The Parity Conditions: World Economy - Interest Rate Parity 1
The Parity Conditions: World Economy - Interest Rate Parity 1
Interest parity conditions are no-arbitrage profit conditions for capital. The easiest way to
understand this condition is consider how a typical investor can save in different locations.
Suppose the home currency is a dollar, and the foreign currency is a euro. Then, assuming a
forward market exists, the investor can either save at home, receiving interest rate i, or
converting by the exchange rate S, receiving interest rate i* abroad, and then converting back to
home currency by the forward rate F obtaining at time t for a trade at time t+1.
Ft ,t +1
(1 + i ) versus (1 + it* ) ×
St
If the gross return on the left greater than that on the right, then investors will place their capital
in the home country; if it is less, then investors will place their capital abroad. With infinite
amounts of capital moving in search of the highest return (and in this example, there is no risk in
Ft ,t +1
(1 + i ) = (1 + it* ) × (1)
St
After manipulation,
(i − i * ) Ft ,t +1 − S t
= (2)
(1 + it* ) St
This condition is called “covered interest rate parity”, reflecting the fact that investors are
If the forward rate is equal to the future spot rate (see “forward premium”), such that
1
World Economy - Interest Rate Parity 2
(entry written for the Princeton Encyclopedia of the World Economy)
© Menzie Chinn, 2007.
(i − i * ) S t ,t +1 − S t
e
= (3)
(1 + it* ) St
Where the e superscript denotes “expected”. Equation (3) is termed “uncovered interest rate
parity”. This expression holds when investors do not require compensation for the uncertainty
associated with trading currencies in the future. It states that expected nominal returns are
When interest rates are low, the following log approximations are often used for
Frankel (1991) has labeled condition (2) holding as characterizing perfect capital mobility, while
condition (3) is associated with perfect capital substitutability. These terms arise from the view
that if (2) does not hold, there must be some sort of impediment – capital controls or the threat
thereof – to the free flow of financial capital. But even if capital is free to move, investors may
still respond to risk; that response to risk might drive a wedge between the expected spot and
forward rate. When investors are risk-neutral in nominal terms, then investors will treat capital
The above conditions pertain to financial capital. In order to consider the mobility of
physical capital, one has to bring into play the prices of commodities. Integration of goods
markets are often defined as relative purchasing power parity holding. Ex ante relative PPP can
be written as:
2
World Economy - Interest Rate Parity 3
(entry written for the Princeton Encyclopedia of the World Economy)
© Menzie Chinn, 2007.
Where p is the log price level. Equation 4 states that expected depreciation equals the expected
inflation differential. Combining (4) with the uncovered interest rate parity condition (3’) leads
This says the expected rate of return on capital, expressed in physical units, is equalized across
borders. To the extent that in neoclassical models the marginal product of capital equals the real
interest rate, this condition is equivalent to the equalization of marginal products of capital
For developed economies since the dismantling of capital controls, covered interest parity holds
fairly well. It should be noted that most tests are conducted using offshore rates, in which case
(2) is sometimes termed “closed interest parity”, although covered interest parity is often used as
Early tests were conducted by Frenkel and Levich (1975). They found that, after
accounting for transactions costs, covered interest parity held for 3 month horizons. Offshore
rates sometimes diverge from onshore rates, so that the findings of covered interest parity are
somewhat weaker.
The question of whether covered interest parity holds for longer horizons is an open one.
Popper (1993) concludes that covered interest differentials at long maturities are not appreciably
greater than those for short (up to one year) maturities. This is a surprising result given that there
are likely a number of regulatory impediments that would tend to introduce frictions into the
arbitrage process. Data from long-date currency swaps confirm this finding.
3
World Economy - Interest Rate Parity 4
(entry written for the Princeton Encyclopedia of the World Economy)
© Menzie Chinn, 2007.
