Emissions Trading
Emissions Trading
Emissions trading
Emissions trading (also known as cap and
trade) is a market-based approach used to
control pollution by providing economic
incentives for achieving reductions in the
emissions of pollutants.[1]
A central authority (usually a governmental
body) sets a limit or cap on the amount of a
pollutant that can be emitted. The limit or
cap is allocated or sold to firms in the form
of emissions permits which represent the
right to emit or discharge a specific volume
of the specified pollutant. Firms are required
to hold a number of permits (or carbon
credits) equivalent to their emissions. The
total number of permits cannot exceed the
cap, limiting total emissions to that level.
Firms that need to increase their emission
permits must buy permits from those who A coal power plant in Germany. Due to emissions trading, coal may become a less
[1] competitive fuel than other options.
require fewer permits. The transfer of
permits is referred to as a trade. In effect,
the buyer is paying a charge for polluting, while the seller is being rewarded for having reduced emissions. Thus, in
theory, those who can reduce emissions most cheaply will do so, achieving the pollution reduction at the lowest cost
to society.[2]
There are active trading programs in several air pollutants. For greenhouse gases the largest is the European Union
Emission Trading Scheme.[3] In the United States there is a national market to reduce acid rain and several regional
markets in nitrogen oxides.[4] Markets for other pollutants tend to be smaller and more localized.
Overview
The overall goal of an emissions trading plan is to minimize the cost of meeting a set emissions target.[5] The cap is
an enforceable limit on emissions that is usually lowered over time aiming towards a national emissions reduction
target.[5] In other systems a portion of all traded credits must be retired, causing a net reduction in emissions each
time a trade occurs. In many cap-and-trade systems, organizations which do not pollute may also participate, thus
environmental groups can purchase and retire allowances or credits and hence drive up the price of the remainder
according to the law of demand.[6] Corporations can also prematurely retire allowances by donating them to a
nonprofit entity and then be eligible for a tax deduction.
Emissions trading 2
Definitions
The economics literature provides the following definitions of cap and trade emissions trading schemes.
A cap-and-trade system constrains the aggregate emissions of regulated sources by creating a limited number of
tradable emission allowances, which emission sources must secure and surrender in number equal to their
emissions.[7]
In an emissions trading or cap-and-trade scheme, a limit on access to a resource (the cap) is defined and then
allocated among users in the form of permits. Compliance is established by comparing actual emissions with permits
surrendered including any permits traded within the cap.[8]
Under a tradable permit system, an allowable overall level of pollution is established and allocated among firms in
the form of permits. Firms that keep their emission levels below their allotted level may sell their surplus permits to
other firms or use them to offset excess emissions in other parts of their facilities.[9]
History
The efficiency of what later was to be called the "cap-and-trade" approach to air pollution abatement was first
demonstrated in a series of micro-economic computer simulation studies between 1967 and 1970 for the National
Air Pollution Control Administration (predecessor to the United States Environmental Protection Agency's Office of
Air and Radiation) by Ellison Burton and William Sanjour. These studies used mathematical models of several cities
and their emission sources in order to compare the cost and effectiveness of various control strategies.[12] [13] [14] [15]
[16]
Each abatement strategy was compared with the "least cost solution" produced by a computer optimization
program to identify the least costly combination of source reductions in order to achieve a given abatement goal.[17]
In each case it was found that the least cost solution was dramatically less costly than the same amount of pollution
reduction produced by any conventional abatement strategy.[18] This led to the concept of "cap and trade" as a means
of achieving the "least cost solution" for a given level of abatement.
The development of emissions trading over the course of its history can be divided into four phases:[19]
1. Gestation: Theoretical articulation of the instrument (by Coase,[20] Crocker,[21] Dales,[22] Montgomery[23] etc.)
and, independent of the former, tinkering with "flexible regulation" at the US Environmental Protection Agency.
2. Proof of Principle: First developments towards trading of emission certificates based on the "offset-mechanism"
taken up in Clean Air Act in 1977.
3. Prototype: Launching of a first "cap-and-trade" system as part of the US Acid Rain Program in Title IV of the
1990 Clean Air Act, officially announced as a paradigm shift in environmental policy, as prepared by "Project
88", a network-building effort to bring together environmental and industrial interests in the US.
4. Regime formation: branching out from the US clean air policy to global climate policy, and from there to the
European Union, along with the expectation of an emerging global carbon market and the formation of the
"carbon industry".
Emissions trading 3
Example
Emissions trading through Gains from Trade can be more beneficial for both the buyer and the seller than a simple
emissions capping scheme.
Consider two European countries, such as Germany and Sweden. Each can either reduce all the required amount of
emissions by itself or it can choose to buy or sell in the market.
For this example let us assume that
Germany can abate its CO2 at a much
cheaper cost than Sweden, e.g. MACS
> MACG where the MAC curve of
Sweden is steeper (higher slope) than
that of Germany, and RReq is the total
amount of emissions that need to be
reduced by a country.
On the right side is the MAC curve for Sweden. RReq is the amount of required reductions for Sweden, but the
MACS curve already intersects the market price of CO2 allowances before RReq has been reached. Thus, given the
market allowance price of CO2, Sweden has potential to make a cost saving if it abates fewer emissions than
required internally, and instead abates them elsewhere.
Emissions trading 4
In this example, Sweden would abate emissions until its MACS intersects with P (at R*), but this would only reduce
a fraction of Swedens total required abatement. After that it could buy emissions credits from Germany for the price
P (per unit). The internal cost of Swedens own abatement, combined with the credits it buys in the market from
Germany, adds up to the total required reductions (RReq) for Sweden. Thus Sweden can make a saving from buying
credits in the market ( d-e-f). This represents the "Gains from Trade", the amount of additional expense that
Sweden would otherwise have to spend if it abated all of its required emissions by itself without trading.
Germany made a profit on its additional emissions abatement, above what was required: it met the regulations by
abating all of the emissions that was required of it (RReq). Additionally, Germany sold its surplus to Sweden as
credits, and was paid P for every unit it abated, while spending less than P. Its total revenue is the area of the graph
(RReq 1 2 R*), its total abatement cost is area (RReq 3 2 R*), and so its net benefit from selling emission credits is the
area ( 1-2-3) i.e. Gains from Trade
The two R* (on both graphs) represent the efficient allocations that arise from trading.
Germany: sold (R* - RReq) emission credits to Sweden at a unit price P.
Sweden bought emission credits from Germany at a unit price P.
If the total cost for reducing a particular amount of emissions in the Command Control scenario is called X, then to
reduce the same amount of combined pollution in Sweden and Germany, the total abatement cost would be less in
the Emissions Trading scenario i.e. (X 123 - def).
The example above applies not just at the national level: it applies just as well between two companies in different
countries, or between two subsidiaries within the same company.
Carbon leakage
Carbon leakage is the effect that regulation of emissions in one country/sector has on the emissions in other
countries/sectors that are not subject to the same regulation (Barker et al.., 2007).[32] There is no consensus over the
magnitude of long-term carbon leakage (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p.31).[33]
In the Kyoto Protocol, Annex I countries are subject to caps on emissions, but non-Annex I countries are not. Barker
et al.. (2007) assessed the literature on leakage. The leakage rate is defined as the increase in CO2 emissions outside
of the countries taking domestic mitigation action, divided by the reduction in emissions of countries taking domestic
mitigation action. Accordingly, a leakage rate greater than 100% would mean that domestic actions to reduce
emissions had had the effect of increasing emissions in other countries to a greater extent, i.e., domestic mitigation
action had actually led to an increase in global emissions.
