Media Politic
Media Politic
By
John Zaller
Draft October 24, 1999
The theory of media politics I propose is, in effect, an extension of Anthony Downs' study, An
Economic Theory of Democracy. In this 1957 classic, Downs showed how party competition for the
support of rational voters could explain many of the most salient features of democratic politics.1 But
Downs' theory hardly mentioned journalists and gave them no independent role in politics. In the present
study, I create a theoretical role for journalists within Downs democratic system and trace out certain
effects of this change. Specifically, I require office-seeking politicians to communicate with voters at least
some of the time through a journalistic profession whose interests are "voice" and audience share.
Because both Downs' theory and my extension of it are rooted in basic political forces, it is plausible to
believe that my theory of media politics applies to political news in the U.S. generally and not merely to
presidential elections. I shall later offer some modest evidence for this view.
In following Downs, my theory of media politics takes a loosely rational choice approach to its subject.
That is, it treats media politics as the product of goal-oriented behavior on the part of key actors in the
political system, namely, politicians, journalists, and citizens. The fact that the goals of these actors, as
specified below, often conflict is what makes politics and, as I hope readers will conclude, my theory of
A straightforward implication of rational choice is that individuals take account of the goal-oriented
behavior of others with whom they interact. It is extremely hard, in my view, to overestimate the
importance of this point for the understanding of media politics (or other forms of political struggle, for that
matter). Everyone in politics does what he or she does in significant part because of what others are
doing or expected to do. Thus, to take a commonplace example, candidates create the kinds of
1 Downs' book is, in important respects, an incisive digest of prior theoretical and empiricial work, notably
that of Schattschneider (1942), Schumpeter (1942), Key (19xx), Black (1958), and Arrow (19XX).
6
campaign events they do because of their beliefs about how journalists are likely to cover the events. Or,
to take an example that I will develop more fully below, journalists facing multi-candidate fields in
presidential primaries routinely limit their coverage to the two or three contenders that they think voters
are most likely to favor. When candidates do what they do because of how they think journalists will
respond, and when candidates are covered (or ignored) because of how they are expected to fare with
voters, one cannot provide a satisfactory explanation by focusing on any single actor in isolation from the
others. Rather, one must take at least theoretical account of the full set of actors and, in particular, how
the actions and anticipated actions of one set of actors affect the actions of others.
This is not easy to do, but it is more natural to attempt it within a rational choice framework than any
other, for this reason: Whereas psychological theories tend to focus on the effects of internal drives and
perceptions on individual behavior, and whereas sociological theories tend to stress the effects of
external structure on behavior, the notion of strategic behavior that is inherent in rational choice posits
that individual behavior is shaped by both external forces (what other individuals are trying to do in a
Although taking a rational choice approach, I by no means assume that everyone's mind works like a
computer, calculating all possible contingencies at each decision point and making the move with the best
expected return. I make a much milder set of assumptions: That individuals at all levels of politics try to
behave in ways that advance goals that are important to them; that individuals are embedded in groups,
such as classes or professions, whose rules and values help them to achieve their goals; and that, thus
assisted, individuals establish patterns of behavior that do generally reflect their goals.
Politicians are probably the only political actors who regularly and consciously calculate the expected
gain for every important action. But voters who, for example, somewhat mindlessly support the party of
their social class, or journalists who are equally mindless in their distrust of authority, may also be
rational, in the sense that their basic patterns of behavior may have initially developed and continue to
Thus, in my use of rational choice, individual choices need not be calculated, or even self-conscious,
in order to represent interest-oriented behavior and hence qualify as rational. A danger in this brand of
7
"soft rational choice" is that anything anyone does might be sloppily described as rational. But I am quite
aware of this danger and do not believe that my theory will suffer greatly from this form of indiscipline.
My basic theoretical posture, then, is that politicians, journalists, and citizens behave in ways that
generally reflect individual goals and interests; that in pursuing their various goals, individuals take
account of the goal-oriented behavior of other individuals with whom they interact; and that the essential
features of media politics can be usefully analyzed as the outcome of all this goal-oriented and strategic
behavior.
Rational choice is often seen as a controversial perspective, especially when it invades new
intellectual terrain. It is, however, hard for me to see what general objection there can be to the
Downs theory of democracy is based on a handful of theoretical postulates. The most important are
that politicians are organized into party teams that care about winning office and nothing else, that voters
wish to elect politicians who give them as much as possible of what they want out of government, and
that both politicians and voters are cold-bloodedly rational in the pursuit of these goals. What voters
want out of government is anything that happens to give them utility, whether in the form of individual
benefits (e.g., social security, low taxes), a prosperous national economy, or social justice for others.
There is no requirement in Downs model that voters be selfish; the only requirement is that voters
From these simple assumptions, Downs deduces many theoretical expectations that most observers
regard as true. For example, Downs argues that, in a two-party system, both parties will converge to the
position of the median voter, that is, the voter who occupies the dead center of the ideological spectrum.
