ContentServer PDF
ContentServer PDF
We thank Edward Conlon, Robert Vecchio, Robert House, and Robert Wood for their
helpful comments during the preparation of this article.
' By man we mean the nongender-specific refrence to human beings in general.
20
1997 Davis, Schoorman, and Donaldson 21
AGENCY THEORY
failing to deliver high performance for their principals (e.g., low ability,
lack of knowledge, and poor information). Agency theorists are not as
concerned with these failings as they are with those resulting from mo-
tivational problems.
The limits and boundaries of agency theory are determined by its
model of man. Where individualistic, self-serving executive motivation is
assumed, shareholders desirous of minimizing the risks associated with
perceived nonalignment of principal-agent utility functions should imple-
ment agency prescriptions. However, this model has its critics. Jensen and
Meckling (1994) criticized this model of man as being a simplification for
mathematical modeling and an unrealistic description of human behav-
ior. Doucouliagos (1994) argued that labeling all motivation as self-
serving does not explain the complexity of human action. Frank (1994)
suggested that this model of man does not suit the demands of a social
existence. Hirsch, Michaels, and Friedman (1987) said that in exchange for
simplicity and elegance in their models, economists engage in a some-
what broad-brush approach that may reduce empirical verisimilitude and
engender less than robust policies. In short, agency theory assumptions
limit its generalizability.
Agency theory provides a useful way of explaining relationships
where the parties' interests are at odds and can be brought more into
alignment through proper monitoring and a well-planned compensation
system. Additional theory is needed to explain other types of human be-
havior, and this is found in literature beyond the economic perspective. To
that end, stewardship theory will now be described.
STEWARDSHIP THEORY
the behaviors of the executive are aligned with the interests of the prin-
cipals.
Previously, stewardship theorists have focused on enabling struc-
tures for upper managers (Donaldson & Davis, 1989, 1991, 1994; Fox &
Hamilton, 1994). For example, Donaldson and Davis (1991) argued that, for
CEOs who are stewards, their pro-organizational actions are best facili-
tated when the corporate governance structures give them high authority
and discretion. Structurally, this situation is attained more readily if the
CEO chairs the board of directors. Such a structure would be viewed as
dysfunctional under the agency theory model of man. However, under the
stewardship model of man, stewards maximize their utility as they
achieve organizational rather than self-serving objectives. The CEO-chair
is unambiguously responsible for the fate of the corporation and has the
power to determine strategy without fear of countermand by an outside
chair of the board. Thus, stewardship theorists focus on structures that
facilitate and empower rather than those that monitor and control.
Given the advantage of stewardship to principals, why isn't there
always a steward relationship, rather than an agency relationship? The
answer lies in the risks that the principals are willing to assume. In the
governance contract between owners and executives, owners must decide
how much risk they are willing to assume with their wealth. Risk-averse
owners will most likely perceive that executives are self-serving and will
prefer agency governance prescriptions. Implementing stewardship gov-
ernance mechanisms for an agent would be analogous to turning the hen
house over to the fox. Agency prescriptions can be viewed as the neces-
sary costs of insuring principal utility against the risks of executive op-
portunism. From this perspective, a better question might be Why would
an owner ever take the risks of stewardship governance prescriptions?
Previously, empirical researchers have attempted to validate either
agency theory or stewardship theory as a "one best way" to corporate
governance, assuming that all managers are either stewards or agents.
The results of these studies have resulted in mixed findings; thus, there is
the need for both agency theory and stewardship theory explanations of
management (Donaldson & Davis, 1994). For example, several researchers
found that the agency prescription of independent board leadership (i.e.,
a nonexecutive board chair) is associated with higher firm performance
(e.g.. Berg & Smith, 1978; Daily & Dalton, 1994; Rechner & Dalton, 1991).
