International Market Entry: How Do Smes Make Decisions?: Journal of International Marketing
International Market Entry: How Do Smes Make Decisions?: Journal of International Marketing
Via dei Caniana 2, 24127 Bergamo, Italy, Phone +390352052618, Email: [email protected]
Alliance Manchester Business School, the University of Manchester, Room F8 Alliance MBS East, Booth
Street East, Manchester M13 9SS, United Kingdom
&
Via dei Caniana 2, 24127 Bergamo, Italy, Phone +390352052559, Email: [email protected]
* Corresponding author
2
Acknowledgment
Authors in alphabetical order. The case collection has been funded by The Foundation for Economic
Education (Finland). Funding from University of Bergamo – “Progetto ITALY – Italian Talented Young
Researcher” is also appreciated. Furthermore the authors wish to thank the JIM review team for their
helpful suggestions.
3
ABSTRACT
Choosing the right international market entry mode is of utmost importance for an
process (DMP), and specifically with regard to small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs). We
study the DMP among SMEs intent on entering international markets and how this affects their
international market development strategy. Using six cases based in Finland and Italy, we
develop a model of the SME DMP. Our results imply that the DMP evolves and goes through
different phases. By focusing on the post-entry phase, this study enhances knowledge on
to initial entry mode with ‘mainstream’ international business literature. Furthermore, SMEs
adopting a more rational DMP are more likely to succeed in foreign markets and consequently
this study demonstrates the importance of real options reasoning as a theoretical lens for making
Keywords: international market entry; market entry strategy; decision making; small and
Acknowledgment:
Authors in alphabetical order. The case collection has been funded by The Foundation for
Italian Talented Young Researcher” is also appreciated. Furthermore the authors wish to thank
INTRODUCTION
Selecting the mode of international market entry is, alongside the market entered, among the
most important decisions an internationalizing firm has to make. These two are among the most
popular research topics in international marketing and international business (e.g. Buckley 2002;
Malhotra, Agarwal and Ulgado 2003; Dow and Larimo 2009), and there is a plethora of studies
explaining the factors affecting the decision. However, there is a notable lack of analysis of the
decision-making process (DMP) in practice (Aharoni, Tihanyi, and Connelly 2011; Brouthers
and Hennart 2007; Nemkova et al. 2015). Ji and Dimitratos (2013) claim, for instance, that while
strategic DMPs of some kind seem to exist in internationalized firms, the area remains mostly
unexplored in the international marketing literature, even though export decision making, for
example, is seen as one of the key drivers of a firm’s success (Tantong et al. 2010). As Hennart
and Slangen (2015: p.119) note, “we lack detailed knowledge of how entry mode decisions are
actually made”, and to gain this knowledge we need to “scrutinize the decision process preceding
foreign entries” and the expansion into foreign markets in the post-entry phase. This issue is
more accentuated in the context of small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs; see e.g., Rialp,
Rialp, and Knight 2005; Schweizer 2012), there being a paucity of empirical research on how the
decision makers in SMEs make decisions when they internationalize (Chetty, Ojala and
Leppaaho 2015; Nummela et al. 2014; Zahra, Korri, and Yu 2005), and when they select entry
and post-entry modes for the different markets in which they are operating.
The purpose of our study is to respond to the call in previous literature for more research on the
DMP behind the choice of entry mode (Brouthers 2013; Hennart and Slangen 2015). We define
an entry mode as “an institutional arrangement that makes possible the entry of a company’s
products, technology, human skills, management or other resources into a foreign country” (Root
5
1977, p. 5). We further refer to the decision-making mode as the ‘method and logic’ used by
managers in SMEs when analyzing a decision to internationalize into a new market or “to
expand the scope of their existing international business” (Child and Hsieh 2014, p. 599). A
further aim is to enhance understanding of how the DMP eventually affects the firm’s
international market development strategy – in other words in the post-entry phase – and the
possibility of changing the entry mode in the future. Our study contributes to the literature in
various ways:
First, using previous literature we argue that three multidimensional constructs characterize
different decision-making modes. The current dominant stream of literature has adopted an
effectuation-causation logic (Nummela et al. 2014; Sarasvathy 2001). We take a more nuanced
view of the decision-making mode by considering rationality as a key concept. With a view to
making modes (Child and Hsieh 2014) and their implications, which takes the form of four
testable propositions. This information will increase awareness of the strengths and weaknesses
of different decision-making modes and their use during the internationalization process. This is
of great importance to SME managers responsible for international marketing activities, who
play a key role in initiating international operations, often starting with exporting.
Second, instead of focusing only on the initial entry mode, we also consider the post-entry phase,
during which, we argue, companies may adopt different decision-making modes. We suggest
that different decision-making modes affect firms’ subsequent operations, something not studied
in detail to date (cf. Hennart and Slangen 2015), and decision-making-mode evolvement. We
thus provide a more integrated picture of the DMPs of SMEs operating in international markets
6
and contribute to the international marketing literature by studying not only how decisions are
made (e.g. Nemkova et al. 2015) but how that process changes.
Third, we highlight the importance of rationality in the choice of entry mode, as well as in the
post-entry phase (Aharoni et al., 2011; Dean and Sharfman, 1996). We extend the notion of
rationality to explain the DMP with regard to ‘planning comprehensiveness’ (or in other words
managers’ approach to planning), the learning process, and time frame. This enables us to study
a DMP beyond the effectuation/causation dichotomy. In addition, we suggest that the different
entry mode decision-making logics have performance implications because they affect firms’
ability to adjust their entry mode after entry. Consequently, we will contribute to decision-
making theories by providing evidence on the outcomes of DMPs (cf. e.g. Nemkova et al. 2015)
and we especially highlight the role of real options reasoning (e.g. Child and Hsieh 2014) as a
theoretical lens for making entry mode decisions in the context of SMEs.
BACKGROUND
Decision making is one of the most important parts of management work, and in the context of
(Katsikeas, Samiee, and Theodosiou 2006; Nemkova et al. 2015; Sharfman and Dean 1997).
Various decision-making styles, models or modes are presented in the literature, the primary
common reference point being the extent to which they are related to rationality (Aharoni,
Tihanyi and Connelly 2011; Child and Hsieh 2014). Rationality is defined as “the reason for
doing something and to judge a behavior as reasonable is to be able to say that the behavior is
understandable within a given frame of reference” (Butler, 2002 p. 226). Rational decision
making is often understood as consisting of steps. These include setting managerial objectives,
7
then searching for information to develop a set of alternatives that will later be compared and
evaluated to enable the company to make the best choice. The selected option is implemented
and subjected to follow-up and control (e.g. Dean and Sharfman 1996).
