03 Frangi Routh Press
03 Frangi Routh Press
ABSTRACT
For the purpose of trade union renewal, it is suggested that trade unions
need to convert themselves from being institutions centred on employer-
employee relations to open source ones engaged with broader social justice issues.
In this article, we offer two elements to the debate on trade union revival: first,
we focus on two rapidly emerging economies with a corporatist and state-
centered union structure (i.e., Brazil and India); second, in the context of these
two countries, we challenge the idea that informal workers are a burden for trade
union organizations. We consider the possible contributions that informal
workers could make towards the renewal of trade unions in these two countries.
We argue that trade unions could take advantage of these contributions if they
overcome the employee horizon, which originated in Western countries and
excludes millions of workers from its purview in Brazil and India. We propose
the concept of “homo faber” as a new horizon for trade union organization, which
is inclusive of both formal as well as informal workers.
INTRODUCTION
T
he debate about the “crisis of unionism” (e.g., Hyman 2002; Turner et
al. 2001) has been countered by many studies (e.g., Fairbrother and
Yates 2003; Levésque and Murray 2006), which focused on different
possibilities to foster union renewal, as a “process of change, underway or
desired to put new life and vigour in the labour movement to rebuild its
43 Just Labour: A Canadian Journal of Work and Society—Volume 21 —Spring 2014
organizational and institutional strength” (Kumar and Schenk, 2006: 30). Many
scholars suggest that unions have to enlarge their horizon to renovate and
revitalize themselves from institutions concerned only with employer-employee
relations to open source institutions engaged with broader social justice issues
(Heery et al. 2012; Fitzgerald and Hardy 2010). This debate is not only limited to
Western countries, but has also drawn academic and union practitioners’
attention in the global South (Benson and Zhu 2008; Chen et al. 2007; Druck,
2006).
Within the framework of this debate, we focus specifically on the possibility
of union renewal in the global South countries through the inclusion of informal
workers into the trade union movement (Gallin 2001; Bonner and Spooner 2011).
If an overall suspicion has prevailed amongst trade unions over the effectiveness
of including informal workers into their fold, our specific aim is to highlight
some positive contributions that informal workers could bring to trade unions’
revitalization in the global South countries.
Our analysis is based on two national cases, namely Brazil and India. These
countries are emerging economies in the global scenario and becoming part of
the most prominent and dynamic world economies (e.g., Jain 2006; ECLAC 2011;
Dossani and Kennney 2009). Irrespective of the tremendous economic changes,
Brazilian and Indian trade unions are still peripheral in character and the
informal economy represents a wide share of their economic activities (IPEA data
2009; NCEUS 2008).
In the first section of this article we introduce the major challenges for
unionism, with a focus on developing countries. In the second section we
underline a specific definition of informal economy and consider three central
limitations, highlighted in scholarly literature, for the inclusion of informal
workers into trade union organizations. We subsequently analyze the
institutional peculiarities of unionism in Brazil and India. In section four, after
tracing a general panorama of the relation between trade unions and informal
workers in the two countries (i.e., inclusive, partial inclusive, or exclusive), we
focus on some important experiences of membership-based organizations of
informal workers in waste-picking, since this is one of the most relevant activities
in the informal economy (Medina 2007). The organizational experiences of
informal workers allow us to propose three principal considerations in the
subsequent section. First, we contradict the perceived adverse impact of informal
workers on trade unionism; secondly, we identify possible resources for trade
unions’ revitalization if the informal workers are included; and thirdly, we
indicate certain aspects that traditional industry-based trade unions can mobilize
in order to attract informal workers. Our analysis challenges the largely taken for
granted “employer-employee” horizon for trade union organization.
Accordingly, we propose the homo faber concept as a possibly more inclusive new
horizon for the overall workforce (including informal workers).
Frangi & Routh 44
From the early stages of industrialization the principal aim of unions has
been the improvement of employment terms and conditions by exercising
institutional pressure towards employers and governments. (Bennet and
Kaufman 2007). With the spread of industrialization from the European core
countries to the global South (Wallerstein 2004), not only were industrial
technologies and productive techniques exported, but as a byproduct, unionism
was also on rise in these countries. However, in the global South, unionism
assumed distinctive characteristics, essentially because it was molded on
economic, political, and cultural environments markedly different from the core
industrial countries (Freeman 2009). Especially since the traditional focus of
unionism in the industrial heartland countries had been dependent on the
employer-employee relation, unions covered only a minority of labour dynamics
in the global South countries where a significant number of workers are not
party to an employer-employee relation. In these countries the formal economic
activities—where employer-employee relation is evident—is coupled with a
persistent huge share of informal economic activities, where the employment
relationship is blurred or even absent (Chen et al. 2007).
