The Propaganda Model
The Propaganda Model
101–112
EDWARD S. HERMAN
University of Pennsylvania, USA
ABSTRACT This article describes the “propaganda model” of media behavior and performance,
initially set down in the book Manufacturing Consent, and addresses some of the scholarly
criticisms leveled against the model since its inception a decade ago. Drawing on contemporary
examples of media reporting, the article argues for the continuing, if not increasing, relevance
of the propaganda model in explaining current media behavior.
In Manufacturing Consent: the political and contend that the media behave
economy of the mass media, Noam fairly and responsibly.1 The exclusion
Chomsky and I put forward a of the propaganda model perspective is
“propaganda model” as a framework noteworthy for one reason, because
for analysing and understanding how that perspective is consistent with long-
the mainstream US media work and standing and widely held elite views
why they perform as they do (Herman that “the masses are notoriously short-
and Chomsky, 1988). We had long sighted” (Bailey, 1948, p. 13) and are
been impressed by the regularity with “often poor judges of their own inter-
which the media operate on the basis ests” (Lasswell, 1933, p. 527), so that
of a set of ideological premises, de- “our statesmen must deceive them”
pend heavily and uncritically on elite (Bailey, 1948, p. 13); and they “can be
information sources and participate in managed only by a specialized class
propaganda campaigns helpful to elite whose personal interests reach beyond
interests. In trying to explain why media the locality” (Walter Lippmann, 1921, p.
perform in this way we looked to struc- 310). In Lippmann’s view, the “manu-
tural factors as the only possible root of facture of consent” by an elite class
the systematic patterns of media be- had already become “a self-conscious
havior and performance. art and a regular organ of popular
Because the propaganda model government” by the 1920s (Lippman,
challenges basic premises and sug- 1921, p. 248).
gests that the media serve antidemo- Clearly, the manufacture of consent
cratic ends, it is commonly excluded by a “specialized class” that can over-
from mainstream debates on media ride the short-sighted perspectives of
bias. Such debates typically include the masses must entail media control
conservatives, who criticize the media by that class. Political scientist Thomas
for excessive liberalism and an adver- Ferguson contends that the major me-
sarial stance toward government and dia, “controlled by large pro t-maximiz-
business, and centrists and liberals, ing investors do not encourage the
who deny the charge of adversarialism dissemination of news and analyses
ISSN 1461-670X Print; 1469-9699 Online/00/010101-12 Ó 2000 Taylor & Francis Ltd
102 EDWARD S. HERMAN
that are likely to lead to popular indig- and they are funded largely by adver-
nation and, perhaps, government ac- tisers who are also pro t-seeking enti-
tion hostile to the interests of all large ties, and who want their
investors, themselves included” (Fer- advertisements to appear in a support-
guson, 1995, p. 400). Political scientist ive selling environment. The media
Ben Page provides evidence that there also lean heavily on government and
are common “elite-mass gaps”, with major business rms as information
“ordinary citizens … considerably less sources and both ef ciency and politi-
enthusiastic than foreign policy elites cal considerations and, frequently,
about the use of force abroad, about overlapping interests, cause a certain
economic or (especially) military aid or degree of solidarity to prevail among
arms sales, and about free-trade the government, major media and other
agreements. The average American is corporate businesses. Government
much more concerned than foreign pol- and large non-media business rms
icy elites about jobs and income at are also best positioned (and
home” (Page, 1996, p. 118). Page suf ciently wealthy) to be able to press-
notes that “the problem for public delib- ure the media with threats of with-
eration is most severe when of cials of drawal of advertising or TV licenses,
both parties and most mainstream me- libel suits and other direct and indirect
dia take positions that are similar to modes of attack. The media are also
each other and opposed to the public” constrained by the dominant ideology,
(Page, 1996, p. 119). The propaganda which heavily featured anti-commu-
model explains the “elite-mass gaps”, nism before and during the Cold War
as well as elite and mainstream media era, and was often mobilized to induce
hostility to this mode of analysis: re- the media to support (or refrain from
fusal to allow it entry into the debate is criticizing) US attacks on small states
understandable given that the gaps are that were labeled communist.