Other researchers found that stewardship's executive-chaired boards
have significantly higher corporate performance (e.g., Donaldson & Davis,
1989, 1991; Finkelstein & D'Aveni, 1994). Still others suggest there is no
significant difference in firm performance between executive- and out-
sider-chaired boards (e.g., Chaganti, Mahajan & Sharma, 1985; Molz,
1988). Empirical evidence is similarly mixed with respect to other gover-
nance dimensions (Donaldson & Davis, 1994). The mixed support for
agency and stewardship theories suggests a need to reconcile these
1997 Davis, Schoolman, and Donaldson 27
have a measurable "market" value. These extrinsic rewards form fhe ba-
sis for fhe reward sysfems that represent the control mechanisms of
agency theory. For example, a principal may create a piecework incentive
system to protect him- or herself from a self-serving agent. Similarly,
medical insurance, 401k savings, and retirement plans may be instituted
as a control mechanism to reduce the likelihood of furnover. Each of fhese
rewards has a quanfifiable value in ferms of dollars fhat is recognized by
both parties. In contrast, in stewardship theory, the focus is on intrinsic
rewards that are not easily quantified. These rewards include opportuni-
ties for growth, achievement, affiliation, and self-actualization. Subordi-
nates in a stewardship relationship are reinforced by these intrinsic,
intangible rewards and are motivated to work harder on behalf of fhe
organizafion. The bases for this distinction can be found in most of the
established theories of motivation, but they are particularly apparent in
the need theories. In a stewardship relationship, the focus would be on fhe
higher order needs of Maslow's hierarchy (1970), on Alderfer's growth need
(1972), and on the achievement and affiliation needs of McClelland (1975)
and McGregor (1966).
A related model of worker motivation, the job characteristics model,
was proposed by Hackman and Oldham (1975, 1976, 1980). These authors
argued that three psychological states (experienced meaningfulness of
work, experienced responsibility for outcomes, and knowledge of the ac-
tual results) mediate the relationship between task characteristics and
internal work motivation. In order to facilifate the attainment of fhese
psychological states, they advocated the redesign of jobs fo increase skill
variefy, task identity, task significance, aufonomy, and feedback. All of
fhese factors are relafed fo increasing fhe opporfunify for growfh and
responsibility for the worker. This model of work mofivafion is consisfent
with the assumptions of sfewardship fheory that increasing the internal
work motivation would lead to higher levels of performance as well as
satisfacfion wifh work. It is interesting to note that in their model Hack-
man and Oldham (1975, 1976, 1980) argued that the growth need strength
of the worker is a moderator of fhe effectiveness of fhis model, suggesfing
that there are some workers for whom fhe assumpfions of the stewardship
model may not fif.
In a more recenf approach to the study of infrinsic mofivafion, Manz
(1986, 1990) developed a theory of self-leadership. According to Manz,
"self-leadership is a comprehensive self-influence perspective that con-
cerns leading oneself fowards performance of naturally motivating tasks
as well as managing to do work that must be done but is not naturally
motivating" (1990: 589). Self-efficacy, self-determination, and feelings of
purpose are characferized as being crifical deferminants of infrinsic mo-
fivation. He argued that self-leadership involves a belief in one's work
that extends beyond the formal reward sysfem and relates to the impor-
tance of shared organizational vision. These views are consistent with the
motivational assumptions of sfewardship theory.
