0% found this document useful (0 votes)
65 views15 pages

Why Do Cities Exist?: Economics 312 Martin Farnham

Cities exist due to comparative advantages and economies of scale in production and exchange. Trading cities form near transportation hubs to facilitate trade, while factory cities develop near concentrated production. As transportation costs fall, city sizes increase due to expanded market areas. Resource-oriented towns also form near immobile inputs like forests, fisheries or mines. As technology changes, optimal locations may shift based on changing costs and available resources and infrastructure. Other factors like taxes, services and proximity to consumers also influence firm locations.

Uploaded by

Min Chan Moon
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
65 views15 pages

Why Do Cities Exist?: Economics 312 Martin Farnham

Cities exist due to comparative advantages and economies of scale in production and exchange. Trading cities form near transportation hubs to facilitate trade, while factory cities develop near concentrated production. As transportation costs fall, city sizes increase due to expanded market areas. Resource-oriented towns also form near immobile inputs like forests, fisheries or mines. As technology changes, optimal locations may shift based on changing costs and available resources and infrastructure. Other factors like taxes, services and proximity to consumers also influence firm locations.

Uploaded by

Min Chan Moon
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
You are on page 1/ 15

Why Do Cities Exist?

Economics 312
Martin Farnham
Conditions under which no cities
would exist (consider a 2-good world)
• Equal productivity of resources (no
comparative advantage)
• Constant returns to scale.
– In exchange (unit cost of each transaction is
same, regardless of quantity transacted)
– In production (unit cost of each unit produced is
same, regardless of quantity produced)
• Together, these eliminate need for
specialization and trade.
– Everyone sits on their own piece of land making
(and consuming) bread and shirts.
– Population distributes itself evenly across space.
Why Do Cities Exist?
• Comparative advantage plus economies of
scale in exchange==>trading cities
– Gains from trade cause resources to be put to
specialized use
– Economies of scale in exchange causes trading
firms to act as intermediary between buyers and
sellers (otherwise buyers seek sellers directly)
• Trading firms (& workers) will tend to concentrate in
areas that facilitate collection and distribution of goods
• Comparative advantage plus economies of
scale in production==>factory cities
– Economies of scale in production means that it
makes sense to concentrate resources (in factory)
• Workers will locate nearby
Econ 312--Farnham 3
Trading Cities
• Cities can serve as a central market place for
regional buyers and sellers or as distribution
centers
• Crossroads, ports, rivers serve as natural
location points for firms seeking to keep
transport costs low.
• Trading firms (distributors) and their
employees will locate near these points
• Rising population drives up land prices
• Residents demand smaller plots of land;
population density rises==>city!
Econ 312--Farnham 4
Factory Cities

• Location of factory will lead workers to locate


nearby (keeps commuting costs down)
• Workers will bid up price of land, demand
smaller lots==>increase in population density
• Note that gains from scale economies are
partly offset by increased transport costs
imposed on customers
• Factory can economize on transportation
costs by locating near population clusters
(trading cities?)
Econ 312--Farnham 5
Per unit Per unit
Factory Factory
Production Production
Cost (plus Cost (plus
transport) transport)
Net
Cost Home
(hours) Production
Cost
Per unit Factory
Production Cost
Miles
0 from
Factory
Factory
Market
Area

Econ 312--Farnham 6
Limits to City Size

• Freight costs
– Decreased transport costs increase radius that
factory can serve competitively==>increases
population of factory workers and city size
– Growth of railroads during Industrial Revolution
increased market size for Eastern manufacturers
and Western farmers==>increased specialization,
and growth of Eastern cities

Econ 312--Farnham 7
Limits to City Size (cont)

• Economies of Scale in production


– Higher economies of scale increase factory’s
market radius, which increases city size
• Commuting Costs
– Worker wage must account for commuting costs
(or else worker will prefer to produce at home)
– Bigger cities have higher commuting costs, hence
may need to pay higher wages (drives up price of
factory output relative to home output; reduces
market radius of factory)

Econ 312--Farnham 8
Resource-Oriented Towns

• Living in BC, we’re familiar with towns that


are neither factory nor trading towns
– Tourist towns
– Resource towns
• Logging (and milling)
• Fishing (and canning)
• Mining (and smelting)
• Both of these types of towns exist due to
industries that locate to be near an
immoveable input (forests, good scenery,
fisheries, etc.)
Econ 312--Farnham 9
Resource-Oriented Towns

• Cities have risen and fallen for reasons


of resource location throughout history
– Mining booms (e.g. California, Australia,
Yukon boom--bust towns)
– Port Alice, BC (logging, milling)
– Fort McMurray, AB (oil sands)
– Kansas City meat processors (near cattle
herds; affected by rail line location)
– Whistler, BC (where ski hill is “resource”)
Econ 312--Farnham 10
Resource-Oriented Towns
• Why are some resources “immobile”?
– Fish could be transported inland for canning, but
refrigerated transport is costly; easier to can fish
near docks.
– Logs can be transported on trucks, but this is
costly. Best to truck short distances to mills
located near forests.
• Log exporting has become more popular as transport
costs fall and trade opens up cheap foreign labour as
alternative to (relatively) expensive local labour
– Iron ore is very heavy relative to finished iron.
• Better to smelt the iron close to the mine, and then ship
the finished product.
Econ 312--Farnham 11
In Some Cases Resources are Best
Processed Near Final Market
• Sand is an important input into glass
– Should glass be manufactured near sand
pits, or near final consumer?
• Final consumer. Because glass is fragile and
benefits from minimizing transport distances.
– Should oil be turned into gasoline near oil
fields or near final consumer?
• Much refining happens near final consumer,
because gas is more volatile (and therefore
dangerous/expensive to transport) than oil.
Econ 312--Farnham 12
As Technology Changes, so may
Location Criteria
• Mills used to locate on streams so power
wheel could be turned by force of water.
– Rise of coal power lessened the need to locate on
a stream
– Also increased relative desirability of transporting
goods (including the input coal) by steamship (as
opposed to horse/cart and rail)
– Rise of coal-powered energy led firms to move
away from small streams, to large rivers, where
access to steamships (transport of inputs and
outputs) was cheaper.
– Key needed resource changed.
Econ 312--Farnham 13
Other Firm Location Criteria

• Local taxes
– Low property, income taxes may attract
businesses to certain locations.
• Local services
– Good roads, good schools (to attract educated
workers), etc. may attract firms.
• Note that these two are generally in
opposition (hard to have low taxes and great
services); however, general efficiency of
government may matter.
Econ 312--Farnham 14
Other Firm Location Criteria

• Proximity to consumers
– Most firms face major transportation cost in
shipping goods to consumer
– Selling through distributors lowers these costs (if
you buy a GM car, you buy it from a dealer, not
directly from a GM plant in Ontario)
– Note that we can show transportation costs on
with either the supply curve or the demand curve.
• i.e. We can think of transport costs as shifting up the
marginal cost curve; or we can think of it shifting down
the marginal willingness-to-pay curve.

Econ 312--Farnham 15

You might also like