This is because if either party moves left or right of center, the other party will then capture of the votes of
centrist voters and thereby win the election. The actual tendency of the Democratic and Republican party
to stay near the middle of the road in most elections seems well-explained by this argument.
8
Another of Downs arguments is that producers are more likely to organize to get what they want out
of government than consumers. Consider, for example, the case of dairy farmers. For such people,
government policy toward milk is extremely important, since their whole livelihood depends on it. For
consumers, on the other hand, milk is only one of hundreds or thousands of things that they purchase. At
the same time, there are relatively few milk producers, which makes it easy for them to know one another
and organize. Milk consumers, on the other hand, are more numerous and therefore harder to organize.
For these reasons, milk producers are more likely to form effective lobbying organizations. This
argument, which generalizes to businesses of all kinds, seems a plausible explanation for the advantages
that many special interests have in getting their way with government.
Actually, these and other arguments in Downs book were originally proposed by scholars other than
cohesive theory about how democracy works if everyone is rational in the pursuit of their political goals.
One of Downs most intriguing arguments is that it is rational for voters to pay little attention to politics
and to rely on simple heuristics, such as party attachment and ideological labels, to decide how to vote.
This argument will be especially important to my theory of media politics and so will be considered below
in more detail.
Some four decades after it appeared in print, Downs' study still captures some of the most important
features of our political system. Politicians who cling to the middle of the road and voters who rely on
party attachment remain, as they were in the 1950s, among the most salient features of the American
political system. Notably, however, Downs specifies an entirely passive role for the journalistic profession
in his theory. The assumption seems to be that reporters reflect the political biases of their publishers but
In the 1950s, this may still have been a plausible assumption. The partisan press of the 19th
century, in which newspapers functioned as virtual adjuncts of the parties, had become far more neutral,
but some vestiges of the old way remained. For the most part, the mass media seemed unaccountably
unassertive, perhaps less assertive than at any other time in American history. In the nomination phase
of presidential selection, reporters basically just stood around outside the "smoke-filled rooms" at which
9
the real decisions were made, hoping for crumbs of information. And they were scarcely more intrusive in
general election campaigns. Even in Time and Newsweek, magazines known for their interpretive style,
typical campaign news consisted of chronological accounts of what the candidates were doing, laced with
lengthy verbatim quotes from their speeches. There were, to be sure, some publishers who played an
active role in politics, but they were acting as agents of their "party team" rather than as members of an
independent journalistic profession. In these circumstances, there was no need for Downs to posit an
independent role for the mass media in the process of elections and governance.
Circumstances, however, have now changed. The old partisan press is fully defunct, and so, for the
most part, is the "lapdog" press of the 1940s and 1950s (this apt term is from Sabato, 1993). Journalists
no longer stand idly by while party nominations are made or mechanically relay candidate information to
the voters in elections. They are key intermediaries in the process by which competing politicians attempt
to mobilize public support in both the nomination and general phases of presidential elections.
The change in the role of the mass media is part of a much larger change in American national
politics, a transition away from Party Politics as the predominant form of political organization and toward
a new system in which media politics is also important. Elaborating on earlier definitions, I suggest that
The defining feature of media politics, as the term is commonly used, is that
politicians seek to gain office, and to conduct politics while in office, through
communication that reaches citizens through the mass media. Parties and interest
groups formerly unchallenged kingpins of mass politics are often left on the
sidelines as independent politicians do battle by means of speeches, press
conferences, advertisements, photo-ops, and various other "public relations" events.
The basic dynamics of Party Politics have been well-understood for some decades through the work of E.
E. Schattschneider, V. O. Key, Jr., Joseph Schumpeter, Kenneth Arrow, and Downs, but media politics is
a relatively new form of organization and hence less well understood. My aim in this book is to develop a
10
theory of the new form and to accommodate it to traditional understandings of American politics, as
The first step in developing the theory is to specify the general goals of each of the key actors
candidates, voters, and journalists. I begin with candidates, the group whose behavior is easiest to
fathom. From the interests of all three types of actors, the dynamics of media politics will later be
deduced.
Downs theory focused on parties and assumed that their only political goal was to capture and hold
political office, formulating policies as necessary to achieve this goal. I make the same assumption,
except that my focus will be on individual politicians rather than on party teams.
Going beyond Downs, I shall also deal with the process by which politicians communicate their policy
proposals to voters, which is the defining feature of media politics. Let me begin with some historical
background.
In the heyday of 19th century party politics, communication with voters was not something that
presidential candidates worried about. As titular head of the Democratic or Republican party, they relied
on their fellow partisans to conduct their campaigns for them (McGerr, 1986). For the most part, this
meant turning the campaign over to city and state units which canvassed door-to-door for the party ticket
and offered public entertainment, in the form of torch-light parades and family picnics, as a means of
mobilizing support.
