0% found this document useful (0 votes)
91 views62 pages

Econ3061 Slides 3

This document outlines the topic of calculus of functions of n variables from an economics textbook. It includes: 1) A definition of partial derivatives as the rate of change of a multivariate function with respect to one variable, while holding other variables constant. 2) A review of rules of differentiation for single-variable calculus, including the chain rule and L'Hopital's rule. 3) An example of a Cobb-Douglas production function as a multivariate function where output depends on capital and labor.

Uploaded by

AmalAbdlFattah
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
91 views62 pages

Econ3061 Slides 3

This document outlines the topic of calculus of functions of n variables from an economics textbook. It includes: 1) A definition of partial derivatives as the rate of change of a multivariate function with respect to one variable, while holding other variables constant. 2) A review of rules of differentiation for single-variable calculus, including the chain rule and L'Hopital's rule. 3) An example of a Cobb-Douglas production function as a multivariate function where output depends on capital and labor.

Uploaded by

AmalAbdlFattah
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 62

ECON 3061

Topic II: Calculus of functions of n variables

Diaa Noureldin
[email protected]

Department of Economics
The American University in Cairo

Econ 3061 - Mathematics for Economists II


Outline for Topic II: Calculus of functions of n variables

The material for this topic is Ch. 11 (except Section 11.6) in the course
textbook (Hoy et al., 2011).

I Partial dierentiation.
I Second-order partial derivative.
I The rst-order total dierential.
I Implicit dierentiation.
I Level curves.
I Homogenous and homothetic functions.
I Economic applications.

1 / 61
RECALL: the derivative

Given y = f (x ), which is a function of one variable. The derivative is


dened as
dy f (x + x ) f (x )
f 0 (x ) = lim .
dx x !0 x
dy
The notation dx is used to denote the derivative of y with respect to
(w.r.t.) x.

The second derivative is dened as


d2y
f 00 (x ),
dx 2

and generally the nth derivative is

dny
f (n ) ( x ) .
dx n

2 / 61
RECALL: the rules of dierentiation I

Recall the following rules of dierentiation:

1. f (x ) = c (c is constant), then f 0 (x ) = 0.

2. f (x ) = cx (c is constant), then f 0 (x ) = c.

3. f (x ) = x n , then f 0 (x ) = nx n 1.

4. f (x ) = cx n (c is constant), then f 0 (x ) = ncx n 1.

5. h(x ) = f (x ) g (x ), then h0 (x ) = f 0 (x ) g 0 (x ).

6. h(x ) = f (x )g (x ), then h0 (x ) = f 0 (x )g (x ) + f (x )g 0 (x ).
f (x ) f 0 (x )g (x ) f (x )g 0 (x )
7. h(x ) = , g (x ) 6= 0, then h0 (x ) = .
g (x ) (g (x ))2

3 / 61
RECALL: the rules of dierentiation II
The rules of dierentiation (continued):

8. If y = f (u ) and u = g (x ), then y = f (g (x )) = h(x ) where h is a


composite function. Then we have the chain rule:

h 0 (x ) = f 0 (u )g 0 (x ),

or
dy dy du
= .
dx du dx

Example
Let y = (3x 4)6 , thus u = g (x ) = 3x 4, and y = f (u ) = u 6 . We
have
dy dy du
= = 6u 5 (3) = 18u 5 = 18 (3x 4)5 .
dx du dx

4 / 61
RECALL: the rules of dierentiation III
The rules of dierentiation (continued):

9. If y = expfg (x )g e g (x ) , then

dy
= e g (x ) g 0 ( x ) .
dx

Example
2 dy 2 2
Let y = e 2x 1, then dx = e 2x 1 (4x ) = 4xe 2x 1.