Within the international marketing context, in particular when export decisions are analyzed,
decision theory has been used as a platform (Nemkova et al. 2015), from two different
perspectives: normative and descriptive. The normative approach “is associated with planning
and is defined as a process… …to formulate a solution to a problem” (Nemkova et al. 2015, p
42). The descriptive approach, however, envisages that “many decisions that affect a firm’s
performance are made outside the planning process” (Nemkova et al. 2015, p 42; see also Grant
The main factors that might influence the SME’s decision-making mode are ‘information
scarcity’ (Buckley 1989; Child & Hsieh 2014; Gabrielsson and Gabrielsson 2013); resource
availability (Evers and O’Gorman, 2011); decision makers’ ‘leadership characteristics’ and their
interpretations of the environment (Oviatt and McDougall 1994; Nielsen and Nielsen 2011;
Child and Hsieh 2014); the entrepreneur’s prior knowledge, experience, business and social
networks (Evers and O’Gorman 2011); the hybrid governance structures in SMEs, in which the
business model is normally co-created with partners, implying that the decision-making process
too is shared with partners (Sarasvathy 2001; Nummela et al. 2014); and goal setting
(Gabrielsson and Gabrielsson 2013). In addition, few smaller firms have the elaborate routines
found in larger organizations, and decisions may be made based on management’s existing
entry mode, when entering a new market, or change in mode (Lu 2002). The international entry
mode choice is a multifaceted decision involving the assessment of uncertainty and risk, control,
commitment, estimated returns, and other strategic objectives (Anderson and Gatignon 1986;
Brouthers and Hennart 2007; Ji and Dimitratos 2013). The change from one non-functioning
entry mode to another may be costly and time-consuming and have negative consequences for
In regard to SMEs, most studies on entry mode choice rely on the very same theories as are
employed by the multinational enterprise literature, including transaction costs and Dunning’s
OLI model (Laufs and Schwens 2014; Nakos and Brouthers 2002). There are suggestions that
decision-making approaches differ between SMEs and large companies (Child and Hsieh 2014;
Wilson and Nutt 2010). However, Laufs and Schwens (2014) found, in their review of such
papers, that specific SME characteristics are rarely considered. They conclude, “with regard to
SMEs’ sensitivity to external challenges, it remains unclear how SMEs and their major actors
What form, then, does the foreign market entry DMP take in SMEs? How do the decision
makers, i.e. individuals, often managers, make decisions when considering a change in entry
mode? In the case of SMEs, the main entry mode decision-making approaches studied recently
are effectuation and causation (e.g. Chetty et al. 2015; Sarasvathy 2001), two alternative logics
used by entrepreneurs taking decisions. The causation logic “sees the environment as largely
beyond the control of decision-makers… ...and consistent with the planned strategy approach”,
while the effectuation logic sees the “environment as endogenous to the actions” of decision
9
makers and “closer to emergent or non-predictive strategies” (Gabrielsson and Gabrielsson 2013,
p. 1359).
In the case of an initial entry, most studies suggest that the entry mode decision first follows an
effectuation approach in which uncertainty and a lack of information induce decision makers to
adopt a ‘less rational approach’, following feelings and intuitions (Chandra et al. 2009; Evers and
O’Gorman 2011; Sarasvathy 2001). It is tempting to think that SME decision making would
evolve into a causation logic and become more systematic and rational over time (see e.g.
Chandra et al. 2009; Gabrielsson and Gabrielsson 2013; Harms and Schiele 2012; Kalinic et al.
2014; Sarasvathy et al. 2014). The available empirical evidence in the SME setting is
inconclusive (Kalinic et al. 2014; Nummela et al. 2014; Schweizer 2012), though, and the two
logics can coexist (Harms and Schiele 2012; Kalinic et al. 2014). According to Nummela et al.
(2014), other important factors that influence the decision-making mode are the managers’
backgrounds and characteristics, which have an impact on their cognitive schemas and therefore
direct them towards different decisions. The product or market type may also have a huge effect
on decision making, and on planning as a basis for decision making (see e.g. the strategic
dimensions presented by Piëst 1994). Hence, it is not clear how managers of SMEs make
something else that dominates the initial entry mode and mode change decisions.
Consequently, more fine-grained approaches have also been suggested. In an attempt to organize
the decision-making styles or modes in SME internationalization, Child and Hsieh (2014)
propose four models that SME leaders may follow. They range from a low to a high level of
planning and rationality: reactivity, incrementalism, bounded rationality, and real options
reasoning (ROR). First, reactive decision making happens when the decision makers simply react
10
to internal and external factors, such as unplanned encounters (Crick and Spence 2005). The
decision tends to be based on short-term planning; it is made under uncertainty without the
(Foss, Foss, and Klein 2007; Jones, Coviello, and Tang 2011).
Second, incrementalism implies a process more rational than reactive. Incremental decision
makers compare alternatives and set objectives and goals, even if they are vague and far from
comprehensive or systematic (Child and Hsieh 2014). We are of the opinion that the effectuation
decisions based on the principle of ‘affordable loss’ rather than the maximization of expected
returns (Kalinic, Sarasvathy, and Forza 2014) – resembles incremental decision making in many
respects.
Bounded rationality is Child and Hsieh’s (2014) third decision-making mode. Some scholars
argue that the decision maker may be rational but the complexity of the environment and the
limited ability of humans to analyze and process information make maximization impossible in
real-life decision making (Simon 1955); in other words, he or she is boundedly rational (see
Cyert and March 1963). This approach assumes that organizations’ strategies, including strategic
decisions about internationalization, are related to the composition, cognitive orientation, and
perceptual process of the top-management team (Greve, Nielsen, and Ruigrok 2009; Kaczmarek
and Ruigrok 2013). Moreover, it considers managers with ownership to be more risk-averse and
Finally, the highest form of rational decision making in Child and Hsieh’s (2014) model is ROR,
defined as the managerial ability to identify, maintain, and exploit real options in their business
environments (Barnett 2008; Driouchi and Bennett 2011). A real option is a specific
(international) investment in an asset with uncertain payoffs (McGrath, Ferrier, and Mendelow
2004), such as joint ventures (Kogut 1991) or investments in R&D units in other locations
(McGrath and Nerkar 2004). ROR implies that, when uncertainty is high, firms may minimize
current investments but secure an option to invest at a later time, when lower uncertainty is
The four decision-making modes presented above are not categories in the strict sense of the
word because they differ in some dimensions but overlap in others. For instance, bounded
rationality and ROR-type decision making both include rational planning and decision-making
rules. These modes can serve as analytical tools in empirical analyses of SME DMPs related to
How do Child and Hsieh’s (2014) four decision-making modes fit into this context of SMEs
deciding on their initial entry mode and likely post-entry mode? Let us elaborate on them further
by focusing on their key features, or dimensions (see Table 1). The dimensions considered
significant for this exercise have been derived from the existing literature. They are
‘comprehensiveness of planning’ (e.g. Child and Hsieh 2014; Ji and Dimitratos 2013; Piëst
1994), path dependencies and learning (e.g. Hutzschenreuter, Pedersen, and Volberda 2007), and
the planning schedule and length of the strategic planning cycle (e.g. Aharoni 1966).
