0% found this document useful (0 votes)
71 views

The Impact of Capital Requirements On Bank Lending: Jonathan Bridges David Gregory

This paper estimates the impact of changing banks' capital requirements on bank capital ratios and lending. It uses data on bank-specific capital requirements in the UK from 1990 to 2011 to examine how banks adjust their capital levels and lending over time following changes in requirements. The key findings are: 1) After an increase in requirements, banks gradually rebuild the capital buffers they hold above the minimum over time. 2) In the year after an increase, banks cut loan growth most for commercial real estate, then other corporate and household secured lending, while growth recovers within three years.

Uploaded by

Muhammed Ayon
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
71 views

The Impact of Capital Requirements On Bank Lending: Jonathan Bridges David Gregory

This paper estimates the impact of changing banks' capital requirements on bank capital ratios and lending. It uses data on bank-specific capital requirements in the UK from 1990 to 2011 to examine how banks adjust their capital levels and lending over time following changes in requirements. The key findings are: 1) After an increase in requirements, banks gradually rebuild the capital buffers they hold above the minimum over time. 2) In the year after an increase, banks cut loan growth most for commercial real estate, then other corporate and household secured lending, while growth recovers within three years.

Uploaded by

Muhammed Ayon
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 35

The impact of capital requirements

on bank lending

Jonathan Bridges David Gregory


Bank of England Bank of England

Mette Nielsen Silvia Pezzini*


Bank of England Bank of England and
Hong Kong Monetary Authority

Amar Radia Marco Spaltro


Bank of England Morgan Stanley

This version: May 7, 2015


Previous version: Bank of England Working Paper No. 486

Abstract

This paper estimates the impact of changing banks’ capital


requirements on bank capital ratios and bank lending. It exploits changes
in bank capital requirements by banking supervisors in the United
Kingdom between 1990 and 2011, provides a novel breakdown of the
lending effects by economic sector and a timeline over which the effects
take place. There are two key results. First, following an increase in
capital requirements, banks gradually rebuild the buffers they hold over
the regulatory minimum so they remain constant. Second, in the year
following an increase in capital requirements, banks, on average, cut (in
descending order based on point estimates) loan growth for commercial
real estate, for other corporates and for household secured lending. Loan
growth mostly recovers within three years. These results may help
quantify how changing capital requirements might affect lending in a
macroprudential policy framework.

Key words: bank capital, bank lending, regulatory capital requirements,


capital buffer, macroprudential policy.
JEL classification: G21, G28.

Corresponding author: Silvia Pezzini: [email protected].


The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Bank of
England or any other institution. We would like to thank Jas Ellis, Haroon Mumtaz, Vicky Saporta, Ron
Smith, James Talbot, Garry Young, an anonymous referee to the Bank of England working paper series, and
seminar participants at the Bank of England and at its Centre for Central Banking Studies, EEA 2013, the
INFINITI Conference on International Finance, the 45th Annual Money Macro and Finance Conference, and
ECOBATE for helpful comments, suggestions and advice, and various members of the Bank of England
Statistics and Regulatory Data Division for help in constructing the data set. Marco Spaltro undertook his
work on the paper while at the Bank of England.
1 Introduction
This paper estimates the effect of changing regulatory capital requirements on bank
capital and bank lending and the time profile of this adjustment. We contribute to the
literature by presenting a holistic view of how banks react to changes in their individual
capital requirements - in particular, we estimate how banks adjust their level of capital; over
what horizon; what categories of sectoral lending, if any, banks adjust; for how long; and how
the adjustment to capital and to lending interact simultaneously.

Having built a rich new data set, we run panel regressions of, first, lending to different
parts of the economy on regulatory capital requirements and observed capital ratios, and
second, of capital ratios themselves on capital requirements. We use the estimates to build
impulse responses that track banks’ capital and sectoral lending responses to a permanent one
percentage point increase in capital requirements. The shape of the impulse responses is
allowed to vary freely both in the short and the long run and takes account of both the direct
impact of a change in capital requirements on lending, and the indirect impact via the
response of bank capital. Robustness checks are also included to examine differences in
responses across time periods, types of banks, and whether capital requirements increase or
decrease.

We are able to exploit several unique features of our data set. By using data on
confidential bank-specific and time-varying capital requirements set by the Bank of England
and the Financial Services Authority (FSA) in the UK between 1990 and 2011, we are able to
directly estimate the relationship between changes in capital requirements and individual
bank lending behaviour. By examining the response of lending at the sectoral level, we allow
both credit supply and credit demand to vary across different sectors of the economy –
to
our knowledge a novel extension to the existing literature. We also estimate responses at the
bank group level (rather than for individual entities) and use a unique measure of ‘true’
lending flows.

This paper has two key findings on the transmission of capital requirements on to bank
lending. The first is that regulatory capital requirements affect the capital ratios held by
banks – following an increase in capital requirements, banks gradually rebuild the buffers
that they initially held over the regulatory minimum. Second, capital requirements affect
lending to the real economy and the effects are heterogeneous across sectors. In the year
following an increase in capital requirements, loan growth falls most to the commercial real
estate (CRE) sector, followed by other corporate lending and household secured lending. The
response of unsecured household lending is not significantly different from zero. Further out,
loan growth for most sectors recovers.

Empirical evidence on the link between capital requirements and bank lending, especially
with a calibration of the effects at the sectoral level, is of great interest to policymakers. The
financial crisis has led to widespread support for the use of capital requirements as a policy
tool (for example Yellen (2010) and Hanson et al (2011)) and it is important to be able to
anticipate the effects of the policy on the real economy. Most jurisdictions around the world

2
are in the process of implementing the countercyclical capital buffer, a key macroprudential
policy instrument in the Basel III framework that increases banks’ capital requirements when
lending is booming and reduces them when lending enters a downturn cycle. In the UK, the
Financial Policy Committee has the additional power to set higher capital requirements on
lending to particular sectors of the economy (household and corporate lending as well as on
intra financial system exposures). 1 While banks’ reactions under a macroprudential policy
framework may differ to some extent (different signalling and leakage mechanisms may apply),
our findings aim to help anticipate how banks may react in their capital levels, their lending
response and over what timeline.

The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. In Section 2 we briefly review the
existing literature on the effects of capital and capital requirements on bank lending. Section 3
describes our data set and presents summary statistics. We explain our econometric
methodology in Section 4. Section 5 presents our results and discusses their implications.
Section 6 presents some extensions and robustness checks and Section 7 concludes.

2 Literature

The relationship between bank capital, bank capital requirements and bank lending has
been studied from a number of different angles over the past. The academic literature on this
subject is rooted in theoretical studies exploring the relationship between a firm’s liability
structure and its cost of funding. A number of empirical studies followed on the impact of
changes in overall capital held by a bank on its lending behaviour. A third strand of literature
explores the impact of regulation on bank capital requirements on bank lending. This strand
has grown in prominence with the advent of macroprudential policy and the need to assess
the relative impact of different policy tools.2

Below we review the theoretical and empirical literature with a specific focus on the
quantitative effects of capital requirements on the supply of credit and place our study in the
context of that literature.

2.1 Early studies

The theoretical benchmark for understanding the impact of a shock to capital funding
remains the Modigliani-Miller theorem (Modigliani and Miller (1958)). In the context of the
banking sector, the key prediction is that changes in the composition of a bank’s liabilities
should not affect the overall funding cost, assuming an unchanged level of risk on the asset
side of the balance sheet. And without a change in funding costs, there is no reason why a

1
Bank of England (2014) provides additional information on these tools.
2
A separate strand of the literature also investigated other aspects of policy such as the ‘bank lending channel’,
or the conditions under which bank lending acts as a channel for monetary policy (Gambacorta and Mistrulli (2004)
and Gambacorta and Marques-Ibanez (2011)). We do not review this literature here.

3
change in the capital ratio of a bank, ceteris paribus, should impact on the price or quantity
of credit.

There may be various frictions in the market for bank equity, however, which cause
changes in capital requirements to have real effects, either in the short or long term. The most
often cited long-term friction is the tax deductibility of debt interest payments, which implies
an increase to bank’s funding costs when capital requirements are raised. Other long-term
frictions include debt overhang –
Myers (1977) –
and asymmetric information Myers and –
Majluf (1984). The existence of short-run frictions might depend on how a bank chooses to
meet a change in its capital requirements. For example, the costs associated with different
ways of adjustment (e.g. cutting dividends versus raising equity) may have implications for
funding costs, and consequently, lending decisions.

In this paper, by investigating the effects of a change in bank capital requirements on


lending behaviour, we implicitly test the existence of such failures of Modigliani-Miller.
Identifying specific frictions is, however, beyond the scope of the paper.