10. If y = log(g (x )), then

dy 1 0
= g (x ).
dx g (x )

Example
dy 1 4x 4x .
Let y = log(2x 2 1), then dx = 2x 2 1
= 2x 2 1

5 / 61
RECALL: the rules of dierentiation IV
The rules of dierentiation (continued):

11. If y = f (x ), where f ( ) is a continuous function then x = f 1 (y ).


Provided that f 0 (x ) 6= 0, we have

dx 1 1
= 0 = .
dy f (x ) dy /dx

Example
dy dx 1
Let y = 3x 2 =) dx = 6x =) dy = 6x . We also have

y 1 /2
x =
3
1 /2
dx 1 y 1 /2 1 1 y 1 /2 1 3x 2
= = =
dy 2 3 3 6 3 6 3
1 /2 1 /2
1 2 1 1 1
= x = = .
6 6 x2 6x

6 / 61
RECALL: the rules of dierentiation V
The rules of dierentiation (continued):

f (x ) 0
12. LHbo pitals rule: If limx !a g (x ) = 0 (i.e. indeterminate), then the
limit can be evaluated as follow:
f (x ) f 0 (x )
lim = lim 0 .
x !a g (x ) x !a g (x )

Example
2 x 2 25
Evaluate limx !5 xx 25 .
5 Since limx !5 x 5 = 00 , then we can use
LHb
o pitals rule:

f (x ) f 0 (x )
lim = lim
x !a g (x ) x !a g 0 (x )
x2 25 2x
lim = lim = 10.
x !5 x 5 x !5 1

7 / 61
RECALL: The total dierential
If f 0 (x0 ) is the derivative of f (x ) at the point x0 , then the total
dierential at the point x0 is
dy = f 0 (x0 )dx.

Example
Let y = x 2 . Let x change from the value 10 to 10.1 (i.e. x = 0.1). We
have that the corresponding y value will change from y = (10)2 = 100
to y = x 2 = (10.1)2 = 102.01. Thus y = 2.01. Using the total
dierential we have

dy = f 0 (x0 )dx
= 20(0.1)
= 2
2.01

noting that f 0 (x ) = 2x and f 0 (x0 = 10) = 2(10) = 20.


You can check that the approximation improves if x is taken to be
smaller and smaller. The opposite is also true. The approximation will be
poorer for a large value of x.
8 / 61
Functions of n variables: Notation
We shall use the following notation:
I x 2 Rn denotes a collection of n points x = (x1 , x2 , ..., xn ).
I y = f (x1 , x2 , ..., xn ) = f (x) denotes a multivariate function f of n
variables.
I Here, Rn is the domain of the function.
I We sometimes use the notation f : Rn ! R, which reads as: the
function f maps from Rn into R.
Example
The output of the rm (y ) depends on two inputs: capital (x1 ) and labor
(x2 ). So we have y f (x) = f (x1 , x2 ), where f : R2 ! R, that is the
function f maps points in R2 (i.e. dierent capital and labor
combinations) into a single value on the real line (R). We can specify
the functional form of f (x) as follows:

y f (x) = Ax1 x2 ,

where A, and are constants. This is known as the Cobb-Douglas


production function.
9 / 61
The partial derivative I
Recall that the derivative
dy f (x + x ) f (x )
f 0 (x ) = lim
dx x !0 x
is interpreted as the rate at which y changes when x changes as we let
the change in x become arbitrarily small.

We can extend this idea to multivariate functions as follows: If


y = f (x1 , x2 ), we can dene the rate at which y changes when x1
changes (keeping x2 constant), and the rate at which y changes when x2
changes (keeping x1 constant). These are called the partial derivatives
of f with respect to its arguments.
Denition
The partial derivatives of f (x1 , x2 ) w.r.t. x1 and x2 , respectively, are
f (x1 , x2 ) y f (x1 + x1 , x2 ) f (x1 , x2 )
f1 (x 1 , x 2 ) = lim
x1 x1 x1 !0 x1
f (x1 , x2 ) y f (x1 , x2 + x2 ) f (x1 , x2 )
f2 (x1 , x2 ) = lim .
x2 x2 x2 !0 x2

10 / 61
The partial derivative II

I The reason for calling these expressions partial derivatives, and for
using the notation "" is that we are changing only one of x1 and x2
at a time, despite the fact that y depends on both of them.
f (x1 ,x2 )
I It is important to note that the partial derivative will in
x 1
f (x1 ,x2 )
general depend on x2 , and the partial derivative x 2 will in
general depend on x1 !
I For instance, the rate of change of output w.r.t. to the labor input
will depend on the level of capital input.
I Similiarly, the rate of change of output w.r.t. to the capital input
will depend on the amount of labor employed in production.

