Sex Family Fertility Haiti
Sex Family Fertility Haiti
by
Timothy T. Schwartz
*****
First published in Hardback in 2008 by Lexington Books as,
“Fewer Men, More Babies: Sex, family and fertility in Haiti.
Chapter 1
Introduction
Fertility
I have three objectives in this book: First, to explain why fertility decline in rural Haiti has not
come about. At 5.0 childbirths per mother, birthrates in towns and rural areas, where 70 percent
of the population live, are among the highest in the Western hemisphere; in Jean Rabel county,
where I conducted much of the research presented below, they are among the highest in the
world. Significant effort and research funds have been devoted to trying to explain why
contraceptive campaigns in Haiti have largely failed, but to date no researcher has satisfactorily
answered that question. On the contrary, it will be seen that explanations for the lack of fertility
decline in rural Haiti have become increasingly obscure, confusing, and unverifiable.
Anthropologists explained high fertility in Haiti with “love” and “prestige,” “absence of
contraceptives,” and “tradition” (Herskovits 1937: 89); “the desire to live with reason, and to die
with dignity” (Lowenthal 1987: 305); “fear of abandonment in women” and “strong tenets . . .
rooted in the culture” (Maynard-Tucker 1996: 1387). Others have argued that it is lack of
knowledge and an ineffective health care system (Jennie Smith 1998: 11), old age security
(Murray 1977), and even land redistribution mechanisms (Murray 1977). It will be shown that in
doing so, in turning to immeasurable variables, remote causation, and value-based explanations,
anthropologists have often contradicted their own data.
The Research
I first went to Jean Rabel as a graduate student in 1991 and 1994 to study missionaries and later
illegal migrant boat voyages. I returned in September 1995 and between that time and June 1997,
I spent fifteen months living in the thatch and tin roofed fishing hamlet of Makab (a pseudonym).
I then worked and conducted research in the region of Jean Rabel until 2001. 2
Early on, I lived in homes of impoverished farmers and fishermen. Later in my research, when I
was employed, I maintained several residences, one in the city of Port-de-Paix, the capital of the
Department de NordOuest, one in the village of Jean Rabel, and two in rural areas. I always had
people from my research sites living with me: children attending school in the city, women who
worked as cook or caretaker for the children, visitors looking for work, and itinerant female
marketing women. My continued relationship as friend, sometimes guardian, and often “patron”
made research easier than it would otherwise have been. When home writing up research results,
if I did not understand something or needed to verify a fact about a person or family, I could
simply turn to the person next to me for clarification.
In addition to living with Jean Rabeliens for the better part of six years, the major surveys I
conducted and draw on in this book are the following:
Polygyny Survey
De facto polygyny is widespread in Jean Rabel and I hypothesized that it is somehow related to
the value of children and therefore an important issue in the research. But inquiry into trends in
polygyny was inadequately addressed in both the Baseline and the Opinion Surveys. In the
Baseline Survey, a question regarding current polygyny was included but there was no question
regarding past polygyny. Past and present polygyny were measured during the Opinion Survey
but only men were asked about past polygyny—wives were not asked about their husbands’ past
polygynous behavior—and the sample was too small to give a statistically reliable image of
polygyny over the course of a Jean Rabel man’s lifetime. Thus, a three-hundred-respondent
polygyny survey was carried out using the same supervisor and in the same two communities as
the Animal and Garden Survey. Two other small polygyny surveys were carried out, one
focusing on forty-one skilled craftsmen and another among sixteen male shaman (known as
bokor or alternatively hougan or, in the approximately 10 percent of cases where the subject is
female, mambo). The areas for these surveys were chosen as a matter of convenience. Being
familiar with people in the area, I was able to confidently substantiate reports by consulting with
more than one local informant.
Notes
1. Generally called peasants, presumably because of their tenuous and limited participation in the
world market, I refer to rural Jean Rabel men and women throughout this book as farmers. The
reason I use the term farmer rather than peasant is because peasant strikes me as too thoroughly
imbued with a historic association to the disparaging, semi-slavery status of the medieval
European serf. A difference in terms also seems to suggest that the impoverished Jean Rabel
cultivator is somehow intrinsically different than the developed world “farmer.” I prefer to use
the same, less disparaging term, farmer, and emphasize the environment as the source of
behavioral differences (see Dalton 1974 for controversy surrounding the term).
2. My initial fieldwork was sponsored by the Curtis Wilgus Foundation. Field work in 1996–
1997 was sponsored by the College of Liberal Arts and Sciences at the University of Florida and
a grant from the National Science Foundation and institutional support from IICA. The 1997
Jean Rabel baseline survey was sponsored by the German GTZ project, the German NGO
AgroActionAlemande (AAA), and the French NGO Initiative Developpement (ID), the directors
of which graciously granted permission to for the data to be used in academic publications.
******
Chapter 2
Review of the Literature: The Neglected Half of Chayanov’s Rule
Introduction
The basis of my arguments is that children are useful on the nonindustrialized farm because they
work. The point might at first seem trite and obvious, but in recent decades social scientists have
so rigorously denied the economic utility of children in developing areas that the denial itself is
fascinating. Moreover, I believe this denial is the smoking gun in understanding why social
scientists have failed to satisfactorily explain Caribbean family structure, kinship, and courting
practices. To illustrate my point I want to begin by going back to an earlier time, before the
modern worldwide fertility decline, to early 20th century social science, when the small farm in
the developing world was intensively studied by a different but no less attentive generation of
social scientists.
From the quote above was derived Chayanov’s rule: “the amount of time peasants devote to
work is proportionate to the household dependency ratio of consumers to producers.” Marshall
Sahlins (1972) brought the “rule” to the fore of U.S. anthropological discourse in Stone Age
Economics, an ethnographic tour de force in which he expounded on the way members of
nonindustrial societies, limited by the domestic mode of production (production organized
around the household), maximize leisure time rather than profits or productivity. But also
inherent in Chayanov’s rule was a principle that bears directly on the thesis of this book: small
farmers dependent on nonindustrialized technologies and “limited by the family labor force” use
high fertility to increase the size of that labor force.
The point was not lost on other social scientists. The economic value of children among small
farmers and the impact that value had on fertility was widely accepted and rigorously
substantiated as a basic tenet of anthropological and demographic theory up to and through the
1970s (Notestein 1945; Liebenstein 1957; Becker 1960; Freeman 1962; Boserup 1965).
Mahmood Mamdani (1973: 14) conducted research in an Indian village and summarized what
became a consensus among many scholars when he wrote that “People are not poor because they
have large families. Quite the contrary: They have large families because they are poor.” At
about the same time, White (1973, 1976, 1982), Nag et al. (1978), and Cain (1977) carried out
similarly renowned studies empirically demonstrating that impoverished families, particularly
those engaged in farming-oriented household livelihood strategies, deliberately use high fertility
to maximize the household labor force.
Demographer John Caldwell (1976) took the point to its logical conclusion, setting up what
should have been the beginning of a florescence of explanations for family, kinship, and courting
patterns focusing on the importance of child labor among small farmers. In his theory of
intergenerational wealth flows, Caldwell (1982: 33) defined wealth as “money, goods, services,
and guarantees that one person provides to another,” and he argued that when wealth flowed
from children to parents—as for example, when children were a valuable source of labor—
fertility would be high as would the emotional and cultural reinforcements that encouraged high
birthrates. This is, as I show in subsequent chapters, precisely what can be seen in rural Haiti
today. Rural Haitians are radically pronatal; the entire rural Haitian social-kinship system and
associated attitudes, opinions, and emotions are adapted to maximizing high birthrates and child
survival; and the economic value of children in terms of their contributions to household
productivity cannot and never has been empirically disputed—not in Haiti. Moreover, this same
extreme pronatalism and economic value of children was, I will show, abundantly evident
elsewhere in the Caribbean before the growth of the tourist and industrial sectors transformed
most regional economies. But first, returning to the issue of economic explanations for high
fertility, on the scholarly front something subsequently went strangely awry.
Social scientists began to steer clear of explanations that gave child labor contributions a
determinant role in high fertility and the formulation of social and kinship patterns. New studies
contradicted earlier ones, concluding that children were rarely if ever a net value to the parental
generation (Das Gupta 1994; Lee 1996). Others focused on old-age security as the principal
economic advantage of offspring, effectively making the intergenerational flow of wealth from
children to parents so remote that it became, at best, a secondary determinant variable (Hugo
1997; Schellekens 1993; DeLancey 1990; Lillard and Willis 1997; Lee et al. 1994). This was not
simply a trend among scholars new to the argument. John Caldwell also changed his emphasis,
explaining resistance to fertility decline in sub-Saharan Africa with reasons that are “cultural and
have much to do with a religious belief system” (Caldwell and Caldwell 1987: 409).
The new trend—that of denying the economic utility of children—can be linked to a shift in our
Western value system of which most anthropologists are a part (Lancy 2007). In her study of the
evolution of child-adult play. Adriana Zelizer (1985: 171) concluded, “while in the nineteenth
century a child’s capacity for labor determined its exchange value, the market price of a
twentieth century child was set by smiles, dimples and curls”; and in a study by Gary Cross
(2004: 4), “Today, as never before, we are obsessed with kids. We come close to worshipping
them.” David Lancy (2007) suggests that it was in fact developed Western governments that
imposed these new values on poor countries. Post-WWII institutions founded to export the new
values included the United Nations Children’s Fund (UNICEF, founded in 1946), Compassion
International (1952), the International Association for the Child’s Right to Play (1961), Children
Incorporated (1964), Child Defense Fund (1973), and the Alliance for Childhood (1997).
The rise of Western child worship and the well-funded institutions that exported the new values
became part of the failure to explain why fertility in much of the world was high in the first
place. It is a classic example of how anthropology has been undermined by the same forces that
drive the discipline—funding agencies. Lancy captured the relationship when he explained:
With modernization, fertility dropped, demand for child workers dried up, and suburbia
mushroomed. Gone were the extended family, the “mother ground” where children played [and
worked] under the casual supervision of adults in the vicinity, and the large brood of sibling
playmates. In their place we have the image of the carefree young mother pushing her toddler on
a swing in the backyard. An image that owed much to mass media and marketing became
enshrined in academic discourse as well. (2007: 277–78)
I return to this issue of funding agencies in chapter 19 where I show how the new values were
promoted in developing countries, but here I want to stay focused on the scholarly negation of
the economic utility of children in the face of overwhelming evidence to the contrary. A close
look at how this denial of child labor occurred in the Caribbean and in Haiti demonstrates the
extremity of the trend and accents why, in order to understand kinship systems and family
patterns, it is so important to rectify it.
When the liquid is coming you can get up and throw it away but at the same time it is your blood
you dashing away, and for that reason I don’t like it. It is a sin, because you are destroying your
blood, it is like killing a child. (Blake 1961; 201)
When explaining this pronatal complex of customs and behavior—extreme desire for children
and aversion to contraceptives—one would expect that social scientists, especially
anthropologists, would have turned to the child labor contributions that were so assiduously
documented in the ethnographic literature. As a rule they did not.
Despite overwhelming evidence to the contrary, social scientists working in the Caribbean
contradicted their own reports and denied the economic utility of children; and they did this
much earlier on than the rejection of the utility of children found elsewhere.
Judith Blake (1961), co-author of the most influential demographic paradigm of the 20th
century—the proximate and intermediate determinants of fertility (Davis and Blake 1956)—
asked a sample of sixty-five Jamaican women, “What is your idea of a good son?” Fully 95
percent of the women interviewed replied, one who “helps” with productive household tasks.
The next most common response (36%) was a son who “obeys,” which according to Blake meant
“he heeds instructions . . . willingly helps in domestic chores,” “thinks of his parents all the time
. . . considers in every way he can help them.” Only 11 percent of respondents mentioned “love
or affection.” Yet, despite her informants clearly telling her the contrary, and despite
acknowledging that “the child in the poorer strata of Jamaican society appears to lead a fairly
burdensome and chore-ridden life,” (62) Blake decided that high fertility in Jamaica had little or
nothing to do with child labor contributions. It was, according to Blake, “a means to non-
economic ends” (250–51).
This tendency to note the critical economic contributions children made to the household while
at the same time downplaying child labor as a determinant of pronatalism or high birth rates was
not the oversight of a select few social scientists; it was and is representative of the entire body
of anthropological, sociological, and demographic literature on the Caribbean. In her summary of
findings from the Women in the Caribbean Project and exhaustive review of Caribbean
ethnographies, Olive Senior summarized:
Where there is no piped water, children are assigned the task of carrying water from a river or
spring some distance from the house. Where there is no cooking gas or electricity or other easily
available fuel, seeking firewood—sometimes at a great distance—is a major daily task. Where
there is no refrigeration and the family income arrives in a fragmentary way, running to the shop
for basic items as needed is a constant activity. Caring for domestic animals and garden plots,
helping with laundry, cooking, cleaning and other housekeeping tasks and caring for younger
siblings are all regarded as the duties of children.
(Senior 1991:34)
Quoting Brodber (1986: 60) in Jamaica, Senior drove the point home:
Children are seen as appendages of elders and have little existence of their own; rarely can they
find occasions to slip away to play with neighboring children. . . . As their parents hire no help,
and as there are no labor saving devices, their human energy is very highly valued and is not
frittered away in play. (Senior 1991: 34)
But having said this, Senior subsequently summarized explanations from the Caribbean
ethnographic literature, presenting children as a maternal burden, wanted because childbearing is
the way that a woman “proves herself to a man,” the way she “completes a family,” the way she
achieves “social recognition,” the result of the “widespread belief in the biblical injunction to be
‘fruitful and multiply,’” and thus bearing children is “a good thing to do,” an activity that “makes
you feel like a woman” and allows women to “realize their self-image” to derive “psychic
satisfaction” (Senior 1991: 67–69). In all of Senior’s discussion of the causes of pronatalism, the
only material factor cited is that woman want children because they are useful as “minders in old
age” (Senior 1991: 67). Nothing is said about the benefits of young children as contributors to
household production, benefits that, as seen, Senior herself noted are of major significance.
Illustrative of the point is also Penn Handwerker, deservedly among the most respected
contemporary anthropologists in the field of fertility, a scholar who has provided the social
sciences with our most powerful cross-cultural statistical model for fertility decline (see
Handwerker 1989). When referring to the islands of St. Lucia, Barbados, and Antigua,
Handwerker (1993) explained that the economic value of children for women consisted not in
labor utility but in the fact that “childbearing was a singularly effective way to secure their future
material welfare [a reference to old age] and to establish the relatively permanent ties to men that
improved their immediate material welfare” (1993: 45).1 Handwerker (1989: 87) made a similar
argument with regard to Barbados, saying that “the probability a woman could adequately
support herself through her own employment was close to zero.” The reason women had children
in the first place was that “young women overtly traded sex for financial support. Pregnancies
and children occurred as mere byproducts of that exchange” (Handwerker 1989: 87–88).
As with many scholars, Handwerker’s focus was on economic opportunities that would have
been expected in upper-class Western industrialized societies, specifically “employment” and
outside economic opportunity. But he gave little attention to the household as a woman’s realm
of productive activity or to other nonformal work activities and, most importantly, to the value of
children in accomplishing such work. And he did this despite noting that:
All children began working when they were capable of helping. . . . As early as five or six, girls
began to sweep, dust, straighten, to wash, dry, and put dishes away. To fetch water, put water on
for tea, to look for eggs, feed the chickens, collect firewood, and to wash, iron, and dry clothes.
