0% found this document useful (0 votes)
34 views3 pages

MATH 115: Lecture XI Notes

1) The document discusses higher-order derivatives, including definitions and examples of computing second and third derivatives. 2) Higher-order derivatives provide information about the instantaneous rate of change of the previous derivatives. For example, the second derivative measures the rate of change of the first derivative. 3) An example shows that the consumer price index (CPI) and its derivatives can be used to measure inflation and changes in the inflation rate over time. The first derivative represents the inflation rate, while the second derivative indicates whether inflation is increasing or decreasing.

Uploaded by

Dylan C. Beck
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
34 views3 pages

MATH 115: Lecture XI Notes

1) The document discusses higher-order derivatives, including definitions and examples of computing second and third derivatives. 2) Higher-order derivatives provide information about the instantaneous rate of change of the previous derivatives. For example, the second derivative measures the rate of change of the first derivative. 3) An example shows that the consumer price index (CPI) and its derivatives can be used to measure inflation and changes in the inflation rate over time. The first derivative represents the inflation rate, while the second derivative indicates whether inflation is increasing or decreasing.

Uploaded by

Dylan C. Beck
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 3

2.

) If demand is inelastic at a price p, then an increase in unit price causes an increase in rev-
enue. Likewise, a decrease in unit price causes a decrease in revenue.

3.) If demand is unitary at a price p, then an increase in unit price causes the revenue to stay
about the same.

Revenue from Loudspeakers, Cont’d. We note that demand is elastic when p = 300 since
E(300) = 3 > 1. On the other hand, when p = 100, we have that E(100) = 13 < 1, hence demand
is inelastic. Because demand is inelastic when p = 100, it follows by the above that an increase in
unit price causes an increase in revenue.

3.5 Higher-Order Derivatives


3.5.1 Higher-Order Derivatives
Recall that the derivative of a differentiable function f (x) is likewise a function f � (x). Often, we
are interested in whether f � (x) is differentiable. By definition of the derivative, we have that

d � f � (x + h) − f � (x)
[f (x)] = lim .
dx h→0 h
d
Given that this limit exists, we write dx [f � (x)] = f �� (x), read “f double prime of x.” Continuing
in this fashion, we may consider third-, fourth-, and higher-order derivatives. We write f �� (x) for
the second derivative, f ��� (x) for the third derivative, f (4) (x) for the fourth derivative, and in gen-
eral, we write f (n) (x) for the nth derivative of f (x). Like before, it is convenient to use equivalent
d2 y �� d3 y ��� dn y
notation dx 2 (or y ), dx3 (or y ), and dxn (or y
(n)
) for f �� (x), f ��� (x), and f (n) (x), respectively.

Higher-Order Derivatives of a Polynomial. Compute the derivatives of all orders of the


polynomial function f (x) = x5 − 3x4 + 4x3 − 2x2 + x − 8.

Solution. We have that

f � (x) = 5x4 − 2x3 + 12x2 − 4x + 1;

d �
f �� (x) = [f (x)] = 20x3 − 36x2 + 24x − 4;
dx

d ��
f ��� (x) = [f (x)] = 60x2 − 72x + 24;
dx

d ���
f (4) (x) = [f (x)] = 120x − 72;
dx

d (4)
f (5) (x) = [f (x)] = 120; and
dx

f (n) (x) = 0 for all n ≥ 6. �

32
Higher-Order Derivatives of a Power Function. Compute the first, second, and third deriva-
tives of the power function g(x) = x2/3 . What is the domain Dg��� of g ��� (x)? Give an intuitive ex-
planation of why Dg� differs from Dg .
Solution. We have that
2
g � (x) = x−1/3 ;
3
� �
�� 2 1 2
g (x) = − x−4/3 = − x−4/3 ; and
3 3 9

� �
��� 2 4 8 −7/3
g (x) = − − x−7/3 = x .
9 3 27
Observe that we have Dg��� = {x : x �= 0} = (−∞, 0) ∪ (0, ∞). We note that this is the domain
of all derivatives of this power function. We note that the domain of g(x) is given by Dg = R. We
can explain the difference between Dg and Dg� by observing that as x approaches 0, the slope of
the line tangent to g(x) grows arbitrarily large, hence g � (x) does not exist at x = 0. �
Higher-Order Derivatives of a Composite Function. Compute the second derivative of the
composite function h(x) = (2x2 + 3)3/2 .
Solution. Using the General Power Rule from section 3.3, we have that
d 3
h� (x) =
h(x) = (2x2 + 3)1/2 · (4x) = 6x(2x2 + 3)1/2 .
dx 2
Using the General Power Rule and the Product Rule, we have that
d � 1
h�� (x) = [h (x)] = (6x) · (2x2 + 3)−1/2 · (4x) + 6(2x2 + 3)1/2
dx 2

