976), Consumer Theory, London, Macmillan.
Hansmann, Henry B. (1986), A Theory of Status Organizations, 2 Journal of Law, Economics and
Organization, 119-130.
Hartog, Hendrik (1981), Property as Government in Eighteenth-Century America: The Case of New
York City, 10 Journal of Legal Studies, 305-341.
Head, John G. (1974), Public Goods and Public Policy, Durham, NC, Duke University Press.
Helpman, Elhanan (1979), On Optimal Community Formation, 1 Economic Letters, 289-293.
Helpman, Elhanan and Hillman, Arye L. (1977), On Optimal Club Size, Foerder Institute, 91/76
Working Paper.
Hillman, Arye L. (1978), The Theory of Clubs: A Technological Formulation, in Sando (ed.), Essays
in Public Economics: The Kiryat Anavim Papers, Lexington, Lexington Books.
Hillman, Arye L. and Swan, Peter L. (1979), Club Participation Under Uncertainty, Mimeo.
Holtermann, A. (1972), Externalities and Public Goods, 39 Economica.
Hummel, Jeffrey Rogers (1990), National Goods Versus Public Goods: Defense, Disarmament and
Free Riders, 4 Review of Austrian Economics, 88-122.
Kaplow, Louis (1993), Should the Governments Allocation Branch be Concerned about the
Distortionary Cost of Taxation and Distributive Effects?, Program in Law and Economics
Discussion Paper, 122 ff.
Kim, O. and Walker, Martin (1984), The Free Rider Problem: Experimental Evidence, 43 Public
Choice, 3 ff.
Knight, Frank H. (1924), Some Fallacies in the Interpretion of Social Cost, 38 Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 582-602.
Kormendi, Roger C. (1979), A New Remedy for the Free Rider Problem? - Flies in the Ointment, 1
0750 Public Goods and Club Goods 949
Oakland, W.H. (1972), Congestion, Public Goods and Welfare, 1 Journal of Public Economics,
339-357.
Oates, W. (1972), Fiscal Federalism, London, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.
Olson, Mancur (1965), The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups,
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press, 186 p.
Pauly, Martin (1967), Clubs, Commonality and the Core, 34 Economica, 314-324.
Pauly, Martin (1970a), Cores and Clubs, 9 Public Choice, 53-65.
Pauly, Martin (1970b), Optimality, Public Goods and Local Government, 78 Journal of Political
Economy, 572-586.
Pearce, David W. (1977), Environmental Economics, London, Longman.
Pigou, A.C. (1920), The Economics of Welfare, London, Macmillan.
Porter, R. (1977), On the Optimal Size of Underpriced Facilites, 67 American Economic Review,
753-760.
Posner, Eric A. (1995), The Regulation of Groups: The Influence of Legal and Nonlegal Santions on
Collective Action, 63 University of Chicago Law Review, 113-197.
Rothenberg, Jerome (1970), The Economics of Congestion and Pollution: An Integrated View, 60
American Economic Review. Papers and Proceedings, 114-121.
Samuelson, Paul A. (1954), The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure, 36 Review of Economic
Statistics, 387-389.
Samuelson, Paul A. (1967), Pitfalls in the Analysis of Public Goods, 10 Journal of Law and
Economics, 199-204.
Sanchez, Isabel (1991), Provisin Voluntaria de Bienes Publicos: Resultados Experimentales
(Volutantary Contributions to Public Goods: Experimental Results), 11 Revista de Economia
Publica, 2 ff.
Sandler, Todd (1977), Impunity of Defence: An Application to the Economics of Alliances, 30
Kyklos, 443-460.
Sandler, Todd (1978), Public Goods and the Theory of the Second Best, 33 Public Finance, 331-343.
Sandler, Todd and Posnett, J.W. (1991), The Private Provision of Public Goods: A Perspective on
Neutrality, 19 Public Finance Quarterly, 22-42.
Sandler, Todd and Tschirhart, John (1980), The Economic Theory of Clubs: An Evaluative Survey,
18 Journal of Economic Literature, 1481-1521.
Schelling, Thomas C. (1969), Models of Segregation, May American Economic Review, 488-494.
Scotchmer, Suzanne (1985), Profit Maximising Clubs, 27 Journal of Public Economics, 25-45.
Seldon, Anthony (1986), The Riddle of the Education Voucher, London, Institute of Economic Affairs.
Shoup, D. Carl (1971), Theoretical Efficiency in Pollution Control: Comment, 9 Western Economic
Journal, 310-313.
Starrett, David A. (1988), Foundations of Public Economics, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1977), The Theory of Local Public Goods, in Feldstein and Inman (eds), The
Economics of Public Services, London, Macmillan.
Sugden, Robert (1981), The Political Economy of Public Choice, Oxford, Martin Robertson.
Tanzi, V. (1972), A Note on Exclusion, Pure Public Goods and Pareto Optimality, 27 Public
Finance, 75-79.
0750 Public Goods and Club Goods 951
Thompson, Earl A. (1973), The Private Production of Public Goods: A Comment, 16 Journal of Law
and Economics, 407-412.
Tideman, T. Nicolaus (1980), The Evaluation of Rules for Making Collective Decisions: A Reply to
Kormendi, 2 Research in Law and Economics, 213-217.
Tiebout, Charles M. (1956), A Pure Theory of Local Government Expenditures, 64 Journal of
Political Economy, 416-424. Reprinted in Cowen, T. (ed.) (1992), Public Goods and Market
Failures, Chapter 9, London: Transaction Publishers.
Turvey, Ralph (1968), Public Enterprise, Harmondsworth, Pengiun.
Turvey, Ralph (1971), Demand and Supply, London, Allen and Unwin.
Van Zandt, David E. (1993), The Lessons of the Lighthouse: Government or Private Provision
of Goods, 22 Journal of Legal Studies, 47-72.
Vasic B. Vukasin (1986), Makroekonomska Politika kao Javno Dobro (Macroeconomic Policy as a
Public Good), 3 Ekonomist, 429-430.
Williams, Stephen F. (1978), Running Out: The Problem of Exhaustible Resources, 7 Journal of
Legal Studies, 165-199.
Wolf, Charles, Jr (1979), A Theory of Nonmarket Failure: Framework for Implementation Analysis,
22 Journal of Law and Economics, 107-139.
Wooders, M. (1980), The Tiebout Hypothesis: Near Optimality in Local Public Good Economies, 48
Econometrica, 1467-1485.
0760
NETWORK EXTERNALITIES
William H. Page
Mississippi College, School of Law
John E. Lopatka
University of South Carolina, School of Law
Copyright 1999 William H. Page and John E. Lopatka
Abstract
A network exists when a products value to the user increases as the number of
users of the product grows. Each new user of the product derives private
benefits, but also confers external benefits (network externalities) on existing
users. Network externalities may cause markets to fail. Networks may not reach
optimal size, because users fail to take account of external benefits. Markets in
which incompatible standards compete may tip in the direction of a standard
that gains an early advantage, even if that standard is objectively inferior.
Suppliers of network goods may compete to become the de facto standard or
may attempt to make their products compatible. The theory of network
externalities has been applied in numerous legal areas including antitrust
(monopolization and cooperative standard-setting); intellectual property (the
scope of protection for dominant software programs); and corporate law (the
selection of contract terms).
JEL classification: K00
Keywords: Increasing Returns, Positive Feedback, Lock-In, Standardization
1. Introduction
The subject of network externalities has become popular in the economic and
legal literature since the mid-1980s. The fundamental idea is that the act of
joining a network confers a benefit on all other participants in the network.
According to proponents, this seemingly simple phenomenon strongly
influences competitive strategies and market outcomes in network markets.
Network externalities can, for example, influence consumers decisions whether
to adopt a new technology and producers decisions whether to standardize
their products. Ultimately, the literature suggests, network externalities can
cause markets to fail: equilibrium may not exist, or multiple equilibria may
exist and the fundamental theorems of welfare economics may not apply
952
0760 Network Externalities 953
(Katz and Shapiro, 1994, p. 94). Networks may not reach optimal size, because
purchasers do not take account of social benefits of their purchases, and
markets may converge on an inferior standard that effectively excludes better
products.
The theory of network externalities is well developed, especially for such a
new field of inquiry. Its policy implications are less clear. Some economists
claim that the inefficiencies associated with network externalities are common
in some important markets, including computer hardware and software,
transportation and telecommunications. And some argue that network
externalities justify changes in the law of antitrust, corporations, economic
regulation and intellectual property. Some of the proposed policy changes
would involve greater government intervention in the market, some would
involve less. Other scholars suggest that courts and policymakers should be
cautious in relying on network externalities. They argue that the theoretical
market failures associated with network externalities would only occur under
rare conditions. They also challenge the empirical evidence that network
externalities have actually thwarted the adoption of better technologies. Any
real market failures in network markets, they argue, probably stem from
familiar economic phenomena (like natural monopoly) that are better analyzed
using conventional tools. Even if the market has failed, government
intervention is inappropriate because network externalities cannot be identified
in practice or government action is likely to be more costly than any benefits
it may produce. In the following discussion, we will address both theoretical
and policy issues, trying wherever possible to keep them distinct.
2. Direct Externalities
3. Indirect Externalities
The analysis of the effect of indirect externalities on the size of virtual networks
is somewhat different. In these markets, externalities may arise because of the
durable nature of the hardware component in the system. The purchaser of
hardware knows he will be locked in to the product for a time, because the
cost of switching to different hardware will be substantial. (On the effects of
switching costs, see Klemperer, 1987a, 1987b, 1989). Consumers then may be
uncertain about the future availability and price of software for the product. If
this uncertainty can be addressed, then the network externality problem
disappears. If, for example, all of the components of the system are
competitively supplied by firms with U-shaped average costs, the market will
reach an efficient competitive equilibrium. The market is indistinguishable
from any competitive market with complementary products (Katz and Shapiro,
0760 Network Externalities 959
1994). Note that this outcome differs from the inefficient outcome in physical
network markets under competition discussed in the previous section.
Katz and Shapiro (1994) argue that network externalities can arise if
hardware is supplied competitively at marginal cost, but differentiated software
is provided at a price above marginal cost by firms subject to scale economies.
Apparently responding to Liebowitz and Margolis, Katz and Shapiro (p. 100)
state that if all goods were priced at marginal cost, these network externalities
would be merely be pecuniary externalities, and market equilibrium in
hardware/software markets would be efficient. If, however, software is not
priced at marginal cost, a suboptimal variety of software may result or software
may be produced at an inefficiently high cost, and the resulting networks may
be smaller than optimal because the marginal social benefit of additional sales
is greater than the private benefit to the purchaser. In such circumstances, Katz
and Shapiro argue, a subsidy to hardware suppliers (or software suppliers) can
increase consumer welfare by expanding the supply and variety of software.
Liebowitz and Margolis presumably would respond that the subsidy in this case
is (theoretically) justified because of imperfect competition in software, rather
than because of any indirect network externality.
If a monopolist supplies both hardware and software, consumers may fear
that, once they are locked in to the durable good, the monopolist will exploit
them by increasing prices of the software. (Farrell and Shapiro, 1988; Katz and
Shapiro, 1994; Shapiro and Teece, 1994). Sponsorship arrangements by the
monopolist may provide a solution. Thus, network externalities can be avoided
if the seller can somehow commit to software prices in advance of purchase. If
such commitment is possible, consumers would have no reason to fear lock-in
specifically. They would, of course, be subject to monopoly pricing (either
single-price or discriminatory), but any inefficiency would then be attributable
to the monopoly, not to network externalities. (Katz and Shapiro, 1985, 1994).
The monopolist may attempt in various ways to approximate a commitment
to future supply of compatible goods at prices consumers expect to pay. It may,
for example, attempt to guarantee a competitive supply of compatible software,
even inviting competitive firms to enter the market (Economides, 1996; Farrell
and Gallini, 1988; Katz and Shapiro, 1994). It may also adopt a policy of
leasing hardware, thereby assuring that customers would not be locked in, were
it to raise software prices. Or it might engage in penetration pricing of
hardware, which would mean that, although consumers may pay high software
prices, they will be compensated by lower hardware prices. Finally, it may rely
on its reputation as a bond securing purchasers against exploitation (Katz and
Shapiro, 1994). If it were to exploit purchasers, it would damage its ability to
sell later generations of its hardware.
960 Network Externalities 0760
value to the user depends upon its inherent benefit (the value of the good to the
purchaser even if no one else adopted it) plus its network benefit. The network
benefits increase with the size of the network. Initial adopters will primarily
take account of the goods (apparent) inherent benefit to them. If that inherent
benefit is greater for good A than for good B, the initial adopters will choose
A. As the size of network increases, it becomes still more advantageous to
choose A over B, and all subsequent adopters will do so. But suppose that,
although B offers lower inherent benefits, its network benefits increase at a
higher rate than those of good A, and at some network size actually exceed
those of A. In theory, B would offer greater social benefits if it were adopted by
the market as a whole; but the market nevertheless chooses A (Farrell and
Saloner, 1986b; Klausner, 1995). Katz and Shapiro (1994, p. 106) state that
standardizing on a single system can be very costly if the system turns out to
be inferior to another system. This type of standardization may also affect
innovation incentives in the market.
Once the market tips toward a single standard, it may remain on that
standard and its successors for a long time. Markets may exhibit excess
inertia and remain locked into a standard, even though an objectively better
standard is available (Katz and Shapiro, 1985; Farrell and Saloner, 1986a).
Present users face substantial switching costs; even though all users would be
better off with the new standard, those benefits do not accrue to the present
users who must pay for switching. New purchasers also may opt for the
established standard because of the immediate benefit that the established
network offers; they do not take account of the benefit that purchasing the new
technology would confer on later purchasers. Even if they anticipate the new
technology would be widely adopted, the benefits of that adoption to the
purchaser may be so far in the future that they are substantially discounted
(Farrell and Saloner, 1986b, p. 947, n. 14).
Theoretical models, however, demonstrate no inevitable tendency of
markets to lock-in on inferior products. Changes in the assumptions underlying
the models (for example, concerning communication and information in the
market) may eliminate the outcome of excess inertia (Farrell and Saloner, 1985,
1986a; Liebowitz and Margolis, 1990). Moreover, markets may actually exhibit
insufficient friction (Katz and Shapiro, 1986b, 1994) or excess momentu
(Farrell and Saloner, 1986b), tipping suddenly and inefficiently to new
technologies. Insufficient friction may be inefficient because consumers do not
take account of the network benefits their purchase of the established product
would confer on existing users. Given this external benefit, it may be socially
preferable to stay with the established technology. Nevertheless, consumers,
fearing that they will be stranded with an obsolete, unsupported technology (the
penguin effect, Farrell and Saloner 1987), may jump to the new technology.
Katz and Shapiro (1986b, 1992) suggest that sponsorship of proprietary
962 Network Externalities 0760
Liebowitz and Margolis (1995a) dispute the suggestion that increasing returns
to scale in high-technology markets lead to market failure. They point out that
the frequently-observed relationship between increasing participation in a
market with indirect network effects and falling prices is ambiguous. Such a
relationship may result from scale economies, but it may also reflect
technological progress. In the latter case, prices drop because advances in
technology reduce industry costs, not because of a network effect.
Liebowitz and Margolis (1994) also criticize the suggestion that markets fail
because the wrong network is chosen, so that total net benefits are lower that
they would have been under the losing technology. This kind of asserted failure
is a function of models that assume inexhaustible scale economies, for only then
does a single network survive. Liebowitz and Margolis argue that the marginal
gains of network size are often exhausted at sizes above a critical mass that is
small relative to the total market. If the benefits of size are exhausted, multiple
networks can exist. In that event, not only are monopoly problems lessened, but
the theoretical question shifts to whether the best set of networks emerge. And
the inframarginal externality that may affect the discrete choice of a network
is not different from other coordination problems that exist in many other
market choices (Liebowitz and Margolis, 1994, p. 141).
Liebowitz and Margolis are especially critical of claims that network
externalities lead consumers to make discrete choices among networks, choices
that do not maximize social welfare. Such externalities cannot be addressed by
taxes and subsidies, because those policies can only affect the scale of a
network. Rather, the assumed market failures occur because network
externalities supposedly prevent value-increasing transitions from one
technology to a superior one. At the extreme, the literature seems to suggest
that economic actors may easily become forever stuck in technologies that are
widely recognized as inferior to available alternatives. Liebowitz and Margolis
(1994, p. 145) colorfully call this the Chicken Little view of market
transitions. They contend that economics has generally not done well in
explaining transition, which affects all components of the economy, not just
networks. Nevertheless, value-increasing transitions do occur, even if the
0760 Network Externalities 963
process is not well understood. Evans and Schmalensee (1996) note that, for
example, the computer software market exemplifies Schumpeters (1942) view
of modern competition - one in which firms and industries are constantly
created and destroyed through the process of innovation.
Whatever the theoretical possibility of market failure brought about by
network externalities, critics complain that empirical support has not been
adduced. Proponents of network externalities, for example, have often pointed
to the conventional QWERTY keyboard as an illustration of lock-in. The
keyboard arrangement was chosen, it is said, to slow down the typist to avoid
mechanical jamming; other arrangements permit faster typing. Even though
technological improvements have eliminated the mechanical problems, users
are locked-in to the inferior QWERTY arrangement - consumers wish to avoid
the costs of learning a different arrangement, and producers will not supply
alternative products because not enough consumers would purchase them.
Liebowitz and Margolis (1990) argue forcefully, however, that the story is
factually incorrect, for the QWERTY keyboard is not demonstrably inferior to
the leading alternative. Similarly, Liebowitz and Margolis (1994) find evidence
that the Beta videotaping format is no better than VHS. In all, Liebowitz and
Margolis believe that real indirect network externalities are of limited
theoretical importance and have not been established empirically. For a similar
discussion of the complexity of the issue of objective superiority of one
technology to another, see Van Vleck (1995).
becoming the de facto standard in the market; or it may arise through collective
standard-setting mechanisms. In addition, converters or adapters may make
products compatible to varying degrees (Farrell and Saloner, 1992). In some
instances, it may be to a firms advantage to try to prevent compatibility with
existing systems and compete with them to become the de facto standard for at
least a part of the market. In other instances, firms may choose to make their
products compatible with other products by licensing or by participation in
coalitions or standard-setting organizations (Katz and Shapiro, 1994).
Compatibility, by expanding the size of networks, offers both private
benefits and private costs to producers and consumers of network goods.
Participants in compatible physical networks receive the direct external benefits
of communicating with a larger number of consumers, and save the costs of
owning two sets of hardware. Participants in compatible virtual networks
receive the indirect benefits of a larger network, including a greater variety of
components that may be mixed and matched to achieve an optimal system
(Matutes and Regibeau, 1988), and a reduced risk of being stranded with
obsolete technology. Producers receive the benefits associated with larger scale.
Compatibility may impose costs, however, depending upon how it is achieved.
If it is achieved by standardization, then there may be a reduction in the variety
of systems and products available to first-time consumers (Gilbert, 1992). If it
is achieved by adapters, the adapters themselves impose costs (Katz and
Shapiro, 1994).
Whether firms have an incentive to create compatibility depends upon how
the resulting changes in the terms of competition affect them. Compatibility
reduces the risk that the market will tip to a rivals sponsored standard, and so
may reduce the intensity of competition, at least in early stages when
incompatible systems would be competing to become the markets de facto
standard (Katz and Shapiro, 1986b). This tendency suggests that some firms
(or coalitions of firms) may have an incentive to agree to adopt a compatible
standard (Besen and Farrell 1994; Katz and Shapiro, 1994). But if systems are
compatible, then the market may accommodate more firms, and so
compatibility may actually increase competition over the long term (Katz and
Shapiro, 1994). Firms that standardize reduce their chances of becoming the
dominant firm.
When networks are incompatible, then competition is between physical
networks or between systems of goods that comprise virtual networks. When
virtual networks are compatible, however, competition is among the
components of the system (Matutes and Regibeau, 1988; Economides 1988,
1996; Katz and Shapiro, 1994). In such situations, the firms preference for
compatibility depends upon the tradeoff between the increased demand that
compatibility creates and the increased competition that it entails. Firms that
believe they offer a better overall system (like Apple Computer in its earlier
years, perhaps) may opt for incompatibility; firms that believe they offer a
better individual component may opt for compatibility. In general, the winner
0760 Network Externalities 965
take most nature of competition between incompatible systems may lead firms
with very promising (or highly regarded) technology to oppose compatibility,
even when compatibility is socially preferable (Katz and Shapiro, 1994). The
social optimum is not achieved because firms individually do not take account
of the effects of compatibility on others.
E. Policy Implications
The theory of network externalities suggests that a single product may emerge
as the de facto standard in the market. Should the presence of network
externalites, and the consequent danger of lock-in, affect the intellectual
property protection given to a proprietary de facto standard? Menell (1987,
1989), relying in part on an analogy to the QWERTY story, has argued that
network externalities justify limiting copyright protection to computer software
that has become the industry standard. In Lotus Development Corp. v. Borland
International (1995), the court adopted this reasoning, holding that Lotus
1-2-3s user interface was a method of operation, like the buttons on a VCR,
and therefore not protectable expression under copyright law. One of the
reasons the court offered was the need for compatibility. The court found it
absurd to suggest that if a user uses several different programs, he or she
must learn how to perform the same operation in a different way for each
program used. A concurring judge added that if Lotus is granted a monopoly
on this pattern, users who have learned the command structure of Lotus 1-2-3
or devised their own macros are locked into Lotus ... Consequently, a
competitor (Borland) should be allowed to copy Lotuss menu command
structure.
This decision adopts a network externality theory raised by Borland and
amici curiae in their briefs on appeal. It has been questioned by Dam (1995),
who points out that compatibility in this case is not the interoperability that
allows use of competitive software or the inteconnection that allows
communication across a physical network. Rather, compatibility in this case
means only that a user may costlessly adopt a competing product. The
argument is that the menu structure has become the de facto industry standard,
and so free copying should be allowed to assure adequate competition. But it is
questionable whether network externalities are at issue here. The users of Lotus
970 Network Externalities 0760
Some scholars have argued that social norms have network aspects.
Conventional rules like those governing right of way for drivers at an
intersection have greater value the more people adopt them. This extension of
the concept of network externalities has been most fully developed by Klausner
and Kahan (Klausner, 1995; Kahan and Klausner, 1996), who have argued that
the adoption of corporate contract terms can create indirect network
externalities. Common use and judicial interpretation of contract terms benefit
the network of firms adopting those terms by, for example, clarifying the
meaning of the set of legal rules governing the firm. Larger network size
generates positive feedback because it increases the stock of judicial precedent
and the common understanding of the relevant rules. Network externalities thus
modify the conception of the firm as a nexus of contracts. They imply that
contract terms that maximize the value of the individual firm may not
maximize social wealth. State corporation laws, by providing default rules for
contractual provisions, are analogous to industry standards in physical networks
like telecommunications, because they can facilitate the creation of networks.
Their goal should be to promote the creation of an optimal mix of uniformity
and diversity by providing open-ended default rules menus of alternative
provisions. Network externalities may also account for the dominance of
Delaware corporation law. Some scholars have suggested that states compete
in a race to the top for corporate charters by offering statutes that maximize
firm value. But Delawares dominance (despite the prevalence of similar laws)
0760 Network Externalities 971
may reflect the positive feedback effect of its large network of incorporated
firms. This result implies that Delaware law has become popular not because
it offers optimal terms, but because it has become locked in.
Allen, Beth (1982), Some Stochastic Processes of Interdependent Demand and Technological Diffusion
Exhibiting Externalities Among Adopters, 23 International Economic Review, 595-608.
Anton, James and Yao, Dennis A. (1995), Standard-Setting Consortia, Antitrust, and High-
Technology Industries, 64 Antitrust Law Journal, 247-265.
Antonelli, Christiano (1992), The Economic Theory of Information Networks, in Antonelli,
Christiano (ed.), The Economics of Information Networks, Amsterdam, North Holland.
Antonelli, Christiano (1993), Externalities and Complementarities in Telecommunications Dynamics,
11 International Journal of Industrial Organization, 299-450.
Antonelli, Christiano (1994), Localized Technological Change and the Evolution of Standards as
Economic Institutions, 6 Information Economics and Policy, 195-216.
Armstrong, Mark, et al. (1995), The Access Pricing Problem, 44 Journal of Industrial Economics,
132-150.
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1975), Vertical Integration and Communication, 6 Bell Journal of Economics,
173-183.
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1995), Declaration Appended to Memorandum of the United States of America in
Support of Motion to Enter Final Judgment and in Opposition to the Positions of IDE Corporation
and Amici (Jan. 17, 1995), United States v. Microsoft Corp., 159 F.R.D. 318 (D.D.C. 1995).
Arthur, W. Brian (1988), Self-Reinforcing Mechanisms in Economics, in Anderson, Philip W. et al.
(eds), The Economy as an Evolving Complex System, Reading, MA, Addison-Wesley, 9-31.
Arthur, W. Brian (1989), Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-In by Historical
Events, 99 Economic Journal, 116 ff.
Arthur, W. Brian (1990), Positive Feedbacks in the Economy, 262 Scientific American, 92 ff.
Arthur, W. Brian (1994), Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy, Ann Arbor, MI,
The University of Michigan Press.
Arthur, W. Brian (1996), Increasing Returns and the New World of Business, July Harvard Business
Review, 100 ff.
Artle, R. and Averous, C. (1973), The Telephone System as a Public Good: Static and Dynamic
Aspects, 4 Bell Journal of Economics, 89-100.
Axelsson, B. and Easton, G. (eds) (1992), Industrial Networks, A New View of Reality, London,
Routledge.
Baird, Douglas G. et al. (1994), Game Theory and the Law, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press.
972 Network Externalities 0760
Baker, Donald I. (1993), Compulsory Access to Network Joint Ventures under the Sherman Act: Rules
or Roulette?, 1993 Utah Law Review, 999-1133.
Balcer, Yves and Lippman, Steven A. (1984), Technological Expectations and Adoption of Improved
Technology, 34 Journal of Economic Theory, 292-318.
Banerjee, Abhijit V. (1992), A Simple Model of Herd Behavior, 107 Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 797 ff.
Baumol, William J. and Sidak, J. Gregory (1994), The Pricing of Inputs Sold to Competitors, 11 Yale
Journal on Regulation, 171-202.