Boys too were assigned tasks at early ages . . . their tasks were primarily outside chores—boys
took care of the stock and helped their fathers. (Handwerker 1989: 81–82)
Anthropologist Ann Brittain is another example. Brittain (1990) made the counterintuitive and
demographically startling observation that fertility rates on the islands of St. Barthelemy and St.
Vincent and the Grenadines (1991a) increased with male migration (fewer men but more
babies)—something that flies in the face of conventional demographic wisdom, but that, as will
be seen in chapter 18, is tantamount to a demographic rule in the traditional Caribbean and has
befuddled a host of other anthropologists. Having discovered this demographic oddity, Brittain
offered a tentative explanation and in doing so deemphasized the value of child labor in favor of
preeminence of contributions, not from young children, but from adult offspring who twenty
years after they were born might seek remunerated employment on distant islands and share it
with their mothers:
The most likely explanation for the connection between the crude rate of emigration five years
earlier seems to be that parents were not acting directly in response to the loss of children
through death or migration, but anticipating the emigration of some of their offspring when they
reached adulthood. . . . Children provide valuable labour in farming families but the presence of
adult offspring may be even more important as a support of old age. (Brittain 1990: 57)
The point is not that the cited scholars did shoddy research. Senior, Handwerker, and Brittain
have produced some of the most commendable anthro-demographic studies on family and
fertility in the Caribbean. The point is that they illustrate how social scientists have, for whatever
reason, glossed over the significance of child labor contributions to household livelihood
strategies and, as I will attempt to demonstrate, in doing so have fallen short of explaining the
determinants of high fertility and family patterns in the region. Despite their own data, they
attributed birth rates to causes such as the desire to feel like a woman, biblical injunctions to “be
fruitful and multiply,” inadvertent byproducts of sex, and the value of grown offspring; at the
same time scholars were often insistent about viewing young children as a burden. Although they
often provided the data that showed otherwise, they paid little attention to the role that children
played in making households productive and little attention to how female engagement in extra-
household marketing activities depended on child labor contributions.
Most scholars asking questions about why family planning initiatives have not been accepted by
the people of Haiti seems to reflect crucial (though often tacit) preconceptions. Not only do these
scholars tend to assume that if people were more educated about the issue and more aware of
their options, and if these options were more accessible to them, then they would choose to
accept family planning. They also tend to imply that this compliance would be good for them.
(Looking back over the pages above, I find that I myself, however unwittingly, also seem to hold
that underlying assumption.) (all punctuation in the original: Smith 1998: 24) 3
Thus, similar to both the cross-cultural and the Caribbean literature regarding fertility decline
and the economic utility of children, an interesting if not academically astonishing facet of the
Haitian ethnographic record is the contradictions that we, as social scientists, have made
ourselves.
Conclusion
Reflecting trends in Western demographic theory at the global level, researchers in the Caribbean
have left a record of stark denial. We have often ignored the determinant role of material
conditions as our informants reported them to us, and specifically, in this case, the value of child
labor. In the following chapters I want to show how reinserting the importance of child labor can
resolve some of the most perplexing issues that have confounded anthropological research,
specifically persistent high fertility in Haiti and the determinants of what many have considered
the Caribbean’s unique courtship, family, and kinship patterns. To do so, I take the reader to Jean
Rabel, Haiti, one of the few regions left in the Caribbean where traditional livelihood strategies
continue to prevail and where there are ample data to demonstrate the mechanics and underlying
causes of kinship and family patterns that prevail there.
*****
Notes
1. Handwerker (1986) provides the most successful model available for fertility decline. His
model explains over 95 percent of the variance in a very large sample of country d/ata,
demonstrating that fertility decline is a consequence of increasing economic opportunities.
However, explaining why fertility declined does not resolve the issue of why it was high in the
first place and, like many contemporary scholars, Handwerker prefers not to emphasize the labor
value of children when they are young.
2. The full quote from Herskovits is as follows:
The love of children, and the prestige which a man gains as head of a large family are factors
that go far to explain the desire for numerous progeny. In this not only is he aided by his own
sophistication in matters of sex…but his desire is furthered as well by the absence of
contraceptives, and the emphasis laid by Church, State, and African traditions on the desirability
of many offspring. (Herskovits 1937: 89)
3. Also important but for editorial reasons omitted is Glen Smucker’s (1983) excellent
ethnography on peasants/farmers in the north of Haiti. Smucker does not attempt to evaluate the
importance of child labor as a cause of pronatalism and thus the insight he provides does not fit
into the literature review in the main text. Smucker’s work is, however, among the most
thorough and instructive resources written on rural life in Haiti and he does make frequent
mention of the economic utility of children, as for example:
After children learn to walk, they are expected to help with domestic tasks, carrying water,
gathering wood and running errands. When they are old enough, boys go to the fields with their
father, and girls take greater responsibility for household domestic tasks and marketing. As they
approach adolescence, boys are assigned their own gardens and livestock. (1983: 232–33).
******
Chapter 3
The Commune of Jean Rabel
Introduction
The commune of Jean Rabel has had a sometimes glorious and prosperous past. It was home to
the most socioculturally complex Indians in the Caribbean, the Classic Taino, and one of the first
places that Christopher Columbus landed in the new world. It became a refuge of pirates and
buccaneers, it was a prosperous quarter of the French colony of Saint Dominigue, the first New
World home to some ten thousand African-born slaves, a strategically important site during the
Haitian wars for independence, and it was an area that produced and exported significant
quantities of rum and plantains during the mid 1900s. But in recent decades Jean Rabel has
experienced deteriorating environmental, economic, and social conditions. The presence of the
State is feeble at best, and no local community organizations exist capable of confronting the
devastating social, economic, and ecological problems that affect the area. International NGOs
have been operating in the commune for fifty years and are presently the only effective
suprahousehold community help organizations and the only real providers of institutional
healthcare, agricultural, and social security services to the 130,320 residents of the region.
Today, contemporary farmers living in Jean Rabel survive in the face of harsh cyclical
environmental conditions exacerbated by the rapid degradation of their natural resource base and
periodic hurricanes, droughts, and floods. The absence of assistance from the State in the form of
an agricultural extension service, price support during market gluts or disaster, aid in storing
crops and moving them to markets, or assistance with infrastructure such as roads and ports
mean that, with the NGOs aside, Jean Rabel families have had to adapt to harsh environmental
and economic conditions on their own. Disease, malnutrition, chronic food shortages, and
scarcity of potable water have been making life even more difficult. To most observers, the
primary force driving the disaster is exponential demographic increment. But as I argue, it is
precisely the demographic increment that is the primary adaptive mechanism.
Geography
The commune is half mountain, half plain, and includes approximately thirty-five kilometers of
Atlantic coastline. Beginning in the humid three-thousand-foot inland mountains and moving
northward toward the sea, the landscape transforms in a quick seven to eight kilometers into
foothills and then fertile plain. The plain runs the entire length of the Jean Rabel coast but a
smaller range of drier low-slung, wind-sheared desert mountains separates the plain from the
ocean. Rainfall varies from one thousand mm in the high inland altitudes to four hundred mm
along the coast (see figures 3.1 and 3.2 below). Rainfall on the drier plains occurs most often in
the autumn and winter months and rain in the mountains falls most heavily in the spring (see
chapter 11, figure 11.1, p. 119). The plains both benefit and suffer from the mountain runoff,
which provides temporary irrigation and, at times, crop-devastating floods.
Rainfall in m m
1200
900
600
300
0
19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19
22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50
Ye a r
1500.00
1000.00
500.00
0.00
196
196
196
196
196
197
197
198
198
198
198
198
198
198
198
198
198
199
199
199
199
199
199
199
5
8
9
6
7
1
2
5
6
6
7
8
9
0
2
3
4
5
8
9
0
3
4
While difficult, the prudent farmers, those who have saved money and those who have planted
sufficient security crops like cassava, yams, and sugarcane, come through crises relatively
unscathed, for the crops planted by Jean Rabel farmers are uniquely suited to surviving drought.
Plants such as sweet potato go into a state of dormancy during drought and then come back
vigorously at first rain and may yield as much as twelve metric tons per acre on as little as four
inches of rainfall. But the more it rains, the more the vine produces (see Bouwkamp 1985;
Onwueme 1978). Or there is cassava, a close competitor with sweet potatoes for the most
productive tropical food plant in terms of calories produced per square meter. It needs more rain
than sweet potatoes to grow, but it is more tolerant of drought, easily surviving dry periods
longer than six months. Further, unlike sweet potatoes, cassava has the unique ability to be stored
in the ground and is hurricane proof because it can lose all its leaves and its branches may break
but the root, which is where the food is, will not die. After drought or hurricanes the plant draws
on carbohydrate reserves in the roots to rejuvenate itself (see Toro and Atlee 1980; Cock 1985).
Or pigeon peas, a bush-like plant with roots reaching six to seven feet beneath the surface,
deeper than cassava, making the plant highly drought resistant. When drought does strike, pigeon
peas shed all their leaves and go into a state of dormancy just like cassava, coming back to life
when the rains return (see Nene et al. 1990). Or sorghum and millit, both crops that yield with
minimum rainfall. The roots reach more than eight feet beneath the surface, enabling the plant to
withstand over two months of drought. When the crop is entirely lost to drought or has been
harvested, the stalks can be cut back and the plant will begin growing again (see Nzeza 1988).
Peanuts are even more drought resistant than sorghum, and in Jean Rabel they are planted in
sandy soil and in the kadas where only cacti and xerophytic plants are found. It is also the
premier high yield cash crop in the mountains, taking over the role that corn and beans fill on the
plains (see Nzeza 1988).
The other lesser but still important crops all fit into an agricultural strategy that is clearly selected
more for eking out a living in the face of an unpredictable market and natural environment than
for participating in the world economy: Lima beans, which are inter-cropped with corn, are
nitrogen fixing and begin to yield two to three months after harvest and continue to yield for as
long as there is sufficient rainfall. Pumpkins and squash also yield continually as long as there is
rain. The most popular yam in the mountains of Jean Rabel (yam reyal) can be planted during
dry spells and will begin to grow with the first rains. Like cassava, it can be stored in the ground
indefinitely, serving as an important food during droughts and other crises. Sugarcane endures
for years, propagates itself without human intervention, can be harvested at any time after it is
mature, and will grow back after being cut. Perhaps most importantly with regard to sugarcane,
the hard fibrous exterior locks in water while the roots extend some eighteen feet underground,
making it a completely drought-resistant source of water and high-energy food for both people
and animals.
During the most severe dry spells, people traditionally purchase cassava and rapadou (a gummy
crudely refined brown sugar wrapped in banana leaf) on the nearby island of La Tortue, an area
with three times the average annual rainfall of Jean Rabel. People also resort to eating boiled
green mangos, and a variety of wild plants, including a yam and several types of seedpods.
Livestock are sold or slaughtered and eaten as they succumb to the drought.
Infrastructure
Jean Rabel is one of the poorest communes in Haiti. For whatever reason—lack of funds,
corruption or apathy—the Haitian State has only a marginal presence and provides few public
services. There is no electricity, no indoor plumbing, and no sewers. In 2000, the State sponsored
a small hospital staffed by four Haitian doctors and two visiting Cuban doctors, but the facilities
permit only minor surgery. The police force consists of eighteen national police officers who are
usually absent from their posts. Even when they are present, they do little more than sit huddled
around their two-room headquarters in the village playing cards and dominoes (albeit it is
difficult for them to do anything else as they have no vehicles—no truck, no motorcycle, not
even a mule). There are no State irrigation works and no State-supported maintenance services.
In the past forty years the State has built only one hundred yards of drainage canal and no new
roads. Older roads in the region are maintained by international intervention agencies.
The Village
The village, or bouk as locals call it, which continues to be the administrative seat of the
commune, is like a place time and progress forgot. The streets are laid out in an orderly grid—a
vestige of the village’s colonial origins—and are made of dirt with muddy drainage ditches
running down both sides. As late as 1992, a spiked colonial cannon still lay discarded by the
roadside. The center of the village is a cluster of several hundred rusty tin roofs, rickety wooden
two-story houses built in the 1930s and 1940s, and a few cement ones built in the 1990s,
evidence of the latest “boom” in NGO intervention activity. Some of the older single-story
houses at the edge of town have been all but swallowed by a creeping lava-like flow of mud that
pours down the eroding hillsides during rainy season. Vehicles have to ford a shallow river to
arrive or leave, and once outside of town the streets fizzle their way out, becoming winding,
rural, rock-strewn and gully-ridden roads and footpaths.
There are only three privately owned noncommercial vehicles in the entire commune, and the
only public transportation for the 130,320 residents is provided by approximately twenty pick-up
trucks, sixteen larger trucks, and two school buses, all privately owned. When traveling to the
distant urban centers of Gonaives and Port-au-Prince, people in Jean Rabel pay H$10 to H$20
(US$3–$US6) to squeeze aboard the overloaded trucks, brightly painted in colorful designs and
bedecked with lights and ornamentation. Bleating goats and squawking chickens are strapped to
the roofs and bumpers as the top-heavy vehicles totter their way along, ever so slowly, often
inching through river beds and down rocky and washed out roads. It takes them ten to twelve
hours to reach the capital by bus.1
Malnutrition and Disease
Despite the occasional natural disasters, the deteriorating environment, absence of modern
utilities, and the poor educational opportunities, life in Jean Rabel might not be so bad, except
for the scarcity of potable water and the high prevalence of infectious diseases. To begin with,
potable water sources are few and far between. The average round trip walking distance from a
Jean Rabel household to the nearest water source is seventy minutes (see chapter 11, table 11.4).
During droughts, many springs dry up and the distance to the water often doubles and can be as
much as three or four times as far. Foreign employees of the French NGO Initiative
Developpement report that only 65 percent of the springs in the region qualify as safe drinking
water. After heavy rains, many springs become polluted with runoff and are unsafe to drink.
Locals often resort to digging holes in river beds and areas where there is ground seepage,
something that also exposes them to contamination from animal and human feces.
Most Jean Rabel households make two hot meals a day. People also eat fruit, avocados, bread,
peanuts, and a series of other inter-meal snacks. But by U.S. standards, 15 to 20 percent of Jean
Rabel children are malnourished, and a 1990 study found that 26 percent of women were mild to
severely malnourished (PISANO 1990). Chronic food scarcity has intensified recently with the
deteriorating environment and with the rise in food aid, something that is arguably a principal
cause of increasing poverty (Richardson 1997). Food aid lowers market prices for staple foods,
reducing the income farmers get for their own produce, which, in lieu of the fact that other
household expenses do not change, lowers household cash reserves for food purchases during the
off season.