From the 1980s onwards, the world economy underwent profound structural
changes, calling into question labour institutions and existing forms of employee
representation. Even if the situation has not been identical in all countries, trade
unions have generally faced difficulties in adjusting and reacting to these global
changes. International studies focusing on this issue of union movement have
largely tended towards the conclusion of a widespread “crisis of unionism” (e.g.,
Hyman 2002; Turner et al. 2001).
In the core industrial countries, the debate about the crisis of unionism is
primarily focused around the substantial decrease in union density in the last
three decades and its consequences (e.g., Ebbinghaus and Visser 2000; Pedersini
2010). With regard to global South countries, the limitations of union
effectiveness in the last decades are substantially debated; trade union
ineffectiveness has been attributed to difficulties in reaching, organizing, and
representing the huge number of workers that are active outside formal
economic activities (e.g., Gallin 2001; Bonner and Spooner 2011). This union
ineffectiveness is important because in spite of some evidence of economic
developments, informal economic activities have not disappeared over time as
was predicted by some scholars, but rather, have been confirmed as expanding
and becoming central to the global South economies (e.g., Chen 2005; Dibben and
Williams 2012). In many cases often over 75 percent of the labour force is
engaged in informal businesses and employment (Jütting and De Laiglesia 2009).
45 Just Labour: A Canadian Journal of Work and Society—Volume 21 —Spring 2014
Brazil and India are two remarkable examples. These two countries are now
considered amongst the most prominent national economies on the global level,
overcoming their peripheral role in the global economic system (e.g., Jain 2006;
ECLAC 2011; Dossani and Kennney 2009). However, two aspects are still central
in these two countries, along with the economic development phenomenon.
First, dramatic social problems typical of global South countries (e.g., the
presence of megalopolises which continue to attract unregulated immigration;
deep social differences) are aggravated by an enormous number of informal
workers in these two countries. According to IPEA data, nearly half of all
Brazilian, and more than 93 percent of Indian workers (NCEUS 2008) are in some
way engaged in informal economic activities. Second, Brazilian and Indian trade
unions are still marginal in character. In fact, as we discuss in section three, they
are only marginally effective in defining national labour dynamics and are
especially unable to substantially influence the working conditions of millions of
informal workers.
Scholars have noted that informal work in the global South is largely relied
upon for survival purposes and in the large majority of cases, does not yield to
overcome the poverty of workers (Mehrotra and Biggeri 2007). In fact, large
proportions of informal economic activities are low paid, highly insecure, and
have poor working conditions (NCEUS 2007; Breman 2009; Jackson 2011).
Irrespective of the relevance of informal workers in the labour market and the
widespread miserable conditions of informal workers, trade unions are generally
suspicious and mistrustful about the possibility of involving informal workers in
their organizations for several reasons (Bonner and Spooner 2011). Among these
reasons, two have been considered prominent with the third being central.
First, in a strategic cost-benefit evaluation, integrating informal workers is
considered a counterproductive investment by the trade unions. In fact, in the
context of widespread union difficulties, primarily reflected in financial
shortages, the integration of informal workers demands significant time and
financial resources while offering uncertain future returns. Reaching out to
informal workers, who are generally scattered and engaged in a diverse range of
activities exerts significant strain on limited resources. Second, unions perceive a
mismatch between their organizational goals and the aspirations of informal
workers. Many informal workers are primarily concerned with mere survival; a
characteristic that is perceived as hampering, or worse, undermining inter-
worker solidarity, one of the fundamental aspects for collective action by unions
(Gallin, 2001).
However, the third central hesitation of trade unions in organizing informal
workers is that many of them are engaged in self-employment or own account work
and accordingly, fall outside the traditional employer-employee horizon of trade
union organization; a horizon originated in the core industrial countries, but that
excludes millions of people from union protection in the global South (Bonner
and Spooner, 2011). But, are informal workers just a burden for trade unions?
Are there resources that informal workers can bring forth for union renewal in
Brazil and India? We address these issues in the following sections.
In order to answer the above questions, the first step is to highlight the
characteristics of Brazilian and Indian trade unionism.