The first and third dimensions can be subsumed into the strategic decision-making literature (cf.
e.g. Liberman-Yaconi et al. 2010), whereas the second is much used in the international
marketing literature and can be found in internationalization process models (e.g. Johanson and
Vahlne 1977, 2009), for example. Next, we explain these dimensions while also considering the
role of rationality, which in this context may be regarded as the key discriminant among the
planning’), relates to managers’ rationality in their planning for the entry-mode decision (e.g.
equity vs. non-equity, low commitment vs. high commitment), or for a change in mode. Child
and Hsieh (2014) focus on four features of decision-making modes in relation to the
comprehensiveness of planning: how planned and goal-driven the process is, whether there are
decision-making rules, and whether alternatives are compared. Entry mode choice is a strategic
decision that should be supported by all kinds of relevant information and analyzed rationally (Ji
and Dimitratos 2013). This requires the analysis of different alternatives (e.g. export, joint
venture, acquisition, or greenfield investment) and the selection of criteria on which to base the
final choice (Malhotra et al. 2003; Morschett et al. 2010). Hence, rationality tends to lead to
finding and analyzing alternatives, as well as yielding more criteria to support the decision. As
mentioned above, managers of SMEs tend to have fewer alternatives because they have limited
capacity to gather and process information. Their limited resources mean that the fully rational
approaches are not always applicable (see e.g. Aharoni et al. 2011 for the ‘full rationality
information, analyzing it, and observing decision-making criteria (Kalinic et al. 2014). This may
mean that firms follow the effectuation logic for their first entry into a new market, but then
13
change to a causation logic, i.e. more rational and planned, when changing mode (Chandra et al.
2009; Gabrielsson and Gabrielsson 2013; Harms and Schiele 2012). Following Child and
Hsieh’s (2014) models, we suggest that SMEs will normally follow a ‘reactive’ decision-making
mode on first entry, then in the post-entry phase follow their ‘real decision-making mode’, be it
P1: SME decision making regarding entry mode is unplanned on first entry but becomes more
The second dimension refers to a pattern of behavior that forms in the context of decision
making regarding internationalization, when the key choices relate to entry mode and target
country (see e.g. Casillas, Moreno, and Acedo 2012; Jones and Coviello 2005). The
emphasize path dependencies (Hutzschenreuter, Pedersen, and Volberda 2007). The key point in
path dependency is that the company will allow evolution to happen rather than trying to go
against it (Hutzschenreuter et al. 2007; Volberda et al. 2001). Such behavior develops from the
company’s accumulated experience and learning, and its achieved degree of involvement
(Andersen 1993). Johanson and Vahlne (1977) describe the evolution of international entry and
operation modes in Swedish companies as an establishment chain. If the company were not
rational in its decision making, its entry-mode and post-entry decisions would depend on its
experience in other markets. The choice of entry mode may therefore be based on, for example,
inertia, a dominant internationalization path, or earlier knowledge and history (Child and Hsieh
2014; Hashai 2011). Hence, previously used market entry modes may be chosen again without a
The assumptions underlying the model are uncertainty and bounded rationality (Johanson and
Vahlne 2009). Uncertainty can be reduced through increase in market knowledge (Liesch,
Welch, and Buckley 2011), and also through ‘learning by doing’. Therefore, post-entry, entry
mode changes made by internationalizing companies with more rational decision making
depend, first, on learning from experience, including current activities in foreign markets, and
second, on the commitments made to strengthen their positions in foreign markets (Johanson and
Vahlne 2009).
P2: Experience in international markets helps companies to develop more rational entry mode
The third dimension concerns the planning schedule and the length of the strategic planning
cycle (see e.g. Aharoni 1966) during the DMP. The consideration of future market growth is
important and may play a significant role in the process, but the impact of time is still not clear.
Liesch et al. (2011, p. 137) call for better understanding of “the way in which time is experienced
by people within the enterprise, and decision makers, in particular”. Some scholars argue that
(Efrat and Shoham 2012). In fact, in the present context, the time frame could affect a company’s
adopted (Foss, Foss, and Klein 2007; Jones, Coviello, and Tang 2011). When the time frame is
short, for example, the company may choose a lower-commitment entry mode and collect less
information, thereby adopting a less rational decision-making mode. With a longer time frame, it
may adopt the Uppsala approach (Johansson and Vahlne 1977) and increase its commitment as
its market knowledge increases, or even follow the ROR approach of minimal current
investments with an option to invest when uncertainty is lower (Brouthers, Brouthers, and
15
Werner 2008). The ROR approach would indicate that the consequences of the decision(s) over
P3 The degree of rationality in an entry mode decision-making model is directly linked to the
time frame. The greater is the rationality, the longer is the time frame
The fourth additional dimension considers the performance implications of choosing and later
changing an entry mode as the firm’s strategy for operating in international markets. To evaluate
the appropriateness of this strategy, performance may be the most important consideration
(Katsikeas, Samiee and Theodosiou 2006). Among the decision-making modes mentioned
earlier, ROR has been regarded as a useful guide to the firm’s strategic decision making under
whether or not ROR will result in favorable performance is still in question (see Klingebiel and
Adner 2015). However, in line with past research on ROR in choosing entry modes (e.g.
Brouthers et al. 2008; Brouthers and Dikova 2010), we believe that, in the case of SMEs, ROR-
based decisions over initial entry mode choice and subsequent change will have superior
performance implications, and we examine this with empirical data. Therefore, our initial
proposition is as follows:
P4. SMEs following ROR to make strategic decisions over initial entry mode choice and
subsequent change will achieve greater performance than those following other decision-making
modes.
METHODOLOGY
To further explore, refine, and develop our theoretically driven propositions, we compared six
SMEs to study how they made decisions before and after entering foreign markets. Our aim was
16
to determine how the different decision-making modes could be linked theoretically to the
existing theories (Lee 1999) by exploring previously unexplained theoretical links. Accordingly,
and following Eisenhardt and Graebner’s (2007) recommendation, we used multiple case studies
to develop and reconnect these theoretical links. This approach is easily generalizable and
Case Selection
In selecting our cases, we used purposeful sampling, which is suitable for studying
underexplored phenomena (Eisenhardt and Graebner 2007; Yin 2003). We chose cases based on
theoretical reasoning, with regard to replication and theory extension (Yin 2003). Eisenhardt
(1989) argues that choosing cases randomly is neither necessary nor preferable. We based our
selection on several criteria that helped to describe the entry mode DMP. First, the cases had to
meet the defining criteria of an SME. We used the Organization for Economic Co-operation and
Development’s definition of SMEs as firms with fewer than 500 employees (OECD 2008). This
threshold is applied in many countries, such as Canada and the USA, for classification in many
Second, the extent of international experience and operations governed the selection. In
particular, we included in our original samples companies that had started operations in at least
one developed market, one of the BRICS countries (i.e. Brazil, Russia, India, China and South-
Africa), and one emerging non-BRICS market. Including different host markets with varying
levels of uncertainty in our sample gave us enough variance to make a robust comparison of
uncertainty and risk perceptions since they are elements that influence the DMP (see Aharoni
1966).
Third, the companies had to have been in operation in the host markets for more than one year
prior to our interviews (conducted in 2014), so that we could observe their post-entry behavior
and entry changes. Finally, we applied accessibility criteria, choosing thirteen potential
companies and finally selecting six of them according to their willingness to participate in the
research and their fit with the criteria described above. Companies A, B and C were based in
Finland and the rest in Italyi. Table 2 gives details of the selected companies.
