0% found this document useful (0 votes)
62 views

Introduction To The Black-Scholes Formula Applying The Formula To Other Assets Option Greeks Delta-Hedging Volatility

The document discusses the Black-Scholes formula for pricing European call and put options. It covers the assumptions of the Black-Scholes model, how to apply the formula, and defines the Greek letters (delta, gamma, vega, theta, rho, psi) used to analyze how the price of an option changes with respect to changes in other variables. It also provides examples of calculating option prices and Greeks.

Uploaded by

Cedric Wong
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
62 views

Introduction To The Black-Scholes Formula Applying The Formula To Other Assets Option Greeks Delta-Hedging Volatility

The document discusses the Black-Scholes formula for pricing European call and put options. It covers the assumptions of the Black-Scholes model, how to apply the formula, and defines the Greek letters (delta, gamma, vega, theta, rho, psi) used to analyze how the price of an option changes with respect to changes in other variables. It also provides examples of calculating option prices and Greeks.

Uploaded by

Cedric Wong
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 42

The Black- Scholes Formula

• Introduction to the Black-Scholes


formula
• Applying the formula to other assets
• Option greeks
• Delta-hedging
• Volatility

1 / 42
Binomial pricing

• Vary the number of binomial steps (think about the


multiperiod example), fix the expiration
• What if infinite number of steps?
• Black-Scholes formula is a limiting case of binomial
formula for the price of a European option

2 / 42
Black-Scholes Formula

• Consider an European call (or put) option written on a


stock
• Assume that the stock pays dividend at the continuous
rate δ
• Same notation as in the binomial pricing model

3 / 42
Black-Scholes Formula (cont’d)
• Call Option price

C(S, K, σ, r, T, δ) = Se−δT N (d1 ) − Ke−rT N (d2 )

• Put Option price

P (S, K, σ, r, T, δ) = Ke−rT N (−d2 ) − Se−δT N (−d1 )

∎ where
ln(S/K) + (r − δ + 21 σ 2 )T √
d1 = √ and d2 = d1 − σ T
σ T
• N (x) is the cumulative normal distribution, the
probability that a number randomly drawn from a
standard normal distribution will be less than x.
• Function “NormSDist” in Excel2007
4 / 42
Normal distribution
• N (x) is the cumulative normal distribution, the
probability that a number randomly drawn from a
standard normal distribution (mean is 0, std. dev. is 1)
will be less than x
(http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Cumulative distribution function).
• Normal distribution
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Normal distribution
• For example,
• N(0)=0.5 chance of average: half
• N(1)=0.841345
• N(-1)=0.158655
• N(2)=0.97725
• N(-2)=0.02275
• N(1)-N(-1)=0.682 chance of falling within [-1,1]
around the mean
5 / 42
Normal distribution

Top panel: Area


under the normal
curve to the left of
0.3. Bottom
panel: Cumulative
normal
distribution. The
height at x = 0.3,
given by N(0.3), is
0.6179.

6 / 42
Black-Scholes (BS) Assumptions

• Assumptions about stock return distribution


• Continuously compounded returns on the stock are
normally distributed and independent over time (no
“jumps”)
• The volatility of continuously compounded returns is
known and constant
• Future dividends are known, either as dollar amount
or as a fixed dividend yield

7 / 42
Black-Scholes (BS) Assumptions (cont’d)

• Assumptions about the economic environment


• The risk-free rate is known and constant
• There are no transaction costs or taxes
• It is possible to short-sell costlessly and to borrow at
the risk-free rate

8 / 42
Applying BS to Other Assets

• Call Options
p
C(F0,T (S), F0,T
p
(K), σ, T ) = F0,T
P
(S)N (d1 )−F0,T
P
(K)N (d2 )

• where
P
ln[F0,T (S)/F0,T
P
(K)] + 12 σ 2 T √
d1 = √ and d2 = d1 − σ T
σ T
and
P
F0,T (S) = Se−δT ; F0,T
P
(K) = Ke−rT

9 / 42
Applying BS to Other Assets (cont’d)

• Options on stocks with discrete dividends


• The prepaid forward price for stock with discrete
dividends is
P
F0,T (S) = S0 − PV0,T (Div)

• Example
• S = $41, K = $40, σ = 0.3, r = 8%, t = 0.25, Div =
$3 in one month
• The BS European call price is ?