embarrassing and suggest that the me- These factors are linked together,
dia do serve narrow elite interests. re ecting the multi-leveled capability of
This article brie y describes the government and powerful business
propaganda model, addresses some of entities and collectives (e.g. the Busi-
the criticisms that have been leveled ness Roundtable; the US Chamber of
against it and discusses how the model Commerce; the vast number of well-
holds up a decade or so after its publi- heeled industry lobbies and front
cation.2 Examples are provided to illus- groups) to exert power over the ow of
trate the ways in which the propaganda information. We noted that the ve fac-
model helps explain the nature of me- tors involved—ownership, advertising,
dia coverage of important political top- sourcing, ak and anti-communist
ics at the turn of the century. ideology—work as “ lters” through
which information must pass, and that
individually and often in cumulative
The Propaganda Model fashion they greatly in uence media
choices. We stressed that the lters
What is the propaganda model and work mainly by the independent action
how does it work? Its crucial structural of many individuals and organizations;
factors derive from the fact that the and these frequently, but not always,
dominant media are rmly embedded have a common view of issues as well
in the market system. They are pro t- as similar interests. In short, the propa-
seeking businesses, owned by very ganda model describes a decentralized
wealthy people (or other companies); and non-conspiratorial market system
THE PROPAGANDA MODEL 103
ironically, to make their case. Commu- ready used it in a 1981 book, Corpo-
nications professor Robert Entman, for rate Control, Corporate Power, and that
example, stated that we damaged our I was mainly responsible for the chap-
case by alleging that media coverage ter in Manufacturing Consent that pre-
of the 1973 Paris accord on Vietnam sented the propaganda model. Of
“was consciously ‘designed by the loyal course, whether traceable to Chom-
media to serve the needs of state skian linguistics or industrial organiza-
power’ … which comes close to en- tion theory, the substantive issues are:
dorsing a conspiracy theory, which the are the assumptions plausible? does
authors explicitly disavow early on” the model work? But showing a poss-
(Entman, 1990, p. 126). The word ible esoteric origin is a form of putdown
“consciously” was Entman’s, and he that suggests remoteness from and
neglected numerous statements about lack of touch with real media people.
the media’s treatment of the Paris ac-
cord that did not t his effort to bring us Failure to Touch Base with
“close to” a conspiracy theory. To say
that we “disavow” a conspiracy theory
Reporters
is also misleading: we went to great
Romano did in fact follow up with the
pains to show that our view is closer to
admonition that we had failed to ask
a free market model; we argued that
reporters why they did what they did.
the media comprise numerous inde-
He implied, without offering any evi-
pendent entities that operate on the
dence, that the journalistic bias we crit-
basis of common outlooks, incentives
icized might have been revealed as for
and pressures from the market,
good cause, if we had only asked for
government and internal organizational
an explanation. However, apart from
forces.
the fact that we did speak with quite a
The propaganda model explains me-
few reporters, the criticism is inane. Are
dia behavior and performance in struc-
reporters even aware of the deeper
tural terms, and intent is an
sources of bias they may internalize?
unmeasurable red herring. All we know
will they not tend to rationalize their
is that the media and journalists often
behavior? More important, if we nd,
mislead in tandem—some no doubt in-
for example, that in reporting on the
ternalize a propaganda line as true,
Nicaraguan and Salvadoran elections
some may know it is false, but the point
of 1984, they asked different questions
is unknowable and unimportant.
in the two elections in exact accord
with the propaganda line of the US
government, would asking journalists
Chomskian Linguistics what went on in their minds serve any
useful purpose? This line of criticism,
Some of the criticisms of the propa-
like the insistence on inquiry into re-
ganda model have been laughable.
porter–proprietor intentions, is a diver-
Carlin Romano, in his review in Tikkun,
sionary ploy that essentially denies the
located the weakness of the model in
legitimacy of a quantitative (or sci-
Chomskian linguistic theories that al-
enti c) analysis of media performance.