Estimates of leakage rates for action under the Kyoto Protocol ranged from 5 to 20% as a result of a loss in price
competitiveness, but these leakage rates were viewed as being very uncertain.[34] For energy-intensive industries, the
beneficial effects of Annex I actions through technological development were viewed as possibly being substantial.
This beneficial effect, however, had not been reliably quantified. On the empirical evidence they assessed, Barker et
al.. (2007) concluded that the competitive losses of then-current mitigation actions, e.g., the EU ETS, were not
significant.
Trade
One of the controversies about carbon mitigation policy thus arises about how to "level the playing field" with border
adjustments.[35] One component of the American Clean Energy and Security Act, for example, along with several
other energy bills put before Congress, calls for carbon surcharges on goods imported from countries without
cap-and-trade programs. Even aside from issues of compliance with the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade,
such border adjustments presume that the producing countries bear responsibility for the carbon emissions.
A general perception among developing countries is that discussion of climate change in trade negotiations could
lead to "green protectionism" by high-income countries (World Bank, 2010, p.251).[31] Tariffs on imports ("virtual
carbon") consistent with a carbon price of $50ton/CO2 could be significant for developing countries. World Bank
(2010) commented that introducing border tariffs could lead to a proliferation of trade measures where the
competitive playing field is viewed as being uneven. Tariffs could also be a burden on low-income countries that
have contributed very little to the problem of climate change.
Trading systems
Kyoto Protocol
As the IPCC reports came in over the years they shed abundant light on the true state of global warming and they
gave support to the environmental effort to address this unprecedented problem. However, the same discussions that
started decades back had never ceased and the crusade for a tangible solution to global climate change had gone on
all the while. In 1997 the Kyoto Protocol was adopted. The Kyoto Protocol is a 1997 international treaty which came
into force in 2005. In the treaty, most developed nations agreed to legally binding targets for their emissions of the
six major greenhouse gases.[36] Emission quotas (known as "Assigned amounts") were agreed by each participating
'Annex 1' country, with the intention of reducing the overall emissions by 5.2% from their 1990 levels by the end of
2012. The United States is the only industrialized nation under Annex I that has not ratified the treaty, and is
therefore not bound by it. The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change has projected that the financial effect of
compliance through trading within the Kyoto commitment period will be limited at between 0.1-1.1% of GDP
among trading countries.[37]
Emissions trading 7
The Protocol defines several mechanisms ("flexible mechanisms") that are designed to allow Annex I countries to
meet their emission reduction commitments (caps) with reduced economic impact (IPCC, 2007).[38]
Under Article 3.3 of the Kyoto Protocol, Annex 1 Parties may use GHG removals, from afforestation and
reforestation (forest sinks) and deforestation (sources) since 1990, to meet their emission reduction commitments.[39]
Annex 1 Parties may also use International Emissions Trading (IET). Under the treaty, for the 5-year compliance
period from 2008 until 2012,[40] nations that emit less than their quota will be able to sell Assigned amount units to
nations that exceed their quota.[41] It is also possible for Annex I countries to sponsor carbon projects that reduce
greenhouse gas emissions in other countries. These projects generate tradable carbon credits that can be used by
Annex I countries in meeting their caps. The project-based Kyoto Mechanisms are the Clean Development
Mechanism (CDM) and Joint Implementation (JI).
The CDM covers projects taking place in non-Annex I countries, while JI covers projects taking place in Annex I
countries. CDM projects are supposed to contribute to sustainable development in developing countries, and also
generate "real" and "additional" emission savings, i.e., savings that only occur thanks to the CDM project in question
(Carbon Trust, 2009, p.14).[42] Whether or not these emission savings are genuine is, however, difficult to prove
(World Bank, 2010, pp.265267).[31]
Australia
recommended more support for research into low emissions technologies and a new body to oversee such research. It
also recognised the need for transition assistance for coal mining areas.[53]
In response to Garnaut's draft report, the Rudd Labor government issued a Green Paper[54] on 16 July that described
the intended design of the actual trading scheme.
Subsequent to this, the emission trading scheme proposed by the Government was defeated in the Senate, with the
Opposition, the Greens and two independent senators opposing the proposed legislation.[55]
New Zealand
The New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme (NZ ETS) is a national all-sectors all-greenhouse gases uncapped
emissions trading scheme first legislated in September 2008 by the Fifth Labour Government of New Zealand[56] [57]
and amended in November 2009 by the Fifth National Government of New Zealand.[58]
Although the NZ ETS covers all-sectors and all-gases, individual sectors of the economy have different entry dates
when their obligations to report emissions and surrender emission units have effect. Forestry, a net sink which
contributed removals of 14 Mts of CO2e in 2008 or 19% of NZ's 2008 emissions,[59] entered on 1 January 2008.[60]
Emissions from stationary energy, industrial and liquid fossil fuel sectors (34 Mts in 2008, 45% of 2008
emissions,[59] entered the NZ ETS on 1 July 2010. Agricultural emissions (mainly 35 Mts of methane and nitrous
oxide emissions from pastoral ruminants or 47% of 2008 emissions[59] ) do not enter the scheme until 1 January
2015.[61]
Tradable emission units will be issued by free allocation to emitters, with no auctions in the short term.[62] The
fishing sector will receive free units on a historic basis, 90 per cent of their 2005 emissions (bullet points 9 & 10
MfE September 2009[61] ). Pre-1990 forests will receive a fixed free allocation of 60 emissions units per hectare.[60]
Allocation to emissions-intensive industry,[63] and agriculture[64] will be provided on an output-intensity basis,
which will be based on the industry average emissions per unit of output and will be uncapped.[65] Bertram and
Terry (2010, p 16 ) state that as there is no 'cap' on emissions, the NZ ETS is not a cap and trade scheme as
understood in the economics literature.[66]
A transition period will operate from 1 July 2010 until 31 December 2012. During this period the price of New
Zealand Emissions Units (NZUs) will be capped at NZ$25. Also, one unit will only need to be surrendered for every
two tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent emissions, effectively reducing the carbon price to NZ$12.50 per tonne
(MfE 2009, second bullet point).[61]
Section 3 of the Climate Change Response Act 2002 (the Act) defines the purpose of the Act as to reduce emissions
from business-as-usual-levels and to fulfill New Zealand's international obligations under the United Nations Frame
Work Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) and the Kyoto Protocol.[67] Some stakeholders have criticized the
New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme for its generous free allocations of emission units and the lack of a carbon
price signal (the Parliamentary Commissioner for the Environment),[68] and being ineffective in reducing emissions
(Greenpeace NZ).[69]
European Union
The European Union Emission Trading Scheme (or EU ETS) is the largest multi-national, greenhouse gas emissions
trading scheme in the world. It is one of the EU's central policy instruments to meet their cap set in the Kyoto
Protocol (Jones et al.., 2007, p.64).[70]
After voluntary trials in the UK and Denmark, Phase I commenced operation in January 2005 with all 15 (now 25 of
the 27) member states of the European Union participating.[71] The program caps the amount of carbon dioxide that
can be emitted from large installations with a net heat supply in excess of 20 MW, such as power plants and carbon
intensive factories[72] and covers almost half (46%) of the EU's Carbon Dioxide emissions.[73] Phase I permits
participants to trade amongst themselves and in validated credits from the developing world through Kyoto's Clean
Emissions trading 10
Development Mechanism.