The current features of Brazilian trade unionism are primarily the outcome of
a corporative and demiurgic state-centred, top-down interventionist policy
during the 1940s (Kaufman, 2004). During that period, the state, through central
47 Just Labour: A Canadian Journal of Work and Society—Volume 21 —Spring 2014
planning promoted the interests of the emerging industries and limited the
possibility of a bottom-up workers’ organization (French, 2001). These policies
were mainly pursued through the promulgation of a fundamental law:
Consolidação das Leis do Trabalho—CLT (1943, Vargas government).3 The CLT
defined the structure and strictly limited the action of collective actors in
industrial relations. Moreover, the CLT detailed the manifold dynamics of the
labour market with a paternalistic approach towards workers. Brazil is defined
as a legislado (legislated) model of industrial relations because labour dynamics
are principally determined by law and the outcome of collective bargaining
processes is marginal (Noronha, 2000). In any case, the huge volume of labour
market laws do not include any specification about informal workers—an
omission that has excluded a significant share of Brazilian workers from the
paternalistic coverage of the CLT rights.
In Brazil, the CLT requires the Labour Ministry to recognize a single union
(called sindicato de base) in each territory (i.e., one municipality or a cluster of a
few) for all the workers in a specific sector and with a specific profession. This
legal principle results in a highly fragmented union representation, even inside
the same firm, which seldom come together in supra-territorial or national union
organizations (Cardoso and Gindin 2009)4. Furthermore, each sindicato de base has
the right to receive revenues from a public tax (imposto sindical) applied to all
workers of a specific territory and specific profession, irrespective of workers’
affiliation to a union. Therefore, there is a weak relationship between the
economic resources available to unions and the number of their affiliates.
Unions, largely ineffective in industrial bargaining, have exploited the state-
embeddedness of the industrial relations scenario and have invested much
energy into political bargaining (i.e., lobbying the state organisation) through
political parties as well as establishing direct relationships with the state
apparatus in order to influence labour regulation (Schneider 2009).
If unions had a central role in triggering the overthrow of the military regime
(1985) (the period called novo sindicalismo [new unionism]), they have faced hard
times afterwards (Sluyter-Beltrão 2010). Union hardship was more visible during
the 1990s as a result of the great economic transformation of Latin America: the
neoliberal turn (Weyland 2007). Three changes in the labour market particularly
weakened the trade unions in Brazil (Ramalho 2010): employment shrinkage in
the traditionally unionised sectors; large outsourcing, which contributed to a
substantial erosion of the traditional form of employment covered by the CLT
(carteira assinada) in favour of the emergence of the atypical forms (i.e., self-
employed, own-account, cooperatives, among others); and, the substantial
increase of the informal economy between the early 1990s and 2002 (which then
slightly decreased).
Since the 1990s, the trade union crisis in Brazil is both quantitative as well as
qualitative. First, there was a substantial decrease in the number of affiliated
Frangi & Routh 48
During the pre-independence era, while the British intended to establish and
control trade unions in India for strategic administrative purposes, they soon
realized that industrial and labour conditions in India were not similar to the
ones prevailing in the United Kingdom. The significant majority of Indian
workers laboured outside the industry setup. The large diverse ranges of
informal economic activities that Indian workers were engaged in were not
conducive to trade union organizations. Accordingly, British colonial officers
concluded that Indian workers could not be organized in trade unions (Wolcott
2008). The trade union movement did not establish roots in India until the 1920s
(discussed presently).
After the Indian independence in 1947, the government pursued a planned
industrialization policy. Similar to Brazil, the Indian government’s primary
strategy to control industrial relations was through legislative mechanism. Two
of the most important industrial relations statutes in India are the Industrial
Disputes Act 1947 and the Factories Act 1948. The first seeks to establish
“industrial peace” and the second imposes liability on the employer for the
safety, health, and welfare of workers employed in factories, thus, detailing
many aspects of the labour-management dynamics. However, none of these two
legislative pillars include any labour rights extendible to informal workers.
Accordingly, informal workers, who constitute the significant majority of the
49 Just Labour: A Canadian Journal of Work and Society—Volume 21 —Spring 2014
increasingly blurred, due to the frequent worker transition from the one to the
other (NCEUS 2008: 44).
In the post-1991 period, trade unions were perceived as an inhibiting factor
towards the liberalization of the economy. Both central and state, governments
introduced reforms that would substantially reduce the already deplorable
bargaining power of trade unions. Unions concentrated more and more on fewer
formal workers—essentially the public sector white-collar workers (Kuruvilla
and Erickson 2002; Bhangoo 2006; Rao 2007)—and suffered substantial losses in
terms of union density. Due to this, some unions internally debated the
possibility to also organize informal workers (Sundar 2008: 160-162).
