Laws of Production and Laws of Algebra: Humbug II: Essays in The Revival of Political Economy
Laws of Production and Laws of Algebra: Humbug II: Essays in The Revival of Political Economy
Humbug II
Chapter 5 of: Edward J. Nell (ed.), Growth, profits, and property.
Essays in the Revival of Political Economy,
Cambridge University Press, 1980
Shaikh
The theoretical basis modity other things being equal -the lower its
relative price.
Recent debates on capital theory have focused The next step in the analysis requires its
on the notion of capital as a factor of production, to the case of production. Initial endow-
which along with labor, to ments are now assumed to contain not just con-
the in sumer goods but also means of production, such
Though the intricate point and counterpoint of as land, machines, raw materials, etc.; in addi-
the controversy often obscure this simple fact, it tion, since the game cannot continue unless
has become increasingly clear that what is at every individual has at least some wealth, it is
stake in the current debate is in essence the generally assumed that each and every initial en-
same issue with which the classical economists, dowment includes potentially saleable labor ser-
particularly Ricardo, grappled that of the divi- vices. By assumption, the ultimate objective of
sion of income between wages and profits. The every individual is consumption: means of pro-
argument thus rages around eco- duction and labor services, however, are not
nomic theory, whose aim it is to represent the directly consumable. At this point, therefore,
workings of a competitive capitalist economy. In production is introduced as a roundabout way of
a sense this is a return to relevance, since much consumption, a process in which inputs are
of modern mathematical economics has stu- transformed into outputs. In order to translate
diously concerned itself, not with descriptive. any given initial endowment into the production
but instead with normative theory, such as the possibilities inherent in it. neoclassical econom-
study of optimal and efficient growth paths, etc.. ics commonly relies on the assumption of a well
(Lancaster, 1968, pp. 9-10). behaved neoclassical production function, one
In neoclassical theory, the model of pure ex- for each commodity produced.
change occupies a central position, for it illus- Each individual then faces three basic
trates simply and elegantly the fundamental methods of arriving at some preferred final allo-
truths of the paradigm, truths which any more cation, methods which he or she is free to use in
complex representations may modify but cer- any combination permitted by the initial endow-
tainly cannot undermine. Thus, in the model of ment and consistent with the utility function.
exchange. trading begins with selfish indi- First, he can trade any of the
viduals each having an arbitrarily determined means of production in his possession for other
initial endowment of goods, and proceeds to a goods he desires; second, he may rent out the
final state in which no one individual can im- n f
prove his or her basket of commodities without and/or rent out his labor power: and third, if his
making someone else worse off. Such a situation
is known as a pareto-optimal allocation, and it
implies a set of final exchange ratios between
This chapter is an expanded, revised version of a
commodities that is, a set of
paper entitled Laws of Production and Laws of
tive prices. What is more, given The Humbug which
of well-behaved neoclassical utility functions for appeared as a note in of
each individual, the equilibrium prices of the Vol. LVI, No. 1 (February, pp.
model of exchange will along with comment by Robert The
the higher the relative availability of some postscript to this chapter assesses comment.
81
initial endowment so permits, he may choose to tures most problematical gifts the natural
become a producer, renting and/or buying selfishness of every individual!
means of production and labor-power and com-
bining these with the elements of his initial en-
dowment to turn out one or more commodities Scarcity pricing parables and the aggregate
via a well-behaved neoclassical production func- production function
tion. Ruled only by his enlightened self-interest,
which dictates that more is better, and con- Traditionally, several models have been used to
strained only by his native abilities and initial en- extend scarcity pricing to the theory of distribu-
dowment, he is assumed to eventually arrive at tion. The simplest, and by far the most widely
some most efficient combination of the used in both the theoretical and empirical litera-
trader-rentier-producer modes, t h e r e b y a t - ture, is the aggregate production function model.
taining his personal optimum in the form of some we is an aggregated ver-
final allocation. sion of the general equilibrium model outlined
Because preferences (utility functions) and above, constructed as an empirically useful
initial endowments are of the analy- approximation, supported the
sis, the whole structure of equilibrium is ruled Even the sophisticates, the so-called
by them, so that once again, the forces of con- high-brows of neoclassical theory, at one time,
sumer sovereignty lead us ineluctably to took this and similar parables seriously:
Pareto-optimality . Equilibrium relative prices . . . In various places I have subjected to de-
are once again prices, a term which now tailed analysis certain simplified models in-
covers the prices of consumption goods, the volving only a few factors of production . . .
wage rate for labor services, and the rental [These] simple models or parables do. I think.