During Phases I and II, allowances for emissions have typically been given free to firms, which has resulted in them
getting windfall profits (CCC, 2008, p.149).[74] Ellerman and Buchner (2008) (referenced by Grubb et al.., 2009,
p.11) suggested that during its first two years in operation, the EU ETS turned an expected increase in emissions of
1-2 percent per year into a small absolute decline.[75] Grubb et al.. (2009, p.11) suggested that a reasonable estimate
for the emissions cut achieved during its first two years of operation was 50-100 MtCO2 per year, or 2.5-5 percent.
A number of design flaws have limited the effectiveness of scheme (Jones et al.., 2007, p.64). In the initial 2005-07
period, emission caps were not tight enough to drive a significant reduction in emissions (CCC, 2008, p.149). The
total allocation of allowances turned out to exceed actual emissions. This drove the carbon price down to zero in
2007. This oversupply reflects the difficulty in predicting future emissions which is necessary in setting a cap.
Phase II saw some tightening, but the use of JI and CDM offsets was allowed, with the result that no reductions in
the EU will be required to meet the Phase II cap (CCC, 2008, pp.145,149). For Phase II, the cap is expected to
result in an emissions reduction in 2010 of about 2.4% compared to expected emissions without the cap
(business-as-usual emissions) (Jones et al.., 2007, p.64). For Phase III (201320), the European Commission has
proposed a number of changes, including:
the setting an overall EU cap, with allowances then allocated to EU members;
tighter limits on the use of offsets;
unlimiting banking of allowances between Phases II and III;
and a move from allowances to auctioning.
In January 2008 Norway, Iceland, and Lichtenstein, joined the European Union Emissions Trading System (EU
ETS) according to a publication from the European Commission.[76] The Norwegian Ministry of the Environment
has also released its draft National Allocation Plan which provides a carbon cap-and-trade of 15 million metric
tonnes of CO2, 8 million of which are set to be auctioned.[77] According to the OECD Economic Survey of Norway
2010, the nation "has announced a target for 2008-12 10% below its commitment under the Kyoto Protocol and a
30% cut compared with 1990 by 2020." [78]
Tokyo, Japan
The Japanese city of Tokyo is like a country in its own right in terms of its energy consumption and GDP. Tokyo
consumes as much energy as "entire countries in Northern Europe, and its production matches the GNP of the
worlds 16th largest country".[79] Originally, Japan had its own cap and trade system that had been in place for some
years, but was not effective.[80] Japan has its own emission reduction policy but not a nationwide cap and trade
program. This climate strategy is enforced and overseen by the Tokyo Metropolitan Government (TMG).[81] The
first phase, which is alike to Japan's scheme, runs up to 2014, these organizations will have to cut their carbon
emissions by 6%; those who fail to operate within their emission caps will from 2011 on be required to purchase
emission allowances to cover any excess emissions, or alternatively, invest in renewable energy certificates or offset
credits issued by smaller businesses or branch offices.[82] Firms whom fail to comply will face fines. According to
local reports, organizations that do not operate within their caps will also be ordered to cut emissions by 1.3 times
the amount they failed to reduce during the first phase of the scheme. The long term aim is to cut the metropolis'
carbon emissions by 25% from 2000 levels by 2020.[83]
United States
An early example of an emission trading system has been the SO2 trading system under the framework of the Acid
Rain Program of the 1990 Clean Air Act in the U.S. Under the program, which is essentially a cap-and-trade
emissions trading system, SO2 emissions were reduced by 50% from 1980 levels by 2007.[84] Some experts argue
that the cap-and-trade system of SO2 emissions reduction has reduced the cost of controlling acid rain by as much as
80% versus source-by-source reduction.[10] [85]
Emissions trading 11
In 1997, the State of Illinois adopted a trading program for volatile organic compounds in most of the Chicago area,
called the Emissions Reduction Market System.[86] Beginning in 2000, over 100 major sources of pollution in eight
Illinois counties began trading pollution credits.
In 2003, New York State proposed and attained commitments from nine Northeast states to form a cap-and-trade
carbon dioxide emissions program for power generators, called the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI). This
program launched on January 1, 2009 with the aim to reduce the carbon "budget" of each state's electricity
generation sector to 10% below their 2009 allowances by 2018.[87]
Also in 2003, U.S. corporations were able to trade CO2 emission allowances on the Chicago Climate Exchange
under a voluntary scheme. In August 2007, the Exchange announced a mechanism to create emission offsets for
projects within the United States that cleanly destroy ozone-depleting substances.[88]
Also in 2003, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) began to administer the NOx Budget Trading Program
(NBP)under the NOx State Implementation Plan (also known as the NOx SIP Call) The NOx Budget Trading
Program was a market-based cap and trade program created to reduce emissions of nitrogen oxides (NOx) from
power plants and other large combustion sources in the eastern United States. NOx is a prime ingredient in the
formation of ground-level ozone (smog), a pervasive air pollution problem in many areas of the eastern United
States. The NBP was designed to reduce NOx emissions during the warm summer months, referred to as the ozone
season, when ground-level ozone concentrations are highest. In March 2008, EPA again strengthened the 8-hour
ozone standard to 0.075 parts per million (ppm) from its previous 0.008 ppm.[89]
In 2006, the California Legislature passed the California Global Warming Solutions Act, AB-32, which was signed
into law by Governor Arnold Schwarzenegger. Thus far, flexible mechanisms in the form of project based offsets
have been suggested for five main project types. A carbon project would create offsets by showing that it has
reduced carbon dioxide and equivalent gases. The project types include: manure management, forestry, building
energy, SF6, and landfill gas capture.
Since February 2007, seven U.S. states and four Canadian provinces have joined together to create the Western
Climate Initiative (WCI),a regional greenhouse gas emissions trading system.[90] July 2010, a meeting took place to
further outline the cap-and-trade system which if accepted would curb greenhouse gas emissions by January
2012.[91]
On November 17, 2008 President-elect Barack Obama clarified, in a talk recorded for YouTube, that the US will
enter a cap-and-trade system to limit global warming.[92]
The 2010 United States federal budget proposes to support clean energy development with a 10-year investment of
US $15 billion per year, generated from the sale of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions credits. Under the proposed
cap-and-trade program, all GHG emissions credits would be auctioned off, generating an estimated $78.7 billion in
additional revenue in FY 2012, steadily increasing to $83 billion by FY 2019.[93]
The American Clean Energy and Security Act(H.R. 2454) , a cap-and-trade bill, was passed on June 26, 2009, in the
House of Representatives by a vote of 219-212. The bill originated in the House Energy and Commerce Committee
and was introduced by Rep. Henry A. Waxman and Rep. Edward J. Markey.[94]
Emissions trading 12
Carbon market
Carbon emissions trading is emissions trading specifically for carbon dioxide (calculated in tonnes of carbon dioxide
equivalent or tCO2e) and currently makes up the bulk of emissions trading. It is one of the ways countries can meet
their obligations under the Kyoto Protocol to reduce carbon emissions and thereby mitigate global warming.