legedly view everything as rooted in
deep structures (Romano, 1989). He
was unaware that the rooting of corpo- Failure to Take Account of Media
rate behavior and performance in struc- Professionalism and Objectivity
ture is the core of modern industrial
organization analysis, that I had al- A more sophisticated version of the last
106 EDWARD S. HERMAN
exceeded that which the propaganda the negative reactions of the serious
model might have anticipated.5 left-of-center media analysts such as
Philip Schlesinger, James Curran, Pe-
ter Golding, Graham Murdock and
Failure to Explain Continued John Eldridge, as well as that of Daniel
Opposition and Resistance Hallin. Of these critics, only
Both Hallin and historian Walter LaFe- Schlesinger both summarizes the ele-
ber in a review in the New York Times ments of our model and discusses our
(LaFeber, 1988) pointed to the contin- evidence. He acknowledges that the
ued opposition to Reagan’s Central case studies make telling points, but in
America policy as somehow incompat- the end he nds ours “a highly deter-
ible with the model. These critics failed ministic vision of how the media oper-
to comprehend that the propaganda ate coupled with a straightforward
model is about how the media work, functionalist conception of ideology”
not how effective they are. Even the (Schlesinger, 1989, p. 297). Speci -
sophisticated and sympathetic Philip cally, he claims that we failed to explain
Schlesinger calls ours an “effects” the weights to be given our ve lters;
model, that “assumes that dominant we did not allow for external in uences,
agendas are reproduced in public opin- nor did we offer a “thoroughgoing
ion”, but he immediately quotes our analysis of the ways in which economic
statement that the “system is not all dynamics operate to structure both the
powerful… Government and the elite range and form of press presentations”
domination of the media have not suc- (quoting Graham Murdock); and al-
ceeded in overcoming the Vietnam though we put forward “a powerful ef-
syndrome” (Schlesinger, 1989, p. 301). fects model” we admit that the system
Nowhere does he cite us saying any- is not all powerful, which calls into
thing like his summary of our alleged question our determinism.
views on effects. We also stated ex- The criticism of the propaganda
plicitly with regard to Central America model for being deterministic ignores
that the elite was suf ciently divided several important considerations. Any
over tactics to allow space and con- model involves deterministic elements,
siderable debate. We did stress, how- so that this criticism is a straw person
ever, that the parameters of debate did unless the critics also show that the
not extend to fundamental challenges system is not logically consistent, oper-
to the US intervention (Herman and ates on false premises, or that the pre-
Chomsky, 1988, pp. xii–xiii). dictive power of the determining
By the logic of this form of criticism of variables is poor. The critics often ac-
the propaganda model, the fact that knowledge that the case studies we
many Soviet citizens did not swallow present are powerful, but they do not
the lines put forward by Pravda demon- show where the alleged determinism
strates that Pravda was not serving a leads to error nor do they offer or point
state propaganda function. to alternative models that would do a
better job.6
The propaganda model deals with
The Propaganda Model is too extraordinarily complex sets of events,
Mechanical and Functionalist and and only claims to offer a broad frame-
Ignores the Existence of Space, work of analysis, a rst approximation,
Contestation and Interaction that requires modi cation depending
on local and special factors, and that
This set of criticisms is at the heart of may be entirely inapplicable in some
108 EDWARD S. HERMAN
cases; but if it offers insight in numer- and Murdock, 1991, p. 19). The Gold-
ous important cases that have large ing–Murdock claim that the propa-
effects and cumulative ideological ganda model focuses on “strategic
force, it is arguably serviceable unless interventions” is a surprising misread-
a better model is provided. Usually the ing, as the model’s lters are built-in
critics stick to generalities and offer no and operate mainly through the inter-
critical detail or alternative model; when nalized recognition and enforcement of
they do provide alternatives, the results constraints and choices based on the
are not impressive.7 structure of power. Strategic interven-
The criticism of the propaganda tions certainly occur, but are of dis-
model for functionalism is also dubious, tinctly secondary importance.