10 / 42
The BS European call price is ?

11 / 42
What if dividends is zero?

12 / 42
Applying BS to Other Assets (cont’d)

• Options on currencies
• The prepaid forward price for the currency is

P
F0,T (x) = x0 e−rf T

• Where x is domestic spot rate and rf is foreign


interest rate
• Example
• x = $0.92/e, K = $0.9, σ = 0.10, r = 6%, T = 1,
and rf = 3.2%
• The dollar-denominated euro call price is ?
• The dollar-denominated euro put price is ?

13 / 42
Applying BS to Other Assets (cont’d)
• Options on futures
• The prepaid forward price for a futures contract is the
PV of the futures price. Therefore

C(F, K, σ, r, T ) = F e−rT N (d1 ) − Ke−rT N (d2 )

∎ where
ln(F /K) + 21 σ 2 T √
d1 = √ and d2 = d1 − σ T
σ T
• Example
• Suppose 1-yr. futures price for natural gas is
$2.10/MMBtu, r = 5.5%
• F = $2.10, K = $2.10, and δ = 5.5%
• If σ = 0.25, T = 1, call price = ? put price = ?

14 / 42
Option Greeks

• What happens to option price when one input changes?


• Delta (∆): change in option price when stock price
increases by $1
• Gamma (Γ): change in delta when stock price
increases by $1: positive for either long call or put
• Vega (Λ): change in option price when volatility
increases by 1%
• Theta (θ): change in option price when time to
maturity decreases by 1 day
• Rho (ρ): change in option price when interest rate
increases by 1%
• Psi (Ψ): change in the option price when there is an
increase in dividend yield of 1%

15 / 42
Option Greeks (cont’d)
• Delta (∆) is the change in option price when stock price
increases by $1
• How to find this out? We are thinking about

C(S + 1, K, σ, r, T, δ) − C(S, K, σ, r, T, δ)
S +1−S
• Formula for call delta: ∆call = e−δT N (d1 ) positive for
long call
• Formula for put delta: ∆put = −e−δT N (−d1 ) = ∆call − e−δT
negative for long put
• Greek measures for portfolios of n options each with
quantity wi , i = 1, 2, ...n.
• The Greek measure of a portfolio is weighted average
of Greeks of individual portfolio components
∆portfolio = ∑ni=1 wi ∆i
• The following graphs show long positions only
16 / 42
Option Greeks – Delta

● Deltas for European puts and calls with different times to


expiration; assume K = $40, σ = 30%, r = 8%, δ = 0.

17 / 42
Option Greeks – Gamma
● Gammas for European puts and calls with different times to
expiration; assume K = $40, σ = 30%, r = 8%, δ = 0. The
figures in the two panels are identical

18 / 42
Option Greeks – Vega
● Vegas for European puts and calls with different times to
expiration; assume K = $40, σ = 30%, r = 8%, δ = 0. The
figures in the two panels are identical

19 / 42
Option Greeks – Theta
● Panels (a) and (b) show the price as a function of time to
expiration for in-the-money, at-the-money, and
out-of-the-money calls and puts. Assume
K = $40, σ = 30%, r = 8%, δ = 0 (to be continued).

20 / 42
Option Greeks – Theta (Cont’d)
● Panels (c) and (d) show call and put thetas as a function of
the stock price for three different times to expiration. Assume
K = $40, σ = 30%, r = 8%, δ = 0.

21 / 42
Option Greeks – Rho

● Rhos for European puts and calls with different times to


expiration; assume K = $40, σ = 30%, r = 8%, δ = 0.