Most newspapers in the 19th century had an informal party affiliation and openly boosted its partys
candidates. To the likes of Joseph Pulitzer, Robert McCormick, and Otis Chandler, fiercely partisan
coverage was more a scared duty than a cause for embarrassment and it was not a duty that was
shirked any more in the news columns than on the editorial pages. Thus, in a study of partisan bias in of
the Chicago Tribune between 1900 and 1992, Burgos (1996) found that headlines attacking Democratic
candidates at the turn of the century were ten times more frequent than ones attacking Republicans. For
11
example, following a dinner gathering of GOP luminaries during the election of 1900, the paper
The person denouncing McKinley in the Tribune headline was Robert B. McArthur, the pastor of the
local Baptist church. If there were other local pastors who felt that the Republican candidate was the
demagogue, they were not given access to the Trib's news pages. As Burgos goes on to show, the
Tribune's blatant and one-sided partisanship declined gradually over the course of this century. As a
result, the paper had become essentially balanced in its presidential campaign coverage, and at much
Despite its glorious past, the tradition of unabashedly partisan journalism has been in decline since
about 1870, the point at which a group of dissident journalists founded a reform movement dedicated to
the ideal of non-partisan and objective coverage (McGerr, 1986). The transformation in the 1960s of
such partisan holdouts as the Los Angeles Times, the Chicago Tribune and Time magazine marked the
The capacity of local party organizations to mobilize support for candidates has also declined greatly
since the 19th century. The upshot is that candidates must now make their own way, both in presidential
primaries and in the general election. That is, they must get out on the campaign trail and try to create
events that a non-partisan press will see fit to report as news. The new situation is well-characterized by
Today, political leaders communicate with the public primarily through news
media that they do not control. The news media now stand between politicians
and their constituents. Politicians speak to the media; the media then speak to
the voters. (1993, p. 1)
Paid advertising helps presidential candidates out of this bind (Jamieson, 1996), but does not eliminate
12
How politicians go about trying to create favorable news is fairly well understood: On the one hand,
they attempt to take actions and create events that promote their campaign agenda and that are so
compelling that reporters will feel obligated to report them as news; and, on the other hand, they attempt
to avoid situations, such as news conferences, that make it difficult for them to control what gets reported
as news.
The kind of coverage that politicians want is also fairly obvious. They seek to be associated with
Candidates, however, may not always be completely clear about the policies they favor. As Downs
argued, a degree of ambiguity may increase their appeal to voters who might otherwise feel distant from
Ambiguity . . . increases the number of voters to whom a party may appeal. This
fact encourages parties in a two-party system to be as equivocal as possible
about their stands on each controversial issue. And since both parties find it
rational to be ambiguous neither is forced by the other's clarity to take a more
precise stand.
Subsequent scholars have not always agreed with Downs on this point (Shepsle, 1972; Bartels, 1988;
Alvarez 1997; but also Page, 1978; Jamieson, 1992, Chapter 9). But whether or not it is rational for
candidates to be deliberately ambiguous, it certainly is rational, if they can get away with it, for them to do
something rather similar: To take different positions in front of different audiences. For example, during
the 1968 presidential campaign, Nixon told northern audiences that he strongly supported the Supreme
Court's 1954 desegregation ruling, but, in a TV broadcast beamed to southern audiences, he carefully
suggested otherwise (Witcover, 1970, p. 385-86). Often because they are in danger of losing, candidates
also sometimes change positions during campaigns; make extravagant or unrealistic promises; or distort
the records of their opponents (Jamieson, 1992). When, for whatever reason, candidates do any of these
things, they want journalists to report their statements as "straight" news, without any hint of challenge.
Also, most politicians (like most non-politicians) have done things in the past that they find embarrassing
13
For politicians, then, the new goal of media politics is to get certain helpful kinds of campaign
information reported as news and to keep other, unhelpful kinds of information out of the news. Put more
As we shall see, this goal tends to bring candidates into more or less continuous conflict with
journalists, who have no interest in running the kind of news that politicians would most like and some
I shall assume that citizens have the same basic outlook in the age of media politics that they did in
the earlier age of party politics, as theorized by Downs. That is, citizens want to elect politicians who will
do what they, as individual citizens, want to have done. Yet, as Downs also argued, citizens are busy
people, and they are sensible enough to appreciate that, as individual voters, their chances to affect
election outcomes are minuscule. Hence, they instinctively minimize their electoral involvement, hoping
for a good result but refusing to put significant effort into it, including the effort necessary to study the
issues and candidates in the election. The payoff is simply not there. Voters are more likely to be
mugged on the way to the polls than to actually affect an election or other political outcome.2 Thus, as
Downs reasoned, for most citizens most of the time it is individually rational to be ignorant about politics.
Citizens will prefer to use their limited time for matters that provide a more direct and certain return for the
effort, such as playing with children, working overtime, or perhaps just watching a comedy on TV.