2.2 Impact of changes in capital held on lending

Much of the literature on the impact of capital shocks on bank lending emerged after the
US recession in the early 1990s, prompted by questions as to whether the economic situation
was exacerbated by capital-constrained banks cutting back on lending – the so-called ‘capital
crunch’ hypothesis. Bernanke and Lown (1991) found that in some regions, a shortage of
equity capital – caused in some cases by bank losses on real estate lending – did limit banks’
ability to make loans, although it is not clear whether the credit crunch played a major role in
worsening the recession.3 Sharpe (1995) argues that the evidence in favour of a capital crunch
is not particularly conclusive. Furfine (2000), in a theoretical model calibrated to the US data,
finds instead that capital regulation can explain the decline in loan growth and the rise in
bank capital.

Peek and Rosengren (1997) use a natural experiment which allows them to disentangle the
impact of a credit supply shock (caused by a reduction in bank capital) from that of credit
demand effects. They analyse the US lending operations of the branches and subsidiaries of
Japanese banks located in the United States, which suffered a large capital shock after the
collapse of equity prices in the late 1980s. They find that a one percentage point fall in the
risk-based capital ratio led to an annual fall in loan growth relative to assets of 4 percentage
points. An alternative identification strategy exploits individual loan-level data (where
availability allows), including matched bank and borrower information. Jimenez et al (2013)
exploit a matched panel for Spain. They find that lending varies with the capital and liquidity
positions of both banks and borrowers as well as with macroeconomic conditions. Albertazzi

3
This was on account of the low coefficients on the capital ratio, suggesting, for example, that the 1988-90 fall

in capital in New England banks explained only 2 to 3 percentage points of that region s significant decline in
lending (total loans fell by 14% between 1990 Q2 and 1991 Q1).

4
and Marchetti (2010) find similar results when using loan-level data on Italian banks for the
period following the collapse of Lehman Brothers.

Heid et al (2004), using dynamic panel data techniques on data from German savings
banks over the period 1993-2000, find evidence that capital buffers influence decisions on both
capital and risk-weighted assets. They find that banks with lower buffers attempt to rebuild
them by simultaneously raising capital and lowering risk-weighted assets; banks with larger
buffers, instead, raise capital and at the same time increase their risk-weighted assets. Stolz
and Wedow (2005), however, using an enlarged sample including data for German cooperative
banks in addition to savings banks, find that poorly capitalised banks do not decrease risk-
weighted assets by more in a downturn than their better capitalised rivals. Similarly, Rime
(2001), in a study of Swiss banks during the period 1989-95, finds that banks with a lower
capital buffer tend to try to increase their capital ratio, but that they adjust through the level
of capital rather than through risk-weighted assets.

Noss and Toffano (2014) study the dynamics of capital and lending at the aggregate level
in the United Kingdom, using time series and a VAR identification approach to identify past
– through their associated movement in other variables,
shocks to banks’ capital ratios that
including lending growth and corporate bond issuance – might proxy for a shock to bank
capital requirements. They find that the level of bank lending might be reduced by as much
as 4.5% in response to a 1 percentage point increase in macroprudential capital requirements
during an economic boom.

Finally, in a study of banks in over 90 countries, Fonseca et al (2010) find that banks with
larger capital buffers charge lower interest rates on their lending and pay lower funding costs
on their borrowing. They find that this effect is larger in developing countries and during
downturns.

2.3 Impact of changes in capital requirements on capital buffers and


lending

Our approach falls into the third branch of literature which links directly changes in
capital requirements and bank lending behaviour. Recent micro-econometric studies tend to
focus on the UK because historically banks have faced different capital requirements over the
past two decades and the regulators have adjusted them relatively frequently.

Ediz et al (1998), in a study using confidential supervisory data for UK banks, find that,
over the period 1989-1995, banks reacted to changes in capital requirements by adjusting the
total level of capital rather than by altering lending. Alfon et al (2005) estimated that UK
banks tend to pass through around 50% of an increase in capital requirements to their capital
ratios (and 20% of reductions in capital requirements).

One well-known approach in this area is the partial adjustment model, in which banks
adjust over time to their target level of capital. Following the partial adjustment process
introduced by Hancock and Wilcox (1994) and using 1996-2007 data, Francis and Osborne
(2009) estimate a target capital ratio for each bank in the UK, which is found to depend

5
principally on the individual bank capital requirement (positively) and bank size (negatively).
The authors then regress bank lending behaviour on the deviation of the actual capital ratio
from target and estimate that a one percentage point increase in capital requirements is found
to lead on average to a fall in total lending of 0.8% and a fall in risk-weighted assets of 1.6%
after one year.

The Macroeconomic Assessment Group (2010), established by the Financial Stability


Board and the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision to assess the impact of higher
regulatory capital and liquidity requirements under Basel III, used the methodology in Francis
and Osborne (2009) amongst others to estimate across different jurisdictions the impact on
lending volumes from a one percentage point increase in the target capital. For an increase in
the capital requirement taking place over two years, these estimates ranged from a 0.7% to a
3.6% fall in lending.

A recent paper looking at the impact of capital requirements on bank behaviour is Aiyar
et al (2014). The aim of their research is to assess whether increases in capital requirements
‘leak’, in the sense that foreign branches can offset reductions in lending by regulated banks.
The paper focusses only on corporate lending and uses a panel data fixed effects framework
that regresses loan growth on changes in capital requirements. It finds, first, that the average
effect of a 1pp increase in capital requirements is a cumulative reduction in corporate loan
growth ranging between 5.7 and 8 percentage points. And second, that ‘leakages’ of regulation
can be considerable – foreign branches operating in the UK offset around a third of the
reduction in corporate lending by UK banks.

3 Data

3.1 Data set construction and overview

A strength of our study is the rich panel data set of UK-supervised banks that we have
constructed. This data set matches new, high-quality sectoral lending data with unique
supervisory data on capital and capital requirements. It fills gaps in existing data sets in a
number of ways and improves the precision of our estimates over existing studies.

First, our data contain a large number of changes to bank capital requirements; we can
access these confidential data because they were collected under the UK regulatory regime.
Second, the sample period (1990-2011) is long enough to measure banks’ behaviour in different
phases of the economic cycle; to our knowledge it is the longest data series used in UK studies.
Third, the lending flows in our data reflect ‘true’ bank lending behaviour, following
considerable efforts by the statistical team at the Bank of England to build a time series that
does not include changes in lending stocks due to reasons other than lending. Fourth, the
analysis of lending at the sectoral level allows us to build more precise estimates of how
changes in policy affect different parts of the economy. Fifth, the data are constructed at the
bank group level. In this section we describe the data set and present descriptive statistics.

6
Our paper makes use of novel data on ‘true lending flows’ as opposed to ’changes in loan
stocks’, an important distinction. We retrieve true lending flows such that they reflect only
‘transactions’, as defined by international standards for economic statistics (in particular the
European System of Accounts, ESA 95). Data used in other UK studies on bank lending
typically come from the monetary returns collected by the Bank of England (or their
equivalent in other countries). These contain detailed information on bank balance sheets,
including the stock of loans. However, changes in loan stocks over time also reflect a range of
other factors that may potentially contaminate the data. These include write-offs, the effects
of securitizations, exchange rate effects, reporting changes, changes to group structures,
reclassifications and changes in the values of securities and repos (Equation (1)). For example,
we would not want to infer that lending has fallen when a bank securitises some loans (thus
removing them from the stock of loans on its balance sheet). Similarly, interpreting write-offs
as reductions in lending would be erroneous. Write-offs lead mechanically to a
contemporaneous fall in both capital and the loan stock, generating a spurious correlation
between the two, regardless of any change in the availability of new credit.

 = 
+  −   + ℎ   +

+ ∆   +  + ∆   +

+    + ℎ  (1)

The ‘true flows’ used in this paper remove this distortion by using additional information
from individual banks’ monetary returns collected by the Bank of England.4 Comparing the
true flows to differences in stocks reveals substantial differences, as shown in Chart 1 for a
bank chosen at random (where x and y values have been rescaled to preserve anonymity).
Failing to take account of these issues, and simply using differences in stocks to proxy flows,
would lead to biased estimates.

In addition, the ‘true’ lending flows described above are calculated at the sectoral level as
per National Accounts classification. This is in response to the critique by Den Haan et al
(2007) who argued that empirical studies that consider only total lending can be misleading.
The intuition is that if different constituent parts of total lending have different laws of
motion, then parameter estimates derived from the sum of the parts will be inaccurate. In our
context, for example, we would expect shifts in demand for loans from CRE companies to
differ from shifts in demand for unsecured credit from households. We therefore estimate
separate equations for loan growth to each sector. This allows us to better control for time
variation in macroeconomic factors that impact the demand for different types of lending
differently, improving our ability to identify the effect of regulatory capital requirements on
lending supply conditions.