22 / 42
Option Greeks – Psi

● Psis for European puts and calls with different times to


expiration; assume K = $40, σ = 30%, r = 8%, δ = 0.

23 / 42
Option Greeks (cont’d)
∎ Greeks for the bull spread examined in Chapter 3, where
S = $40, σ = 0.3, r = 0.08, and T = 91 days, with a purchased
40-strike call (option 1) and a written 45-strike call (option 2).
The column titled “combined” is the difference between
column 1 and column 2.

40-strike call 45-strike call Combined


ωi 1 -1 –
Price 2.7804 0.9710 1.8094
Delta 0.5824 0.2815 0.3009
Gamma 0.0652 0.0563 0.0088
Vega 0.0780 0.0674 0.0106
Theta -0.0173 -0.0134 -0.0040
Rho 0.0511 0.0257 0.0255

24 / 42
Option elasticity

• Option elasticity (Ω)


• the if stock price changes by ε delta approximation
gives the approximate change in the option price:
ε×∆
• this works for small ε
• the if stock price changes by ε delta-gamma
approximation gives the approximate change in the
option price: ε × ∆ + 12 ε2 × Γ
• this works better when ε becomes larger

25 / 42
Option elasticity (cont’d)

• Option elasticity (Ω)


• Ω describes the risk of the option relative to the risk
of the stock in percentage terms: If stock price (S)
changes by 1%, what is the percent change in the
value of the option (C)?
change in C change in S×∆
% change in C S∆
Ω≡ = C
change in S
= C
change in S
=
% change in S S S
C

• S = $41, K = $40, σ = 0.30, r = 0.08, T = 1, δ = 0


• Elasticity for call:
Ω = S∆/C = $41 × 0.6911/$6.961 = 4.071
• Elasticity for put:
Ω = S∆/C = $41 × (−0.3089)/$2.886 = −4.389

26 / 42
Option elasticity (cont’d)

• Option elasticity (Ω) (cont’d)


• The volatility of an option σoption = σstock × ∣Ω∣
• The risk premium of an option γ − r = (α − r) × Ω
• The Sharpe ratio of an option
• Recall Sharpe ratio is the mean excess return
over its standard deviation
• Sharpe ratio for call = α−r
σ =Sharpe ratio for stock
• where ∣ . ∣ is the absolute value, γ: required
return on option, α: expected return on stock,
and r: risk-free rate

27 / 42
Option elasticity

● Elasticity for call and put options with different times to


expiration; assume K = $40, σ = 30%, r = 8%, δ = 0.

28 / 42
Delta-Hedging

• Market makers attempt to hedge in order to avoid the risk


from their arbitrary positions due to customer orders
• Market-makers can control risk by delta-hedging
• Delta-hedged positions should expect to earn risk-free
return

29 / 42
Delta-Hedging

• Delta hedging entails using the stock to offset the risk of


the option
• If you are a market maker, writing these options exposes
you to risk of the underlying, thus it is necessary to cover
the positions with stocks
• If you short a call, long stocks, if you short a put, short
stocks

30 / 42
Delta-Hedging (cont’d)

• Market-maker sells one option, and buys ∆ shares


• To self-finance, market-maker has to borrow money to
buy stocks
• Three sources of profit
• overnight gain on shares ∆t (St+1 − St ), less
• overnight change on the option Ct+1 − Ct , less
• interest rM Vt where M Vt = ∆t St − Ct is the market
value of the portfolio

31 / 42
Delta-Hedging (cont’d)

• Investor always has a positive gamma, but market-maker


always has a negative gamma (recall delta-gamma
approximation)
• Recall gamma is the same for both call and put
• Recall market-maker also has to borrow money to buy
stocks (financing cost)
• Still, source of market-maker profit to delta hedge a call:
positive theta – calls become less expensive with time.
This is called time decay.
• Therefore the matter is which effect is larger
• Again, zero sum game between an investor and a
market-maker

32 / 42
Delta-Hedging (cont’d)

Price and Greek


information for a call
option with Purchased Written
S = $40, K = $40, σ = Call price 2.7804 -2.7804
0.30, r = 0.08 Delta 0.5824 -0.5824
(continuously Gamma 0.0652 -0.0652
compounded), Theta -0.0173 0.0173
T − t = 91/365, and
δ = 0.

