Corbett A 2004
Corbett A 2004
Copyright 2004 by
Baylor University
Self-Serving or Self-
E T&P Actualizing? Models of
Man and Agency Costs
in Different Types of
Family Firms: A
Commentary on
“Comparing the Agency
Costs of Family and
Non-family Firms:
Conceptual Issues and
Exploratory Evidence”
Guido Corbetta
Carlo Salvato
I n their article “Comparing the agency costs of family and non-family firms: Con-
ceptual issues and exploratory evidence,” Chrisman, Chua, & Litz (2004) develop a con-
ceptualization and empirical investigation of the effects of agency relationships in family
firms. Their main purpose is to understand whether, and to what extent, family firms have
higher total agency costs than non-family firms. The authors develop a conceptual frame-
work, which is of particular value to researchers of family businesses, outlining four
conditions that determine the relative level of agency costs in family and non-family
firms. These are (1) asymmetric altruism; (2) separation of ownership and management;
(3) conflict of interests between owners and lenders; and (4) conflict of interests between
dominant and minority shareholders. Although the framework is not directly tested by
the authors, it is, in itself, a valuable addition to the literature and research thrust of the
Please send correspondence to: Guido Corbetta at [email protected] and Carlo Salvato at
[email protected].
Empirical research so far has shown compelling evidence of agency relationships and
costs within family firms. However, results are at least partially contrasting (Gomez-
Mejia, Nuñez-Nickel, & Gutierrez, 2001; Schulze, Lubatkin, & Dino, 2003; Chrisman
et al., 2004). Reasons for these mixed empirical results may rest in family firm char-
acteristics. Family firms are often depicted as relying on mutual trust, intra-familial
altruism in its purest sense (i.e., unselfish concern and devotion to others without expected
return to oneself), and clan-based collegiality. Models of man (Simon, 1957) in which
organizational behaviors are rooted may differ between family and non-family firms,
among different family firm types, and among family firms active in different countries.
Hence, some of the assumptions on which agency theory is based may not hold in family
firms.
Agency theory rests on human assumptions of self-interest and present value maxi-
mization. In contrast, it is generally accepted that wealth creation is not necessarily the
only or even the primary goal of all family businesses (Davis & Tagiuri, 1989; Sharma,
Chrisman, & Chua, 1997). As Chrisman et al. (2004) explicitly acknowledge, it is gen-
erally accepted that family firms have both economic and non-economic goals.
What is the favored model of man in family firms, then? Psychological and situa-
tional factors that differentiate between agency and stewardship theories define two dif-
ferent models of man. According to agency theory, organizational human behavior is
rooted in economic rationality (Simon, 1997). The model of man underlying agency
theory is that of the self-serving individual, a rational actor who seeks to maximize his
or her individual utility (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). Instead, the model of man underly-
ing stewardship theory “is based on a steward whose behavior is ordered such that
pro-organizational, collectivistic behaviors have higher utility than individualistic, self-
serving behaviors” (Davis et al., 1997, p. 24). This model is essentially that of the “self-
The different model of man behind organizational behavior, at least in some types of
family firms, suggests that stewardship theory may be a potentially suitable vantage point
to address family business dynamics. In contrast to agency theory, stewardship theory
defines situations in which managers and employees are not motivated by individual
goals, but rather behave as stewards whose motives are aligned with the objectives of
the organization, such as sales growth, profitability, innovation, international expansion,
and company reputation (Davis et al., 1997). The steward’s pro-organizational behavior,
aimed at maximizing organizational performance, will in turn benefit the steward’s
principals.
Despite its potential, stewardship theory has not been extensively adopted in family-
business studies. Chrisman et al. (2004) admit that stewardship relationships may exist,
or even prevail, at least in some family firms. However, their analysis—coherently
anchored to the agency framework—does not develop this alternative any further. Yet,
the low coefficient of determination yielded by their test (Adjusted R2 is only .081) indi-
cates modest predictive power for their regression model. There may therefore be an a
priori risk of specification error through omitted variables bias in agency models applied
to family firms. In other words, agency theory alone offers a significantly, but only par-
tially, appropriate explanation of family firm performance.