sale prices of means of production (Hershleifer, have considerable heuristic value in giving in-
1970). sights into the fundamentals of interest theory
Under carefully fashioned assumptions in- in all of its complexities. (Samuelson, 1962,
volving well-behaved utility and production
functions, these sorts of models are determinate The originators of the production func-
in the sense that one or more possible equilibria tion theory of distribution (in the static
can be shown to exist. But the model, as out- sense, where I still think it should be taken
lined here, contains no reference to the uniform fairly seriously) were Wicksteed, Edgeworth,
rate of profit which is supposed to characterize and Pigou. (Hicks, 1965, p. 293, footnote 1)
competitive capitalism. The explanation of this Though aggregate or surrogate production
rate of profit is what (descriptive) neoclassical function models occupy the bulk of the theoreti-
capital theory is all about. Moreover, given that cal and empirical literature on the distribution of
the basic parables of the theory have already income in a capitalist society, the essential char-
identified the equilibrium price of every good or acteristic of this and all other parables of neo-
service as a scarcity price, one that reflects its classical theory concerns their attempt to ex-
individual and social scarcity, the task that con- plain the wage rate and the rate of profit as scar-
fronts the theory is clear: somehow, the rate of city prices of labor and capital, respectively,
profit too must be explained as the scarcity price determined in the final analysis by efficiency
of some thing with both the price and quantity of considerations. It was precisely this techno-
this thing to be mutually determined in some cratic apologia for capitalism which became the
market. This market, it turns out, is the capital target of the neo-Keynesian counterattack of
market, in which demand is determined by indi- the during the so-called Cambridge cap-
viduals preferences for present versus future ital controversies.
consumption their taste for investment One of the most striking, and for neoclassical
(Dewey, 1965) and supply is determined by the economics most devastating, results of the
technological structure. The price that suppos- above capital controversies was the proof that
edly emerges from this interaction is the of version of the neoclassical parable, in which
interest, the scarcity index of the quantity of the rate of profit varied inversely with the quan-
and with the addition of a few more con- tity of capital and the wage rate inversely with
venient assumptions, the rate of profit is made the quantity of labor (so that each at least be-
equal to this rate of interest. haved like a scarcity price) was valid in static
cun then, it is argued, the distri- conditions prices in possible
bution in is competitive equilibria were proportional to labor
sequence the values. I apply,
in fact, within this wondrous construct, capital- to that particular version of the parable
ism itself represents the resolution of one of known as the aggregate (or surrogate)
82 Shaikh
tion function, in which the wage rate and the rate former can be most generally described as fitting
of profit not only move inversely to the quan- a function of the Q(t) = to
tities of labor and capital, respectively, but are observed data while the latter consists of
also equal to and determined by their respective that aggregate marginal products of capital
marginal products. Considering that the neoclas- and labor are equal to their respective unit
sical in a
counterrevolution the classical school, ify structural coefficients. In general, for both
against Ricardo and Marx in particular (Dobb, time series and cross-section data, the
1970, p. and above all, against the labor Douglas function wins out: the sum of coeffi-
theory of value in form, it is gratifying to dis- cients usually approximate closely to unity
cover in the end these parables themselves (thus implying constant returns to scale), with
depend on the simple labor theory of value. The the additional bonus of a close agreement
irony is inescapable. between the labor exponent and the share of
These and other inimical results were not lost wages in the value of output (thus support-
on the faithful. As awareness of the internal in- ing aggregate marginal productivity theory)
consistencies of neoclassical theory began to (Walters, 1963, p. 27).
grow, many were led to abandon it. But for In a recent paper, Franklin Fisher concedes
others, hope died hard; and hope, it seems, lay that the requirements under which the produc-
in the data. As a neoclassical theorist, can tion possibilities of a technically diverse
only that the relevant question is what is economy can be represented by an aggregate
relevant: should we make our predictions on the production function are far too stringent to be
basis of what Mrs. Robinson has called perverse believable (Fisher, 1971, p. 306). He proposes
technical behavior the therefore to investigate the puzzling uniformity
that been repeatedly of the empirical results by means of a simulation
1971, p. 254, emphasis added) experiment: each of industries in this simu-
What has been repeatedly observed, it is lated economy is assumed to be characterized
argued, is the empirical efficacy of aggregate by a microeconomic Cobb-Douglas production
production functions. spite of the very function relating its homogeneous output to its
strongest theoretical requirements for their homogeneous labor input and its own
existence, the use of such functions flourishes machine stock. The conditions for theoretical
the current justification being that their empiri- aggregation are studiously violated, and the
cal basis appears strong. In study after study, question is, how well, and under what circum-
empirically derived functions appear to strongly stances, does an aggregate Cobb-Douglas func-
support both the constancy of returns to scale tion represent the data generated? In such an
and the equality of marginal products with economy, the aggregate wage share is often vari-
rewards: in for hnth able over time, so that in general an aggregate
series and cross-section studies (within any one Cobb-Douglas would not be expected to give a
country), the Cobb-Douglas function appears to good fit. What seems to surprise Fisher, how-
dominate the field, ever, is that when the wage share happens coin-
For the neoclassical faithful, these results rep- cidentally to be roughly constant, a
resent their salvation; no matter what those crit- Douglas production function will not only fit the
ics from Cambridge say, the real world, it data well but provide a good explanation of
would is Or is it? The wages,
answer is simple: no. m aggregate Cobb
strength production is illusion, that the the
due not to some mystical laws of production, but constancy is presence
instead, to some rather prosaic laws of algebra. of production
To see why, however, we must first examine is runs the
how production functions are estimated. the success
is due to
the constancy shut-e.
