0% found this document useful (0 votes)
40 views16 pages

Modern Money Theory: A Criticism From The Periphery Rodrigo Vergnhanini Bruno de Conti

This document provides a summary and criticism of Modern Money Theory (MMT) from the perspective of peripheral countries. It argues that while MMT correctly critiques some elements of mainstream economics, it fails to acknowledge the external constraints faced by peripheral countries with currencies that do not fulfill international money functions. Specifically, currencies from peripheral countries are illiquid internationally and demand depends on international liquidity preferences and market confidence, leading to higher and more volatile interest rates as well as exchange rate pressures from capital flows. As such, monetary, fiscal and exchange rate policies in peripheral countries face constraints not considered by MMT.

Uploaded by

leolaurindorj
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
40 views16 pages

Modern Money Theory: A Criticism From The Periphery Rodrigo Vergnhanini Bruno de Conti

This document provides a summary and criticism of Modern Money Theory (MMT) from the perspective of peripheral countries. It argues that while MMT correctly critiques some elements of mainstream economics, it fails to acknowledge the external constraints faced by peripheral countries with currencies that do not fulfill international money functions. Specifically, currencies from peripheral countries are illiquid internationally and demand depends on international liquidity preferences and market confidence, leading to higher and more volatile interest rates as well as exchange rate pressures from capital flows. As such, monetary, fiscal and exchange rate policies in peripheral countries face constraints not considered by MMT.

Uploaded by

leolaurindorj
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 16

Modern

Money Theory: a criticism from the periphery


Rodrigo Vergnhanini1
Bruno De Conti2

Abstract

This paper presents the recent debate on modern money theory (MMT) and
contributes to a critical view on its application to peripheral countries. MMT has been
centered on both demystifying postulates of the ‘New Macroeconomic Consensus’ and
offering an alternative theory to reach full employment with price stability. However, it has
been criticized for assuming that constraints on domestic policies are generally self-imposed,
not arising from international markets. Using the “international currency hierarchy” approach,
this paper argues that peripheral countries, in the context of financial globalization, are not
fully sovereign in determining its own macroeconomic policy. Our main argument is that
currencies issued by peripheral countries do not fulfill money classical functions at the
international level. Being hence illiquid at the international scenario, these peripheral
currencies (and assets) are demanded by the international investors only in the quest for high
returns; moreover, this demand depends on the “international liquidity preference” and the
markets’ confidence in this country. Consequently, interest rates in peripheral countries tend
to be higher and volatile. Additionally, the exchange rate is potentially under the pressure of
this capital flows movements. Finally, monetary, fiscal and exchange policies in peripheral
countries have constrains that are not considered by MMT.

Keywords: modern money theory, currency hierarchy, functional finance, policy constraints,
peripheral countries.

JEL Classification: E40, E63, F40.


1
PhD candidate at the Institute of Economics, University of Campinas, Brazil. E-mail address:
[email protected]
2
Professor at the Institute of Economics, University of Campinas, Brazil. E-mail address:
[email protected]
16
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

1. Introduction

The Modern Money Theory (MMT) approach has gained increasing visibility for
predicting the crisis of the European Monetary Union (EMU). Already in the 1990s, MMT
claimed that the EMU institutional design would lead to growth problems due to the absence
of fiscal branch. ‘It will be as if each EMU member country were to attempt to operate fiscal
policy in a foreign country; deficit spending will require borrowing in that foreign currency
according to the dictates of private markets’ (Wray 1998, p. 92). Although there is much
disagreement regarding the causes of EMU stagnation (even among heterodox economists),
MMT took advantage of its acknowledged economic forecasts to claim the victory of their
theoretical assumptions over mainstream economics (see Wray 2012).
On the one hand, MMT raises important questions to demystify some elements of the
so-called “New Macroeconomic Consensus” (NMC)3. For instance, it refutes the necessity of
causing recession and unemployment as the only efficient path in order to restore balanced
growth.
On the other hand, it has been criticized for assuming that countries are, in almost
every case, free from international markets to unrestrictedly expand government deficit and
set domestic macroeconomic policies so as to provide full employment. Any fear of deviating
from markets’ rules would be based on irrational fear and on misunderstandings on how
economy and public budget actually functions. Due to these claims, MMT has attracted
criticism from both the orthodox and the heterodox economics.
The purpose of this article is to develop a heterodox critique against MMT, from the
perspective of the “international currency hierarchy” framework. In essence, it argues that
countries do face external constraints over domestic policies and that the disciplinary power of
international markets is greatly asymmetric, being more severe in those countries that issue
the so-called peripheral currencies.
The article is divided in four sections, in addition to this introduction. Section two
introduces MMT’s theoretical underpinnings as well as its policy proposals, based on Wray’s
seminal work Understanding modern money (1998) and some recent articles. The third chapter
presents some general appraisals from heterodox economists; Thomas Palley’s works were
greatly considered, since they provide a wide compilation of MMT’s problems, from both
theoretical and practical standpoints. Section four adds a periphery perspective in order to
contradict MMTs main claim of ‘macroeconomic sovereignty’ as a generally applicable rule;
this section is aligned with the research scope on ‘international currency hierarchy’, that argue
that the International Monetary System asymmetries are quite important for the
understanding of economic dynamism and policy options in any country. Finally, some
conclusive remarks are raised.
2. Modern Money Theory: foundations and general criticism
The MMT seeks to demystify some common views regarding the functioning of the
economy and builds a theoretical framework to support its bold policy proposals. The present
section explores the MMT view on: i) the nature of government deficits; ii) the supply of