4
Although in principle it would be possible to construct a true flows series from loan-level credit register data
used in some of the literature – e.g. Jimenez et al (2013) – these loan-level data are not available for the UK. And
we are not aware of efforts to build ‘true’ lending flows in the literature using non-UK data.

7
Chart 1: Data quality of true lending flows
Amounts 1200
Bank 1 - True lending flow
Bank 1 - Difference in stocks 1000

800

600

400

200

0
1 4 7 10 13 16 19 22 25 28 31 34 37 40 43 46 49 52 55
-200
Time
periods -400
Note: these data are based on a real bank, but have been rescaled by a
constant factor.

We therefore calculate loan growth for each of four sectors: i) secured lending to
households; ii) unsecured lending to households; iii) lending to CRE corporations; and iv)
lending to non-real estate non-financial corporations. The level of granularity to distinguish
between (iii) and (iv) is, however, only available since 1997. Table 1 shows each sector’s share
in the stock of loans to the real economy at the end of 20115 and the Basel I and II regulatory
risk weights applied to each.

Table 1: Size and regulatory risk weights of each lending sector


Share of Basel II
Basel I
outstanding (standardised) risk
risk weights
stock of loans6 weights7
35% for LTV≤ 80%
Secured lending to households 65% 50% Up to 45% for LTV>
100%

Unsecured lending to households 8% 100% 100%

Lending to CRE corporations 11% 100% 100%

20%-100%
Lending to non-real estate
16% 100% dependent on
corporations
credit rating

5
‘Real economy’ lending is defined as the stock of loans to households and PNFCs.
6
Stock of loans includes only the four “real economy” sectors included in Table 1. Lending to other financial
companies is not included in this paper, given it is less directly linked to economic activity and is typically very
volatile.
7
Note, however, that larger UK banks implemented the Internal Ratings Based (IRB) approach rather than
Standardised approach under Basel II.

8
Another feature of our data set is that it is constructed at the banking group level, on
what is termed a ‘consolidated’ basis, as opposed to an unconsolidated (individual entity)
basis. The reason is that both lending and capital decisions are, in our view, likely to be
determined at the group level. Banking groups typically report their lending strategy and
results at the group level. And the capital resources and constraints of a subsidiary are likely
to influence decisions at a group level. The importance of group cash flow and capital
resources is highlighted in Houston et al (1997); Ashcraft (2008) shows that parent groups act
as a source of strength in times of distress by providing liquidity and capital.

For this reason we use consolidated returns for bank capital resources and capital
requirements and we ‘quasi-consolidated’ the lending data from the monetary returns by
8
summing across constituent parts of a banking group. This means that, using Lloyds
Banking Group as an example in Figure 1, we analyse the capital and lending figures for the
group and not for its six sub-entities separately (Lloyds, TSB, Cheltenham and Gloucester,
Halifax, Bank of Scotland, Birmingham Midshires).

Figure 1: Example group structure for Lloyds Banking Group

Lloyds
Banking
Group

Lloyds
Banking HBOS
Group

Cheltenham & Bank of Birmingham


Lloyds TSB Halifax
Gloucester Scotland Midshires

In case of mergers and acquisitions, frequent in our sample, we do not consolidate pre-
merger entities as if they were one unit before the merger happens. Rather, after a merger we
end the time series for that group and we establish a new banking unit after the mergers. We
also exclude at least a quarter of data after any merger, as balance sheets can exhibit peculiar
behaviour around the time of mergers and acquisitions.9 This treatment makes our sample less
balanced, but we see this as preferable to backwards engineering a synthetic aggregate of

8
It is worth noting that the two data sources differ in scope, even after the monetary returns are quasi-
consolidated. The monetary returns capture the UK operations of a wide set of UK and foreign banks, whereas the
regulatory returns capture the UK and foreign operations of UK-regulated banking groups. And ‘quasi-consolidated’
data do not strip out intra-group activity that is not included in truly consolidated data.
9
For example, following Lloyds acquisition of HBOS (Halifax Bank of Scotland) in January 2009, both the
Lloyds Banking Group and HBOS series terminate in 2008Q4 and a new series for Lloyds Banking Group
commences in 2009Q3, excluding 2009Q1 and Q2.

9
merged banks, as is sometimes done in the literature. Any other data-cleaning procedure is
detailed in Appendix 1.

3.2 The UK regulatory capital framework – 1990-2011

Under both the Basel Accord and European Directives on capital requirements, a bank’s
total capital ratio (total capital / risk-weighted assets) had to be at least 8% of risk-weighted
assets (RWA). On top of the hard floor of 8%, UK regulators have, for over two decades, set
bank-specific minimum capital requirements –
the source of variation that we exploit in this
paper. A breach of this bank-specific minimum capital requirement leads to enhanced
supervisory action and can ultimately result in the loss of a firm’s banking licence.

These bank-specific minimum capital requirements were formerly known as ‘trigger ratios’
and were set by the Bank of England.10After 1997, the FSA inherited the setting of trigger
ratios from the Bank, and following the Financial Services and Markets Act of 2001, trigger
ratios were renamed Individual Capital Guidance (ICG). After Basel II was introduced in
2008, the setting of individual capital requirements became part of the Pillar 2 ‘supervisory
review’ process conducted by the FSA and subsequently the Prudential Regulation Authority
(PRA).

Trigger ratios were initially set by the Bank of England to compensate for the uniformity
and simplicity of the Basel capital adequacy framework and varied across banks according to
the risk profile of the firms, the bank’s size and position in chosen markets, as well as the
future outlook in those markets. It also allowed the regulator to capture other risks not
covered in the Basel capital adequacy framework, such as operational, legal, and interest rate
risks, as well as factors such as the quality of risk management, the quality of internal control
and accounting systems and plans for future developments of the business. In the UK Pillar 2
individual capital requirements are now divided into parts –
a Pillar 2A requirement, to
cover risks either not captured, or not fully captured by Pillar 1, and a Pillar 2B requirement,
intended to cover risks to which a firm might become exposed over a forward-looking planning
horizon (e.g. due to changes in the economic environment).

As noted by Francis and Osborne (2009), individual ratios were typically reviewed every
18-36 months, resulting in significant time-series as well as cross-sectional variation. This is
illustrated in Chart 2 below.

3.3 Descriptive statistics

Our panel data set includes data from 1990 Q1 until 2011 Q3 and is thus a sufficiently
long sample to capture all stages of the business cycle. We have included all banks, both
active and inactive, which have reported total UK assets greater than Θ5 billion at any time

10
The Bank of England also used to set ‘target ratios’, typically set 50-100bps above the trigger to avoid an
accidental breach.

10
since 1990 Q1.11 As a result, our panel contains 53 banking groups, each with an average of 30
quarters of data.12

Table 2 presents summary statistics for the capital and lending variables used in this
analysis: for each bank, the minimum capital requirement, its changes, the observed capital
ratio, household secured loan growth, household unsecured loan growth, CRE loan growth and
the growth in loans to non-CRE companies.13

Table 2: Summary statistics14

Std 10% 90%


Obs Mean Dev percentile percentile

1,590 9.93 1.79 8.00 11.99


Minimum capital requirement (% of RWA)
Changes in minimum capital requirement
1,590 0.03 0.32 -0.03 0.05
(percentage point)
Changes in minimum capital requirement
(percentage point) –
excluding [-0.1; 0.1] 253 0.17 0.79 -0.53 0.95
range
Capital ratio (% of RWA) 1,549 15.82 8.27 10.65 22.57

Secured loan growth (%, q on q) 1,298 0.50 5.78 -6.43 5.54

Unsecured loan growth (%, q on q) 1,459 1.62 5.27 -2.78 7.38

Non-CRE companies loan growth (%, q on q) 857 1.55 8.78 -9.44 11.96

CRE loan growth (%, q on q) 897 2.49 10.73 -7.26 12.51

Chart 2 shows the variation in the minimum capital requirements over the sample period.
Excluding negligible changes (smaller than 0.1 in absolute value), there were 253 changes in
the sample, with a slight prevalence of increases (143 occurrences) over decreases (110
occurrences). The changes were mostly between 0 and 1 percentage point in absolute value
(Chart 3). Chart 4 illustrates how capital buffers (i.e. the difference between the overall
capital ratio and the minimum requirement) broadly fell across banks in the decade leading
up to the crisis, before being rebuilt in the last two years of the sample.

11
An inactive bank is defined as one which has dropped out of the sample by 2011Q3, perhaps because it was
taken over.
12
The panel includes the lending operations of foreign-owned banks with UK resident subsidiaries.
13
Throughout this paper, minimum capital requirements and actual capital ratios are defined in ‘total capital’
terms. In other words, the numerator of these ratios includes all types of regulatory capital.
14
For further detail on some of the variables see Appendix 2.