Prior to the dismantling of capital controls, and in many emerging markets today, covered
interest parity is unlikely to hold. In other words, covered interest differentials could be
interpreted as political risk, associated with the possibility of governmental authorities placing
restrictions on deposits located in different jurisdictions (clearly this is something that is not
relevant when all the deposits are offshore). Aliber (1973) is credited with this interpretation,
while Dooley and Isard (1980) provided empirical estimates for the DM/dollar rate.
expected exchange rate changes are unobservable. In the literature, most tests of UIP are actually
joint tests of UIP and the rational expectations hypothesis, i.e., that ex post realizations of the
exchange rate are a unbiased measure of the ex ante exchange rate, viz., s te,t +1 = E ( st +1 | I t ) . This
assumption combined with equation (2’) yields this standard regression equation (sometimes
s t +1 − s = β 0 + β 1 ( f t ,t +1 − st ) + υ t +1 (6)
Where under the joint null hypothesis υ t +1 is a mean zero error unpredictable using past
information, and β 1 = 1 .
The evidence in favor of this joint hypothesis of UIP and rational expectations is quite
weak. The regression of the ex post change of the spot exchange rate on either the forward
discount (in equation 6), or the interest differential (in equation 7) typically yields a slope
4
World Economy - Interest Rate Parity 5
(entry written for the Princeton Encyclopedia of the World Economy)
© Menzie Chinn, 2007.
coefficient estimate that is not only different from unity, but in fact negative and different from
zero at conventional levels of statistical significance. This is true for reserve currencies (the U.S.
dollar, the yen, the Swiss franc, the deutschemark, the franc, or their successor currency, the
euro) at horizons up to a year. It is also true for some emerging market currencies (see Frankel
and Poonawala, 2006). One interesting characteristic of these regressions is that, although the
coefficients are typically different from zero in a statistical sense, the proportion of total
variation explained is typically very small; it is not rare to obtain negative adjusted R-squared’s.
At longer horizons, (3, 5, 10 years) the evidence is more supportive of the combined UIP-
rational expectations hypothesis. Chinn and Meredith (2004) document that estimates of the β 1
coefficient are usually not significantly different from the posited value of unity at 5 and 10 year
horizons. The panel regression coefficient at different horizons in these regressions is depicted in
Figure 1.
1.2
/
0.8 Unbiasedness
0.67 0.68
coefficient value
0.4
0.09
0.0
-0.4
-0.54
-0.8 -0.76 -0.76
5
World Economy - Interest Rate Parity 6
(entry written for the Princeton Encyclopedia of the World Economy)
© Menzie Chinn, 2007.
The finding that the joint hypothesis of uncovered interest parity and rational
expectations holds better at long horizons than at short appears to be robust. Nonetheless, some
caution is necessary here. Consider regressions involving ten year interest differentials; by 2003,
there would only be three non-overlapping observations available per currency. Interestingly,
Chaboud et al. (2005) find that UIP also holds at extremely short horizons of a few minutes.
Other interesting results pertain to periods of extreme market turmoil. Flood and Rose
(2002), following their 1996 work, find that uncovered interest parity holds better in recent times
when the sample encompasses successful attacks on currency pegs. Nonetheless, the still find
expectations hypothesis. Froot and Frankel (1989) rely upon survey-based measures of exchange
rates to calculate expected depreciation. They find that for reserve currencies (against the U.S.
dollar) it is much more difficult to reject the null hypothesis that β 1 = 1 . Using a broader set of
currencies over a different sample period, Frankel and Chinn (1993) find that while the estimates
of the slope coefficient are always greater than zero, the null of a unit coefficient is rejected in
one instance. Hence, for a wider set of currencies – including some emerging market currencies
– the uncovered interest parity hypothesis does seem to carry less weight.
A new area of research involves investigation of whether uncovered interest parity holds
for emerging markets. Bansal and Dahlquist (2000) found that there was a basic asymmetry in
whether UIP holds. In particular, they find that when the U.S. interest rate is lower than foreign
country rates, UIP holds, while UIP fails to hold when the U.S. rate is higher. They also find that
idiosyncratic factors, such as the GDP per capita of the foreign country, are important in
6
World Economy - Interest Rate Parity 7
(entry written for the Princeton Encyclopedia of the World Economy)
© Menzie Chinn, 2007.