3
For details about the NMC, see Arestis and Sawyer (2008).
17
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

money; iii) the role of external sector; and iv) policy propositions. The main reference is Wray
(1998), but it also includes some recent developments of this theoretical approach.
According to the conventional view, government spending mainly relies on tax
revenues. Any deficit budget should be financed either through the issuing of non-interest
bearing debt by the Treasury (currency) or through the selling of interest-earning bonds. The
first alternative is commonly believed to cause inflation, since it directly expands the money
supply. Government borrowing, on the other hand, increases the demand for loanable funds,
possibly driving up interest rates and, at least partially, crowding out private borrowing. Over
the long run, this could lead to supply bottlenecks and cost-push inflation.
Most economists of different persuasion believe that government deficits may even be
desirable in specific situations. However, their persistent shape should be avoided because it
could lead to some deficit-to-GDP ratio in which market loses confidence in governments’
ability to retire its debt. In this sense, government deficit is supposed to rely on domestic
public expectations and its will to take up the debt. Eventually, the government would have to
impose austerity on its population with the aim of conquering (or reconquering) markets’
confidence in order to sell bonds internationally.
The MMT approach is based on Lerner’s concept of ‘functional finance’. It states that
rather than tax revenues or bond sales, government spending is financed through fiat money4.
The reasoning is considered as follows.
Firstly, the government issues fiat money and spends it by hiring services and buying
products from the public. The state money is widely accepted because it is the only unit of
account that officially meets tax liabilities. We see therefore the crucial influence of the
chartalist view proposed by Knapp (1924), according to which non-metallic money is accepted
due to the ability of the state to impose and collect taxes in this currency. That is why some
authors refer to the MMT as the “neo-chartalists”5 (e.g. Lavoie 2013, 2014).
From this perspective, taxes serve simply as a reserve clearing drain that is flowed back
to the government funds. Because taxes cannot be paid until state money is injected in the
economy, persistent government deficits derive from the normal functioning of the economy
and surpluses, on the opposite side, unleash strong deflationary forces.
As a result, according to MMT, government deficit spending is never subject to market
discipline as long as the bonds are issued in the domestic currency. Furthermore, ‘most of the
pressures that governments currently believe that arise from international markets are
actually self-imposed constraints coming from a misunderstanding of the nature of
government deficits’ (Wray, 1998, p. 75). Debt-limit rules, balanced budget requirements as
well as the setting of a sovereign currency system based on the conversion to gold or to
foreign currency are constraints that should be understood as ‘necessarily politically imposed’


4
Fiat Money is the one that has no inherent value neither any “real backing”. Its value is therefore
based only on trust. For details, see Knapp (1924) and Goodhart (1989).
5
According to Lavoie (2013, p.2), “[b]esides the obvious authors who have inspired modern chartalists,
Smith, Knapp and Keynes, it may be said that the originators of modern monetary theory are Warren
Mosler, Hyman Minsky, Abba Lerner and Wynne Godley, as their writings are often invoked by neo-
chartalists”.
18
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

(Wray, 2014b, p. 29).

This reasoning rests upon the idea that the government is sovereign to issue any
amount of state money and is completely capable of maintaining its value. According to the
famous sentence proposed by Lerner (1943, p. 313), “money is a creature of the state”. In
addition – as discussed above –, its acceptability could never be questioned because it is
enforced by the payment of tax liabilities.
Another important theoretical underpinning of MMT regards the supply of money.
Some economists have not abandoned the traditional monetarist belief that the central banks
set the amount of money and that this determines the rate of inflation6. According to this
view, the monetary authority provides reserves to the banking system and, through a ‘stable’
money multiplier, it expands the money base. In the textbooks, this has been called the
‘verticalist’ approach (money supply being completely inelastic to interest rates).

However, according to MMT – in line with Keynesianism –, the central bank has never
controlled the quantity of money or the amount of reserves. ‘In the real world banks make
loans not mattering the reserve positions, afterwards borrowing reserves to meet
requirements’ (Wray 1998, p. 107).
The decision to lend money depends on the price of reserves and the expected
returns. In other words, the bank lends money if it assumes that this operation is profitable,
regardless of the quantity of reserves. It plays an active role in determining the composition of
its assets and liabilities. Hence, the causation is the reverse of what is commonly stated: firstly,
the provision of loans meets the demand for finance; secondly, the bank buys reserves from
the central bank in order to meet the legal requirements. In this scheme, the central bank
plays a quite passive role, providing or draining the amount of reserves determined by the
banking operation.
MMT incorporates the ‘horizontalist’ approach, which means that: i) the central bank
determines the short-term interest rate directly (and the short-term retail lending indirectly, as
the wholesale rate is marked up); and ii) the supply of money is endogenous to finance
demand.
The assumptions on money supply, government finance and value of the currency
have important implications on the role of monetary and fiscal policies.
The orthodox view assumes that the monetary policy has discretionary control over
the reserves and the quantity of money. The MMT claims that ‘the orthodox view
fundamentally confuses fiscal policy with monetary policy; fiscal policy has more to do with the
quantity of money and with the value of it while monetary policy simply determines overnight
interest rates’ (Wray, 1998, p. 98). Monetary policy is defensive and dependent on the
Treasury operations. It includes those Treasury and central bank operations that drain reserves
or set the overnight interest rate target. Bond sales are destined to substitute non-interest
earning government fiat money for interest-earning government liabilities (and constitute an
interest rate maintenance account). Fiscal policy, on the other hand, is intended to determine
the quantity of state money available and, through taxation, maintain the value of the

6
For details, see Friedman (1953).
19
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

currency. As mentioned above, the goal of the fiscal policy is to operate based on the
functioning of the economy and not on what the traditional doctrine called ‘sound finance’.
The principle of functional finance, advocated by Abba Lerner (1943, p. 39), states that:

“(…) the first financial responsibility of the government (…) is to keep the total rate of
spending in the country on goods and services neither greater nor less than that rate which
at the current prices would buy all the goods that is possible to produce”.