Market trend
Carbon emissions trading has been steadily increasing in recent years. According to the World Bank's Carbon
Finance Unit, 374 million metric tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent (tCO2e) were exchanged through projects in
2005, a 240% increase relative to 2004 (110 mtCO2e)[95] which was itself a 41% increase relative to 2003 (78
mtCO2e).[96]
In terms of dollars, Felipe de Jesus Garduo Vazquez uses the World Bank has estimated that the size of the carbon
market was 11 billion USD in 2005, 30 billion USD in 2006,[95] and 64 billion in 2007.[97]
The Marrakesh Accords of the Kyoto protocol defined the international trading mechanisms and registries needed to
support trading between countries, with allowance trading now occurring between European countries and Asian
countries. However, while the USA as a nation did not ratify the Protocol, many of its states are now developing
cap-and-trade systems and are looking at ways to link their emissions trading systems together, nationally and
internationally, to seek out the lowest costs and improve liquidity of the market.[98] However, these states also wish
to preserve their individual integrity and unique features. For example, in contrast to the other Kyoto-compliant
systems, some states propose other types of greenhouse gas sources, different measurement methods, setting a
maximum on the price of allowances, or restricting access to CDM projects. Creating instruments that are not truly
fungible would introduce instability and make pricing difficult. Various proposals are being investigated to see how
these systems might be linked across markets, with the International Carbon Action Partnership (ICAP) as an
international body to help co-ordinate this.[99] [100]
Business reaction
With the creation of a market for mandatory trading of carbon dioxide emissions within the Kyoto Protocol, the
London financial marketplace has established itself as the center of the carbon finance market, and is expected to
have grown into a market valued at $60 billion in 2007.[101] The voluntary offset market, by comparison, is projected
to grow to about $4bn by 2010.[102]
23 multinational corporations came together in the G8 Climate Change Roundtable, a business group formed at the
January 2005 World Economic Forum. The group included Ford, Toyota, British Airways, BP and Unilever. On
June 9, 2005 the Group published a statement stating that there was a need to act on climate change and stressing the
importance of market-based solutions. It called on governments to establish "clear, transparent, and consistent price
signals" through "creation of a long-term policy framework" that would include all major producers of greenhouse
gases.[103] By December 2007 this had grown to encompass 150 global businesses.[104]
Emissions trading 13
Business in the UK have come out strongly in support of emissions trading as a key tool to mitigate climate change,
supported by NGOs.[105] However, not all businesses favor a trading approach. On December 11, 2008, Rex
Tillerson, the CEO of Exxonmobil, said a carbon tax is "a more direct, more transparent and more effective
approach" than a cap-and-trade program, which he said, "inevitably introduces unnecessary cost and complexity". He
also said that he hoped that the revenues from a carbon tax would be used to lower other taxes so as to be revenue
neutral.[106]
The International Air Transport Association, whose 230 member airlines comprise 93% of all international traffic,
position is that trading should be based on benchmarking, setting emissions levels based on industry averages,
rather than grandfathering, which would use individual companies previous emissions levels to set their future
permit allowances. They argue grandfathering would penalise airlines that took early action to modernise their
fleets, while a benchmarking approach, if designed properly, would reward more efficient operations".[107]
Enforcement
Another significant, yet troublesome aspect is enforcement.[108] Without effective MRV and enforcement the value
of allowances is diminished. Enforcement can be done using several means, including fines or sanctioning those that
have exceeded their allowances. Concerns include the cost of MRV and enforcement and the risk that facilities may
be tempted to mislead rather than make real reductions or make up their shortfall by purchasing allowances or offsets
from another entity. The net effect of a corrupt reporting system or poorly managed or financed regulator may be a
discount on emission costs, and a (hidden) increase in actual emissions.
According to Nordhaus (2007, p.27), strict enforcement of the Kyoto Protocol is likely to be observed in those
countries and industries covered by the EU ETS.[109] Ellerman and Buchner (2007, p.71) commented on the
European Commission's (EC's) role in enforcing scarcity of permits within the EU ETS.[110] This was done by the
EC's reviewing the total number of permits that member states proposed that their industries be allocated. Based on
institutional and enforcement considerations, Kruger et al. (2007, pp.130131) suggested that emissions trading
within developing countries might not be a realistic goal in the near-term.[111] Burniaux et al.. (2008, p.56) argued
that due to the difficulty in enforcing international rules against sovereign states, development of the carbon market
would require negotiation and consensus-building.[112]
Emissions trading 14
Criticisms
Emissions trading has been criticised for a variety of reasons.
In the popular science magazine New Scientist, Lohmann (2006)
argued that trading pollution allowances should be avoided as a climate
change policy. Lohman gave these reasons for this view. First, global
warming will require more radical change than the modest changes
driven by previous pollution trading schemes such as the US SO2
market. Global warming requires "nothing less than a reorganisation of
society and technology that will leave most remaining fossil fuels Chicago Climate Justice activists protesting cap
and trade legislation in front of Chicago Climate
safely underground." Carbon trading schemes have tended to reward
Exchange building in Chicago Loop
the heaviest polluters with 'windfall profits' when they are granted
enough carbon credits to match historic production. Carbon trading
encourages business-as-usual as expensive long-term structural changes won't be made if there is a cheaper source of
carbon credits. Cheap "offset" carbon credits are frequently available from the less developed countries, where they
may be generated by local polluters at the expense of local communities.[113]
Lohmann (2006b) supported conventional regulation, green taxes, and energy policies that are "justice-based" and
"community-driven."[114] According to Carbon Trade Watch (2009), carbon trading has had a "disastrous track
record." The effectiveness of the EU ETS was criticized, and it was argued that the CDM had routinely favoured
"environmentally ineffective and socially unjust projects."[115]
Annie Leonard provided a critical view on carbon emissions trading in her 2009 documentary The Story of Cap and
Trade. This documentary emphasized three factors: unjust financial advantages to major pollutors resulting from free
permits, an ineffectiveness of the system caused by cheating in connection with carbon offsets and a distraction from
the search for other solutions.[116]
Offsets
Forest campaigner Jutta Kill (2006) of European environmental group FERN argued that offsets for emission
reductions were no substitute for actual cuts in emissions. Kill stated that "[carbon] in trees is temporary: Trees can
easily release carbon into the atmosphere through fire, disease, climatic changes, natural decay and timber
harvesting."[117]
Supply of permits
Regulatory agencies run the risk of issuing too many emission credits, which can result in a very low price on
emission permits (CCC, 2008, p.140).[74] This reduces the incentive that permit-liable firms have to cut back their
emissions. On the other hand, issuing too few permits can result in an excessively high permit price (Hepburn, 2006,
p.239).[118] This is one of the arguments in favour of a hybrid instrument, that has a price-floor, i.e., a minimum
permit price, and a price-ceiling, i.e., a limit on the permit price. A price-ceiling (safety value) does, however,
remove the certainty of a particular quantity limit of emissions (Bashmakov et al.., 2001).[119]
Emissions trading 15
Incentives
Emissions trading can result in perverse incentives. If, for example, polluting firms are given emission permits for
free ("grandfathering"), this may create a reason for them not to cut their emissions. This is because a firm making
large cuts in emissions would then potentially be granted fewer emission permits in the future (IMF, 2008,
pp.2526).[120] This perverse incentive can be alleviated if permits are auctioned, i.e., sold to polluters, rather than
giving them the permits for free (Hepburn, 2006, pp.236237).[118]
On the other hand, allocating permits can be used as a measure to protect domestic firms who are internationally
exposed to competition (p.237). This happens when domestic firms compete against other firms that are not subject
to the same regulation. This argument in favour of allocation of permits has been used in the EU ETS, where
industries that have been judged to be internationally exposed, e.g., cement and steel production, have been given
permits for free (4CMR, 2008).[121]
Auctioning
The revenues from auctioning go to the government. These revenues could, for example, be used for research and
development of sustainable technology.[122] Alternatively, revenues could be used to cut distortionary taxes, thus
improving the efficiency of the overall cap policy (Fisher et al.., 1996, p.417).[123]
Distributional effects
The Congressional Budget Office (CBO, 2009) examined the potential effects of the American Clean Energy and
Security Act on US households.[124] This Act relies heavily on the free allocation of permits. The Bill was found to
protect low-income consumers, but it was recommended that the Bill be changed to be more efficient. It was
suggested that the Bill be changed to reduce welfare provisions for corporations, and more resources be made
available for consumer relief.