The question that now arises is the attitude of rationally ignorant citizens toward political news. The
answer, in broad outline, is obvious: They will mostly disdain it. Yet the little attention voters do pay may
be very important to politicians and journalists, since their livelihoods depend on the response of the
I should add that there are many kinds of news besides political news. These varieties include
entertainment news, consumer news, sports news, and medical news. Most business advertising is also
2 My colleague, Tom Schwartz, claims credit for this formulation of the classic problem.
14
a form of news, namely, product news. My theory of media politics is concerned only with political news,
by which I mean news that is primarily about public policy-making and leadership selection.
So what do rationally ignorant citizens want out of the relatively small amount of political news they
consume? I suggest several interests, each following in a loosely deductive sense from the basic notion
of rational ignorance.
Rational voters want to keep tabs on political events, if only to know how their tax bills or benefit
checks are likely to change. They just don't want to devote much energy to it. Hence, rational voters do
not want to be immersed in details, nor do they want large quantities of dense substantive information
and analysis, nor do they want news reports that attempt to be encyclopedic and comprehensive, full of
context and history about every aspect of the public affairs. Stated negatively, the overriding message of
Remember that this imperative concerns political news but not necessarily other kinds of news.
Indeed, the contrast with other kinds of news is illuminating. It is probably not rational for citizens to
ignore or mostly ignore health news, since it conveys information that can tangibly improve the length or
quality of their lives. Even if most health news were boring or irrelevant to one's personal condition, it
could still be worth paying close attention to it since the individual benefits of even an occasional story
that is personally relevant can be very great. But the same cannot be said for political news. A citizen
can spend his entire waking life digesting political news and, in consequence, make extremely wise
political choices and yet be no better off than if he or she had done no studying at all.
What the rational voter wants, then, is help in focusing as efficiently as possible on those matters that
As indicated, voters know or at least intuitively appreciate that it is not worth their time to give
careful consideration to their vote choices because their power to affect events is tiny. Yet despite this,
election outcomes can have quite large effects on individual voters. Depending on who wins, taxes may
15
be cut or raised, welfare or Medicare benefits may be expanded or slashed, the government may draft
young people to fight in overseas wars. In light of this fundamental asymmetry elections can affect
individual voters far more than individual voters can affect elections I reach the following conclusion:
The rational citizen will be more interested in information about how the
election is likely to come out than in information that will help him to cast a
wise vote.
To whatever (modest) extent rational voters seek information whose purpose is to help them form an
informed opinion or cast a wise vote, they will seek information about matters that are controversial.
When elites achieve a consensus on a policy, the policy is likely to be adopted no matter who wins the
election, and if this is so, there is no reason for each voter to try to figure out for herself or himself which
side is best and which candidate favors it. If, on the other hand, elites disagree, the election outcome
may determine what policy is adopted, thus giving voters an incentive to pay some bit of attention. By
When elites do disagree, each side works hard to articulate the best arguments for its position and to
expose the weaknesses of the other side's position. And they have every incentive to state their
arguments in terms that ordinary people can readily understand. By monitoring such disagreements,
citizens can often get incisive information on the basis of little effort. Of course, even a little bit of effort
may be more than most voters want to make. Yet they know that some of their fellow citizens will be
paying attention, if only for the entertainment value of politics, and they want this minority of politics
junkies to be able to see what it going on. And finally, even if voters do not themselves want to pay
attention to most conflicts, they want to retain the option of paying attention, in case some really important
issue should come up. For all these reasons, rational voters do not want political conflict swept under the
carpet, away from public view; nor do they want any elite group politicians or journalists to
When political elites disagree, rational citizens want exposure to both sides of the
argument, and under no circumstances do they ever want to see one side
monopolizing public discussion.
16
Nonetheless, rational citizens are ambivalent toward elite conflict, including conflict between
politicians and journalists. They are, as indicated, engaged by it and (insofar as they pay any attention)
wish to know both sides. But they also want to limit their attention to politics, and if elites engage in too
much fighting, then paying attention to conflict loses its value as a heuristic. Much like the harried parent
who scolds bickering children to "just work it out among yourselves," citizens wish to avoid being called
upon to arbitrate all of the numerous issues on which ideologically contentious and often self-interested
Rational citizens become impatient with elites who disagree too much,
withdrawing attention, trust, or votes, as appropriate.
Rational citizens want to be exposed to some but not a great deal of elite
conflict.
An important difficulty with this line of argument is that, although I have claimed that citizens wish to
focus on controversial matters because their vote or opinion is more likely to be consequential in such
matters, the possibility that an individual voter could ever be pivotal is extremely remote, even in a close
election turning on a controversial issue. Thus, as my UCLA colleague Tom Schwartz has observed, the
claim that a voter is more likely to be pivotal in a close election is like the claim that a tall man is more
likely to bump his head on the moon. In light of this basic political reality, it seems prudent to develop an
Since the difference between news and entertainment is often a subtle one,3 the most promising line
of argument is that citizens watch political news in order to be entertained. The question then arises:
It is beyond my power to develop an original theory of entertainment, so I will work from the
conventional view of what citizens find enjoyable in non-political domains of entertainment: sex, violence,
3 As Neuman (1991, p. 114) observes, "Theories of education and mass communication have been
troubled by a naive distinction between information and entertainment. Although in common parlance we
all routinely make such distinctions, in the practice of day-to-day mass communications the two elements
are inextricably intertwined. Neither the communicator nor the audience can meaningfully determine
which element of a message or which characteristic of the delivery medium is most successful in
attracting attention or in amusing or informing the audience."