One of the main arguments suggested in this commentary is that the impact of family
structure and dynamics on the family firm is mediated by the “model of man,” provided
it is widely shared. As a matter of fact, the owning family has a strong influence on vir-
tually all psychological and situational antecedents of organizational behavior. Hence, the
owning family has a crucial impact in shaping the “model of man” prevailing within the
organization as either the self-serving, economically rational man postulated by agency
theory, or the self-actualizing, collective serving man suggested by stewardship theory.
An analysis of the family business literature suggests that the family exerts an impact
on the prevailing “model of man” through the role played by family goals, degree of
altruism, degree of trust, emotions and sentiments, and their influence on relational con-
tracts (Figure 1).
Family firms are arenas characterized by financial and non-financial family goals
(Tagiuri & Davis, 1996). When financial goals prevail in a family, family members’ moti-
vation to operate in the family firm will be based on lower order needs and extrinsic
Family-related psychological and situational factors affecting the favored model of man
Prevalence of Prevalence of
agency relationship stewardship behavior
factors, thus favoring the emergence of agency relationships. On the contrary, when non-
financial goals prevail, this will foster motivation based on higher-order needs and intrin-
sic factors, thus favoring steward-principal relationships.
A second family dynamic influencing organizational behavior within the family firm
is the degree of altruism. Relationships in family firms are embedded in the parent-child
relationship found in the household, which is characterized by altruism. Altruism affects
organizational behavior in several ways. However, the assumption of altruism in the stew-
ardship framework is that of unselfish concern and devotion to others without expected
return (unlike the notion of altruism adopted by economic theory and borrowed by agency
scholars; e.g., Schulze et al., 2003). As such, this notion of altruism makes each employed
family agent a de facto owner of the firm, acting in the belief that they have a residual
claim on the family estate. This mechanism closely recalls the concept of psychological
ownership, whose primary effect is a strong sense of identification and high value com-
mitment towards the firm (Pierce, Kostova, & Dirks, 2001). Moreover, a high degree of
altruism influences individual conduct in family firms and helps strengthen family bonds,
thereby tempering the exercise of authority based on institutional power and high power
distance, both conducive to agency problems.
Some of the results emerging from Chrisman et al.’s (2004) article may be biased by
the peculiarities of investigated companies. Firms in their sample are fairly small, very
young, and characterized by an unusually high growth rate. Most of them are probably
start-ups or first-generation family firms, still heavily dependent on their founder(s). Not
surprisingly, and without considering non-response, 79% of the companies in their sample
are family firms, according to the adopted definition.
However, family firms are not a homogeneous group of organizations. A recent,
empirically validated classification identifies three organizational types (Salvato, 2002)
based on variables such as ownership, the presence of shareholders and managers exter-
nal to the family, active involvement of family members, and number of generations
involved. The three resulting family firm types are (1) the founder-centered family firm;
(2) the sibling or cousin consortium, which is still fully owned and managed by the
family(ies); and (3) the open family firm, in which both ownership and control are par-
tially shared with non-family shareholders and professional managers. These firms differ
in the role the founder and/or owner families play in the life of the company. Moreover,
they differ in terms of their entrepreneurial orientation and its determinants. Hence, as
Chrisman et al. (2004) suggest in the discussion and caveats section, we can conjecture
that agency costs are different in each of the three firm types.
When, for example, ownership is concentrated in one individual (as in the case
of founder-based family firms), issues of asymmetric altruism (ALT) may simply not
exist. In contrast, when ownership is divided among several family members (as in a
sibling/cousin consortium), the hypothesis that ALT is higher in family firms may actu-
ally hold true.
Agency costs arising from separation of ownership and management (OM) depend
on the extent of owner-management, too. Whenever the company is managed by a
sole owner, as most founder-based family firms, OM may be non-existing. In contrast,
managerial control by individuals owning a minority of shares (as in many sibling/cousin
consortia), or even no shares at all (as in many open family firms) may raise OM to the
level of non-family firms. Moreover, there may be curvilinear effects between agency
costs and CEO stock ownership, as suggested by Morck, Shleifer, & Vishny (1988).