(Emphasis added.) (Fisher, 1971, p. 306).
The empirical basis of aggregate production It is obvious that so long as aggregate shares
functions are roughly constant, the appropriate economet-
ric test of aggregate neoclassical production and
The most popular methods of estimating ag- distribution theory requires a Cobb-Douglas
gregate production functions have been the function. Such a test would then apparently cast
single equation least squares method and the some light on the degree of returns to scale
factor shares method (Walters, 1963). The (through the sum of the coefficients), and the
applicability of aggregate marginal productivity Dividing through by
theory (through the comparison of the labor and
capital exponents with the wage and profit
shares, respectively). What is not obvious, how-
ever, is that so long as aggregate shares are con- By definition, the profit and wage shares,
stant, an aggregate Cobb-Douglas function respectively, are
having apparently constant returns to scale
will always provide an exact fit, for any data
whatsoever.
so WC may write,
to
= + where (1 + (3)
B
These
propositions, it will be shown, are It is important to note that all relations given
consequences of constant shares, and it will be so far are true for aggregate data at
argued that the puzzling uniformity of the empir- all, irrespective of production or distribution
ical results is due in fact to this law of algebra conditions.
and not to some mysterious law of production. Suppose now we are faced with particular
In fact, in order to emphasize the independence data which for some unspecified reasons exhibit
of any laws of an constant shares, so that Re-
illustration is provided in the form of the rather membering that the dotted variables are time
implausible data of the Humbug economy, for derivatives etc.), we can immedi-
even data such as this is perfectly consistent ately integrate the identity (3):
with a Cobb-Douglas function having constant
returns to scale, neutral technical change,
and satisfying marginal productivity rules, so
long as shares are constant. dt In k +
Laws of algebra = =
corrected of
Figure 5.3
, I I I I I I
2.0 2.4 2.8 3.2 3.6 4.0
Figure 5.4
Combining these two fitted functions, one ar- by a microeconomic Cobb -Douglas production
rives at a numerical specification for even the function:
Humbug data (Table 5. I)!
where = 1, . . . , N (14)
Fishers simulation experiments. Earlier, I men-
tioned Franklin Fishers extensive (and expen- (The are constant over time, but in general
sive) simulation experiments, in which he finds, A,(t), and K,(t) are not.)