Complicating the problem of scarce drinking water and malnutrition—or perhaps largely as a
consequence of these factors—are high rates of infectious diseases. The exact rates are difficult
to ascertain. No one is keeping count of the sick and less than half the population uses the fifteen
NGO-sponsored clinics in the region (the estimate is courtesy of clinic staff who fail to keep the
records). By any measure, at least 10 percent of infants die in their first year of life and 25
percent of children do not survive past the age of five. Interviews with sixty-four women
revealed that in the twelve months prior to the interview, twenty-two (34%) had at least one bout
with a debilitating disease that left them bedridden for several days to months, and as seen in the
following chapter, at any given time about 5 percent of adult Jean Rabel women suffer from a
sexually transmitted disease.2
Migration
Many Jean Rabeliens desperately try—and many have succeeded—to escape to the city and to
neighboring countries, to the United States, and to Europe. For example, the migration of the
village elite, from whose ranks come political leaders and people in positions of public trust and
power, is alarming. Since the early 1980s the number of village residents has grown from 3,294
to the current estimate of 8,000 people (out of the total commune population of 130,320). But
longtime Jean Rabel residents explain that more that 80 percent of the villagers who were present
in the early 1980s are gone.
In an attempt to corroborate these reports and to measure the extent of migration out of the
village, I took a list of village residents from a 1960 open letter to then President Francois
Duvalier that I found in a Port-au-Prince newspaper (Nouvelliste 1960). The letter was a plea for
aid after a storm had washed out the local cemetery, uncovering graves and sending coffins and
cadavers floating through the streets. There were 178 signatures on the letter. Using local
informants, we were able to identify eighty-two of the individuals listed in the letter, all the rest
presumably having long ago left with their entire families. For sixty-nine of the individuals,
information was obtained on the number of children they had and the current whereabouts of
these children. Of the individuals, thirty-one had left Jean Rabel; twenty-one of these had
immigrated to Miami. Of the 287 offspring identified, 76 percent had left Jean Rabel and 57
percent had immigrated to the United States.3
The same trends are evident in rural areas. In a 1992 random sample of two rural areas near Jean
Rabel, I compared tin-roofed households (a sign of higher income) to thatch-roofed houses (a
sign of lower income).4 None of the sixty-nine heads of thatch-roofed households had any
children in the United States and only three had a sibling in the United States. In contrast, seven
of twenty-seven tin-roofed household heads had siblings and four had children living in the
United States (Schwartz 1992).
It is not that migrant families have more money because they have migrants. It is the inverse. As
one moves from the poorest rural areas into those zones where there is a relative concentration of
wealth, migration becomes the dominant theme. In one of the only irrigated zones in the region I
found that 74 percent of all children of the largest landowners had left the region. Thirty-one
percent (31%) were reported as being in the United States, and this percentage did not take into
consideration the age of the children and the fact that some were still very young and hence had
not yet emigrated (see tables 3.4 and 3.5).
Overall, reproductive-age women in the Jean Rabel commune have a 4.5 percent rate of
contraceptive use, which is one-fourth the rate for Haiti as a whole (18%), one-seventh that of
the lowest country rate in the Caribbean (Guatemala at 31%), and one-thirteenth the level of
contraceptive use for Latin America and the Caribbean as a whole (59%). The contraceptive use
rate in Jean Rabel is compatible with the four lowest country rates in the world—Mozambique at
2 percent, Ethiopia and Niger at 4 percent, and Eritrea at 5 percent (see the UN 2000).
Thus, today, while technology remains virtually unchanged from what it was two centuries
ago—indeed, more rudimentary—Jean Rabel is inhabited by 130,320 residents, an average of
279 people per km2 or 724/mile2. Forty-six percent of Jean Rabeliens are children under fifteen
years of age and 57 percent of residents are under twenty years of age (see figure 3.1). Very few
women are interested in using contraceptives and if the current fertility rate continues, the
population of Jean Rabel will double in the next twenty years, reaching 260,000 people, 1,548
people per square mile. 10
Table 3.8: Population of Jean Rabel in the years 1780–1997*
Conclusion
Droughts, hurricanes, periodic famine, declining soil productivity, and spectacular and
catastrophic erosion would seemingly militate against high birth rates but, as will be seen, while
large numbers of children may be illogical from the standpoint of the population as a whole, it is
logical from the standpoint of the family and, more importantly, from the standpoint of the
women who are the owners and managers of households, the primary productive units around
which labor is organized in Jean Rabel. But before getting to that, I want show how the high
fertility seen above is accomplished in the face of an array of factors averse to high birth rates,
specifically disease, malnutrition, intensive labor regimes, conjugal unions interrupted by male
absenteeism, and a scarcity of men with the financial resources to care for young children.
******
Notes
1. During the Baseline Survey, 35 percent of household respondents told interviewers they own
at least one donkey, 8 percent reported owning a horse, and 7 percent percent of households
owned a mule. But this later data was skewed by the drought that was occurring and so I have
used data from the Polygyny Survey carried out two years later and in which questions regarding
pack animals were included. Intuitively, I believe the Polygyny Survey results reflect general
conditions in Jean Rabel but it focused on only two communities, one in the mountains and one
on the plain, and therefore must be interpreted with this in mind.
2. The interviews were conducted at the Nan Sentren Clinic by missionary Carol Ann Truelove.
Of the women interviewed, thirty-four were visiting the clinic because they were pregnant or
nursing mothers and of these, ten had experienced a debilitating illness in the previous year;
thirty of the interviewees were currently sick at the time of the interview, and ten of these had
experienced a prior debilitating illness within the previous twelve months.
3. The identification of “prestigious” is simply those individuals who were most easily
recognized, about which informants had no questions, and were double-checked without
complication.
4. These samples were chosen from lists made in two neighborhoods. Beginning at a random
starting point, every fifth household was chosen from the lists.
5. Promotion of contraceptives began with the opening of the Protestant-funded Nan Sentren
clinic and accelerated in the later 1980s, when the French NGO InterAid began taking over
regional clinics that the Catholic Church sponsored and managed.
6. The organizations that actually do the promoting, funding, and/or supplying of contraceptives
are Profamil, PROMESS, EEU, USAID, CARE, PISANO, ID, and MSPP. AAA plans to join the
effort in 2000. The fees for contraceptives are 25 gdes (US$1.50) to place Norplant, 25 gdes
(US$1.50) to remove Norplant, 5 gdes (US$0.30) consultation fee for all other chemical
contraceptives (Depo-Provera, Noristat, and pills). Condoms are given away at clinics and sold
in rural stores at three condoms for 2 gdes (US$0.12 ). Tubal ligation is 50 gdes (US$3.00).
Charges account for the cost of service and not the cost of contraceptives, which are considered
gratuitous.
7.
Table 3.9: Knowledge of contraceptive methods (N = 1,132)
8. The figures in the table have been adjusted to account for skewing by the fact that over 50
percent of the patients listed are actually tubal ligation patients. The codes are as follows.
a Regions are based on clinic zones and do not coincide with commune boundaries.
b Population estimate based on census by missionaries responsible for the Faith Medical Clinic,
Mare Rouge Medical Clinic, and Kote d’Fer Medical Clinic.
c Population estimate based on 1997 Baseline Survey; represents 70 percent of population in the
commune of Jean Rabel.
d Mole St. Nicolas, Temps Perdu, Kot d’Fer, and La Montagne; only La Montagne (population
of reproductive age women = 2,910) is within the commune of Jean Rabel.
There were 24 vasectomies in the region, all in Nan Sentren.
9. The average age of the women was 34.5; the average number of children ever born was 6.0;
and the average number of living children was 5.15.
10. From the time of the revolution to the time of the end of U.S. military occupation, the
population in Jean Rabel grew very little. Ostensibly this was because of high death rates that
began declining in 1915 with the occupation of Haiti by the U.S. Marines. As seen, just prior to
the wars in 1789, Moreau had recorded a population of twelve thousand in the commune; nine
thousand of these people were slaves who would likely have stayed in the region after
independence had been won. In 1919, a priest named Marcel Simonneau visited Jean Rabel and
reported there were 20,000 people in the commune. But it is not clear where Simonneau got this
estimation and I have deferred to the 1919 US Marine Corps census, which placed the population
at 14,802. Simmoneau did report that there were one thousand baptisms a year—something the
priest should well know—which translates to a gross fertility rate of about sixty-seven births per
thousand people. This is too high. It is twenty-two births higher than Hutterites and eighteen
births higher than the highest crude birth rate recorded during the 1990s. Thus, perhaps
Simonneau was correct in estimating a population of 20,000. Verschuren reports that in 1936
there were thirty-five thousand inhabitants and this looks like an estimation based on the 1919
figure and would fit well with a population growth of about 4 percent—derived from the gross
fertility rate of fifty. But, again, it is not stated where these data came from and the census of
1950, fourteen years later—when the population should have increased by at least another 50
percent—found only 33,372 people living in the Commune—less than Veschueren estimated in
1936. The most prudent course of action seems to be to eliminate the 1936 estimate and go with
the 1950 census if for no other reason than they are censuses. That is what I have done here.
Nevertheless, the important point is that, whichever population estimates are used, population
growth has been much higher since 1919 and it has steadily increased throughout the century.
The population growth rate estimate appears and probably is slightly too high and this could very
well be caused by undercounts in early censuses. However, with the youthful population
structure of current Jean Rabel—something that typically results in a low death rate—and, as
will be seen in a later chapter, with a total fertility rate of more than seven children per woman
and completed fertility rates of about eight children per woman, population growth rates above 3
percent are not simply possible but likely.
*****
Chapter 4
Extremely High Fertility
Introduction
High fertility seen in the previous chapter is a spectacular demographic feat. If Jean Rabel were a
country, then at the time I carried out the research for this book it would have had the second
highest total fertility rate (TFR) in the world: 7.1 births per mother. The achievement is startling
because in the endeavor to reproduce, Jean Rabel women face extreme adversity. High rates of
infectious diseases, low-fat and low-calorie diets, high rates of female malnutrition, demanding
exercise regimes, and a high rate of male absenteeism diminish the probability of pregnancies
and weigh heavily against the likelihood of high birth rates. Yet, Jean Rabel fertility rates
measure up impressively to that of the early 20th century Hutterites, people who had the highest
sustained fertility levels ever recorded. Thirty-two percent of Jean Rabel women equal or exceed
the median ten births attained by early to mid 20th century Hutterite women (Eaton and Mayer
1953; Larsen and Vaupel 1993; Nonaka et al. 1994). In this chapter I compare Jean Rabel
women to their Hutterite counterparts to show how remarkable high fertility is and how
efficacious are the customs that make it possible.1
Figure 4.1: Completed fertility in Jean Rabel for women over 45 yrs
Factors that Dampen Fertility
High incidence of diseases, widespread malnutrition, intensive physical exertion and labor
regimes, and the disruption of unions through male absenteeism are all factors associated with
low birth rates. All are also factors conspicuous in the lives of Jean Rabel women.
Data from the Baseline Survey indicate that 5.7 percent of Jean Rabel women never succeed in
carrying a pregnancy to full term, a figure close to the median of 4.2 percent reported for all
developing countries (Vaessen 1984). But clinic records for pregnant women also indicate that,
at any given time, 5 to 10 percent of women in the region suffer from sexually transmitted
diseases such as chlamydia, HIV/AIDS, and syphilis—maladies that interrupt and sometimes
prematurely end reproductive careers. As seen, other widespread and debilitating diseases such
as malaria, typhoid, and hepatitis annually leave over 30 percent of women in the region
bedridden and sexually incapacitated for months and sometimes years. 2
Malnutrition and high levels of physical exertion are also factors known to lower fertility by
inducing amenorrhea—the suspension of menstrual cycles for three or more months. In the
Baseline Survey, women were found to generally consume low-fat, high-carbohydrate diets (see
table 4.1). And 26 percent of Jean Rabel women were found to be slightly to severely
malnourished.3
10
8
8
8 8 8 8
7 7 7
7
6
6 6
4 5
3
2
0 1
AG 84
15
20 to 1
25 to 2
30 to 2
35 to 3
40 to 3
45 to 4
50 to 4
55 to 5
60 to 5
65 to 6
70 to 6
75 to 7
80 to 7
E
to 9
>
84
9
4
9
4
9
4
9
4
9
4
9
4
An average of six hours per week is also spent picking produce from the gardens, and another
twelve to twenty-four hours are spent walking back and forth from the nearest water source to
hand scrub clothes. This total exercise regime certainly matches or exceeds the five miles of
jogging per week that induced amenorrhea in 6 percent of the U.S. subjects studied by Feight et
al. (1978) and is probably closer to the weekly physical exertion of women in the same study
who ran forty-five miles per week inducing amenorrhea in 43 percent of the cases. Extended
breastfeeding, necessary in the absence of high-protein baby formulas, is also known to suppress
ovulation (WHO 1999); and 63 percent of women in the Jean Rabel Baseline Survey reported
breast feeding their last child for eighteen to twenty-seven months (see figure 4.3).4
Percentage of women
30%
20%
10%
0%
5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27
Another factor researchers have identified as a determinant of low fertility is reduced exposure to
the risk of pregnancy through late entry into union or disrupted union through factors such as
wage migration (Bongaarts and Potter 1983; Williams et al. 1975; Blake 1954). Male
absenteeism is part of the rural Haitian demographic profile. Males in Haiti migrate to larger
Haitian cities and overseas to the Bahamas, the United States, and the Dominican Republic at a
significantly higher rate than their female counterparts. The result is lower male-to-female sex
ratios. In the Baseline Survey, 10 percent of Jean Rabel men in the twenty- to forty-nine-year-old
age groups were reported as being absent and no longer considered as members of the household
from which they originated. Furthermore, in the Opinion Survey, 26 percent of men in union
reported having been away from home for at least 30 of the preceding 365 days (see table 4.3).
Congruent with male transience, 52 percent of Jean Rabel women in the twenty- to twenty-four-
year-old age group and 26 percent of women in the twenty-five to twenty-nine-year-old age
group were not in union at the time of the interview,,, and at least 26 percent of women abandon
or are abandoned by their first spouse during the course of their reproductive careers (see table
4.4).
In a society with strongly enforced values regarding monogamy and premarital pregnancy, the
type of male absenteeism and transience being described would disrupt ongoing conjugal union
and force a minority of women to remain out of union and childless. Yet, according to
respondents in the Opinion Survey, the average age at first union for Jean Rabel women is 21.7
years and the average age at first childbirth is 22.3 years. These averages for Jean Rabel women
are not unusually high or low. For example, the average age women in the remote rural
Dominican Republic first enter into unions and give birth is significantly lower than the averages
cited for Jean Rabel (McPherson and Schwartz 2001). Nevertheless, entry into union at moderate
age and the high birth rates are accomplished despite high rates of male absenteeism.
As will be seen in the following two chapters, Jean Rabel society has adapted to male migration
with an array of customs, beliefs, and behaviors that, with respect to fertility, allow women to
overcome the problem of male absenteeism.