11
Chart 2: Variation in minimum capital Chart 3: Magnitude of changes in
requirements minimum capital requirements
Frequency of absolute changes>0.1 Episodes
Increases (n=143)
Decreases (n=110) 35 140

30 120

25 100

20 80
923
episodes 60
15
(437 40
10 positive,
486 20
5
negative)
0 0
1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 2011 < -1 -1 to - < |0.1| 0.1 to 1 1 to 2 2 to 3 More
0.1 than 3
Percentage points
Sources: Bank of England and FSA Sources: Bank of England and FSA
Note: Excludes when minimum capital requirements did not
change. In total there are 253 episodes of changes larger than
0.1 in absolute value

Chart 4: Capital buffer


Per cent of RWA
14
interquartile range
12
median
10

0
90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

Sources: Bank of England and FSA

4 Methodology

To determine how banks typically react to a change in capital requirements, we estimate


dynamic panel equations for bank capital and loan growth for each sector as follows:

& &
*+, *+,
  = !
+ " #
$  , $ + " (
$  , $ + ) + - + .  (2)
$'
$'

12
3
2  = !3 + " 43$ 
 2 , $ +
$'

3 3

+ " #3$  , $ + " (3$  , $ + 53 6 


+ ) 78+9 + -78+9 + :  (3)
$'
$'

Where   is actual capital as a fraction of risk-weighted assets for bank i in quarter t;
2  is quarterly loan
 , is the capital requirement (trigger ratio) set by the regulator; 
growth based on the true flows as described in Section 3.1; and 6 ,
is a vector of bank-
specific micro controls that might affect lending, namely proportion of Tier 1 capital and the
leverage ratio. These variables describe the quality of capital resources, in addition to the
quantity captured by trig15. ) and - denote bank and time fixed effects respectively, and :
and . are error terms.

The number of lags in each equation was determined in a general to specific procedure,
testing down from four lags and restricting the number of lags for capital and the capital
requirement to be the same both within and across equations. The lagged dependent variables
have the effect of mopping up residual autocorrelation. Equation (2) is estimated on the full
sample (with the only restriction that secured and PNFC loan growth were non-missing) while
equation (3) is estimated for each different type of lending (secured, unsecured, CRE and non-
CRE corporates). Each equation is estimated separately –
the correlation between error
terms in the lending and capital equation is small and insignificantly different from zero for
each lending equation, which allows us to treat the responses similarly to as if estimated as a
system.

We use fixed effects for banks and for quarterly time periods. Banks’ fixed effects control
for unobserved heterogeneity at the bank level; for example, systematic differences in business
models, domicile or size. Quarterly time fixed effects control for macroeconomic factors -
including demand-side effects that are common to all banks at a given point in time; for
example, if all banks’ lending flows were lower in a certain period because of weak demand,
the time dummies would capture this by taking a lower value in that particular period.
Estimating each sectoral lending equation separately, with separate time fixed effects, allows
for different patterns of demand in each sector, improving our ability to identify the impact of
regulatory capital requirements on bank lending supply conditions.16

Nonetheless, we do not claim watertight identification: even with fixed effects at the
sectoral level, demand effects might confound our estimates if, for example, capital
requirements were increased for banks mainly operating in a particular area of the UK at the

15
Aside from these controls for the quality of capital resources, we also experimented with additional controls
for liquidity and prospects for capital resources. These were excluded from the final specification and they did not
improve the fit of the model or materially influence the main results.
16
It should be noted that the time fixed effects will also control for any supply-side effects that are common to
all banks and that these fixed effects cannot control for demand-side effects within a given sector that are specific to
a given bank.

13
same time as demand fell in that particular area.17 In order to better identify credit demand,
loan-level data would be required. But such data does not exist for the UK, which is, to our
knowledge, the only jurisdiction for which there are data on time-varying bank-specific capital
requirements. Researchers are therefore presented with a trade-off: either they are able to
control for credit demand by using loan-level data containing borrower characteristics (for
example, using the Spanish credit register as in Jimenez et al (2013)) but have to use proxies
for changes in capital requirements; or have the latter but not the former, as in our case.

The results are broadly robust to explicitly including macro controls (GDP and inflation)
instead of time fixed effects, but the latter are better at soaking up all factors common to
banks at any point in time without the need to model them.

The presence of both lagged dependent variables and fixed effects causes a well-known
bias (Nickell, 1981). But as our sample contains a relatively large number of time periods and
only a moderate cross-section –
relative to many panel datasets using panel data –
techniques with fixed effects remains preferable to Generalised Method of Moments (GMM).
That is because the lagged dependent variable bias declines as the number of time period
increases, and our estimates will be consistent as long as there is no autocorrelation of the
error terms. Judson and Owen (1999) suggest using standard fixed effects estimation rather
than GMM in unbalanced panels when T is large, which applies to our data, where the
average bank has a time series of 30 quarters. Standard errors are robust and clustered at the
bank level.

An additional issue arises because methods that involve pooling data (such as the fixed
effects estimator and other panel methods) assume homogeneity of coefficients across banks.
Pesaran and Smith (1995) suggest using the Mean Group estimator to tackle this issue.
However, the highly unbalanced nature of our panel (which is partly a result of the treatment
of mergers and acquisitions, see Section 3.1) means that this estimator is not appropriate.
That is because the Mean Group estimator would give a very large weight to coefficients
estimated for banks with only few observations, leading to very high standard errors. We
instead relax the homogeneity assumption by investigating in Section 6 the impact of capital
requirements for different types of banks.

Central estimates for impulse responses are calculated using the point estimates from
equations (2) and (3), while the calculation of confidence intervals follows the methodology
used in Beyer and Farmer (2006). Specifically, we take 2,500 draws from the joint normal
distribution with mean and variance-covariance matrices given by the vectors of point
estimates and variance-covariance matrices estimated from equations (2) and (3). The impulse
responses are ranked within each quarter and the upper and lower bounds of the confidence

17
In addition, it is possible that supervisors tended to increase capital requirements when they were concerned

about asset quality. In that case, the estimated effect might be rather large as it would capture the bank s lending
response to both higher capital requirements and concerns about asset quality. However, Aiyar, Calomiris and
Wieladek (2014) provide some evidence that this is unlikely to be the case. They find that changes in write-offs
(lagged, present and future) cannot predict changes in capital requirements and note from Francis and Osborne
(2009) that the UK discretionary regime was meant to ‘ fill gaps in the early Basel I system, which did not

consider risks related to variation in interest rates, or legal, reputational and operational risks .

14
interval are given by the 16th and 84th percentiles, as is typical in the macro literature
following Sims and Zha (1999).

5 Results

This section presents the main results on how banks adjust their capital and lending
following a change in capital requirements, based on the estimates from the two dynamic
panel equations (2) and (3). Tables 3 and 4 present the capital ratio and sectoral lending
responses to a one percentage point permanent increase in capital requirements, while Charts
5 to 9 illustrate the dynamics of the adjustment process. A full set of coefficient estimates for
all of our preferred specifications can be found in Appendix 3.

5.1 The impact of capital requirements on capital ratios

Equation (2) examines how a bank’s capital ratio behaves in relation to its own capital
requirement and past capital ratios. Banks are found to actively adjust their total capital held
in response to changes in capital requirement, as opposed to letting the capital buffer adjust in
equal and offsetting measure. This result is in line with other studies that use UK data, such
as Alfon et al (2005) and Francis and Osborne (2009).

Chart 5: Capital ratio impulse response Table 3: Capital ratio response to 1pp
increase in capital requirements
Response to a
1.5

1pp increase in
capital
requirements
Percentage points
1

Change in observed
capital ratio after 1
.5

year 0.41*
(68% CI) [0.16 : 0.68]
Central estimate 68% CI
Change in observed
0

0 1 2
Year
3 4 5
capital ratio after 3
years 0.95*
(68% CI) [0.38 : 1.54]
Note: Capital ratio impulse response following a Dependent variable
permanent one percentage point increase in the
capital requirement at time 0.
(no. of lags) 4
R2 0.95
Observations 1,095
Note: * denotes significantly different from zero
using the 68% confidence interval. The regression
includes bank and quarterly time fixed effects.

Our central estimate suggests that, following a one percentage point permanent increase in
capital requirements, banks start to increase their capital ratio (potentially via a combination
of raising new capital, retaining profits or reducing assets) (Chart 5). After one year, banks

15
have increased their capital ratio by 0.4pp and after 3 years by 0.9pp (Table 3); the initial
buffer is fully restored in less than four years. Our central estimate suggests that the
adjustment settles just above 1pp, indicating that banks increase their capital ratio broadly
one for one in response to an increase in capital requirements. The confidence interval in
Chart 5 highlights the considerable uncertainty around this central estimate, but suggests that
the positive response of actual bank capital ratios to an increase in regulatory requirements is
statistically significant.