and the critics sometimes seem to call It is also untrue that the propaganda
for more functionalism. The model model implies no constraints on media
does describe a system in which the owners and managers; we recognized
media serve the elite, but by complex and spelled out the circumstances un-
processes incorporated into the model der which the media will be relatively
that involve mechanisms and policies open—mainly, when there are elite dis-
whereby the powerful protect their in- agreements and when other groups in
terests naturally and without overt con- society are interested in, informed
spiracy. This would seem one of the about and organized to ght about is-
model’s merits; it shows a dynamic and sues. The propaganda model does
self-protecting system in operation. start from the premise that a critical
The same corporate community that political economy will put front and cen-
in uences the media through its power ter the analysis of the locus of media
as owner, dominant funder (advertis- control and the mechanisms by which
ing) and major news source also un- the powerful are able to dominate
derwrites the efforts of Accuracy in the ow of messages and limit the
Media and the American Enterprise In- space of contesting parties. The limits
stitute to in uence the media through on their power are certainly important,
harassment and the provision of right- but why should these get rst place,
thinking experts. Critics of propaganda except as a means of minimizing the
model functionalism such as Eldridge power of the dominant interests,
and Schlesinger contradictorily point to in ating the elements of contestation,
the merit of analyses that focus on and pretending that the marginalized
“how sources organize media strate- have more strength than they really
gies” to achieve their ends.8 Apparently possess?
it is admirable to analyze corporate mi-
cro strategies to in uence the media,
but to focus on global corporate efforts Enhanced Relevance of the
to in uence the media is illegitimate Propaganda Model
functionalism.
Golding and Murdock criticize the The dramatic changes in the economy,
model for its focus on “strategic inter- the communications industries and
ventions”, that allegedly cause us to politics over the past dozen years have
“overlook the contradictions in the sys- tended on balance to enhance the ap-
tem. Owners, advertisers and key pol- plicability of the propaganda model.
itical personnel cannot always do as The rst two lters—ownership and ad-
they wish.” Analyzing “the nature and vertising—have become ever more im-
sources of these limits” is a “key task” portant. The decline of public
of critical political economy (Golding broadcasting, the increase in corporate
THE PROPAGANDA MODEL 109
power and global reach and the merg- on behalf of corporate America (Carey,
ers and centralization of the media 1995; Stauber and Rampton, 1995).
have made bottom-line considerations This industry understands how to utilize
more in uential in the US, in Europe journalistic conventions to serve its
and many other countries. The compe- own ends. Studies of news sources
tition for advertisers has become more reveal that a signi cant proportion of
intense and the boundaries between news originates in public relations re-
editorial and advertising departments leases. There are, by one count,
have weakened further. Newsrooms 20,000 more public relations agents
have been more thoroughly incorpor- working to doctor the news today than
ated into transnational corporate em- there are journalists writing it (Dowie,
pires, with budget cuts and even less 1995, pp. 3–4).
management enthusiasm for investi- The fth lter—anti-communist ideol-
gative journalism that would challenge ogy—is possibly weakened by the col-
the structure of power (Herman and lapse of the Soviet Union and global
McChesney, 1997). In short, the pro- socialism, but this is easily offset by the
fessional autonomy of journalists has greater ideological force of the belief in
been reduced. the “miracle of the market” (Reagan).
Some argue that the Internet and the There is now an almost religious faith
new communication technologies are in the market, at least among the elite,
breaking the corporate stranglehold on so that regardless of evidence markets
journalism and opening an unpre- are assumed to be benevolent and
cedented era of interactive democratic non-market mechanisms are suspect.
media. There is no evidence to support When the Soviet economy stagnated in
this view with regard to journalism and the 1980s, it was attributed to the ab-
mass communication. In fact, one sence of markets; the disintegration of
could argue that the new technologies capitalist Russia in the 1990s is blamed
are exacerbating the problem. They on politicians and workers failing to let
permit media rms to shrink staff even markets work their magic. Journalism
as they achieve greater outputs, and has internalized this ideology. Adding it
they make possible global distribution to the fth lter in a world where the
systems that reduce the number of me- global power of market institutions
dia entities. Although the new technolo- makes non-market options seem
gies have great potential for democratic utopian gives us an ideological pack-
communication, there is little reason to age of immense strength.