1997 Davis, Schooiman. and Donaldson 29
Use of Power
Situational Factors
Management Philosophy
In the early debates between Argyris and the advocates of the eco-
nomic model of man, one of the critical points of contention was whether
organizational theory should be focused on descriptive or normative mod-
els of the organization. Simon (1957a,b; 1973) and others (e.g., Cyert &
March, 1963) argued that the economic model, and therefore implicitly the
agency theory assumptions, were the predominant basis of relationships
in organizations. They cited numerous examples of behavior by both prin-
cipals and agents to support this claim. In contrast, Argyris (1973a,b) ar-
gued that the management philosophy of most organizations was based
on economic assumptions and that this became a self-fulfilling prophecy
regarding the nature of relationships that would develop. He advocated
the development of normative models of organization based on self-
actualizing assumptions in order to create an organizational culture that
supported the development of stewardship types of relationships. The
position advocated by Argyris (1973) was similar to the arguments ad-
vanced earlier by McGregor (1960) in his discussion of Theory Y manage-
ment and by Likert (1961) in his comparison of System 4 management with
more control-oriented systems. The common message in each of these
theories is that the assumption about the model of man drives the devel-
opment of management philosophies and management systems, which
then serve to produce behavior in the organization that is consistent with
the assumptions. Each of these theorists advocated the development of
normative models of organization and a break from the traditional man-
agement philosophies in order to facilitate the self-actualizing behaviors
that are consistent with stewardship theory.
More recently, Walton (1980, 1985) advocted what he called a high-
commiímení management philosophy. This approach to management
was characterized as being highly participative and consisting of open
communication, empowerment of workers, and the establishment of
trust. Lawler (1986, 1992) elaborated on this view by contrasting the man-
agement philosophies he described as confroi orienfed versus invoJve-
menf orienfed. According to Lawler, the control-oriented approach is
based on a management philosphy that the thinking and controlling
part of the work must be separated from the doing part of the work.
In contrast, involvement-oriented approaches emphasize self-control
and self-management and do not create a separation among thinking,
controlling, and doing the work. The key assumption in involvement-
oriented approaches is that when employees are given challenges and
1997 Davis, Schooiman, and Donaldson 33
early age, and relationships are not related to status or role. Formal re-
spect and deference are seldom shown. This pattern of differences is
also observed in organizational life. In high power distance cultures, or-
ganizations are centralized, and they include large differences in author-
ity, salary, and privileges between those at the top and those at the bot-
tom. In low power distance cultures, organizations are decentralized,
there is more consultation in decision making, and the differences in
salary and perquisites are minimized. Similar to the discussion of the
individualism-collectivism dimension, Hofstede (1980, 1991) and others
(e.g., Triandis, 1995) have argued that although the national culture cre-
ates a predisposition to either high or low power distance, there can be
considerable variance in power distance across organizations and indi-
viduals in the same country.
High power distance cultures are conducive to the development of
agency relationships, because they support and legitimize the inherent
inequality between prinicpal and agent. This idea is especially true in the
context of work, because the development of hierarchies, of layers of su-
pervision (as control mechanisms), and of inequalities in rewards and
status may lead the agents to "ideologically reject the boss's authority
completely, while in practice they will comply" (Hofstede, 1991: 35). This
characterization by Hofstede is similar to the predictions regarding the
self-serving agent described in agency theory. Low power distance cul-
tures are more conducive to the development of stewardship relation-
ships, because their members place greater value on the essential equal-
ity of the principal and the manager. This orientation encourages the
development of relationships between principals and managers that are
an essential part of stewardship theory.
Proposition 8; Peopie in a iowpower distance culture are
more likely to develop principal-steward relationships
than are people who are in a high power distance cul-
ture
Although the individualism-collectivism and power distance dimen-
sions are not perfectly correlated, there appears to be a pattern of rela-
tionships that make the predictions regarding the cultural antecedents of
stewardship theory somewhat complicated. For example, the United
States is generally regarded as an individualistic culture with low power
distance. Individualism would suggest a predisposition to agency theory,
whereas low power distance would predict more stewardship theory out-
comes. Simiarly, Japan is a high power distance, collectivist culture, lead-
ing to similarly conflicting predictions. The apparent contradictions in
predictions suggested by these variables may provide a valuable expla-
nation for the process by which agency and stewardship relationships
develop. For example, we might expect that members of a collectivist
culture would move very quickly to establish an organizational structure
that is conducive to the development of stewardship relationships (e.g..