References
[1] Stavins, Robert N. (November 2001). "Experience with Market-Based Environmental Policy Instruments" (http:/ / www. rff. org/ documents/
RFF-DP-01-58. pdf). Discussion Paper 01-58 (Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future). . Retrieved 2010-05-20. "Market-based
instruments are regulations that encourage behavior through market signals rather than through explicit directives regarding pollution control
levels or methods".
[2] Montgomery, W.D. "Markets in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs". Journal of Economic Theory 5 (December
1972):395-418
[3] EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) (http:/ / www. decc. gov. uk/ en/ content/ cms/ what_we_do/ change_energy/ tackling_clima/
emissions/ eu_ets/ eu_ets. aspx). UK Department of Energy and Climate Change. Retrieved 2009-01-19.
[4] "USEPA's Clean Air Markets web site" (http:/ / www. epa. gov/ airmarkets/ ). US EPA. . Retrieved 2009-11-03.
[5] Cap and Trade 101 (http:/ / www. americanprogress. org/ issues/ 2008/ 01/ capandtrade101. html), Center for American Progress, January 16,
2008.
[6] Sullivan, Arthur, and Steven M. Sheffrin. Economics: Principles in action. Upper Saddle River, NJ, 2003. ISBN 0130630853
[7] Judson Jaffe, Matthew Ranson and Robert N. Stavins (2009). "Linking Tradable Permit Systems: A Key Element of Emerging International
Climate Policy Architecture" (http:/ / www. boalt. org/ elq/ documents/ elq36-4-01-jaffe-2009-1209. pdf). Ecology Law Quarterly 36 (789). .
Retrieved 2010-08-25.
[8] Tietenberg Tom (2003). "The Tradable-Permits Approach to Protecting the Commons: Lessons for Climate Change" (http:/ / oxrep.
oxfordjournals. org/ cgi/ reprint/ 19/ 3/ 400?ijkey=324rjCyD25Jfk& keytype=ref). Oxford Review of Economic Policy 19 (3): 400419.
doi:10.1093/oxrep/19.3.400. . Retrieved 2010-08-25.
[9] Stavins, Robert N. (November 2001). Experience with Market-Based Environmental Policy Instruments (http:/ / www. rff. org/ documents/
RFF-DP-01-58. pdf). Discussion Paper 01-58. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future. . Retrieved 2010-08-25.
[10] Stavins, Robert N (1998). "What Can We Learn from the Grand Policy Experiment? Lessons from SO2 Allowance Trading" (http:/ / www.
jstor. org/ stable/ 2647033). The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 3 (American Economic Association) 12 (3): 6988. .
[11] Bryner, Gary C. Blue Skies, Green Politics: the Clean Air Act of 1990. Washington D.C.:Congressional Quarterly Inc., 1951.
[12] Burton, Ellison; Sanjour, William (1967). "An Economic Analysis of the Control of Sulphur Oxides Air Pollution". DHEW Program
Analysis Report No. 1967-69 (Washington, DC: Ernst and Ernst).
Emissions trading 16
[13] Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1968). A Cost-Effectiveness Study of Particulate and SOx Emission Control in the New York
Metropolitan Area. NTIS: PB-227 121/1. Contract Number: PH-86-68-37. Washington, DC: Ernst and Ernst.
[14] Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1969). A Cost-Effectiveness Study of Air Pollution Abatement in the Greater Kansas City Area.
NTIS: PB-227 116/1. Washington, DC: Ernst and Ernst.
[15] Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1969). A Cost-effectiveness Study of Air Pollution Abatement in the National Capital Area. NAPCA
Contract No. PH 86-68-37, NTIS: PB227110. Washington, DC: Ernst and Ernst.
[16] Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1970). Applications of Cost-effectiveness Analysis to Air Pollution Control. DHEW Contract No.
CPA 22-69-17. Washington, DC: Ernst and Ernst.
[17] Burton, Ellison; Sanjour, William (1969-03). "Multiple Source Analysis of Air Pollution Abatement Strategies" (http:/ / home. comcast. net/
~jurason/ anonftp/ Multiple Source Analysis of Air Pollution Abatement Strategies. pdf). Federal Accountant XVIII: 4869. .
[18] Burton, E. S.; William (1970). "A Simulation Approach to Air Pollution Abatement Program Planning" (http:/ / home. comcast. net/
~jurason/ anonftp/ A Simulation Approach to Air Pollution Abatement Program Planning. pdf). Socio-Economic Planning Science 4:
147150. doi:10.1016/0038-0121(70)90036-4. .
[19] Voss, Jan-Peter (2007-06). "Innovation processes in governance: the development of emissions trading as a new policy instrument" (http:/ /
www. ingentaconnect. com/ content/ beech/ spp/ 2007/ 00000034/ 00000005/ art00003). Science and Public Policy. 5 (Ingentaconnect) 34:
329343. doi:10.3152/030234207X228584. . Retrieved 2009-11-03.
[20] Coase, Ronald H. 1960. The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and Economics. 3:1-44.
[21] Crocker, T. D. (1966). The Structuring of Atmospheric Pollution Control Systems. The Economics of Air Pollution. H. Wolozin. New York,
W. W. Norton & Co.: 61-86.
[22] Dales, John H. 1968. Land, Water, and Ownership (http:/ / www. jstor. org/ pss/ 133706). The Canadian Journal of Economics,
1(4):791-804.
[23] Montgomery, W David. 1972. Markets in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs (http:/ / www. sciencedirect. com/ science/
article/ B6WJ3-4CYGBY2-PD/ 2/ 8497b83217afcb9dd9197f22fb18ac5b), Journal of Economic Theory 5(3):395-418.
[24] Tietenberg, Tom; Johnstone, Nick (2004). "ExPost Evaluation of Tradeable Permits: Methodological Issues and Literature Review" (http:/ /
books. google. co. nz/ books?hl=en& lr=& id=I9Q1HHd4UNQC& oi=fnd& pg=PA9& dq="Tietenberg"+ "Ex+ post+ evaluation+ of+
tradeable+ permits:+ methodological+ . . . "+ & ots=DRG5-3jVMr& sig=-KQEL-bOW1YsZy-blPMQlvZ1okY#v=onepage& q=& f=false).