These experiences are generally locally based. One example is the SINTEIN
(Sindicato dos Trabalhadores na Economia Informal de São Paulo; Union of workers in
informal economy of São Paulo) that was organized as an umbrella union for
informal workers by the CUT (Central Unica dos Trabalhadores) of São Paulo.
Other selective initiatives have been undertaken by the CUT in Rio de Janeiro
and in Sergipe to organize a sector largely marked by informality (i.e., domestic
workers by the Sindicato das trabalhadoras domésticas do Rio de Janeiro and Sindicato
das trabalhadoras domésticas do Sergipe).
Unions have also attempted to reach informal workers indirectly, mainly
through collaboration with state actors, national and international NGOs, and
community-based organizations through projects promoting the welfare of lower
income citizens, most of whom are active in the informal economy (Ramalho,
2010). Frequently, in these mostly state-funded projects, unions are often
indicated as the leading organizations because of their well-established
organizational structure and their long lasting relations with the state apparatus.
In particular, CUT established a new national department in 1999 (Agência de
Desenvolvimento Solidário/CUT) focused on the sustenance of the economic
solidarity initiatives, most of which are targeted towards informal workers. In
this case, trade unions have primarily concentrated their actions in providing
some technical support—and not co-opting informal workers into union
membership—in order to sustain already exiting solidarity-based economic
initiatives, such as microenterprises and cooperatives, some of them in waste-
picking activities. Additionally, we have to note, as argued by Lima (2007) and
Souza (2008), many of the unions promoting solidarity-based economic
initiatives contribute to the erosion of the core employee profile (carteira assinada),
which has already been largely destabilized by neoliberal policies.
Even if unions are not markedly active in organizing informal workers,
informal workers have demonstrated that they are not amorphous. There are
several examples of informal workers’ membership-based organizations in the
country and in the informal waste-picking activity in particular (Velloso 2005;
Dias 2010; Coletto 2010; Coelho and Godoy 2011). Even though these
organizations principally promote the economic interests of the members, many
of them are engaged with broader social right issues of the members (Coletto
2010).
Some membership-based organizations developed important networks of
collaboration amongst themselves in order to promote the economic as well as
social rights of their members. De Aquino et al. (2009) described some cases of
economic collaboration amongst the waste-pickers’ organizations in the South of
Brazil. Dias (2010) underlines that self-managed waste-pickers’ organizations
demonstrate the ability to come together through the federation, especially to
facilitate social rights of the catadores. For example, the CATAUNIDOS unites
eight waste-pickers’ self-managed organisations in the region of Belo Horizonte.
Frangi & Routh 52
In 2009, SEWA had 1,256,944 members across India, among them 631,345
members in the state of Gujarat. SEWA’s financing is based on annual
membership contribution from members (of five rupees) and donations from a
range of government and private donors, Indian and foreign. The trade union’s
governance is carried out by a mix of professional cadres and informal worker
members—high levels of participation by members in all aspects of the union
characterise SEWA functioning (Bhat 2006).
Even though delivery of services is the primary goal, SEWA’s role is not
limited to it. SEWA has a strong external presence (both national and
international) in the policy-development sphere. Counting on the members’
engagement and participation, SEWA lobbies the government on several issues
in favor of informal workers and against myriad forms of discrimination against
women informal workers (Dave, Shah and Parikh 2009).
The Kagad Kach Patra Kashtakari Panchayat (KKPKP) is another important
example of the non-amorphousness and organisational strength of informal
workers in India.7 The KKPKP is a union of waste-pickers in Pune, Maharashtra.
KKPKP registered itself as a union in 1993 (Antony 2001). Unlike SEWA, KKPKP
admits both men and women members (Chikarmane and Narayan, undated).
One of the principal purposes of the union is to promote waste-picking as
productive, valuable, and meaningful work in order to ensure that waste-pickers
are recognized and respected as workers (Shekar 2009). The KKPKP works on
the same principles that SEWA adopts in its functioning. While on one hand the
KKPKP organizes to provide for socio-economic benefits to its members, on the
other, it mobilizes its members for direct political action and lobbying.