1997 Davis, Schoolman, and Donaldson 37
flat decentralized, and team based), but they would have difficulty de-
veloping the truly participative, challenging style of trusting interper-
sonal relationships because of high power distance. This is a common
characterization of Japanese attempts to develop high-involvement man-
agement philosophies. In contrast, in the United States, we might expect
to encounter great resistance to the restructuring of organizations into
flatter, more decentralized, team-based units, but once this restructuring
is accomplished, we would expect the members to function well as a
high-involvement team.
The conflict that is suggested by the cultural dimensions is not lim-
ited to culture. It is certainly conceivable that some of the psychological
mechanisms may suggest one theory, whereas other mechanisms may
suggest the alternate. We might also expect the possibility of a mismatch
between the management philosophy and the psychological characteris-
tics of the managers. Although the specific interactions of these anteced-
ents in the prediction of stewardship versus agency relationships is very
intriguing, we believe it is beyond the scope of this article. The further
development of this model in terms of the more specific predictions would
be a logical next step regarding the empirical testing of the main effects
specificed in this model.
The disucssion so far has focused on the core issues underlying
agency and stewardship theories. A summary of the primary differences
between the two theories is shown in Table 1. The primary difference lies
TABLE 1
Comparison of Agency Theory and Stewardship Theory
Agency Theory Stewardship Theory
Model of Man Economic man Self-actualizing man
Behavior Self-serving Collective serving
Psychological Mechanisms
Motivation Lower order/economic Higher order needs (growth,
needs (physiological, achievement,
security, economic) self-actualization)
Extrinsic Intrinsic
Social Comparison Other managers Principal
Identification Low value commitment High value commitment
Power Institutional (legitimate, Personal (expert, referent)
coercive, reward)
Situational Mechanisms
Management Philosophy Conrol oriented Involvement oriented
Risk orientation Control mechanisms Trust
Time frame Short term Long Term
Objective Cost control Performance Enhancement
Cultural Differences Individualism Collectivism
High power distance Low power distance
?)
38 Academy of Management Review January
nGURE'l
Principal-Manager Choice Model
Principal's Choice
Agent Steward
1 2
Manager's
Choice
3 4
gains utility from fulfilling the purposes and objectives of the organiza-
tion. Likewise, the principal chooses to create a stewardship situation that
is involvement oriented and empowering. The mutual gains resulting
from this state of fit are high.
The dilemma occurs because there is the possibility of a different
choice by each party. If the principal chooses an agency relationship and
the manager chooses a steward relationship, the result is likely to be a
very frustrated manager who feels betrayed by the principal. When stew-
ards are controlled as if they were agents, they cannot enjoy the types of
internal rewards they desire (i.e., growth, achievement, or self-
actualization), and as a reult, they may engage an antiorganizational
behaviors (Argryis, 1964). The application of control may create disenfran-
chised employees, because principals, rather than those persons actually
doing the work, assume the responsibility of deciding and orchestrating
firm procedures. Managers in controlling, less trusting climates may not
have the opportunity to behave as stewards and therefore may experience
decreased feelings of self-worth, self-responsibility, and self-control
(Argryis, 1964) and have less desire to behave as stewards. In this
situation, the workplace becomes depersonalized, and the manager may
begin to view him- or herself as an interchangeable unit. In such envi-
ronments, employees may resort to antagonistic adaptive activities such
40 Academy ot Management Review January
CONCLUSIONS
Alderfer, C. P. 1972. Existence, relatedness. and growth: Human needs in organizational set-
tings. New York: Free Press.
Argryis, C. 1964. integrating the individual and the organization. New York: Wiley.
Argryis, C. 1973a. Organization man: Rational and self-actualizing. Public Administration
Review. 33 (July/August): 354-357.
Argryis, C. 1973b. Some limits of rational man organizational theory. Public Administration
fleview, 33 (May/June): 253-267.
Atkinson, J. W. 1957. Motivational determinants of risk-taking behavior. Psychological Re-
view. 64: 359-372.