11 / 61
The partial derivative: General denition

Denition
The partial derivative of a function y = f (x1 , x2 , ..., xn ) = f (x) w.r.t.
the variable xi is:

f f (x1 , ..., xi + xi , ..., xn ) f (x1 , ..., xi , ..., xn )


fi ( x ) = lim .
xi x i !0 xi

We can also use alternative notation for the general denition of the
partial derivative:

f f (xi + xi jx i ) f (x)
f i ( x ) = f 0 ( xi j x i ) = lim ,
xi x i !0 xi

where the notation f 0 (xi jx i ) denotes the derivative of f (x) w.r.t. to its
i th argument, holding all other xs (apart from xi ) constant.

12 / 61
The partial derivative: Examples I
Example
Let y = f (x1 , x2 ) = x13 + 5x2 . In this example, we have the arguments of
f being additively separable. We have

f
f1 = 3x12
x1
f
f2 = 5.
x2

Example
Let y = f (x1 , x2 ) = x12 x2 . We have

f
f1 = 2x1 x2
x1
f
f2 = x12 .
x2

13 / 61
The partial derivative: Examples II

Example
Let y = f (x1 , x2 ) = 10x1 x22 5x13 + 4x2 + x1 x2 . We have

f
f1 = 10x22 15x12 + x2
x1
f
f2 = 20x1 x2 + 4 + x1 .
x2

You should note that in these examples, the partial derivative will in
general depend on all the arguments of f .

14 / 61
The demand function I

We have that the demand for product a (QaD ) will depend on the price of
a (Pa ), the price of a related good b (Pb ) as well as income (I):

QaD = f (Pa , Pb , I).

We also have the following expected signs for the partial derivatives:
I
Q aD
P a fP a < 0 (law of demand).
I
Q aD
P b fP b > 0 (goods a and b are substitutes).
I
Q aD
P b fP b < 0 (goods a and b are complements).
I
Q aD
I fI > 0 (good a is a normal good).
I
Q aD
I fI < 0 (good a is an inferior good).

15 / 61
The demand function II

Example
Let
QaD = f (Pa , Pb , I) = 50Pa + 10Pb 2I.
Then we have
I
Q aD
P a fP a = 50 (downward sloping demand curve).
I
Q aD
P b fP b = 10 (goods a and b are substitutes).
I
Q aD
I fI = 2 (good a is an inferior good).

16 / 61
The utility function I

Let the utility function be given by

U (x1 , x2 ) = x1 x21
.

We have the marginal utility functions ( xU1 and U


x2 ).

I U 1 1
x 1 U1 = x1 x2 , which is positive for > 0.

I U U2 = x1 (1 )x2 , which is positive for


x 2
1 > 0 () < 1.
I Therefore, for U to be a feasible utility function, we need 0 < < 1.

17 / 61
The utility function II

For 0 < < 1, the marginal utility functions satsify the law of
diminishing marginal utility. This is obvious since

U 1 1 x21
= x1 x2 =
x1 x11

U (1 )x1
= x1 (1 )x2
= .
x2 x
2

I U U
We have x 1 > 0, however x 1 # as x1 ".
I U U
We have x 2 > 0, however x 2 # as x2 ".

18 / 61
The production function
Let Q = f (K , L) be a production function for a rm, where Q, K and L
denote output, capital and labor, respectively.
Example
Let Q = 3L1 /2 K 1 /2 . We have
Q 3 1 /2 1 /2
QL = L K
L 2
Q 3
QK = L1 /2 K 1 /2 .
K 2

The quantity QL is known as the marginal product of labor (MPL).


Similarly, Q
K is known as the marginal product of capital (MPK).

The concept of the production function can also be applied on the macro
level, where Q denotes aggregate economic output (or GDP), L denotes
the labor force and K denotes the capital stock (or cumulative
investments).

19 / 61
The Cobb-Douglas production function
The Cobb-Douglas production function is given by

Q = AL K .

I A > 0, 0 < , < 1 are technology parameters.


I The marginal product functions are

Q 1 AK
= AL K =
L L1
Q 1 AL
= AL K = 1 .
K K
I Note that both marginal product functions satisfy the law of
diminshing marginal productivity.
I We have QL > 0; however QL # as L ".
I Q Q
Also K > 0; however K # as K ".

20 / 61
The Cobb-Douglas production function with 3 inputs
With three factors of production, the Cobb-Douglas production function
is given by

Q = Ax1 x2 x3 , A > 0, 0 < , , < 1.