Bensaid, Bernard and Lesne, Jean-Philippe (1996), Dynamic Monopoly Pricing with Network
Externalities, 14 International Journal of Industrial Organization, 837 ff.
Bental, Benjamin and Spiegel, Menahem (1995), Network Competition, Product Quality and Market
Coverage in the Presence of Network Externalities, 43 Journal of Industrial Economics,
197-208.
Berg, Sanford V. (1987), Public Policy and Corporate Strategies in the AM Stereo Market, in Gabel,
H. Landis (ed.), Product Standardization as a Tool of Competitive Strategy, North Holland.
Berg, Sanford V. (1988), Duopoly Compatibility Standards with Partial Cooperation and Standards
Leadership, 3 Information Economics and Policy, 35-53.
Besen, Stanley M. (1992), AM versus FM: The Battle of the Bands, 1 Industrial and Corporate
Change, 375 ff.
Besen, Stanley M. and Farrell, Joseph (1994), Choosing How to Compete: Strategies and Tactics in
Standardization, 8 Journal of Economic Perspectives, 117 ff.
Besen, Stanley M. and Johnson, Leland Law (1986), Compatibility Standards, Competition, and
Innovation in the Broadcasting Industry, Rand Publication No. R-3453-NSF.
Bijl, Paul W.J. and Goyal, Sanjeev (1995), Technological Change in Markets with Network
Externalities, 13 International Journal of Industrial Organization, 307-325.
Bolter, Walter et al. (1990), Telecommunications Policy for the 1990s and Beyond, New York, M.E.
Sharpe, Inc.
Borenstein, Severin et al. (1995), Antitrust Policy in Aftermarkets, 63 Antitrust Law Journal,
455-482.
Braunstein, Yale and White, Lawrence (1985), Setting Technical Compatibility Standards: An
Economic Analysis, 30 Antitrust Bulletin, 337 ff.
Brinig, Margaret F. (1995), A Maternalistic Approach to Surrogacy, 81 Virginia Law Review,
2377-2399.
Brinig, Margaret F. and Buckley, Francis H. (1996), The Market for Deadbeats, 25 Journal of Legal
Studies, 201-232.
Brown, Jack E. (1993), Technology Joint Ventures to Set Standards or Define Interfaces, 61 Antitrust
Law Journal, 921-936.
Cabral, Luis (1990), On the Adoption of Innovations with Network Externalities, 19 Mathematical
Social Sciences, 229-308.
Carlton, Dennis W. and Frankel, Alan S. (1995), The Antitrust Economics of Credit Card Networks,
63 Antitrust Law Journal, 643-668.
Carlton, Dennis W. and Klamer, J. Mark (1983), The Need for Coordination among Firms, with
Special Reference to Network Industries, 50 University of Chicago Law Review, 446-465.
0760 Network Externalities 973
Carlton, Dennis W. and Salop, Steven (1996), You Keep on Knocking but You Cant Come In:
Evaluating Restrictions on Access to Input Joint Ventures, 9 Harvard Journal of Law and
Technology, 319-352.
Choi, Jay Pil (1994), Irreversible Choice of Uncertain Technologies with Network Externalities, 25
Rand Journal of Economics, 382 ff.
Choi, Jay Pil (1996), Do Converters Facilitate the Transition to a New Incompatible Technology?: A
Dynamic Analysis of Converters, 14 International Journal of Industrial Organization, 825 ff.
Chou, Chien-fu and Shy, Oz (1990), Network Effects Without Network Externalities, 8 International
Journal of Industrial Organization, 259-270.
Church, Jeffrey and Gandal, Neil (1990), Complementary Network Externalities and Technology
Adoption, 11 International Journal of Industrial Organization, 239-260.
Church, Jeffrey and Gandal, Neil (1992a), Integration, Complementary Products, and Variety, 1
Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 651-675.
Church, Jeffrey and Gandal, Neil (1992b), Network Effects, Software Provision, and Standardization,
40 Journal of Industrial Economics, 85-104.
Church, Jeffrey and King, I.P. (1993), Bilingualism and Network Externalities, 26 Canadian Journal
of Economics, 337-345.
Cohen, William E. (1996), Competition and Foreclosure in the Context of Installed Base and
Compatibility Effects, 64 Antitrust Law Journal, 535-569.
Compton, Charles T.C. (1993), Cooperation, Collaboration, and Coalition: a Perspective on the Types
and Purposes of Technology Joint Ventures, 61 Antitrust Law Journal, 861-897.
Conner, Kathleen R. (1995), Obtaining Strategic Advantage from being Imitated: When can
Encouraging Clones Pay?, 41 Management Science, 209-225.
Conrad, Cecilia and Duchatelet, M. (1987), New Technology Adoption, 5 International Journal of
Industrial Organization, 315-321.
Cowan, Robin (1990), Nuclear Power Reactors: A Study in Technological Lock In, 50 Journal of
Economic History, 541-567.
Cowan, Robin (1991), Tortoises and Hares: Choice among Technologies of Unknown Merit, 101
Economic Journal, 801-814.
Cowan, Robin (1992), High Technology and the Economics of Standardization, in Dierkes, Meinolf
and Hoffmann, Ute (eds), New Technology at the Outset, Frankfurt/M and New York, Campus,
279-300.
Crandall, Robert W. and Sidak, J. Gregory (1995), Competition and Regulatory Policies for
Interactive Broadband Networks, 68 Southern California Law Review, 1203-1237.
Dam, Kenneth W. (1995), Some Economic Considerations in the Intellectual Property Protection of
Software, 24 Journal of Legal Studies, 321-377.
David, Paul A (1985), Clio and the Economics of Qwerty, 75 American Economic Review, 332-337.
David, Paul A. (1986), Understanding the Economics of Qwerty, in Parker, W.N. (ed.), Economic
History and the Modern Economist, Oxford, Basil Blackwell.
David, Paul A. and Bunn, Julie Ann (1988), The Economics of Gateway Technologies and Network
Evolution, 3 Information Economics and Policy, 165-202.
David, Paul A. and Greenstein, Shane (1990), The Economics of Compatibility Standards: An
Introduction to the Recent Research, 1 Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 3-41.
974 Network Externalities 0760
David, Paul A. and Steinmueller, W. Edward (1994), Economics of Compatibility Standards and
Competition in Telecommunication Networks, 6 Information Economics and Policy, 217-241.
Desruelle, Dominique et al. (1996), Complementarity, Coordination and Compatibility: An Analysis
of the Economics of Systems, 14 International Journal of Industrial Organization, 747 ff.
Domowitz, Ian (1995), Electronic Derivatives Exchanges: Implicit Mergers, Network Externalities,
and Standardization, 35 Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 163-175.
Dowd, Kevin and Greenaway, David (1993), Currency Competition, Network Externalities and
Switching Costs: Towards an Alternative View of Optimum Currency Areas, 103 Economic
Journal, 1180-1189.
Dratler, Jay, Jr (1996), Microsoft as an Antitrust Target: IBM in Software?, 25 Southwestern
University Law Review, 671-744.
Dybvig, Philip and Spatt, Chester (1983), Adoption Externalities as Public Goods, 20 Journal of
Public Economics, 231-247.
Economides, Nicholas (1988), Desirability of Compatibility in the Absence of Network Externalities,
78 American Economic Review, 108-121.
Economides, Nicholas (1991), Compatibility and the Creation of Shared Networks, in Guerin-Calvert,
Margaret and Wildman, Steven (eds), Electronic Services Networks: A Business and Public
Policy Challenge, New York, Prager Pub. Inc.
Economides, Nicholas (1993a), Network Economics with Application to Finance, 2 Financial
Markets, Institutions, and Instruments, 89-97.
Economides, Nicholas (1993b), A Monopolists Incentive to Invite Competitors to Enter in
Telecommunications Services, in Pogorel, Gerard (ed.), Global Telecommunications Services
and Technological Changes, Amsterdam, Elsevier.
Economides, Nicholas (1996), The Economics of Networks, 14 International Journal of Industrial
Organization, 673 ff.
Economides, Nicholas (1997), Network Externalities, Complementarities, and Invitations to Enter,
European Journal of Political Economy, forthcoming.
Economides, Nicholas and Himmelberg, Charles (1995), Critical Mass and Network Evolution in
Telecommunications, in Brock, Gerard (ed.), Toward a Competitive Telecommunications
Industry: Selected Papers from the 1994 Telecommunications Policy Research Conference,
Mahwah, NJ, Lawrence Erlbaum Association.
Economides, Nicholas and Salop, Steven (1992), Competition and Integration among Complements,
and Network Market Structure, 40 Journal of Industrial Economics, 105-123.
Economides, Nicholas and White, Lawrence (1994), Networks and Compatibility: Implications for
Antitrust, 38 European Economic Review, 651-662.
Economides, Nicholas and White, Lawrence (1995), Access and Interconnection Access Pricing: How
Efficient is the Efficient Component Pricing Rule?, 40 Antitrust Bulletin, 557-579.
Economides, Nicholas and White, Lawrence (1996), One-Way Networks, Two-Way Networks,
Compatibility, and Antitrust, in Gabel, David and Weiman, David (eds), Opening Networks to
Competition: The Regulation and Pricing of Access, Amsterdam, Kluwer Academic Press.
0760 Network Externalities 975
Encaoua, David et al. (1996), Compatibility and Competition in Airlines: Demand Side Network
Effects, 14 International Journal of Industrial Organization, 701 ff.
Evans, David S. and Schmalensee, Richard (1996), A Guide to the Antitrust Economics of Networks,
Spring Antitrust, 36-39.
Farrell, Joseph (1989), Standardization and Intellectual Property, 30 Jurimetrics Journal, 35-50.
Farrell, Joseph (1996), Creating Local Competition, 49 Federal Communications Law Journal,
201-215.
Farrell, Joseph and Gallini, Nancy (1988), Second-Sourcing as a Commitment: Monopoly Incentives
to Attract Competition, 103 Quarterly Journal of Economics, 673-694.
Farrell, Joseph and Saloner, Garth (1985), Standardization, Compatibility, and Innovation, 16 Rand
Journal of Economics, 70-83.
Farrell, Joseph and Saloner, Garth (1986a), Economic Issues in Standardization, in Miller J. (ed.),
Telecommunications and Equity, Amsterdam, North Holland.
Farrell, Joseph and Saloner, Garth (1986b), Installed Base and Compatibility: Innovation, Product
Preannouncements, and Predation, 76 American Economic Review, 940-955.
Farrell, Joseph and Saloner, Garth (1986c), Standardization and Variety, 20 Economic Letters,
71-74.
Farrell, Joseph and Saloner, Garth (1987), Competition, Compatibility and Standards: The Economics
of Horses, Penguins and Lemmings, in Gabel, H. Landis (ed.), Competitive Strategies for
Product Standards, London, McGraw Hill.
Farrell, Joseph and Saloner, Garth (1988), Coordination Through Committees and Markets, 19 Rand
Journal of Economics, 235-252.
Farrell, Joseph and Saloner, Garth (1992), Converters, Compatibility, and the Control of Interfaces,
40 Journal of Industrial Economics, 9-36.
Farrell, Joseph and Shapiro, Carl (1988), Dynamic Competition with Switching Costs, 19 Rand
Journal of Economics, 123 ff.
Farrell, Joseph and Shapiro, Carl (1989), Optimal Contracts with Lock-In, 79 American Economic
Review, 51 ff.
Farrell, Joseph and Shapiro, Carl (1992), Standard Setting in High-Definition Television, 1
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics 1.
Fischel, William A. (1980), Externalities and Zoning, 35 Public Choice, 37-43.
Fischel, William A. (1994), Zoning, Nonconvexities, and T. Jack Fosters City, 35 Journal of Urban
Economics, 175-181.
Gabel, H. Landis (1991), Competitive Strategies for Product Standards, London, McGraw Hill.
Gallini, Nancy and Karp, Larry (1989), Sales and Consumer Lock-in, 56 Economica, 279-294.
Gandal, Neil (1994), Hedonic Price Indexes for Spreadsheets and an Empirical Test for Network
Externalities, 24 Rand Journal of Economics, 19-39.
Gandal, Neil (1995), A Selective Survey of the Literature on Indirect Network Externalities, 17
Research in Law and Economics, 23-31.
Gandal, Neil (1996), Compatibility Standards and Complementary Network Externalities in the PC
Software Market, Review of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming.
Garud, Raghu and Kumaraswamy, Arun (1993), Changing Competitive Dynamics in Network
Industries: An Exploration of Sun Microsystems Open Systems Strategy, 14 Strategic
Management Journal, 351-369.
976 Network Externalities 0760
Gifford, Daniel J. (1996), Microsoft Corporation, the Justice Department, and Antitrust Theory, 25
Southwestern University Law Review, 621-670.
Gilbert, Richard J. (1989), Mobility Barriers and the Value of Incumbency, in Schmalensee, Richard
and Willig, Robert (eds), 1 Handbook of Industrial Organization, 475 ff.
Gilbert, Richard J. (1992), Symposium on Compatibility: Incentives and Market Structure, 40
Journal of Industrial Economics, 1 ff.
Gilbert, Richard J. and Sunshine, Steven C. (1995), Incorporating Dynamic Efficiency Concerns in
Merger Analysis: The Use of Innovation Markets, 63 Antitrust Law Journal, 569-601.
Gillette, Clayton P. (1996), Rules, Standards, and Precautions in Payment Systems, 82 Virginia Law
Review, 181-251.
Graham, Lawrence D. and Zerbe, Richard O., Jr (1996), Economically Efficient Treatment of
Computer Software: Reverse Engineering, Protection, and Disclosure, 22 Rutgers Computer and
Technology Law Journal, 61-142.
Gross, Irwin R. (1994), A New Framework for Software Protection: Distinguishing Between
Interactive and Non-Interactive Aspects of Computer Programs, 20 Rutgers Computer and
Technology Law Journal, 107-187.
Habermeier, Karl F. (1989), Competing Technologies, the Learning Curve, and Rational
Expectations, 33 European Economic Review, 1293-1311.
Hanna, Ramsey (1994), Note: Misusing Antitrust: The Search For Functional Copyright Misuse
Standards, 46 Stanford Law Review, 401-448.
Harbord, David and Hoehn, Tom (1994), Barriers to Entry and Exit in European Competition Policy,
14 International Review of Law and Economics, 411-435.
Hazlett, Thomas (1995), Predation in Local Cable TV Markets, 40 Antitrust Bulletin, 609-644.
Henriet, D. and Moulin, Herve (1996), Traffic Based Cost Allocation in a Network, 27 Rand
Journal of Economics, 332-345.
Ignatin, Gary R. (1992), Note: Let the Hackers Hack: Allowing the Reverse Engineering of
Copyrighted Computer Programs to Achieve Compatibility, 140 University of Pennsylvania Law
Review, 1999-2050.
Johnston, Jason S. (1993), The Influence of The Nature of the Firm on the Theory of Corporate Law,
18 Journal of Corporation Law, 213-244.
Kahai, Simran K. et al. (1995), Deregulation and Predation in Long-Distance Telecommunications:
An Empirical Test, 40 Antitrust Bulletin, 645-666.
Kahan, Marcel and Klausner, Michael (1996), Path Dependence in Corporate Contracting: Increasing
Returns, Herd Behavior and Cognitive Biases, 74 Washington University Law Quarterly.
Kattan, Joseph (1993), Market Power in the Presence of an Installed Base, 62 Antitrust Law Journal,
1-21.
Katz, Michael L. and Shapiro, Carl (1985), Network Externalities, Competition, and Compatibility,
75 American Economic Review, 424-440.
Katz, Michael L. and Shapiro, Carl (1986a), Technology Adoption in the Presence of Network
Externalities, 94 Journal of Political Economy, 822-841.
Katz, Michael L. and Shapiro, Carl (1986b), Product Compatibility Choice in a Market with
Technological Progress, 38 Oxford Economic Papers, 146-165.
Katz, Michael L. and Shapiro, Carl (1992), Product Introduction with Network Externalities, 40
Journal of Industrial Economics, 55 ff.
0760 Network Externalities 977
Katz, Michael L. and Shapiro, Carl (1994), Systems Competition and Network Effects, 8 Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 93-115.
Klausner, Michael (1995), Corporations, Corporate Law, and Networks of Contracts, 81 Virginia
Law Review, 757-852.
Klemperer, Paul (1987a), The Competitiveness of Markets with Switching Costs, 18 Rand Journal
of Economics, 138-150.
Klemperer, Paul (1987b), Markets with Consumer Switching Costs, 102 Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 375 ff.
Klemperer, Paul (1989), Price Wars Caused by Switching Costs, 65 Review of Economic Studies,
405-420.
Krauss, Michael I. (1994), Regulation vs. Markets in the Development of Standards, 3 Southern
California Interdisciplinary Law Journal, 781-808.
Kristiansen, Eirik Guaard (1996), R&D in Markets with Network Externalities, 14 International
Journal of Industrial Organization, 769 ff
Lamberton, D.M. and Neumann, K.-H. (1994), The Economics of Standards, 6 Information
Economics and Policy, 193-194.
Langlois, Richard N. (1992), External Economies and Economic Progress: The Case of the
Microcomputer Industry, 66 Business History Review, 1-50.
Lehr, William (1996), Compatibility Standards and Industry Competition: Two Case Studies, 4
Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 97-112.
Lemley, Mark A. (1996), Antitrust and the Internet Standardization Problem, 28 Connecticut Law
Review, 1041 ff.
Lemley, Mark A. and OBrien, David (1997), Encouraging Software Reuse, 49 Stanford Law
Review, 255 ff.
Lewis, Tracy R. and Yao, Dennis A. (1995), Some Reflections on the Antitrust Treatment of
Intellectual Property, 63 Antitrust Law Journal, 603-619.
Liebowitz, S.J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1990), The Fable of the Keys, 22 Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-26.
Liebowitz, S.J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1994), Network Externality: An Uncommon Tragedy, 8
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 133-150.
Liebowitz, S.J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1995a), Are Network Externalities a New Source of Market
Failure?, 17 Research in Law and Economics, 1-22.
Liebowitz, S.J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1995b), Path Dependence, Lock-in, and History, 11
Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 205-226.
Liebowitz, S.J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1995c), Policy and Path Dependence: From Qwerty to
Windows 95, 33 Regulation.
Liebowitz, S.J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1995d), Reply to Comments by Regibeau and Gandal, 17
Research in Law and Economics, 41-46.
Liebowitz, S.J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1996), Should Technology Choice be a Concern of Antitrust
Policy, 9 Harvard Journal of Law and Technology, 283-318.
Lopatka, John and Page, William H. (1995a), Microsoft, Monopolization, and Network Externalities:
Some Uses and Abuses of Economic Theory in Antitrust Decisionmaking, 40 Antitrust Bulletin,
317-370.
Lopatka, John and Page, William H. (1995b), Posners Program for the Antitrust Division: A
Twenty-Five Year Perspective, 48 SMU Law Review, 1713-1747.
Lunney, Glynn S., Jr (1996), Lotus v. Borland: Copyright and Computer Programs, 70 Tulane Law
Review, 2397-2436.
978 Network Externalities 0760
Matutes, Carmen and Padilla, A. Jorge (1992), Shared ATM Networks and Banking Competition,
38 European Economic Review, 1113-1138.
Matutes, Carmen and Regibeau, Pierre (1988), Mix and Match: Product Compatibility without
Network Externalities, 19 Rand Journal of Economics, 221-234.
Matutes, Carmen and Regibeau, Pierre (1989), Standardization Across Markets and Entry, 40
Journal of Industrial Economics, 467-487.
Matutes, Carmen and Regibeau, Pierre (1992), Compatibility and Bundling of Complementary Goods
in a Duopoly, 40 Journal of Industrial Economics, 37-54.
McAndrews, James and Rob, Rafael (1996), Shared Ownership and Pricing in a Network Switch, 14
International Journal of Industrial Organization, 727 ff.
Menell, Peter S. (1987), Tailoring Legal Protection for Computer Software, 39 Stanford Law Review,
1329-1372.
Menell, Peter S. (1989), An Analysis of the Scope of Copyright Protection for Application Programs,
41 Stanford Law Review, 1045-1071.
Menell, Peter S. (1994), The Challenges of Reforming Intellectual Property Protection for Computer
Software, 94 Columbia Law Review, 2644-2254.
Morris, Charles R. and Ferguson, Charles H. (1993), How Architecture Wins Technology Wars,
March Harvard Business Review, 89-91.
Owen, David R. (1996), Note: Interfaces and Interoperability in Lotus v. Borland: A Market-Oriented
Approach to the Fair Use Doctrine, 64 Fordham Law Review, 2381-2423.
Perritt, Henry H., Jr (1995), Access to the National Information Infrastructure, 30 Wake Forest Law
Review, 51-103.
Perrot, Anne (1993), Compatibility, Networks, and Competition: A Review of Recent Advances,
Transportation Science.
Pirrong, Stephen Craig (1995), The Self-Regulation of Commodity Exchanges: The Case of Market
Manipulation, 38 Journal of Law and Economics, 141-206.
Postrel, S.R. (1990), Competing Networks and Proprietary Standards: the Case of Quadraphonic
Sound, 19 Journal of Industrial Economics, 221-234.
Rasmussen, Robert K. and Skeel, David A., Jr (1995), The Economic Analysis of Corporate
Bankruptcy Law, 3 American Bankruptcy Institute Law Review, 85 ff.
Regibeau, Pierre (1995), Defending the Concept of Network Externalities, 17 Research in Law and
Economics, 33-39.
Regibeau, Pierre and Rockett, Katherine (1996), The Timing of Product Introduction and the
Credibility of Compatibility Decisions,14 International Journal of Industrial Organization, 801
ff.
Ribstein, Larry E. (1995a), Linking Statutory Forms, 58 Journal of Law and Contemporary
Problems, 58 ff.
Ribstein, Larry E. (1995b), Statutory Forms for Closely Held Firms: Theories and Evidence from
LLCs, 73 Washington University Law Quarterly, 369 ff.
Ribstein, Larry E. and Kobayashi, Bruce H. (1995), Uniform Laws, Model Laws and Limited Liability
Companies, 66 University of Colorado Law Review, 947-999.
Ribstein, Larry E. and Kobayashi, Bruce H. (1996), An Economic Analysis of Uniform State Laws,
25 Journal of Legal Studies, 131-99.
Robinson, Glen O. (1996), The New Communications Act: A Second Opinion, 29 Connecticut Law
Review, 289-329.
0760 Network Externalities 979
Rohlfs, Jeff (1974), A Theory of Interdependent Demand for a Communications Service, 10 Bell
Journal of Economics, 141-156.
Saloner, Garth (1990), Economic Issues in Computer Interface Standardization: the Case of UNIX,
1 Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 135-156.
Scharfstein, David S. and Stein, Jeremy C. (1990), Herd Behavior and Investment, 80 American
Economic Review, 465 ff.
Shapiro, Carl (1995), Aftermarkets and Consumer Welfare: Making Sense of Kodak, 63 Antitrust
Law Journal, 483-511.
Shapiro, Carl and Teece, David J. (1994), Systems Competition and Aftermarkets, 39 Antitrust
Bulletin, 135 ff.
Shy, Oz (1996), Technology Revolutions in the Presence of Network Externalities, 14 International
Journal of Industrial Organization, 785 ff.
Takeyama, L.N. (1994), The Welfare Implications of Unauthorized Reproduction of Intellectual
Property in the Presence of Network Externalities, 42 Journal of Industrial Economics, 155-165.
Teece, David J. (1994), Information Sharing, Innovation, and Antitrust, 62 Antitrust Law Journal,
465-481.
Teter, Timothy T. (1993), Note: Merger and the Machines: An Analysis of the Pro-Compatibility
Trend in Computer Software Copyright Cases, 45 Stanford Law Review, 1061-1098.
Thum, Marcel (1994), Network Externalities, Technological Progress, and the Competition of Market
Contracts, 12 International Journal of Industrial Organization, 269-289.
Turnbull, Shann (1995), Innovations in Corporate Governance: The Mondragon Experience, 3(3)
Corporate Governance: An International Review, 167-180.
Turnbull, Shann (1997), Stakeholder Co-orporation, 29(3) Journal of Co-operative Studies, 18-52.
Van Vleck, Va Nee L. (1995), Reassessing Technological Backwardness: Absolving the Silly Little
Bobtailed Coal Car, 55 Journal of Economic History, 383 ff.
Veall, Michael R. (1995), On Product Standardization as Competition Policy, 18 Canadian Journal
of Economics, 416-425.
Vita, Michael G., and Wellford, Charissa P. (1994), Regulating the Electromagnetic Environment:
Alternative Approaches to Policy, in Fleming, James R. and Gemery, Henry A. (eds), Science,
Technology, and the Environment, 238 ff.
Weiman, David F. and Levin, Richard C. (1994), Preying for Monopoly? The Case of Southern Bell
Telephone Company, 1894-1912, 102 Journal of Political Economy, 103-126.
Wortman, Tara J. (1995), Note: Unlocking Lock-In: Limited Liability Companies and the Key to
Underutilization of Close Corporation Statutes, 70 New York University Law Review, 1362-1408.
980 Network Externalities 0760
Other References
Jorde, Thomas M. and Teece, David J. (1993), Rule of Reason Analysis of Horizontal Arrangements:
Agreements Designed to Advance Innovation and Commercialize Technology, 61 Antitrust Law
Journal, 579-619.
Ordover, Janusz A. and Willig, Robert D. (1981), An Economic Definition of Predation: Pricing and
Product Innovation, 91 Yale Law Journal, 8 ff.
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, New York, Harpercollins.
Sheff, David (1994), Game Over: How Nintendo Conquered the World, New York, Vintage Books.
Cases
Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, Inc., 504 U.S. 45 (1992).
Lotus Development Corp. v. Borland Intl, 49 F.3d 807 (1st Cir. 1995), affd by an equally divided
Court, 116 S. Ct. 804 (1996).
Money Station, Inc. v. Board of Governors of Federal Reserve System, 81 F.3d 1128 (D.C. Cir.
1996).
National Collegiate Athletic Assn v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85 (1984).
United States v. Eastman Kodak Co., 853 F. Supp. 1454 (W.D.N.Y. 1994).
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 159 F.R.D. 318 (D.D.C. 1995), revd, 56 F.3d 1448 (D.C. Cir.
1995).