Tradeable Permits: Policy Evaluation, Design And Reform. OECD Publishing. ISBN9789264015029. .
[25] Chomitz, Kenneth M (1999). "Evaluating Carbon Offsets from Forestry and Energy Projects: How Do They Compare?" (http:/ / papers.
ssrn. com/ sol3/ papers. cfm?abstract_id=630729). Policy Research Working Paper Series. 2357. The World Bank. .
[26] Map: Pollution hotspots (http:/ / news. bbc. co. uk/ 2/ hi/ science/ nature/ 4083331. stm), BBC map of areas that suffer from intense local
pollution, BBC News, 2004-12-13. Retrieved 2009-10-19.
[27] "Chicago Climate Exchange prices" (http:/ / www. chicagoclimatex. com/ ). Chicagoclimatex.com. 2009-08-04. . Retrieved 2009-11-03.
[28] Weitzman, M. L. (1974-10)). "Prices vs. Quantities" (http:/ / www. jstor. org/ pss/ 2296698). The Review of Economic Studies (The Review
of Economic Studies Ltd.) 41 (4): 477491. doi:10.2307/2296698. .
[29] Philibert, Cdric (2006-10). "Certainty versus ambition economic efficiency in mitigating climate change" (http:/ / www. iea. org/ textbase/
papers/ 2006/ certainty_ambition. pdf). International Energy Agency Working Paper Series (Paris: International Energy Agency/OECD)
LTO/2006/03. . Retrieved 2010-01-24.
[30] Jacoby, D.H.; Ellerman, A.D. (2004-03). "The safety valve and climate policy" (http:/ / dspace. mit. edu/ handle/ 1721. 1/ 3561). Energy
Policy (Sciencedirect.com) 32 (4): 48149. doi:10.1016/S0301-4215(03)00150-2. . Retrieved 2009-11-03.
[31] World Bank (2010). "World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate Change" (http:/ / go. worldbank. org/ BKLQ9DSDU0).
The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433. . Retrieved
2010-04-06.
[32] Barker, T. et al. (2007). "11.7.2 Carbon leakage. In (book chapter): Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective. In (book): Climate Change
2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B.
Metz et al. Eds.)" (http:/ / www. ipcc. ch/ publications_and_data/ ar4/ wg3/ en/ ch11s11-7-2. html). Print version: Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. . Retrieved 2010-04-05.
[33] Goldemberg, J. et al. (1996) (PDF). Introduction: scope of the assessment. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of
Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change
(J.P. Bruce et al. Eds.) (http:/ / www. ipcc. ch/ ipccreports/ sar/ wg_III/ ipcc_sar_wg_III_full_report. pdf). This version: Printed by Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. PDF version: IPCC website. doi:10.2277/0521568544.
ISBN9780521568548. .
[34] Barker, T. et al. (2007). "Executive Summary. In (book chapter): Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective. In (book): Climate Change
2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B.
Metz et al. Eds.)" (http:/ / www. ipcc. ch/ publications_and_data/ ar4/ wg3/ en/ ch11s11-es. html). Print version: Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. . Retrieved 2010-04-05.
[35] Houser, Trevor; Rob Bradley, Britt Childs Staley, Jake Werksman, Robert Heilmayr (2008). Leveling The Carbon Playing Field:
International Competition and U.S. Climate Policy Design (http:/ / www. wri. org/ publication/ leveling-the-carbon-playing-field). Peterson
Institute for International Economics. .
[36] "Kyoto Protocol" (http:/ / unfccc. int/ kyoto_protocol/ items/ 2830. php). UNFCCC website. . Retrieved 2009-09-16.
Emissions trading 17
[37] "Climate Change 2007: Mitigation of Climate Change, Summary for Policymakers from [[IPCC Fourth Assessment Report (http:/ / web.
archive. org/ web/ 20070518152103/ http:/ / www. mnp. nl/ ipcc/ docs/ FAR/ Approved+ SPM+ WGIII_0705rev5. pdf)]"] (PDF). Working
Group III, IPCC. 2007-05-04. pp. Item 25, page 33. Archived from the original (http:/ / www. mnp. nl/ ipcc/ docs/ FAR/ Approved SPM
WGIII_0705rev5. pdf) on May 18, 2007. . Retrieved 2007-05-10.
[38] IPCC (2007). "Glossary J-P. In (book section): Annex I. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the
Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. Eds.)" (http:/ / www. ipcc. ch/
publications_and_data/ ar4/ wg3/ en/ annex1sglossary-j-p. html). Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y.,
U.S.A.. . Retrieved 2010-04-23.
[39] "LULUCF under the Kyoto Protocol" (http:/ / unfccc. int/ methods_and_science/ lulucf/ items/ 4129. php). UNFCCC website. . Retrieved
2010-04-28.
[40] "UNFCCC Countries 1990 to 2012 emissions targets" (http:/ / unfccc. int/ kyoto_protocol/ background/ items/ 3145. php). UNFCCC
website. 2008-05-14. . Retrieved 2009-11-03.
[41] "Emissions Trading" (http:/ / unfccc. int/ kyoto_protocol/ mechanisms/ emissions_trading/ items/ 2731. php). UNFCCC website. . Retrieved
2009-09-16.
[42] Carbon Trust (March 2009). "Global Carbon Mechanisms: Emerging lessons and implications (CTC748)" (http:/ / www. carbontrust. co. uk/
Publications/ pages/ publicationdetail. aspx?id=CTC748& respos=2& q=global+ carbon+ market& o=Rank& od=asc& pn=0& ps=10).
Carbon Trust website. . Retrieved 2010-03-31.
[43] Deborah White (2010). "George Bush Refuses to Sign Kyoto Protocol to Stem Global Warming" (http:/ / usliberals. about. com/ od/
environmentalconcerns/ p/ KyotoProtocol. htm). About.com (The New York Times Company). . Retrieved 2010-11-06.
[44] http:/ / www. american. com/ archive/ 2009/ november/ the-quiet-yet-historic-death-of-the-kyoto-protoco
[45] Adam, David (2009-09-15). "US planning to weaken Copenhagen climate deal, Europe warns" (http:/ / www. guardian. co. uk/
environment/ 2009/ sep/ 15/ europe-us-copenhagen). The Guardian (London). .
[46] "The Greenhouse Gas Reduction Scheme" (http:/ / greenhousegas. nsw. gov. au/ ). NSW: Greenhouse Gas Reduction Scheme
Administrator. 2010-01-04. . Retrieved 2010-01-16.
[47] Passey, Rob; MacGill, Iain; Outhred, Hugh (2007). "The NSW Greenhouse Gas Reduction Scheme: An analysis of the NGAC Registry for
the 2003, 2004 and 2005 Compliance Periods" (http:/ / www. ceem. unsw. edu. au/ content/ userDocs/ CEEM_DP_070827_000. pdf). CEEM
discussion paper DP_070822. Sydney: The UNSW Centre for Energy and Environmental Markets (CEEM). . Retrieved 2009-11-03.