17
suspense, humor, and human drama. Perhaps unfortunately, politics offers relatively little sex or humor
though it must be said that journalists are quick to exploit what there is of them but politics does
offer an abundance of a near-equivalent to violence, namely, political conflict. And where there is conflict,
there is often suspense and drama as to how it will be settled. Hence, one might argue that journalists
would tend to focus on political conflict because their audience will find conflict more entertaining than
consensus.
But how much conflict? To judge from movies and sports, the taste for conflict probably varies greatly
across individuals. Some people watch movies like The Texas Chain-Saw Massacre and go to ice
hockey games, while others prefer The Sound of Music and golf. Yet even in the most violent movies,
one rarely sees more than one episode of major violence every 15 minutes or so, and the same may be
true even for ice hockey. Boxing is more violent, but it has a small audience. If we take something like
Star Wars as the exemplar of a successful mass entertainment offering, we might infer that the taste of
the median entertainment consumer is for some but not a great deal of violence that is well-organized and
not too brutal. From this reasoning, I infer that entertainment audiences prefer political news having
As a separate matter, I note the widespread but by no means universal popularity of sports
broadcasting and sports news. Most sports offers some sort of violence, and all offer the distinctive
element of organized competition. From this one may infer that many citizens find competition per se to
be entertaining and that, by extension, many will be attracted to political news that describes such
competition.
To keep my parallel lines of argument clear, let me recapitulate: Reasoning from the notion of
rational ignorance, I infer that citizens want 1) to avoid wasting time on political news whose only purpose
is help them develop informed opinions and cast wise votes, and that insofar as citizens want any political
4 Violent entertainment nearly always includes stereotypically good guys and bad guys, thus suggesting
that having someone to cheer for and against is essential to the enjoyment of conflict. If today's citizens
fail to enjoy political conflict as much as my discussion suggests or as much as they seem to have
enjoyed it in the 19th century it may be because the non-partisan press, unlike its 19th century
counterpart, does not frame domestic political conflict as a battle between good guys and bad guys. See
McGerr, 1986.
18
news at all, they want news that 2) emphasizes what government is likely to do to citizens more than how
citizens can affect what government will do, and that 3) provides some but not a great deal of conflict.
Because the latter two or these inferences derive from the debatable assumption that rationally ignorant
citizens want any political news at all, I provided an auxiliary justification for them, which is that citizens
derive pure entertainment value from news that stresses competition and some but not too much conflict.
This analysis of mass preference for news is not based on the direct testimony of the citizenry, as
expressed in public opinion surveys. Such testimony seems to suggest higher levels of public interest in
politics than can be justified from the notion of rational ignorance. For example, 49 percent of
respondents to a 1992 survey said that they were "very much interested" in that year's political
campaigns, while 40 percent professed to being "somewhat interested" and only 11 percent said they
were "not much interested." Another question found that 27 percent claim to follow what's going on in
government and public affairs "most of the time," 41 percent follow it "some of the time," and 32 percent
These numbers, though not extremely high, nonetheless indicate more interest than my theory can
comfortably accommodate but also more than probably really exists. For there is a clear tendency of
many citizens to attribute more interest to themselves in verbal statements than they exhibit by their
actual political behavior. Thus, Doris Graber (1984) found in her study of the news consumption habits
that ordinary citizens were often bored by the news, but that they nonetheless
Over the years, journalists have occasionally tried schemes to increase the attention citizens pay to
19
...many editors and marketers think that the few noble experiments to improve
election issue coverage and offer more in-depth political reporting are up against
a basic obstacle: People really do not want more serious news, even when they
say they do. (p. 22-23)
Those who call for public-affairs programming on television do not tend to watch
it when it is made available... Those who claim to attend to the media for
purposes of acquiring information do score slightly higher on tests of learning and
recall, but the differences are surprisingly small...
The key finding ... that must be dealt with candidly if we are to understand the
nature of low-salience learning in regard to politics and culture is simply that
people are attracted to the path of least resistance. For knowledge acquisition in
general, and for public-affairs knowledge in particular, people are not inclined to
give such matters a great deal of effort. (p. 95, 103)
Politicians seem to have arrived at a similar conclusion. In the 1996 election, the major party
candidates were offered free TV time on an experimental basis by several networks, provided they use it
for a serious discussion of the issues. But Dole claimed only about three quarters of the time allotted him
and Clinton used his time for what seemed like boilerplate excerpts from his stump speeches. In the last
election in Britain, neither party used the full two hours of free TV time they are guaranteed by law, and in
Israel, there is a joke that when the candidates claim their free TV time, water pressure throughout the
The little attention citizens pay to the serious news they currently get suggests that they may want
All over the country the trend is to hire market research firms to find out how to
win more subscribers. The main casualty of packaging the press has been the
amount of space devoted to hard news whether local, state, national, or
international which has dropped sharply as publishers bend to popular tastes
and business pressures. (p. 20)
Perhaps the clearest indication that many citizens are not as interested in politics as they claim to be
is how few citizens possess even a rudimentary knowledge of the political system and its leading figures.