I The marginal product functions are



Q 1 x2 x3
= Ax1 x2 x3 = A
x1 x11

Q 1 x1 x3
= Ax1 x2 x3 = A 1
x2 x2

Q 1 x1 x2
= Ax1 x2 x3 = A 1
.
x3 x3

I All marginal products satisfy the law of diminshing marginal


productivity.
I The marginal product of each input is decreasing in that input;
however it is increasing in the other two inputs.
21 / 61
The Cobb-Douglas production function: Example
Let
Q = 10L1 /3 K 1 /2 .

I Q = 10 L 2 /3 K 1 /2 = 10 K 1/2 .
L 3 3 L 2/3
1/3
I Q

= 1
5L K / 3 1 / 2 L
= 5 K 1/2 .
K
Suppose the total labor force is 25 million workers, and the capital stock
(measured in monetary terms) is LE 15 billion. Then we have

Q 10 K 1 /2 10 (15)1 /2
= = = 1.51
L 3 L2 /3 3 (25)2 /3
Q L1 /3 (25)1 /3
= 5 = 5 = 3.77.
K K 1 /2 (15)1 /2
The gures are interpreted as follows:
I As labor increases by 1 unit (i.e. 1 million workers), Q increases by
LE 1.51 billion.
I As capital increases by 1 unit (i.e. LE 1 billion), Q increases by
LE 3.77 billion.
22 / 61
In-class exercises I

Find the derivatives of the following functions:


2 +3x +2
1. y = e 2x .

2
2. y = e x log x 2 .

3. y = e log (x ) .

23 / 61
In-class exercises II
Find the partial derivatives of the following functions:

2x23
y = x12 e 3x2 +x1 x3 + .
x1

24 / 61
In-class exercises III

1. Find the marginal product functions for the following Cobb-Douglas


production function:

y = 10x11 /2 x21 /3 x31 /4 .

2. Find the marginal product functions for the following CES (constant
elasticity of substitution) production function:
2
1 /2 1 /2
y = 12 0.4x1 + 0.6x2 .

25 / 61
The constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production
function I
The CES production function with 2 inputs is given by:
1 /r
y = A x1 r + (1 ) x2 r
,

where A > 0, 0 < < 1 and r > 1.

The marginal products are


y 1 (1/r ) 1
= A x1 r + (1 ) x2 r
r x1 r 1
x1 r
A (1/r ) 1
= x1 r + (1 ) x2 r
.
x1r +1
y 1 (1/r ) 1
= A x1 r + (1 ) x2 r r (1 ) x2 r 1
x2 r
A (1/r ) 1
= (1 ) r +1 x1 r + (1 ) x2 r .
x2

26 / 61
The CES (constant elasticity of substitution) production
function II
y Ar
The marginal products can be written in a simpler form. Multiply x1 by Ar ,
we have
y Ar A (1/r ) 1
= x1 r + (1 ) x2 r
x1 Ar x1r +1
(1/r ) 1
Ar +1 x1 r + (1 ) x2 r
= .
Ar x1r +1
Also note that
1/r r +1
y r +1 = A x1 r + (1 ) x2 r

(1/r ) 1
= Ar +1 x1 r + (1 ) x2 r
.
Thus we have
r +1
y y r +1 y
= r r +1 = r .
x1 A x1 A x1
And Similarly, we have
r +1
y (1 ) y r +1 (1 ) y
= = .
x2 Ar x2r +1 Ar x2
27 / 61
The CES (constant elasticity of substitution) production
function III

The marginal products are


r +1
y y
=
x1 Ar x1
r +1
y (1 ) y
= .
x2 Ar x2

Note that we have the condition that r > 1, which implies that
r +1 > 0.

This in turn implies


I y
Diminishing marginal productivity of input 1: x 1 # as x1 ".
I y
Diminishing marginal productivity of input 2: x 2 # as x2 ".

28 / 61
Second-order partial derivatives
I Now that we have dened the (rst-order) partial derivative, we now
move on to dene the second-order partial derivatives.
I Recall the denition of the rst-order partial derivatives of f (x1 , x2 ):
f (x1 , x2 ) y f (x1 + x1 , x2 ) f (x1 , x2 )
f1 (x 1 , x 2 ) = lim
x1 x1 x1 !0 x1
f (x1 , x2 ) y f (x1 , x2 + x2 ) f (x1 , x2 )
f2 (x1 , x2 ) = lim .
x2 x2 x2 !0 x2

I A function of n variables, y = f (x1 , x2 , ..., xn ), will have n rst-order


partial derivatives f1 , f2 , ..., fn .
I The second-order partial derivatives are given by

fi (x1 , x2 , ..., xn )
fij = , i , j = 1, 2, ..., n.
xj

I fij is found by rst dierentiating the function f (x) w.r.t. xi , and then
dierentiation the result w.r.t. xj .