Hutterite couples are never separated after marriage. In the history of the group since 1875 there
has been only one divorce and only 4 desertions. We know of one other case where husband and
wife separated temporarily to live in different colonies. (p. 223)
Thus, while reproductive-age Jean Rabel women are faced with a 10 percent deficit of men,
Hutterite women are outnumbered by men. And, as might be expected, there was an average of
13 percent more reproductive-age Hutterite women in union than there are in contemporary Jean
Rabel.5, 6
But despite all of the limiting factors, including the absence of many Jean Rabel men and the
physiological factors mitigating against high fertility, 32 percent of contemporary Jean Rabel
women who have completed their childbearing careers equal or exceed the median ten children
born per Hutterite woman in the years 1880 to 1950. Contemporary Jean Rabel fertility levels are
13 percent higher than contemporary Hutterites (Eaton and Mayer 1953; Larsen and Vaupel
1993; Nonaka et al. 1994).7
Table 4.5: Hutterites vs. Jean Rabeliens: Percentage of women in union per five-year age
group and sex ratios (includes widows)
Conclusion
Fertility in Jean Rabel is extremely high despite nutritional, epidemiological, and social factors
that work against it. In the following chapter I want to show that this extremely high fertility is
not the inadvertent consequence of people helplessly procreating while lamenting the burden of
more children. On the contrary, this high fertility in the face of adverse conditions is made
possible by a specific array of interrelated beliefs, customs, and behaviors that promote
childbirth.
Notes
1. Jean Rabel’s TFR of 7.1 is 48 percent higher than Haiti‘s overall country TFR of 4.8 children
and 20 percent higher than the rural Haitian TFR of 5.9 children per woman (EMMUS 1994/95).
The Hutterites had a sustained overall TFR of 8.0 to 8.5—the commonly cited Hutterite fertility
rates are median completed fertility and the TFR of married women, one of which is discussed in
the text. The highest birth rate in the UN data base, year 2000—date of the Jean Rabel Baseline
Survey--was Niger at 7.25 births per mother (see the UN web site).
2. Infecundity is deduced from the number of women who have completed their childbearing
years without bearing children (age > 45) (see Vaessen 1984). There was no relevant clinic data
available in Jean Rabel. The records that have been kept at the hospital are sporadic and
unreliable. More often than not, nurses failed to record the results for STD tests. The observation
is generalized from data collected at the Bombardopolis clinic, which is in the Far-West but
outside the commune of Jean Rabel, and there is little reason to believe there is a difference
between the communes. Other epidemiological data are similar.
3. The determination of malnutrition was based on a brachial measure of less than 18.5
centimeters. The size of the sample was 770 women.
4. There might be a way around suppression of ovulation through breastfeeding. The suppression
of ovulation is apparently a reflex response to suckling. According to a research review by
Larsen and Vaupel (1993), a woman must nurse her infant at least four times a day for a
minimum of twenty minutes each time. By conscious design or simply custom, Hutterite women
only allow their babies to nurse for ten minutes or less. Further, supplementary foods are
introduced early and by six to seven weeks the infant is fed before it is given the breast.
Interestingly, while it is not known how long Jean Rabel women allow infants to nurse, they too
introduce foods extremely early, often within days of birth, a practice that healthcare workers
have ardently and with little success tried to overcome.
5. Eaton and Mayer (1953) only found evidence of ten illegitimate births in the Hutterite
population between 1875 and 1950, indicating that few births occur before marriage. The age-
specific birth rate in 1950 for women twenty to twenty-four was 1.4 births.
6. Hutterite women during the period 1880 to 1950—when their fertility was highest—entered
union at 22 years, only .3 years later than among Jean Rabel women, and bore their first child a
mean thirteen months later, at 23.1 years of age—about ten months later than Jean Rabel women.
7. Jean Rabel women between the ages of fifteen and forty-five years old have an overall average
birth interval of 50.5 months—one child every 4.2 years. But in a sample of eighty-nine women
who have already begun childbearing, the average interbirth interval was thirty-two months—
one child every 2.7 years.
The latter data on interval birth intervals was obtained from a Nan Sentren clinic run by
missionary Carol Anne Truelove. The clinic has records on female birth histories dating back to
1984 when the clinic was first opened. The clinic serves a population of approximately sixty
thousand, half within the commune of Jean Rabel and half outside of the commune boundaries
(the population estimate is based on a census by clinic staff carried out in 1991; the extrapolation
was based on 3 percent estimated population growth). Records were chosen based on the
presence of information for the first and last child born to the mother—some women had begun
their childbearing career elsewhere or had left the region. There were thirty-two women who had
used contraceptives, with an average interbirth interval of 37.1 months and a standard error of
the mean of 2.3 months (95% CI = 32.5 – 41.6 months). There were fifty-seven records for
women who had never used contraceptives, with an average interbirth interval of 29.6 months
and a standard error of the mean of 1.3 months (95% CI = 28.3 – 30.9 months).
Chapter 5
The Pronatal Sociocultural Fertility Complex
Introduction
The extremely high fertility seen in the previous chapters is made possible by what I call rural
Haiti’s pronatal sociocultural fertility complex, an array of social behaviors that allow Jean Rabel
women to overcome high disease, poor nutrition, and scarcity of financially eligible
reproductive-age males. Jean Rabeliens want children for themselves, for family, for friends, and
for neighbors. The merits of having numerous children are a commonly discussed topic, even
with strangers. The farmers generally regard childless people with suspicion and derision.
Contraceptives are thought to make women sick, even to cause death, and women who use them,
particularly young women, are thought of as immoral. Abortion is abhorred as a grievous crime
and a sin, and women revealed to have had an abortion are publicly humiliated, their families are
fined, and they may face imprisonment. In contrast, pregnant and postpartum women are relieved
of heavy work, fed unusually large amounts of choice foods, cared for and waited on by family
and friends, and massaged daily by a paid attendant. Overall, this pronatal complex of behaviors
articulates with a series of sexual beliefs and behaviors seen in the following chapter to function
as a catalyst of high fertility despite malnutrition, intensive work regimes, and disease.
Pronatal Attitudes, Customs, Beliefs, and Behaviors
For a Jean Rabelien not to have children is tragic. Childless people, especially women, are pitied,
even criticized as millet (mules), and sometimes suspected of being lougawou (witches) or
having sold their unborn children to demons (li te manje yo). 1
With parenthood comes adulthood and respect. As one man once remarked to me; “it is children
that bring you respect” (se ti moun k-ap fe moun respekte ou). Another man explained, “a
woman needs children or her husband will not respect her” (yon fi bezwenn ti moun paskè san ti
moun gason ki rete ave-li l-ap manke respè). People who have not yet borne children are
considered children themselves, no matter what their age. Not to have children at all is a far
greater shame than having children outside of a union or with someone who is considered
disreputable.
Not only do Jean Rabeliens want children, but they want everyone else to have children as well.
The first question a rural Jean Rabelien asks a stranger is, “how many children do you have?”
(kombyen pitit ou genyen?). Responses to childlessness almost invariably go as follows: “why
don’t you have children?” (pou ki sa ou pa gen pitit?); “you are supposed to make children” (ou
sipoze fe pitit); “you are supposed to make lots of children” (ou sipoze fe anpil pitit); “you are
supposed to make children when you are young” (ou sipoze fe pitit jen); “children are a good
thing” (ti moun se yon bon bagay); “children can help you” (ti moun ka ede ou).
Most women are eager to bear children. Childless women in their early twenties who are not in
school will lament their barrenness, “I need to have a child” (m bezwenn fe yon timoun), and
their age “I am beginning to get too ripe” (m presk mi). A woman who cannot get pregnant visits
leaf doctors and clinics. She might make costly pilgrimages to distant sacred sites to ask for help
from the Virgin Mary or a Catholic saint.2 In a commonly occurring phenomenon known as
perdisyon, discussed in greater detail in the following chapter, the woman may blame kolegs (co-
wives) and other jealous rivals for magically tying her fetus up, in vitro, arresting the pregnancy.
To overcome the affliction she goes to the spiritual healer (bokor) to ask for help, she visits the
local mid-wife (matwon) who tapes her stomach to hold the imaginary fetus in place, and she
goes to massage specialists who arrange (ranje) the imaginary fetus in a position to grow.
Abortion
Despite the overwhelmingly pronatal attitudes, there are still some young Jean Rabel women
who are reluctant to begin their reproductive careers. In May 1997, a fifteen-year-old girl in the
village of Jean Rabel tried to abort an unwanted pregnancy by popping fourteen antimalarial pills
(chloroquin) into her mouth and washing them down with raw rum (kleren). An hour later, while
waiting at the village spring, in the midst of a crowd of other children sent to fill water buckets
for their households, she fell dead.
There are other girls who steadfastly disavow that they are pregnant right up until the time their
bulging stomachs make denial impossible. In an incident that took place in the summer of 1997, I
carried a convulsing sixteen-year-old rural girl to the Jean Rabel hospital. Unbeknownst to
everyone, including her siblings and parents, the teenager was eight months pregnant, a condition
she had concealed by tying torn strips of cloth around her stomach. The French doctor who
treated the young woman told me that the stomach tying had almost killed her. She spent the
entire following month being cared for in the hospital until giving birth to a healthy baby boy.
But while some young women try to avoid first pregnancies, most succumb to social pressures
that bear on young women reluctant to begin childbearing. A twenty-five-year-old woman
explained to me, “my mother said that if she caught us taking birth control pills she would club
us to death” (mama-m di si li jwenn nou pran gren li tap tiye nou anba baton). Social pressures
against abortion are even stronger. Mothers, grandmothers, sisters, and female friends are quick
to condemn abortion and older female confidants counsel young girls against abortion by
explaining that it will rot their vaginal canals, making them disgusting to men, and that they will
burn in hell for having committed the “greatest of all sins” (pi gwo pech). Men, too, have
something to say about abortion. In an Opinion Survey subsample, forty men were asked what
they would do if their wife had an abortion, and 62.5 percent responded that they would abandon
their wife and another 25 percent said they would have her arrested. Only one man said he would
do nothing. Of responses falling into the category of “other,” one man said “I would sit down
and talk to that woman to see what the hell was wrong with her.” The three remaining men
responding “Other” said they would kill their wives with sorcery.4
By law, women are supposed to be imprisoned for aborting pregnancies. In reality, imprisonment
is rare. But women are, nevertheless, ridiculed and publicly disgraced. In an instance witnessed
by a U.S. missionary working in the Jean Rabel area, a fifteen-year-old girl who had allegedly
aborted a fetus was tied to a post in a busy market while a civil servant spent his day standing
nearby announcing her crime over a handheld loudspeaker. In the spring of 1998, in the thatch-
roofed, seaside hamlet of Makab, where my research began, fishermen found a fetus floating in
the sea. The news spread quickly and literally hundreds of people descended from the hills into
the tiny village. The police were summoned. Houses were searched, and eventually the still-
bleeding sixteen-year-old mother was discovered hiding under a sheet in the corner of a friend’s
house. As the police led the humiliated girl away, the crowd chanted her name, “Viki! Viki!
Viki!” 5
Pregnancy
The typical Jean Rabel woman does not understand the female menstrual cycle in a way that
would permit her to avoid pregnancy. Many young women are taught by their mothers or other
female elders that pregnancy occurs most readily during or just after menstruation, and many
young women believe they cannot become pregnant as the result of a single sexual encounter.
But older women in rural Jean Rabel understand very well that missed menstrual cycles may
mean pregnancy, and they carefully track the dates of their and their daughter’s menstrual cycle
so they can act swiftly to defend against sorcery that may arrest development of the fetus and so
they can begin to care for and nourish the gestating fetus.
When a woman knows that she is pregnant, she takes up the habit of spitting, supposedly to spare
the fetus the ill effects of bile but something that also informs others of her special condition.
Family and friends relieve her of heavy work and attend to her needs. If she is a young woman,
she is encouraged not to travel, mount pack animals, or ride on the back of motorcycles. She is
encouraged to eat nutritious and fatty foods and she should never be refused a food of her
choosing. The stingy individual who refuses food to a pregnant woman is menaced with the
belief that a boil will erupt on his/her eye.6
The new mother remains confined in the house for five days, during which time female family
members and often a paid midwife attend to her. She is given hot ginger tea twice a day, once in
the morning and once at night. Each morning she is bathed with warm water. Each afternoon she
is given a sweat bath, for which she sits on a steaming pot of water with a sheet draped over her
head. Instead of the usual two meals a day and rare portion of meat, she is fed three meals a day,
all including the luxury of meat, especially goat and chicken slaughtered specifically to feed her.
7 After five days, the mother may leave the house, but for the first two months she must not
engage in heavy work, not leave the homestead, never go out at night for fear the cold (fredi) will
make her sick, bathe only with warm water, and not speak loudly or do heavy work.8
Conclusion
High fertility in Jean Rabel is indisputably bound with the beliefs seen above. The association of
pregnancy and childbirth with duty; the concern with conception and the care and rewarding
attentiveness toward pregnant women; the abhorrence of contraceptives and abortion; the
misinforming of young women concerning the mechanics of pregnancy; and the censuring of
childless individuals all act to promote conception among Jean Rabel women. In addition to
these blatantly pronatal attitudes, high fertility is further reinforced through local customs and
belief systems that remove social, legal, and moral barriers to pregnancy, values associated with
what I want to call the sexual moral economy, the subject of the next chapter.
******
Notes
1. Several women in the survey illustrated this point, one woman for example saying, “If you
don’t have children, there is a name they call you, they curse you mule.” (Si ou pa gen ti moun,
gen yon non yo konn di ou, y-ap joure ou millet si ou pat fe ti moun).
Witch is here meant in the anthropological sense of being the incarnation of antisociety and it is
a very widespread if not pancultural ideological phenomenon. Mischief caused by witches is
usually peculiar to the society. A witch is conceptualized as a threat where the society is most
vulnerable. Thus, pastoralists often believe witches suck the milk and blood from their animals at
night. Agriculturists often conceptualize witches as destroyers of crops. Haitians fear witches as
the eaters of children—usually manifest in the form of disease but also as the causal agent in
accidents. The supposed behavior of the Haitian witch, the lougawou, is testimony to a strong
pronatalist tendency in Haiti and a dependency on children.
2. There are a series of sacred sites throughout Haiti. Some of these sites are associated with
voudou deities and some with the sighting of the Virgin Mary or the presence of a saint. There is
a sacred rock in Mare Rouge, just on the outskirts of the commune of Jean Rabel. The rock is
called Marie Noel and people leave written prayers in the crevices of the rock. The next nearest
sacred site to Jean Rabel is Anse-a-Fleur, where people visit once a year for an annual voudou
festival. If my understanding is accurate—and in this instance there is a good chance it is not—
several years ago a doll was found and elevated to the status of a manifestation of Saint Anne.
The doll is kept in a shrine in the yard of a mambo (female spirtual practitioner).
3. Even many well-educated rural Haitians believe that AIDS is caused by sorcery—as when one
person goes to a bokor (“witch doctor”) to kill another person—and that venereal diseases are
caused by jealous spouses who ranje (magically fix) their partners so that other lovers will fall
ill.
4. M ta chita pale a fi sa pou we sa li genyen.
5. “Viki” had until only days before the incident been away to school in the village. “Abortion”
is, according to the only civil judge in Jean Rabel during 1999, the worst crime known (Sa se pi
gwo krim ki ka genyen). It is considered voluntary homicide. A woman can be given life in
prison as can anyone who participated in the abortion. In practice, it is not always if ever like
this. Police and judges do tend to arrest everyone who might be involved in an abortion and there
is usually a grand interrogation. But fines rather than prison tend to be the rule. Although
humiliated, neither of the girls whose abortion stories were told in the body of the text spent time
in jail. In the village and in the department seat Port-de-Paix, abortion services are reportedly
available for H$50.00 and by western-trained medical doctors. During a chance encounter in the
city, a judge of a neighboring Jean Rabel commune once told me he was in town to help a
fifteen-year-old girl he had impregnated locate a doctor to abort the fetus. Further, in rural areas
there are leaf doctors known to specialize in abortificants. Nevertheless, there is a definitive
ideological horror associated with abortion and a very public disapproval of it, particularly
among the truly rural people of the region.