Only about a quarter can typically name the Speaker of the House of Representatives, and only ten
percent the Chief Justice of the Supreme Court information that is scarcely obscure. In 1992, after
nearly four decades of continuous Democratic control of the House of Representatives, only about half
20
knew which party controlled the House.5 It is easy to multiply such examples of citizen ignorance (Delli
The fact that citizens know something about government and politics shows that many pay passing
attention to public affairs. But it is hard to make the case that more than a few more than, say, the
mere 10 percent who can name the Chief Justice of the Supreme Court pay much more than that.
Journalists are a highly differentiated group. They are spread across newspapers, news magazines,
TV, and radio, and they vary in style from "happy talk" TV news anchors to the erudite Robert MacNeil of
PBS. My theory of media politics primarily concerns elite journalists, by which I mean journalists who
specialize in coverage of national politics or who work for a nationally prestigious organization such as the
New York Times, CBS News, or Newsweek. I focus on this group of journalists because, by common
observation, they tend to set the news agenda for other media. I shall sometimes refer to other
journalists, especially local journalists who do not specialize in national politics but do sometimes cover it,
because they may also affect media politics. But unless I specifically say so, all of my references to
What , then, do elite journalists want? How, if at all, can their "interests" be generally characterized?
A simple answer to this question is that, like politicians and just about everyone else, journalists want
career success. In the case of journalists, career success means producing stories that make it onto the
front page or get lots of airtime on the evening news, from whence flow fat salaries, peer respect, and
What, we must then inquire, gets onto the front page and the top of the evening news?
5 Actually, 59 percent named the Democrats in the 1992 survey, while about 10 percent named the
Republicans. If, as seems prudent, we assume that the 10 percent who named the Republicans were
guessing, there must have been another 10 percent who guessed Democrats and happened to hit the
right answer. Subtracting the likely percentage of guessers from 59 percent yields 50 percent an
impressively low number for such an obvious piece of information
21
Certainly one part of the answer is that, in the competitive business of journalism, the stories that
make it onto the front page are the ones that the public is interested in. From this it follows that the most
successful journalists are the ones who are most adept at appealing to the tastes of the mass audience.
Yet this is scarcely the whole story. For although the tastes and interests of the mass audience must
certainly affect the kind of news that journalists provide, it would be very dubious to assume that "what
elite journalists want" is to provide the mass audience with exactly what it wants. Indeed, the opposite
assumption may be closer to the mark: That what journalists want is to be freed from subservience to the
mass audience, so that they can provide the public with the kind of news that they, as professional
journalists, feel the public needs. "Too many of us in hard news," as CBS news anchor Dan Rather has
bluntly written, "are looking for that extra tenth of a ratings point" and thereby "blurring the distinctions and
standards between news and entertainment."6 In a similar vein, NBC anchor Tom Brokaw has openly
pined for the early days of TV news when journalists could dictate to a captive audience. "When I started
out in the 1960's," he said in an interview, "there were effectively two network news programs, and at 6:30
P.M. people turned on either Huntley-Brinkley or Walter Cronkite and got their news for the day. And I'd
The ambivalent attitude of elite journalists toward their clientele that is, wanting a large audience but
not wanting to kowtow to its low brow preferences is, I believe, similar to that of many other professional
groups, including architects, doctors, lawyers, and professors in research universities. What
professionals want is to sell their customers the most sophisticated product they can whether the
imaginative structures of elite architects, the heroic scientific medicine of top doctors, the hypercomplex
By sophisticated, I mean products that are complex, non-routine, and dependent on the special skill
of the provider. The reason that, as I suggest, professionals want to offer products that are sophisticated
22
in this sense is that they can charge more money for them, find them more interesting to work on, and
can more readily use them as vehicles for showing off to their peers.