29 / 61
Second-order partial derivatives (continued)
It is clear that for a function of n variables, there will be n2 second-order
partial derivatives.

Example
For y = f (x1 , x2 ) we have 4 second-order partial derivatives:

f11 f12
f21 f22

Example
For y = f (x1 , x2 , x3 ) we have 9 second-order partial derivatives:

f11 f12 f13


f21 f22 f23
f31 f32 f33

This makes it clear that we can neatly present the second-order partial
derivatives using matrices.
30 / 61
The gradient vector

First let us dene the gradient vector, denoted by 5f , which collects all
the rst-order partial derivatives of the n-variable function f (x).

Denition
The gradient vector is 2 3
f1
6 f2 7
6 7
5f = 6 .. 7.
4 . 5
fn

The reason is it called the gradient vector is that each element fi


indicates the rate of change in f (x) w.r.t. xi . This analogous to signs
indicating the grades or steepness that we nd when driving a car
through hills or mountains.

31 / 61
The gradient vector: Examples

Example
Find the gradient vector for f (x) = 2x12 + 3x2 + x34 + 1. We have
2 3 2 3
f1 4x1
5 f = 4 f2 5 = 4 3 5 .
f3 4x33

Note that this function is additively separable.

Example
Find the gradient vector for f (x) = x12 x23 x34 . We have
2 3 2 3
f1 2x1 x23 x34
5f = 4 f2 5 = 4 3x12 x22 x34 5 .
f3 4x12 x23 x33

32 / 61
The Hessian matrix

The Hessian matrix, denoted by 52 f , collects the second-order partial


derivatives.

Example
For y = f (x1 , x2 ), we have n2 = 22 = 4 second-order partial derivatives:

f1 (x1 , x2 ) f1 (x1 , x2 )
f11 , f12
x1 x2
f2 (x1 , x2 ) f2 (x1 , x2 )
f21 , f22 .
x1 x2
The Hessian matrix is given by

f11 f12
52 f = .
f21 f22

33 / 61
The Hessian matrix (continued)

For n = 3, the Hessian matrix is given by


2 3
f11 f12 f13
52 f = 4 f21 f22 f23 5 .
f31 f32 f33

And generally for any n, the Hessian is given by


2 3
f11 f12 f1n
6 f21 f22 f2n 7
6 7
52 f = 6 .. .. . . .. 7 .
4 . . . . 5
fn1 fn2 fnn

34 / 61
The Hessian matrix: Example I
Find the Hessian matrix for f (x) = x12 x23 .

Solution
First, the gradient vector (i.e. vector of rst-order partial derivatives) is

f1 2x1 x23
5f = = .
f2 3x12 x22

We now compute

f1 f1
f11 = 2x23 , f12 = 6x1 x22 ,
x1 x2
f2 f2
f21 = 6x1 x22 , f22 = 6x12 x2 ,
x1 x2
and we have
f11 f12 2x23 6x1 x22
52 f = = .
f21 f22 6x1 x22 6x12 x2

35 / 61
The Hessian matrix: Example II
Find the Hessian matrix for f (x) = x12 x23 x34 .

Solution
The gradient vector (i.e. vector of rst-order partial derivatives) is
2 3 2 3
f1 2x1 x23 x34
5f = 4 f2 5 = 4 3x12 x22 x34 5 .
f3 4x12 x23 x33

We now compute
f1 f1 f1
f11 = 2x23 x34 , f12 = 6x1 x22 x34 , f13 = 8x1 x23 x33 ,
x1 x2 x3
f2 f2 f2
f21 = 6x1 x22 x34 , f22 = 6x12 x2 x34 , f23 = 12x12 x22 x33 ,
x1 x2 x3
f3 f3 f3
f31 = 8x1 x23 x33 , f32 = 12x12 x22 x33 , f33 = 12x12 x23 x32 ,
x1 x2 x3
and we have
2 3 2 3
f11 f12 f13 2x23 x34 6x1 x22 x34 8x1 x23 x33
52 f = 4 f21 f22 f23 5 4
= 6x1 x22 x34 6x12 x2 x34 12x12 x22 x33 5 .
f31 f32 f33 8x1 x23 x33 12x12 x22 x33 12x12 x23 x32 36 / 61
Symmetry of the Hessian matrix

We notice from the previous examples that the Hessian matrix is


symmetric, i.e. fij = fji 8i, j.