A couple of ethnographic examples to note: In the early summer of 1997, in the incident where a
fourteen-year-old girl in the village died after trying to abort a fetus with a dose of fourteen
chloroquins washed down with rum, the police commissioner ordered the arrest of the twenty-
two-year-old man who had prescribed the medicines, but he was subsequently released. Between
1996 and 1998, at least two girls in nearby Mole St. Nicolas were caught aborting viable
fetuses—one of which lived to be adopted by a UN medic in the area with a project to repair the
local high school. Neither of the girls served time in prison.
Mention should also be made of la djablesse, the Haitian boogeywoman. All over Haiti la
djablesse are believed to live alone in caves. They are giant female, human-like creatures, with
breasts sagging to the ankles, extremely long hair, moss and weeds hanging off their bodies. La
djablesses are associated with fertility. A la djablesse is thought to hunt men and if she gets hold
of one, she leads the man back to her cave, where she forces the man to impregnate her. The
sexual appetite of a la djablesse is thought to be insatiable. Simpson (1942) explained that in
Plaisance in the north of Haiti, la djablesses were thought to be young girls who died before
having sex and were caught in the netherworld of spirits. Simpson reported that because of the
fear that a deceased virgin could become a la djablesse, cadavers of young girls were deflowered
with a stick before burial. Their were no reports of this practice in Jean Rabel and local farmers
explained la djablesse as a human-like animal rather than a spirit.
6. See Harris and Ross (1987; 5, 164–67) for a cross-cultural discussion of nutritional
deprivation of pregnant mothers.
7. Plantains are also an important element in the postpartum mother’s diet. She may eat red and
black beans but white beans and rice are considered dangerous as they are cold (fret) foods that
can make the woman ill. A partial list of other dangerous versus not dangerous foods follows:
Healthy
Corn
Taro
Banana
Flour
Corn
Goat
Chicken
Dangerous
Sweet potato
White beans
8. During confinement, only those people who were present during the actual birth may enter the
house. All is applicable even if the baby dies. If the child is a boy, restrictions may apply for as
long as three months and if the baby is a girl, restrictions may be lifted as early as 2 months.
Boys are thought of as harder to bear and thus it takes longer to get over the birth.
Chapter 6
The Sexual Moral Economy
Introduction
The attitudes, customs, beliefs, and behaviors seen in the previous chapter are complemented by
a specific econo-sexual patterns of behavior found throughout rural Haiti. Rural Haitian women
assiduously negotiate sexual acquiescence to men and they do so with the goal of material gain.
Ira Lowenthal (1984: 22) first described this behavior in detail when he reported that women in
his research community referred to their genitals as intere-m (my assets), lajan-m (my money), or
manmanlajan-m (my capital), in addition to tè-m (my land); a common proverb was, chak famn
fet ak yon kawo te—nan mitan janm ni (every women is born with a parcel of land—between her
legs). Lowenthal (1984) described this type of female commoditization of sexuality as a “field of
competition” wherein women are at a socially constructed advantage: men are conceived of and
taught to think they need sexual interaction with women, while women portray themselves and
are taught to think of themselves as able to get along without sex and thus are able to exact
material rewards for sexual contact with men. Called “gendered capital” by Richman (2003:
123), these sexual-material values are universal in rural Haiti and apply whether the woman in
question is dealing with a husband, lover, or more casual relationship.
Jean Rabel is no different, and in later chapters I show that the commoditization of womanhood
being described is linked to a sexual division of labor and rights and duties associated with
control of the household, children, extra-household income, and female marketing activities; but
here I simply want to describe “gendered capital,” or what may alternatively be described as
rural Haiti’s sexual-moral economy, and show how it combines with the pronatal sociocultural
fertility complex seen in the previous chapter to make extremely high fertility possible despite
conditions aversive to conception. In accomplishing this I will illustrate my points with songs
that rural adolescent girls in Jean Rabel compose, sing, and act out in theatrical performances
called téat. Reminiscent of Jorge Duany (1984: 186), who stated that the traditional song “cannot
fail to create and recreate the most important social values of the group that produced it,” and
John Szwed (1970: 220), who wrote that “song forms and performances are themselves models
of social behavior that reflect strategies of adaptation to human and natural environments,” the
songs I present below highlight the uniform sexual-material-domestic value system found
throughout rural Haiti.
******
Vwasi lè mango,
Vwasi lè mango, yo dous e yo koket
Bon swa madamwazel mwen di ou bon swa
Se yon banan ki vini pou-l sikre
As can be seen, the song relies heavily on metaphors. In this particular song, informants
explained that mangos, ubiquitous in Haiti and the all-time favorite fruit, symbolize the girls’
budding young breasts. The eroticism of fruit and particularly a mango with its soft juicy flesh is
clear to native speakers, the declaration that “it is mango season,” means that it is time to eat
mangos, the fruit is ripe, or rather, the girl has come of age and she is ready to engage in sexual
relations. The “good day young lady” is an introduction to the young woman. The next line
reveals the speaker, a man, represented as another fruit, a plantain, which has come to add sugar
(sikre). The plantain also happens to be the most phallic shaped fruit in Haiti leaving little doubt
for analysis (any remaining doubts are erased by snickering Haitian informants). The references
to Pepsi and Coca Cola are metaphors for prestige. In Jean Rabel these are, aside from beer, the
most expensive locally available beverages and they have correspondingly high prestige value,
representing the speaker as a high roller.
Thus, the songs I use below to illustrate the sexual moral economy all touch on the theme of sex.
The songs also, as will be seen, highlight female ideals and aspirations, gender relations, control
over resources, parent-daughter relationships, and most importantly of all, the rules,
expectations, and norms associated with male-female sexual interaction, all of which, I argue, are
interrelated in what might be called a type of sexual-moral economy. The analysis, conducted
with the assistance of local informants who helped explain the double and sometimes triple
meaning of the words to the songs, begins with a look at a socially constructed problem that Jean
Rabel women have and the representation of that problem in téat songs.
I went to Port-de-Paix
I went to buy a little wooden club
Little club, if it falls I will make it rise again
Two feet tied, two arms crossed
I have a place
I have a place on my body that boys don’t know
Where is it?
Below my mound
Below my mound
******
M ale Pò-de-Pe
M-al achte yon ti baton
Ti baton si-l tonbe m-a leve-l
Dè pye mare, dè bra-m kwaze
Mwen g’on kote
Mwen g’on kote nan ko-m ti gason pa konnen
Ki kote li ye?
Anba ti vant mwen
Anba ti vant mwen
The reference to “a little wooden club” is an obvious phallic symbol (clubs are not something
that everyone in Jean Rabel is walking around with and while old infirm people might use a
cane, purchasing one is nonsensical). The line “if the club falls” signifies the loss of an erection
and this image is reinforced by the next line, which in Kreyol uses the verb leve (rise) and anko
(again)—“I will make it rise again”—rather than ranmase, the Kreyol word for “pick up”—“I
will pick up the club.” The next line, “Two feet tied, two arms crossed,” suggests restraint or
prohibited access to the woman’s sexuality. The remaining lines, “I have a place boys don’t
know . . . below my mound” are a proclamation of virginity and chastity: “below my mound” is
translated from “anba ti vant mwen,” it literally means “below my little stomach.” In effect, the
girl may choose, “buy,” a penis to fondle, making it rise again and again, but her own genitals
have never been “known” by boys.
******
This song humorously summarizes the attitudes with which Jean Rabel women imbue their
sexuality. As with the other songs, it is a play on words, but words already very sexual. The
Kreyol term lamayet designates a sexy dance movement, and informants explained that it is
combined with the word mache (to function, operate, work) to form the implied verb “to
hump”—make the dance (lamayet) function, or less suggestively, to enable the girl to better
shake her hips. Lage literally means “to let go” and a Haitian male “come on” is lage-m nan
reyal la, which means “let me loose in your alley.” But in terms of money, a very common
colloquialism is lage sink goud nan min mwen (let a dollar go in my hand). Thus, lage li nan
riyèl la is a play on these two expressions and to state it literally it means “just throw the money
in my vaginal canal.” So the song is a rather ingenious circular play on words that reduced means
“I need two dollars. Why? Because if you want me to perform sex that is what it costs to get my
hips going. So just throw the two dollars right in my vagina.” The Jean Rabeliens who reviewed
these songs with me could hear this particular song several times in succession and would laugh
hysterically every time.
Conclusion
In previous chapters I showed that fertility rates in Jean Rabel compare favorably with the
highest rates ever recorded, those of the 19th and 20th century Hutterites. High fertility is
achieved in spite of the presence of factors that should suppress fertility, including the
absenteeism of men, free distribution of contraceptives by both government and private,
nonprofit agencies, and common physiological factors among Jean Rabel women such as STDs,
the practice of prolonged lactation, and malnutrition. I linked high fertility to the pronatal
sociocultural fertility complex. Both women and men exalt the blessings of having numerous
children, caress and laud the pregnant, ridicule the childless, scorn contraceptives, and
criminalize abortion. In this chapter it was shown that customs and beliefs in Jean Rabel
reinforce the pronatal sociocultural fertility complex: In spite of—or perhaps because of— male
absenteeism and male poverty, men are encouraged to be sexually aggressive; women are
rewarded and remunerated for sexual intercourse, while confining it to acceptable and financially
capable fathers; conflict over infidelity and ambiguous paternity are rationalized with fictive
illnesses and appeal to superstition and magic. These patterns of behavior are embedded in a
flexible type of sexual-material negotiation between men and women, what other scholars have
called “gendered capitalism” as well as part of a “field of competition” and that I referred to as
the sexual moral economy. It is this sexual moral economy that can be viewed as a substitute for
the stable male breadwinner seen among the Hutterites and not possible in Jean Rabel—not if
women are to achieve high levels of fertility.
The questions remain: a) how did these beliefs and behaviors come about, b) what and who
sustains them, and c) why, despite the obviously deteriorating economic and environmental
conditions and the readily available alternative of using birth control, do Jean Rabeliens continue
to avidly favor high fertility and display behaviors and beliefs that promote early and frequent
pregnancies among young women? Is it, as foreign experts often suggest, that they are tradition
bound, ignorant, unable to let go of deeply embedded values regarding large families? Or is there
another, more basic explanation? Could it be the economic utility of children so often denied in
the literature? Shedding light on this question requires a closer examination of the material
struggle for everyday existence that confronts farming men and women living in Jean Rabel.
*****
Notes
1. The exception is if, when her spouse enters into a union with another woman, the first wife
immediately severs the relationship. She then has a right to shamelessly enter into union with
another man, but she has sacrificed the house built by the first husband; see chapters 14–15.
2. The figures are from the baseline subsample, n = 136, 68 women and 68 men. In the baseline
sample (N = 1,586, missing = 146) the averages were 5.9 children per male household head
interviewed (875) and 5.2 children per female household head interviewed (560).
3. Credit for first reporting on perdisyon goes to Gerald Murray (1976), who convincingly
explained the phenomenon as the only theologically appropriate approach to treating fertility
because in Haiti the actual act of conception is entirely a matter for God (bon dieu) and,
therefore, folk healers must first diagnosis a pregnancy before they can begin to treat the
childless woman. When first reading Murray’s article as an undergraduate I was strongly
tempted to extend his observation to explain perdisyon as a belief maintained and reinforced by
women in union to justify pregnancy in the absence of their husbands, an especially appealing
explanation as Haiti has a history of over one hundred years of male wage migration. And I do
not argue with the notion that this may be one function that perpetuates the acceptance of the
belief in perdisyon. Nor does Murray doubt this occurs (personal communication). In a
discussion of the issue, anthropologist Ira Lowenthal affirmed that he knows at least six Haitian
women, all in union with men who claim to have experienced perdisyon and all invoked the
belief in the context of conception in their husband’s absence. I too have seen perdisyon used
this way in at least one instance. In my own research, however, the primary function of
perdisyon appears, as explained in the text, not to be a rationale for pregnancy but for barrenness.
Women typically decide they are experiencing perdisyon before they are really pregnant and it is
recognition of the condition at this stage that makes it authentic in the eyes of the woman’s
family, friends, and lovers. The condition is from that point on used to tag the next child born to
that particular man with whom she was having relations when perdisyon began.
In six of the eight cases of perdisyon reported in Makab, it was the woman’s first pregnancy, her
husband had at least one other madam (wife), and she explained her perdisyon as being induced
magically by one of her husband’s other wives. Treatment can get costly. It is understood that
Western-trained medical doctors generally do not recognize or believe in the affliction, but there
are medsin (herb doctors), matwons (midwives), manyè (massage specialists), and mambos and
bokors (shaman) who specialize in helping women to overcome perdisyon and get the fetus
growing again.
4. Accusations of magic go both ways. Both men and women can go to the bokor for a magic
spell or charm. A woman can jayjay—tame/brainwash/stupefy—a man with food cooked in
water with which she has bathed her genitals or food that has been covered with an unwashed
genital rag.
*****
Chapter 7
House, Yard, and Market
Introduction
In order to understand high fertility and the cultural complex of behaviors that reinforce it in Jean
Rabel, it is necessary to understand the economy in which it is embedded, for it is the economic
exigencies and opportunities that make children important in the struggle to survive in the Jean
Rabel harsh environment. Thus, this and the following three chapters describe the local market
system, occupations, and income.
It will be seen that despite decades of effort and tens of millions of dollars in development funds
described in chapter 3, contemporary Jean Rabel functions largely as an autonomous regional
economy with little involvement in the global market. The State provides no significant public
services to the population of the region. Houses are simple constructions of thatch, sticks, and
mud. The principal income-generating and subsistence activities are agriculture, livestock
raising, petty commerce, and charcoal production. Also, approximately 5 percent of the
population depends directly on fishing to make a living.
This does not mean, however, that Jean Rabeliens do not seek alternative sources of income
outside the household. A dazzling degree of specialization exists in both the production of local
material goods and provision of services. A minority of men earn relatively high incomes as
skilled craftsmen. Another alternative is seasonal agricultural work and most men at some point
in their lives migrate temporarily to urban areas, overseas, or to the Dominican Republic where
they work as menial wage laborers. Some women also go to the city and work as maids or cooks,
but local and migrant wage opportunities are fewer for women. The primary feminine
opportunity is marketing, something that all rural women eventually engage in, and something
that has the potential to put women on economically equal footing with men.
But in coming to understand these extra-household income earning opportunities one should
keep in mind that prerequisite to pursuing them is membership in a household production unit.