5.2 The impact of capital requirements and capital ratios on sectoral


loan growth

Equation 3 examines how banks’ sectoral loan growth is related to their individual capital
requirement, observed capital ratio and past loan growth. Table 4 presents the results from
the regressions

Table 4: Loan growth response to 1pp increase in capital requirements

(1) (2) (3) (4)


Household Household Non-CRE
CRE loan
secured loan unsecured corporates’
growth
growth loan growth loan growth

Peak impact on loan


growth quarterly rate (pp) -0.77* -0.19* -4.04* -2.05*
(68% CI) [-1.07 : -0.49] [-0.37 : -0.01] [-5.56 : -2.63] [-3.51 : -0.73]
(quarter) 1 5 1 1

Impact on loan growth rate


over year 1 (annual, pp) -0.94* -0.68 -8.07* -3.86*
(68% CI) [-1.69 : -0.20] [-1.43 : 0.03] [-10.46 : -5.70] [-6.05 : -1.54]

Long-run impact on
quarterly loan growth (at
end-year 3, pp) 0.18 -0.16 -1.33* -0.67
(68% CI) [-0.01 : 0.39] [-0.36 : 0.04] [-1.85 : -0.77] [-1.34 : 0.05]

Dependent variable (no.


of lags) 2 2 2 2
R2 0.21 0.12 0.10 0.09
Observations 1,143 1,358 809 760

Note: * denotes significantly different from zero using the 68% confidence interval. The effect over year
1 is calculated as the sum of the four quarterly effects. All regressions include bank and quarterly time
fixed effects.

16
a) Household secured lending

An increase in capital requirements is associated with a temporary reduction in secured


loan growth, which on our central estimate lasts less than a year (Chart 6). In the first
quarter following the regulatory change, household secured loan growth falls sharply, with a
peak impact of reducing the quarterly growth rate by 0.8pp. The cumulative effect over the
first year is -0.9pp (Table 4). After the first year, as the bank accumulates capital towards
restoring its buffer, loan growth returns to its previous rate.

Chart 6: Secured loan growth impulse Chart 7: Unsecured loan growth impulse
response response
.5

.5
.25
.25

Percentage points
Percentage points

0
0

-.25
-.25

-.5
-.5

-.75
-.75

-1
-1

Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI

0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

Note: Secured loan growth impulse response Note: Unsecured loan growth impulse response
following a permanent one percentage point increase following a permanent one percentage point increase
in the capital requirement at time 0. in the capital requirement at time 0.

b) Household unsecured lending

Household unsecured loan growth exhibits a much shallower response to an increase in


capital requirements (Chart 7). Our central estimate is for a trough fall in quarterly loan
growth of 0.2pp after five quarters and a reduction in the loan growth rate of 0.7pp
cumulatively after a year and 0.2pp in the long run. Of these effects, only the trough fall in
the 5th quarter is significantly below zero.

c) CRE lending

Turning to corporate lending, we analyse lending to CRE and other industries separately.18
Following an increase in capital requirements, CRE lending falls sharply (Chart 8). The
results suggest that, faced with a 1pp increase in capital requirements, banks reduce CRE loan
growth by around 4pp after a quarter; this effect is statistically significant. The cumulative
fall in loan growth over the first year is 8pp. Further, our main specification suggests a
permanent effect, with quarterly loan growth remaining 1.3pp (around 5pp annualised) lower.
However, as noted in Sections 6.1 and 6.3 respectively, this result is not significant before the
crisis and may be driven by decreases in banks’ capital requirements.

18
We have also estimated the model for lending to all PNFCs over the longer time series, but there appears to be
little effect from changes in capital requirements to lending. This may not be surprising as the equations for all PNFCs rely
on lending data from a range of diverse industries with potentially different responses.

17
Chart 8: CRE loan growth impulse Chart 9: Non-CRE corporates’ loan growth
response 1 impulse response

1
0

0
-1

-1
Percentage points

Percentage points
-2

-2
-3

-3
-4

-4
-5

-5
Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI
-6

-6
0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

Note: CRE loan growth impulse response Note: Non-CRE corporates’ loan growth impulse
following a permanent one percentage point response following a permanent one percentage point
increase in the capital requirement at time 0. increase in the capital requirement at time 0.

d) Non-CRE corporate lending

Following an increase in capital requirements, loan growth to companies in other


industries19 also falls significantly; the magnitude of this effect is more muted than for real
estate but stronger than for secured lending (Chart 9). The central estimate suggests a trough
fall of 2.1pp in quarterly loan growth in the first quarter and a 3.9pp fall in annual growth by
the end of the first year. There is no significant long-run impact.

5.3 Discussion

Taking the above together, there are two key findings. First, regulatory capital
requirements affect the capital ratios held by banks following an increase in capital –
requirements, banks gradually rebuild the buffers that they initially held above the regulatory
minimum. Second, capital requirements affect lending with heterogeneous responses in
different sectors of the economy –
in the year following an increase in capital requirements,
banks cut (in descending order based on point estimates) loan growth for CRE, other
corporates and household secured lending. The response of unsecured household lending is
shallower and insignificant over the first year as a whole. Loan growth mostly recovers within
3 years. The exception is CRE lending for which there is evidence of a long-run effect. But,
given this result may be driven by episodes in which capital requirements were falling, and is
not significant before the crisis, we refrain from placing too much weight on it.20

These results are not directly comparable to those of other studies. But a very rough
comparison to Macroeconomic Assessment Group (2010), Aiyar et al (2014) and Noss and

19
Non-CRE corporates ’
loan growth is calculated as corporate lending less CRE lending. Due to differences in
definitions, especially related to a reclassification of housing associations, this measure tends to be less precise than that of
CRE lending.
20
During the crisis, lenders suffered large losses on their CRE and other corporate loan books (in absolute terms
and relative to household lending). The CRE lending market is a particularly cyclical industry; this may be one
explanation for our result, discussed in Section 6.4, that CRE lending is more sensitive to capital requirements when
there is a negative output gap.

18
Toffano (2014) can be made by calculating the cumulative effect over three years21 for each
sector in our study, and then calculating the total effect using the sector shares from Table A
as weights. On that measure, we find that the impact of a 1pp increase in the capital
requirement on loan volumes is about -3.5%, compared to between -0.7 and -3.6% in
Macroeconomic Assessment Group (2010), -5.7 to -8.0% in Aiyar et al (2014) and -4.5% in
Noss and Toffano (2014). The finding of Noss and Toffano (2014) that the effect is larger for
lending to corporates (and in particular CRE) than to households is consistent with our point
estimates in Table D, and could be one explanation why Aiyar et al (2014) who look at–
corporate lending only –
find a relatively large effect.

Our results reflect how, on average, individual banks respond to a change in their own
confidential and microprudential capital requirements. Whilst our findings may contain some
insights into how macroprudential policy will impact bank behaviour, there are likely to be a
number of differences in the macroeconomic implications. First, the extent of ‘leakages’ –
where entities not subject to a change in capital requirements step in to pick up any slack in
lending left by banks subject to the change –
may be different when capital requirements are
changed for a large set of banks simultaneously.

Second, a macroprudential policy regime may have different implications for the way in
which banks adjust their capital ratios to a regulatory chance. Following a system-wide
increase in capital requirements, banks might not restore their capital buffers in the same way
as in the past because they may not be able to all simultaneously acquire capital. On the
other hand, a synchronised regulatory change may diminish any signalling problems associated
with raising additional capital. Also, during the transition to higher global regulatory
standards, increasing capital requirements might augment rather than reduce lending for
initially undercapitalised banks if confidence effects boost their resilience and capacity to lend.
Furthermore, macroprudential regulators are often required to consider the wider implications
of changing capital requirements, which could include any adverse impact on lending for –
example, while the FPC’s primary objective is to protect and enhance the resilience of the UK
financial system, it also has a secondary objective to support the economic policy of the
Government.

Third, macroprudential capital requirements are intended to operate within a more


systematic and transparent framework than their microprudential counterpart. For example,
we might expect banks to react in a different way to anticipated and unanticipated changes in
their capital requirements, such that a transparent and well-communicated macroprudential
regime may induce different bank behaviour, to the extent that future policy decisions are
more easily anticipated.

As a result, our study cannot be read as a like-for-like map of how changing capital
requirements likely affects bank capital and lending in a macroprudential framework; but it is

21
The effect in Macroeconomic Assessment Group (2010) is for the 18th quarter of simulation; Aiyar, Calomiris
and Wieladek (2014) assumes that changes in capital requirements have no effect on loan growth after four quarters;
while Noss and Toffano (2014) estimate the effect over 4 years. The studies also differ along other dimensions.

19
a useful guide to how banks have adjusted their capital ratios and lending structure on
average in response to past microprudential supervisory actions.