The family firm’s life cycle may also have an impact on agency costs arising from
the conflict of interest between owners and lenders (OL), depending on the debt/equity
ratio prevailing in each stage of a family firm’s life.
Finally, when ownership is concentrated in one or few related families, costs arising
from the conflict of interests between dominant and minority shareholders (DM) are likely
to be comparatively low, if not null. In contrast, if the family firm is participated by finan-
cial institutions such as venture capitalists or other shareholders external to the family,
REFERENCES
Argyris, C. (1973). Organization man: Rational and self-actualizing. Public Administration Review,
33(July/August), 354–357.
Chrisman, J.J., Chua, J.H., & Litz, R.A. (2004). Comparing the agency costs of family and non-family firms:
Conceptual issues and exploratory evidence. Entrepreneurship Theory & Practice, 28(4).
Chua, J.H., Chrisman, J.J., & Steier, L.P. (2003). Extending the theoretical horizons of family business
research. Entrepreneurship Theory & Practice, 27(4), 331–338.
Davis, J.A. & Tagiuri, R. (1989). The influence of life-stage on father-son work relationships in family com-
panies. Family Business Review, 2(1), 47–74.
Davis, J.H., Schoorman, F.D., & Donaldson, L. (1997). Toward a stewardship theory of management.
Academy of Management Review, 22(1), 20–47.
Eisenhardt, K.M. (1989). Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management Review, 14(1),
57–74.
Gomez-Mejia, L.R., Nuñez-Nickel, M., & Gutierrez, I. (2001). The role of family ties in agency contracts.
Academy of Management Journal, 44(1), 81–95.
Greenwood, R. (2003). Commentary on: “Toward a theory of agency and altruism in family firms.” Journal
of Business Venturing, 18(4), 491–494.
Handler, W.C. & Kram, K.E. (1988). Succession in family firms: The problem of resistance. Family Busi-
ness Review, 1, 361–381.
James, H.S., Jr. (1999a). What can the family contribute to business? Examining contractual relationships.
Family Business Review, 12(1), 61–71.
James, H.S., Jr. (1999b). Owner as manager, extended horizons and the family firm. International Journal
of the Economics of Business, 6(1), 41–56.
Jensen, M.C. & Meckling, W.H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and owner-
ship structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305–360.
Jones, G.R. (1983). Transaction costs, property rights, and organizational culture: An exchange perspective.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 28, 454–467.
Morck, R., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1988). Management ownership and market valuation: An empirical
analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 20, 293–316.
Pollak, R.A. (1985). A transaction cost approach to families and households. Journal of Economic Litera-
ture, 23(2), 581–608.
Salvato, C. (2002). Antecedents of entrepreneurship in three types of family firms. Jönköping International
Business School, Research Report 1/2002.
Schulze, W.S., Lubatkin, M.H., & Dino, R.N. (2003). Toward a theory of agency and altruism in family
firms. Journal of Business Venturing, 18(4), 473–490.
Sharma, P., Chrisman, J.J., & Chua, J.H. (1997). Strategic management of the family business: Past research
and future challenges. Family Business Review, 10(1), 1–35.
Simon, H.A. (1997). Administrative behavior, 4th ed. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.
Steier, L. (2003). Variants of agency contracts in family-financed ventures as a continuum of familial altru-
istic and market rationalities. Journal of Business Venturing, 18(5), 597–618.
Tagiuri, R. & Davis, J.A. (1996). Bivalent attributes of the family firm. Family Business Review, 9(2),
199–208.
Carlo Salvato is a professor at the Università Cattaneo—LIUC, in the Entrepreneurship Research and
Development Center.
We appreciate the insightful comments we received from Lloyd Steier, two anonymous reviewers, and par-
ticipants in the Second Annual Conference on Theories of Family Firms at Wharton Business School, which
significantly improved our commentary.