Data Collection
Interviews are a highly efficient method by which to gather rich, empirical data, especially about
infrequent phenomena (in our research, the DMP driving foreign market entry mode choice)
(Eisenhardt and Graebner 2007). We therefore conducted in-depth interviews with key
informants from the case companies. We ensured that the interviewees were individuals who
were fully familiar with, and highly knowledgeable about, the companies’ international
operations, and who had been involved in the DMP for international expansion and entry mode
We started with structured interviewing, guided by the extant research (see Smith 2014), and we
conducted a total of eleven interviews within the six companies, each lasting between one and
two hours. They were digitally recorded and then transcribed on a word processor. Before
conducting the main interviews, we carried out two interviews with managers in two of the
companies as a pre-test so that we could make any necessary modifications. Similarly, after
18
doing our data analysis and coding, we conducted four additional interviews with informants
from Companies A, B, and C to check the validity of the data and for follow-up purposes. The
Appendix gives a sample of the main questions asked during the interviews.
In addition, we consulted the websites of the case companies to obtain information about their
internationalization histories, products, industry branches and other related secondary materials.
Moreover, we studied the companies’ archival documents, such as company bulletins, and asked
our key informants to evaluate the comprehensiveness of our data. We also ensured our
informants had been involved in the DMPs for entry mode and post-entry changes. All this
enabled us to triangulate our data (Smith 2014). The fact that these archival sources were
produced in ‘real time’ mitigated the impact of retrospective sense making and potential memory
Data Analysis
Like most qualitative research, our analysis progressed through a cycle of inductive and
deductive reasoning (e.g. Walsh and Bartunek 2011). During the early stages, we were
influenced by previous research on SME managers’ decision-making modes, and were familiar
with the continuum of rationality, as discussed above. We therefore began our analysis by
classifying each of our six cases following Child and Hsieh’s (2014) categories, so as to
We coded our data according to the principles of thematic analysis (Braun and Clarke 2006),
utilizing analytic replication in which each case served as its own experiment (Eisenhardt and
Graebner 2007; Yin 2003). We first created a list of first-order themes from our case evidence.
19
We then read the relevant literature again to see how we could explain what we had found in our
data. For example, we related the statements regarding whether the managers had considered
other alternatives when deciding to enter a market (first-order theme) to alternative analyses
theoretical dimensions, as represented in our data structure (see Maitlis and Lawrence 2007).
Through this procedure, we categorized our second-order themes into three main entry mode
decision-making dimensions, namely approach to planning, path dependency, and time. These
dimensions may have varying levels of importance, depending on the SME’s decision-making
mode. Table 4 shows our data structure, and in Table 5 we use illustrative examples to explain
The companies’ performance was measured by asking informants the following: “Are you
satisfied with the success of your entry? Have the objectives set for the entry been fulfilled?”
(See Appendix). We used secondary data such as company websites to validate this subjective
performance measurement.
FINDINGS
We now describe how the different decision-making modes of the SMEs were linked to the
aforementioned dimensions, and how this affected initial market entry and post-entry changes.
First, we examine the SMEs’ rationality in their planning approaches, whether they analyzed
alternatives, and whether they used criteria in their decisions. We then assess the extent to which
they were influenced by their previous market entry choices – in other words, their path
20
dependency. Finally, we explain the effect of time on the respective decisions and the decision-
making mode’s possible impact on performance. In Table 6, we summarize our findings from
each case.
Approach to Planning
Initial P1: SME decision making regarding entry mode is unplanned on first entry but becomes
more rational and systematic over time for post-entry mode changes.
We started our analysis with the question of whether or not rationality in the DMP characterized
the approach to planning and the effect on the choice of entry, in both entry and post-entry
mode, did not have a rational approach to planning: there was no advance planning; entry was
the result of serendipitous events; most of the information collected related to management
perceptions of market size and cultural distance; and possible alternatives were not considered
(see Table 5). As the manager said regarding the United Arab Emirates, “everything starts from
meetings with buyer during exhibitions followed by direct sales to department stores”. Then, in
the post-entry phase, the company had been contacted by a partner willing to develop a joint
venture. The decision was thus a reaction to a market request and, due to the alertness and
limited, it is still possible to see a planning process. First, they analyzed the market. If they saw
an opportunity (e.g. Decision Making Criteria for Company A in Table 5), they entered the
21
market in a low-commitment mode, and from that point, step by step, they increased their
commitment. The three companies, with limited planning and analysis, decided to enter different
markets (e.g., Company C in Russian Market, Company A in Chinese Market and Company E in
Indian market) with distributor agreements. Then, they started to collect relevant information
from the market through customers and distributors and increase their commitment to wholly
owned subsidiaries as soon as they felt that the market was ready to accept the company’s
product. The basic decision making criteria is evident in these cases: collect information, mostly
from trusted people and mostly regarding market opportunities based on people’s feelings and
Company F represents a more rational approach in terms of planning. First, it conducted market
research; then, it normally entered the market with a distributor partnership; finally, after a few
years of operations, it decided which alternatives suited it best in that particular market. Different
DMPs were followed for each possible post-entry mode: when a lower level of commitment was
needed, the Area Manager made the decision; with a higher level of commitment, as in the case
of the sales subsidiary, the CEO selected the manager to run the subsidiary, and everyone from
sales to production to IT would be involved in preparing the business plan. Company F clearly
followed the bounded rationality mode, with a much more well-defined process for data
collection and analysis compared to the incremental mode, even though the main decision-
We found that Company B took the most rational planning approach. It first entered the market
operating in the market, waiting for the right time to increase its commitment. As a result, it was
able to compare the alternatives and make a more appropriate decision in the end. It did this in
22
the case of South Korea: first, it entered via exporting, and then, having operated there for years,
it decided to acquire a manufacturing company. “Over the years…we learned about the market
quite well… [then] we acquired a manufacturing company there [South Korea]”, the manager
noted. The approach to planning was thus rather systematic: the alternatives were compared and
the decision made accordingly. The procedure followed was rational, similar to ROR.
With regard to the above discussion, our case studies show how SMEs’ approach to planning
varies depending on the extent to which they analyze entry mode alternatives and consider
dimension). Cases with a more rational decision-making mode, such as Company B and F,
consider more entry mode alternatives and have rigorous decision making criteria. This,
however, does not affect the initial entry-mode strategy. In fact, a low commitment mode was
selected in almost all cases (see Table 6, Initial Entry Mode (OM-E)). This allowed for market
entry with the goal of increasing market knowledge (see Liesch et al. 2011). On the other hand,
our results reveal that the planning approach affects the choice of post-entry operational mode. In
sum, we believe on the basis of our analysis that the decision-making mode has a stronger
influence on the SME’s choice of strategy post-entry. This confirms the original proposition,
Final P1: The relationship between decision-making mode and approach to planning is
stronger in post-entry, i.e. after the SME enters a given market, than pre-entry phase. As
such, the more rational an SME’s decision-making mode, the more rational is its approach
to post-entry planning.