Consider architecture. If an architect had a choice between designing a no-frills "box" or a building, or
instead an irregularly shaped, subtly shaded, and elaborately styled "structure" of her own design, which
would she choose? The latter, of course, since architects can get higher fees, more intellectual
satisfaction, and greater peer recognition for producing the latter type of building. The major constraint on
this professional impulse is the consumer, who might want "just a box", or at least something that costs
A primary difference between professionals and others kinds of business people is that professionals
are, to some extent, free of market constraints. They achieve this freedom by developing standards of
what good professional work consists of, socializing fellow professionals into accepting and applying
these standards, and educating the public to accept the standards. To whatever extent they can,
professionals also seek institutional support for their standards, whether in the form of favorable
government regulation, monopolistic control over work in their jurisdiction, or private sweetheart
arrangements. These professional standards may, of course, serve the socially useful purpose of limiting
charlatanism and quackery. They may also result in higher quality service than would be produced in a
purely competitive market, though any such judgment needs to be made on a case-by-case basis. But
they also help professionals to do more lucrative and interesting work than they otherwise could. In
economic terms, professional standards constitute an attempt to create cartels in restraint of trade. Or, as
George Bernard Shaw more colorfully put it, "every profession is a conspiracy against the laity."
There is a venerable tradition of studies in the sociology of the professions that emphasizes these
unsavory aspects of professional life (e.g., Larson, 1978). Yet professional cartels by which I mean
control of a work jurisdiction by an exclusive group are difficult to maintain, particularly under
conditions of rapid social or technological change, and they are doubly hard to maintain in the presence
of free market competition (Abbott, 1988). Consider briefly again the case of architecture: Because
architects, like journalists and many other professionals, must deal with clients having lamentably
unsophisticated "taste," and because even clients who have been socialized into accepting architects'
23
notion of good taste may lack the money to pay for it, there is always a market for architects willing to
forsake elite values by putting up no-frills buildings at low cost. Thus, within architecture and many other
work jurisdictions, there can be intense competition between higher and lower status providers.
Frequently, moreover, new groups rise to challenge old ones. Thus, as Abbott has described, social
workers challenge psychiatrists for control of the mental health jurisdiction. Likewise, accountants have
taken over a large part of the business formerly done by lawyers. Information technologists are
displacing traditional librarians. Solo practice physicians have lost ground to numerous groups, from
nurses to anesthesiologists and most recently to accountants. Throughout the professional world, there
is a continuous jostling among service providers and resultant reshuffling of both work jurisdictions and
The constant challenge for high status or elite professionals, then, is to develop sophisticated
services, to fend off competition by lower status and non-professional providers, and to get the
consuming public to accept their high status product. Acceptance may be achieved through open market
competition, but more often it is achieved by restraining competition through professional codes of
All of this applies in a straightforward manner to political journalism . Elite reporters would like to
produce a highly sophisticated news product, which in their case means a product rich in journalistic
interpretation and critical analysis. They want to do this because for reasons of pay, status, peer
Thus, journalists have an interest in creating and selling a form of journalism that offers more than
stenographic transcription of what others have said, or one that appeals to the lowest common
denominator of the mass market. What elite journalists want is a profession that adds something to the
news a profession that not only reports, but also selects, frames, investigates, interprets, and regulates
the flow of political communication. What journalists add should be, in their ideal, as arresting and
manifestly important as possible if possible, the most important part of each news report, so as to call
attention to journalists and to the importance of their work. Commenting in this vein on the rise of
24
The interpretive style empowers journalists by giving them more control over the
news message. Whereas descriptive reporting is driven by the facts, the
interpretive form is driven by the theme around which the story is built. As Paul
Weaver notes, facts become "the materials from which the chosen theme is
illustrated." The descriptive style casts the journalist in the role of a reporter.
The interpretive style requires the journalist to act also as an analyst. The
journalist is thus positioned to give shape to the news in a way that the
descriptive style does not allow.
The interpretive style elevates the journalist's voice above that of the news
maker. As the narrator, the journalist is always at the center of the story ... (p.
102)
The extent to which journalists can, in practice, get away with elevating themselves above the
newsmakers they cover is limited, since the news consuming public tends to be more interested in the
newsmaker than in the news reporter. Yet, as description of the journalistic ideal, Patterson's observation
is exactly right.
By "voice" I mean any sort of distinctively journalistic contribution, whether it be hidden information,
analytic perspective, or simply personality. It is not necessary for my model to work that every journalist
have a realistic chance to become Bob Woodward or George Will or Sam Donaldson, whose voices are
renowned throughout the land. It is enough that ordinary journalists find it materially and psychologically
rewarding to express as much voice in the news as they can persuade their audiences to accept.
The drive for journalistic voice is far from innocuous. In ways I will describe more fully below, it leads
journalists to adopt an adversarial stance toward others, most notably politicians, who venture onto their
turf and who, as already noted, also wish to control the content of the news; it leads them to create and
emphasize distinctive news products over which they can maintain control and which affirm their status as
being "in charge" of political communication; and, because so much political conflict now consists of what
are, in effect, propagandistic battles for public opinion, the desire for voice leads journalists to contest
political parties for "the organization of political conflict." By the organization of political conflict, I mean
25
the selection of issues and candidates for voter attention; the criteria for so selecting; and the kinds of
appeals that are made to voters. As I argue below, reporters often end up selecting the same candidates
and issues that party professionals select or would select, but they also make a distinctively journalistic
Like other professionals, journalists would not describe their motivations in such self-interested terms.