0770
PATH DEPENDENCE
Stan J. Liebowitz
Professor of Economics and Associate Dean
School of Management, University of Texas at Dallas
Stephen E. Margolis
North Carolina State University
Copyright 1999 Stan J. Liebowitz and Stephen E. Margolis
Abstract
What role does the past play in current economic conditions? Economic models
usually determine equilibrium ending points without concern for intermediate
disequilibrium conditions or the prior history of the system. That the past does
play some role is obvious, but the nature of its impact requires careful
delineation. Some path dependence theorists have argued that past decisions
might have locked-in certain inferior outcomes. In making sense of this claim
particular attention needs to be paid to the meaning of inferior. Upon
investigation, such claims have been found to be without empirical support (in
private markets) and based on fairly narrow theoretical assumptions. In
nonmarket contexts less is known.
JEL classification: K0, K2, L5.O3, L0
Keywords: Path Dependence, Network Externality, Network Effect, Lock-In
1. Introduction
Most generally, path dependence means that where we go next depends not
only on where we are now, but also upon where we have been. History matters.
Stochastic processes are path dependent if they exhibit memory: The probability
distribution for the process at time t+1 depends upon more of the history of the
system than just its state at time t.
As it has recently been applied in economics, path dependence means that
equilibrium allocations depend on history. Economic allocations that are path
dependent could not be predicted by knowledge of the efficient allocations, or
the conditions that determine the efficient allocation, alone (Arthur, 1989). An
expectation of path dependence accordingly is in conflict with economic models
981
982 Path Dependence 0770
precedent does not play an explicit role and where we might expect evolution
toward efficiency, such influence would appear magnified in the law, where
precedent has such an explicit role.
In the remainder of this entry, we examine the theoretical and empirical
claims of the economic literature on path dependence. We start with a simple
example of path dependence, offered to help fix ideas. Following that, we offer
a taxonomy of path dependence claims that draws on our article in the Journal
of Law, Economics and Organization. In our view, some of the confusion
around path dependence has resulted from a failure to distinguish among types
of path dependence claims. We offer a remedy here. Following that, we present
a discussion of the means by which market behaviors would tend to unravel
instances of path dependence that constitute inefficiencies. The possibility that
profit-seeking activities may be able to undo harmful path dependence reduces
the issue to an empirical one: Are there documented instances of harmful path
dependence? We close on that issue.
There are three possible efficiency outcomes where past conditions or decisions
exhibit a persistent influence on a dynamic process. First, such persistence
might do no harm. That is to say, an initial action does put us on a path that
cannot be left without some cost, but that path happens to be optimal (although
not necessarily uniquely optimal). For example, a capricious decision to part
ones hair on the left may lead to a lifetime of left-side parting, but the initial
urge to part on the left might capture all there is to be taken into account. On
a grander scale, our decision to use a particular system for powering the
machinery in a plant may be a controlling influence for decades, but the
long-term effects of the decision may be fully appreciated by the initial decision
maker and fully taken into account. We have used the term first-degree path
dependence to indicate instances in which persistence of prior conditions or
decisions exists, but with no implied inefficiency. This taxonomy of path
dependence claims appears in our 1995 paper in the Journal of Law,
Economics and Organization. Mark Roes 1996 Harvard Law Review paper
also offers a related categorization of path dependence. In Roe, path
dependence can be weak (the efficiency of the chosen path is tied with some
alternatives), semi strong, (the chosen path is not the best but not worth fixing,
or strong (the chosen path is highly inefficient, but we are unable to correct it).
Since information is always imperfect, a second possibility arises. When
individuals fail to predict the future perfectly, it is possible, even likely, that
decisions appearing efficient ex ante may not always appear to be efficient ex
post. Here the inferiority of a chosen path is unknowable at the time a choice
is made, but we later recognize that some alternative path would have yielded
greater wealth. In such a situation, which we have termed second-degree path
dependence, persistence of prior conditions or decisions leads to outcomes that
are regrettable and costly to change. They are not, however, inefficient in any
meaningful sense, given the assumed limitations on knowledge.
Related to this second type of path dependence is third-degree path
dependence. In third-degree path dependence, persistence leads to an outcome
that is inefficient - but in this case the outcome is remediable. That is, there
exists some feasible arrangement for recognizing and achieving a preferred
outcome, but that outcome is not obtained. Williamson (1993b, p. 140) offers
the term remediability to describe the condition that such feasible alternatives
exist, and urges remediability as the appropriate standard for public policy
discussion. Similar positions have been argued by Demsetz, Coase, Calabresi
and Dahlman, among others. In the framework that these authors have
advocated, market failure is not demonstrated unless a specific policy
recommendation can be shown in which the benefits exceed the costs, including
all of the administrative costs of the policy. For actual policy purposes, it of
986 Path Dependence 0770
correct this error. This is a third-degree claim. Davids reader is likely to find
the claim of path dependence in the third-degree form to be more palatable
because of his earlier establishment of weaker forms of path dependence.
Paul Krugman has offered industrial location as an example of inefficient
path dependence. If there were economies of having several firms in the same
industry produce at a single location, we would expect firms to congregate
somewhere. It could happen that firms simply congregate around the first
location at which a plant is established. In such a circumstance, there would be
no reason to think that the location chosen by such an industry is efficient.
Krugman uses the example of the accumulation of carpet manufacturing firms
around Dalton, Georgia (this city is the center of carpet production in the
United States; Krugman offers it as an example of path dependence and as an
example of the defects of traditional economic models). In such cases, it is
argued, economics does not tell us which location would be chosen for an
industry, and that it would only be by the sheerest of coincidences that the
choice of location for a single plant would turn out to be the efficient location
for an entire industry. There are several problems with this argument. First,
there are some reasons to think that the first firm at a particular location would
have chosen a location that is congenial to its industry. Second, most industries
have multiple production sites, and therefore there would be competition among
these candidate sites as a focus for industrial agglomeration. (For example,
many carpet plants operate successfully in locations outside of Georgia, both in
the Southeast and elsewhere.) Finally, locational choices may often involve a
choice among a number of equally efficient alternatives. The fact that
economics cannot explain the choice of a particular location over equivalently
attractive alternatives is no evidence against the efficiency of the chosen
outcome.
Path dependence along with the QWERTY story have moved out of
academic writing and into the arena of public policy. In the Los Angeles Times
(October 5, 1995), Steve Steinburg writes, regarding the adoption of an internet
standard, [I]ts all too likely to be the wrong standard. From Qwerty to Dvorak
keyboards, to Beta vs. VHS cassettes, history shows that market share and
technical superiority are rarely related. In The Independent (September 5,
1995) Hamish McRae discusses the likelihood of lock-in to inferior standards.
He notes the Beta and VHS competition as well as some others, then adds,
Another example is MS-DOS, but perhaps the best of all is the QWERTY
keyboard. This was designed to slow down typists ... . In Fortune (May 15,
1995) Tim Smith reports that QWERTY was intended to slow down typists,
and then notes, Perhaps the stern test of the marketplace produces results more
capricious than we like to think. In a long feature series in the Washington
Post (November 13, 1995), Steve Pearlstein argues that modern markets,
particularly those linked to networks, are likely to be dominated by just a few
firms. After introducing readers to Brian Arthur, he states, The Arthurian
0770 Path Dependence 989
Technology 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
A
Technology 4 7 10 13 16 19 22 25 28 31 34
B
The story that goes with the table is that there are two technologies that are in
competition with each other. A would-be adopter arrives on the scene and
chooses between technologies A and B. Assume for now that an adopter
receives a payoff (value), as shown in the table, that is determined by the total
number of adopters of a given technology. So, for example, if there are 21
adopters of technology A, each would enjoy a payoff of 12. The payoffs increase
with the number of adopters, which incorporates the increasing returns
assumption. These increasing returns might be due to either economies in
990 Path Dependence 0770
variant of the technology that is. Firms can advertise, they can lease out the
goods that implement the technology, they can enter strategic alliances. On the
consumer side, a large user of a technology may be able to profit from adopting
technology B regardless of the choices of other users. For example, large firms
with numerous typists would have switched to Dvorak if Dvorak really did offer
significant advantages.
The model that gives us lock-in from the numbers in the table not only
reduces producers to the role of mere spectators, but it also assumes that
consumers have no foresight. For if consumers were aware of the entire table,
all that is required to prevent lock-in to an inferior alternative is that adopters
can make reasonable forecasts of the number of eventual adopters. If, for
example, early adopters know that they will be joined by 100 more, they will
see that everyone will be better off with technology B. The latecomers will see
it that way too, and the early-comers know it. (For a more complete discussion
of this example, including an alternative interpretation of the table, see our
1995 paper.)
The kind of foresight that we are talking about here is not the domain of
gifted visionaries. It is the kind of foresight that led consumers to buy an FM
radio (as opposed to AM) in the early 1960s, cassette players in the 1970s (as
opposed to eight-track), and CD players in the 1980s (as opposed to analog
phonograph recordings). It leads newlyweds to buy a service for eight even
when they do not yet know three other couples in town. And in 1990, it led
consumers to buy Windows-based computers even when most machines were
still DOS-based .
Finally, this model of lock-in also imposes certain other theoretical
restrictions that may or may not commonly occur in the world. For example,
to obtain the lock-in that Arthur demonstrates, the technology that offers
smaller benefits at low levels of use must enjoy greater economies of scale. That
is, the returns functions must cross, or initial consumer decisions will not put
us on wrong paths. Since changes in payoffs must be due to economies of scale
or network effects, it must be presumed that these influences differ across
technologies. While it is certainly possible that this could occur, the
requirements for lock-in are far more stringent than might appear upon a casual
reading. In particular, it would seem that network effects would most likely
exert the same influence on either of two rival standards or technologies.
6. Cases
games. Sony slowed down the tape, allowing the taping of two hour programs,
albeit at lower quality. Matsushita in turn slowed down VHS to get four hours
of taping time, and RCA entered an agreement to market the four-hour VHS
machine. RCAs judgement that longer taping time was more important to
consumers than smaller cassettes appears in retrospect to be correct.
Everywhere that consumers had a choice they overwhelmingly chose VHS even
though the price differential was negligible (RCA came in with a startlingly
low $1000 price, but this was matched by Zeniths $996 price within the week).
Picture quality seems not to have been the issue either. Consumer Reports
product testing at the time indicated no clear advantage in picture quality for
either format, finding VHS better in two tests, Beta better in one, and a tie in
another (Klopfenstein, 1989, p. 28).
What this case actually demonstrates is not lock-in but rather the ability of
markets to facilitate a switch from one path or standard to another. In spite of
Betas two-year head start, the market shifted very quickly to a format that
offered an advantage to consumers. It is noteworthy that broadcasters
eventually standardized on the Beta format. The main difference between the
formats, other than the size of the cassette, is the way the cassette is threaded.
The Beta method, although more complicated, offers some advantages in
editing videotape and in special effects. This advantage is unimportant to most
home users, but is important to broadcasters. Broadcasters and home users
rarely exchange video tapes, so there is little benefit for compatibility between
the two. It is interesting, therefore, that professional broadcast users
standardized on Beta, which is advantageous to them, and home users adopted
VHS, which, with its longer taping time, is preferable to them.
The third of these path dependence stories is computer operating systems.
It is sometimes claimed that although Microsoft operating systems are inferior
to the Macintosh operating system, Macintosh failed because consumers were
so locked-in to DOS that they would not make the switch to the better system.
This claim requires close examination along several dimensions. First, the
superior operating system is not the one that is theoretically ideal, but the one
that is most efficient given the cost of the hardware required to run it. That is,
economic efficiency is what counts, not some form of engineering efficiency.
When DOS was king, computer memory was expensive and processors were
slow. The graphical interface of the Macintosh required far more computing
power to update than the DOS interface, on the order of fifteen to one. To take
advantage of graphical documents required much processing and storage
capacity, making it more expensive to get reasonable performance from a
Macintosh machine. As the price of memory fell and processors became faster,
the DOS operating system took on the features of the Macintosh, until at the
present time they (Windows95 and the Macintosh) are almost identical in
functionality for the typical consumer. Often overlooked is the fact that the
994 Path Dependence 0770
better operating system, the graphical operating system, did win, when it was
justified by the cost. Again, it is worth noting that graphics professionals, for
whom graphical processing was critical even at very high prices, moved to the
Macintosh early on, when there was no good DOS alternative. That continues
to be the market where the Macintosh has its greatest market share.
Van Vleck (1997) digs deeply into the claim, longstanding in the literature
of economic history, that the British use of a small coal car (compared to the
US and Germany) was an example of persistence of technological
backwardness; a kind of path dependence. Van Vleck shows rather
convincingly that the small coal car was an efficient response to differences in
prevailing conditions in Great Britian.
Of particular relevance for law and economics is work by Bruce Kobayashi
and Larry Ribstein on the adoption of uniform laws by states. For certain areas
of the law, particularly where laws effect dealings with outsiders,
standardization of statutes is efficient. Kobayashi and Ribstein (1996) studies
the adoption of statutes that allow limited liability companies and find that
while there are strong tendencies toward uniformity, the first form of a
provision is not particularly to become the standard form. Again this is contrary
to an expected influence from path dependence. In a related paper, Ribstein and
Kobayashi (1996) do find evidence of an influence of efficiency in states
tendencies regarding uniformity of statutes. They show that uniformity is much
more likely to be found in those areas of the law in which uniformity is
particularly advantageous.
Our attention has been largely limited to the role of path dependence in market
choices. Our observation is that where feasible improvements to an allocation
can be identified, private actors will attempt to engage in exchanges that will
allow them to profit from accomplishing these improvements. We do note,
however, that many social choices do not take place in markets, and in fact may
not even be recognized explicitly as choices.
The choice of religious and social institutions does not take place in an
explicit market. The choice of government, for much of history, has not even
been a choice for individual citizens. The institution of slavery was not a
voluntary transaction. In these cases, the forces that would normally promote
an efficient solution in the market do not necessarily come to the fore. A lack
of ownership of alternative institutions is one problem, but a more important
and fundamental problem is the absence of voluntary, feasible transactions. If
the state or military controls the proceeds from productive activities, there may
not be a feasible way to wealth-increasing improvements, since the beneficiaries
can not write enforceable contracts to pay off the despots who control the
0770 Path Dependence 995
Arthur, W. Brian (1989), Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-In by Historical
Events, 97 Economic Journal, 642-665.
Arthur, W. Brian (1990), Positive Feedbacks in the Economy, 262 Scientific American, 92-99.
Arthur, W. Brian (1994), Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy, Ann Arbor,
Michigan, University of Michigan, Institute of Public Administration.
Berg, Sanford V. (1989), The Production of Compatibility: Technical Standards as Collective Goods,
42 Kyklos.
Besen, Stanley M. and Joseph Farrell (1994), Choosing How to Compete: Strategies and Tactics in
Standardization, 8 Journal of Economic Perspectives.
Black, Bernard and Kraakman, Reinier H. (1996), A Self-Enforcing Model of Corporate Law, 109
Harvard Law Review, 1911-1979.
Blanchard, Olivier Jean and Summers, Lawrence H. (1987), Hysteresis in Unemployment, 31(2)
European Economic Review, 288-295.
Carlton, Dennis W. and Klamer, J. Mark (1983), The Need For Coordination among Firms, With
Special Reference to Network Industries, 50 University of Chicago Law Review.
Cook, Philip J. and Frank, Robert H. (1996), The Winner-Take-All Society : Why the Few at the Top
Get So Much More Than the Rest of Us, Penguin USA, reprint.
Chapman, Bruce (1994), The Rational and the Reasonable: Social Choice Theory and Adjudication,
61 University of Chicago Law Review, 41-122.
Chou, D. and Shy, O. (1990), Network Effects without Network Externalities, 8 International
Journal of Industrial Organization, 259-270.
Church, J and Gandal, Neil (1992), Network Effects, Software Provision, and Standardization, XL
Journal of Industrial Economics, 85-104.
Church, Jeffrey and Gandal, Neil (1993), Complementary Network Externalities and Technological
Adoption, 11 International Journal of Industrial Organization, 239-260.
Cowan, Robin (1991), Tortoises and Hares: Choice among Technologies of Unknown Merit, 101
Economic Journal, 801-814.
Dam, Kenneth W. (1995), Some Economic Considerations in the Intellectual Property Protection of
Software, 24 Journal of Legal Studies, 321 ff.
David, Paul A. (1985), Clio and the Economics of QWERTY, 75(5) American Economic Review,
332-337.
David, Paul A. (1992), Heroes, Herds and Hysteresis in Technological History: Thomas Edison and
the Battle of the Systems Revisited, 1 Industrial and Corporate Change, 129-180.
De Duve, Christian (1995), Vital Dust: Life as a Cosmic Imperative, New York, Basic Books.
Demsetz, H. (1973), Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint, 10 Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-22.
Dixit, A. and Nalebuff, Barry (1991), Thinking Strategically, New York, Norton.
Economides, Nicholas (1989), Desirability of Compatibility in the Absence of Network Externalities,
79 American Economic Review, 1165-1181.
Farrell, Joseph and Saloner, Garth (1976), Installed Base and Compatibility: Innovation, Product
Preannouncements, and Predation, 5 American Economic Review, 940-955.
0770 Path Dependence 997
Farrell, Joseph and Saloner, Garth (1985), Standardization, compatibility, and Innovation, 16(1)
Rand Journal of Economics, 70-83.
Franz, Wolfgang (1990), Hysteresis: An Overview, 2 Empirical Economics, 109-125.
Gould, Stephen J (1991), The Panda Thumb of Technology, in X (ed.), Bully for Brontosaurus, New
York, Norton.
Hunt, Shelby D. and Morgan, Robert M. (1996), The Resource Advantage Theory of Competition:
Dynamics, Path Dependencies, and Evolutionary Dimensions,60 Journal of Marketing, 107-114.
Kahan, Marcel and Klausner, Michael (1996), Path Dependence in Corporate Contracting: Increasing
Returns, Herd Behavior and Cognitive Biases, 74 Washington University Law Quarterly.
Kaplan, Steven N. and Ramseyer, J. Mark (1996), Those Japanese Firms, with their Disdain for
Shareholders: Another Fable for the Academy, Washington University Law Quarterly.
Katz, Michael L. and Shapiro, C. (1986), Technology Adoption in the Presence of Network
Externalities, Journal of Political Economy, 822-841.
Katzner, Donald (1993), Some Notes on the Role of History and the Definition of Hysteresis and
Related Concepts in Economic Analysis, 15(3) Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 323-345.
Kiwit, Daniel (1996), Path-Dependence in Technological and Institutional Change - Some Criticisms
and Suggestions, 7 Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines, 69-93.
Klopfenstein, B.C. (1989), The Diffusion of the VCR in the United States, in Levy, M.R. (ed.), The
VCR Age, California, Newsbury Park, Sage Publications.
Kobayashi, Bruce H. and Ribstein, Larry E. (1996), Evolutions of Spontaneous Uniformity: Evidence
from the Evolution of the Limited Liability Company, 34 Economic Inquiry, 464-483.
Krugman, Paul R. (1994), Peddling Prosperity, New York, Norton.
Lardner, J. (1987), Fast Forward, New York, Norton.
Levinson, R.J. and Coleman, Mary T. (1992), Economic Analysis of Compatibility Standards: How
Useful is it,, FTC working paper 1992.
Liebowitz, S.J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1990), The Fable of the Keys, 22 Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-26.
Liebowitz, S.J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1994a), Network Externality: An Uncommon Tragedy, 8
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 133-150.
Liebowitz, S.J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1994b), Are Network Externalities a New Source of Market
Failure?, 16 Research in Labor Economics.
Liebowitz, S.J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1995), Path Dependence, Lock-in and History, 11 Journal
of Law, Economics, and Organization, 205-226.
Lopatka, John and Page, William H. (1995), Microsoft, Monopolization, and Network Externalities:
Some Uses and Abuses of Economic Theory in Antitrust Decision Making, Summer 1995 The
Antitrust Bulletin, 317-369.
Mokyr, Joel (1991), Evolutionary Biology, Technological Change and Economic History,43 Bulletin
of Economic Research, 127-147.
Nelson, Richard R. and Winter, Sidney G. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change,
Cambridge, MA, Belknap of Harvard University Press.
North, Douglass C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
998 Path Dependence 0770
Ribstein, Larry E. (1995), Statutory Forms for Closely Held Firms: Theories and Evidence from
LLCs, 73 Washington University Law Quarterly, 369 ff.
Ribstein, Larry E. (1995), Linking Statutory Forms, 58 Journal of Law and Contemporary
Problems, 58 ff.
Ribstein, Larry E. and Kobayashi, Bruce H. (1995), Uniform Laws, Model Laws and Limited Liability
Companies, 66 University of Colorado Law Review, 947-999.
Ribstein, Larry E. and Kobayashi, Bruce H. (1996), An Economic Analysis of Uniform State Laws,
34 Journal of Legal Studies, 131-199.
Roe, Mark J. (1996), Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics, 109 Harvard Law Review,
641-668.
Schelling, Thomas C. (1978), Micromotives and Macro Behavior, New York, Norton.
Van Vleck, Va Nee L. (1997), Delivering Coal By Road and Rail: The Efficiency of the Silly Little
Bobtailed Coal Wagon, 57 Journal of Economic History, 139-160.
Vita, Michael G. and Wellford, Charissa P. (1994), Regulating the Electromagnetic Environment:
Alternative Approaches to Policy, in Fleming, James R. and Gemery, Henry A. (eds), Science,
Technology, and the Environment.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1993a), Contested Exchange Versus the Governance of Contractual Relations,
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 103-108.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1993b), Transaction Cost Economics and Organization Theory, 2 Industrial
and Corporate Change, 107-156.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1994), The Politics and Economics of Redistribution and Inefficiency, 17
Greek Economic Review, December 1995, pp. 115-136.
0780
NON-LEGAL SANCTIONS
Stephan Panther
Institute of Economics, AWM, Universitt Hamburg
Copyright 1999 Stephan Panther
Abstract
A. Introduction
Law and economics has focused on the analysis of the (efficiency) effects of
formal legal rules, which are enforced by a specialized central agency, the
state, employing legal sanctions. However, even in fully developed market
economies with a high degree of division of labor, formal legal rules do not
comprise the total picture. They would do so only if it were possible to specify
and enforce a comprehensive set of property rights perfectly, and, building on
this, perfectly specify and enforce contracts. In such a world, actors would only
interact through voluntary contracts, not influencing each other in any other
way. It is a perfectly secure world. Even if it is not characterized by perfect and
complete information for every actor, actors expectations concerning each
others behavior are sure to be fulfilled since an omniscient, omnipotent and
benevolent government guarantees perfect enforcement. This world, of course,
is utopian.
The world we live in knows only incompletely specified and enforced
property rights and contracts. The arm of the law does not reach everywhere.
Crimes remain unsolved, courts err and using them is costly, and hence some
999
1000 Non-legal Sanctions 0780
cases are simply never filed. Contracts do not contain provisions for all possible
contingencies that might arise. Rulers, politicians and government officials are
self-interested and hard to control and it actually might be a blessing that they
are not omniscient and omnipotent. In our world, formal legal rules and legal
sanctions no longer determine behavior with certainty. Other factors
co-determine actions. Especially non-legal rules (social norms) and non-legal
sanctions play prominent roles.
Before turning our attention to these (see also the comments on Lindenberg,
1990, and Schlicht, 1997, in Section 6 below), it should be noted that the other
important factors shaping action are cognitive rules and schemata. After all, it
is the subjective perception of rules and sanctions which matters for individual
behavior, a point stressed by Opp (1985). Denzau and North (1994) discuss this
issue in a neo-institutionalist framework. Lessig (1996) and Sunstein (1996)
raise some cognitive issues in relation to law, the latter especially suggesting
that the mere declaration of a rule as a law may influence the prevailing social
norms.
with criteria laid down in a legal rule. Of course, the law frequently delegates
the decision over the precise content of the required behavior to other, possibly
private, actors. Contract law is centered on this idea. It nevertheless remains
clear when conduct is law abiding and when not. In modern western societies
the law also regularly contains binding constitutive, procedural and controller
selection rules, the existence of which is, however, not taken as part of the
definition of a legal sanction here.
Social norms are to non-legal sanctions what laws are to legal sanctions.
Coleman (1990), Elster (1989a) and Hechter (1987) are monographs containing
comprehensive treatments of social norms from a methodological
individualistic perspective. Coleman is the prime reference. Elsters treatment,
while full of insight, is hampered by his non-consequentialist definition of
norms. Opp (1985) is a systematic account in the form of an article, Opp (1979)
provides a systematic comparison of sociological and economic accounts of
norms as far as available at the date of publication.
All of the aspects of a sanctioning system just discussed may be regulated
by a system of social norms. The main debate has, however, been on the issue
of whether a mere substantial rule, a prescription or prohibition of an action,
constitutes a social norm, or whether an attached remedial rule, the
specification of a sanction in case of deviation, has to be present, too. The latter
view is taken here, which is argued, for example, in Weise (1996). It is also
implied by Coleman (1990, pp. 241-249), while Elster (1989a, pp. 98-100)
favors the former. See Crawford and Ostrom (1995) for a comprehensive
discussion.
Given the primary focus of this review on non-legal sanctions, we will
classify social norms by the way they are enforced. While the following is one
common classification, it is by no means universally accepted. It follows largely
Ellikson (1991, pp. 123-136) and Kiwit and Voigt (1995). (See also James
Coleman, 1990, pp. 241-249 for a somewhat different view.)
External norms are enforced through sanctions by non-specialized members
of a society. Ellikson (1991) further distinguishes situations where sanctions are
administered by those against whom a norm has been transgressed (second
party control) from those where originally nonaffected parties are involved in
sanctioning (third party control). Decisions about and enforcement of the
sanction may lie with the same actor or may be separated. The non-specialized
nature of enforcement does not imply anything about the severity of the
sanction, which may range from expression of disapproval to ostracism to
physical violence.
Internal norms have been internalized to such a degree that their
transgression, while benefiting narrow self-interest, causes discomfort, psychic
costs. In contrast to external norms, issues of policing do not arise here. The
very actor who deliberates a deviation from a rule also sanctions himself (first
party control). Cooter (1996) (Cooter, 1994, is an earlier version) contains a
1002 Non-legal Sanctions 0780
B. Theory
this is due to special personal traits or not. When I want to clearly distinguish
between the two notions of reputation, I will use the term g-reputation if I want
to refer to the game theoretic usage of the term, and cs-reputation for the
common sense notion. This common sense notion of reputation leads us to the
next section.