to his surprise, that aggregate Cobb-Douglas At any instant of time, the total stock of labor
functions seem to work for his simulated L(t) in the economy is given. The basic proce-
economy even when the theoretical conditions dure followed in the model is to allocate this
for such an aggregate function are carefully vio- given supply among the existing industries so as
lated, so long as the particular simulation run to equalize the industry marginal products of
happens to have roughly constant wage (and
labor MPL): this of course
hence profit) shares (Fisher, 1971, p. 306). yields the maximum aggregate output Q(t)
It is worth noting at this point that what Fisher
means by aggregate production functions work-
In general, the marginal product of a
ing, is not simply that they give a good fit to Douglas function is =
Since these are all equalized for the various in-
gross output or gross output per worker
but also that the estimated marginal dustries to a single ievel, we can denote this
products of labor, and presumably of capital, common level by and write:
closely approximate the actual wage and profit
rates, respectively (Fisher, 1971). W(t)
1 have already demonstrated in section on the
represents the imputed rental (uniform
laws of algebra why in general an aggregate
wage rate) of a unit of labor, so that the wage bill
Cobb-Douglas may be expected to work, in the
in the industry is:
sense explained earlier, for data which
constant wage shares. In this section, however,
it will be shown that even Fishers massive com-
Thus, the aggregate wage bill is:
puter simulation is in reality only an application
of the laws of algebra. = =
The the Fishers simu- so that the wage share in total output Q(t)
lated economy consists of N industries, each is:
producing the same type of output Q, using
homogeneous labor but its own type wage share =
of machine stock Thus and are both
quantities of the same good, produced by indus-
tries i and j, respectively, whereas and are Finally, since Q,(t) is the gross output of the
stocks of different types of machines. industry, and = Q,(t) its wage bill,
Each industry is assumed to be characterized the difference between the two, the gross
Table 5. I. data
Actual
share of Humbug Humbug
property output per capital per
Year income worker worker
B/B
in the industry, is treated as the imputed chine being a different type. An index of
rental of its unique machine stock K,(t). De- capital has therefore to be constructed,
fining this gross profit and it is known that in gcncrnl any such
as (t), we have: will violate the strict conditions under which
the microeconomic Cobb-Douglas production
= functions can bc theoretically aggregated into
= gross profits in industry
a macroeconomic Cobb -Douglas production
Since output and labor L,(t) are homoge- function (Fisher, 1971, pp. 307-08). On the
neous across industries, their respective basis of aggregation theory, therefore, one would
gregates are derived by simple addition. But not expect the macroeconomic variables in this
since each industry has a type of simulated economy to behave as if they were
chine, an capital hy even
derived by adding machines together, each if aggregate shares happen to remain roughly
constant over time. That, of course, is the rea- implies that each firms output and
son for Fishers surprise at his results. employment grow at roughly the same rate. That
Fisher chooses to construct an aggregate is, dropping time subscripts and denoting time
index in two steps. First, he runs the model derivatives by dots:
economy over its 20-year period, from which he
gets the gross profits of any given industry,
for each of 20 years. Similarly, over each of the
20 years he knows the machine stock K,(t) in the It is the central result
same industry: the ratio of the sums of
of this paper that constant shares, any ag-
these two is the average rate of return in the
gregate data Q , L whatsoever can be
industry:
described by a function of the form Q(t) =
providing the residual is
a function of time. What we must there-
= 20 year average rate of return
fore do for Fishers experiments. in order to see
in industry (19) why aggregate Cobb-Douglas functions work
for them, is to examine this residual
The units of each average return are output By definition, from Equation (3)
per machine type Thus Fisher can use these
in any one period t to aggregate the individual in-
dustry machine stocks into an aggregate index of
= = Fishers
index of capital is denoted by J. Thus =
J(t) = = Q/Q and K/K = and:
denote these roughly constant relative outputs The growth rate of the aggregate capital index
by Pi, and the constant wage share by (1 s), is a bit more complicated. In Equation (20)
J(t)
the lack of time subscript denoting their con- we defined
stancy:
J,(t) =
1 I
we know so
in important to note that the
Q(t) Q;(t) and when summed over each
sum to I.
From this, we can derive
In the
expression (32) for the basic structural
parameters are and Of these, repre-
Of the terms in expression we sents the rate of growth of the machine stock
know that L/L over any given simulation run, whereas rep-
from and from (27). To resents the rate of technical change in the in-
this, we need only add the fact that in general, dustry. (Since the are constant over any given
ignoring small random Fisher as- run, changes in the shift parameter repre-
sumes that the shift parameter grows at an es- sent the only possible technical change in any in-
sentially constant rate, which differs from dustry.)
to industry. Fisher partitions his simulations into two
basic groups. In the first of these, which he calls
(30) Hicks experiments, he sets all = 0. Thus,
in each of these experiments, there is technical
All of this gives change 0) but no growth in the size of the
machine stock = 0). Under these condi-
tions, reduces to a constant over time.
References
Similarly for employment from (23).
In = + + (small ran- Brown, P. 1957. The Meaning of Fitted
dom deviations). Ignoring the small deviations, and Douglas Functions, of Eco-
differentiating gives (Fisher, 1971, p. 309) nomic&,
Dobb, M. H. 1970. Some Reflections on the Sraffa
dt K,(t) System and the Critique of the So-called
Classical Theory of Value and Distribution, un-
= published.
Dewey, D. 1965. York:
Columbia University Press.
Dropping the time subscript, and differentiating,
Ferguson, C. E. 1969. The Theory
Production Distribution. Cambridge: Cam-
+
bridge University Press.
1971. Capital Theory Up to Date: A Comment on
+ (1 Mrs. Robinsons Article, Journal
Economics, Vol. IV, No. 2, 250-4.
Fisher, F. 197 1. Aggregate Production Functions and
the Explanation of Wages: A Simulation Experi-
ment, of Economics Statistics