Like Brazil, waste-pickers’ organizations in India are also developing
coalitions in furthering their interests. The KKPKP became part of a coalition of
eight waste-pickers’ organizations from the states of Bihar, Delhi, Gujarat,
Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, and Maharashtra, who forged an alliance called
SWACHH in 2005 (KKPKP, 2009). The KKPKP functions as the secretariat for the
alliance. SWACHH is currently constitutive of twenty-four organizations
working with waste-pickers’ problems. SWACHH prepared a national policy on
solid waste management, and proposes to lobby government(s) in order to
implement their policy proposal. Issues such as gender discrimination, door-to-
door waste collection, organizational assistance, and networking are some of its
mandates.
These informal workers’ organizations are mostly ignored by formal sector
trade unions. Accordingly, scholars note that the major challenge for traditional
trade unions in India today is to successfully integrate the “interests and
objectives” of informal workers (Haan and Sen 2007: 80).
Frangi & Routh 54
picker organizations entered into relations with public actors in order to achieve
contracts for waste collection (Velloso 2005; Pereira and Teixeira 2011). They
thereby demonstrate their capacity to collectively interact with public actors and
to be accountable for their actions.
Not only does analysis of the Brazilian and the Indian cases suggest some
counter-evidence to concerns regarding the negative impact of informal workers
in unions, it also underlines three specific resources that informal workers in
both countries can offer for union renovation. An appreciation of these possible
strategic resources could sensitize a union to adopt a more inclusive perspective
on membership, rather than favoring a closure with narrower core members.
First, in both countries the opening of the national economy to global
challenges since the 1990s has largely eroded the already feeble union strength.
Even if there are some little signs of recovery, the current trade union density is
far away from the glorious era of novo sindicalismo in Brazil, when unions had a
relevant social protagonism. Similarities can be seen with the Indian case where
unions became even more fragmented and marginal social actors in the
industrial relations scenario.
In Brazil, after the neoliberal turn, trade unions have followed a defensive
strategy, mainly targeting white-collar public sector employees for membership.
The public sector white-collar employees are a category of workers whose rank
and file activity is historically limited. Similarly in India, in the post-
liberalization era, unions have mostly drawn their strength from public sector
workers who constitute a small minority of workers in the country.
A shift from formal employees to a wider worker horizon can provide unions
with higher probabilities to maintain the critical mass to persist as a reliable
social and political force, in terms of the numbers of workers represented.
Moreover, by targeting informal workers in addition to formal employees,
unions can benefit from the shift from a concentration of white-collar public sector
workers—who generally enjoy high salaries and good working conditions in these
countries—to the incorporation of the vitality, resistance habits, and experience
of informal workers shaped by the hardship of their working conditions. This
qualitative membership change could also contribute towards trade union
renovation.
Second, including informal workers into union membership will also pose an
open challenge to the structural state-centred features of the Brazilian and Indian
industrial relations dynamic. In Brazil, union efforts to organize informal
workers in their regular membership—and not as marginal constituents, as
observed—can be a way to open a fissure in the corporative iron cage of
57 Just Labour: A Canadian Journal of Work and Society—Volume 21 —Spring 2014
unionism as determined by the CLT. In fact, the CLT and the other laws about
trade unions do not take into account any possible representation of informal
workers. In India, the three primary legislations regulating industrial relations—
the Industrial Disputes Act, 1947, the Factories Act, 1948, and the Trade Unions
Act, 1926—all take industrial employees as their point of reference and
accordingly, leave informal workers from the purview of legislative safeguards.
SEWA challenged this strong employer-employee framework of labour laws
despite being initially refused registration as a trade union because its members
were not employed in an establishment. However, the union got registered by
challenging the predominant notion of employment in an establishment. In any
case, its self-employed members remain organized separately from (formal)
employees. A wider organizational horizon by Indian unions can overcome this
mutually exclusive organizational dualism (i.e., unions for formal and unions for
informal workers) and thereby largely challenge the dense labour law apparatus
that excludes millions of workers.
Third, trade unions in Brazil and in India are a highly fragmented
organizational lot characterized by many divergences. In Brazil, the numerous
sindicatos de base organized along professional and territorial cleavages and in
India, the different national party-linked and independent unions undermine the
unity of a comprehensive collective representation. Even if the first impression
about the inclusion of informal workers suggests that just another dimension is
being added to the already fragmented trade union movement in these two
countries by the inclusion of the informal workers into their organizations, the
trade unions can create new spaces of convergence and develop possible agendas
for collaboration. In fact, informal workers are transversally widespread in
different sectors, professions, and regions but share important common
characteristics, specificities, and necessities. Integrating informal workers can, in
turn, provide an important point of agenda-convergence amongst many different
unions in Brazil, as well as in India. Some evidence of this convergence has
become apparent recently in India (Sundar 2008: 170-172).