When third parties administer sanctions, the information and motivation issues
already relevant for multilateral second party control gain considerably in
importance. In particular the motivation problem becomes more pointed: why
should an actor sanction another, usually at least foregoing cooperation benefits
in doing so, when the other has not deviated against him? The theoretical
answers to these issues are as yet more exploratory than comprehensive.
Consider the contribution of Klein and Leffler (1981) mentioned in Section
4. In its simplest version, all demanders are identical in all respects and the
behavior of the supplier is identical towards them. If the supplier cheats, he
cheats all demanders and only second-party sanctions occur as a consequence.
Nevertheless, it can and has been interpreted as a model of cs-reputation in the
sense just introduced.
Suppose quality were stochastic (for example, reliability) and consequently
not every buyer could observe quality in the period after purchase. Assume that
the information transmission problem is solved. Upon receiving the information
that quality is poor, a reputational equilibrium of the following kind is
self-enforcing, needing no threats to would-be deviators from the punishment
path: every demander expects poor quality and is only willing to pay the
correspondingly lower price, and the supplier, knowing this, will actually
provide poor quality at the lower cost. Since punishment strategies constitute
an equilibrium, there is no motivation problem for sanctions to be administered.
Bendor and Mookherjee (1990) also assume that the information problem
is solved. They model a multitude of actors engaged in simultaneous repeated
bilateral exchanges. The motivation problem is dealt with by assuming a
prisoners dilemma structure on payoffs and calling for the equilibrium of the
single shot stage game (the non-cooperative action) to be played as a
punishment. Two of their results are worth mentioning: referring to the
interpretation of discount factors as reflecting separation probabilities, they
state that non-legal sanctions by second parties are sufficient in very stable
societies, third-party sanctions are effective at intermediate levels of stability,
and in a society with very unstable relationship only legal enforcement can
sustain cooperation. Furthermore, for third-party control to be effective, either
the payoffs from exchanges with different actors have to influence each other
1008 Non-legal Sanctions 0780
or they have to differ. If payoffs from exchanges are separable and symmetric,
third-party enforcement is ineffective.
Kandori (1992) has tackled the information problem by trying to find
minimal requirements for third-party sanctions to be effective. He looks at this
question in a random matching game with bilateral exchange: every period,
actors are reshuffled into new pairs. Kandori basically confirms the intuition
about the role cs-reputation may play in such a situation: he finds conditions
under which a label, determined by the past actions of an actor and known to
the player he is matched with at the start of their trading period, is sufficient
for cooperation to be sustained. The motivation problem reappears, since
Kandori considers general payoff structures. Hirshleifer and Rasmusen (1989)
discuss the somewhat related issue of ostracism.
Kandori (1992) and especially Ellison (1994) have analyzed another kind
of equilibrium, which does not require any information transmission. Whenever
a player has been cheated, he will cheat any other player in the game. In a
contagious process, cooperation will eventually break down. This becomes
interesting if one assumes a public randomization device (a public signal, for
example, a campaign for moral renewal). Using this idea, Ellison shows that
such a contagious process can be of finite length. This is shown for prisoners
dilemma games and random matching of pairs. In addition, the result does not
require too patient players and equilibrium can even be stable in situations
where deviations may occur by mistake. We may then find periods of
widespread deviation alternating with periods of cooperation in a population.
6. Internal Norms
Internal norms provide first party sanctions. The actor deliberating a deviation
from a rule foresees at the same time an internal non-legal sanction in the form
of reduced utility. The potential importance of internal norms is fairly obvious.
Nevertheless, they have been somewhat disreputable in mainstream economic
theory, since their use amounts to explanation via preferences. Economists have
been very skeptical about any direct way of obtaining data about preferences
and in the absence of data, postulating a preference for something can explain
virtually any behavior. However, as survey techniques have become more and
more sophisticated in other social sciences and experiments have gained
general approval in economics, evidence on preferences can be obtained and
tested far more reliably. This has put internal norms back on the research
agenda of methodological individualistic theoreticians.
Despite their temporary disrepute, internal norms have very reputable
ancestors. No one less than the founding father of modern economics, Adam
Smith, has been counted among those who have developed a full blown theory
0780 Non-legal Sanctions 1009
C. Applications
7. Family
9. Pre-Legal Societies
10. Property
11. Contract
Both Charny (1990) and Rubin (1993) are comprehensive treatments of the
issue of non-legal sanctions in relation to contracts (see also Kronman, 1985
for a somewhat earlier and more limited account). Both are written in an
0780 Non-legal Sanctions 1013
deals. Basically, business partners do not know whether the opposing party will
defect and quit the market or whether it is there to stay. Legal rules,
information gathering and formal private policing are used as remedies.
In a brilliant historical study, Greif (1994) has compared the community-
and reputation-based enforcement mechanism of a medieval Jewish trader
community in Islamic North Africa with the individualistic enforcement
mechanism of their Genuese contemporaries combining analytical clarity with
a host of interesting institutional issues. A notable result is the likely superiority
of the communal system at any moment in time combined with its inferiority
in the opening up of new trading areas.
The literature on second-party sanctions based on external norms is large.
Concerning contract law, however, as may have become clear already in
Section 4, it is largely identical with the literature on relational/long-term
contracts which is dealt with in a chapter section in this encyclopedia. The
relatively new models of the endogenous determination of the severity of the
sanction via exit from and re-formation of relationships have, however, not yet
found their way into this literature.
When we leave the framework of purely external norms and take internal
sanctions into account, the theory of relational contracts developed by Macneil
over the course of the last twenty years is a prime reference. Macneil can take
credit for being the first to formulate a theory covering relational contract
(which has been acknowledged by writers like Williamson). It has been
changing considerably over time. A good, concise statement of its latest stage
of development is Macneil (1987), along with Macneil (1983, 1985). The
theory stresses the relevance of internalized solidarity and reciprocity norms in
ongoing contractual relationships, apart from the disciplining role of other
sanctions. His theory is not developed in close contact with economic reasoning
and therefore is not always easy to understand from this frame of mind.
Lindenberg and de Vos (1985) criticize it from a revisionist rational choice
perspective, to which Macneil (1987) replies. Lindenberg (1988) presents a
theoretical design of his own applying his framing theory (see Section 6). The
approach centers on the idea of weak solidarity in long-lasting contract
relationships. While selfish gain-maximization is the main aim, solidarity
norms enter the decision as a secondary factor. By way of contrast, the strong
solidarity present in close-knit social units like families is characterized by the
fulfillment of normative duties as the main aim and selfish aims as a secondary,
distracting, factor. Lindenberg argues that strong solidarity frequently is
detrimental to contractual relationships.
Several other publications dealing with non-legal sanctions in relation to
contracts also implicitly or explicitly refer to both internal and external norms.
Experimental work supporting the importance of internal norms in contracts
is presented by Hackett (1994). Very interesting work based on anthropological
0780 Non-legal Sanctions 1015
12. Corporations
by raising the disutility of an offence in the first place, it may actually reduce
the deterrent effect rather than increase it. Rasmusen (1996) considers other
models of stigma. The models analyze self-enforcing third-party sanctions,
are adverse selection and moral hazard driven, and give rise to multiple
equilibria. Karpoff and Lott (1993) include an empirical study of the interaction
between criminal sanctions and the loss of reputation caused by these sanctions
in the case of corporate fraud.
Acknowledgments
Abreu, Dilip (1988), Towards a Theory of Discounted Repeated Games, 56 Econometrica, 383-396.
Adams, Michael (1996), Norms, Standards, Rights, 12 European Journal of Political Economy,
363-375.
Akerlof, George A. (1982), Labor Contracts as Partial Gift Exchange, 97 Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 543-569.
Allen, Douglas W. and Lueck, Dean (1992), The Back Forty on a Handshake: Specifik Assets,
Reputation, and the Structure of Farmland Contracts, 8 Journal of Law, Economics and
Organization, 366-376.
Anderson, C. Leigh and Swimmer, Eugene R. (1997), Some Empirical Evidence on Property Rights
of First Peoples, 33 Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 1-22.
Anderson, Terry L. and Hill, Peter J. (1975), The Evolution of Property Rights: A Study of the
American West, 18 Journal of Law and Economics, 163-179.
Arnott, Richard J. and Stiglitz, J.E. (1991), Moral Hazard and Nonmarket Institutions: Dysfunctional
Crowding Out or Peer Monitoring?, 81 American Economic Review, 179-190.
Becker, Gary S. (1974), A Theory of Social Interaction, 82 Journal of Political Economy,
1063-1093.
Becker, Gary S. and Murphy, Kevin M. (1988), The Family and the State, 31 Journal of Law and
Economics, 1-18.
0780 Non-legal Sanctions 1021
Becker, Gary S., Landes, Elisabeth M. and Michael, Robert T. (1977), An Economic Analysis of
Maritial Instability, 85 Journal of Political Economy, 1141-1187.
Ben-Porath, Y. (1980), The F-Connection: Families, Friends and Firms and the Organization of
Exchange, 6 Population Development Review, 1-30.
Bendor, Jonathan and Mookherjee, D. (1990), Norms, Third Party Sanctions, and Cooperation, 6
Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 33-63.
Benson, Bruce L. (1984), Guns for Protection and other Private Sector Responses to the Fear of
Violent Crime, in Kates, Don, Jr (ed.), Firearms and Violence: Issues of Regulation, Cambridge,
MA, Ballinger, 329-356.
Benson, Bruce L. (1986), Guns for Protection and other Private Sector Responses to Governments
Failure to Control Increasing Violent Crime, 8 Journal of Libertarian Studies, 75-109.
Benson, Bruce L. (1988), Legal Evolution in Primitive Societies, 144 Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics, 772-788.
Benson, Bruce L. (1989a), The Spontaneous Evolution of Commercial Law, 55 Southern Economic
Journal, 644-661.
Benson, Bruce L. (1989b), Enforcement of Private Property Rights in Primitive Societies: Law without
Government, 9 Journal of Libertarian Studies, 1-26.
Benson, Bruce L (1990), The Enterprise of Law: Justice Without the State, San Francisco, Pacific
Research Institute for Public Policy.
Benson, Bruce L. (1991a), An Evolutionary Contractarian View of Primitive Law: The Institutions
and Incentives Arising Under Customary American Indian Law,5 Review of Austrian Economics,
65-89.
Benson, Bruce L. (1991b), Reciprocal Exchange as the Basis for Recognition of Law: Examples from
American History, 10 Journal of Libertarian Studies, 53-82.
Benson, Bruce L. (1992a), The Evolution of Values and Institutions in a Free Society: The
Under-Pinnings of a Market Economy, 5 International Journal on the Unity of Sciences,
411-442. Reprinted in Radnitzky, Gerard and Bouillon, Hardy (eds), Values and the Social Order
Vol.I, Aldershot, Avebury, 87-125.
Benson, Bruce L. (1992b), Customary Law as a Social Contract: International Commercial Law, 2
Constitutional Political Economy, 1-27.
Benson, Bruce L. (1994), Are Public Goods Really Common Pools: Considerations of the Evolution
of Policing and Highways in England, 39 Economic Inquiry, 249-271.
Benson, Bruce L. (1995), An Exploration of the Impact of Modern Arbitration Statutes on the
Development of Arbitration in the United States, 11 Journal of Law, Economics, and
Organization, 479-501.
Bernheim, B. Douglas, Shleifer, Andrei and Summers, Larry (1985), The Strategic Bequest Motive,
93 Journal of Political Economy, 1045-1076.
Bernstein, Lisa (1992), Opting Out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the
Diamond Industry, 21 Journal of Legal Studies, 115-157.
Bernstein, Lisa (1996), Merchant Law in a Merchant Court: Rethinking the Codes Search for
Immanent Business Norms, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 1765-1823.
Besley, T. and Coate, Stephen (1995), Group Lending, Repayment Incentives and Social Collateral,
46 Journal of Development Economics, 1-18.
Black, Bernard and Kraakman, Reinier H. (1996), A Self-Enforcing Model of Corporate Law, 109
Harvard Law Review, 1911-1979.
1022 Non-legal Sanctions 0780
Bhm-Bawerk, Eugen (1881), Rechte und Verhltnisse vom Standpunkte der volkswirtschaftlichen
Gterlehre (Rights and Relationships from the Point of View of the Economic Theory of Goods),
Innsbruck, Wagner.
Carr, Jack L. and Landa, Janet T. (1983), The Economics of Symbols, Clan Names and Religion, 12
Journal of Legal Studies, 135-156.
Chami, Ralph and Fischer, Jeffrey (1995), Community Banking, Monitoring and the Clinton Plan,
14 Cato Journal, 493-508.
Charny, David (1990), Nonlegal Sanctions in Commercial Relationships, 104 Harvard Law Review,
375-467.
Charny, David (1996), Illusions of a Spontaneous Order: Norms in Contractual Relations, 144
University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 1841-1858.
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1973), The Fable of the Bees: An Economic Investigation, 16 Journal of Law
and Economics, 11-33.
Choi, Chong Ju (1993), Buying versus Creating Reputation, 13 International Review of Law and
Economics, 99-101.
Chong, Dennis (1996), Values versus Interests in the Explanation of Social Conflict, 144 University
of Pennsylvania Law Review, 2079-2134.
Coate, Stephen and Ravallion, Martin (1993), Reciprocity Without Commitment. Characterization and
Performance of Informal Insurance Arrangements, 40 Journal of Development Economics, 1-24.
Coleman, James S. (1990), Foundations of Social Theory, Cambridge, MA, Belknap of Harvard
University Press.
Cooter, Robert (1994), Structural Adjudication and the New Law Merchant: A Model of Decentralized
Law, 14 International Review of Law and Economics, 215-231.
Cooter, Robert (1996), Decentralized Law for a Complex Economy: The Structural Approach to
Adjudicating the New Law Merchant, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 1644-1696.
Cooter, Robert and Landa, Janet T. (1984), Personal Versus. Impersonal Trade: The Size of Trading
Groups and Contract Law, 4 International Review of Law and Economics, 15-22.
Crawford, Sue E.S. and Ostrom, Elinor (1995), A Grammar of Institutions, 89 American Political
Science Review, 582-600.
Denzau, Arthur and North, Douglass C. (1994), Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions,
47 Kyklos, 3-31.
Eger, Thomas (1995), Eine konomische Analyse von Langzeitvertrgen (An Economic Analysis of
Long-Term Contracts), Marburg, Metropolis.
Ellikson, Robert C. (1986), Of Coase and Cattle: Dispute Resolution among Neighbors in Shasta
County, 38 Stanford Law Review, 623-687.
Ellikson, Robert C. (1987), A Critique of Economic and Sociological Theories of Social Control, 16
Journal of Legal Studies, 67-99.
Ellikson, Robert C. (1989), A Hypothesis of Wealth-Maximizing Norms: Evidence from the Whaling
Industry, 5 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 83-97.
Ellikson, Robert C. (1991), Order Without Law, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Ellison, Glenn (1994), Cooperation in the Prisoners Dilemma with Anonymous Random Matching,
61 Review of Economic Studies, 567-588.
0780 Non-legal Sanctions 1023
Elsner, Wolfram (1989), Adam Smiths Model of the Origins and Emergence of Institutions: The
Modern Findings of the Classical Approach, 23 Journal of Economic Issues, 189-213.
Elster, Jon (1989a), The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press.
Elster, Jon (1989b), Nuts and Bolts for the Social Sciences, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Elster, Jon (1996), Rationality and the Emotions, 106 Economic Journal, 1386-1397.
Epstein, Richard A. (1992a), The Path to The T.J. Hooper: The Theory and History of Custom in the
Law of Tort, 21 Journal of Legal Studies, 1-38.
Epstein, Richard A. (1992b), International News Service vs. Associated Press: Custom and the Law
as Sources of Property Rights in News, 78 Virginia Law Review, 85-128.
Epstein, Richard A. (1995), The Status-Production Sideshow: Why the Antidiscrimination Laws are
Still a Mistake, 108 Harvard Law Review, 1085-1109.
Fafchamps, Marcel (1992), Solidarity Networks in Preindustrial Societies: Rational Peasants with a
Moral Economy, 41 Economic Development and Cultural Change, 147-174.
Felson, Marcus (1986), Linking Criminal Choices, Routine Activities, Informal Control, and Criminal
Outcomes, in Cornish, Derek B. and Clarke, Ronald V. (eds), The Reasoning Criminal, New
York, Springer, 119-128.
Frank, Robert H. (1987), If Homo Economicus could choose his own Utility Function, would he want
One with a Conscience?, 77 American Economic Review, 593-604.
Frank, Robert H. (1988), Passions within Reason, New York, W.W. Norton.
Frey, Bruno S. (1993a), Motivation as a Limit to Pricing, 14 Journal of Economic Psychology,
635-664.
Frey, Bruno S. (1993b), Does Monitoring Increase Work Effort?, 31 Economic Inquiry, 663-670.
Frey, Bruno S. (1993c), Shirking or Work Morale? The Impact of Regulating, 37 European
Economic Review, 1523-1532.
Frey, Bruno S. (1997), Not Just for the Money: an Economic Theory of Personal Motivation,
Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
Friedman, David D. (1979), Private Creation and Enforcement of Law: A Historical Case, 8 Journal
of Legal Studies, 399-415.
Ghosh, Parikshit and Ray, Debraj (1996), Cooperation in Community Interaction Without Information
Flows, 59 Review of Economic Studies, 63-80.
Glaeser, E.L., Sacerdote, B. and Scheinkman, Jose A. (1996), Crime and Social Interactions, 111
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 507-548.
Gorton, Gary and Mullineaux, Donald J. (1987), The Joint Production of Confidence: Endogenous
Regulation and Nineteenth Century Commercial-Bank Clearinghouses, 19 Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking, 457-468.
Greenberg, Stephanie W. and Rohe, William M. (1986), Informal Social Control and Crime
Prevention in Modern Urban Neighborhoods, in Taylor, Ralph B. (ed.), Urban Neighborhoods:
Research and Policy, New York, Praeger, 79-118.
Greif, Avner (1994), Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A Historical and Theoretical
Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies, 102 Journal of Political Economy,
912-950.
1024 Non-legal Sanctions 0780
Greif, Avner, Milgrom, P. and Weingast, Barry (1994), Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement:
The Case of the Merchant Guild, 102 Journal of Political Economy, 745-776.
Gth, Werner and Kliemt, Hartmut (1994), Competition or Cooperation. On the Evolutionary
Economics of Trust, Exploitation and Moral Attitudes, 45 Metroeconomica, 155-187.
Gutrie, James and Turnbull, Shann (1995), Audit Committees: Is There a Role for Corporate Senates
and/or Stakeholders Councils?, 3(2) Corporate Governance: An International Review, 78-89.
Hackett, Steven C. (1994), Is Relational Exchange Possible in the Absence of Reputations and
Repeated Contact?, 10 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 360-389.
Hgg, P. Goran T. (1994), The Economics of Trust, Trust Sensitive Contracts, and Regulation, 14
International Review of Law and Economics, 437-451.
Hasen, Richard L. (1996), Voting Without Law, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law Review,
2135-2179.
Hechter, Michael (1987), Principles of Group Solidarity, Berkeley, University of California Press.
Hirshleifer D. and Rasmusen, Eric (1989), Cooperation in a Repeated Prisoners Dilemma with
Ostracism, 12 Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 87-106.
Huang, Peter H. and Wu, Ho-Mou (1992), Emotional Responses in Litigation, 12 International
Review of Law and Economics, 31-44.
Huang, Peter H. and Wu, Ho-Mou (1994), More Order without More Law: A Theory of Social Norms
and Organizational Cultures, 10 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 390-406.
Iannaccone, Laurence R. (1992), Sacrifice and Stigma: Reducing Free-riding in Cults, Communes, and
other Collectives, 100 Journal of Political Economy, 271-291.
Johnston, Jason Scott (1996), The Statute of Frauds and Business Norms: A Testable Game-Theoretic
Model, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 1859-1912.
Kamiat, Walter (1996), Labor and Lemons: Efficient Norms in the Internal Labor Market and the
Possible Failures of Individual Contracting, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law Review,
1953-1970.
Kandori, Michihiro (1992), Social Norms and Community Enforcement, 59 Review of Economic
Studies, 63-80.
Karpoff, Jonathan M. and Lott, J.R., Jr (1993), The Reputational Penalty Firms Bear from
Committing Criminal Fraud, 36 Journal of Law and Economics, 757-802.
Katz, Avery (1996), Taking Private Ordering Seriously, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law
Review, 1745-1764.
Kimball, Miles (1988), Farmers Cooperatives as Behavior Toward Risk, 78 American Economic
Review, 224-232.
Kiwit, Daniel and Voigt, Stefan (1995), berlegungen zum Institutionellen Wandel unter
Bercksichtigung des Verhltnisses Interner und Externer Institutionen (On Institutional Change
Acknowledging the Relationship Between Formal and Informal Institutions), 46 Ordo, 117-147.
Klein, Benjamin and Leffler, Keith B. (1981), The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual
Performance, 89 Journal of Political Economy, 615-641.
Kranton, Rachel E. (1996a), The Formation of Cooperative Relationships, 12 Journal of Law,
Economics, and Organization, 214-233.
0780 Non-legal Sanctions 1025
MacNeil, Ian R. (1985), Relational Contract: What We Do and Do Not Know, Wisconsin Law
Review, 483-525.
MacNeil, Ian R. (1987), Relational Contract Theory as Sociology, 143 Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics, 272-290.
Matsumura, Toshihiro and Ryser, Marc (1995), Revelation of Private Information about Unpaid Notes
in the Trade Credit Bill System in Japan, 24 Journal of Legal Studies, 165-187.
McAdams, Richard H. (1995), Cooperation and Conflict: The Economics of Group Status Production
and Race Discrimination, 108 Harvard Law Review, 1003-1084.
McAdams, Richard H. (1996), Group Norms, Gossip and Blackmail,144 University of Pennsylvania
Law Review, 2237-2292.
McMaster, Robert and Sawkins, John W. (1996), The Contract State, Trust Distortion, and
Efficiency, 54 Review of Social Economy, 145-167.
Milgrom, P., North, Douglass C. and Weingast, Barry (1990), The Role of Institutions in the Revival
of Trade: the Medieval Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs, 2 Economics
and Politics, 1-23.
Miller, Geoffrey P. (1993), Ritual and Regulation: A Legal Economic Interpretation of Selected
Biblical Texts, 22 Journal of Legal Studies, 477-501.
North, Douglass C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Opp, Karl Dieter (1979), The Emergence and Effects of Social Norms, 32 Kyklos, 775-801.
Opp, Karl Dieter (1985), Sociology and Economic Man, 141 Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics, 213-243.
Opp, Karl Dieter (1989), The Economics of Crime and the Sociology of Deviant Behaviour: A
Theoretical Confrontation of Basic Propositions, 42 Kyklos, 405-430.
Ostrom, Elinor (1990), Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Ostrom, Elinor, Gardner, Roy and Walker, James M. (1992), Covenants With and Without a Sword:
Self-Governance is Possible, 86 American Political Science Review, 404-417.
Ostrom, Elinor, Gardner, Roy and Walker, James M. (1994), Rules, Games, and Common Pool
Resources, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press.
Pauly, Mark V. (1990), The Rational Non-Purchase of Long-Term-Care Insurance, 98 Journal of
Political Economy, 153-168.
Pildes, Richard H. (1996), The Destruction of Social Capital Through Law, 144 University of
Pennsylvania Law Review, 2055-2077.
Pirrong, Stephen Craig (1995), The Efficient Scope of Private Transactions Cost Reducing Institutions:
The Successes and Failures of Commodity Exchanges, 24 Journal of Legal Studies, 229-255.
Pollak, Robert A. (1985), A Transaction Cost Approach to Families and Households, 23 Journal of
Economic Literature, 581-608.
Posner, Eric A. (1995), The Regulation of Groups: The Influence of Legal and Nonlegal Sanctions on
Collective Action, 63 University of Chicago Law Review, 133-197.
Posner, Eric A. (1996a), Law, Economics and Inefficient Norms, 145 University of Pennsylvania
Law Review, 1697-1744.
Posner, Eric A. (1996b), Norms, Formalities, and the Statute of Frauds: A comment on Discovering
Contract, 145 University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 1971-1986.
0780 Non-legal Sanctions 1027
Posner, Eric A. (1998), Symbols, Signals, and Social Norms in Politics and the Law, 27 (2) Journal
of Legal Studies, 765-798.
Posner, Richard A. (1980), A Theory of Primitive Society, With Special Reference to Law, 23
Journal of Law and Economics, 1-53.
Posner, Richard A. (1981), The Economics of Justice, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1987), Takeovers in Japan: Opportunism, Ideology and Corporate Control, 35
UCLA Law Review, 1-63.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1991), Legal Rules in Repeat Deals: Banking and the Shadow of Defection in
Japan, 20 Journal of Legal Studies, 91-117.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1994), Learning to Love Japan: Social Norms and Market Incentives, 31
University of San Diego Law Review, 263 ff.
Ramseyer, J. Mark (1996), Products Liability Through Private Ordering, 144 University of
Pennsylvania Law Review, 1823-1840.
Ramseyer, J. Mark and Nakazato, Minoru (1989), The Rational Litigant: Settlement Amounts and
Verdict Rates in Japan, 18 Journal of Legal Studies, 263-290.
Rasmusen, Eric (1996), Stigma and Self-Fulfilling Expectations of Criminality, 39 Journal of Law
and Economics, 519-543.
Richter, Wolfram F. (1995), Optimal Provision Against the Risk of Old Age, 52 Finanzarchiv,
339-356.
Rock, Edward B. and Wachter, Michael L. (1996), The Enforceability of Norms and the Employment
Relationship, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 1913-1952.
Rubin, Paul H. (1993), Private Mechanisms for the Creation of Efficient Institutions for Market
Economies, in Somogyi, Laszlo (ed.), The Political Economy of The Transition Process in
Eastern Europe,, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
Rubin, Paul H. (1994), Growing a Legal System in the Post-Communist Economies, 27 Cornell
International Law Journal, 1-47.
Rubin, Paul H. (1996), Promises, Promises: Contracts in Russia and Other Post-Communist
Economies, Shaftesbury Papers, Edward Elgar and the Locke Institute.