Spending and taxes should therefore be balanced to accommodate full employment.


However, the operation of functional finance is not enough to guarantee that condition. How
could the government generate full employment and at the same time keep price stability?

The MMT recommends the government acting as an employer of last resort (ELR),
providing jobs at a basic public sector wage (BPSW). Any person who is able and willing to
work would be provided with a job in the ELR program. The BPSW would be set by the
government at a level that is lower than the minimum wage in the private market. As the
economy grows, some workers would be transferred from the ELR program to the private
market, receiving better salaries. On the other hand, in cycle downturn ELR could
accommodate workers dismissed by private firms. This way, the buffer stock program would
stabilize aggregate income and aggregate demand, diminishing regressive effects of recession
(Mitchell and Wray, 2005).

At the same time, since it constitutes an important element in the production cost of
every economic activity, the unskilled labor is supposed to be the best commodity for the
buffer stock program. The stabilization of the ELR wage would serve as reference to other
wages, costs and prices, thus contributing to overall price stability (see Mitchell, 1998). The
ELR would therefore allow the government deficit to vary countercyclically, filling the demand
gap and avoiding deflationary pressures.

Summing up, the MMT claims that the government has autonomy to increase deficit
spending by issuing money or selling bonds at any amount needed (as long as the bonds are
issued in the domestic currency). Because it could never default the payment of a debt that is
denominated in its own currency, the market would not doubt its payment capacity. Since the
government is free of any market constraints in its policy-making, it should implement a fine-
tuning between monetary and fiscal policies in order to reach and maintain full employment
with price stability.
Wray (1998, 2012) and Tcherneva (2006) assume that the external sector does not
constraint autonomous domestic policies as long as: i) the exchange regime is free from any
pegging rules; ii) the government is not indebted in a foreign currency. In this case, if the
exchange rate is free to float, then it would adjust to domestic policies without major
consequences7.

The MMT recognizes that if the country is forced to international indebtedness


because it is obliged to issue debt in a foreign currency or because it needs goods or services


7
Lavoie (2014, p. 343) states that this argument is “relatively uncontroversial”. Unlike, this paper will try
to demonstrate that it is quite controversial, notably for peripheral countries.
20
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

that are not available in exchange for the domestic currency, then it would be subjected to
constraints of international markets (Wray, 2014a).

“Sometimes governments believe that the ‘market’ forces them to issue foreign-currency-
denominated bonds. There is only one case in which this would be true - when the
government wishes to purchase goods and services that are not for sale in terms of the
domestic fiat money. (…) [in this case] it will have to obtain additional foreign currency in
the future to service the debt. In some situations, markets might fear that a government will
not be able to do this – which could lead to default – causing a rational run out of these
bonds. As a result, the government may be forced to impose austerity on its population to
maintain a trade surplus to obtain the needed foreign currency” (Wray 1998, p. 88).

However, this condition is considered by MMT to be punctual, not applying to the


general case:

“In this one case, the austerity can be at least partially blamed on ‘market discipline’.
However, it must be recognized that this is only because the government desired goods and
services that were not for sale in the domestic currency. In all other cases, the government
is not subject to ‘market discipline’, and any austerity and hardship is self-inflicted” (Wray,
1998, p. 88).

3. General criticisms

One may therefore notice that the MMT raises important debates. On the one hand, it
contradicts the conventional theory, notably on the assumption of the governments’ necessity
to always and accurately obey to the so-called “market discipline”. On the other hand, it raises
polemic arguments even for non-orthodox authors. That is why several criticisms are being
placed on the assumptions of MMT, stimulating rich debates. In this section, some of the most
important heterodox appraisals are considered.
The first disagreement is related to the origin of money. As discussed in the previous
section, MMT states that the value of money derives exclusively from public demand through
the imposition of taxes. Rochon and Vernengo (2003) and Palley (2015a, 2015b) criticize this
simplification. Although they agree that state money is Chartal, they assert that this must not
be seen as the core of the concept; money in the broader sense should be rather defined
according to the fulfilment of its three functions: store of value, exchange means and unit of
account (in accordance with Keynes’ writings)8.
Lavoie (2011)9, Palley (2015a, 2015b) and Cesaratto (2016) also question the
‘consolidation’ assumption between the monetary and the fiscal authorities, proposed by the
MMT. On that matter, Lavoie (2013) states that insisting in this “fictitious” assumption creates
room for misunderstanding. In his opinion, claiming, for instance, that taxes and securities do
not finance the expenditures of central governments is counter-productive because it has no
adherence to the reality – even in the USA.
From a theoretical perspective, Palley (2013) questions the lack of a rigorous