23
Path Dependency
Initial P2: Experience in international markets helps companies to develop more rational entry
The rationality of each decision-making mode is also observable through the approach to path
dependency (Child and Hsieh 2014). The main findings of our research reveal that all the firms
adopted a low-commitment mode when entering mostly new markets, in line with the Uppsala
model (Johansson and Vahlne 1977). The Uppsala model also describes a learning path through
experience and previous decision making that influences future international decisions (Casillas
et al. 2012; Hutzschenreuter et al. 2007). Our findings further show that in some cases a learning
process can be detected, with the operation mode in post entry phase repeated in some of the
On the other hand, we found that the companies engaging in more rational decision-making were
less dependent on their earlier experiences; for example, they considered and compared a wider
variety of operation modes in the post-entry phase (e.g. see Company A and F in China in Table
5). Company B followed a similar approach in Norway and South Africa: it started with a
distributor agreement, then, after collecting all necessary information, it decided to change to
different operational modes that it believed could produce better outcomes in the future, namely
Experience in foreign markets can also cause companies to change decision-making mode. In
company E, for example, during the post-entry phase in Turkey, the learning path in the previous
market encouraged the management team to change its decision-making mode to a more rational
one (i.e. incremental to ROR). Instead of cooperating with a distributor for a few years and then
opening a sales subsidiary, as it had done previously, it collected all possible information
24
regarding the investment in advance, and then decided to postpone the sales subsidiary option to
a later stage.
We therefore observe that the more rational SMEs follow a learning path in terms of decision-
making mode, have a wider variety of modes in their past entry-mode portfolio, and are more
flexible in selecting their post-entry operation modes (see Table 4, second-order themes of ‘path
dependency’ dimension). Stated differently, these SMEs are less path dependent. On the other
hand, SMEs which base their decision making on reactivity and incrementalism tend to have a
smaller number of alternatives and a smaller number of operation modes at their disposal, and
their learning path is about selecting the best operation mode for all markets. They tend to
choose modes with which they are familiar (Child and Hsieh 2014). Against this background, we
Final P2: The more rational an SME’s decision-making mode, the stronger is the effect of
past experience on entry mode choice; such SMEs are likely to consider a wider variety of
alternative post-entry operation modes, and are also more likely to change their decision-
Time
Initial P3: The degree of rationality in an entry mode decision-making model is directly linked to
the time frame. The greater is the rationality, the longer is the time frame.
Time is an important dimension of the SME’s DMP (Efrat and Shoham 2012). Our analysis
reveals that decision makers who are less rational analyze the information from a short-to-
medium-term investment perspective. Company D, for example, had considered the fact that the
market size and interest in a “product made in Italy” could change in the medium term and
therefore decided to maintain its lower commitment even in the post-entry phase.
25
On the other hand, when higher levels of rationality prevailed, as in Company C, the planning
was somewhat longer-term; for example, expecting that the Russian market “could be about ten
times bigger in a few years”, the company decided to increase its commitment through a sales
subsidiary. At higher levels of rationality, companies collect and analyze information more
rigorously upon noticing potential opportunities, before deciding whether and how to act. When
market potential is confirmed, a goal is set for the long term and the company’s decision makers
consider potential strategic developments. Company E, for example, in the case of the Turkish
market, analyzed all the alternatives and decided – based on the strength of the market’s potential
– to enter it through a low-commitment distributor that could later become a sales subsidiary that
would meet its long-term goals. Similarly, Company B’s manager noted, “It is very important to
take into account the future [market] potential and operations… We do not make the same
agreements in [all] the markets”. After Company B enters a foreign market, it then allows itself
sufficient time to compare alternative operating modes in that market and change if necessary.
Accordingly, if appropriate, it will then make a longer-term decision and choose a higher-
commitment mode, such as a WOS in the form of an acquisition. This had happened in both
South Korea and South Africa. In the case of South Korea, the management took almost a decade
to decide to change mode, eventually choosing a production plant as the best alternative. This
approach requires a longer-term view of future operations and tends to build on long-term goals
(see Table 4, second-order themes of ‘time’ dimension). We may conclude from our data that, in
general, whether companies take a long or short-term perspective on their future operations and
market development differs according to their decision-making mode. Therefore, we confirm our
proposition as follows:
26
Final P3: The more rational the decision-making mode of an SME, the longer is its
Performance
Initial P4: SMEs following ROR to make strategic decisions over initial entry mode choice and
subsequent change will achieve greater performance than those following other decision-making
modes.
Our analysis also reveals that ROR (e.g. Brouthers et al. 2008; McGrath 1997), in which
managers plan future developments in advance rather than reacting to the market situation, is the
most effective strategy for producing a successful entry-mode choice. Company B, for instance,
entered South Africa with a rational, long-term approach. It established a sales subsidiary only
after it had acquired extensive market knowledge, established connections, and was able to
compare alternatives. The company was happy with its performance. As the interviewed
manager said, “we are successful in the market”. It apparently used ROR in its decision-making
process.
On the other hand, examples of less rational decision-making include decisions taken for an
investment that did not produce results (Company A), and a joint venture that was not successful
(Company F). For example, Company A entered the US market following incrementalism logic.
According to one of the managers, since the USA “seemed” to be a big, promising market, they
decided to enter it via a sales subsidiary. After making a significant investment, however, the
managers found the market more complicated than expected, forcing a decrease in commitment.
This lost them “millions of euros” before they changed their market objectives.
27
Company F faced a similar situation in China: it opened a production plant in a joint venture
with a local company, following a reactive approach in considering the options with regard to
cooperating with a possible partner. The partnership was not successful, however. The company
had to start again from the beginning, this time with a distributor that helped it acquire
knowledge and build up networks. Only then could the company select the best operating mode
It thus seems that following ROR gives SMEs more alternatives from which to choose, thereby
minimizing downside exposure (to control and investment uncertainty) and maximizing potential
gains for each market. We believe this is a less risky decision-making method, in that combining
value creation with cost reduction may lead to better decisions (e.g. Company E changes to ROR
Final P4: SMEs adopting a more rational decision-making mode, such as ROR, are more
On the basis of the above analysis, we now develop a dynamic model of SME decision making
when entering foreign markets and then changing their initial entry mode (see Figure 1). As our
analysis shows, most of the companies entered new markets with a low commitment without
following a pre-defined DMP. The part above the dashed line in Figure 1 describes the typical
We also found the managers’ decision making ‘less rational’ at the early stage of market entry,
meaning they did not make decisions very systematically. Decision making in the initial entry-
28
mode phase can be described as very ‘path dependent’: the companies started with low-
commitment entry modes they were familiar with. Exporting was dominant (supporting existing
studies on SMEs, see e.g. the review of Laufs and Schwens 2014). This means that ‘reactive’ and
‘incremental’ decision-making modes prevailed among most of our case companies. However,
other dimensions enabled a more detailed analysis. First, limited planning took place. Second,
there were exceptions. For example, while Company B started with exporting, it clearly took a
longer time horizon in its decision making. Its management team was already using rudimentary
ROR with the ‘means they had’ at the time of the decision making.