Schelling, Thomas C. (1960), The Strategy of Conflict, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Schlicht, Ekkehart (1993), On Custom, 149 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics,
178-203.
Schlicht, Ekkehart (1997), On Custom in the Economy, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Schwartz, Alan and Scott, Robert E. (1995), The Political Economy of Private Legislatures, 143
University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 595-654.
Shapiro, C. and Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1984), Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline
Device, 74 American Economic Review, 433-444.
Sinden, J.A. (1994), Learning To Love Japan: Social Norms and Market Incentives, 31 University
of San Diego Law Review, 263 ff.
Sugden, Robert (1986), The Economics of Rights, Co-operation and Welfare, Oxford, Basil
Blackwell.
Sunstein, Cass R. (1996), On the Expressive Function of Law, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law
Review, 2055-2077.
Telser, Lester G. (1980), A Theory of Self-Enforcing Agreements, 53 Journal of Business, 27-44.
Udry, Christopher (1994), Risk and Insurance in a Rural Credit Market. An empirical Investigation
in Northern Nigeria, 61 Review of Economic Studies, 495-526.
1028 Non-legal Sanctions 0780
Ullman-Margalit, Edna (1977), The Emergence of Norms, Oxford, Oxford Clarendon Press.
Versteeg, J. Russell (1989), Law and the Security of Homeric Society. A Response to Richard A.
Posner, 10 Journal of Legal History, 265-284.
Weber, M. (1921), Economy and Society, Berkeley, University of California Press.
Weise, Peter (1996), Verhaltenskoordination durch Soziale Krfte und Normen (Coordination of
Behavior through Social Forces and Norms), in Priddat, Birger and Wegener, Gerhard (eds),
Zwischen Evolution und Institution (Between Evolution and Institution), Marburg, Metropolis,
187-209.
Weitzman, Lenore J. (1981a), The Economics of Divorce: Social and Economic Consequences of
Property, Alimony and Child Support Awards, 28 UCLA Law Review, 1181-1268.
Weitzman, Lenore J. (1981b), The Marriage Contract, New York, NY, Free Press.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1983), Credible Commitments: Using Hostages to Support Exchange, 73
American Economic Review, 519-540.
Witt, Ulrich (1986), Evolution and Stability of Cooperation without Enforceable Contracts, 39
Kyklos, 245-266.
Young, Peyton H. (1996), The Economics of Convention, 10 Journal of Economic Perspectives,
105-122.
Zweifel, Peter and Strwe, Wolfram (1994), Pflegeleistung und Pflegeversicherung in einem
Zwei-Generationen Modell (Long-Term-Care and Long-Term-Care-Insurance in a Two-Generation
Model), 51 Finanzarchiv, 28-47.
Other References
Becker, Gary S. (1981), A Treatise on the Family, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York and London, The
Free Press.
Taylor, Michael (1976), Anarchy and Cooperation, London et al., John Wiley.
0790
LEGAL ERROR
Warren F. Schwartz
Professor of Law
Georgetown University Law Center
Copyright 1999 Warren F. Schwartz
Abstract
Important legal rules, most significantly the rule which makes an injurer liable
if she is negligent, require that in order to avoid liability an injurer must take
socially optimal care. Since the rule is cast in general terms and, consequently,
does not specify what the injurer must do to avoid liability, the judge or jury
deciding the case must determine what socially optimal care for the injurer was
in the circumstances in which the injury occurred. Legal error occurs when the
judge or jury set socially optimal care at too low or too high a level.
An injurer deciding what to do to minimize the sum of precaution costs and
liability costs takes the possibility of error into account. The possibility that too
little care will be required will tend to induce the injurer to take too little care.
The effect of the possibility that too much care will be required depends on the
causality rule which is applied. If an injurer who is held liable for failing to
take that care determined to be required is liable for all harm which occurs,
including that harm which would have occurred even if the required care had
been taken, the possibility that excessive care may be required will tend to make
an injurer take excessive care. If, however, an injurer is liable only for that
harm which would not have occurred if the required care had been taken, the
injurer will take optimal care even if liability will be imposed if more than
optimal care is not taken. It is difficult to draw any confident conclusions as
to the frequency with which each of the two causality rules are employed.
A second model is employed to analyze legal error. Under this model, an
injurer does not choose a level of care but makes a binary choice between
compliance and violation of the rule. Under this approach both errors in
holding injurers who have complied with the rule liable or in exonerating
injurers who have not complied with the rule will reduce the incidence of
compliance with the rule.
The practical usefulness of the analysis of legal error is greatly reduced by
the absence of evidence either as to the errors which actually occur or the effect
of those errors on the incentives of injurers.
JEL classification: K00
Keywords: Legal Error, Causality in Torts, Implementing a Negligence Rule,
Injurers Compliance Strategy
1029
1030 Legal Error 0790
1. Introduction
Legal rules imposing liability on injurers for the harm they do to victims are
often framed to require that injurers must exercise reasonable care (or some
equivalent term) to avoid causing harm to persons who may be injured by their
actions. Rules cast in this form do not specify what injurers must do to avoid
causing injury. The determination of what constituted reasonable care in the
circumstances which in fact obtained when the particular injurer caused harm
to the particular victim is made by the judge or jury empowered to decide the
claim for damages brought by the victim against the injurer.
A common example in the literature (Polinsky, 1989, p. 40) is the speed at
which an automobile is driven. Since the reasonable care standard does not
specify a speed at which automobiles must be driven in various circumstances
the judge or jury is required to decide what speed was reasonable. If the speed
at which the car was driven exceeds that determined to be reasonable the
injurer is liable to the victim. Legal error occurs when the judge or jury
incorrectly determines what speed was reasonable in the circumstances which
obtained when the injury occured.
2. Legal Error
The analysis of legal error focuses on the question of how the behavior of
injurers will be affected by the expectation that legal error will sometimes
occur. This analysis takes two forms, depending on what is posited as the
controlling rule with respect to the liability of an injurer for harm which would
have occurred even if the injurer had taken the care (in the example driven at
the speed) which she was legally obligated to take.
Calfee and Craswell and Goetz independently developed the analysis of the
effects of legal error on the assumption that an injurer who is held to have
failed to take the required level of care is liable for all harm which occurs,
including that harm which would have occurred even if the mandated care had
been taken. In the terms of our example, reducing speed to the socially optimal
level does not necessarily mean that all expected harm will be eliminated.
However, the analysis developed by Calfee and Craswell and Goetz proceeds
on the assumption that the liability of the injurer includes that harm which
would have occurred even if socially optimal care had been taken. Kahan and
Grady proceed from a different assumption. They posit that an injurer is liable
only for that harm which would have been prevented by taking the required
care. The difference in the assumption made by Calfee and Craswell and Goetz
on the one hand, and Kahan and Grady, on the other, leads to dramatically
different conclusions as to the effect of legal error on the incentives of injurers.
The Calfee and Craswell and Goetz analysis concludes that legal error impairs
the incentives of injurers in two ways, one (to return to the example) tending
to induce them to drive too fast and the other to induce them to drive too
slowly. The actual speed chosen by an injurer depends on the relative strength
of these two tendencies. Generally, unless the variance in the errors
determining socially optimal care is very great, the tendency to take too much
care will dominate and, in the terms of the example, the driver will go too
slowly. By contrast, Kahan and Grady conclude that legal error can only
operate to induce injurers to take too little care, in the terms of the example,
drive too fast.
To understand the impact of legal error on injurers it is necessary to analyze
how an injurer decides at what speed to drive. If there were no legal error, so
that legally mandated speed were always set equal to socially optimal speed, the
injurer, under the assumption underlying the analysis of Calfee and Crasswell
and Goetz, has a powerful incentive to drive at the socially optimal speed. If
1032 Legal Error 0790
she goes faster she becomes liable for all harm which occurs, including the
harm which would have occurred even if she had driven at the socially optimal
speed. And, she has no reason to go more slowly because it is unnecessary to
do so to avoid all liability for harm to victims.
Legal error changes this calculation by introducing two possibilities: (1)
Sometimes, even if the injurer drives at or below the socially optimal speed, she
will be held liable for all harm which occurs. (2) Sometimes, even if the injurer
exceeds the socially optimal speed, she will not be held liable.
To understand how these possibilities affect the choice of speed by the
injurer it is necessary to analyze the decision process of an injurer seeking to
adapt optimally to the possibility of legal error. The injurer wants to minimize
the sum of two costs : (1) the costs of care to avoid causing harm (slowing
down); and (2) expected liability. Expected liability, in turn, depends on the
expected harm and the probability that the injurer will be held liable and be
required to compensate victims for the harm done to them. Since expected
liability depends both on harm caused and the probability of being held liable,
and taking care (in the example, slowing down) affects both, the injurer
considers both in deciding how much care to take (how fast to go).
The injurer first calculates the probability of being held liable at various
speeds by anticipating the distribution of views as to what constitutes socially
optimal speed which will be held by the decision makers to whom a claim for
damages by a victim may be assigned. The probability of being held liable for
going at any particular speed depends on the proportion of potential decision
makers the injurer anticipates will conclude that socially optimal speed is less
than the speed at which the car is driven. This is, of course, an exercise in
prediction by the injurer with respect to the views that will be taken by judges
and juries. The analysis simply shows how the behavior of the injurer will vary
with her belief as to what the actual distribution of views will be.
The estimate of the injurer as to the probability of being held liable
associated with various speeds becomes a crucial component in the injurers
choice of the speed which is individually optimal because it will minimize the
sum of the costs of care (slowing down) and expected liability. The analysis of
the injurers choice of speed posits that the distribution of views of potential
decision makers is such that the two possibilities noted above exist: (1) there
is some probability that the injurer will be held liable even if the speed she
chooses is at or below the social optimum; and (2) there is some probability that
the injurer will not be held liable even if the speed she chooses exceeds the
social optimum. More generally, it is posited that the lower (higher) the speed
chosen the smaller (larger) is the probability of being held liable.
The first of these possibilities will tend to cause the injurer to choose too
low a speed (take too much care) and the second to choose too high a speed
(take too little care). The reason which induces the injurer to choose too low
0790 Legal Error 1033
a speed simply is that if there is some probability that liability will be imposed
even if the socially optimal speed is chosen, it is individually beneficial for the
injurer further to decrease her speed and, thus, reduce the probability of being
held liable. If the benefit, in the form of reducing the probability of being held
liable, exceeds the cost of additional slowing down it will be in the interest of
the injurer to do so. Since, under the Goetz and Calfee and Croswell analysis,
liability extends to all harm, whether or not it would have been prevented by
taking socially optimal care, reductions in the probability of being held liable
are very valuable and, as a result, the incentive to take excessive care very
strong.
The way in which the probability that the injurer may not be held liable
even if she drives faster than the social optimum causes the injurer to choose
a speed higher than the social optimum is somewhat more subtle. Decreasing
speed is privately beneficial to the injurer (the impact on the probability of
being held liable aside) if it decreases either the probability of causing harm or
the severity of that harm which does occur.This is so because, as noted above,
expected harm is one component of expected liability. In this respect the private
perspective of the injurer and the social perspective are identical.The
probability that the injurer will not be held liable even if she chooses a speed
which exceeds the social optimum, however, causes the private calculation of
the injurer to depart from the social optimum.This is so because the private
value of reducing expected harm is not the entire reduction but, rather, the
reduction multiplied by the probability of being held liable. Thus, if, for
example, a reduction in speed is evaluated as costing the injurer four dollars but
reducing expected harm by six it is socially desirable that the reduction in speed
occur. However, if there is only a 50 percent chance that the injurer will be
held liable the injurers private evaluation of the reduction in expected harm will
be only three dollars and the injuer will prefer not to reduce speed even if it is
socially desirable to do so.
Thus, in sum, legal error tends both to induce the driver to go too fast and
too slowly. Which effect will dominate depends on the distribution of views of
potential decisionmakers and the costs and benefits associated with different
speeds. In general, absent great variance in the views of potential
decisionmakers the tendency to go too slowly will dominate.
Kahan and Brady accept the conclusion of Calfee and Craswell and Goetz
with respect to the impact of legal error in the form of failing to hold an injurer
laible even though she has not taken optimal care.They agree that error of this
kind will tend to cause injurers to take too little care (drive too fast).They,
however, disagree with the conclusion that error in the form of holding injurers
laible even though they have taken socially optimal care will induce injurers to
take excessive care (drive too slowly).
The source of this disagreement is the difference between what is assumed
to be the liability of an injurer for harm which would have occurred even if the
injurer had taken the care she was legally required to take. Grady and Kahan
1034 Legal Error 0790
posit that the injurer is liable only for the harm which would not have occurred
if legally mandated care had been taken. They demonstrate that, on this
assumption, an injurer will not be induced to take more than socially optimal
care even if she anticipates that legal error in the form of setting the required
level above socially optimal care will occur.
Kahan chooses an example which makes his position both clear and
persuasive. He hypothesizes a case in which the issue is the height of a fence
which is required to be built to protect people from being hit by cricket balls.
He illustrates the difference between his position and that taken by Calfee and
Craswell and Goetz by asking whether a person who builds a fence which is
lower than is legally required would be liable for injury resulting from a ball
flying so high that it would have sailed over the legally required fence if it had
been in place. It seems quite plausible to answer no to this question since the
failure to build the fence has not caused the injury.
But Kahan argues that if this is so the anticipation of legal error in the form
of imposing liability on a person who builds a fence which is of socially optimal
height, on the erroneous premise that a higher fence is socially optimal, will not
induce the building of the higher fence. He reasons as follows. Suppose, for
example, that a socially optimal fence is ten feet high but decision makers
conclude that it is eleven feet high and, as a result, impose liability if the
socially optimal ten foot fence is built. Indeed, suppose that there is no
distribution of views but that this error is made by all decision makers. Kahan
concludes that even on this strong assumption the socially optimal ten foot
fence will be built.
He arrives at this conclusion by asking whether the cost of increasing the
size of the fence from ten feet to eleven feet will, from the perspective of the
person deciding how high a fence to build, be justified by the associated
reduction in expected liability. The essential premise underlying his answer to
this question is that if the legally mandated eleven-foot fence is not built,
liability is limited to harm resulting from balls which would not have gone over
it. If the socially optimal ten-foot fence is built it will block all balls flying no
higher than ten feet. Thus the benefit achieved by increasing the size of the
fence from ten feet to eleven feet is to avoid liability for those balls which
would have gone over a ten-foot fence but be blocked by an eleven-foot fence.
Since it is assumed that the ten-foot fence is socially optimal the cost of
increasing the size of the fence above ten feet must exceed the associated
reduction in liability. As a result, the ten-foot, socially-optimal fence, and not
the erroneously mandated eleven-foot fence, will be built.
0790 Legal Error 1035
It is not clear the extent to which the Calfee and Craswell and Goetz analysis,
or that of Grady and Kahan, better captures the consquences of legal error. In
principle, the account of Grady and Kahan appears to be persuasive. It may be,
however, that because application of this approach requires a determination of
the question of what harm would have occured even if required care had been
taken, that the Calfee and Craswell and Goetz approach is taken when this
question is particularly difficult to answer.
In the example used by Kahan it is easy to separate the harm which would
have been prevented if different levels of care had been taken from that which
would have occurred anyway. A ball flying so high that it would have gone
over a fence of specified height is an easy concept to understand and apply.
The case of optimal speed for a car, and many others, are much more
problematic. Suppose that a person is hit by a driver going faster than the
required speed. It is true, and explicitly assumed in the standard analysis, that
there will be some probability that the person would have been injured even if
the driver had been going at or below the required speed. Taking this
probability into account requires some means for distinguishing the harm
which would have been prevented from the harm which would have occurred,
if the required care had been taken. Moreover, the uncertainty as to exactly
which victims would not have been harmed would require some probablistic
method of awarding damages such as has been proposed with respect to cases
where uncertainty of damages is present (Shavell, 1987, p. 115).
All of this may simply be too complicated to be worth dealing with. In
principle, the issue of what harm would have occurred to the particular plaintiff
even if required care had been taken is present in all cases. Often, however, the
issue is ignored and the injurer is held liable for all harm which occurs when
she fails to take the care required by the governing rule. Thus the approach of
Grady and Kahan may reflect actual practice when it is feasible to determine
what harm would have occurred even if the required care had been taken and
the approach of Calfee and Craswell and Goetz taken when it is not feasible to
do so.
victim will only sue if the expected recovery exceeds the cost of suing. Putting
the possibility of strategic exploitation of the costliness of defense and
uncertainty of outcome aside, the expected value of suing depends on the
amount of damages which it is anticipated will be recovered and the probability
of recovering. Although taking strategic possibilities into account complicates
the analysis, it remains true that the probability of success is an important
determinant of the value of a suit. Thus, if the victim-plaintiffs probability of
success can be reduced, so, too, can the expected value of the action. If the
expected value of the action can be reduced to an amount less than the costs of
the suit, the suit will not be brought.
Since the probability of a plaintiff succeeding varies with the care taken (the
speed at which the car is driven) the injurer can reduce her expected liability
by choosing a level of care which reduces victims chances of success to so low
a level that the expected value of suing becomes less than the cost of suing. As
a result, increasing care (going more slowly) is individually beneficial for an
injurer in that not only can it make it less likely that those victims who do sue
will recover, but also it reduces the number of victims who have a sufficiently
high chance of prevailing that they will sue.
amount which should be done to avoid causing harm. The individual optimum
is determined by the effectiveness of care in reducing expected harm and the
probability of being held liable associated with different levels of care. In this
framework overdeterrence means that individuals take excessive care and
underdeterrence that individuals take too little care. By contrast, under the
view which conceives of the compliance choice as a binary one, there can be no
overdeterrence and underdeterrence which means that some people choose to
violate rather than comply.
The essential difference between the two approaches derives from two
interrelated consequences of positing the compliance choice as a binary one: (1)
the person making a compliance choice cannot adapt her behavior to the legal
system by taking into account the variations in the probability of being held
liable associated with doing more or less to avoid the harm which the legal rule
is designed to prevent. (2) Under the binary approach error consists of imposing
liability on the innocent or convicting the guilty. There is no place in the
analysis for different magnitudes of error. Under the continuous approach,
however, legal error consists of arriving at a standard which departs from the
social optimum. There are, consequently, more or less egregious errors,
depending on how far the standard departs from the social optimum.
Moreover, the magnitude and frequency of these errors matter because the
person making a compliance choice takes them into account in choosing how
much will be done to avoid causing the harm which the legal rule is designed
to prevent. It is in this process of adaptation that the incentive to overcomply
arises. By doing more than is socially optimal the probability of being held
liable can be reduced. This possibility is not taken into account when the
compliance choice is posited as a binary one.
Ben-Shahar, Omri (1995), Informed Courts, Uninformed Individual and the Economics of Judicial
Hindsight, 151 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 613-630.
Bouckaert, Boudewijn and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (1995), Mistake of Law and the Economics of Legal
Information, in Bouckaert, Boudewijn and De Geest, Gerrit (eds), Essays in Law and Economics
0790 Legal Error 1039
II: Contract Law, Regulation, and Reflections on Law and Economics, Antwerpen, Maklu, 217-245.
Bundy, Stephen M. (1994), Valuing Accuracy: Filling out the Framework: Comment, 23 Journal of
Legal Studies, 411-433.
Calfee, John E. and Craswell, Richard (1984), Some Effects of Uncertainty on Compliance with Legal
Standards, 70 Virginia Law Review, 965-1003.
Craswell, Richard and Calfee, John E. (1986), Deterrence and Uncertain Legal Standards, 2 Journal
of Law, Economics, and Organization, 279-303.
Goetz, Charles J. (1984), Law and Economics: Cases and Materials, St. Paul, West Publishing.
Good, I.J. and Tullock, Gordon (1984), Judicial Errors and a Proposal for Reform, 13 Journal of
Legal Studies, 289-298.
Grady, Mark F. (1988),Discontinuities and Information Burdens: Review of the Economic Structure
or Tort Law by William M. Landes and Richard A. Posner, 56 George Washington Law Review,
658-pp.
Grady, Mark F. (1989), Untaken Precautions, 18 Journal of Legal Studies, 139-156.
Graham, John D. and Wiener, Jonathan Baert (1995), Risk vs. Risk: Tradeoffs in Protecting Health
and the Environment, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Gravelle, Hugh S.E. (1983), Judicial Review and Public Firms, 3 International Review of Law and
Economics, 187-205.
Hylton, Keith N. (1990), Costly Litigation and Legal Error under Negligence, 6 Journal of Law,
Economics, and Organization, 433-452.
Kahan, Marcel (1989), Causation and Incentives to Take Care under the Negligence Rule,18 Journal
of Legal Studies, 427-447.
Kaplow, Louis (1994a), The Value of Accuracy in Adjudication: An Economic Analysis, 23 Journal
of Legal Studies, 307-401.
Kaplow, Louis (1994b), Optimal Insurance Contracts when Establishing the Amount of Loss is
Costly, 19 Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance, 139-152.
Kaplow, Louis and Shavell, Steven (1994), Accuracy in the Determination of Liability, 37 Journal
of Law and Economics, 1-15.
Kaplow, Louis and Shavell, Steven (1996), Accuracy in the Assessment of Damages, 39 Journal of
Law and Economics, 191-209.
Katz, Avery and Beckner, Clinton F., III (1995), The Incentive Effects of Litigation Fee Shifting when
Legal Standards are Uncertain, 15 International Review of Law and Economics, 205-224.
Kobayashi, Bruce H. and Lott, John R., Jr (1992), Low Probability-High Penalty Enforcement
Strategies and the Efficient Operation of the Plea Bargaining System, 12 International Review
of Law and Economics, 69-77.
MacKaay, Ejan (1979), Les Notions Floues ou lconomie de lImprcision (Fuzzy Concepts or the
Economics of Imprecision), 12 Langages, 33-50.
MacKaay, Ejan (1980), Le Nozione Fluide Ovvero lEconomia DellImprecisione (Fuzzy Concepts
or the Economics of Imprecision), Informatica e Diritto, 253-274.
Ortiz, Daniel R. (1994), Neoactuarialism: Comment, 23 Journal of Legal Studies, 403-409.
Png, Ivan Paak-Liang (1986), Optimal Subsidies and Damages in the Presence of Judicial Error, 6
International Review of Law and Economics, 101-105.
1040 Legal Error 0790
Polinsky, A. Mitchell (1989), An Introduction to Law and Economics (2nd edn), Boston, Little
Brown.
Polinsky, A. Mitchell and Shavell, Steven (1989), Legal Error, Litigation, and the Incentive to Obey
the Law, 5 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 99-108.
Rasmusen, Eric (1995), Predictable and Unpredictable Error in Tort Awards: The Effect of Plaintiff
Self Selection and Signaling, 15(3) International Review of Law and Economics, 323-345.
Shavell, Steven (1987), Economic Analysis of Accident Law, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press.
Stith, Kate (1990), The Risk of Legal Error in Criminal Cases: Some Consequences of the Asymmetry
in the Right to Appeal, 57 University of Chicago Law Review, 1-61.
0800
NORMS AND VALUES IN LAW AND
ECONOMICS
Denis J. Brion
Professor of Law
Washington and Lee University - School of Law
Copyright 1999 Dennis Brion
Abstract
1. Definitions
Economics is the study of how people and society end up choosing, with or
without the use of money, to employ scarce resources that could have alternative
uses, to produce various commodities and distribute them for consumption, now
or in the future, among various persons and groups in society. It analyzes the c o s t s
and benefits of improving patterns of resource allocation. (Samuelson, 1976, p. 3)
This definition proceeds from the assumption that resources are scarce,
establishes the analytical focus as the allocation of resources to productive
activities and the distribution of wealth among the members of society, and
adopts efficiency in resource allocation as a fundamental criterion of
evaluation.
Law might be defined in a material sense as the complex of
constitutional provisions, bodies of legislative enactments, such as codes and
statutes, and, particularly in common law systems structured with an
independent judiciary, the continually developing body of judicial doctrine.
1041
1042 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 0800
Functionally, the law defines the scope, powers and limitations of such
elements of governance as the obligatory institutions of public agencies and
defines the permissible ambit of relations among legal persons and between
legal persons and entities of governance.
Proceeding from these definitions, law and economics is the use of the
analytical techniques and values of economic analysis either for explanation
or for prescription. In the realm of explanation, it is the enterprise of
developing models that, in economic terms, accounts for the phenomena of
human activity - the ongoing decisions and actions of such legal institutions
as legislative bodies and the judicial process, and such practices as the
legally permissible interactions of individuals. In the realm of prescription,
law and economics discourse advocates the application of economic
principles in the decision making of legal institutions, both substantively and
procedurally, and the use of economic principles in shaping the permissible
scope of interactions among legal persons.
The discussion which follows will first describe the values that underlie the
explanatory discourse of law and economics and then describe the values
that underlie prescriptive discourse. This discussion will reveal that law and
economics discourse is a substantially heterogeneous enterprise. And it is
heterogeneous because the values that underlie it do not resolve into a
unified, mutually consistent whole (Rakoff, 1996; Trebilcock, 1993).
2. Explanatory Discourse
3. Prescriptive Discourse
valuing user (Goetz and Scott, 1977). In the law of property, least cost
avoider analysis justifies shifting entitlements to the more productive user
(Polinsky, 1989; Posner, 1998).
This element of Chicago School analysis is based on hierarchical values.
The paramount criterion of evaluation is aggregate societal wealth.
Collective institutions, both private and public, have a substantial role in
directing resources toward wealth-producing activities. Entitlements are not
protected from erosion or transfer in order to shift resources to more
productive users, thereby subordinating individual rights to the social good.
A substantial spread in the distribution of power and wealth is acceptable in
order to achieve the maximization of aggregate wealth (Riley, 1989;
Thompson et al., 1990).
A third mainstream approach, identified with Yale Law School, also
rejects the concept of natural or inherent rights (Mercuro and Medema,
1997, pp. 79-83; Malloy, 1990, pp. 69-75) Although this approach accords a
substantial role to both public and private collective institutions, public
institutions have a paramount role. These institutions provide a milieu of
discourse by which the paramount values of society are determined, and
have a substantial role in directing economic and social arrangements to
advance the realization of these values (Ackerman, 1980, 1984;
Rose-Ackerman, 1992). Because these ends are collective rather than
individualistic in nature, then this approach, like the second branch of
Chicago School analysis, is substantially hierarchical in character. This
approach, however, is unlike the hierarchical branch of Chicago School
analysis in two respects. It tends to prefer more qualitative utility concepts of
social welfare over more quantitative measures of aggregate wealth
(Brownsword, 1997). And it treats the pattern of the distribution of wealth as
a highly relevant consideration in the determination of social welfare
(Rose-Ackerman, 1985).