8
Four functions if we consider the finance function (Keynes, 1930).
9
In spite of some criticisms, Lavoie (2013, 2014) agrees with many of the statements of the MMT.
21
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

explanation for the functioning of both inflation and interest rates. According to Palley, MMT
implicitly assumes ‘L-shaped’ inflation curve and ignores the developments attained by the
Phillips curve (less unemployment tends to lead to inflationary pressures). In addition, it also
places no role to expectations in the process of price formation. Palley believes this configures
a regression in the understanding of the inflationary phenomenon.
It is worth noting that Keynes (1936, chapter 21), whose work served as important
inspiration for the MMT approach, argued that inflationary pressures may arise as a
consequence of economic growth even when the economy is below the level of full
employment10 – thus, denying the validity of an “L-shaped” inflation curve.
. Furthermore, Palley (2013) argues that a zero natural interest rate – as MMT
implicitly assumes – would lead to inflation and asset instability (in a Minskyan perspective).
Monetary policy, supposed to operate exclusively in a defensive manner in response to fiscal
policy measures, loses its purpose in fighting instability of domestic financial sectors. Tymoigne
and Wray (2014, p. 31) replied to that criticism by arguing that financial regulation should be
enough to counterbalance low interest rate and promote stability.
When open economies are regarded, MMT has recently emphasized the role of
flexible exchange rate as a stabilizing device in countries that need to obtain foreign currency.
According to the critics, differently from what MMT advocates, exchange rates should
not be free to float. Palley (2015b) reminds that a major reason why flexible exchange rates do
not insulate economies comes from structuralist macroeconomics literature, principally
associated with Latin America. In this perspective, exchange rate depreciation triggered by
money financed deficits can cause significant disruptive imported-inflation effects in both
developing and open-developed economies. Krugman and Taylor (1978) argued long ago that
exchange rate depreciation can also be contractionary, due to distributional effects on
aggregate spending. Although not referring to MMT, Flassbeck (2001) and, more recently, Rey
(2015) also proposed that a free exchange rate regime in emerging countries do not insulate
their economies – not allowing therefore an autonomous economic policy.

Moreover, Palley argues that the covered interest parity (CIP) is incompatible with
MMT. Its recommendation of setting domestic interest rate at zero would require, as to avoid
capital reflux, a process of continuous domestic currency appreciation, which, in term, would
lead to financial instability and real economic disruption (Palley 2015b, p. 55).
Cesaratto (2012a, 2012b, 2012c) agrees that there are important open economy
considerations neglected by MMT. For instance, the great majority of ‘real-world’ economies


10
Keynes presents five motives for that matter: “i) effective demand will not change in exact proportion
to the quantity of money; ii) since resources are not homogeneous, there will be diminishing, and not
constant, returns as employment gradually increases; iii) since resources are not interchangeable, some
commodities will reach a condition of inelastic supply whilst there are still unemployed resources
available for the production of other commodities; iv) the wage-unit will tend to rise, before full
employment has been reached; v) the remunerations of the factors entering into marginal cost will not
all change in the same proportion” (Keynes, 1936 [1964], chapter 21, p. 254).


22
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

need to obtain goods and services that are not for sale in the domestic currency. This means
that the necessity of obtaining foreign currency and maintaining the power parity of its
national currency in terms of foreign one is rather a general rule than an exception. Therefore,
in order to overcome the foreign constraint, governments may have either to adopt fixed
exchange rate regimes and attract foreign finance, or to limit their growth11 rate. Therefore,
austerity is not always self-imposed, as argued by MMT, but most of economies are, in fact,
subjected to some kind of ‘market discipline’.

According to Cesaratto, MMT focuses much on the ‘internal aspect’ of full money
sovereignty. However, full sovereignty depends also on the capacity of issuing an
internationally accepted currency. Cesaratto highlights that only the currencies of mercantilists
countries – that is, those with persistent current account surpluses – and the United States of
America may have unlimited acceptance. Non-mercantilist countries do need to implement
exchange rate management in order to obtain external equilibrium.
In response to these criticisms concerning the functioning of open economies, some
MMT exponents (e.g. Tymoigne and Wray, 2014) have advocated exchange rate pegging. This
acknowledgment however undermines MMT’s main claim about sovereign money freeing
governments from standard market disciplines and financial constraints (Palley 2015b, p. 55).
Pegging limits the freedom of monetary policy, requires foreign exchange reserves and is also
subjected to speculative attacks, which further constrain policy.
4. Critique from the periphery

This final section intends to show how some monetary specificities of peripheral
countries tend to determine even further restrictions on macroeconomic autonomy. From a
more general perspective, there may be other specificities in the periphery, apart from the
international monetary aspect, that cause diminished macroeconomic sovereignty. For
instance, domestic supply bottlenecks may become a difficulty for the country to
autonomously increase its aggregate demand without causing deficits in external trade12.
However, the present section intends to focus exclusively on the external constraints placed by
the status of peripheral currencies at the international monetary system (IMS).
First of all, it is important to notice that only a few national currencies are able to
satisfy the three basic functions of money also in the international scenario13. According to De
Conti et al. (2013, pp. 4-5), this ability is determined by international political economy
conditions, such as the issuer’s economic dimension and integration with the world economy,


11
On this matter, see the contributions of Thirlwall (1979), as well as the further developments of the
literature on external constrained growth models.
12
For details, see the works from the ECLAC (e.g. Bielschowsky, 2000).
13
A great reference for the studies concerning the different abilities of the national currencies to fulfil
their classical functions at the national and the international level, see Cohen (1998). Eichengreen et al.
(2005) discusses the inability of many countries to issue external debt in their own national currencies
(the authors name it “original sin”); although quite interesting, this proposal does not consider all
implications arising for a country from the fact that it issues a currency that does not fulfil
internationally any of the classical functions of money.
23
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

its geopolitical power and its will to internationalize its currency14.

The international monetary system is therefore configured by domestic currencies


with different abilities to fulfil their functions at the international level. The US dollar
represents currently the system’s key-currency. The second most important currency
regarding the international use is the euro. At a third level, we find the Japanese yen, the
Sterling pound, the Swiss franc, the Canadian dollar and the Australian dollar15. All of them
may be named ‘central currencies’, since they are also used at the international level. On the
other hand, there are the national currencies that cannot fulfill money’s classical functions in
the international scenario: the ‘peripheral currencies’. Since they are not money at the
international level, these currencies are demanded worldwide only as financial assets.