CONCLUSION
In India and Brazil, countries that have passed through a dramatic economic
growth in the more recent years, informal activities represent a substantial share
of labour market occupations. Moreover, these countries are characterized by
mainly corporative and state-centered unionisms, not particularly effective in
defining labour conditions.
Additionally in these two countries, and more generally in the global South,
unions are generally suspicious about the possibility of integrating informal
workers into their membership. Involving informal workers is considered a
financial drain. Moreover, informal workers are considered amorphous.
However, the most significant limitation in organizing informal workers is that
they fall outside the traditional employer-employee relation. We challenged
these three aspects and attempted to offer a different perspective, (i.e., one in
which informal workers can bring resources to union revitalization).
First, it is a matter of number and representation. Through the organization
of informal workers in India and Brazil, unions can gain a critical mass and get
closer to lower level workers and not just remain the representative of a marginal
and wealthier share of workers such as the white-collar elite public workers.
Second, the inclusion of informal workers can pose a challenge to the state-
centered corporative structure of industrial relations in the two countries,
thereby opening some fissures in the legal iron cage that does not take into
account the millions of informal workers. Third, the organization of informality
can become an element that can promote agenda convergence and links among
the highly fragmented union structure in Brazil and India.
In order to take advantage of the resources that informal workers can bring to
revitalize unions, a significant change in the union organizational horizon is
required. We propose the homo faber perspective as the new union horizon, which
is inclusive of both formal and informal workers. This radical change is not easy,
but the stakes are high for the integration of informal workers. It can become a
turnaround in the prevention of human misery, still high in both the countries,
and in the promotion of a wider distribution of the positive economic growth
that Brazil and India are undergoing, which has not yet benefitted the majority of
informal workers.
61 Just Labour: A Canadian Journal of Work and Society—Volume 21 —Spring 2014
NOTES
1 Dr. Frangi also collaborates with the Interuniversity Research Centre on Globalization and
Work - Centre de recherche interuniversitaire sur la mondialisation et le travail
(CRIMT).
2 Work on this article was done as a Rechtskulturen Fellow at the Faculty of Law,
Humboldt University, Germany.
3 “Consolidação das Leis do Trabalo” (CLT) can be translated as the consolidation (in
the sense of systematization) of labour laws. CLT is a collection that comprises
several labour laws from 1930, clearly influenced by the fascist labour code
previously emitted by Mussolini in Italy (Cook 2007).
4 For example, in the Brazilian division of a multinational corporation Frangi (2012)
counted more than 120 sindicatos di base. Among national unions organizations
(centráis sindicais), the most important ones are: CUT (Central Única dos Trabalhadores)
that is placed on progressive positions; and FS (Força Sindical), which is
comparatively more conservative.
5 The Act also charts out the rights and obligations of members of registered trade
unions. However, if a trade union is not registered as per the law, members of the
trade union do not enjoy statutory rights provided under the Trade Unions Act.
6 Based on the Trade Unions Act, 1926, definition the Labour Department refused to
register SEWA as a trade union, reasoning that since there were no recognised
employers, workers of the union would have no one to bargain or struggle against.
SEWA argued that a trade union does not need to be posed against employer(s) since
the primary purpose of a trade union is the promotion of unity amongst workers. See
SEWA(c); Bhat 2006: 9-10, 17-18.
7 Kagad Kach Patra Kashtakari Panchayat (KKPKP), available at
http://www.wastepickerscollective.org/ (site visited 7 June 2012).
8 At the national level an example of lobbying success is the constitution of the NCEUS
under pressure from the trade unions in the country. Trade Unions such as SEWA
had been instrumental in pursuing the Commission and the resultant legislation
(Bhat 2006; Hill 2010: 76-77). National Commission for Enterprises in the
Unorganised Sector (NCEUS) constituted by the Government of India in the year
2004 (Reserve Bank of India 2008).
REFERENCES
Ali, S. 2011. “Indians on Strike—Caste and Class in the Indian Trade Union
Movement”. New Labor Forum. 20(2): 33-39.
Antony, P. 2001. Towards Empowerment: Experiences of Organizing Women Workers.
New Delhi: ILO.
Bayat, A. (2004): “Globalization and the Politics of the Informals in the Global
South”. Pp. 79-102 in Urban Informality: Transnational Perspectives from the
Middle East, Latin America, and South Asia, edited by A. Roy and N. Alsayyad.
Lanham, MD: Lexington Books,.
Frangi & Routh 62