Does this hold in all cases? The answer is YES.

Theorem
( Youngs Theorem) For a function y = f (x1 , x2 , ..., xn ) with
continuous rst- and second-order partial derivatives, the order of
dierentiation in computing the cross-partials does not matter. That is
fij = fji 8i, j = 1, 2, ..., n.

37 / 61
The Hessian matrix for additively separable functions I

I Recall the additively separable function f (x) = 2x12 + 3x2 + x34 + 1


(see above). We have
2 3 2 3
f1 4x1
5 f = 4 f2 5 = 4 3 5 .
f3 4x33

such that f1 is a function of only x1 , f2 is a function of only x2


(constant function in this case), and f3 is a function of only x3 .

I It is obvious that this feature holds in general for any additively


separable function.

I This immediatley implies that all the cross-partials will be zeros, and
the Hessian matrix will be diagonal in this case.

38 / 61
The Hessian matrix for additively separable functions II

For the additively separable function f (x) = 2x12 + 3x2 + x34 + 1, it is


straightforward to show that the Hessian matrix is given by
2 3 2 3
f11 f12 f13 4 0 0
52 f = 4 f21 f22 f23 5 = 4 0 0 0 5.
f31 f32 f33 0 0 12x32

Verify this as an exercise.

39 / 61
RECALL: The total dierential
If f 0 (a) is the derivative of f (x ) at the point x = a, then the total
dierential at the point x = a is
dy = f 0 (a)dx.
The total dierential is used to approximate the change in y (y ) for a
given change in x (x) within a neighbourhood of the point x = a. That
is
y = f (a + x ) f (a)
can be approximated by
dy = f 0 (a)dx.

40 / 61
The total dierential for a function of 2 variables
For y = f (x) = f (x1 , x2 ), where f : R2 ! R, the total dierential is
f f
dy = dx1 + dx2 = f1 dx1 + f2 dx2 .
x1 x2
The interpretation here is as follows:
I At a specic point where x1 = a1 and x2 = a2 , i.e. y = f (a1 , a2 ), we
could change only x1 and get the result
y = f (a1 + x1 , a2 ) f (a1 , a2 ),
which can be approximated by
dy = f1 (a1 , a2 )dx1 .

I Similarly, we could change only x2 and get the result


y = f (a1 , a2 + x2 ) f (a1 , a2 ),
which can be approximated by
dy = f2 (a1 , a2 )dx2 .

I Allowing for both x1 and x2 to change leads to the above denition.


41 / 61
The total dierential: A geometric view
Plot of y = f(x ,x ) = 1 - x 2 - x 2
1 2 1 2

10

-10

-20
y

-30

-40

-50
5
0 5
0
-5 -5
x x
2 1

42 / 61
The total dierential for a function of n variables

For y = f (x) = f (x1 , ..., xn ), where f : Rn ! R, the total dierential is

f f f
dy = dx1 + dx2 + + dxn
x1 x2 xn
= f1 dx1 + f2 dx2 + + fn dxn
n
= fi dxi .
i =1

In this multivariate case, the total dierential is used to approximate


changes in y given simultaneous changes in the inputs xi , i = 1, 2, ..., n.

43 / 61
The total dierential: Example

Let
1
y = f (x) = 2x12 + x1 x2 3x32 .
2
Find the total dierential for f (x).

Solution
The total dierential is given by

dy = f1 dx1 + f2 dx2 + f3 dx3


1 1
= 4x1 + x2 dx1 + x1 dx2 (6x3 ) dx3 .
2 2

44 / 61
Implicit dierentiation I
When we have y = f (x ), we have an explicit function.
Example
dy
The function y = 3x 2 + 4, where dx = 6x.

Sometimes we have F (x, y ) = c, c is a constant, which is called an


implicit function.
Example
For
x 2 y 3 + 3xy 2 + y = 22
which has the form F (x, y ) = c. This is an example where y is an
implicit function of x, since changes in x induce changes in y for the
equation to hold.