In order to understand the quality (or the characteristics) of the demand for these
currencies, it is hence useful to analyze the theory of portfolio choice. According to Keynes,
monetary economies are characterized by fundamental uncertainty and, in this context, the
liquidity preference figures as a good thermometer of agents’ expectations and confidence.
According to Keynes’ portfolio choice model (Keynes, 1936, chapter 17; Keynes, 1930), an
asset yields, altogether with quasi-rent (q), maintenance cost (c) and capital gains (a), a
liquidity premium (l)16. This justifies why agents allocate part of their wealth in liquid
applications – including money -, even if they provide lower – or none - monetary returns. The
attribute of liquidity depends on the asset capability to be converted into means of payments
with little monetary and temporal costs. Domestically, state money is normally the most
important means of payments17, so it is the liquid asset par excellence. All other assets must
therefore offer a monetary return that is enough to compensate their relative illiquidity
against money. In Keynes’ words, bonds yield interest rates in order to offer a premium for its
illiquidity.
Transferring this reasoning to the international level, it is important to notice that only
a few currencies are used as means of payments18. Therefore, only these currencies are ‘the
liquid assets par excellence’ at the international arena. All other currencies, that we name
‘peripheral currencies’, are not liquid at the international level, even if they are domestically

14
The determinants of the international usage of a currency are far from consensual. Resende and
Amado (2007) and Resende (2005) claim for instance that the current account performance
is the main cause of a country’s currency position in the International Monetary System.
15
Some authors may find it better to include also the New Zealand dollar and some other currencies.
Since this paper focuses on the peripheral currencies, these controversies concerning the list of the
“central currencies” do not cause any problem for the arguments. It is also important to notice that the
Chinese renmimbi is quickly increasing its usage at the international level; this issue goes however
beyond the scope of this paper (for details, see for instance Guttmann, 2016).
16
Andrade and Prates (2013) propose an interesting analysis of the exchange rate dynamics that uses
this Keynes (1936 [1964]) chapter 17’s equation.
17
In some countries, international currencies are used domestically as a mean of payments too, but it
configures an exception. For an analysis of the currencies that do not fulfil money classical functions
even in the domestic level, see Cohen (1998).
18
There are no precise data concerning the currencies used for the international trade, but Guttmann
and Plihon (2011) indicate that the US dollar’s share is between 40 and 45% and the euro’s share is
within the range of 15 and 20% of the total. De Conti and Prates (2016) show with data from the SWIFT
Watch that for the Customer initiated and institutional payments, US dollar (43%), Euro (30%) and
Sterling pound (9%) are responsible for 82% of the transactions (data for Nov. 2015).
24
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

the most liquid assets. Hence, these peripheral currencies (and the assets denominated in
these currencies) have to pay a premium for this ‘international illiquidity’ (De Conti, 2011). The
direct consequence is that bonds denominated in peripheral currencies have a priori higher
interest rates, since these rates have to satisfy global investors’ exigency to earn a premium for
the international illiquidity of these assets.
For that reason, the uncovered interest rate parity (UIP) theory is not sufficient to
explain the determination of the interest rate level. It states that domestic interest rate should
equal international interest rate plus the country risk premium and the expected exchange
rate variation. However, due to the above-mentioned monetary asymmetry, peripheral
countries must offer an additional premium in order to offset the currency international
illiquidity19.
The implicit return attributed to liquidity depends on agents’ liquidity preference.
Then, this dimension is not objective, but it is based on conventions, being therefore
susceptible to a great volatility. Consequently, peripheral countries are not able to freely
determine the short-term interest rate. First of all, the assets denominated in peripheral
currencies (including public bonds) have to pay a premium for their international illiquidity.
Secondly, since the ‘international liquidity preference’ (De Conti 2011, Guttmann 2016) may
change suddenly and intensively, peripheral currencies interest rate must reflect it, tending to
be highly volatile20.
In the context of financial globalization, national currencies are also financial assets
associated to the trade-off returns/risks, like commodities, bonds, securities etc. Taking again
into account the theory of portfolio choice, it is hence clear that ‘since peripheral currencies
are not as liquid as central ones (the same reasoning being valid for the assets denominated in
each of these currencies), international agents will demand them only in the quest of high
yields’ (De Conti et al. 2013, p. 6).
The world faces therefore an ‘international currency hierarchy’ with important
economic implications for the peripheral countries, but also for the international capital flows
dynamics. Since the basic interest rates of some currencies are extremely different,
international agents may execute profitable ‘carry trade’ operations. They may raise funds in
central currencies, creating liabilities at relatively lower costs, and buy assets denominated in
lower-ranked currencies, which offer higher returns. The operation of carry-trade makes
pressure over the depreciation of the funding currency and the appreciation of the target one.
As long as the expectations are sustained, there is over-appreciation of the target currencies.
From a Minskyan perspective21, the reversal of the cycle determines a sudden ‘flight from risk’