They would instead stress their commitment to supplying the hidden information and analytic
perspectives necessary for ordinary citizens to understand what is really happening. In their eyes, their
aggressive and increasingly interpretive styles of reporting serve to "protect" their news audiences, "who
cannot gather their own news," from politicians and others who have "axes to grind" and are trying to
mislead the public.8 But while such motives can lead to the same type of news product as the motive of
maximizing voice, it is tempting to interpret them as simply an ideological justification of the role they
would like to play. This justification has more than a little validity most successful ideologies do but
its validity is not the main point for journalists. The main point is the sophisticated conception of
Yet reporters are constrained in their desire to produce sophisticated product by the need to sell the
product to a consuming public that has, as noted, relatively little interest in political news. They are
further constrained by their inability to restrict competition from low-brow providers, such as tabloids,
"happy talk" anchor personalities, and talk radio. And, as we will see in a moment, journalists must also
contend with the challenge of an extra-professional group, politicians, who would also like to control the
content of mass communication. Ross Perot's brilliant use of interview programs like the Larry King Show
and Today is only one of many indications of this challenge. Hence, when elite journalists like Rather
and Brokaw complain about the decline of news standards, they are, in effect, complaining about their
inability to maintain control over their work jurisdiction. What they would like is to return to the days when,
8 The general thrust of this paragraph, along with the particular words in quotations, are adapted from an
insightful discussion in Gans (1979, 186) on the importance journalists attach to objectivity. I have altered
Gans' meaning by claiming that journalists see the background and analytic perspectives they supply as
serving the same function as objective information, namely, "protecting" the public from deception.
26
owing to the limited number of news outlets, they could do so on the basis of what was, in effect, a
Although elite journalists project an air of great dignity and cool self-confidence, their most important
mass outlets top newspapers, national news magazines, and network news shows are all losing
audience share. In contrast, local TV news and other forms of soft news are gaining market share.
Writing of network TV news, New York Times media critic Walter Goodman has written,
Television news, as your local anchor might put it, is under fire. The target is not
the violence that is agitating viewers and politicians, but a creeping tabloidization,
not only of local news, which serious observers have never considered of much
account, but of national news too, pride of the networks.9
What is true of network TV news is, to a lesser but still significant extent, true as well for other mass
outlets. Elite journalism is under fire more-or-less continuous fire from a mass audience that isn't
much interested in politics, lower-status journalists willing to meet the mass audience on its own level,
and politicians vying to control their own communication and increasingly adept at doing so. Elite
journalists are no patsies in this struggle, and they certainly do not appear to be in danger of going the
way of homeopathic healers, mediums, and other once successful but now defunct professional groups.
At the very least, they will survive as niche providers in a few big city newspapers, off-peak television
hours, PBS, and various cable and small-circulation venues. But elite journalists are in a more precarious
Let us, then, assume the existence of a citizenry with an interest in holding politicians accountable on
the basis of minimal political involvement or attention to the news; a journalistic profession with interests
in attracting large audiences and expressing journalistic voice; and politicians with an interest in building
political support via communication that reaches citizens through the news media. What follows from
these assumptions?
9 "'Tabloid Charge Rocks Network News," The New York Times, February 13, 1994, section 2, p. 29,
1994.
27
What follows, generally speaking, is a great deal of tension and sometimes open conflict among the
players. The key actors have quite different interests and they frequently jostle with one another in the
pursuit of them. The three most basic conflicts may be identified as follows:
Conflict between the interests of journalists and citizens. Journalists would like to produce a more
Conflict between the interests of politicians and journalists. Politicians and journalists both have an
Conflict between the interests of politicians and citizens. The basic interest of citizens is to hold
politicians accountable on the basis of what the politicians have accomplished while in office or say
they will accomplish if elected to office. Depending, however, on their accomplishments in office or
ability to deliver on their promises, some politicians may have an interest in bamboozling the public.
In these and other ways, media politics is rife with actual and potential conflicts between the major
actors. But it does not follow that any problem necessarily exists. Perhaps, for example, politicians have
an interest in bamboozling the public but are unable, because of journalists interest in exposing them, to
do so. Or perhaps it would be good for democracy if journalists were able to sell the public a little more
news than rationally ignorant citizens really want to consume. Before we reach any conclusions about
whether the conflicts I have identified are helpful, harmful or merely innocuous for democratic politics, it is
In the course of this book, I argue that these conflicts play out in the form of three patterns of
The Rule of the Market, or the tendency of market competition to force journalists to lower the overall
The Rule of Anticipated Importance, or the tendency of journalists to devote attention to occurrences
The Rule of Product Substitution, or the tendency of journalists to substitute their voice for that of
28
The next chapter takes up the Rule of the Market. Chapters 4 and 5 then develop the theoretical and
empirical groundwork necessary for testing rules of anticipated importance and product substitution. This
testing occurs in Chapters 6 and 7. Finally, Chapter 8 assesses the big question of how media politics
29