Bass, B. M. 1960. Leadership, psychology, and organizational behavior. New York: Harper.
Berg, S. V., & Smith, S. K. 1978. CEO and board chairman: A quantitative study of dual vs.
unitary board leadership. Directors & Boards, 3(l):34-39.
Berle, A., & Means, G. 1932. The modern corporation and private property. New York: Mac-
millan.
Brown, M. E. 1969. Identification and some conditions of organizational involvement. Admin-
istrative Science Quarterly, 14: 346-355.
Chaganti, R. S., Mahajan, V., & Sharma, S. 1985. Corporate board size, composition and
corporate failures in retailing industry. Journal oí Management Studies. 22: 400-417.
Chiles T. H., & McMackin, J. F. 1996. Integrating variable risk preferences, trust, and trans-
action cost eocnomics. Academy oí Management Review. 21: 73-99.
Cosier, R. A., & Dalton, D. R. 1983. Equity theory and time: A reformulation. Academy oí
Management Review. 8: 311-319.
Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. 1963. A behavioral theory ol the ¡irm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Pren-
tice Hall.
Daily, C. M., & Dalton, D. R. 1994. Bankruptcy and corporate governance: The impact of board
composition and structure. Academy oí Management Journal. 37: 1603-1617.
D'Aveni, R. A., & MacMillan, I. C. 1990. Crisis and the content of managerial communications:
A study of the focus of attention of top managers in surviving and failing firms. Admin-
istrative Science Quarterly, 35: 634-657.
Demsetz, H., & Lehn, K. 1985. The structure of corporate ownership: Theory and consequencs.
Journal of Political Economics. 93: 11-55.
Donaldson, L. 1990. The ethereal hand: Organizational economics and management theory.
Academy oí Management Review. 15:369-381.
Donaldson, L., & Davis, J. H. 1989. CEO governance and shareholder returns; Agency theory
or stewardship theory. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Academy of Man-
agement, Washington, DC.
Donaldson, L., & Davis, J. H. 1991. Stewardship theory or agency theory: CEO governance and
shareholder returns. Australian Journal oí Management. 16: 49-64.
Donaldson, L., & Davis, J. H. 1994. Boards and company performance—Research challenges
the conventional wisdom. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 2: 151-160.
Doucouliagos, C. 1994. A note on the volution of homo economicus. Journal o/ Economics
issues, 3: 877-^83.
Finkelstein, S., & D'Aveni, R. A. 1994. CEO duality as a double-edged sword: How boards of
directors balance entrenchment avoidance and unity of comand. Academy ol Manage-
ment Journal. 37: 1079-1108.
1997 Davis, Schooiman, and Donaldson 45
Fleishman, E. A., & Harris, E. F. 1962. Patterns of leadership behavior related to employee
grievances and turnover. Personnel Psychology, 15: 43-56.
Fox, M. A., & Hamilton, R. T. 1994. Ownership and diversification: Agency theory or steward-
ship theory. Journal ol Management Studies, 31:69-81.
Frank, R. H. 1994. Microeconomics and behavior. New York: McGraw-Hill.
French, J. R. P., & Raven, B. 1959. The bases of social power. In D. Cartwright (Ed.), Síudies in
social power: 150-167. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Institute for Social Research.
Gibson, J. L., Ivancevich, J. M., & Donnelly, J. H. 1991. Organizations. Homewood, IL: Irwin.
Hackman J. R., & Oldham, G. R. 1975. Development of the job diagnostic survery. Journal ol
Applied Psychology, 60: 159-170.
Hackman, J. R., & Oldham, G. R. 1976. Motivation through the design of work: Test of a theory.
Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 15: 250-279.
Hackman, J. R., & Oldham, G. R. 1980. Work redesign. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Herzberg, F., Mausner, B., & Snyderman, B. B. 1959. The motivation to work. New York: Wiley.
Hirsch, P., Michaels, S., & Friedman, R. 1987. "Dirty hands" versus "clean models." Theory and
Society, 16: 317-336.