However, as argued above, different decision-making modes, which can be described through
the lenses of different decision-making dimensions, were more likely to guide the firms post-
entry. Learning takes place ‘within the decision-making mode’ and leads companies to adopt a
new [more rational] decision-making mode (in Figure 1, see the descriptions of paths A and B
below the dotted line, showing two typical developments of the DMP). Company E provides an
example, having moved from incrementalism to ROR in its decision making when entering a
Generally the case companies used ‘more rational’ decision-making logic post-entry, e.g. when
deciding to change from one operating mode to another. In fact, it can be seen that companies
deciding to change operating mode in a given market took a different planning approach, with
different methods of analyzing the alternatives and decision-making criteria. The extent of
relying on previous experience (e.g. past entry-mode choices) and consideration of future
developments in the particular market also varied. For example, Company B entered South
Korea via exporting. However, its managers constantly analyzed the market, waiting for the right
time to increase their investment – exercising the option to wait or defer (Trigeorgis 1993) – and
29
when the time came they followed a rational decision-making path and changed the initial mode
DISCUSSION
expansion, particularly in SMEs. Deciding to enter a new market via exporting, strategic
alliances, or foreign direct investment, for instance, has implications in terms of investment risk,
organizational control, and resource commitment (Anderson and Coughlan 1987; Efrat and
Shoham 2012). Our literature review reveals a lack of research on the process SMEs follow
Theoretical Implications
Our study makes four main contributions to the existing literature. First, by focusing on post-
international marketing literature related to initial entry mode (Buckley 2002) with ‘mainstream’
theories explaining SMEs’ entry modes (see Laufs and Schwens 2014). Recent DMP literature
causation (e.g. Kalinic et al. 2014). We have shown that this simplification, focusing on (only)
two DMP logics, does not provide a full picture of what happens when SMEs make their entry-
decision-making modes built on three dimensions (see also the conceptual work of Child and
Hsieh 2014). The results of our study enhance understanding of the entry-mode DMP.
30
Second, we suggest that different decision-making modes affect the evolution of operations, or
post-entry changes, thereby narrowing the gap highlighted by previous research (Hennart and
Slangen 2015). While SMEs entering a new market seem to select lower commitment without
following a pre-defined DMP (exhibiting rather rudimentary ‘reactive decision making’ based on
internal or external stimuli), post-entry they use all available resources to make the appropriate
choice. As different market operations may be in different phases at the company level, less
rational and more rational planning can co-exist, although at the market level their use may be
sequential (see e.g. Nemkova et al. 2015 for propositions on the co-existence of improvisation
and planning in international marketing contexts, and Chetty et al. 2015 for differences between
decisions on foreign markets and entry modes). However, it is interesting to note that, among our
case companies, only Company E clearly changed its decision-making mode as regards entry.
The other focal companies became more rational post-entry but their evolution seemed to take
place ‘within the decision-making mode’, i.e. they did not change their DMP but became more
efficient in their use of the focal decision-making mode. Company B used ROR at the outset, so
decision-making mode change does not apply to it. Interestingly, ROR may contain both
effectuation (in the initial decision-making phase regarding low-commitment entry modes such
as exporting) and causation (post-entry when the company is following a different approach to
planning) elements.
Third, our research confirms the importance of rationality as a point of reference for the
decision-making mode in internationalization (Aharoni et al. 2011; Child and Hsieh 2014; Dean
and Sharfman 1996). Rationality, which can be assessed with a number of indicators (cf. e.g.
Liberman-Yaconi et al. 2010), drives the quantity and quality of information to collect, the
number of alternatives to contemplate, the approach to future operations, and experience. In our
31
work we have used “approach to planning”, “path dependency” and “time” dimensions to define
the degree of rationality. We suggest that this approach has been useful and could be used in
future studies.
Fourth, we demonstrate the important role of ROR as a theoretical lens for SME entry-mode
decision making. ROR asserts that treating international investments as real options gives
managers the flexibility to defer, expand, or abandon investment projects in the future (Li and Li
2010). For instance, firms facing high uncertainty and investment irreversibility may minimize
their investment through low-commitment entry (Li and Rugman 2007; in our case exporting).
This minimizes downside risk exposure – controlling investment uncertainties – by deferring part
of the investment until uncertainty is lower; at the same time, they obtain an option to participate
in potential upside benefits (Folta 1998; McGrath and Nerkar 2004; Sanchez 2003). Applying
ROR to the literature on SME decision making facilitates operating-mode choice, producing
making methods.
Managerial Implications
Our cases illustrate the DMPs of SMEs entering new markets. International entry-mode
strategies and post-entry developments are difficult decisions, falling initially under the remit of
international marketing managers. The main problem relates to the ability to collect all the
information needed to produce the most profitable decision. The managerial implications
discussed here relate to the importance of long-term thinking when entering new markets. Even
meaning that the choice “is not made once for all; it is made and re-made endlessly” (Lindblom
1959, p. 86) – it is evident that searching for information and determining what is relevant are
32
activities crucial for ensuring continuous operational success in chosen markets. How companies
learn to find, analyze and use this information is largely related to path dependency and
experiential knowledge. In the case of (newly) internationalizing SMEs, this often means
recruitment challenges, given that international experience accumulates from learning by doing
and the required knowledge may not exist within the company. Hence, managers need to learn
Moreover, our findings imply that ROR offers SME managers more alternatives, which, as much
as possible, lowers risk (see also Brouthers et al. 2008). This gives some support to the use of
ROR to achieve above-average performance. Managers could create options in the focal market
by entering through a low-investment mode, which would give them more flexibility. When a
market is associated with high uncertainty, for example, managers can make incremental, small
(low-commitment) investments instead of postponing the entire process (Bowman and Hurry
1993; Brouthers and Dikova 2010). They could enter a market via exporting and wait for the
right time to expand the investment. Should the uncertainty increase, meanwhile, they have the
option of abandoning the investment project without incurring high costs. This, as we have
shown, could result in superior performance. At the same time, it allows managers to exploit
opportunities in different markets without having to collect all the information. This is
Our research has several limitations. First, given its qualitative nature we can only make
analytical generalizations. Consequently, we would encourage future studies with large samples
and different country settings to test the refined propositions. Second, interviews with more
informants, e.g. with sales managers, country managers and CEOs, could identify any
33
information bias between CEOs and other members of management, better validating our study.