[48] Farr, Malcolm (2007-06-04). "Howard flying blind on climate" (http:/ / web. archive. org/ web/ 20071013133557/ http:/ / news. com. au/
heraldsun/ story/ 0,21985,21844556-5005961,00. html). Herald Sun. Archived from the original (http:/ / www. news. com. au/ heraldsun/
story/ 0,21985,21844556-5005961,00. html) on October 13, 2007. . Retrieved 2009-04-03.
[49] "Australian Carbon Trade to Boost Affordable Energy" (http:/ / www. planetark. com/ dailynewsstory. cfm/ newsid/ 48946/ story. htm).
Planet Ark. 2008-06-24. . Retrieved 2009-04-03.
[50] Smith, Peter (2009-05-05). "Rudd delays carbon trading" (http:/ / www. ft. com/ cms/ s/ 0/ 8fe917cc-390c-11de-8cfe-00144feabdc0. html).
The Financial Times. . Retrieved 2009-11-03.
[51] Department of Climate Change and Energy Efficiency (2010-05-05). "Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme" (http:/ / www. climatechange.
gov. au/ en/ media/ whats-new/ cprs-delayed. aspx). Press release. . Retrieved 2010-06-14.
[52] "Garnaut Climate Change Review" (http:/ / www. garnautreview. org. au/ CA25734E0016A131/ WebObj/
GarnautClimateChangeReviewInterimReport-Feb08/ $File/ Garnaut Climate Change Review Interim Report - Feb 08. pdf) (PDF). . Retrieved
2009-11-03.
[53] "Garnaut Review" (http:/ / www. garnautreview. org. au/ domino/ Web_Notes/ Garnaut/ garnautweb. nsf). Garnaut Review. . Retrieved
2009-11-03.
[54] "Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme Green Paper" (http:/ / web. archive. org/ web/ 20080822225451/ http:/ / www. greenhouse. gov. au/
greenpaper/ index. html). Greenhouse.gov.au. 2009-10-14. Archived from the original (http:/ / www. greenhouse. gov. au/ greenpaper/ index.
html) on August 22, 2008. . Retrieved 2009-11-03.
[55] Emma Rodgers (2009-12-02). "Senate kills off emissions trade laws" (http:/ / www. abc. net. au/ news/ stories/ 2009/ 12/ 02/ 2759595. htm).
Australian Broadcasting Corporation. . Retrieved 2010-07-29.
[56] Parker, David (2008-09-10). "Historic climate change legislation passes" (http:/ / www. beehive. govt. nz/ release/ historic+ climate+
change+ legislation+ passes). New Zealand Government Media Release. . Retrieved 2008-09-10.
[57] "Climate Change Response (Emissions Trading) Amendment Act 2008 No 85" (http:/ / www. legislation. govt. nz/ act/ public/ 2008/ 0085/
latest/ DLM1130932. html). www.legislation.govt.nz. Parliamentary Counsel Office. 2008-09-25. . Retrieved 2010-01-25.
[58] Nick Smith (2009-11-25). "Balanced new law important step on climate change" (http:/ / beehive. govt. nz/ release/ balanced+ new+ law+
important+ step+ climate+ change). New Zealand Government Press Release. . Retrieved 2010-06-14.
[59] MfE (April 2010). New Zealands Greenhouse Gas Inventory 19902008 (http:/ / www. mfe. govt. nz/ publications/ climate/
greenhouse-gas-inventory-2010/ index. html). ME 1009. Ministry for the Environment. ISSN1179-223X. . Retrieved 2010-05-22
[60] MfE (2010-01-14). "How will the changes impact on forestry?" (http:/ / www. climatechange. govt. nz/ emissions-trading-scheme/
questions-and-answers-amendment-act. html#forestry). Questions and answers about amendments to the New Zealand Emissions Trading
Scheme (ETS). Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government (www.climatechange.govt.nz). . Retrieved 2010-05-16.
[61] MfE (September 2009). "Summary of the proposed changes to the NZ ETS" (http:/ / www. mfe. govt. nz/ publications/ climate/
emissions-trading-bulletin-11/ index. html#summary). Emissions trading bulletin No 11. Ministry for the Environment (MfE), NZ
Emissions trading 18
[82] Tokyo kicks off carbon trading scheme (http:/ / www. guardian. co. uk/ environment/ 2010/ apr/ 08/ tokyo-carbon-trading-schemeTokyo/ ),
April, 2010.
[83] [Tokyo kicks off carbon trading scheme (http:/ / www. guardian. co. uk/ environment/ 2010/ apr/ 08/ tokyo-carbon-trading-schemeTokyo/ ),
April, 2010.
[84] Acid Rain Program 2007 Progress Report (http:/ / www. epa. gov/ airmarkt/ progress/ arp07. html), U.S. Environmental Protection Agency,
January 2009.
[85] Carlson, Curtis, Dallas Burtraw, Maureen Cropper, and Karen L. Palmer. 2000. Sulfur dioxide control by electric utilities: What are the
gains from trade? Journal of Political Economy 108: 1292-1326.
[86] "Emissions Reduction Market System What Is ERMS?" (http:/ / www. epa. state. il. us/ air/ erms/ ). Illinois EPA. 2007. .
[87] Memorandum of Understanding (http:/ / www. rggi. org/ docs/ mou_12_20_05. pdf) - Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative
[88] Beyond the Kyoto six (http:/ / www. carbon-financeonline. com/ index. cfm?section=features& id=11092& action=view& return=home)
Carbon Finance 7 March 2008
[89] (http:/ / www. epa. gov/ airmarkets/ progsregs/ nox/ sip. html), Environmental Protection Agency, August 13, 2010
[90] (http:/ / www. westernclimateinitiative. org/ index. php) Western Climate Initiative}
[91] California, New Mexico and 3 Canadian provinces outline regional cap-and-trade program (http:/ / articles. latimes. com/ 2010/ jul/ 28/
local/ la-me-climate-pact-20100728), Los Angeles Times, July 28, 2010
[92] 17 novembre 2008. "YouTube A New Chapter on Climate Change" (http:/ / it. youtube. com/ watch?v=hvG2XptIEJk). It.youtube.com. .
Retrieved 2009-04-03.
[93] "President's Budget Draws Clean Energy Funds from Climate Measure" (http:/ / www. renewableenergyworld. com/ rea/ news/ article/
2009/ 03/ presidents-budget-draws-clean-energy-funds-from-climate-measure?cmpid=WNL-Friday-March6-2009). Renewable Energy World.
. Retrieved 2009-04-03.
[94] "The American Clean Energy and Security Act (H.R. 2454)" (http:/ / energycommerce. house. gov/ index. php?option=com_content&
view=article& id=1633& catid=155& Itemid=55). Energycommerce.house.gov. 2009-06-01. . Retrieved 2010-06-14.
[95] "Carbon Finance" (http:/ / carbonfinance. org/ docs/ StateoftheCarbonMarket2006. pdf). Carbon Finance. 2009-01-15. . Retrieved
2009-04-03.
[96] "Microsoft Word Carbon Market Study 2005 - FINAL Letter.doc" (http:/ / carbonfinance. org/ docs/ CarbonMarketStudy2005. pdf).
Carbonfinance.org. 2009-01-15. . Retrieved 2009-04-03.
[97] "Carbon Finance" (http:/ / carbonfinance. org/ docs/ State___Trends--formatted_06_May_10pm. pdf). Carbon Finance. 2009-01-15. .