By way of summary, the mainstream of law and economics prescriptive
discourse is dominated by approaches that are grounded either in
individualist values or in hierarchical values. These values are, however,
mutually inconsistent. Thus, mainstream discourse is properly characterized
more as a debate than as a collective enterprise refining a unitary social
scientific model under the aegis of a monolithic set of values.
As this discourse has matured, other voices, based on other values, have
entered the debate. A prominent alternative is the discourse of critical legal
studies, which itself is considerably heterogeneous (Unger, 1986; Kelman,
1987). Moreover, it has tended to be reactive in nature, in the sense of
seeking to reveal, and to criticize, the tendency of mainstream academic
discourse and judicial doctrine to advance hierarchical values behind a
rhetoric of individual values. Thus, there has been a tendency in a
0800 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 1047
4. Mutual Critique
does not accurately capture the views expressed by Professors Kaldor and
Hicks, who took the position that wealth distribution is a relevant
consideration for the political decision maker, and that, on the assumption of
declining marginal utility in consumption, the principle of utility
maximization entails a presumption of relative equality in the distribution of
wealth, offset by a degree of inequality in order to provide an incentive to
produce (Kaldor, 1939).
An alternative approach to the dominant, neoclassic model
conceptualizes economic action in dynamic terms, tending toward
disequilibrium as technology, resource endowments, and perceptions of
utility change (Klein, 1977; Malloy, 1994). Producers can be seen as
possessing the power to create and manipulate demand, and not simply react
to demand (Bartlett, 1973), and the ultimate productive resource is human
intelligence and human inventiveness (Schultz, 1981; Reich, 1983, 1991).
Because human capacity is susceptible to enhancement by the investment of
maintenance and education, then wealth maximization can be understood
more in terms of a dynamic process of investment in human capital than in
the efficient allocation of material resources.
5. Summary
By way of summary, a rich array of values underlies the discourse of law and
economics. Descriptive models of economic action and the working of the
legal and political processes offer a mix of approaches to the explanation of
the phenomena of economic action. The dominant discourse presents models
that are numerate in character and that adopt the equilibrium approach of
neoclassic microeconomics. A minor theme in this discourse presents
models that are more qualitative in character and that adopt an alternative
dynamic approach.
The array of values that underlies prescriptive discourse is similarly
heterogeneous. The dominant discourse offers approaches based on
competing individualist and hierarchical values. Minor themes in this
discourse offer approaches based on the values of communality and
1052 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 0800
B. Theory
6. Theory
Related to the substance of the values that underlie law and economics
discourse and the heterogeneity of these values is the matter of the cause of
this heterogeneity - the question whether this conflict might be a
consequence of the particular natures of the categories of economics and of
law, or the inevitable nature of a discourse that takes place across the
boundary between distinct areas of intellectual endeavor or, perhaps, the
particular way in which this discourse has proceeded.
That this heterogeneity of values falls into a particular pattern in law and
economics discourse is replicated in other areas of discourse. Jurisprudential
theories can be understood as falling into a pattern of hierarchical positivism
and formalism, individualistic classical law, natural law, and communitarian
Marxist theory (Barry, 1988; Epstein, 1988; Peller, 1988). On a more
particular level, judicial doctrine in United States courts, rather than
developing, as the formalist account might predict, toward an ever more
complete structure of rules and principles, can be mapped onto this same
pattern of underlying values. This pattern can be seen in the different
conceptualizations of ownership of land that implicitly determine the
outcomes in particular cases - ownership as sole and despotic dominion
(Blackstone, 1765/69:2), a vested entitlement of the individual protected
from State interference [Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260 U.S. 393
(1922)]; ownership as the nexus by which the individual is lodged in a
hierarchical order, in which the State holds the power to impose substantial
limits on the right to use [Penn Central Transp. Co. v. City of New York,
438 U.S. 104 (1978)]; ownership as a right subordinate to the natural biotic
webs that define the physical and biological order of the natural environment
[Just v. Marinette County, 201 N.W.2d 761 (Wis. 1972)]; and ownership as
the nexus by which the individual is lodged in a local community, in which
the always emergent matrix of communal values determines the limits on
individual use [Goldblatt v. Town of Hempstead, 369 U.S. 590 (1962)]. In
the criminal law as well, doctrine can be categorized in terms of the
conceptualization of criminality - subjective criminality, harmful
consequences and manifest criminality (Fletcher, 1978), underlain by,
respectively, individualist, hierarchical, and communitarian values.
The political ideologies manifested in the deliberations and actions of
legislative bodies and in public political discourse can be mapped onto a
0800 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 1053
The study of who gets what and why, unlike the study of plants or planets,
cannot help being an ideologically charged undertaking. Despite the laborious
techniques and scientific pretension, most brands of economics are covertly
ideological. Marxian economics, with its labor theory of value, assumes the
inevitability of class conflict, and hence the necessity of class struggle,
Keynesianism, with its conviction that industrial capitalism is systematically
unstable, offers an equally scientific rationale for government intervention.
Neoclassical economics, with its reliance on the efficiency of markets, is a
lavishly embroidered brief for laissez-faire. (Kuttner, 1985)
C. Debate
7. Debate
A final matter is the function of values in law and economics discourse. Not
only are these values heterogeneous in character but also they can be
advanced for a heterogeneity of purposes. Values can serve as the focus of
theoretical debate over whether a unifying set of values can emerge within a
particular culture. Such a debate would conform to the methods of
systematic philosophy and its foundationalist project (Rorty, 1979).
Alternatively, values can provide the means for refining a particular
conceptualization of economic action in legal processes. Such an enterprise
would conform to the methods of normal science (Kuhn, 1970).
Additionally, values provide the deep basis for advocacy - the enterprise of
achieving consensus, whether in academic discourse, political discourse or
discourse in the judicial process. Finally, values are a necessary ingredient to
the quasi-foundationalist enterprise of the pragmatic method, in which
discourse is directed toward the cash value of employing one or another set
of values in order to solve a particular problem in the arena of human action
(Cotter, 1996; James, 1987).
Adams, Michael (1991), Normen, Standards, Rechte (Norms, Standards, Rights), Juristenzeitung,
941-955.
Adams, Michael (1994), Rechte und Normen als Standards, in Tietzel, M. (ed.), Homo
Oeconomicus, XI (3), konomik der Standardisierung, 501-553.
Adelstein, Richard P. (1989), Islands of Conscious Power: Louis D. Brandeis and the Modern
Corporation, 63 Business History Review, 614-656.
Adelstein, Richard P. (1991), Deciding for Bigness: Constitutional Choice and the Growth of
Firms, 2(1) Constitutional Political Economy, 7-30.
Anderson, Elizabeth (1993), Value in Ethics and Economics, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press.
Armentano, Dominick T. (1987), Comment: Efficiency, Liberty, and Antitrust Policy, in Dorn,
James A. and Manne, Henry G. (eds), Economic Liberties and the Judiciary, Fairfax, George
Mason University Press, 309-316.
Arup, Christopher (1982), Accounting for the Social Costs of Technology Through the Legal
Process, in Cranston, Ross and Schick, Anne (eds), Law and Economics, Canberra, Australian
National University, 25-38.
Ault, David E. and Rutman, Gilbert L. (1985), Comment (on Bilmes Paper), 7 Research in Law
and Economics, 149-156.
Baker, C. Edwin (1974), Utility and Rights: Two Justifications for State Action Increasing
Inequality, 84 Yale Law Journal, 39-59.
Baker, C. Edwin (1975), The Ideology of the Economic Analysis of Law, 5 Philosophy and
Public Affairs, 3-48.
Baker, C. Edwin (1980), Starting Points in the Economic Analysis of Law, 8 Hofstra Law Review,
939-972.
Bandow, Doug (1987), The Conservative Judicial Agenda: A Critique, in Dorn, James A. and
Manne, Henry G. (eds), Economic Liberties and the Judiciary, Fairfax, George Mason
University Press, 257-271.
Barry, Norman P. (1988), The Classical Theory of Law, 73 Cornell Law Review, 283-291.
Bartlett, Randall (1973), The Economic Foundations of Political Power, New York, NY, Free
Press.
Bebchuk, Lucian Arye (1980), The Pursuit of a Bigger Pie: Can Everyone Expect a Bigger Slice?,
8 Hofstra Law Review, 671-709.
Benson, Bruce L. (1988), Legal Evolution in Primitive Societies, 144 Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics, 772-788.
Benson, Bruce L. (1989), Enforcement of Private Property Rights in Primitive Societies: Law
Without Government, 9 Journal of Libertarian Studies, 1-26.
Benson, Bruce L. (1989), The Spontaneous Evolution of Commercial Law, 55 Southern
Economic Journal, 644-661.
Benson, Bruce L. (1990), Customary Law with Private Means of Resolving Disputes and
Dispensing Justice: A Description of a Modern System of Law and Order Without State
Coercion, 9 Journal of Libertarian Studies, 25-42. Reprinted as Law and Order Without
State Coercion, in Veljanovski, Cento (ed.), Regulation, Regulators and the Market, 1991,
London, Institute of Economic Affairs, 159-179.
Benson, Bruce L. (1991a), Reciprocal Exchange as the Basis for Recognition of Law: Examples
from American History, 10 Journal of Libertarian Studies, 53-82.
1056 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 0800
Benson, Bruce L. (1991b), An Evolutionary Contractarian View of Primitive Law: The Institutions
and Incentives Arising Under Customary American Indian Law, 5 Review of Austrian
Economics, 65-89.
Benson, Bruce L. (1992), The Evolution of Values and Institutions in a Free Society: The
Under-Pinnings of a Market Economy, 5 International Journal on the Unity of Sciences,
411-442. Reprinted in Radnitzky, Gerard and Bouillon, Hardy (eds), Values and the Social
Order Vol.I, Aldershot, Avebury, 87-125.
Benson, Bruce L. (1993), The Impetus for Recognizing Private Property and Adopting Ethical
Behavior in a Market Economy: Natural Law, Government Law, or Evolving Self-Interest, 6
Review of Austrian Economics, 43-80.
Benson, Bruce L. (1994a), Legal Philosophy, in Boettke, Peter J. (ed.), The Elgar Companion to
Austrian Economics, London, Edward Elgar, 270-275.
Benson, Bruce L. (1994b), Emerging from the Hobbesian Jungle: Might Takes and Makes Rights,
5 Constitutional Political Economy, 129-158. Translated into Spanish and republished (1995),
Las Instituciones y Los Derechos de Propiedad al Emerger de la Jungla Hobbesiana: La
Fuerza Quita los Reprinted Derechos y los Crea Libertas, 12, 35-75.
Bilmes, Jack (1985a), Rejoinder to Ault and Rutmans Comment, 7 Research in Law and
Economics, 157-158.
Bilmes, Jack (1985b), Freedom and Regulation: An Anthropological Critique of Free Market
Ideology, 7 Research in Law and Economics, 123-147.
Black, Duncan (1958), The Theory of Committees and Elections, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press.
Blackstone, William (1765/1769), 2. Commentaries on the Law of England. (Reprinted), Buffalo,
William S, Hein & Co. (1992).
Bloustein, E.J. (1978), Privacy is Dear at any Price: A Response to Professor Posners Economic
Theory, 12 Georgia Law Review, 421-495.
Blum, Walter J. and Kalven, Harry, Jr (1967), The Empty Cabinet of Dr. Calabresi: Auto
Accidents and General Deterrence, 34 University of Chicago Law Review, 239-273.
Reprinted in Rabin, Robert L. (ed.) (1983), Perspectives on Tort Law, Boston, Little Brown,
178-190.
Bouckaert, Boudewijn (1984), Efficintie of Rechtvaardigheid: het Onvermijdelijk Dilemma?
(Efficiency or Justice: the Unavoidable Dilemma?), 29 Tijdschrift voor Sociale
Wetenschappen, 101-133.
Bovens, M.A.P. and Witteveen, W.J. (1987), Bruce Ackerman over Sociale Rechtvaardigheid, de
rol van de Rechter en Law and Economics (Bruce Ackerman on Social Justice, the Role of
the Judiciary and Law and Economics), Staatkundig Jaarboek, Ars Aequi Libri, 255-278.
Bowers, James W. (1991), Whither What Hits the Fan? Murphys Law, Bankruptcy Theory, and
the Elementary Economics of Loss Distribution, 26 Georgia Law Review, 27-83.
Brennan, Geoffrey and Buchanan, James M. (1981), The Normative Purpose of Economic
Science: Rediscovery of an Eighteenth Century Method, 1 International Review of Law and
Economics, 155-166.
Brennan, Geoffrey and Buchanan, James M. (1988), Is Public Choice Immoral? the Case for the
Nobel Lie, 74 Virginia Law Review, 179-189.
0800 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 1057
Breyer, Stephen G. (1987), Economics and Judging: An Afterword on Cooter and Wald, 50(4)
Law and Contemporary Problems, 245-252.
Brietzke, Paul H. (1997), How and Why the Marketplace of Ideas Fails, 31 Valparaiso
University Law Review, 951-969.
Bromley, Daniel W. (1990), The Ideology of Efficiency: Searching for a Theory of Policy
Analysis, 19 Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 86-107.
Brown, John Prather (1973), Toward an Economic Theory of Liability, 2 Journal of Legal
Studies, 323-349.
Brownsword, Roger (1997), Contract Law, Co-operation, and Good Faith: The Move from Static
to Dynamic Market-Individualism, in Deakin, Simon and Michie, Jonathan (eds), Contracts,
Co-operation and Competition: Studies in Economics, Management and Law, Oxford,
Oxford University Press, 255-284.
Buchanan, James M. (1962), The Relevance of Pareto Optimality, 6 Journal of Conflict
Resolution, 341-354.
Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon (1962), The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations
of Constitutional Democracy, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press.
Buxbaum, Hertig and Hirsch, Hopt (eds), European Economic and Business Law, Legal and
Economic Analyses on Integration and Harmonization, Berlin, Walter De Gruyter, 401 p.
Calabresi, Guido (1970), The Cost of Accidents: A Legal and Economic Analysis, New Haven,
CT, Yale University Press.
Calabresi, Guido (1980), An Exchange about Law and Economics: A Letter to Ronald Dworkin, 8
Hofstra Law Review, 553-562.
Calabresi, Guido and Melamed, A. Douglas (1972), Property Rules, Liability Rules, and
Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral, 85 Harvard Law Review, 1089-1128.
Calsamiglia, Albert (1988), Justicia, Eficiencia y Derecho (Equity, Efficiency and the Law), 1
Revista del Centro de Estudios Constitucionales, 327 ff.
Campbell, David (1996), The Relational Constitution of the Discrete Contract, in Campbell,
David and Vincent-Jones, Peter (eds), Contract and Economic Organisation: Socio-legal
Initiatives, Aldershot, Dartmouth, 40-66.
Campbell, David (1997), The Relational Constitution of Contract and the Limits of Economics:
Kenneth Arrow on the Social Background of Markets, in Deakin, Simon and Michie, Jonathan
(eds), Contracts, Co-operation and Competition: Studies in Economics, Management and
Law, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 529-596.
Campbell, David and Harris, Donald R. (1993), Flexibility in Long-term Contractual
Relationships: The Role of Co-operation, 20 Journal of Law and Society, 166-191.
Cass, Ronald A. (1987), Coping with Life, Law, and Markets: A Comment on Posner and the
Law-and-Economics Debate, 67 Boston University Law Review, 73-97.
Centi, Jean-Pierre (1987), Quel Critre dEfficience pour lAnalyse Economique du Droit (Which
Efficiency Criterion for Economic Analysis of Law), 2 Revue de la Recherche Juridique.
Chami, Ralph and Fischer, Jeffrey (1995), Community Banking, Monitoring and the Clinton Plan,
14 Cato Journal, 493-508.
Chapman, Bruce (1979), Law, Morality and the Logic of Choice: An Economists View, 29
University of Toronto Law Journal, 114-137.
1058 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 0800
Chapman, Bruce (1982), Individual Rights and Collective Rationality: Some Implications for
Economic Analysis of Law, 10 Hofstra Law Review, 455-481.
Chapman, Bruce (1983), Rights as Constraints: Nozick vs Sen, 15 Theory and Decision, 1-10.
Chapman, Bruce (1987), Raising Johnny to be Good: A Problematic Case for Economic Analysis
of Law, 34 University of Toronto Law Journal, 358-376.
Chapman, Bruce and Quinn, J.J. (1982), Efficiency, Liberty and Equality: Three Ethical
Justifications for Regulatory Reform, 20 Osgoode Hall Law Journal, 512-535.
Coase, Ronald H. (1960), The Problem of Social Cost, 3 Journal of Law and Economics, 1-44.
Coase, Ronald H. (1988), The Firm, The Market, and the Law, Chicago, University of Chicago
Press.
Cohen, Jane Maslow (1987), Posnerism, Pluralism, Pessimism, 67 Boston University Law
Review, 105-175.
Coleman, Jules L. (1980a), Efficiency, Utility, and Wealth Maximization, 8 Hofstra Law Review,
509-551.
Coleman, Jules L. (1980b), Efficiency, Exchange and Auction: Philosophic Aspects of the
Economic Approach to Law, 68 California Law Review, 221-249.
Coleman, Jules L. (1982a), The Economic Analysis of Law, in Pennock, J. Roland and Chapman,
John W. (eds), Nomos XXIV: Ethics, Economics and the Law, New York, New York
University Press, 83-103.
Coleman, Jules L. (1982b), Corrective Justice and Wrongful Gain, 11 Journal of Legal Studies,
421-440.
Coleman, Jules L. (1984), Economics and the Law: A Critical Review of the Foundations of the
Economic Approach to Law, 94 Ethics, 649-679.
Coleman, James S. (1987), Norms as Social Capital, in Radnitzky, Gerard and Bernholz, Peter
(eds), Economic Imperialism: The Economic Approach Applied Outside the Field of
Economics, New York, Paragon House, 133-155.
Coleman, Jules L. (1988), Markets, Morals and the Law, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press,
393 p.
Coleman, Jules L. and Kraus, Jody S. (1986), Rethinking the Theory of Legal Rights, 95 Yale
Law Journal, 1335-1371.
Commons, John R. (1932), The Problem of Correlating Law, Economics and Ethics, 8 Wisconsin
Law Review, 3-26.
Cooter, Robert D. (1983), Justice and Mathematics: Two Simple Ideas, in Skurski, Roger B. (ed.),
New Directions in Economic Justice, Notre Dame Press.
Cooter, Robert D. (1984), Prices and Sanctions, 84 Columbia Law Review, 1523-1560.
Cooter, Robert D. (1987a), Torts As the Union of Liberty and Efficiency: An Essay on Causation,
63 Chicago-Kent Law Review, 522-551.
Cooter, Robert D. (1987b), Liberty, Efficiency, and Law, 50 Law and Contemporary Problems,
141-163.
Cooter, Robert D. (1987c), Justice At the Confluence of Law and Economics, 1 Social Justice
Research, 67 ff.
Cooter, Robert D. (1989), The Best Right Laws: Value Foundations of the Economic Analysis of
Law, 64 Notre Dame Law Review, 817-837. Reprinted in Levit, Nancy and Hayman, Robert
(eds) (1994), Jurisprudence: Contemporary Readings, Problems, and Narratives, St Paul,
MN, West Publishing Co., West.
0800 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 1059
Cooter, Robert D. (1989), Rawlss Lexical Orderings are Good Economics, 5 Economics and
Philosophy, 47 ff.
Cooter, Robert D. (1990), Merit Goods: Some Thoughts on the Unthinkable, in Brennan, Geoffrey
and Walsh, Cliff (eds), Rationality, Individualism, and Public Policy, Canberra, Centre for
Research in Federal Financial Relations, 186-192.
Cooter, Robert D. (1994), Structural Adjudication and the New Law Merchant: A Model of
Decentralized Law, 14 International Review of Law and Economics, 215-231. Reprinted
under the title, The Structural Approach to Decentralizing Law: A Theory of Games and
Norms, in a book edited by Gerard Hertig.
Cooter, Robert D. (1996), Punitive Damages, in Gray, Christopher B. (ed.), Philosophy of Law:
An Encyclopedia, New York, Garland Inc.
Cooter, Robert D. and Gordley, James (1994), The Cultural Case for Inequality: An Economic
Model of Merit Goods Based on Aristotelian Ideas of Akrasia and Distributive Justice, in
Cowan, Robin and Rizzo, Mario J. (eds), Profits and Moralilty, Chicago, University of
Chicago Press, 150-175.
Cooter, Robert D. and Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1980), Can Litigation Improve the Law Without the
Help of Judges?, 9 Journal of Legal Studies, 139-163.
Cooter, Robert D. and Rappoport, Peter (1984), Were the Ordinalists Wrong About Welfare
Economics?, 22 Journal of Economic Literature, 507 ff. Reprinted in Blaug, Mark (ed.),
Pioneers in Economics Section IV, Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, forthcoming.
Cooter, Robert and Ulen, Thomas S. (1997), Law and Economics, 2nd edn, Reading, MA,
Addison-Wesley.
Cordato, Roy E. (1992), Welfare Economics and Externalities in an Open Ended Universe: A
Modern Austrian Perspective, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Cosentino, Fabrizio (1988), Autonomia Privata e Paternalismo del Legislatore nella Prospettiva
dellAnalisi Economica del Diritto (Individual Autonomy and the Paternalism of the Legislator:
An EAL Perspective), Rivista Critica del Diritto Privato, 473-511.
Cotter, Thomas F. (1996), Legal Pragmatism and the Law and Economics Movement, 84
Georgetown Law Journal, 2071-2141.
Craswell, Richard (1993), On the Uses of Trust, 36 Journal of Law and Economics, 487-500.
Dahl, Robert A. (1985), A Preface to Economic Democracy, Berkeley, University of California
Press.
Dau-Schmidt, Kenneth G. (1984), Sentencing Antitrust Offenders: Reconciling Economic Theory
with Legal Theory, 9 Wm. Mitchell Law Review, 75 ff.
Dau-Schmidt, Kenneth G. (1990), An Economic Analysis of the Criminal Law as a Preference
Shaping Policy, Duke Law Journal, 1-38.
Dau-Schmidt, Kenneth G. (1995), Legal Prohibitions as More Than Prices: The Economic
Analysis of Preference Shaping Policies in the Law, in Malloy, Robin P. and Braun,
Christopher K. (eds), Law and Economics: New and Critical Perspectives, New York, Peter
Lang, 153 ff.
De Beus, J.W. (1989), Markt, Democratie en Vrijheid (Market, Democracy and Liberty), Zwolle,
Tjeenk Willink, 682 p.
De Geest, Gerrit (1990), Public Choice, Mensbeeld en Ideologie (Public Choice, Model of Man
and Ideology), 19 Rechtsfilosofie en Rechtstheorie, 109-122.
1060 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 0800
Englard, Izhak (1982), The Failure of Economic Justice, 45 Harvard Law Review, 1162-1178.
Epstein, Richard A. (1985), Takings: Private Property and the Power of Eminent Domain,
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Epstein, Richard A. (1988), The Classical Legal Tradition, 73 Cornell Law Review, 292-299.
Epstein, Richard A. (1995), Simple Rules for a Complex World, Cambridge, MA, Harvard
University Press.
Eschenburg, Rolf (1978), Vertragstheoretisches Denken in der konomie (Contractual Theory in
Economics), 23 Hamburger Jahrbuch fr Wirtschaft und Gesellschaftspolitik, 221-236.
Farber, Daniel A. (1989), Review Essay: Environmentalism, Economics and the Public Interest,
41 Stanford Law Review, 1021-1043.
Farber, Daniel A. and Frickey, Philip P. (1991), Law and Public Choice: A Critical Introduction,
Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Feinman, Jay M. (1988), Practical Legal Studies and Critical Legal Studies, 87(3) Michigan Law
Review, 724-731.
Ferber, Marianne A. and Nelson, Julie A. (eds) (1993), Beyond Economic Man: Feminist Theory
and Economics, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Fletcher, George P. (1972), Fairness and Utility in Tort Theory, 85 Harvard Law Review,
537-573. Reprinted in Rabin, Robert L. (ed.) (1983), Perspectives on Tort Law, Boston, Little
Brown, 239-255.
Fletcher, George P. (1978), Rethinking Criminal Law, Boston, Little Brown.
Fletcher, George P. (1987), Why Kant, 87 Columbia Law Review, 421-432.
Freeman, Donald (1981), Value Maximization and Welfare Theory, 10 Journal of Legal Studies,
409-419.
Friedman, Lawrence M. (1984), Two Faces of Law, Wisconsin Law Review, 13-35.
Gaakeer, Jeanne (1994), De Taal van het Recht en de Taal van de Economie, ofwel Integratie en
het Gevaar van Steno (Laws Language and Economics Language, or Integration and the
Danger of Shorthand), in Foqu, R. et al. (eds), Gentegreerde Rechtswetenschap, Arnhem,
Gouda Quint, 423-441.
Gallie, W.B. (1956), Essentially Contested Concepts, 56 Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society,
167-198.
Gemtos, Petros A. (1998), Oi Theoretikes Vaseis tes Oikonomikes Analyses tou Dikaiou (The
Theoretical Bases of Economic Analysis of Law), 46 Nomiko Vema.
Gjerdingen, Donald H. (1986), The Politics of the Coase Theorem and its Relationship to Modern
Legal Thought, 35 Buffalo Law Review, 871-935.
Goetz, Charles J. and Scott, Robert E. (1977), Liquidated Damages, Penalties and the Just
Compensation Principle: Some Notes on an Enforcement Model and a Theory of Efficient
Breach, 77 Columbia Law Review, 554-594.
Goldberg, Victor P. and Olmstead, Alan L. (1975), Institutional Change and American Economic
Growth - A Critique of Davis and North, 12 Explorations in Economic History, 193-210.
Goodman, John C. (1978), An Economic Theory of the Evolution of Common Law, 7 Journal of
Legal Studies, 393-406.