We need to nd a rule to be able to nd dy dx when we are dealing with


implicit functions. This is called implicit dierentiation.

45 / 61
Implicit dierentiation II
To deal with this problem, we totally dierentiate the implicit function
F (x, y ) = c as follows:
Fx dx + Fy dy = 0
Fy dy = Fx dx
which in turn implies
dy Fx
= , Fy 6= 0.
dx Fy

Example
For
x 2 y 3 + 3xy 2 + y = 22,
we have
dy Fx 2xy 3 + 3y 2
= = .
dx Fy (3x 2 y 2 + 6xy + 1)

This is an example of the application of the Implicit Function Theorem


which is stated on the following slide.
46 / 61
The Implicit Function Theorem
The Implicit Function Theorem can be stated as follows: Given
F (x1 , x2 , ..., xn , y ) = c, and assuming Fy 6= 0, then the partial
derivatives are given by
y Fxi
= .
xi Fy

Example
Compute the partial derivatives of

F (x1 , x2 , y ) = 3x1 x2 + x2 y 2 + x12 x2 y = 10.

Here we can use the Implicit Function Theorem to compute the partial
derivatives. We have
y Fx1 (3x2 + 2x1 x2 y )
= =
x1 Fy 2x2 y + x12 x2
y Fx2 3x1 + y 2 + x12 y
= = .
x2 Fy 2x2 y + x12 x2

47 / 61
Level Curves
Suppose we have an explicit function y = f (x1 , x2 ). Then
y = f (x1 , x2 ) = c, c is a constant,
is the level curve of y .

Using the total dierential, we have


dy = f1 dx1 + f2 dx2 = 0
f2 dx2 = f1 dx1
dx2 f1
= .
dx1 f2

Example
Let y = f (x1 , x2 ) = 2x1 + 3x2 . Then the level curve for this function is

y = 2x1 + 3x2 = c,

where c can take dierent values. Also we have


dx2 f1 2
= = .
dx1 f2 3
48 / 61
Level curves: The Indierence curve
Let U (x1 , x2 ) be the utility function from consumption of goods x1 and
x2 . The level curves are given by U (x1 , x2 ) = c.

Using the total dierential, we have

U U
dU = dx1 + dx2 = 0.
x1 x2
U U
Dene MU1 x 1 and MU2 x 2 . Then we have

MU1 dx1 + MU2 dx2 = 0


MU2 dx2 = MU1 dx1
dx2 MU1
=
dx1 MU2
dx2 MU1
= = MRS
| {z }
dx1 MU2
| {z } Marg. rate of substitution
Slope of IC

49 / 61
Level curves: The Indierence curve (example)
Let U (x1 , x2 ) = ln(x1 ) + (1 ) ln(x2 ), 0 < < 1. Below is the plot
of U (x1 , x2 ) for = 0.5.
Plot of U(x ,x ) = (1/2)log(x ) + (1/2)log(x )
1 2 1 2

2.5

1.5
U(x ,x )
2
1

0.5

0
10

5 10
8
6
4
2
x 0 0
2 x
1

50 / 61
Level curves: The Indierence curve (example, continued)
The level curves (indierence curves) are given by
U (x1 , x2 ) = ln(x1 ) + (1 ) ln(x2 ) = c ( = 0.5):
Level curves of U(x ,x ) = (1/2)log(x ) + (1/2)log(x )
1 2 1 2
10

6
2
x

1
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
x
1

51 / 61
Level curves: The Indierence curve (numerical example)

For U (x1 , x2 ) = 14 ln(x1 ) + 34 ln(x2 ), nd the marginal rate of


susbtitution between x1 and x2 .

Solution
We rst compute the marginal utilities:

U 1 U 3
MU1 = = , MU2 = = ,
x1 4x1 x2 4x2
and the marginal rate of substitution is given by
1
dx2 MU1 4x1 x2
MRS = = = 3
= .
dx1 MU2 4x2
3x1

52 / 61
Level curves: The Isoquant
Let Q = f (L, K ) be the production function using labor (L) and capital
(K ) inputs. The level curves are given by Q = f (L, K ) = c.