Using the forward discount in the stead of interest differentials, Frankel and Poonawala
(2006) find that there is substantial heterogeneity in the results. What matters importantly is the
exchange rate regime; highly managed exchange rate regimes are associated with currencies that
If uncovered interest parity does not seem to hold at short horizons, it seems unlikely that real
interest parity, described as exact equalization of real interest rates, would hold. However, one
could still test the weaker condition that movements in real rates in one country would be met by
The key difficulty with testing this condition, like that of uncovered interest parity, is that
market expectations are not directly observable. Hence, one can conduct only joint tests for real
interest parity. In Fujii and Chinn (2001), ex post realizations of inflation, and ex ante measures
computed using recursive time series models, are used to calculate real interest rates. They find
that there real interest parity holds with different strength at different horizons. As in numerous
previous studies (Cumby and Obstfeld, 1984; Mark, 1985), the real interest parity (RIP)
hypothesis is decisively rejected with short horizon data. At five to ten-year horizons, however,
the empirical evidence becomes far more supportive and in some cases the RIP hypothesis is not
rejected. In general, RIP, up to a constant, holds better at long horizons than at short. These
In recent years, several countries have begun issuing inflation-indexed debt securities.
Hence, one can obtain “real” real interest rates for a select number of countries, including the
U.S., the U.K., Canada and France. A cursory investigation reveals that there is no evidence of
7
World Economy - Interest Rate Parity 8
(entry written for the Princeton Encyclopedia of the World Economy)
© Menzie Chinn, 2007.
equalization. Moreover, while there is some covariation, it is not anywhere near one for one.
However, the thinness of the markets and the differences in the maturities of the relevant debt
References
Aliber, R.Z., 1973, “The Interest Parity Theorem: A Reinterpretation,” Journal of Political
Economy 81: 1451-1459.
Bansal, R. and M. Dahlquist, 2000, ‘The forward premium puzzle: different tales from developed
and emerging economies,’ Journal of International Economics, Volume 51: 115-144.
Chaboud, A.P. and J. H. Wright, 2005, “Uncovered Interest Parity: It Works, But Not For Long,”
Journal of International Economics 66(2): Pages 349-362.
Chinn, Menzie D., 2006, “The (Partial) Rehabilitation of Interest Rate Parity: Longer Horizons,
Alternative Expectations and Emerging Markets,” Journal of International Money and
Finance 25(1) (February): 7-21.
Chinn, Menzie D. and Guy Meredith, 2004, “Monetary Policy and Long Horizon Uncovered
Interest Parity,” IMF Staff Papers 51(3) (November): 409-430.
Cumby, Robert E. and M. Obstfeld (1984) “International Interest Rate and Price Level Linkages
under Flexible Exchange Rates: A Review of Recent Evidence,” in J. F. O. Bilson and
R. C. Marston (editors) Exchange rate Theory and Practice (University of Chicago
Press, Chicago, IL).
Dooley, M.P. and P. Isard, 1980, “Capital controls, political risk, and deviations from interest-
rate parity,” Journal of Political Economy 88(2): 370-84.
Flood, R.P. and A.K. Rose, 1996, “Fixes: Of the Forward Discount Puzzle,” Review of
Economics and Statistics: 748-752.
8
World Economy - Interest Rate Parity 9
(entry written for the Princeton Encyclopedia of the World Economy)
© Menzie Chinn, 2007.
Flood, R.B. and A. K. Rose, 2002, “Uncovered Interest Parity in Crisis,” International Monetary
Fund Staff Papers 49: 252-66.
Frankel, Jeffrey and Jumana Poonawala, 2006, “The Forward Market in Emerging Currencies:
Less Biased Than in Major Currencies,” NBER Working Paper No. 12496 (August).
Frenkel, J.A., and R.M. Levich, 1975, “Covered Interest Parity: Unexploited Profits?” Journal of
Political Economy 83(2): 325-338.
Froot, K.A. and J.A. Frankel, 1989,"Forward Discount Bias: Is It an Exchange Risk Premium?"
Quarterly Journal of Economics 104(1) (February): 139-161.
Fujii, Eiji and Menzie D. Chinn, 2001, “Fin de Siècle Real Interest Parity,” Journal of
International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 11(3/4): 289-308.
Popper, H., 1993, “Long-Term Covered Interest Parity—Evidence From Currency Swaps,”
Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 12, No. 4, pp. 439-48.