33 / 42
Delta-Hedging (cont’d)

• Delta-hedging for 2 days: (daily rebalancing and


marking-to-market):
• Day 0: Share price = $40, call price is $2.7804, and
∆ = 0.5824
• Sell call written on 100 shares for $278.04, and
buy 58.24 shares.
• Net investment:
(58.24 × $40) − $278.04 = $2051.56
• At 8%, overnight financing charge is
$0.45[= $2051.56 × (e0.08/365 − 1)]

34 / 42
Delta-Hedging

• Delta-hedging for 2 days: (daily rebalancing and


marking-to-market):
• Day 1: If share price = $40.5, call price is $3.0621,
and ∆ = 0.6142
• Overnight profit/loss:
($40.5 − $40)58.24 + ($2.7804 − $3.0621)100 −
$0.45 = $29.12 − $28.17 − $0.45 = $0.50
• Buy (0.6142 − 0.5824)100 = 3.18 additional
shares for $128.79 to rebalance

35 / 42
Delta-Hedging

• Delta-hedging for 2 days: (daily rebalancing and


marking-to-market):
• Day 2: If share price = $39.25, call price is $2.3282
• Overnight financing charge is
$0.48[= ($2051.56 + $128.79) × (e0.08/365 − 1)]
• Overnight profit/loss:
($39.25 − $40.5)61.42 + ($3.0621 − 2.3282)100 −
$0.48 = −$76.78 + $73.39 − $0.48 = −$3.87

36 / 42
Overnight profit as a function of the stock price for a
delta-hedged market maker who has written a call. Bad:
gamma and interest expense. Good: theta.
Overnight Profit ($)

5
$0.50 Profit
0

-5

-10

-15

-20

-25 $40.50

-30

37 38 39 40 41 42 43
Stock Price ($)
37 / 42
Delta-Hedging (cont’d)

• What about put delta-hedging?


• Long a put, buy shares to delta hedge
• Write a put, sell shares to delta hedge
• Investor always has a positive gamma, but market-maker
always has a negative gamma (recall delta-gamma
approximation)
• The matter is how large the price change is
• Investor also has to borrow money to buy stocks
(financing cost)
• For investor, theta can be positive or negative. Positive
means the put option is more valuable

38 / 42
Implied Volatility

• Volatility is unobservable
• Choosing a volatility to use in pricing an option is difficult
but important
• One approach to obtaining a volatility is to use history of
returns
• However history is not a reliable guide to the future
• Alternatively, we can invert the Black-Scholes formula to
obtain option implied volatility

39 / 42
Implied Volatility (cont’d)

• The volatility of the returns consistent with observed


option prices and the pricing model (typically
Black-Scholes)
• One can use the implied volatility from an option
with an observable price to calculate the price of
another option on the same underlying asset
• Checking the uniformity of implied volatilities across
various options on the same underlying assets allows
one to verify the validity of the pricing model in
pricing those options

40 / 42
Implied Volatility (cont’d)

• The volatility of the returns consistent with observed


option prices and the pricing model (typically
Black-Scholes)
• In practice implied volatilities of in, at, and out-of-the
money options are generally different resulting in the
volatility skew
• Implied volatilities of puts and calls with same strike
and time to expiration must be the same if options
are European because of put-call parity

41 / 42
Implied Volatility (cont’d)

Black-Scholes
implied volatilities
for S&P 500
options, October
19, 2007, based
on midday option
prices from
www.cboe.com;
assumes S =
1508.08, r = 4.5%,
and δ = 0.02.

42 / 42

You might also like