Using the total dierential, we have

f f
dQ = dL + dK = 0.
L K
f f
Dene MPL L and MPK K . Then we have

MPL dL + MPK dK = 0
MPK dK = MPL dL
dK MPL
=
dL MPK
dK MPL
= = MRTS
| {z }
dL MPK
| {z } Marg. rate of tech. substitution
Slope of Isoquant

53 / 61
Level curves: The Isoquant (example)
Let Q = f (L, K ) = L K (1 ) , 0 < < 1. Below is the plot of
Q = f (L, K ) for = 13 .
1/3 2/3
Plot of Q(L,K) = L K

120

100

80

60
Q

40

20

0
10
10
8
5 6
4
2
K 0 0
L

54 / 61
Level curves: The Isoquant (example, continued)
The level curves (isoquants) are given by Q = f (L, K ) = L K (1 ) =c
( = 13 ):
1/3 2/3
Level curves of Q(L,K) = L K
10

5
K

0
0 2 4 6 8 10
L

55 / 61
Level curves: The Isoquant (numerical example)

For Q = f (L, K ) = L1 /3 K 2 /3 , nd the marginal rate of technical


susbtitution between L and K .

Solution
We rst compute the marginal productivities:
2 /3 1 /3
f 1 K f 2 L
MPL = = , MPK = = ,
L 3 L K 3 K

and the marginal rate of technical substitution is given by


2 /3
1 K
dK MPL 3 L K
MRTS = = = 1 /3
= .
dL MPK 2 L 2L
3 K

56 / 61
Homogenous functions I
Denition
A multivariate function y = f (x1 , x2 , ..., xn ) is homogenous of degree
k, i.e. H k , if and only if:

f (x1 , x2 , ..., xn ) = k f (x1 , x2 , ..., xn ).

Example
Let y = f (x1 , x2 ) = 3x1 x2 . We have

f (x1 , x2 ) = 3 (x1 ) (x2 ) = 2 3x1 x2 = 2 f (x1 , x2 ),

therefore it is homogenous of degree 2.

Example
x1
Let y = f (x1 , x2 ) = 3x22
. We have

(x1 ) x
f (x1 , x2 ) = 2
= 2 12 = 1
f (x1 , x2 ),
3 (x2 ) 3x2

therefore it is homogenous of degree 1. 57 / 61


Homogenous functions II: Cobb-Douglas

Example
Let Q = f (L, K ) = L K , 0 < , < 1. We have

f (L, K ) = (L) (K ) = + L K = + f (L, K ),

therefore it is homogenous of degree + .

+ Homog. Returns to Interpretation


of degree Scale (RtS)
1 1 (or H 1 ) Const.RtS Inputs " by , output " by
>1 > 1 (or H >1 ) Inc. RtS Inputs " by , output " by more than
<1 < 1 (or H <1 ) Dec. RtS Inputs " by , output " by less than

58 / 61
Eulers Theorem
If a multivariate function y = f (x1 , x2 , ..., xn ) is homogenous of degree k
(i.e. H k ), then
n
f i xi = ky .
i =1

Example
Cobb-Douglas production function: From above we have that
Q = f (L, K ) = L K is H + . Then

fL L + fK K = ( + ) Q.

Thus Eulers Theorem relates the marginal productivities, inputs, output


and returns to scale in a single equation.

You are required to derive the result in the example above as an


exercise.

59 / 61
Homothetic functions

Denition
If a multivariate function y = f (x1 , x2 , ..., xn ) is homogenous of degree k
(i.e. H k ), then g (y ) is homothetic if g 0 (y ) > 0.

As implied by the denition, homothetic functions are monotonic


transformations of homogenous functions. A monotonic tranformation is
any function g ( ) where g 0 ( ) > 0.

Examples of monotonic transformations


y
g (y ) y + 2 2y 2 y 2 ln (y ) e y
1 1
g 0 (y ) 1 2 2 2y y ey

You will study the properties of homothetic functions in more detail in


intermediate and advanced microeconomics.

60 / 61
Homothetic functions: Example

Let y = f (x1 , x2 ) = x1 x2 . We have that

f (x1 , x2 ) = (x1 ) (x2 ) = 2 x1 x2 = 2 y .

Therefore this is a function that is H 2 .

Example
The function g (y ) = y + 10 = x1 x2 + 10 is a homothetic function since
it is a monotonic transformation of a homogenous function, where
g 0 (y ) > 0.

Example
The function g (y ) = ln (y ) = ln (x1 x2 ) is a homothetic function since it
is a monotonic transformation of a homogenous function, where
g 0 (y ) > 0.

61 / 61

You might also like