19
This premium for the illiquidity of the currency at the international level is different from the country
risk premium, since it does not concern domestic aspects, but rather the configuration of the IMS.
Carneiro (2008) shows also that the interest rate in peripheral countries tend to be higher than in
central ones due to the IMS hierarchy.
20
Brazilian economic history is full of moments when the interest rate had to suddenly increase due to
reasons that have no relation to the domestic economy. De Conti (2011) analyses data for countries that
issue central currencies and peripheral currencies, concluding that the interest rate volatility tends to be
higher in those that issue peripheral currencies.
21
See Minsky (1986).
25
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

and causes target currencies (usually the peripheral ones) to depreciate intensively. It is not
difficult though to notice the transmission mechanism arising from the speculative and
unstable character of liquidity cycles to the exchange rate movements in peripheral
countries22.
As mentioned above, from the international investor perspective, the portfolio
composition is defined considering the variety of assets with their specific risk-return
attributes. During the rise of the so-called ‘appetite for the risk’, there emerges a demand for
increasingly less liquid assets in the search for exceptional yields. However, in the moment of
reversion of the optimistic expectations, there is a sudden movement towards the most liquid
assets. Since this portfolio reconfiguration is not national, but international; and it is not
individual, but collective23, it determines international liquidity cycles24.
Such liquidity cycles have been object of intense investigation since the 2008 crisis,
even within mainstream economics. Rey (2015), for instance, provides evidences on the
functioning of international financial cycles. The author shows empirical correlation between
the VIX index – which is widely seen as a market proxy for risk aversion and uncertainty – and
international capital flows. She also finds that surges in gross flows are also accompanied by
increases in leverage and in risky asset prices.
Ahmed and Zlate (2014) indicate that inflows directed to emerging economies are
determined by global appetite for the risk, growth and interest rate differentials - assessing the
predominant role of external factors. Accordingly, Bruno and Shin (2014) estimate that “global
cost push” factors, such as VIX index and interest rate of central currencies, are more
important to explain international financial cycles than “local demand pull" factors. Before
them, within the Post-Keynesian tradition, Resende and Amado (2007) demonstrated through
an empirical analysis that the economic cycles of three Latin American countries (Brazil,
Argentina and Mexico) have been determined by the international financial system and not
only by their respective domestic financial system. These researches have given empirical
support to the theories of an “international currency hierarchy”25.

Within this tradition, Prates (2002) proposed the existence of three related
asymmetries that affect peripheral countries. Firstly, the financial asymmetry implies that
financial flows (inflows and outflows) in peripheral economies are usually important relatively
to each country’s financial market. Secondly, the monetary asymmetry determines that private
capital flows are directed to peripheral economies mainly as long as there is a reduction in
international liquidity preference and that assets allocated in peripheral countries are the first
to be sold in moments of risk aversion and/or huge losses in other markets. Third and finally,

22
On recent empirical evidences of this correlation, see Bruno and Shin (2014). For a theoretical
discussion, see De Conti et al. (2013).
23
Due to conventions or even to “herd behavior”.
24
Prates (2002) also highlight that the international liquidity preference is determined by reasons that
are external to the country where the assets are issued.
25
Using a heterodox framework, Biancarelli (2007) had also analysed the international liquidity cycles of
th st
the end of the XX and the beginning of the XXI centuries, showing the alternation of massive
movements of private capital flowing to or from peripheral countries. The author also shows that the
direction of these flows is determined by reasons that are beyond the economic outcomes and the
macroeconomic policies of peripheral countries.
26
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

macroeconomic asymmetry, which is a result of the last two, consists in the lack of autonomy
peripheral countries face to choose and implement national macroeconomic policies.
Concerning this last asymmetry, the necessity to set much higher interest rates as to
compensate the lower liquidity of their domestic currencies is the first evidence, but not the
only one, since the exchange rate policy is also under strict constraints.
As we have seen in the first section of this paper, MMT’s allegation is that these
constrains related to the level of the interest rates would actually be self-imposed, since the
eventuality of a capital flight would not be a problem in a free floating exchange rate regime.
The idea is that the exchange rate movements would automatically counteract these capital
flights. Then, what MMT says is that a country that simply allows its exchange rate to freely
float is able to autonomously choose the level of the interest rate. However, when we see the
specificities of the exchange rate in peripheral countries, we see that this is not a smooth
solution.
As a matter of fact, the free floating of exchange rate in peripheral countries leads to
cyclical crisis because private capitals follow a speculative, volatile logic that finally has a huge
impact over the volatility of exchange rates. Peripheral countries, thus, usually adopt some
kind of administrated exchange rates with the purpose of avoiding both sudden default
(caused by currencies mismatches of domestic agents) and inflationary pressures26. That
means that macroeconomic policy should also be concerned with exchange rate stability
objectives27.
Besides, international private capitals may impose strict market discipline over
government budget, requiring full commitment with decreasing government deficits. If the
government decides to abandon primary surpluses targets and increases its public deficits, the
market will perceive it as a lower commitment to debt retirement and expect some
depreciation trend over the exchange rate. Due to expectations, it may also imply higher long-
term interest rates. Not much is needed to cause the ‘flight to liquidity’ movement,
considering that financial investments in peripheral countries follow a speculative logic. Any
action that goes against ‘market discipline’ and the so-called ‘sound finance’ may lead to self-
fulfilling prophecy of currency depreciation. Hence, MMT’s proposal about the impossibility of
default of a State when it is indebted in its own currency should take into account that the
international demand for assets denominated in peripheral countries is so volatile that in the
end the governments in peripheral countries feel strongly constrained by the permanent
threat of a capital flight, inevitably incurring in a fiscal policy that is far from autonomous.