Life in Jean Rabelien—including extra-household endeavors activities—is embedding in a
materially simplicity adapted principally to minimizing risk in the face of drought and radically
unpredictable market conditions. Jean Rabeliens have no choice but to live in simple houses
constructed of inexpensive local materials, to employ inexpensive domestic and transport
technologies, and to preserve materially simplistic alternative strategies for meeting subsistence
needs. In order to provide for the most basic comforts and conveniences, such as furniture, tin
gas-lamps, and labor-saving devices such as graters and coffee strainers, Jean Rabeliens turn to a
flourishing regional marketing system. (Unless otherwise indicated, percentages assigned to
technologies defined below are based on findings from the 1,586 household Baseline Survey—
see chapter 1, p. 5)
Houses
Most houses in Jean Rabel are constructed from local materials. The walls are made of interlaced
sticks and are plastered inside and out with clay or lime (83%).1 Floors are generally dirt (87%)
and roofs are thatch (82%) derived from one of several types of palm or one of several types of
local grasses.2 A local vine is used to lash the poles of the house together. On average, the
houses contain two rooms (75%), one to six doors (85%), and one to four wooden-shuttered
window openings (64%).
It is a man’s task to build a house and there are several alternative housing styles and
construction methods. A rural house can cost from less than 500 gdes (US$30.00) to several
thousand Haitian dollars (US$1,000). On the expensive extreme, a man can purchase the land
and all necessary construction materials and contract labor for every task involved in building the
house. Cement, if used, is the most expensive item, but only the best houses are constructed
using cement. On the other extreme, a man with no property and little money is at liberty to build
a house on state land and can build the house almost entirely from foraged materials and with his
own labor and the help of family and friends. 3
Table 7.1: Regional distribution of market days in and around Jean Rabel
Figure 7.1: Market Villages
N
Atlantic Oc ean
x
k ot de fer
Village
J ean R abel
x x x
Ma W ouj
X Lac oma Pas k adebw a
x
Bab Pany ol
x
Beauc haun
x
La R es erv e
Note: Kot de Fer, Ma Wouj and Paskadebwa fall outside the Commune of Jean Rabel
[- - - -- -- -- -- ] = Commune boundaries
[ _________ ] = 10 km.
In Jean Rabel markets one finds not only piles of fruits and vegetables, but locally produced
beeswax candles, tin-can lamps, thatch brooms, ropes made of sisal or shredded food aid sacks,
tin graters and funnels, cloth coffee and juice strainers, locally crafted wooden mortars and
pestles, saddles, saddle blankets, saddlebags, bridles, ropes, baskets, grass sacks, sleeping mats,
scrap-iron bed frames, and wooden furniture. Locally produced castor oil is sold as a body lotion
and hair relaxer. Bundles of wood are sold as cooking fuel and tiny packets of split pitch pine are
sold as kindling. Domestic tobacco is sold in powder and leaf forms. Other locally produced
items found include clay pipes, domestic rum concocted with aromatic leaves, roots and spices,
homemade sweets made from peanuts, sesame seeds, melted brown sugar and manioc flour, and
rolls made with cane syrup and ginger.6,7
This is not to say that Jean Rabel markets are stocked entirely with local products. There are
also imported staples and necessities that people are able to purchase with their meager earnings:
pinto beans, flour, rice, hair ties, used clothing, shoes, wash basins, pots and pans, dishes,
drinking glasses, eating utensils, fragrant soaps, machetes, hoes, and kerosene. But whether
imported or produced locally, there are very few items sold in the rural Jean Rabel marketplaces
that do not relate directly to subsistence. One finds, for example, no bicycles, sporting goods,
toys, labor-saving appliances, art, radios, videos, music cassettes, sunglasses, or imported
gourmet foods. Nor does one find Hostess Twinkies or Lay’s potato chips or items considered
necessities by people elsewhere such as toilet paper, tissues, and maxi pads. There are no even
shampoo and deodorant are rarities. In summary, the Jean Rabel economy is not disconnected
from the world economy. But corrals of braying donkeys and trains of travelers who have walked
for half a day and some overnight to sell their livestock and produce is very much an early 21st
century anachronism. And it is very much oriented toward provisioning subsistence needs rather
than prestigious or pleasurable wants.
Consumption: Dependency on Household Production vs. the Market
Comparison of results from the Baseline Survey (labled GAFAW) with results from two other
large Jean Rabel surveys (PISANO 1990 and SCID 1993) shows that households consume more
than they sell for at least four of the six most commonly planted crops. But the fact that Jean
Rabeliens consume much of what they produce should not obscure their dependency on the
regional market. In the Opinion Survey, 86.3 percent of all respondents reported getting more of
the household food supply from the market than from gardens. And in the spring of 1998,
Thomas Hartmanship of the German NGO Agro Action Allemande captured the importance of
the market to Jean Rabeliens in a survey in which 128 randomly selected farmers in Jean Rabel
were asked, “Where do you most commonly get the produce consumed in your household?”
Only in the case of greens and fruits did respondents cite the garden as a more important source
of foodstuffs than markets (see tables 7.2 – 7.6).
This emphatically does not mean farmers are not producing enough for their own needs. As will
be seen below, farmers expect an impressive surplus in at least three out of every four years. The
point is that farmers sell their crops and use the money as a storage medium while also rolling
the cash over in the market, effectively earning additional income along the way.
If, for example, a Jean Rabelien is given a bag of rice, he/she will not stash it in a dark recess of
the house to be doled out bit by bit over a period of weeks or months. Rather, the rice is sent
straight to the market where the woman, her mother, or a younger female household member
converts it to cash. The cash obtained is then used to engage in other marketing activities and to
purchase other foods and provisions as needs arise.
In effect, the market system looms large in local household livelihood strategies. Virtually all
households are involved in the market system and while about one-half of most crops are
consumed by household members, the other half gets sold and the profits eventually spent on
food staples. Thus we can say that Jean Rabeliens are not subsistence farmers but best defined as
subsistence-oriented market producers.
Farming
No matter what other skills a person has or what other income-earning activities he or she
engages in, everyone in Jean Rabel, except for the very few full-time fishermen, is a farmer.
When asked to report the three most significant sources of household income, over 90 percent of
Jean Rabel respondents reported agriculture and 50 percent mentioned livestock. Every
household head owns or access to at least some garden land and every household has at least a
few animals. The farming technologies practiced are those best suited to surviving in the face of
an unpredictable environment characterized by drought and hurricane, absence of infrastructure,
absence of long-term storage facilities, and absence of effective state-sponsored extension
services or crisis management.
Specifically, the strategies are generalized, low-risk and low-investment strategies that provide
for household consumption, subsistence expenses, and little more. The point is, no matter how
one looks at the issue, farming is the backbone of the Jean Rabel economy, it provides a complex
of economic security otherwise unavailable in the face of economic, ecological, and social
insecurity, and it depends on social organization focused on the household and family.
Agriculture
Agriculture in Jean Rabel is a low-risk and low-input activity. Only 2 percent of farmers in the
baseline survey reported using chemical pesticides, and less than 1 percent reported using
chemical fertilizers. The only tools reportedly used by farmers were hoes and machetes. No
tractors, wagons, or even animal-drawn plows are available for use. Currently, not a single
irrigation pump exists in the entire commune of Jean Rabel, and only 40 out of 3,723 (0 .01%) of
the plots reported on in the baseline survey were irrigated by a gravity-driven system.8 As seen
earlier, crops planted in Jean Rabel are adapted to harsh environments. Relatively high yields of
these crops can be produced with minimal effort in a wide range of soil pH conditions, and they
tend to be resilient in the face of unpredictable rainfall patterns, and most importantly, periodic
drought. The five principal crops planted are corn, beans, sweet potatoes, cassava, and peanuts—
the same five crops most important to the Taino Indians who inhabited the area in pre-
Columbian times (Newsom 1993; Rouse 1992). To this basket of Taino domesticates early
colonists and slaves added three of the most drought resistant crops on the planet: sorghum,
millet, and pigeon peas, crops that continue to be of great importance to Jean Rabeliens, and the
lima bean, a quick growing, high yielding legume (Moreau 1797). Most of the crops do not
require simultaneous harvesting but rather are crops that yield slowly over a period of several
months or year round, making several staples available in the garden in every month of the year
(see table 7.5).
Table 7.5: Regional planting cycles on the plain Jean Rabel (H = harvest)
Fruit Trees
Crop harvesting cycles are complemented by the availability of produce from at least nineteen
types of fruit and nut trees, most of which are not planted deliberately but rather selectively
permitted to grow and the harvests of which conveniently fall during the leanest months for
garden produce. Fruits are sold in the markets for local consumption, they are given away freely
among friends and neighbors, and are consumed in abundance by everyone, especially children,
and particularly mangos, the unrivaled favorite fruit in Jean Rabel.9
100%
90% 91
86
80%
70%
60%
56
50%
40%
40
30%
Go at s Sh e ep Pi gs Ca tt le
Strategies for raising livestock are similar to those employed in agriculture: minimal costs,
minimal risks. The greatest livestock expense most farmers incur, besides actually purchasing the
animals, is the cords used to tether them (if the farmer decides to purchase rather than make the
cords, they cost 3 gdes per animal—US$0.15). Farmers plant clusters of drought-resistant native
grass called zeb gine (guinea grass) in their gardens and around their houses to be used as animal
fodder. Sugarcane b
+agasse and leaves, banana leaves, and pigeon pea foliage also provide high protein fodder
superior to most grasses. Corn, millet, and bean leaves and stalks are stored on rooftops; when
drought strikes, the stored fodder is moistened with salt water and fed to the animals. When
market prices are low, surplus garden produce, particularly sweet potatoes, mangos and bread
fruit, are fed to livestock rather than sold. Animals are grazed in gardens after harvests or
tethered in fallow fields. With the exception of pigs—the one animal sometimes fattened on
purchased supplements—farmers only purchase feeds during prolonged crises, and these are
invariably grasses or garden refuse found in neighboring ecological zones.10
Livestock serves primarily as a cash reserve for the household. When an animal is slaughtered,
much of the meat gets sold, primarily to provide for other subsistence needs. In the Baseline
Survey, the single most frequently cited reason for both killing and selling animals was so that
other food could be purchased with the proceeds from the sale of the surplus meat.11
The months most commonly cited as times of animal slaughter and sale are precisely those
months householders identify as the hardest/leanest of the year, the same months that crop
harvests are at a minimum. The relationship between hard times, animal slaughter, and animal
sales only deviates slightly when schools open in September and October and tuition payments
come due (see figure 7.8 below).
Figure 7.8: Months animals are sold and slaughtered by lean months
Months
MonthsAnimals aresold
animals are Sold,
andSlaughtered bylean
slaughtered by Lean Months
months
number of respondents 1250
1000 Sell
Slaughter
750 Lean Months
500
250
0
Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec
Months
months
Conclusion
The opinions of some aid experts to the contrary, the ethnographic fact is that daily life in Jean
Rabel is heavily dependent and deeply involved in farming. It is these conditions that, it will be
seen, give way to the particular kinship and family structures found in the area, and it is the
failure to identify them and accurately understand what they mean for social life that has
inhibited an understanding of rural Haitians. Low income levels and the need to maintain a
degree of self-sufficiency in the face of impending drought and uncertain market opportunities
mean that Jean Rabeliens have little choice but to employ inexpensive domestic and transport
technologies and to reserve alternative strategies for obtaining material necessities. They walk or
ride pack animals, sometimes for several days, to get where they are going and their houses are
simple constructions of thatch, sticks, and mud. In order to satisfy subsistence needs and provide
for the most basic comforts and conveniences, such as furniture, tin gas lamps, and labor-saving
devices such as graters and coffee strainers, they turn to a flourishing regional marketing system.
The Jean Rabel economy is free from dependency on outside goods and services and this
autonomy occurs at two levels: the regional level and the household level. At the regional level
there is a thriving system of exchange, monetarily based, and characterized by the production of
local goods and a rotating market system. At the household level, people do not depend on any
public service. Every material item and every service that can be purchased also has a cost-free
substitute. Soap can be replaced by special leaves, and a sleeping mat, instead of being purchased
in the local market, can be made at home. Even houses, the single greatest lifetime expense for
most Jean Rabeliens, can be constructed almost completely independent of nondomestic, paid
labor or imported materials. None of this means that Jean Rabeliens live in a system completely
shut off from the outside world. Imported staples, for example, can be found in all regional
marketplaces, most notably imported rice, beans, and flour, which to varying degrees Jean
Rabeliens purchase and consume; and imported plastic items such as hair berets and perfumes
are common in the market. What it does mean is that Jean Rabeliens have recourse to a
remarkable degree of autonomy and even self-sufficiency at the level of the household and they
are also eager participants in an equally remarkable local economy that can be conceptualized as
a regional subsistence market system. In the following chapter, I want to take a look at the
income that the most basic household-based livelihood strategies generate, for, in the
competition for development funds, aid workers and researchers have often exaggerated and
misused income data as well.
*****
Notes
1. Wattle and daub, sticks woven together and plastered with mud, lime or cement. Most
kitchens are also constructed in this way but without being plastered.
2. Local names for types of thatch: kokoye, latanye, and pay la preskil. Local names for grasses:
zeb gini, zeb kos, zeb able, and zeb kanna.
Roofs have to be patched frequently but not uncommonly endure upward of four decades and in
at least one instance a grass roof was reported to be seventy years old, albeit it had been added to
over the years.
3. The process of building a house usually goes as follows: Branches for house supports and the
I-beam that holds the house together are cut from living trees that belong to the man, begged off
a friend, or purchased from the market. For the walls, a man gathers rocks or, if the house is
going to be wattle and daub, sticks (galata is a common source of sticks; see below). For plaster,
he makes his own lime by cooking lime rocks, or if he cannot find lime rocks, he uses clay,
which is abundant in the area (preferably a white clay). His wife or future wife, mother,
grandmother, sisters, and other female relatives, neighbors, and friends will likely carry dirt and
sand as needed. The dirt and sand is mixed with lime or clay to make a weak cement. In some
areas like La Presque’Ile near Mole St. Nicolas, the man may harvest his own roof thatch or he
can use Guinea grass found on State lands. In most areas thatch from the Royal Palm is sold for
2-3 gdes per bundle and a typical house can be covered with about four hundred bundles. The
vines that lash the house poles together can be gathered in the bush and the poles that form the
roof platform are usually from galata, a very straight branch derived from a kind of sisal plant
that is ubiquitous on the dry State lands (kadas). Of course, all the materials can be purchased,
but the only materials that typically cannot, if necessary, be foraged are the locally hewn boards
used to make window shutters and doors.
To build the house: Neighbors and family, enticed by free rum, are assembled to help erect the
frame. The main poles are planted several feet in the ground. Other framing poles are nailed to
these. At this point the structure is a standard rectangular house skeleton with a simple A-frame
roof. (Friends and neighbors typically fade away at this time, returning to help when the roof is
put on.) The doors and windows are then framed, most often by a paid boss. The galata branches
are laid across the roof and lashed with vine to the house frame and then the thatch, strung on
lengths of vine, three leaves to a length, is fastened to the house. Then the walls go up. If the
walls are rock, the rocks are cemented together with lime or clay mixed with sand and dirt; if the
walls are what is locally called klisay, then sticks are horizontally interlaced between vertical
poles. Doors and windows are then framed and the structure is plastered inside and out with pure
clay or lime. The jobs for which bosses are typically employed are framing the house and
framing the doors and windows; masonry, if the house is stone; and as mentioned, hanging the
doors and windows.