expect the Internet to serve democratic
ends if it is left to the market (Herman
and McChesney, 1997, pp. 117–35). Further Applications
The third and fourth lters—sourcing
and ak—have also strengthened as The propaganda model ts exceedingly
mechanisms of elite in uence. A re- well the media’s treatment of the pass-
duction in the resources devoted to age of the North American Free Trade
journalism means that those who sub- Agreement (NAFTA) and the sub-
sidize the media by providing sources sequent Mexican crisis and meltdown
for copy gain greater leverage. More- of 1994–5. Once again there was a
over, work by people such as Alex sharp split between the preferences of
Carey, John Stauber and Sheldon ordinary citizens and the elite and busi-
Rampton has helped us see how the ness community; polls consistently
public relations industry has been able showed substantial majorities opposed
to manipulate press coverage of issues to NAFTA—and to the bailout of in-
110 EDWARD S. HERMAN
of 1992–3, the media’s refusal to take spelled out in more detail the contest-
the single-payer option seriously, de- ing forces both within and outside the
spite apparent widespread public sup- media and the conditions under which
port and the effectiveness of the these are likely to be in uential. How-
system in Canada, served well the in- ever, we made these points, and it is
terests of the insurance and medical quite possible that nothing we could
service complex (Canham-Clyne, have done would have prevented our
1994). The uncritical media reporting being labeled conspiracy theorists,
and commentary on the alleged ur- rigid determinists and deniers of the
gency of scal restraint and a balanced possibility that people can resist (even
budget in the years 1992–6 t well the as we called for resistance).
business community’s desire to reduce The propaganda model remains a
the social budget and weaken regu- very workable framework for analyzing
lation. The applicability of the propa- and understanding the mainstream me-
ganda model in these and other cases, dia–perhaps even more so than in
including the “drug wars”, seems clear 1988. As noted earlier in reference to
(Chomsky, 1991, pp. 114–21). Central America, the media’s perform-
ance often surpassed expectations of
media subservience to government
Final Note propaganda. It did so, also, in their
reporting on the Persian Gulf and
In retrospect, perhaps we should have Yugoslav wars of 1990 and 1999, re-
made it clearer that the propaganda spectively (Kellner, 1992; Mowlana et
model was about media behavior and al., 1992; Herman, 1999, pp. 161–6;
performance, with uncertain and vari- Chomsky, 1999). We are still waiting
able effects. Perhaps we should have for our critics to provide a better model.
Notes
1
For a discussion and illustration of the narrow focus of mainstream debates on media bias see Chomsky,
1989, pp. 160–80.
2
Noam Chomsky analyses some of these criticisms in Chomsky, 1989: Appendix 1.
3
The government, a primary and powerful source, was pressing its case hard, and trying to downgrade human
rights issues: it mobilized its resources of “ ak” and anti-communist ideology to keep the media in line; and
the owners and quite a few journalists of the dominant media were not unsympathetic to the government
attempt to overthrow the Sandinista government.
4
On the ring of Raymond Bonner from the New York Times, its signi cance in curbing media criticism of US
policy and the role of the Wall Street Journal as a media ak machine, see “The Wall Street Journal As
Propaganda Agency”, chapter 9 in Herman, 1999.
5
For compelling documentation on this extraordinary subservience, see Chomsky, 1989, pp. 197–261.
6
I should note that the case studies in Manufacturing Consent are only a small proportion of those that
Chomsky and I have done that support the analysis of the propaganda model. Special mention should be
made of those covering the Middle East, Central America and terrorism. See especially Chomsky, 1983, 1986,
1989; Herman, 1982; Herman and O’Sullivan, 1990.
7
In fact, the only attempt to offer an alternative model was in Nicholas Lemann’s review of Manufacturing
Consent (Lemann 1989). For an analysis of this effort see Chomsky 1989, pp. 145–8.
8
The quotation is from Schlesinger (1989: 284), cited approvingly by Eldridge (1993: 29).
9
For a fuller account, “NAFTA, Mexican Meltdown and the Propaganda System”, chapter 14 in Herman, 1999.
See also Lee, 1995.
References
Bagdikian, Ben (1987) The Media Monopoly, Boston: Beacon Press.
Bailey, Thomas (1948) The Man in the Street: the impact of American public opinion on foreign policy, New York:
Macmillan.
112 EDWARD S. HERMAN