Hodgetts, R. M., & Luthaus, F. 1993. U.S. multinationals' compensation strategies for local
management: Cross-cultural implications. Compensation and Benelits Review, 25:42-48.
Hofstede, G. 1980. Cuifure's consequences: /nternafiona/ dillerences in worJ-reJaied values.
Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.
Hofstede, G. 1991. Cultures and organizations: Soltware ol the mind. London: McGraw-Hill.
Hofstede, G. 1993. Cultural constraints in management theories. Academy ol Management
Executive, 7(1): 81-90.
Hosmer, L. T. 1995. Trust: The connecting link between organizational theory and philosoph-
ical ethics. Academy ol Management Review, 20: 379-403.
James, L. R., Demaree, R. G., Mulaik, S. A., & Ladd, R. T. 1992. Validity generalization in the
context of situational models. Journal ol Applied Psychology, 77: 3-14.
Jensen, M. C, & Meckling, W. H. 1994. The nature of man. Journal ol Applied Corporate
Finance, 7(2): 4-19.
Jensen, M. C, & Meckling, W. H. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs
and ownership structure. Journal ol Financial Economics, 3: 305-360.
Katz, D., & Kahn, R. L. 1978. The social psychology ot organizations (2nd ed.). New York: Wiley.
Kelman, H. C. 1958. Compliance, identification, and intemalization: Three processes of atti-
tude change. Journal ol Conflict Resolution, 2: 51-60.
Kelman, H. C. 1961. Processes of opinion change. Public Opinion Quarterly, 25: 57-78.
Lawler, E. E. 1986. High involvement managmeent. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Lawler, E. E. 1992. The ultimate advantage. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Liden, R. C, Wayne, S. J., & Dean, S. (1993). A longitudinal study on the early development of
leader-member exchange. Journal ol Appliced Pschology, 78: 662-674.
Likert, R. 1961. New patterns ol management. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Mael, F., & Ashforth, B. E. 1992. Alumni and their alma mater: A partial test of the reformu-
lated model of organizational identification. Journal ol Organizational Behavior, 13:
103-123.
46 Academy oí Management Review January
Steers, R. M., & Black, J. S. 1994. Organizaíionaí Behavior. New York: HarperCollins.
Steers, R. M., & Porter, L. W. 1991. Motivation & work behavior. (5th ed.). New York: McGraw-
Hill.
Sussman, M., & Vecchio, R. P. 1982. A social influence interpretation of worker motivation.
Academy of Management Review, 7: 177-186.
Triandis, H. C. 1990. Cross-cultural studies of individualism and collectivism. In J. J. Berman
(Ed.), Nebraska symposium on motivation, vol. 37: 41—134. Lincoln: University of Nebraska
Press.
Triandis, H. C. 1995. ¡ndividualism and collectivism. Boulder, CO: Westview.
Triandis, H. C , Dunnette, M., & Hough, I. M. (Eds.). 1993. Cross-cultural studies. Handboot of
industrial and organizational psychology. Vol. 4. Palo Alto, CA: Consulting Psycholo-
gists.
Turner, J. C. 1981. The experimental social psychology of intergroup behavior. In J. C. Turner
& H. Giles (Eds.), Intergroup behavior: 66-101. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Walsh, J. P., Seward, J. K. 1990. On the efficiency of internal and external corporate control
mechanisms. Journal of Management Review, 15: 421-458.
Walton, R. E. 1980. Establishing and maintaining high-commitment work systems. In J. R.
Kimberly, R. H. Miles, & Associates (Eds.), The organizational life cycle: Issues in the
creation, transformation, and decline of organizations: 208-290. San Francisco: Jossey-
Bass.
Walton, R. E. 1985. From control to commitment in the workplace. Harvard Business Review,
63(2): 76-84.
Williamson, O. E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism: Firms, markets, relational
contracting. New York: Free Press.