6 Extensions and robustness checks

We investigate the robustness of our results along five dimensions: a) influence of the
financial crisis; b) heterogeneity by size of bank; c) asymmetry between increases and
decreases in capital requirements; d) business cycle variation in banks’ responses; and e)
heterogeneity by size of the capital buffer. We note that the results in this section are based
on preliminary analysis intended to provide some idea of where our main results come from
and interrogate their robustness, rather than on fully developed econometric exercises. More
details on the methodology and charts of impulse responses are available in Appendix 4.

6.1 Influence of the financial crisis

To examine the influence of the financial crisis on our results, we re-estimate equations (2)
and (3) excluding data from 2008 onwards. The results on capital and on secured lending are
generally robust to this exclusion. In the case of unsecured lending, lending responds more
negatively when estimated on data until 2007 only. One possible explanation is that, while
unsecured loan growth responded to changes in individual banks’ capital requirements before
2007, after 2007 it became less responsive because of pricing and demand effects. First, when
setting loan quantities and prices, it is plausible that the increase in riskiness of unsecured
borrowers after 2007 and the cost to cover potential credit losses from defaulting borrowers
dwarfed any reaction to changes in capital requirements. Button et al (2010) show that the
cost of capital is only a very small fraction of the overall price of an unsecured loan.22 Second,
demand for unsecured credit may have increased since the start of the crisis as households
used relatively more unsecured credit to smooth banks’ restrictions in secured credit.

Effects on corporate lending, on the contrary, become more muted if the crisis years are
excluded. For CRE lending, the long-run growth rate effect is not present when estimating
only until 2007. And for lending to other corporations, there are no significant effects before
the crisis.

6.2 Heterogeneity by size of bank

The results do appear to differ between large and small banks, although the degree is
dependent on how ‘large’ is defined – whether by the size of total assets, real economy
lending or sectoral lending; whether by size of loan stocks or by growth rates; whether the
definition is dynamic, such that a bank can change from large to small or vice versa over time,
or static. This dependence limits inference on how large and small banks behave differently.
But to give an example, when defining large banks in a given quarter as the top 50% in terms

22
Specifically, in decomposing the pricing of unsecured loans, Button, Pezzini and Rossiter (2010) estimated
that a 10% unsecured loan rate (for a Θ10,000 personal loan) would comprise around 450bps to cover credit losses
and only 80bps to cover the cost of setting aside regulatory capital.

20
of total assets in that quarter, small banks generally appear to be the main driver of the
results on lending. Large banks tend to exhibit less negative effects initially, with the
exception of lending to non-CRE corporates. That may be because large, most likely
international, banking groups have more flexibility as to how they raise and allocate capital
than small banks. As such, they may be able to better insulate themselves from, or respond to,
regulatory actions

6.3 Asymmetry between increases and decreases in capital requirements

The results presented in Section 5 assume that banks react symmetrically, i.e. banks’
responses to an increase in capital requirements are the mirror image of their response to a
decrease. Initial analysis suggests this is not the case for all sectors empirically. The strong
initial reaction for CRE and household secured lending in particular appear to be driven by
increases rather than decreases in capital requirements: CRE lending is lowered by 4.7pp in
response to a 1pp increase in capital requirements, but increased only 2.1pp in response to a
similar decrease in capital requirements, and secured lending to households is not significantly
affected by reductions in capital requirements. This result chimes with Elliott et al (2013),
who find, in a study of macroprudential policy actions –
taking place throughout the
twentieth century and spanning a wide range of instruments, including interest rate controls,
reserve requirements and capital requirements –
in the United States, a policy tightening has
a larger effect on lending than an easing. On the other hand, the long-run growth effect for
lending to the CRE sector appears to be driven by reductions in banks’ capital requirements.
The effects for lending to the non-CRE corporate sector are more symmetrical.

6.4 Business cycle variation in banks’ responses

Banks’ response to changes in capital requirements might vary over time with the business
cycle. Here we examine the extent to which responses vary between times when the output
gap is positive or zero (‘good’ times), and when the output gap is negative (‘bad’ times).23

We find that banks tend to cut corporate lending more when the output gap is below zero;
CRE lending is initially reduced by 4.6pp and non-CRE corporate lending by 3.9pp in that
case. In contrast, CRE lending is reduced by only 1.8pp and non-CRE corporate lending by
0.5pp when the output gap is positive, and these effects are insignificant. For unsecured
lending to households, the immediate reaction is also stronger when the output gap is negative,
but loan growth returns more quickly to normal in that case. Finally, the initial response is
similar for household secured lending, but the response for times when the output gap is
positive exhibits a somewhat puzzling positive response in the long run.

23
An alternative would be to split the sample based on whether GDP growth was above or below its long-run
trend, but a dummy based on this split is too volatile for the exercise to be meaningful.

21
6.5 Heterogeneity by size of the capital buffer

It is possible that banks with capital buffers close to zero are particularly sensitive to
changes in the regulatory capital requirement. We examine this hypothesis by estimating
impulse responses for banks with lagged capital buffers above and below 1.5 per cent. Based
on our central estimates, we do indeed find that the initial lending reaction is stronger for
banks with smaller capital buffers, with the exception of CRE lending where the initial
reaction is similar. But further out, CRE and non-CRE corporate loan growth remains
subdued for banks with large buffers while it recovers completely for banks with small buffers.
Lending to households recovers for both sets of banks.

7 Conclusion

Our results suggest that changes in capital requirements affect both capital and lending.
In response to an increase in capital requirements, banks gradually increase their capital ratios
to restore their original buffers held above the regulatory minimum. Banks also reduce loan
growth –in the year following an increase in capital requirements, banks cut (in descending
order based on point estimates) loan growth for CRE, other corporates and household secured
lending. The response of unsecured household lending is shallower and not significant over the
first year as a whole. Loan growth mostly returns to normal within 3 years. Finally, initial
analysis suggests that banks’ responses differ depending on bank size, capital buffers held, the
business cycle, and the direction of the change in capital requirements.

These results reflect how, on average, individual banks responded in the past to a change
in their own confidential and microprudential capital requirements. As such, they cannot be
used to directly infer the macroeconomic effects of macroprudential policy.24 But as long as we
lack empirical evidence on the effectiveness of the new policy tools, and to the extent that
there will be similarities in the way in which banks respond to changes in capital requirements,
our results will contain some quantitative insights into how changing capital requirements in a
macroprudential framework might affect lending.

24
See Section 5.3 for a fuller discussion.

22
Appendices

Appendix 1 – Data cleaning

Mergers and acquisitions:


acquisitions: As discussed in Section 3, we have split bank groups in order to
take account of mergers and acquisitions. As reported balance sheet characteristics often
display volatility around the time of a merger or acquisition, we excluded the quarter
associated with the merger, following Kashyap and Stein (2000). However, even then jumps in
the data remained common around M&A activity, so in some cases we excluded additional
quarters based on judgement.

Start-
Start-ups and wind-
wind-downs: Similarly, data jumps are often present when a bank is starting
up or winding down. Therefore we eliminated the first four quarters in a start-up and the last
four quarters in a wind-down.

Outliers: We removed banks with less than five time-series observations. We also removed
outliers by excluding some observations at the top and bottom of the range of each variable,
cutting the top and bottom 1-5% depending on the noisiness of the original data.

Appendix 2 – Key variable (Table A1)

Variable Definition Source Notes

2 ,,<<=>*
 Quarterly growth of secured Monetary returns Uses true flow
loans to households of M4Lx
2 ,,<<?9=>*
 Quarterly growth of unsecured Monetary returns Uses true flow
loans to households of M4Lx
2 ,,,9@**A>
 Quarterly growth of loans to Monetary returns Uses true flow
CRE private non-financial of M4Lx
corporations
2 ,,,9@*989*A>
 Quarterly growth of loans to non Monetary returns Uses true flow
real estate private non-financial of M4Lx
corporations
 , Published total capital ratio Regulatory returns % of risk-
(includes all types of qualifying weighted assets
regulatory capital)
 , Trigger requirement: Regulatory returns % of risk-
Required total capital resources weighted assets
Risk weighted assets
1 , Tier 1 capital ratio: Regulatory returns
Tier 1 capital
Total regulatory capital
 , Leverage: Regulatory returns
Total assets
Tier 1 capital

23
Appendix 3 – Full table of results

Table A2 shows the full set of coefficient estimates for our main specifications described in
equations (2) and (3). These estimates are used to generate the impulse responses shown in
Section 5 using the method explained in Section 4.