Retrieved 2009-04-03.
[98] Stavins, Robert N., and Judson Jaffe (2008). Linkage of Tradable Permit Systems in International Climate Policy Architecture, Harvard
Project on International Climate Agreements. (http:/ / belfercenter. ksg. harvard. edu/ publication/ 18580/ )
[99] International Carbon Action Partnership (http:/ / www. icapcarbonaction. com/ ) ICAP website
[100] Linkage of Tradable Permit Systems in International Climate Policy Architecture (http:/ / belfercenter. ksg. harvard. edu/ publication/
18580/ ) Robert N. Stavins and Judson Jaffe, Harvard Project on International Climate Agreements
[101] "Point Carbon news" (http:/ / www. pointcarbon. com). Pointcarbon.com. . Retrieved 2009-11-03.
[102] The carbon market (http:/ / www. ft. com/ cms/ s/ 2/
282b278c-f4db-11db-b748-000b5df10621,dwp_uuid=3c093daa-edc1-11db-8584-000b5df10621. html) Fiona Harvey, FT April 27, 2007
[103] http:/ / www. weforum. org/ pdf/ g8_climatechange. pdf
[104] List of climate leaders (http:/ / www. epa. gov/ climateleaders/ partners/ ) EPA December 12
[105] "Appendix C: UK Position on the EU Emissions Trading Scheme" (http:/ / www. berr. gov. uk/ files/ file39578. pdf) (PDF). Meeting the
Energy Challenge A White Paper on Energy May 2007. UK Department of Trade and Industry. . Retrieved 2009-11-03.
[106] "Exxon supports carbon tax" (http:/ / www. canada. com/ calgaryherald/ news/ calgarybusiness/ story.
html?id=e8aecbbb-16c6-412d-8054-7e64e2b176ef). Calgary Herald News. 2009-01-09. .
[107] "What You Need to Know About Emissions Trading" (http:/ / web. archive. org/ web/ 20070303092647/ http:/ / www. iata. org/ NR/
rdonlyres/ 95D34D98-7906-4A23-8884-1FA561709037/ 53257/ EmissionsTrading. pdf). International Air Transport Association. Archived
from the original (http:/ / www. iata. org/ NR/ rdonlyres/ 95D34D98-7906-4A23-8884-1FA561709037/ 53257/ EmissionsTrading. pdf) on
March 3, 2007. . Retrieved 2009-09-26.
[108] Ott, Hermann E. (1998-10-26). "Emissions Trading in the Kyoto Protocol, Finished and Unfinished Business" (http:/ / www. iisd. ca/
journal/ ott. html). Linkages Journal. 4 3. .
[109] Nordhaus, W.D. (2007). "To Tax of Not to Tax: Alternative Approaches to Slowing Global Warming" (http:/ / www. oxfordjournals. org/
our_journals/ reep/ press_releases/ freepdf/ issue1. pdf). Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (1). . Retrieved 2010-04-28.
[110] Ellerman, A.D. and B.K. Buchner (2007). "The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocation, and Early Results" (http:/
/ www. oxfordjournals. org/ our_journals/ reep/ press_releases/ freepdf/ issue1. pdf). Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (1). .
Retrieved 2010-04-28.
[111] Kruger, J. et al. (2007). "Decentralization in the EU Emissions Trading Scheme and Lessons for Global Policy" (http:/ / www.
oxfordjournals. org/ our_journals/ reep/ press_releases/ freepdf/ issue1. pdf). Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 1 (1). .
Retrieved 2010-04-28.
[112] Burniaux, J-M. et al. (6 June 2009). The Economics of Climate Change Mitigation: How to Build the Necessary Global Action in a
Cost-Effective Manner (http:/ / appli1. oecd. org/ olis/ 2009doc. nsf/ linkto/ eco-wkp(2009)42). Economics Department Working Papers No.
Emissions trading 20
Further reading
Chichilnisky, C. and G. Heal (eds) (2000). "Environmental Markets: Equity and Efficiency" (http://www.
chichilnisky.com/publication.php). Print version: Columbia University Press, New York, Chichester, West
Sussex. Web version: Graciela Chichilnisky's website. Retrieved 2010-05-12.
Gilbertson, T. and O. Reyes (1 November 2009). "Carbon Trading: how it works and why it fails" (http://www.
carbontradewatch.org/publications/carbon-trading-how-it-works-and-why-it-fails.html). Dag Hammerskjold
Foundation. Retrieved 2010-05-14.
IEA (2005). "Act Locally, Trade Globally- Emissions Trading for Climate Policy" (http://www.iea.org/
publications/free_new_Desc.asp?PUBS_ID=1579). International Energy Agency (IEA), Head of Publications
Service, 9 rue de la Fdration, 75739 Paris Cedex 15, France. p. 236. Retrieved 2010-05-12.
Lin Feng and Jason Buhi (2009). "Emissions Trading Across China: Incorporating Hong Kong and Macau into an
Urgently Needed Air Pollution Control Regime Under 'One Country, Two Systems'" (http://papers.ssrn.com/
sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1441395). Florida State University Journal of Transnational Law & Policy, Vol.
19, 2009. Retrieved 2010-10-17.
Norregaard, J. and V. Reppelin-Hill (1 January 2000). "Taxes and Tradable Permits as Instruments for
Controlling Pollution: Theory and Practice. Working Paper No. 00/13" (http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/
cat/longres.cfm?sk=3411.0). International Monetary Fund, Fiscal Affairs Department. Retrieved 2010-05-12.
Reinaud, J. and C. Philibert (22 November 2007). "Emissions trading: trends and prospects" (http://www.iea.
org/publications/free_new_Desc.asp?PUBS_ID=2001). International Energy Agency website. p. 43. Retrieved
Emissions trading 21
2010-05-12.
External links
Q&A with Dr. Daniel Fine on Cap and Trade legislation and policy (http://www.opednews.com/Diary/
Dr-Daniel-Fine-on-Cap-and-by-Helen-Fine-090617-238.html)
Dr. Daniel Fine of the New Mexico Center for Energy Policy on Cap and Trade (http://nmcep.nmt.edu/index.
php/NMCEP-and-Related-News/cap-and-trade-changing-everything.html)
Emissions Trading and CDM (http://www.iea.org/subjectqueries/keyresult.asp?KEYWORD_ID=4124)
International Energy Agency website
Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading (http://www.oecd.org/env/cc/emissiontrading) Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development website
US EPA's Acid Rain Program (http://www.epa.gov/airmarkets/progsregs/arp/index.html)
Illinois Emissions Reduction Market System (http://www.epa.state.il.us/air/erms/)
Texas Emissions Banking and Trading program (http://www.tceq.state.tx.us/permitting/air/nav/
air_banking.html)
"The Making of a Market-Minded Environmentalist" (http://www.strategy-business.com/press/article/
08201?pg=0), article by Fred Krupp in Strategy+Business (registration reqd) that articulates some of the
reasoning and history behind emissions trading in California
International Emissions Trading Association (http://www.ieta.org/)
EU-ETS for airlines (http://www.aviaso.com/)
Article Sources and Contributors 22
License
Creative Commons Attribution-Share Alike 3.0 Unported
http:/ / creativecommons. org/ licenses/ by-sa/ 3. 0/