Third, the companies analyzed are of different sizes. There could be a size bias in decision-
making mode selection, and we would recommend future studies take this into account. For
instance, a follow-up quantitative study could control the effect of firm size on the relationship
Finally, we have only one primary data-collection point with most of the case companies. The
study of DMPs would naturally benefit from longitudinal data collection, which would yield a
more detailed picture; indeed, there may be some data-collection bias. All in all, longitudinal
studies may enable us to see more changes in decision-making modes, whereas the changes
identified here mostly take place ‘within mode’. More radical changes might happen through
learning over time. It is interesting, however, that despite the clear focus on experiential
investigation into the construct of experiential knowledge in this regard (Knight and Liesch
2002). In general, there is a need for better understanding of how managers perceive time in the
internationalization process, and how time relates to decision making (see e.g. Middleton,
(rational) decision making. First, our results indicate that dimensions such as market uncertainty,
experience, and network availability influence operating-mode choice, and we believe that future
analyses could assess those dimensions’ impact on decision-making mode. Moreover, we see an
interesting area for future research regarding cultural differences and the impact of psychic
distance on entry-mode decision making (Dimitratos et al. 2011); e.g. top management team
heterogeneity. In addition, an interesting avenue for future research would be the interplay
34
between effectuation and causation decision logics and the different decision-making modes
discussed here. As an example, we are yet to identify in detail the relation between ROR and
these two types of decision-making logic. Early in the DMP, ROR suggests that companies make
small investments in uncertain environments and wait to see what opportunities arise in the
future. This resembles effectuation logic. Later on, however, ROR suggests that companies
analyze additional information and make more rational decisions over whether to increase or
decrease their investments. This resembles causation logic. Future studies could shed more light
on such unresolved issues. All in all, however, we have tackled an area of the SME
internationalization literature in which much has remained unexplored, i.e. the international
marketing DMP (see e.g. Rialp et al. 2005; Schweizer 2012), and we believe that our study and
the six cases with various entry and operating modes constitute an interesting platform for further
research.
CONCLUSION
Using six cases from Finland and Italy, we examine in detail the DMP of SMEs deciding to enter
new foreign markets. In so doing, we develop a model in which we analyze the cases based on
three different dimensions (see Figure 1): approach to planning, path dependency of entry mode,
and time planning. Each dimension comprises several factors that SMEs consider in their
decision making relative to foreign-market entry mode and post-entry operations. In further
analyses we link these dimensions to the SMEs’ different decision-making modes. Consequently,
our study gives new insights into SMEs’ DMPs around initial entry mode choice and
international market development strategy (i.e. post-entry operating mode), and how the DMP
evolves.
35
REFERENCES
Aharoni, Yair (1966), The foreign investment decision process (Vol. 403.). Harvard University
135–142.
Andersen, Otto (1993), "On the internationalization process of firms: A critical analysis,"
——— (1997), "Internationalization and Market Entry Mode: A Review of Theories and
Anderson, Erin and Anne T. Coughlan (1987), "International Market Entry and Expansion Via
——— and Hubert Gatignon (1986), "Modes of foreign entry: A transaction cost analysis and
Barnett, Michael L. (2008), "An attention-based view of real options reasoning," Academy of
Bell, Jim, Dave Crick and Stephen Young (2004), "Small firm internationalization and business
Bowman, Edward H. and Dileep Hurry (1993), "Strategy through the optoins lens: an integrated
Braun, Virginia and Victoria Clarke (2006), "Using thematic analysis in psychology,"
Brouthers, Keith D. (2013), "A retrospective on: Institutional, cultural and transaction cost
——— and George Nakos (2004), "SME Entry Mode Choice and Performance: A Transaction
———, Lance E. Brouthers and Steve Werner (2008). "Real Options, International Entry Mode
——— and Desislava Dikova (2010), "Acquisitions and Real Options: The Greenfield
——— and Jean-Francois Hennart (2007), "Boundaries of the Firm: Insights From International
Buckley, Peter J. (1989), "Foreign direct investment by small and medium sized enterprises: The
Butler, Richard (2002), "Decision making," in Organization Sorge, A., London: Thomson
Learning, 224–251.
Casillas, Jose C., Ana M. Moreno and Francisco J. Acedo (2012), "Path dependence view of
37
Chandra Yanto, Chris Styles and Ian Wilkinson (2009), "The recognition of first time
Chetty, Sylvie, Arto Ojala, and Tanja Leppäaho (2015), "Effectuation and foreign market entry
Child, John and Linda H.Y. Hsieh (2014), "Decision mode, information and network attachment
Crick, David and Martine Spence (2005), "The internationalisation of “high performing” UK
Cyert, Richard M. and James G. March (1963), A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood
Dean, James W. and Mark P. Sharfman (1996), "Does Decision Process Matter? A Study of
368–396.
Dimitratos, Pavlos, Andreas Petrou, Emmanuella Plakoyiannaki and Jeffrey E. Johnson (2011),
Dow, Douglas and Jorma Larimo (2009), "Challenging the conceptualization and measurement
Driouchi, Tarik and David J. Bennett (2011), "Real options in multinational decision-making:
Managerial awareness and risk implications," Journal of World Business, 46(2), 205–219.
Efrat, Kalanit and Aviv Shoham (2012), "Born global firms: The differences between their short-
Eisenhardt, Kathleen M. (1989), "Building theories from case study research. Academy of
——— and Graebner, Melissa E. (2007), "Theory Building from Cases: Opportunities and
Evers, Natasha, and O’Gorman, Colm (2011), "Improvised internationalization in new ventures:
the role of prior knowledge and networks," Entrepreneurship & Regional Development,
23(7–8), 549–574.
Folta, Timothy B. (1998), "Governance and uncertainty: The tradeoff between administrative
Foss, Kirsten, Nicolai J. Foss and Peter G. Klein (2007), "Original and Derived Judgment: An
1912.
Gabrielsson, Peter and Gabrielsson, Mika (2013), "A dynamic model of growth phases and
George, Gerard, Johan Wiklund and Shaker A. Zahra (2005), "Ownership and the
Grant, Robert M. (2003), "Strategic Planning in a Turbulent Environment: Evidence from the Oil
Greve, Peder, Sabina Nielsen and Winfried Ruigrok (2009), "Transcending borders with
Harms, Rainer and Holger Schiele (2012), "Antecedents and consequences of effectuation and
Hashai, Niron (2011), "Sequencing the expansion of geographic scope and foreign operations by
Hennart, Jean-Francois and Arjen H. Slangen (2015), "Yes, we really do need more entry mode
122.
Hutzschenreuter, Thoma, Torben Pedersen and Henk W. Volberda (2007), "The role of path
Ji, Junzhe and Pavlos Dimitratos (2013), "An empirical investigation into international entry
Johanson, Jan and Jan-Erik Vahlne (1977), "The internationalization process of the firm. A
——— and Jan-Erik Vahlne (2009), "The Uppsala internationalization process model revisited:
36(3): 284-303.
———, ———, and Yee Kwan Tang (2011), "International Entrepreneurship research (1989–
2009): A domain ontology and thematic analysis," Journal of Business Venturing, 26(6),
632–659.
Kaczmarek, Szymon and Winfried Ruigrok (2013), "In at the Deep End of Firm
Kalinic, Igor, Saras D. Sarasvathy and Cipriano Forza (2014), "“Expect the unexpected”:
Katsikeas, Constantine S., Saeed Samiee and Marios Theodosiou (2006), "Strategy Fit and
Kogut, Bruce (1991), "Joint ventures and the option to expand and acquire," Management
Laufs, Katharina and Christian Schwens (2014), "Foreign market entry mode choice of small and
Lee, Thomas W. (1999), Using qualitative methods to organize research. Newbury Park: CA:
Sage.