Table A2: Results for main loan growth and capital equations
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Secured Unsecured CRE loan Non-CRE Capital
loan growth loan growth growth corporates’
loan growth

Trigger ratio (-1) -0.771** -0.131 -4.044** -2.055 0.118


(0.304) (0.509) (1.517) (1.434) (0.082)
Trigger ratio (-2) 0.838** -0.015 2.685* 1.391 -0.088
(0.310) (0.546) (1.351) (1.658) (0.094)
Trigger ratio (-3) 0.058
(0.307)
Trigger ratio (-4) -0.009
(0.180)
Capital (-1) 0.132 -0.149 0.203 0.348 1.673***
(0.181) (0.133) (0.516) (0.298) (0.056)
Capital (-2) -0.096 0.180 -0.168 -0.385 -1.294***
(0.184) (0.121) (0.479) (0.340) (0.142)
Capital (-3) 0.878***
(0.186)
Capital (-4) -0.333***
(0.096)
Tier 1 ratio (-1) 0.026 0.019 -0.006 0.003
(0.021) (0.016) (0.055) (0.037)
Leverage ratio (-1) 0.040 0.027 0.175 -0.166
(0.046) (0.040) (0.140) (0.107)
Dependent variable (-1) 0.269*** 0.051 0.006 -0.066
(0.053) (0.059) (0.041) (0.065)
Dependent variable (-2) 0.180*** 0.172*** -0.002 0.051
(0.046) (0.040) (0.065) (0.054)
Time and bank fixed effects yes yes yes yes yes

Constant -3.900 -1.171 5.871 12.496 0.754*


(3.164) (2.639) (10.941) (10.617) (0.415)

Observations 1,143 1,358 809 760 1,095


R-squared 0.213 0.120 0.103 0.090 0.945
Number of banks 41 50 37 39 41
Note: Fixed effects regressions of loan growth and capital. Capital is actual capital as a fraction of risk-weighted assets.
Trigger ratio is the capital requirement set by the regulator. Tier 1 ratio is the ratio of tier 1 capital to total regulatory
capital. Fisher-type panel unit root tests suggest no unit roots for any of the variables used. Robust standard errors in
parentheses. ***p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.10.

24
Appendix 4 – Extensions and robustness checks

a) Influence of the financial crisis

The robustness check for the effect of the financial crisis explained in Section 6.1 was
conducted by estimating equations (2) and (3) for a subsample containing data from before
the crisis (up to end 2007). Chart A1 shows the impulse responses for lending to each sector
for the pre-crisis period.

Chart A1: Loan growth impulse responses pre-crisis

Secured Unsecured

.5
.5

.25
.25

Percentage points
Percentage points

0
0

-.25
-.25

-.5
-.5

-.75
-.75

-1
-1

Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI

0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

CRE Non-CRE corporates


1

1
0

0
-1

-1
Percentage points

Percentage points
-2

-2
-3

-3
-4

-4
-5

-5

Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI


-6

-6

0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

Loan growth impulse responses following a permanent one percentage point increase in the
capital requirement at time 0.

To test formally for the existence of a structural break during the crisis, we created
interaction variables between a crisis dummy (taking value 1 from 2008 Q1 onwards) and the
regressors in the lending equations. We then estimated the regressions with the additional
interaction variables and tested for their joint significance. According to this test, there is a
structural break if the interaction variables are jointly significant. The results are presented in
Table A3.

Our tests suggest that the null hypothesis is not rejected for secured and non-CRE
corporate lending, so that there was no structural break in those series. On the other hand,
we find structural breaks for household unsecured and CRE lending.

25
Table A3: F-tests for structural break during the crisis
F Prob>F Structural break?
Secured lending 1.21 0.3181 No
Unsecured lending 2.89 0.0102 Yes
CRE lending 4.54 0.0007 Yes
Non-CRE corporate lending 1.20 0.3236 No
F-tests for structural break during the crisis. The null hypothesis is that there was no structural break.

b) Heterogeneity by size of bank

To examine whether there is heterogeneity in the lending and capital results depending on
bank size (as discussed in Section 6.2), we estimated the following dynamic panel equations:

& & &

  = !
+ " #

$  , $ + " (

$  , $ + -
 ,
+ " #
3$  , $ ∗  ,

$'
$'
$'

&

+ " (
3$  , $ ∗  ,
+ )

+ )
3 + .  (V1)
$'

3 3
2  = !3 + " 43
$ 
 2 , $ + " #3
$  , $
$'
$'

3 3
2 , $ ∗  ,

+ " (3
$  , $ + 53
6 
+ -3  ,
+ " 433$ 
$'
$'

3 3

+ " #33$  , $ ∗  ,


+ " (33$  , $ ∗  ,
+ 533 6 
∗  ,

$'
$'

+ )3
+ )33 + :  (V2)

where  ,
is a dummy variable taking the value 1 if a bank is ‘large’ and 0 if a bank
is ‘small’. We use lagged size to avoid any potential endogeneity problems. Our preferred
definition of ‘large’ is a bank that is in the top 50% of the distribution at that point in time in
terms of total assets. We also tried an array of alternative definitions of bank size, based on
the stock of lending to the real economy (households and corporates) and the stock of lending
to each sector. We also considered the growth rate of these variables rather than the stock to
test for differential effects for fast-growing banks. We also estimated our equations separately
for subsamples of small and large banks. As discussed in Section 6.2, the results are sensitive
to the choice of definition. Chart A2 shows the impulse responses of lending in each sector for
small and large banks using our preferred definition of ‘large’.

26
c) Asymmetry between increases and decreases in capital requirements

As a preliminary attempt to see whether banks respond symmetrically to increases and


decreases in capital requirements, we estimate equations (2) and (3) for subsamples containing
episodes of increases and decreases in capital requirements separately. We define an increase
in capital requirements episode as one in which the capital requirement has ‘net’ increased
over the previous year (ie  ,
−  , W ≥ 0, so offsetting changes do not count). Column
1 in Chart A3 shows the impulse responses of lending in each sector following an increase in
capital requirements, and column 2 shows the impulse responses following a decrease in
capital requirements.

27
Chart A2: Loan growth impulse responses for small and large banks
Small banks Large banks
Household secured
.5

1
.5
0

Percentage points
Percentage points
-.5

0-.5
-1

Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI


-1.5

-1
0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

Household unsecured

1.5
.5

1
Percentage points

Percentage points
0

.5
-.5

Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI


-.5
-1

0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

CRE corporates
0

0
-1
-2
Percentage points

Percentage points
-3 -2
-4

-4
-6

-5

Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI

0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

Non-CRE corporates
0

5
-1
Percentage points

Percentage points
0
-2

-5
-3

Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI


-4

-10

0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

Loan growth impulse responses following a permanent one percentage point increase in the
capital requirement at time 0.

28
Chart A3: Loan growth impulse responses for increases and decreases in capital
requirements
1pp increase in capital requirement 1pp decrease in capital requirement
Household secured

1
.5

.5
0

Percentage points
Percentage points

0
-.5

-.5
-1

Central estimate 68% CI

-1
Central estimate 68% CI
-1.5

0 1 2 3 4 5
0 1 2 3 4 5 Year
Year

Household unsecured

2
.5

1
Percentage points
0
Percentage points

-1 0
-.5

-2
-1

Central estimate 68% CI


-3

Central estimate 68% CI


0 1 2 3 4 5
0 1 2 3 4 5 Year
Year

CRE corporates
4
2
0

3
Percentage points
Percentage points
-2

2
-4

1
-6

Central estimate 68% CI


Central estimate 68% CI
0
-8

0 1 2 3 4 5
0 1 2 3 4 5 Year
Year

Non-CRE corporates
4
1

3
0

Percentage points
Percentage points

2
-1

1
-2

0
-3

Central estimate 68% CI


-1

Central estimate 68% CI


-4

0 1 2 3 4 5
0 1 2 3 4 5 Year
Year

The first (second) column shows loan growth impulse responses following a permanent one
percentage point increase (decrease) in capital requirements, estimated on banks that
experienced an increase (decrease) or no change in their capital requirement over the previous
four quarters.

29
d) Business cycle variation in banks’ responses

We examine variation over the business cycle by estimating responses when the output
gap is positive and when it is negative. The specification is similar to that in equations (A1)
and (A2), but with the lagged size dummy replaced by a lagged output gap dummy.25 We use
output gap figures from the Office for Budget Responsibility (see Pybus (2011) and OBR
(2013)). The results are presented in Chart A4.

e) Heterogeneity by size of capital buffer

Finally, we look at the extent to which banks with large capital buffers tend to respond
differently to a change in capital requirements than those with small buffers. We do so using a
specification similar to that in equations (A1) and (A2), but with the lagged size dummy
based on whether the bank’s lagged capital buffer is above or below a threshold. The choice of
threshold reflects a trade-off between having sufficient observations in both groups for
estimation and being close enough to zero that one would expect banks in the low capital
buffer group to be particularly affected by a change in capital requirements. The results
presented in Chart A5 are based on a threshold of 1.5 per cent.

25
Contrary to the lagged size dummy, the lagged output gap dummy is not included on its own because it does
not vary across firms within quarters.