Gordon, Scott (1980), Welfare, Justice and Freedom, New York, Columbia Univ Press.
1062 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 0800
Grady, Mark F. (1994), Modern Accident Law Does Not Fit Corrective Justice Theory, 2 Annual
Review of Law and Ethics, 7 ff.
Grant, Robin F. (1989), Judge Richard Posners Wealth Maximization Principle: Another Form of
Utilitarianism?, 10 Cardozo Law Review, 815-845.
Gray, John H. (1989), Contractarian Method, Private Property, and the Market Economy, in
Chapman, John W. and Pennock, J. Roland (eds), NOMOS XXXI: Markets and Justice, New
York, New York University Press, 13-58.
Guest, Stephen F.D. (1984), Utilitarianism, Economics and the Common Law, 5 Otago Law
Review, 656-663.
Hadfield, Gillian K. (1992), Bias in the Evolution of Legal Rules, 80 Georgetown Law Journal,
583-616.
Hammond (1982), The Economics of Justice and the Criterion of Wealth Maximization (Book
Review), 91 Yale Law Journal, 1493-1507.
Hanak, Andrs (1979), Neoklasszicista Justitia (Neo-classicist Justice), 12 Jogtudomnyi
Kzlny, 855-859.
Hardin, Garrett (1968), The Tragedy of the Commons, 162 Science, 1243-1248.
Harrison, Jeffrey L. (1986), Egoism, Altruism, and Market Illusions: The Limits of Law and
Economics, 33 UCLA Law Review, 1309-1363.
Harsanyi, John C. (1977), Morality and the Theory of Rational Behaviour, 44 Social Research.
Hasen, Richard L. (1996), Voting Without Law, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law Review,
2135-2179.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1993), Comments on Bertrand Lemmeniciers paper Social Justice and its
Controversies, 4 Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines, 263-268.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1996), Neofileleutherismos, Dikaio kai Oikonomike Analyse ton Thesmon:
Eisagoge ste Melete ton Neon Oikonomikon Theorion gia to Dikaio, ten Koinonia kai ten
Politike (The so-called Neo-Liberalism, the Law and the Economic Analysis of Institutions:
Introduction to the Study of the New Economic Theories on Law, Society and Politics), 6
Aissymnetes.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1997), Eisagoge sten Oikonomike Analyse tou Dikaiou (Introduction to the
Economic Analysis of Law), Aristotle University of Thessaloniki School of Law and
Economics, Department of History, Philosophy and Sociology of Law.
Hatzis, Aristides N. (1997), Krise tou Dikaiou e Krise tes Theorias tou? Prolegomena se mia
Oikonomike Theoria tou Dikaiou ton Symvaseon (A Crisis of Law or a Crisis of Its Theory?
Prolegomena of an Economic Theory of Contract Law), working paper presented in a workshop
under the auspices of Panteios University.
Hayashida, Seimei (1993), Jissenteki Suiron to Ho to Keizaigaku (Practical Reasoning and Law
and Economics), XXXHotetsugaku Nempo 1992 (Annual of Legal Philosophy 1992), 44-59.
Heertje, A. (1966), Conflictstof voor juristen en economen (Conflict Material for Lawyers and
Economists), 15 Ars Aequi, 14-16.
Heller, Thomas C. (1976), The Importance of Normative Decisionmaking: The Limitations of
Legal Economics as a Basis for a Liberal Jurisprudence, Wisconsin Law Review, 385-502.
0800 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 1063
Kelman, Mark G. (1983), Misunderstanding Social Life: A Critique of the Core Premises of Law
and Economics, 33 Journal of Legal Education, 274-284.
Kelman, Mark G. (1987), A Guide to Critical Legal Studies, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University
Press.
Kelman, Mark G. (1987), The Necessary Myth of Objective Causation Judgments in Liberal
Political Theory, 63 Chicago-Kent Law Review, 579-637.
Kennedy, Duncan (1976), Form and Substance in Private Law Adjudication, 89 Harvard Law
Review, 1685-1778. Reprinted in Kronman, Anthony T. and Posner, Richard A. (eds) (1979),
The Economics of Contract Law, Boston, Little Brown, 100-107.
Kennedy, Duncan (1981), Cost-Benefit of Entitlement Problems: A Critique, 33 Stanford Law
Review, 387-445.
Kerkmeester, Heico (1997), De Retoriek van de Rechtseconomie (The Rhetorics of Law and
Economics), in Feteris, E.T. et al. (eds), Op Goede Gronden, Nijmegen, Ars Aequi Libri,
207-213.
Klein, Burton H. (1977), Dynamic Economics, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1980), A Guide to the Perplexed Claims of Efficiency in the Law, 8
Hofstra Law Review, 591-639.
Kornhauser, Lewis A. (1998), Private Ordering in the Shadow of the Law, in Garth, Levine, and
Sarat (eds), Justice and Power in the Study of Law and Society, Northwestern University
Press, forthcoming.
Kozyris, Phaedon I. (1991), Treis Provlematismoi sten Amerikanike Theoria tou Dikaiou (Three
Conjectures in American Jurisprudence), 39 Nomiko Vema, 715-728.
Kozyris, Phaedon I. (1996), Protaseis Dianemetikes Dikaiosynes sto Telos tes Istorias: Ta Kyria
Erotemata me Apla Logia (Proposals of Distributive Justice in the End of History: Basic
Questions Made Easy), 3 Kritike Epitheorese, 23-81.
Kronman, Anthony T. (1980), Wealth Maximization as a Normative Principle, 9 Journal of Legal
Studies, 227-242.
Kuhn, Thomas (1970), The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, Chicago, University of Chicago
Press.
Kunz, Harald (1985), Zur Entstehung und Verhaltenswirkung sozialer Normen, mit einigen
Argumenten fr eine Okonomisch Rationale Kriminalpolitik (On the Evolution and the
Incentive Effect of Social Norms, with Some Arguments for an Economic Rational Crime
Policy), 68 Monatsschrift fr Kriminologie und Strafsrechtsreform, 202-215.
Kuttner, Robert (1985), The Poverty of Economics, 2 Atlantic Monthly, 74-84.
Landes, William M. and Posner Richard A. (1987), The Economic Structure of Tort Law,
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Lee, Dwight R. (1988), Politics, Ideology, and the Power of Public Choice, 74 Virginia Law
Review, 191-198.
Leff, Arthur A. (1974), Economic Analysis of Law: Some Realism about Nominalism, 60
Virginia Law Review, 451-482.
Lutz, Mark A. (1988), Social Economics: Retrospect and Prospect, Boston, Kluwer Academic
Publishers.
MacNeil, Ian R. (1980), The New Social Contract: An Inquiry into Modern Contractual
Relations, New Haven, CT, Yale University Press.
0800 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 1065
MacPherson, C.B. (1985), The Rise and Fall of Economic Justice and Other Papers, Oxford,
Oxford University Press.
Malloy, Robin Paul (1986), Equating Human Rights and Property Rights - the Need for Moral
Judgment in an Economic Analysis of Law and Social Policy, 47 Ohio State Law Journal,
163-177.
Malloy, Robin Paul (1988a), Market Philosophy in the Legal Tension Between Childrens
Autonomy and Parental Authority, 21 Indiana Law Review, 889-900.
Malloy, Robin Paul (1988b), The Merits of the Smithian Critique: A Final Word on Smith and
Posner, 36 University of Kansas Law Review, 266-274.
Malloy, Robin Paul (1988c), The Invisible Hand or the Sleight of Hand? Adam Smith, Richard
Posner and the Philosophy of Law and Economics, 36 University of Kansas Law Review, 209
ff.
Malloy, Robin Paul (1990a), Law and Economics: A Comparative Approach to Theory and
Practice, St. Paul, West Publishing Company.
Malloy, Robin Paul (1990b), Is Law and Economics Moral? - Humanistic Economics and a
Classical Liberal Critique of Posners Economic Analysis, 24 Valparaiso University Law
Review, 147-161.
Malloy, Robin Paul (1990c), The Limits of Science in Legal Discourse - A Reply to Posner, 24
Valparaiso University Law Review, 175-181.
Malloy, Robin Paul (1994), Adam Smith and the Modern Discourse of Law and Economics, in
Malloy, Robin Paul and Evensky, Jerry (eds), Adam Smith and the Philosophy of Law and
Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 113-150.
Malloy, Robin Paul and Evensky, Jerry (eds) (1994), Adam Smith and the Philosophy of Law and
Economics, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Markovits, Richard S. (1983), Legal Analysis and the Economic Analysis of Allocative Efficiency:
A Response to Professor Posners Reply, 11 Hofstra Law Review, 667-689.
McCloskey, Donald N. (1988), The Rhetoric of Law and Economics, 86 Michigan Law Review,
752-767.
McGee, Robert W. (1992), Business Ethics and Common Sense,Westport, CT, Quorum Books,
302 p.
McGee, Robert W. (1994), A Trade Policy for Free Societies:The Case Against Protectionism,
Westport, CT, Quorum Books, 197 p.
McGee, Robert W. (1996a), Essays on Accounting, Taxation and Public Finance, Dumont
Institute for Public Policy Research. http://www.hili.com/~dumontin
McGee, Robert W. (1996b), Taxation, Ethics and Public Policy, Dumont Institute for Public
Policy Research. http://www.hili.com/~dumontin
McGee, Robert W. (1996c), The New Prohibitionism: The Movement to Regulate Personal
Behavior, Dumont Institute for Public Policy Research. http://www.hili.com/~dumontin
McGee, Robert W. (1996d), Economics and Ethics, Dumont Institute for Public Policy Research.
http://www.hili.com/~dumontin
McGee, Robert W. (1996e), Essays in Law and Economics from a Right Perspective, Dumont
Institute for Public Policy Research. http://www.hili.com/~dumontin
McGee, Robert W. (1996f), Some Thoughts on Accounting, Ethics and Public Policy, Dumont
Institute for Public Policy Research. http://www.hili.com/~dumontin
1066 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 0800
McGee, Robert W. and Block, Walter E. (1996), A Rights Perspective on Law, Economics and
Ethics, Dumont Institute for Public Policy Research. http:/www.hili.com/~dumontin
Meade, James E. (1964), Efficiency, Equality, and the Ownership of Property, London, Allen and
Unwin, 92 p.
Medema, Steven G. (1993), Is There Life Beyond Efficiency? Elements of a Social Law and
Economics, 51 Review of Social Economy, 138-153.
Mercuro, Nicholas and Medema, Steven G. (1997), Economics and the Law: From Posner to
Postmodernism, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Michelman, Frank I. (1967), Property, Utility and Fairness: Comments on the Ethical Foundations
of Just Compensation Law, 80 Harvard Law Review, 1165-1258. Reprinted in Ackerman,
Bruce A. (ed.) (1975), Economic Foundations of Property Law, Boston, Little Brown, 100 ff.
Michelman, Frank I. (1978), Norms and Normativity in the Economic Theory of Law, 62
Minnesota Law Review, 1015-1048.
Michelman, Frank I. (1979), A Comment on Some Uses and Abuses of Economics in Law, 46
University of Chicago Law Review, 307-315.
Michelman, Frank I. (1982), Ethics, Economics, and the Law of Property, in Pennock, J. Roland
and Chapman, John W. (eds), Nomos XXIV: Ethics, Economics and the Law, New York, New
York University Press, 3-40.
Miller, Edythe S. (1990), Economic Efficiency, the Economics Discipline, and the
Affected-with-a-Public-Interest Concept, 24 Journal of Economic Issues, 719-732.
Mishan, Ezra J. (1969), Welfare Economics: An Assessment, Amsterdam, North-Holland.
Morse, Jennifer Roback (1997), Who is Rational Economic Man?, 14 Social Philosophy and
Policy, 177-206.
Nance, Dale A. (1997), Guidance Rules and Enforcement Rules: A Better View of the Cathedral,
83 Virginia Law Review, 837-937.
Ng, Yew Kwang (1988), Economic Efficiency versus Egalitarian Rights, 41 Kyklos, 215-237.
Nieuwenhuis, J.H. (1984), Recht en Belang (Law and Interests), Flores Debitorem, 65-74.
Nieuwenhuis, J.H. (1988), Ieder het Zijne (Each His Own), 2 RMThemis, 73-84.
Nieuwenhuis, J.H. (1997), De Ramp op het Pikmeer (The Pikmeer Disaster), Deventer, Kluwer, 22
p.
Niskanen, William A. (1971), Bureaucracy and Representative Government, Chicago, Atherton.
Nozick, Robert (1974), Anarchy, State, and Utopia, New York, Basic Books.
Nutter, Warren G. (1968), Economic Welfare and Welfare Economics, 2 Journal of Economic
Issues, 166-172.
ODriscoll, Gerald P., Jr (1980), Justice, Efficiency, and the Economic Analysis of Law: A
Comment on Fried, 9 Journal of Legal Studies, 355-366.
Ogus, Anthony I. (1980), Economics, Liberty and the Common Law, 18 Journal of Society of
Public Teachers of Law, 42-57.
Olson, Mancur (1971), The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups,
New York, Shocken, Books.
0800 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 1067
Posner, Richard A. (1990a), Rebuttal to Malloy, 24 Valparaiso University Law Review, 183-184.
Posner, Richard A. (1990b), Law and Economics, 24 Valparaiso University Law Review,
163-173.
Posner Richard A. (1992), Sex and Reason, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Posner Richard A. (1998), Economic Analysis of Law (5th edn), New York, Aspen Publishers, Inc.
Priest, George J. (1977), The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Legal Rules, 6
Journal of Legal Studies, 65-82.
Radin, Margaret J. (1982), Property and Personhood, 34 Stanford Law Review, 957 ff.
Radin, Margaret Jane (1987), Market-Inalienability, 100 Harvard Law Review, 1849-1937.
Radin, Margaret J. (1989), Justice and the Market Domain, in Chapman, John W. and Pennock, J.
Roland (eds), NOMOS XXXI: Markets and Justice, New York, New York University Press,
165-197.
Raes, Koen (1988), Rechtstheorie als Ideologiekritiek (Legal Theory as Ideological Criticism), in
Kamstra, O.W.M. et al. (eds), Nederlandsche Rechtswetenschap, Zwolle, Tjeenk Willink,
283-298.
Raes, Koen (1990), Het Recht van de Schaarste (The Law of Scarcety), 16 Recht en Kritiek,
380-394.
Rahmsdorf, Detlev W. (1987), konomische Analyse des Rechts, Utilitarismus und die Klassische
Deutsche Philosophie (Economic Analysis of Law, Utilitarianism and the Classical German
Philosophy), 18 Rechtstheorie, 487-501.
Rahmsdorf, Detlev W. and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds) (1988), Ethische Fragen der
Wirtschaftspolitik und des Rechts (Ethical Questions of Political Economics and Law), Berlin,
Dietrich-Reimer-Verlag, 219 p.
Raiteri, Monica (1988), Giustizia Distributiva e Funzione Giudiziaria: Qualche Osservazione nella
Prospettiva della Analisi Economica del Diritto (Distributive Justice and the Judicial Function,
Some Observations form the Viewpoint of the Economic Analysis of Law), Materiali per una
Storia della Cultura Giuridica, 209-228.
Rakoff, Todd D. (1996), Too Many Theories, 94 Michigan Law Review, 1799-1809.
Rawls, John (1971), A Theory of Justice, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Reich, Charles A. (1996), Property Law and the New Economic Order: A Betrayal of Middle
Americans and the Poor, 71 Chicago-Kent Law Review, 817-823.
Reich, Robert B. (1983), The Next American Frontier, New York, Times Books.
Reich, Robert B. (1991), The Work of Nations: Preparing Ourselves for 21st Century Capitalism,
New York, Alfred A. Knopf.
Riley, Jonathan (1989), Justice under Capitalism, in Chapman, John W. and Pennock, J. Roland
(eds), NOMOS XXXI: Markets and Justice, New York, New York University Press, 122-162.
Rizzo, Mario J. (1980), The Mirage of Efficiency, 8 Hofstra Law Review, 641-658.
Rorty, Richard (1979), Philosophy and the Mirror of Nature, Princeton, Princeton University
Press.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1985), Inalienability and the Theory of Property Rights, 85 Columbia
Law Review, 931-969.
0800 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 1069
Seidl, Christian (1997), Das Wesen liberaler Rechte (On the Essence of Liberal Rights), in Ott,
Claus and Schfer, Hans-Bernd (eds), konomische Analyse des Rechts, Fnftes
Travemnder Symposium zur Analyse des Rechts, Berlin, Springer.
Seita, Alex Y. (1989), Common Myths in the Economic Analysis of Law, Brigham Young
University Law Review, 993-1112.
Sen, Amartya K. (1970), Collective Choice and Social Welfare, San Francisco, Holden-Day.
Sen, Amartya K. (1977), Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioral Foundations of Economic
Theory, 6 Philosophy and Public Affairs, 317-344.
Sen, Amartya K. (1979), Personal Utilities and Public Judgments: Or Whats Wrong with Welfare
Economics?, 89 Economics Journal, 537-558.
Spitzer, Matthew L. and Hoffman, Elizabeth (1980), A Reply to Consumption Theory, Production
Theory and Ideology in the Coase Theorem, 53 Southern California Law Review, 1187-1223.
Steiner, J.M. (1976), Economics, Morality and the Law of Torts, 26 University of Toronto Law
Journal, 227-252.
Strowel, Alain (1987), Utilitarisme et Approche Economique dans la Thorie du Droit. Autour de
Bentham et de Posner (Utilitarianism and Economic Approach in Legal Theory. On Bentham
and Posner), 18 Revue Interdisciplinaire dEtudes Juridiques, 1-45.
Sunstein, Cass R. (1989), Disrupting Voluntary Transactions, in Chapman, John W. and Pennock,
J. Roland (eds), NOMOS XXXI: Markets and Justice, New York, New York University Press,
279-302.
Symposium (1980), Symposium on Efficiency as a Legal Concern, 8 Hofstra Law Review,
485-972.
Symposium (1996a), Elizabeth Andersons Value in Ethics and Economics, 106 Ethics.
Symposium (1996b), Law, Economics, and Norms, 144 University of Pennsylvania Law Review.
Symposium (1998), Problems of Market Liberalism, 15 Social Philosophy & Policy.
Thompson, Michael et al. (1990), Cultural Theory, Boulder, CO, Westview Press.
Thurow, L. (1970), Equity vs. Efficiency in Law Enforcement, 18 Public Policy, 451-459.
Toulmin, Stephen (1990), Cosmopolis: The Hidden Agenda of Modernity, Chicago, University of
Chicago Press.
Trebilcock, Michael J. (1993), The Limits of Freedom of Contract, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press.
Tribe, Laurence H. (1985), Constitutional Calculus: Equal Justice or Economic Efficiency, 98
Harvard Law Review, 592-621.
Trimarchi, Pietro (1970), Sul Significato Economico dei Criteri di Responsabilit Contrattuale
(Economic Meaning of Contract-Liability Criteria), Rivista Trimestrale di Diritto e
Procedura Civile, 512-531.
Tsibris, Michalis R. (1989), Oikonomike Analyse tou Dikaiou: To Epomeno Vema (Economic
Analysis of Law: The Next Step), 37 Nomiko Vema, 574-586.
Tullock, Gordon (1971), The Logic of the Law, New York, Basic Books.
Tullock, Gordon (1980), Two Kinds of Legal Efficiency, 8 Hofstra Law Review, 659 ff.
Tullock, Gordon (1982), Welfare and the Law, 2 International Review of Law and Economics,
151-163.
0800 Norms and Values in Law and Economics 1071
Unger, Roberto Mangabeira (1976), Law in Modern Society: Toward a Criticism of Social
Theory, New York, NY, Free Press.
Unger, Roberto Mangabeira (1984), Passion: An Essay on Personality, New York, NY, Free
Press.
Unger, Roberto Mangabeira (1986), The Critical Legal Studies Movement, Cambridge, MA,
Harvard University Press.
Van Manen, Niels F. (1994), Eigenbelang, Chaos en Sociale Orde (Self-interest, Chaos and Social
Order), in Raes, Koen and Willekens, H. (eds), Economische Verklaringen van het Recht,
Den Haag, VUGA, 75-92.
Varat, Jonathan D. (1986), Review Essay: Economic Ideology and the Federal Judicial Task
(Review of the Federal Courts: Crisis and Reform by Richard A. Posner), 74 California Law
Review, 649-674.
Veblen, Thorstein (1899), The Theory of the Leisure Class, New York, MacMillan.
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1981), The Economic Theory of Tort Liability - Toward a Corrective
Justice Approach, in Burrows, Paul and Veljanovski, Cento G. (eds), The Economic
Approach to Law, London, Butterworths, 125-150.
Veljanovski, Cento G. (1981), Wealth Maximization, Law and Ethics - on the Limits of Economic
Efficiency, 1 International Review of Law and Economics, 5-28.
Waldron, Jeremy (1990), Criticizing the Economic Analysis of Law (Book Review of Jules L.
Coleman, Markets, Morals, and the Law), 99 Yale Law Journal, 1441-1471.
Weinrib, Ernest J. (1980), Utilitarianism, Economics and Legal Theory, 30 University of Toronto
Law Journal, 307-332.
Weise, Peter and Eger, Thomas (1990), Normen als Gesellschaftliche Ordner (Norms as Social
Co-ordination Parameters), 8 konomie und Gesellschaft, 65-111.
White, Barbara (1987a), Coase and the Courts: Economics for the Common Man, 72 Iowa Law
Review, 577-635.
White, James Boyd (1987b), Economics and Law: Two Cultures in Tension (Alumni
Distinguished Lecture in Jurisprudence), 54 Tennessee Law Review, 161-202.
Wittman, Donald A. (1979), A Diagrammatic Expositon of Justice, Theory and Decision,
207-237.
Wittman, Donald A. (1982), Efficient Rules in Highway Safety and Sports Activity, 72 American
Economic Review, 78-90.
Wu, Ho-Mou and Huang, Peter H. (1994), More Order without More Law: A Theory of Social
Norms and Organizational Cultures, 10 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization,
390-406.
Zwier, Paul J. (1985), The Consequentialist/Nonconsequentialist Ethical Distinction: A Tool for
the Formal Appraisal of Traditional Negligence and Economic Tort Analysis, 26 Boston
College Law Review, 905-944.
0900
GENERAL STRUCTURE OF THE LAW
Donald Wittman
Department of Economics, University of California at Santa Cruz
Copyright 1999 Donald Wittman
Abstract
Economic theory can provide insight into the general structure of the law
and the organization of topics in this encyclopedia. After arguing that all of
law is contract law, I show how economics can be used to explain the choice
between criminal law and tort law, liability rules and property rights, prior
regulation and post liability, restitution and torts, and courts and
legislatures.
JEL classification: K1
Keywords: Structure, Torts, Contracts, Criminal Law, Property Rules,
Liability Rules
1. Introduction
The first and possibly the best response is that all areas of the law are guided
by the same principle - to create efficient outcomes. An outcome is Pareto
efficient if one person cannot be made better off without making someone
1072
0900 General Structure of the Law 1073
worse off (we will not deal with the distinction between wealth
maximization and the Pareto principle here). A useful way of conceiving
such a result is to suppose that the parties write an optimal contract. In this
way, contract law, torts and restitution can be viewed as different
manifestations of contract law. For example, in automobile accidents, the
law implicitly asks what kind of contract would have been drawn up between
the victim and the injurer before the accident happened. The negligence
standard finds a person negligent if she did not undertake cost effective
preventive procedures. The hypothetical contract suggests that each party
would agree to be non-negligent. In the same way, restitution can be seen as
contract law for affirmative obligations between parties who otherwise are
not transacting with each other.
The analysis can be extended to other areas. As a city grows, it is
inefficient to allow pre-existing quarries, feedlots and the like to remain. To
use the contract analogy, if a contract had been written thirty years earlier,
the feedlot and the citys residents would have agreed to shut down the
feedlot when the city expanded. In the United States, such nuisances can be
shut down via a civil action or under a zoning regulation. Either way the
nuisance owner is not compensated - the courts interpretation of the
Constitution does not consider such a regulation a taking (see Boehm v.
Philadelphia, 1915) nor do the courts require the plaintiffs to compensate
the nuisance maker for moving costs (see Ensign v. Walls, 1948). Despite
their greatly different genealogy, these two areas of law treat the situation in
a similar way. And despite the fact that property law was developed before
contract law, the concept of contracts enlightens our understanding of the
limits of property.
Depending on ones taste, one can stretch the contract analogy still
further. During the enlightenment, the concept of a social contract was very
popular (see Rousseau) and this concept has been updated in the more recent
past to explain constitutional theory (see the chapters in the encyclopedia
devoted to this topic).
Economics as a discipline is a great generalizer that tends to cross
subject headings. Demand curves are drawn for cars, food and marriage.
Likewise in the law, an economic concept can be used in seemingly
unrelated areas. For example, if party X acts inefficiently, it makes economic
sense that a second party, Y, optimally mitigates the damages that might
arise. For example, if a plumber installs a bathtub drain improperly so that
bath water leaks into the ceiling below, economic efficiency dictates that the
homeowner stops using the bathtub once the problem is discovered. The cost
of not taking a bath is less than the benefit of not having the ceiling collapse.
This is known as mitigation of damages in contract law. Similarly, it
makes no economic sense for a farmer to plant a crop in the presence of
sulfur fumes from a nearby factory since sulfur fumes kill crops. Therefore
1074 General Structure of the Law 0900
the farmer will not be compensated for the cost of planting the crop, but only
for the lost profits in not being able to plant the crop in the first place
(United Verde Extension Mining Co. v. Ralston, 1931 - see Wittman, 1981).
This is known as the doctrine of avoidable consequences in tort law.
Finally, in continental law, a passerby is required to rescue a person lying
unconscious on a railroad track if the cost of rescue is trivial. Again, this is
just mitigation of damages in a different disguise. So three totally different
areas of law are guided by the same economic reasoning.
Having first argued that, at some fundamental level, economic theory
provides a unified explanation of the law and then giving an example of an
economic concept that is applied to seemingly unrelated legal subjects, I will
now try to argue that economic theory can also provide an explanation for
the differential structure of the law. Of necessity, the distinctions will be
more in shades of gray rather than in black and white.