= 12x2 (2x2 + 3)−1/2 + 6(2x2 + 3)1/2

12x2 + 6(2x2 + 3)
= (Get a common denominator.)
(2x2 + 3)1/2

6(4x2 + 3)
= √ . �
2x2 + 3
Recall that the derivative of a differentiable function f (x) at a point (x, f (x)) gives the slope of
the line tangent to f (x) at that point, i.e., the derivative of f (x) measures the instantaneous
rate of change of f (x) at the point (x, f (x)). Given that f � (x) is differentiable, it follows that
the second derivative of f (x) gives the slope of the line tangent to f � (x) at the point (x, f � (x)),
i.e., the second derivative of f (x) measures the instantaneous rate of change of f � (x) at the point
(x, f � (x)). Given that f (x) has derivatives of all orders, continuing in this way, it follows that the
derivative of f (n) (x) gives the slope of the line tangent to f (n) (x) at the point (x, f (n) (x)), i.e., the
derivative of f (n) (x) measures the instantaneous rate of change of f (n) (x) at the point (x, f (n) (x)).
Often, these higher-order derivatives have meaningful interpretations.

33
Magnetic Levitation Train, Cont’d. Recall that the position of the magnetic levitation train
from before is given by the quadratic function s(t) = 4t2 , where s(t) is the distance (in feet) cov-
ered by the train, and t is time (in seconds). We note that the first derivative of s(t) gives the
velocity s� (t) = v(t) of the train at time t. Furthermore, the second derivative of s(t) gives the
acceleration s�� (t) = v � (t) = a(t) of the train at time t. Computing the velocity and acceleration of
the train at time t, we have that v(t) = 8t and a(t) = 8. We interpret these results as saying that
at time t, the train is traveling at a speed of 8t feet per second in the positive direction, and the
train’s speed is increasing by a rate of 8 feet per second per second in the positive direction.

Ball Launch from a Rooftop. Consider tossing a ball straight up into the air from the roof
of a building. We will assume that the motion of the ball is given by s(t) = −16t2 + 24t + 120,
where s(t) is the height of the ball from the ground measured in feet, and t is the time from the
launch. Determine the height of the building. Compute and interpret the meaning of the velocity
and acceleration of the ball 3 seconds after launch.

Solution. We note that s(0) = 120, hence the building is 120 feet tall. We compute the veloc-
ity and acceleration by taking the first and second derivative of s(t), respectively. We have that
v(t) = −32t + 24 and a(t) = −32. We interpret these results as saying that at time t, the ball is
traveling at a speed of −32t + 24 feet per second in the positive direction, and the ball’s speed is
increasing by a rate of 32 feet per second per second in the negative direction. �
Unsurprisingly, higher order derivatives have interesting interpretations in economics, as well.
Definition. We say that the consumer price index (CPI) measures changes in the price level
of a fixed market basket of consumer goods and services purchased by households over time.
Use the function I(t) (a ≤ t ≤ b) to denote the CPI from year a to year b. Observe that the first
derivative of I at time t = c (a < c < b) yields the rate of change of I at c, given by I � (c).
I � (c)
Definition. We define the inflation rate of the economy at time t = c as the quantity I(c)
.

By definition, the second derivative of I at time t = c (a < c < b) yields the rate of change of
I � at c, given by I �� (c). Certainly, it is possible for I � (t) to be positive while I �� (t) is negative. We
interpret this as indicating that the economy is experiencing inflation since the CPI is increasing;
however, the rate at which the CPI is growing is decreasing. Briefly stated, inflation is slowing.

Inflation Rate of an Economy. Consider the CPI function I(t) = −0.2t3 + 3t2 + 100 from the
year 2008 to 2016 (0 ≤ t ≤ 9). Find the inflation rate at the beginning of 2013 (t = 6). (Round to
four decimal places, if necessary.) Prove that inflation was decreasing at that time.

Solution. We have that I � (t) = −0.6t2 + 6t, hence I � (6) = 14.4 and I(6) = 164.8. By definition, we
� (6)
have that the inflation rate is II(6) ≈ 0.0874 = 8.74%. We prove that inflation was decreasing at
the beginning of 2013 by showing that I �� (6) < 0. We have that I �� (t) = −1.2t + 6, from which it
follows that I �� (6) = −1.2. We conclude that inflation was decreasing in early 2013. �

34

You might also like