30
Chart A4: Loan growth impulse responses by output gap
Output gap below zero Output gap above or equal zero
Household secured

1.5
.5

1
Percentage points

Percentage points
0

0 .5
-.5

-.5
Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI
-1

-1
0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

Household unsecured
.5

1
0

.5
Percentage points

Percentage points
-.5

0
-1

-.5

Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI


-1.5

0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

CRE corporates
2

1
0
0
Percentage points

Percentage points
-1
-2

-2
-4

-3
-6

Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI


-4
-8

0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

Non-CRE corporates
1
0 -2
Percentage points

Percentage points
0
-4

-1
-6

Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI


-8

-2

0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

Loan growth impulse responses following a permanent one percentage point increase in the
capital requirement at time 0. Output gap figures used to split the sample are from the Office
for Budget Responsibility (see Pybus (2011) and OBR (2013)).

31
Chart A5: Loan growth impulse responses by capital buffer size
Capital buffer below 1.5 Capital buffer above or equal to 1.5
Household secured
.5

.5
0

0
Percentage points

Percentage points
-1 -.5

-.5
-1.5

-1
-2

Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI

0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

Household unsecured

.5
1 0
Percentage points

Percentage points
0
-1

-.5
-2

Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI


-3

-1

0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

CRE corporates
0
0

-2
-2
Percentage points

Percentage points
-4
-4

-6
-6

Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI


-8

-8

0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

Non-CRE corporates
2

0
0

-1
Percentage points

Percentage points
-2

-2
-4

-3
-6

-4

Central estimate 68% CI Central estimate 68% CI


-8

0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year Year

Loan growth impulse responses following a permanent one percentage point increase in the
capital requirement at time 0.

32
References

[1] Aiyar, S, Calomiris, C W and Wieladek, T (2014), ‘Does Macropru Leak? Evidence
from a UK Policy Experiment’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 46(1), pp.
181-214.

[2] Albertazzi, U and Marchetti, D J (2010), ‘Credit supply, flight to quality and
evergreening: an analysis of bank-firm relationships after Lehman’, Banca d’Italia
Working Paper 756.

[3] Alfon, I, Argimón, I and Bascuñana-Ambrós, P (2005), ‘How individual capital


requirements affect capital ratios in UK banks and building societies’, Banco de
Espana Working Paper 515.

[4] Ashcraft, A B (2008), ‘Are Bank Holding Companies a Source of Strength to Their
Banking Subsidiaries?’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 40:2-3, pp. 273-294.

[5] Bank of England (2014), ‘The Financial Policy Committee’s powers to supplement
capital requirements. A policy statement’.

[6] Bernanke, B S and Lown, C S (1991), ‘The Credit Crunch’, Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, no. 2, pp. 205-39.

[7] Beyer, A and Farmer, R E A (2006), ‘A method to generate structural impulse-


responses for measuring the effects of shocks in structural macro models’, ECB
Working Paper Series 586.

[8] Button, R, Pezzini, S and Rossiter, N (2010), ‘Understanding the price of new
lending to households‘, Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Vol. 50, No. 3, pp. 172-
182.

[9] Den Haan, W J, Sumner, S W and Yamashiro, G M (2007), ‘Bank loan portfolios
and the monetary transmission mechanism’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 54:3, pp.
904-924.

[10] Ediz, T, Michael, I and Perraudin, W (1998), ‘The Impact of Capital Requirements
on UK Bank Behaviour’, FRBNY Economic Policy Review, October.

[11] Elliott, D J, Feldberg, G and Lehnert, A (2013), ‘The History of Cyclical


Macroprudential Policy in the United States’, Finance and Economics Discussion
Series, 2013-29.

[12] Fonseca, A R, Gonzalez, F and Pereira da Silva, L (2010), ‘Cyclical Effects of Bank
Capital Buffers with Imperfect Credit Markets: International Evidence’, Banco
Central Do Brasil Working Paper Series, 216.

33
[13] Francis, W and Osborne, M (2009), ‘Bank regulation, capital and credit supply:
Measuring the impact of Prudential Standards’, FSA Occasional Paper Series, 36.

[14] Friedman, B (1991), ‘Comments and discussion’, Brookings Panel on Economic


Activity.

[15] Furfine, C (2000), ‘Evidence on the Response of US Banks to Changes in Capital


Requirements’, Bank of International Settlements Working Paper, No. 88.

[16] Gambacorta, L and Marques-Ibanez, D (2011), ‘The bank lending channel: Lessons
from the crisis’, BIS Working papers No 345, May.

[17] Gambacorta, L and Mistrulli, PE (2004), ‘Does bank capital affect lending behaviour’,
Journal of Financial Intermediation, 13(4), pp. 436-57, October.

[18] Hancock, D and Wilcox, J (1994), ‘Bank Capital and the Credit Crunch: The Roles
of Risk-Weighted and Unweighted Capital Regulation’, Journal of the American Real
Estate and Urban Economics Association, 22:1, pp. 59-94.

[19] Hanson S G, Kashyap A K and Stein J C (2011), ‘A Macroprudential Approach to


Financial Regulation’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25:1, pp. 3-28.

[20] Heid, F, Porath D and Stolz, S (2004), ‘Does capital regulation matter for bank
behaviour? Evidence for German savings banks’ Discussion Paper Series 2: Banking
and Financial Studies 2004, 03, Deutsche Bundesbank, Research Centre, (3), pp. 493‐
513.

[21] Houston J, James C and Marcus D (1997), ‘Capital Market Frictions and the Role of
Internal Capital Markets in Banking’, Journal of Financial Economics, 46:2, pp. 135-
164(30).

[22] Jimenez, G, Ongena, S, Peydro, J and Saurina, J (2013), ‘Macroprudential Policy,


Countercyclical Bank Capital Buffers and Credit Supply Credit Supply: Evidence
from the Spanish Dynamic Provisioning Experiments’, European Banking Center
Discussion Paper No. 2012-011.

[23] Judson, R A and Owen, A L (1999), ‘Estimating Dynamic Panel Data Models: A
Guide for Macroeconomists’, Economics Letters, 65:1, pp. 9-15.

[24] Kashyap, A K and Stein, J C (2000), ‘What do a million observations on banks say
about the transmission of monetary policy?’, American Economic Review, 90:3, pp.
407-428.

[25] Macroeconomic Assessment Group (MAG) (2010), ‘Assessing the macroeconomic


impact of the transition to stronger capital and liquidity requirements: Interim
Report’, August, Financial Stability Board and the Basel Committee on Banking
Supervision.

34
[26] Modigliani, F and Miller, M (1958), ‘The cost of capital, corporation finance and the
theory of investment’, American Economic Review, 48:3, pp. 261–297.

[27] Myers, S C (1977), ‘Determinants of Corporate Borrowing’, Journal of Financial


Economics, 5:2, pp. 147-175.

[28] Myers, S C and Majluf, N S (1984), ‘Corporate financing and investment decisions
when firms have information that investors do not have’, Journal of Financial
Economics, 13:2, pp. 187-221.

[29] Nickell, S (1981), ‘Biases in Dynamic Models with Fixed Effects’, Econometrica, 49:6,
pp. 1417-1426.

[30] Noss, J and Toffano, P (2014), ‘Estimating the impact of changes in aggregate bank
capital requirements during an upswing’, Bank of England Working Paper No. 494.

[31] OBR (2013), ‘Economic and Fiscal Outlook’, Office for Budget Responsibility, March.

[32] Peek, J and Rosengren, E S (1997), ‘The international transmission of financial


shocks: the case of Japan’, American Economic Review, 87:4, pp. 495-505.

[33] Pesaran, M H and Smith, R P (1995), ‘Estimating Long-Run Relationships from


Dynamic Heterogeneous Panels’, Journal of Econometrics, 68:1, pp. 79-113.

[34] Pybus, T (2011), ‘Estimating the UK’s historical output gap’, Office for Budget
Responsibility Working Paper No. 1.

[35] Rime, B (2001), ‘Capital Requirements and Bank Behaviour: Empirical Evidence for
Switzerland’, Journal of Banking and Finance, 25(4), pp. 789-805.

[36] Sharpe, S (1995), ‘Bank Capitalization, Regulation, and the Credit Crunch: A
Critical Review of the Research Findings’, DP 95-20, Financial and Economics
Discussion Series, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington,
DC.

[37] Sims, C A and Zha T (1999), ‘Error bands for impulse responses’, Econometrica, 67:5,
pp. 1113-1156.

[38] Stoltz, S and Wedow, M (2005) ‘Banks’ Regulatory Capital Buffer and the Business
Cycle: Evidence for German Savings and Co‐operative Banks’, Deutsche Bundesbank
Discussion Paper, No. 07/2005.

[39] Yellen, J L (2010), ‘Macroprudential Supervision and Monetary Policy in the Post-
crisis World’, Speech, Federal Board of Governors.

35

You might also like