The macroeconomic autonomy is therefore more restricted in peripheral countries


than in those that issue central currencies28. As argued, due to the IMS configuration,
peripheral countries tend to have: i) higher interest rates in order to pay a premium for the

26
That is why even countries that officially declare a free floating exchange rate regime actually
intervene in the forex market (having therefore a de facto dirty flotation regime).
27
For details, see Carneiro (2008), De Conti (2011) and Prates (2015).
28
Paula et al. (2017) presents an interesting discussion about the challenges peripheral countries face in
order to implement economic policies in the age of financial globalization. According to them, peripheral
countries should pursuit current account balance, “in order to prevent capital flows boom-bust-cycles
with subsequent financial crises” (p. 17).
27
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

illiquidity of their currencies at the international level; ii) volatile interest rates, since they
reflect the ‘international liquid preference’ and it may suddenly change due to reasons that are
exogenous to the country that is being analyzed; and iii) volatile exchange rates, due to the
volatility of the capital that flows to peripheral countries29; iv) fiscal policy constraints arising
from the country’s insertion at the financial globalization (that is, the importance of the
foreign capital for their financial markets).
It is therefore clear that international currency hierarchy states different degrees of
freedom for the countries according to their position in the IMS.
Evidently, peripheral countries may face the above-mentioned trends. One important
strategy that is adopted in many of them is the accumulation of huge international reserves, in
order to increase the possibility of facing the reversion of the international liquidity cycles (and
convince markets about this possibility). The second possible tool is erecting an apparatus of
capital flow regulations that inhibit their speculative movements or reduce their effects over
the exchange rate. Anyway, the task is not easy and the important point is that peripheral
countries may not act as central ones, among other reasons, because their currency is not
accepted as so at the international level.
5. Final remarks

The paper discussed the MMT, presenting its important refusal of the common views
regarding the imprudence of public deficits. However, the paper also discussed some issues
that are not consensual about the theoretical model MMT uses to support its audacious policy
proposals. Moreover, there are also international political economy obstacles that would have
to be offset.
When open economies are considered, there are further difficulties placed by
international markets. A strong currency depreciation should be avoided if the country needs
to obtain goods and services that are not available in domestic currencies, if it has debts
denominated in the foreign currency, or if it wants to avoid inflationary pressures. Therefore,
the country may need to attract foreign capitals by offering a minimum level of interest-rate
(which, by the way, is exogenously set, by the international liquidity preference). Alternatively,
it may adopt a fixed exchange rate, or issue its debt in the international currency. In all cases,
domestic policy would have to follow other objectives than only full employment.
Furthermore, if there are several theoretical and political restrictions in applying the
MMT in central countries, the obstacles placed to peripheral countries are even greater. Due
to international monetary asymmetry, these countries are obliged to set their interest rate at a
higher level to compensate the relative illiquidity of their domestic currencies. Moreover,
‘sudden stops’ could result from exogenous changes in liquidity cycles. Exchange rates, as a
result, tend to be very volatile and should be subject to government administration.
In conclusion, this article proposes that in one hand MMT raises important questions
about NMC’s obsession for market friendly policies in central countries. Nevertheless, on the
other hand, the MMT claim that countries are all sovereign to operate with their domestic

29
In spite of this trend, some countries are successful in actively maintaining a stable exchange rate. The
most eloquent example is China.
28
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

currency – being capable of reaching full employment with price stability – is not observed in
most countries, notably the peripheral ones. We propose therefore that a frank dialogue
between authors that defend MMT and those who use a currency hierarchy framework may
be very fruitful for the development of both theories and – most important – for the
formulation of effective economic policies for peripheral countries.

References

Ahmed, S. and Zlate, A. (2014) “Capital flows to emerging market economies: a brave new
world?”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 48(Part B), p. 221-248.
Andrade, R. and Prates, D. (2013) “Exchange Rate Dynamics in a Peripheral Monetary
Economy”. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 35(3), p. 399-416.
Arestis, P. and Sawyer, M. (2008) “New consensus macroeconomics and inflation targeting :
Keynesian critique.” Economia E Sociedade, 17(special number), p. 629–653.
Biancarelli, A. (2007) Integração, ciclos e finanças domésticas: o Brasil na globalização
financeira. PhD Thesis, Institute of Economics, University of Campinas.
Bielschowsky, R. (2000) Cinquenta anos de pensamento na CEPAL. Rio de Janeiro:
Record/CEPAL.
Bruno, V. and Shin, H. (2014) “Cross-border banking and global liquidity”. BIS working paper, n.
458, Bank for International Settlements.
Carneiro, R. (2008), “Globalização e inconversibilidade monetária”. Revista de Economia
Política, 28(4), p. 539-556.
Cesaratto, S. (2012a) “A reply to Wray – part I”. Naked Keynesianism Blog. Available at
<http://nakedkeynesianism.blogspot.com.br/2012/08/a-reply-to-wray-part-i.html>.
Accessed on 15/07/2014.
Cesaratto, S. (2012b) “A reply to Wray – part II”. Naked Keynesianism Blog. Available at
<http://nakedkeynesianism.blogspot.com.br/2012/08/a-reply-to-wray-part-ii.html>.
Accessed on 15/07/2014.
Cesaratto, S. (2012c) “The spurious victory of MMT”. Naked Keynesianism Blog. Available at
<http://nakedkeynesianism.blogspot.com.br/2012/07/spurious-victory-of-mmt.html>.
Accessed on 15/07/2014.
Cesaratto, S. (2016) “The state spends first: Logic, facts, fictions, open questions”, Journal of
Post Keynesian Economics, 39(1), p. 44-71.
Cohen, B. (1998) The geography of money. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
De Conti, B. (2011) Políticas cambial e monetária: os dilemas enfrentados por países emissores
de moedas periféricas. Phd Thesis, University of Campinas and University of Paris 13.
De Conti, B. and Prates, D. (2016) “The International Monetary System hierarchy: determinants
and current configuration”. The 28th Annual EAEPE Conference, Manchester, UK.
De Conti, B., Prates, D. and Plihon, D. (2014) “A hierarquia monetária e suas implicações para
as taxas de câmbio e de juros e a política econômica dos países periféricos”. Economia
e Sociedade, 23(2), p. 341-372.