Three examples are given below taken from friends of the author. The first man built a small 9.5
x 15 (ft) house, a typical two-room structure. The man hired both a carpenter and a mason. He
was nevertheless able to realize a considerable savings by digging his own clay/mud/plaster,
cooking his own lime, and gathering vines himself. The man also gathered poles, galata, and
thatch from trees growing on his property. He felled a tree for boards and his father, a
professional sawyer, sawed the boards free of charge.
The house listed below is the other extreme of the rural houses. It is not the grand cement houses
as seen in small villages but it is the upper scale of the rural houses and almost all the material
and many of the services were purchased. It was built by a woman whose husband was away
working in Port-de-Paix but who sent her money to construct the house. It is 10 x 22 feet:
Wild yams: dala (manje siklon, grate li kom manioc ame), chat, galata
Wild beans, greens and stalks: piyant (used as a kind of coffee), karaibe, doliv, laman, epina
wouj , lyann panye, kou pye, lalo, chou mantad, chou kore, kresan, konkonm, zeb egwi, bondye
bay, wild cabbage
Fruits that grow on vines: Militon, Grenadia
Tree seed pods that are eaten from trees during crisis: bwa fè (grenn), bwa dom (grenn nan
kos), bwa blan (grenn nan kos—tankou pistach), tamarin (kouvre grenn nan kos), and brizie
(grenn)
Fruit trees: unripened corosol and and green mangos are also eaten during times
of crisis, guayav, chou palmis, zamond, kenep, papay, korosol zombi, kachima, kayimit (2) pye
bwa, manje fri, seriz/cherries, siwal
Wild animals: liza (iguana), chat (feral cat), pentad (guinea fowl), toutril (turtle
dove), and any other bird they can catch except those listed below:
Birds not eaten: kwak blanch (cow egret), karanklou (buzzard), serpante, kone–gen gwo, gen
piti (unknown)
6. Tobacco was grown abundantly in the region until the last decade when a disease reportedly
made planting tobacco unprofitable. One still finds small plots of tobacco but it is not the
industry it reportedly used to be. Much tobacco in the region, and in much of Haiti, comes from
the Kass market place on the Central Plateau. The Kass market is only three kilometers from the
border with the Dominican Republic and it is possible that low grade tobacco is purchased from
the Dominicans and sold in Kass and it also possible that some tobacco grown in Kass in sold on
the Dominican side of the border. But most people report very little cross border trade in
tobacco. The people in the region of Kass explain that Dominican Tobacco is not the same kind
as Haitians prefer and vice versa. Further, there is a tremendous amount of tobacco grown nearby
on the some fifteen thousand hectares of mud flat that used to be the upper reaches of Lake
Peligre—formed by the Peligre hydroelectric dam on the Artibonite river.
7. Up until 1986, rum was distilled locally. Today, raw rum is imported from Leogone. There is
little trade with Cape Haitian, the alternative source (another large rum-producing area).
8.
Table 7.13: Crops by use of chemical pesticides and fertilizers
Note: Units of analysis = crops
9. Mangos originated in India and were introduced sometime during the colonial period.
Breadfruit (as well as sisal) came from the South Pacific and is believed to have been first
brought to the Caribbean in 1792 by the famous Captain Bligh—three years after his fabled
“mutiny on the Bounty” voyage. Avocados originated in the Mexican highlands but by colonial
times there was a West Indian variety (see Encyclopedia Britannica).
10. Chickens and other poultry are fed grains by owners not to fatten them up but as a means of
keeping them near the house (pou yo pa al lwenn)—most of what chickens eat is what they find
on their own, i.e., insects, grass seeds, and vegetal refuse.
Pigs are the one special case of an animal requiring high investments, such as vitamin and feed
supplements, to be profitable. This makes pigs a problem for people disinclined to make
monetary investments in their livestock. As one man told the author; kochon gen plis kob pase
tout bet min yo reme mouri twop (pigs yield more money than all animals but they like to die too
much), which makes them a losing investment for most Jean Rabel farmers. Evidence for the
lack of interest and the failing success of pig raising in Jean Rabel comes from recent projects
promoting investment in hogs.
11. People in Jean Rabel do not make cheeses or other products from goat milk, but 36.1 percent
of people reported milking goats for home consumption—something the author has never seen
and is somewhat skeptical about.
Cow owners do not make cheese, butter, or yogurt from cow’s milk—presumably because of low
milk fat production related to the lack of high protein feeds and deteriorating quality of grazing
land. But, people possessing cows reported milking for home consumption and local sale—
something the author has seen often and is not skeptical about. The milk is boiled with cinnamon
sticks and salt added.
*****
Chapter 8
Farming and Household-Based Production
Introduction
At the time of this research, the UN listed per capita annual income in Haiti as US$398, making
it far and away the poorest country in the Western hemisphere; estimates for Jean Rabel were
lower, ranging from US$100.00 per household (UNOPS 1997) to US$350.00 per household
(CARE 1996; see also CARE 1997), meaning that with an average of just under six people per
household, even CARE’s more liberal estimate translates to an annual per capita income of
US$60, giving Jean Rabel an income level one-sixth of that of Haitians overall and only slightly
higher than the two lowest per capita GDPs in the world—the Democratic Republic of the Congo
at US$52 and Sudan at US$59 (Stepick 1982; CARE 1996; United Nations 2000, 2007).
The use of such measurements as indices of human misery, suggesting squalor and the need for
intervention, are erroneous. What they measure are remunerated employment and involvement in
the world economy. They tell us little about living standards in terms of health, nutrition, leisure
time, happiness, and social security. The significance of this will be returned to in later chapters
for it is precisely this type of Western-based standards that bias our understanding of life in
places like Jean Rabel, where people have gardens and animals, where they forage for plants and
small animals and where they have their own thriving internal regional economies and are loath
to report income.
Moreover, even when measures of income are based on surveys, such as the cited data for Jean
Rabel, these surveys are often conducted with few controls and invariably embedded in fund-
soliciting campaigns sponsored by organizations dependent on foreign aid. For example, the
estimate of US$100 annual per household income came from UNOPS (United Nations Office of
Project Services)—an organization whose employees depend on projects funded by the UN—
translating to per capita US$17; a ridiculously low sum of 4 cents per day. How the UN aid
workers came up with these estimates is a mystery. They cite no source for the data, and they
discuss no systematic study of household income in the region.
The CARE estimate is problematic as well. CARE (the largest multinational charity in the world
and the NGO with an exclusive on U.S.-government-funded charity activities in Jean Rabel) was
lavishly funded by the U.S. government (more than US$250,000) to come up with the cited
household estimate (US$350 per household per year; or 15 cents per day per person). The
calculation came from a study of northwest Haiti, and involved a sophisticated, 1,400-household
cluster sample in which twenty-six communities were visited by teams of university-educated
Haitian interviewers. Focus groups were held in each community and a large number of local
households were subsequently visited to interview the breadwinners and obtain precise details
regarding household expenses and income. The study was vitiated by an inclination for
respondents to conceal their wealth and a lack of initiative on the part of CARE to correct for
this. For example, in the fishing hamlet of Makab where I lived for eighteen months, CARE
interviewers reported that less than 20 percent of households owned livestock. But when I began
my research one year later, there were in fact only two of a total of forty-three households that
did not own at least one goat or sheep. One member of the community, a man who villagers
report was included in the survey, had upwards of one hundred goats, a detail that was not
reflected in the CARE report.1 Thus, if these findings can be generalized to other communities
studied by CARE and UNOPS, the image of Jean Rabel households spending a daily average of
US$0.96 is an underestimate. The question is then, how much of an underestimate?
Agricultural Income
In order to estimate income from agriculture we need to first know three things: average
holdings, types of garden, and yields.
Average Holdings
The mean garden size in Jean Rabel is .82 hectares and at any one time the average household
works 2.8 gardens on a total of 2.3 hectares of land. On the other hand, the average amount of
land reportedly owned per household is 1.13 kawo or 1.46 hectares (1 kawo =1.29 hectares)—the
difference being attributable to sharecropping and underreporting of landownership. Almost one-
third of respondents, 413 households, reported owning no land; 87.7 percent of households own
2 kawo or less; and 1.1 percent of households claimed to own more than 5 kawo of land. The
number of landless farmers is suspect and probably a consequence of deceptive reporting—some
respondents expected that the survey would be followed by food-aid distribution to the poorest
households. should not be interpreted to mean that land is concentrated. The largest landholder in
the sample owned only 12 kawo, and there are no larger plantations or vast tracks of private land
in Jean Rabel.
Type of Garden
While the vast majority of land is “dry,” there is nevertheless another 4.7 percent of garden land
considered “fertile” and “irrigated.” On these plots farmers can naturally expect higher and more
dependable yields. Table 8.2 above sums up the types of land tenure—i.e., how farmers obtained
access to their garden plots.
500
400 410
387
300 305
Count
200 206
100
99
54
0
1.0 2.0 3.0 4.0 5.0 6.0 7.0 8.0 9.0 10.0
In the Polygyny Survey, which included questions on livestock not adequately addressed in other
surveys, the average farming household possessed 3.1 adult goats, 2.5 sheep, .8 cows, and 1.1
donkeys. Assuming that goats and sheep can yield a mean three offspring per year (the average is
three litters of two kids per litter, every two years) and that a cow or donkey has approximately
.8 calves per year, then the typical household earns about 4,465 gdes annually on its weaned
livestock (US$266). This figure does not include the most prominent animal in Jean Rabel,
poultry, or the most expensive horses, donkeys, and pigs.2
Similar to agriculture, livestock provides a broad spectrum of income-earning opportunity among
different households. Household earnings from livestock are based on the number of animals a
household unit can successfully tend. For the sake of demonstrating these differences, at the
bottom of table 8.6 is the tabulated total annual revenue for a household that has one of each
animal listed—i.e., one goat, one sheep, one cow, and one hog. The same estimates can be used
to calculate projected income from livestock for a hypothetical household with two of each
animal, or three, and so on. The calculations are not meant to reflect exact actual conditions—
there is, for example, no particular reason why a household would own two goats, two sheep,
two pigs, and two cows—but percentages given are based on actual number of animals
reportedly owned by households included in the Polygyny Survey, and the figures demonstrate
the economic differences that result from one household having the capacity to care for more
livestock than another.
Special mention is required regarding pigs, an animal that has tremendous but seldom-realized
income-earning potential. Piglets sell for 250 gdes (US$14.88), meaning that a litter of ten can
yield the owner(s) a respectable 2,500 gdes (US$148.80), and a single well-fed pig sold in the
Port-de-Paix market can fetch as much as 6,000 gdes (US$357.14). But most farmers do not have
the capital available to provide feeding pigs nutritionally sufficient quantities of food to breed or
to grow to a significant size, and so most pigs are bought, raised, and then sold as stunted adults
for approximately 750 gdes (US$50.68). For the latter reason, I have limited the income in table
8.6 calculated for pigs to 750 gdes per animal.
Conclusion
An analysis of household livelihood strategies and income shows that while people in rural Haiti
may be poor, they are not as poor as portrayed neither by intervention experts and charity
workers nor as suggested in many reports and statistics submitted by aid agencies. Nor are
people in Jean Rabel helplessly sitting around waiting for the next shipment of food aid. On the
contrary, they are earnestly engaged in trying to survive and assure security in the face of an
unpredictable and harsh environment. The basis of this survival is farming livelihood strategies
focused on the household.
The significance of these strategies cannot be gainsaid. There is nothing secure in Jean Rabel
beyond the limits of the household. There is no dependable State to provide aid, job security, or
unemployment insurance. Foreign intervention agencies, who have come to help, are not there to
provide welfare services and the unhappy fact is that even in times of crisis they reach a very
small portion of the population; have actually acted as agents of foreign agricultural interests
seeking new markets. Individual security, food, and shelter, all depend on being a member of a
household. The only people who are not members of a household are a few mentally disturbed
individuals called pov (poor), easily spotted in their shabby straw hats and scraggly, matted hair;
a bowl in hand for begging coins, they wander from market to market, and sleep on the tiny front
porches of nicer houses and in churches—and, interestingly, they are very few.
People who sell and purchase in markets are invariably operating on behalf of a household. The
produce, livestock, cooked foods, and artisan goods sold are the fruits of the combined efforts of
household members, and the vast bulk of the proceeds from the sale of these products will be
returned to the household in the form of food purchases and items needed to continue household
production—such as saddles, ropes for livestock, seeds, and tools for the garden.
Some households are able to derive greater income from these activities than other households.
But although the emphasis thus far has been on the potential economic differences between
households, an equally remarkable feature is the general narrowness of these differences. No
household for which data was gathered had planted more than eleven gardens and no household
owned more than 12 kawo of land. The maximum number of cattle belonging to any of the
households visited during the Polygyny Survey was six; the maximum number of goats,
fourteen; the maximum number of sheep, twelve; the maximum number of hogs, eight. No
household owned more than four donkeys, two horses, or two mules. The explanation for the
relatively equal distribution of wealth among households is simply that, in rural Jean Rabel,
despite soil exhaustion and the declining availability of new land, the balance between the three
primary elements of production—land, labor, and capital—is skewed most heavily by a scarcity
of labor, the subject of a subsequent chapter.
But there is another level of economic activity beyond the household and that has a determining
impact on social life, kinship, and family structure: fishing, specialized retail marketing, and
craftsmanship. I begin with a chapter on fishing to show what income-generating options are
available beyond the household, to what degree people use them, and how much income they
earn, for it is in understanding differences in extra-household income-generating opportunities
that we can get an idea of the causes underlying specific kinship patterns in Jean Rabel,
especially with regard to conjugal union.
Notes
1. It was also not clear if CARE analysts were aware of the fact that fully 65% of male household
heads in the community had more than one wife with whom they had borne children, who they
continued to help support, and who they considered as a spouse; i.e., they had more than one
family. The wives resided in multiple households, some within the fishing hamlet but most in
other fishing villages and in isolated hillside homesteads. If CARE researchers were aware of
this fact, they did not reveal it nor, of course, did they specify how they dealt with it in their
analysis.
2. Chickens are raised for consumption and sale; secondarily for eggs that are eaten and sold.
Depending on its size, a chicken sells for 15 to 100 gdes (US$0.89 to 5.95). Goats and sheep are
raised primarily for sale. Kids and lambs sell for 200 to 250 gdes (US$11.90 to 14.88); an adult
goat or sheep sells for 300 to 1,000 gdes (US$17.86 to 58.52). Both animals are also slaughtered
for consumption, especially goats and especially when a woman has given birth. The meat is
often dried for short-term storage or resale. After chickens, goats are the animal most commonly
slaughtered in association with religious ritual. Pigs fetch the highest price of any livestock
raised for sale. Piglets sell for 200 to 500 gdes (US$ 11.90 to 29.76); and an adult pig can sell for
as much as 6,000 gdes (US$ 357.14). Pigs are almost always sold rather than slaughtered for
consumption in association with religious rituals. To be profitable, pigs demand large
investments in feed and veterinary services: 27.5% of all pig owners reported using veterinary
services and medicines, the highest use of veterinary services for any animal. Cattle sell for
2,500 to 4,500 gdes (US$148.80 to 267.86); a calf sells for 1,000 to 1,500 gdes (US$ 58.52 to
89.29). Depending on size, strength, and age, the price of a donkey ranges from 500 to 2,500
gdes (US$29.76 to 148.81). The price of a horse ranges from 1,000 to 4,000 gdes (US$58.52 to
238.10). And the price of a mule, the most prized pack animal, ranges from 1,750 to 7,500 gdes
(US$ 104.17 to 446.43). Horses, donkeys, and mules are the prime means of transportation and
are reportedly never eaten or slaughtered. Even a sick or injured donkey, horse, or mule is simply
left to die rather than euthanized.