Transaction costs in its many guises is often the key to explaining structural
differences in the law. Consider the choice between protecting an
entitlement via a property right (voluntary transfer) and a liability rule
(compensated involuntary transfer). If a state wants to build a highway from
A to B, all landowners along the proposed highway have monopoly positions
and each will try to extract all the surplus value for herself. Ordinary market
mechanism are not viable (that is, they have extremely high transaction
costs) in this case. So the state employs eminent domain (a type of liability
rule). As another example, drivers do not negotiate with other drivers and
pedestrians for the right to put these other people in danger - the transaction
costs would be too high. Instead, they pay ex post for any involuntary
transfer (see Demsetz, 1972, for an extended argument). On the other side,
where market transaction costs are low, entitlements tend to be protected by
a property right - I cannot cut down my neighbors cherry tree and, if I
threaten to do so, my neighbor can get an injunction to prevent such an
action. Of course, if I pay him enough, he may let me engage in my
obsession.
The standard explanation for not using a liability rule in this case is that
it is an imperfect measure of relative value and shifts the costs of decision
making onto third parties (courts). Kaplow and Shavell (1996) have argued
that this explanation is flawed. Under the shadow of a court-imposed
liability rule, the parties can negotiate an outcome that does reflect higher
value. For example, if the courts say that the damage to my neighbor is only
$1,000 when I cut down his tree when in fact it is worth $2,000 to him not
0900 General Structure of the Law 1075
having his tree cut down, then he will be willing to bribe me $500 not to cut
down the tree and I will accept the bribe if cutting cherry trees is worth only
$1,200 to me (since cutting it down will mean a loss of the $500 bribe plus
the court imposed liability of $1,000).
But Kaplow and Shavells argument ignores transaction costs. To
illustrate, we consider the entitlement structure for movie stars. Paul
Newman is both a movie star and an entrepreneur (he has his own line of
spaghetti sauce and salad dressing). Paul Newman has the property right to
use photographs of himself or his name in advertising, and he can sell that
right if it maximizes the return on his human capital. In this way, sales are
value maximizing. However, such a property right system involves some
exchange costs. Paul Newman must be contacted and a price must be
negotiated. These costs are not trivial, yet they are unlikely to be very large
since this is not a case of bilateral monopoly (as hard as it is to believe, there
are substitutes for Paul Newman, perhaps Tom Cruise). Furthermore only a
few people might be involved.
If there were a communal right to Paul Newmans name in advertising,
then his name would be overused. Paul Newman Bail Bonds might bring
in increased profits to the bail bondsman, but decrease the overall profits of
products with Newmans name). Turning this communal right into Paul
Newmans property right would be extremely expensive. Every time he
bought out one person, another person would arise to make use of his name
or picture. So the right would likely remain a communal right, with overuse
but no exchange costs. If Paul Newman could buy back the rights, the
transaction costs would be very high - he would have to buy the right from
many to stop them from using his name (this should be compared to the case
were Paul Newman is given the right and then sells it to a few).
When the law gives Paul Newman the property right to his name for
advertising, even if the particular allocation is incorrect, it is easily remedied
(the other party will just buy the right to Paul Newmans name if it is worth
more to the other party than to Paul Newman). When Paul Newmans
entitlement to use his name for advertising purposes is only protected by a
liability rule, the courts assessment of the damage to Paul Newman may be
off. If the court overestimates the cost, essentially Newmans entitlement to
his own name is protected by a property right; if the court significantly
underestimates the damage, then his entitlement is virtually a communal
right. It is very hard to remedy such a mistake, and if it is corrected, very
high transaction costs are involved as the actor must buy back the right from
numerous contenders. Furthermore, the negotiated price depends on the
courts valuation or expected valuation. This adds a needless level of cost
and/or uncertainty. So transaction costs are a key to the choice between a
property right and a liability rule.
1076 General Structure of the Law 0900
This topic covers some of the same territory as the previous section but
under the assumption that high transaction costs prevent negotiation
between the two sides.
Consider the case where a factory pollutes the air and the efficient
outcome is that the factory reduces the pollution rather than the neighbors
undertake damage prevention. If there is perfect information, pollution
taxes, quantity restrictions and liability for the damage can all be set to yield
the same efficient outcome. We employ the standard diagram where smoke
is on the horizontal axis and dollars are on the vertical axis (see Figure 1).
Then the marginal cost of increased smoke to the neighbors is increasing
and the marginal benefit to the firm of increased smoke is decreasing (since
the marginal cost of smoke abatement rises). The optimal amount of
pollution is where these two curves intersect. Setting a pollution tax (or per
unit of smoke liability rule) equal to t, the dollar value at the intersection of
the marginal cost and benefit curves, will encourage the factory to produce
until the tax equals the marginal benefit; that is, the factory will produce the
optimal amount, s*. Similarly, a regulation that the factory produce no more
than the optimal amount of smoke, s*, will again result in the optimal
amount of smoke. If the factory is liable (either to the victims or to the
government) for the area under the marginal cost of smoke curve, it will
again choose the optimal amount of smoke damage.
When there is imperfect information, the various methods need not
result in the same outcome (see Figure 2).
0900 General Structure of the Law 1077
Figure 1
$ C(s) = C 0+ C s1
Marginal cost of smoke
B(s) = B 0 + B 1 s
Marginal benefit of smoke
s* Smoke
Assume that the marginal cost of smoke is C(s) = C0 + C1s + u and that
the marginal benefit of smoke is B(s) = B0 + B1 s + v, where u and v are
independently and symmetrically distributed random variables with mean
zero. u and v are observed by the pollutee and the polluter, respectively, but
not by anyone else, including the courts or other government agencies.
Under quantity regulation, the level of smoke is set where the expected
marginal benefit from smoke abatement equals the expected marginal cost.
This level is denoted by Gs . Thus C0 + C1 Gs = B0 + B1 Gs , or
Figure 2
0900 General Structure of the Law 1079
Equivalently,
[( C12 / B12 )+ 2 2
v u ] / ( 2v + 2u )
Common law, Roman law and civil law distinguish between two groups
(contracts, specificatio, contrat) and (tort, delict, responsibilite civile). These
groups roughly correspond to low and high transaction cost situations. In
contracts the parties are already transacting with each other; in many tort
situations the parties first meet after the damage. But does the nature of the
rules differ between these two groupings? A key difference may be the role
of information transmission.
Contract law is often concerned with promoting efficient information
exchange. Hadley v. Baxendale (1854) is the defining case. When the risk
of loss is known to only one party to the contract, then the other party is not
0900 General Structure of the Law 1081
liable for the loss if it occurs. This creates the right incentives for the
knowledgeable party to inform the other when it is cost effective for the
other party to undertake additional precaution.
There are many applications of the basic principle. In trade between two
parties involving a standard item, if the seller has superior information about
the product, it is often economically efficient to have the seller inform the
buyer. Even if it is not a standard product, such as selling a home, if the
information can be obtained cheaply by the seller (say by living in the
house), then it is economically efficient for the seller to transmit this
information to the buyer rather than having potential buyers undertake
repeated and costly inspections. Hence in many jurisdictions, home sellers
are required to state what items are in disrepair (however, they are not
required to state whether their neighbors house will be up for sale in few
weeks). Also, all easements on the property are required to be recorded and
on the deed.
On the other side, there are many situations where such information
transmission is not required. A geologist is not required by law to tell the
present owner of the land that the land is likely to have significant oil
deposits. To require such a disclosure would reduce the returns to
specialized knowledge regarding oil discovery and ultimately result in a
suboptimal amount of oil exploration. Thus in contracts, product liability,
and real estate much of the law is devoted to determining the optimal
amount of information transmission and then designing rules to promote
that outcome.
In contrast, the issue of optimal information transmission is likely to be
irrelevant for those tort cases involving harm between people who otherwise
would have little contact (that is, for high transaction cost cases). And in
such situations, the injurer is liable even for damages that are unforeseen.
For example, if a drunk driver smashes into a person with an eggshell skull
and as a consequence the victim suffers much greater damage than would
ordinarily be the case, the drunk driver is still liable for the additional
damage. It would not have helped if the victim carried around a big sign
stating that he was especially susceptible to head injuries, and in general
carrying around such a sign would not be cost effective. Furthermore, if
drunk drivers were liable for less than the actual harm to eggshell skulls,
then economic efficiency would require that drunk drivers be liable for more
than the actual harm to rock skulls.
However, the issue of information transmission is not entirely absent
from high transaction cost situations. Automobiles are required to have
brake lights, and in the United States mercaptane is added to natural gas (in
this way, people in the vicinity of a natural gas pipe line leak can be warned
of the danger by the smell).
1082 General Structure of the Law 0900
Contract and torts differ in another important way. Contracts are written
ex ante and, when possible, courts tend to rely on the written document
rather than engage in their own cost-benefit analysis. The parties to the
contact have a comparative advantage in determining the optimal contract.
As a consequence, courts tend to hold the breacher strictly liable for the
foreseeable damages rather than the courts determining on their own
whether the breacher was negligent (of course, one might argue that the
word breach is often synonymous with the word negligent). In contrast, the
implicit contract in torts is determined by the courts ex post. As a result, the
negligence rule is more likely to be invoked as the courts have to determine
the efficient outcome on their own. See Posner (1992, Chapter 6) for further
arguments along this line.
The tort system deals with harms, so why do need a separate system for
crimes? For example, why is assault a crime in addition to being a tort?
Posner (1985, 1992, Chapter 7) has a well thought-out explanation for
needing criminal law in addition to civil law. Essentially, criminals are often
judgment proof (their wealth cannot cover their debts) and therefore the tort
system is inadequate.
Most crimes involve a coerced transfer in the context of low transaction
costs. The person who was shot in a robbery or gave up her wallet to avoid
being shot was not a volunteer to the transaction. In order to prevent the
conversion of a property right into a liability rule, a punitive damage should
be imposed on the perpetrator beyond the payment for the actual harm,
which itself may be very high (people do not like to be subjected to physical
violence). But unlike breach of contract and many other types of torts, it is
often hard to detect the perpetrator of a crime. If the criminal is not always
caught, the price to be paid has to be multiplied by 1 over the probability of
being punished. Also the criminal should pay for the cost of detection. This
raises the price of the crime for those who are actually caught still higher.
The resulting high price of a crime means that the criminal is often
judgment proof.
Because the person is judgment proof the victim of the crime or her heirs
will not have sufficient incentive to find the criminal and bring him to court
and the criminal will not be sufficiently deterred by the tort system. In turn,
this means that people may undertake self-protection (bodyguards, extra
locks, and so on) to avoid being robbed because they know they will not be
sufficiently compensated if they are robbed. So the criminal should be liable
not only for the robberies committed but also for the cost of prevention that
others undertook to prevent the robbery from occurring (but see Kermit and
0900 General Structure of the Law 1083
Lott, 1995, who argue to the contrary). This raises the optimal punishment
still further beyond the capacity of the tort system
So the robber needs a non-monetary punishment such as a prison
sentence to adequately deter and/or to physically restrain if deterrence is not
sufficient. Hence the state enters into the equation. Unlike ordinary torts
where the judgment itself involves no social cost but merely a transfer from
one party to another, incarceration involves significant costs. So optimal
punishment must take this into account.
It should be recognized that the judgment-proof explanation is not the
whole story. Criminals may be jailed for petty crimes even when they are
wealthy, wealthy anti-trust defendants may be both prosecuted for their
crimes and sued for their torts, and there are victimless crimes that are not
torts. Also the role of intention has not been fully analyzed. See Klevorick
(1985a, 1985b) and Fletcher (1985) for further arguments against the
economic model.
The legal system sometimes regulates the inputs and at other times charges
for the output. For example, a person can be fined for drunk driving even in
the absence of an accident and/or be found liable for the damage when there
is an accident. To the economist, but perhaps not to the general public, the
question is why society does not rely solely on sanctioning the output. Fining
inputs involves monitoring and distortion costs. Since inputs only increase
the likelihood of an accident, there are many more occurrences of the former
than the latter. Hence, input monitoring is generally more expensive than
output monitoring. Also there are many inputs into the production of the
output. Imposing fines for only a few of the inputs will distort the choice set
towards those activities that cannot be monitored.
There are several answers to the puzzle. A person may not be sufficiently
deterred if they are judgment proof. The judgment-proof problem is much
less likely to occur if inputs are sanctioned. The cost of input monitoring can
be significantly reduced if there are only random checks. Also, it is
sometimes easier to observe inputs than outputs. There may not be other
witnesses to the scene of the accident besides those that were involved.
Under such circumstances, it may be hard to disentangle the truth. Thus it
may make more sense to monitor the inputs, such as drunk driving. See
Wittman (1977) and Shavell (1984b) for more detailed arguments.
Not all people are adequately deterred by the threat of punishment for the
outcome so they are prevented from further inputs. Drunk drivers sometimes
1084 General Structure of the Law 0900
lose their licenses and are put in jail if they continue to drive under the
influence. Private parties can obtain injunctions rather than suing ex post for
the resulting harm. Especially in criminal law, inputs are subject to sanction.
If X shot at Y and missed, the law does not wait until X has killed Y before
doing something about it. Of course, the punishment of attempts has to be
less than the punishment for completions; otherwise the person would have
more incentive to complete. See Posner (1992) for a more thorough
exposition.
Another line of argument considers the defensive action by other parties.
Others may undertake economically justified counter-measures to the
inappropriate input so that the likelihood of an accident is significantly
reduced. Such measures are costly and should be imposed on the party
acting inappropriately even if there is no accident. For example, others may
swerve out of the way or not even drive in the first place in order to avoid
drunk drivers. Such defensive activity by others is costly and should be paid
for by the drunk driver even though there was no accident. Hence there are
fines for drunk driving, speeding, and so on. For a more thorough argument
see Wittman (1981).
If both potential injurers and their victims are risk averse, then risk
sharing may be optimal. A potentially fruitful line of research is to
investigate how a division between input and output monitoring might
improve risk allocation. This would go beyond the standard principal-agent
models.
The choice of monitoring technology is applicable to goods as well as
bads. In comparison to their counterparts in stores, the income of traveling
salesmen are based more on sales than hours on the job. Paying household
help by the hour is easier than calculating the value of all of the individual
services which may vary from week to week. On the other side, hiring
someone to come in and just clean your rugs (or windows) is based on the
output.
Input and output monitoring need not be a choice between one or the
other. Sometimes it makes sense to do both. But there is always a question of
how much input monitoring is necessary - one might require pasteurization
but not specify the shape of the bottle in which the milk is sold.
not to the host cedars. In the state of Virgina, apples are an important
agricultural crop while cedars are used mainly for ornamental purposes.
Should owners of cedar trees be liable for the harm to apple orchards and the
benefit to themselves if the cedar trees are not cut down or should apple
growers be liable for the harm to the cedar growers and the benefit to the
apple growers if they are? In the absence of transaction costs, this question
cannot be answered. Either way, one side is harmed while the other side is
benefited.
But in the real world there are transaction costs and such costs are
asymmetrical in the two regimes of restitution and tort. In this situation the
optimal outcome is clearly to have the cedar trees cut down. If cedar tree
owners are liable for the damage to apple growers, they will cut down their
trees and, except for mistakes, there will be no court cases. If apple growers
(or the state) are liable for the benefit derived from cutting down cedar trees,
then all of the cedar tree owners will go to court to collect for the benefit of
cutting down their trees. This involves high transaction costs. Although
courts can easily estimate that the total cost to all of the cedar tree owners is
less than the benefit to all of the apple tree growers, determining the cost to
each cedar tree owner is much higher. Furthermore, such a system would
require apple growers to compensate all people who would have otherwise
planted cedar trees but did not since the apple growers benefit from such a
decision. This would make court costs astronomical.
Restitution for benefits has higher court transaction costs than torts for
harm (hence the relative unimportance of the law of restitution in
comparison to tort law). So when does it make sense to have restitution? We
want restitution when the long-run entry of the desirable activity would be
seriously eroded if compensation for the benefit did not exist - that is, we
want compensation when the transaction costs of compensation are
outweighed by the increased existence of the desired activity. Consider
bounty hunters who track down people who fled on bail before their case
went to trial. If bounty hunters were liable for not catching the criminal, no
one would enter the business. So they are rewarded instead. Within the law
of restitution proper, doctors can collect for services to an unconscious
person found lying on the road even though the payment involves a
transaction cost. The doctor bill is generally standard (there is no need for
an expensive evidentiary hearing) and without such a payment doctors might
just drive by. See Landes and Posner (1978) and Wittman (1984).
doctor comes upon an injured person in the middle of a desert, the doctor
cannot take advantage of her monopoly position by demanding the persons
life savings in return for rescue. She is only allowed to charge her customary
rate, that is the competitive price, for such services. Much the same holds for
breach of contract. Opportunism arises when one of the parties to a contract
exploits the monopoly power temporarily gained through the contractual
relationship. Again, the remedy is relatively simple - such opportunistic
behavior is punished by the courts so that the parties have incentive not to
breach in the first place.
In contrast, there is no easy solution to the problem posed by the
monopoly of political power - no third party can enforce the contract
between the government and the people. Thus creating an effective
government while at the same time avoiding the dangers of monopoly power
is the fundamental concern of democratic constitutional theory. The
Federalist Papers were devoted to finding the proper balance between a
well-functioning government and protection from tyranny.
Democracies need to prevent the majority from exploiting the minority
via the majoritys control of government and at the same time this protection
should not allow the minority to exploit the majority. The conflict is always
there. If all issues were resolved by simple majority rule, then the majority
could exploit the minority, especially if there were a clear majority/minority
cleavage in society (say along ethnic lines). Any tampering with simple
majority rule (including such seemingly innocuous changes as having a
majority rule legislature voted in by majority rule) will result in a bias for
the status quo. See May (1952) who demonstrates that only a simple
majority rule satisfies the conditions of anonymity (all people are treated
alike), neutrality (if people reverse their preferences, the choice is reversed),
and positive responsiveness. Consequently, any attempt to protect the
minority will enable the minority to extort monopoly rents from the
majority.
The problem is acute when unanimity is the decision rule. Although
unanimity as an intellectual concept is at the foundation of constitutional
theory, in practice it would be unworkable. Everyone would try to extract the
gains from an agreement for herself. This monopoly holdout problem would
make collective decision making impossible. In practice, something less
than majority rule is required so that transaction costs are not too high (see
Buchanan and Tullock, 1962).
Beyond the majority/minority issue is the agency problem. The
government usually has a near monopoly on the means of coercive power.
What is to prevent the military from over-throwing an election? Of course,
this problem exists for all governments, not just those that are democratic
(see Skepardas, 1997). This problem is thus more serious than the agency
problem facing corporations - stockholders can throw out their managers
0900 General Structure of the Law 1087
Finally, we should not forget a major reason for the subheadings in law is
that there are returns to specialization. Both family law and bankruptcy law
may use the same economic analysis, but the factual details still differ.
Focusing in one area helps the practitioner if not always the theorist.
This contribution has shown how economic theory can provide insight
into the general structure of the law. There is considerable room for more
research in this area. The answers provided are not complete and there are
many more questions to be asked. Examples of the latter include: how and
why state laws differ from federal laws, and how and why civil and criminal
procedure differ.
Acknowledgments
I would like to thank Steven Shavell and the referee for helpful comments.
0900 General Structure of the Law 1089
Dowd, Kevin (1996), Competition and Finance: A New Interpretation of Financial and Monetary
Economics, Macmillan Press, 572 p.
Ellickson, R.C. (1973), Alternatives to Zoning: Convenants, Nuisance Rules, and Fines as Land
Use Controls, 40 University of Chicago Law Review, 681-782.
Epstein, Richard A. (1975), Intentional Harms, 4 Journal of Legal Studies, 391-442.
Epstein, Richard A. (1979), Nuisance Law: Corrective Justice and its Utilitarian Constraints, 8
Journal of Legal Studies, 49-102.
Fletcher, George P. (1985), A Transaction Cost Theory of Crime?, 85 Columbia Law Review,
921-930.
Frech, H.E. III (1979), The Extended Coase Theorem and Long Run Equilibrium: The
Non-Equivalence of Liability Rules and Property Rights, 27(1) Economic Inquiry, 254-268.
Friedman, David D. (1991), Impossibility, Subjective Probability, and Punishments for Attempts,
20 Journal of Legal Studies, 179-186.
Grady, Mark F. (1994), Positive Theories and Grown Order Conceptions of the Law, 23 Swedish
Law Review, 461 ff.
Hamilton, Alexander, Jay, John and Madison, James (1961), The Federalist Papers, New York,
New American Library.
Kaplow, Louis (1990), A Note on the Optimal Use of Nonmonetary Sanctions, 42 Journal of
Public Economics, 245-247.
Kaplow, Louis and Shavell, Steven (1995), Do Liability Rules Facilitate Bargaining? A Reply to
Ayres and Talley, 105(1) Yale Law Journal, 221-233.
Kaplow, Louis and Shavell, Steven (1996), Property Rules versus Liability Rules: An Economic
Analysis, 109 Harvard Law Review, 715-790.
Kermit, Daniel and Lott, J.R., Jr (1995), Should Criminal Penalties Include Third Party Avoidance
Costs?, 24 Journal of Legal Studies, 523-534.
Kitch, Edmund W. (1987), Law and the Economic Order, in Lipson, Leon and Wheeler, Stanton
(eds), Law and the Social Sciences, New York, Russel Sage Foundation, 109-149.
Klevorick, Alvin K. (1985a), Legal Theory and the Economic Analysis of Law, 85 Columbia Law
Review, 905-920.
Klevorick, Alvin K. (1985b), On the Economic Theory of Crime, 28 Nomos, 289 ff.
Kolstad, Charles D., Ulen, Thomas S. and Johnson, Gary V. (1990), Ex Post Liability for Harm vs.
Ex Ante Safety Regulation: Substitutes or Complements?, 80 American Economic Review,
888-901.
Krier, James E. and Schwab, Stewart J. (1995), Property Rules and Liability Rules: The Cathedral
in Another Light, 70 New York University Law Review, 440 ff.
Landes, William M. and Posner, Richard A. (1978), Salvors, Finders, Good Samaritans, and Other
Rescuers: An Economic Study of Law and Altruism, 7 Journal of Legal Studies, 83-128.
Landes, William M. and Posner, Richard A. (1981), An Economic Theory of Intentional Torts, 1
International Review of Law and Economics, 127-154.
Levmore, Saul (1985), Explaining Restitution, 71 Virginia Law Review, 65-124.
Levmore, Saul (1986), Waiting for Rescue: An Essay on the Evolution and Incentive Structure of
the Law of Affirmative Obligations, 72 Virginia Law Review, 879-941.
Long, Robert A., Jr (1984), A Theory of Hypothetical Contract, 94 Yale Law Journal, 415-434.
1092 General Structure of the Law 0900
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1995), Public Law Versus Private Law in Environmental Regulation:
European Union Proposals in the Light of United States and German Experience, in Eide,
Erling and Van Den Bergh, Roger (eds), Law and Economics of the Environment, Oslo,
Juridisk Forlag.
Rousseau, Jean Jacques (1954), The Social Contract (translated by Kendall, W.).
Rubin, Paul H. (1982), Common Law and Statute Law, 11 Journal of Legal Studies, 205-223.
Ryssdal, Stray A.C. (1995), An Economic Analysis of Civil Suits and Appels, Oslo, Juridisk
Forlag.
Ryssdal, Stray A.C. (1995), Legal Realism and Economics as Behavior - A Scandinavian Look at
the Economic Analysis of Law, Oslo, Juridisk Forlag.
Schap, David (1986), The Nonequivalence of Property Rules and Liability Rules, 6 International
Review of Law and Economics, 125-132.
Shavell Steven (1984a), A Model of the Optimal Use of Liability and Safety Regulation, 15 Rand
Journal of Economics, 271-280.
Shavell Steven (1984b), Liability for Harm versus Regulation of Safety, 13 Journal of Legal
Studies, 357-374.
Shavell Steven (1985), Criminal Law and the Optimal Use of Nonmonetary Sanctions as a
Deterrent, 85 Columbia Law Review, 1232-1262.
Shavell Steven (1986), The Judgment Proof Problem, 6 International Review of Law and
Economics, 45-58.
Shavell Steven (1990), Deterrence and the Punishment of Attempts, 19 Journal of Legal Studies,
435-466.
Skepardas, Stergios (1997), The Market for Protection and the Origin of the State, Irvine Working
Paper.
Spulber, Daniel F. (1988), Optimal Environmental Regulation under Asymmetric Information, 35
Journal of Public Economics, 163-181.
Staaf, Robert J. (1983), Liability Rules, Property Rights, and Taxes, 5 Research in Law and
Economics, 225-231.
White, Michelle J. and Wittman, Donald A. (1981), Optimal Spatial Location Under Pollution:
Liability Rules and Zoning, Journal of Legal Studies, 249-268.
White, Michelle J. and Wittman, Donald A. (1983a), Pollution Taxes and Optimal Spatial
Location, Economica, 297-311.
White, Michelle J. and Wittman, Donald A. (1983b), A Comparison of Taxes, Regulation, and
Liability Rules under Imperfect Information, 12 Journal of Legal Studies, 413-425.
Wiggins, Steven N. and Ringleb, A.H. (1992), Adverse Selection and Long Term Hazards: The
Choice between Contract and Mandatory Liability Rules, 21 Journal of Legal Studies,
189-215.
Wittman, Donald A. (1977), Prior Regulation versus Post Liability: The Choice Between Input and
Output Monitoring, 6 Journal of Legal Studies, 193-211.
Wittman, Donald A. (1981), Optimal Pricing of Sequential Inputs: Last Clear Chance, Mitigation
of Damages and Related Doctrines in the Law, 10 Journal of Legal Studies, 65-91.
Wittman, Donald A. (1984a), The Geometry of Justice, Theory and Decision, 239-250.
Wittman, Donald A. (1984b), Liability for Harm or Restitution for Benefit?, 13 Journal of Legal
Studies, 57-80.
1094 General Structure of the Law 0900
Cases
Boehm v. Philadelphia (1915), 59 Pa. Super. Ct 441.
Ensign v. Walls (1948), 323 Mich. 49; 34 N.W. 2d 549.
Hadley v. Baxendale (1854), 156 Eng. Rep 145.
Miller v. Schoene (1958), 276 U.S. 272.
United Verde Extension Mining Co v. Ralston (1931), 296 P. 262.