Leonard-Barton, Dorothy (1990), "A dual methodology for case studies: synergistic use of a
longitudinal single site with replicated multilpe sites," Organization Science, 1(3), 248–266.
Li, Jing and Yong Li (2010), "Flexibility versus commitment: MNEs’ ownership strategy in
——— and Alan M. Rugman (2007), "Real options and the theory of foreign direct investment,"
Liesch, Peter W., Lawrence S. Welch and Peter J. Buckley (2011), "Risk and Uncertainty in
Japanese firms’ entry mode choice," Journal of International Business Studies, 33(1), 19–
37.
Maitlis, Sally and Thomas B. Lawrence (2007), "Triggers and enablers of sensegiving in
Malhotra, Naresh K., James Agarwal and Francis M. Ulgado (2003), "Internationalization and
McGrath, Rita G. (1997), "A real options logic for initiating technology positioning
———, Walter J. Ferrier and Aubrey L. Mendelow (2004), "Real Options as Engines of Choice
——— and Atul Nerkar (2004), "Real options reasoning and a new look at the R&D investment
Middleton, Stuart, Peter W. Liesch and John Steen (2011), "Organizing time: Internationalization
Morschett, Dirk, Hanna Schramm-Klein and Bernhard Swoboda (2010), "Decades of research on
market entry modes: What do we really know about external antecedents of entry mode
Nakos, George and Keith D. Brouthers (2002), "Entry mode choice of SMEs in Central and
Nemkova, Ekaterina, Anne L. Souchon, Paul Hughes and Micevski Milena (2015), "Does
Nielsen, Bo B. and Sabina Nielsen (2011), "The role of top management team international
Nummela, Nina, Sami Saarenketo, Paivi Jokela and Sharon Loane (2014), "Strategic decision-
making of a born global: A comparative study from three small open economies,"
OECD. (2008), "Definition of small and medium sized enterprises (SMEs)," (accessed October
Pan, Yigang and David K. Tse (2000), "The hierarchical model of market entry modes," Journal
Rialp, Alex, Josep Rialp and Gary A. Knight (2005), "The phenomenon of early
Root, Franklyn R. (1977), Entry strategies for foreign markets: from domestic to international
Sanchez, Ron (2003), "Integrating transaction costs theory and real options theory," Managerial
44
Sarasvathy, Saras D. (2001), "Causation and effectuation: Toward a theoretical shift from
26(2), 243–263.
Sharfman, Mark P. and James W. Dean (1997), "Flexibility in Strategic Decision Making:
217.
Simon, Herbert A. (1955), "A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice," Quarterly Journal of
Smith, Wendy K. (2014), "Dynamic Decision Making : A Model of Senior Leaders Managing
Tantong, Phattarawan, Kiran Karande, Anil Nair, and Anusorn Singhapakdi (2010), "The Effect
Trigeorgis, Lenos (1993), "Real Options and Interactions With Financial Flexibility," Journal of
Volberda, Henk W., Charles Baden-Fuller and Frans A.J. Van Den Bosch (2001), "Mastering
strategic renewal: mobilizing renewal journeys in multi-unit firms’," Long Range Planning,
34(2), 159–178.
45
Walsh, Ian J. and Jean M. Bartunek (2011), "Cheating the fates: Organizational foundings in the
Mäntymäki (2011), "Theorising from case studies: Towards a pluralist future for
Wilson, D. C., & Nutt, P. C. (Eds.). (2010). Handbook of decision making. Chichester: Wiley.
Yin, Robert K. (2003), Case study research: Design and methods. Thousand Oaks: CA: Sage.
Zahra, Shaker A., Juha Santeri Korri and Jifeng Yu (2005), "Cognition and international
What factors are important for you when making decisions about the strategy with which to enter a new
foreign market? What factors affect your decision?
Could you describe your normal decision-making process when deciding on the strategy with which to
enter a new foreign market?
How did you enter market A? [Note: A stands for the name of the country]
Did you have any pre-defined goals when you decided to enter market A?
- What was the goal? Was it a short-term or long-term goal? Did it change before the entry due to
external factors? Why? Did it change during the decision-making process? Why?
Did you consider alternative ways to enter the market?
- How did you analyze the alternatives? Did you collect any information for each alternative? If
yes, how? If no, why?
What were your final decision-making criteria?
How did you make the decision?
When did you make the decision?
How long did it take to make the decision?
When making the decision, how much did you consider your future operations and the development of
the market?
Since entry what has happened in the market?
Have you changed your operating mode? If yes, why?
Have your objectives changed since entry?
Did you use different modes of operation in market A?
What was your perception of the market at the time of entry in relation to uncertainty and risk?
Has your perception of the uncertainty and risk decreased since entry?
How important was the market for your business and your industry at the time of entry, and how
important is it now? Why?
Are you satisfied with the success of your entry?
Have the objectives set for the entry been fulfilled?
47
Time Short term Short to medium term Medium term Long term
• Goal time Short Medium Long Long
• Long-term approach Short Medium Medium Long
• Decision-making Short Medium Medium Long
length
Statements showing whether the managers’ goals were short Goal time (GO-TI)
term or long term
Statements showing how much they considered their future Long-term approach (LTA)
operations and market development Time
Statements indicating how long it took to make the decision, Decision-making length
and how long the decision-making process was. (DML)
51
APPROACH AL- Only for Japan Only for USA Only for Sweden Only for future development Only for future development Only for future development
TO AN
PLANNING
DM Management Market potential Market potential + Management perception + Affordable loss Market potential + Intermediary
C perception + Market Market knowledge Market potential
size
PATH AL Only for Japan Only USA Partner comparison Only for Turkey Only for future development Only for future development
DEPENDE through different DMP
NCY
OM Dist. Direct Direct Dist. Agency Sales Dist. Dist. Direct Dist. Dist. Dist. Plant Dist. Dist. Dist. Dist. Dist.
export export subs export
-E
OM Partnership with local Prod. Agency Sales Dist. Dist. Sales Sales Dist. WOS Sales Sales subs Sales Exclusive Prod. plant Sales
company to open corners plant subs Subsi subs sales subs subs dealer subs
-F and shops diary subs
TIME GO From medium- to long- From medium- to long- From short- to long-term Long term goal Long term goal Long term goal
- TI term goal term goal goal
LT YES - future YES - future sales and YES - future potential YES - future development YES - market size and YES - future potential and
A development and operations and market share considering market size future development operations
opportunity
Note: Dist. is an abbreviation for Distributor. Prod. is an abbreviation for Production plant.
53
Figure 1. Integrated Model of the SME Decision-Making Process related to Initial entry phase and Post entry phase
Approach to Approach to
planning planning
(limited) (strong)
Endnote
i
The choice of Finland and Italy was based mainly on accessibility due to the authors’ geographic locations. Further,
both Italy and Finland are advanced European economies. Factors such as the cultural differences between these two
countries, the different psychic distances to the host countries, and the different market sizes fall beyond the purpose
and scope of this research.