29
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

Eichengreen, B., Hausmann, R. and Panizza, U. (2005) “The Mystery of Original Sin”. In: B.
Eichengreen and R. Hausmann (eds.) Other People's Money. Chicago and London:
Chicago University Press.
Flassbeck, H. (2001) “The exchange rate: economic policy tool or market price?” Discussion
paper, n. 157, United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Geneva.
Friedman, M. (1953) “The case for flexible exchange rates”, In: M. Friedman (ed.) Essays in
Positive Economics, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 157-203.
Goodhart, C. (1989) Money, Information and Uncertainty. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Guttmann, R. (2016) Finance-Led Capitalism. New York: Palgrave Macmillan US.
Guttmann, R. and Plihon, D. (2011) "Whither the Euro? History and Crisis of Europe’s Single-
Currency Project", In: G. Epstein and H. Wolfson (eds.) Handbook of the political
economy of financial crises, New York: Oxford University Press, pp.357-377.
Keynes, J. (1930 [1970]) “Treatise on money, vol.2 – The Applied Theory of Money”, in The
Collected Writtings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. VI. London: MacMillan.
Keynes, J. (1936 [1964]) The general theory of employment, interest and money. London:
MacMillan. 14ed.
Knapp, G. (1924) The State Theory of Money. London: Macmillan & Company Limited.
Krugman, P. and Taylor, L. (1978), “Contractionary Effects of Devaluation,” Journal of
International Economics, 8(3), pp. 445–456.
Lavoie, M. (2013) “The monetary and fiscal nexus of neo-chartalism: a friendly critique”.
Journal of Economic Issues, 47(1), p. 1–32.
Lavoie, M. (2014) Post-Keynesian economics: new foundations. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar
Publishing.
Lerner, A. (1943) “Functional Finance and the Federal Debt”. Social Research, 10(1), p. 38–51.
Minsky, H. (1986) Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. London: McGraw-Hill Education.
Mitchell, W. (1998) “The Buffer Stock Employment Model and the NAIRU: The Path to Full
Employment”, Journal of Economic Issues, 32(2), p. 547–555.
Mitchell, W. and Wray, R. (2005) “In defense of employer of last resort: a response to Malcolm
Sawyer”, Journal of Economic Issues, 39(1), p. 235-244.
Palley, T. (2013) “Money, fiscal policy, and interest rates: a critique of modern monetary
theory”, Working Paper, n. 109, Institute for Macroeconomics, Dusseldorf, Germany.
Palley, T. (2015a) “Money, Fiscal Policy, and Interest Rates: a critique of modern monetary
theory”, Review of Political Economy, 27(1), p. 1-23.
Palley, T. (2015b) “The Critics of Modern Money Theory (MMT) are Right.’ Review of Political
Economy, 27(1), p.45–61.
Paula, L., Fritz, B. and Prates, D. (2017) “Keynes at the periphery: Currency hierarchy and
challenges for economic policy in emerging economies”, Journal of Post Keynesian
Economics, 40(2), p. 183-202.
Prates, D. (2002), Crises financeiras dos países “emergentes”: uma interpretação heterodoxa.
PhD Thesis, Institute of Economics, University of Campinas.

30
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

Prates, D. (2015) O regime de câmbio flutuante no Brasil 1999-2012: especificidades e dilemas.


Brasília: IPEA.
Resende, M. (2005) O padrão dos ciclos de crescimento da economia brasileira: 1947-
2003. Economia e sociedade, Campinas, 14(1-24), p.25-55.
Resende, M. and Amado, A. (2007) Liquidez internacional e ciclo reflexo: algumas observações
para a América Latina. Revista de Economia Política, 27(1), p.41-59.
Rey, H. (2015) “Dilemma Not Trilemma: The Global Financial Cycle and Monetary Policy
Independence” Working Paper, n. 21162, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Cambridge.
Rochon, L. and Vernengo, M. (2003) “State money and the real world: or Chartalism and its
discontents”, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 26(1), p. 57– 67.
Tcherneva, P. (2006) “Chartalism and the tax-driven approach”, in P. Arestis and M. Sawyer
(eds.), A Handbook of Alternative Monetary Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p.
69-86.
Thirlwall, A. (1979) "The balance of payments constraint as an explanation of the international
growth rate differences." BNL Quarterly Review, 32(128), p.45-53.
Tymoigne, E. and Wray, R. (2014) “Modern money theory: a reply to Palley”, Review of Political
Economy, 27(1), p. 24–44.
Wray, R. (1998) Understanding Modern Money: The Key to Full Employment and Price Stability,
Cheltenham, U.K: Edward Elgar.
Wray, R. (2007) “The Employer of Last Resort Programme: Could It Work for Developing
Countries?”, Economic and Labour Market Paper, no. 2007/5, International Labour
Office, Geneve, Switzerland.
Wray, R. (2012) “Paul McCulley – MMT Won: Declare Victory But Be Magnanimous About It”.
EconoMonitor, Randall Wray Blog. Available at
<http://www.economonitor.com/lrwray/2012/06/25/paul-mcculley-mmt-won-
declare-victory-but-be-magnanimous-about-it/>. Accessed on 24/03/2016.
Wray, R. (2014a) “MMT and external constraints”. EconoMonitor, Randall Wray Blog. Available
at <http://www.economonitor.com/lrwray/2014/02/24/mmt-and-external-
constraints/>. Accessed on 24/03/2016.
Wray, R. (2014b) “From the State Theory of Money to Modern Money Theory: An Alternative
to Economic Orthodoxy”, The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection,
n.792, p. 1–35.

31
nd
BRAZILIAN KEYNESIAN REVIEW, 3(2), p.16-31, 2 Semester/2017

You might also like