3. Goats and sheep have a gestation period of 148–150 days and give birth about three times
every two years, meaning six kids. They browse on almost anything, but sheep are reportedly
more finicky and less hardy than goats. At ten months either a sheep or a goat can be bred. They
have twenty-one-day menstrual cycles. Cattle have a gestation period of 280–283 days.
*****
Chapter 9
Fishing
Introduction
Fishing involves a relatively high investment in local materials and craftmanship services. Many
of the materials needed must be purchased but some may be procured cost-free by resourceful
individuals. Fishermen do not have access to outboard motors, fiberglass hulls, or refrigerated
storage. Instead, sails, paddles, and wooden hulls prevail, and fish are salted, dried, and sold in
local markets or hauled by boat or pack animal to markets in the provincial city of Port-de-Paix.
Nevertheless, based on local standards, fishing is a significant source of income.
Fishing Communities
Fishing-dependent families comprise 4.4 percent of the Jean Rabel population or about 5,800
men, women and children (roughly one thousand households), most of whom are also dependent
to varying degrees on their gardens and livestock raising.
They live in two permanent fishing villages in protected harbors on the coast of Jean Rabel (Bord
Mer and Port-al-Acu) or in semi-permanent encampments along the arid coastal region stretching
from Bord Mer west for approximately seven kilometers. The posts are almost entirely inhabited
by people from farming communities who learned to fish by visiting their cousins in fishing
hamlets and then struck out on their own, spending the fishing season in the most remote and
often most productive sites where they build small lean-to like houses called joupas. Some of the
men remain full time at the outposts. A steady trickle of wives, children, and cousins of the
fishing-farmers come down to the posts to retrieve the fish and carry them back into hillside
communities to be sold in the market.
Fishing Vessels
Farmers who fish part time use rudely fashioned one-man kayaks called topye. More heavily
invested fishermen use kanots, row boats that average 11.5 feet in length.
In all of Jean Rabel there are some seventy kanots and 350 topye, small kayaks that are
approximately eight feet in length. The most modern material on boats in Jean Rabel are nails:
the smallest vessels are the topye kayaks, mentioned above, that are made of three logs lashed
and nailed together. Row boats are less common but more important: the hulls are made from
locally harvested and hewn oak, avocado, or a wood known locally as sad. For a waterproof
sealant, fishermen buy a fiberglass-type substance called brè, derived from the nut of a local tree.
When heated over a fire, brè becomes a sticky tar-like paste that cools to a hard glass (brè is also
used as a coating for iron goods such as latches and hinges, and to repair leaky water buckets).
Strips of cloth are dipped in the brè while it is hot and then pounded with a wooden mallet into
the spaces between the boards from which the boat is fashioned. The entire hull is then coated
with the resin. Oars are made of wooden poles with an oval length of board lashed to the end. A
corn cob or piece of wood serves as a drain plug; a discarded plastic bowl or kalbas gourd is used
to bail the boat. On larger vessels—also simply constructed and of which there are only four in
the region—a manual bilge pump is fashioned from a length of bamboo or PVC, a wooden pole,
and a goat skin, which looks and works like an inverted plunger. Sails are sewn together from
used denim. The occasional boat motor in Jean Rabel fishing communities is usually a gift from
some overseas relative, but is invariably a short-lived luxury that gets sold or stored away the
first time it breaks. There are three compressors in the region but they all belong to the same
man, a resident of the Island of La Tortue who supplies Port-au-Prince restaurants with seafood.
Income
The principal means of catching fish is with weirs, known locally as nas, and fishermen calculate
in terms of each weir. The weirs are bamboo, held together with vine. They cost from 30 gdes for
the smallest to 85 gdes for the largest weirs. Fishermen pay other men to transport the weirs from
the market to the fishing hamlets—carrying weirs being considered below the dignity of a
respectable fisherman—and for a weir to be carried from the market to most coastal settlements
costs a maximum of 30 gdes for a large weir and 15 gdes for a small weir. The weir does not
come preassembled but must be woven together with vine (5 gdes). A durable waterproof rope is
made from the nylon threads of shredded food-aid sacks and is needed to raise and lower the
weir (108 gdes), and for the floating nas four one-gallon jugs are needed (20 gdes); four sticks to
make a frame so that the weir can be raised and lowered into the sea without collapsing under its
own waterlogged weight (4 gdes); and a sack of rocks for an anchor (5 gdes).
The lifetime of a weir is approximately equivalent to the duration of the fishing season, about
four and a half months. But weirs are sometimes swept away by currents, stolen by thieves, and
destroyed by big fish and moray eels that get to the catch before the fisherman. All this makes it
difficult to estimate how much a weir will yield. The poorest fishermen tend to estimate 150–400
gdes, but the wealthiest and most knowledgeable fishermen—some of whom actually keep
records—consistently estimate that, lost weirs factored in, a large weir yields on average 1,000
gdes over the course of the rekolt. This later estimate makes the most sense if one considers the
investment in money and time. Deducting the cost of the weir (247 gdes), the lifetime yield is
743 gdes. Thus for three to six months (average 135 days) the average daily yield per weir is 5.1
gdes. A fisherman usually needs at least one helper, which means he must give him some of the
fish—usually a fourth to a third of the catch. So before totaling, 30 percent of income must be
deducted which brings the income down to 3.6 gdes per weir per day. Most fishermen will work
a couple weirs during the off season, but during the most intense months of the rekolt—
September thru November—fishermen who own their own boats typically work twenty weirs,
about 72 gdes per day (US$4.30).1 Men without boats, women, and even children will have three
or four weirs that are checked by husbands, cousins, or kanot-owning neighbors.
Sen (seines), the long nets used for shore fishing, and filè (simple nets) that are set farther out to
sea or along the cliff-lined coasts, both presuppose that a fisherman has a kanot. Owning a sen is
the economic pinnacle of fishing in the region. Because of the high winds and often violent shore
break, there are only three seines within the commune of Jean Rabel, but during the fish rekolt
some men go to nearby Mole St. Nicolas, where there is a large protected harbor and fishing is
significantly different than along the exposed Jean Rabel coast. At the “Mol,” there are seventeen
seines varying in length from 160 to 400 meters, with an average of 300 meters and a cost of
about 50,000 gdes.2
Based on books kept for five seines at nearby Mole St. Nicolas, the average yield per seine in
1998 was 30,000 gdes (US$1,786). But 1998 was an off year, and seine owners report an average
closer to 40,000 (US$2,381) gdes per year . Half of the catch (20,000 gdes) goes to the owner of
the seine and half goes to the crew. This means that for the approximately 408 men who have a
secured place hauling in seines at the Mol every year, their average income from this particular
activity is 833 gdes (or US$50). For the owners of seines, income is substantially more. With an
estimated annual repair cost of approximately 5,000 gdes per year, seine owners earn about
15,000 gdes (US$893)—of course they have other expenses as well, specifically boats of which
they need at least one (US$93 has been deducted as an approximate cost of a boat over its ten+
year lifetime).3
Nets are less expensive, shorter than seines, more portable, and do not need a position; hence
they are more common, especially among fishermen in the commune of Jean Rabel, who only
have a few rarely used seines. Nets are put anywhere that seems opportunistic. They can be left
overnight or simply left and checked daily like a nas. The average net is about seventy meters
long and five meters deep and cost about 1,500 gdes (US$90).4 Serious fishermen earn about
5,000 gdes per season per net. During the winter months, when lobster migrate from deeper
waters, and provided there are buyers, some net fishermen earn windfalls as high as one
thousand Haitian dollars in a single catch. The calculations have been omitted for these
unpredictable windfalls. I focus instead on more consistent earnings, specifically, fishermen with
nets go on what are called boukan (an apparent linguistic survival from the buccaneer era), where
they camp out in remote coastal villages. Women also go along and they salt and dry the fish.
On a boukan a boat usually has four marin (mariners) and a net. The marin set the net up
overnight and check it in the morning. They sometimes spend the day trying to round fish up by
swimming and slapping the water, trying to drive the fish into the net (called bat dlo, beating the
water, in Creole). As with seines, the catch is split 50/50 between owner and crew—owner gets
50 percent and the crew gets 50 percent—the difference, however, is the owner takes out the
costs of damages to the net before the catch is split. On local boukan (Kapafou, Lapreskil, La
Grenad, Las Kayo) a net owner can earn from 250 to 1,000 gdes. Marin earn 75 to 350 gdes.
Boats usually go on two local boukan a year, for five to eight days each, in the months of
November and December.
In the months of January to May, after the local fishing season is over, many of the full-time
fishermen in the region go to the island of La Tortue on the north coast, where they have second
or third—and in some cases fourth and fifth—wives. There a kanot with a net can reportedly
make from 15,000 gdes to 25,000 gde in a season. This usually means about 9,000 gdes for the
owner of the net and kanot, 3,000 gdes for each marin and 2,000 gdes for damages to the net.
It is important to understand the significance of owning a boat and nets or a sein. In general,
kanot in the region range from 11 to 16 feet long and the regional average is 13.5 feet (a boat
longer than 18 feet is called a chat and is used for transport). A kanot costs from 3,500 gdes to
12,500 gdes.5 In Makab, three of twenty-one boats kept there were owned by women. But it is
usually men who own the boats and it is always men who fish. The small kayaks mentioned
above are only good for small weirs and line fishing and they sell for 500 gdes.
A boat is the first and most important ingredient in serious fishing and a significant indicator of
wealth and the factors that set one man apart from another. In Makab, the only polygynous man
who was not a boat owner was a healer. Most weirs belong to men. Women whose husband or
sons fish may invest in weirs and some weirs will be assigned to a child. But it is always a man
who raises and checks weirs.
By local standards, fishing is a significant source of income. As seen in table 9.1, a fisherman
who owns his own boat, a net, and fishing weirs earns about US$1,268, about twice the US$679
that the average farmer can expect.
Conclusion
Fishing in Jean Rabel is a technologically basic endeavor in that most resources are procured
locally or derived from scrapped industrial goods. Nevertheless, compared to farming it requires
a large investment and yields congruently high income. A fisherman who owns his own boat, a
net, and fishing weirs, is on a financial level equivalent with or greater than that of farmers and
even skilled craftsmen seen in the following chapter. Moreover, although most fishermen are
also dependent to varying degrees on farming strategies, the income they earn and the fact that it
is earned independently of the household and contributions from other household members—
most importantly their spouse—allow many of them to engage in conjugal union with more than
one woman. In subsequent chapters I will take a closer look at the relationship between income,
how it is earned, and conjugal unions. But first there are several other very important sources of
income.
*****
Notes
. In the 1999 fishing season, six men in Makab—men with kanots—had the following number of
weirs: Mirabo, twenty; Francois, fourteen; Lanyo, thirty-five; Albè, twenty; Joseph, twenty-two;
Antonio, fifteen.
2.
Table 9.2: Cost of 300 meter seine in Haitian dollars (1 Haitian dollar = gdes: 1 US dollar
(1999) = 16.8 gdes )
3. Most financial and catch information on seines is based on Obreun, the largest seine owner in
the region. Obreun has a university degree in fisheries. In 1998 he earned 74,900 gdes for all five
of his seines. Another 74,900 gdes—the other half of the catch—went to the 120 marins who
hauled in the seines. He paid 26,860 gdes in reparations. He reports, however, that in a normal
year he grosses between 100,000 and 200,000 gdes (an equivalent sum going to the marins).
Obreun reports that farming is much more lucrative for him, irrigated land he inherited being his
biggest earner. Note that the seines do not yield him a great deal; if he makes US$20,000 in a
very good year on all five seines and pays US$6,000 for reparations, he is left with US$14,167.
Furthermore, this is indisputably among the three wealthiest men in the region, giving one an
idea of the upper limits of income.
Note also that, except in the gran mer (the ocean), fisherman at the “Mol” do not use the floating
nas.
4. There are two kinds of filè: filè twa nap and filè sinmp. A filè twa nap is essentially thre layers
of netting and the filè sinmp is only one layer of netting. The former is made of thicker nylon
string (#9 and #36); the latter is made of finer #6 and #9 nylon string:
5. In Jean Rabel, kanots are smaller because seines, which require larger boats, are scarce. In
Jean Rabel, the average local kanot is about 11 feet and the cost is 3,500 to 7,500 gdes
*****
Chapter 10
Work, Craftsmen, and Marketing Specialists
Introduction
As seen in chapter 8, agriculture and livestock rearing are the most important economic activities
in Jean Rabel. Literally everyone is somehow involved in farming and, when asked to report the
three most significant sources of household income, over 87 percent of Jean Rabel respondents
reported agriculture, and 50 percent mentioned livestock. But these were not the only sources of
income: 45 percent cited commerce as the most important source, 20 percent mentioned charcoal
production, 15 percent mentioned manual labor, and 12 percent mentioned “professional,” which
here includes both skilled labor and teaching. In this chapter I deal with these other categories of
income. Unlike farming strategies, which are relatively equal opportunities based on household
organization strategies, these other income-generating activities are more akin to fishing in that
they are performed outside of the household, and access to and success at such activities are
based on political contacts, age, sex, skill, and work ethic. Differential economic opportunity and
success create differentials in social power and it will be seen in a later chapter that in examining
the behavior of these individuals, the most economically active who by dint of their control over
others—or dint of others who control them—are a vital determinant of family structure and
kinship patterns.
Most specialists, men and women, work for the smallest pittance. For example, it costs 2 gdes
(US$.12) for the sewing up of a pair of sandals, 1 gde (US$.06) for a sweet roll, 1 gde for a cup
of coffee, 7.5 gdes (US$.45) for a session of sorcery, 6 gdes for a twenty-foot rope, 5 gdes for a
lamp, and 25 gdes (US$1.50) for a chair. Basket and hat makers earn no more than 10 to 15 gdes
per day (US$0.60 to US$0.89). Successful healers are often the wealthiest individuals in an area,
but most herb doctors and midwives earn respect but little money. A midwife for example makes
50 gdes (US$3.00) per birth and is lucky to get one birth per month. A manyè (type of masseuse)
makes two or three gdes a consultation (US$.12 to $.18) and is lucky to have one consultation
per day—which will probably require a walk of several miles. One compensation for the low
fees is that service specialists generally must be fed and men are given rum while they work. But
the actual labor cost is usually very low. Specialists invariably also have their own home,
livestock and gardens, the economic foundation of Jean Rabel, upon which they depend for
survival.
Table 10.4: Urban blue collar pay scales, Port-de-Paix (adjusted for rental fees)
* 1 dollar = 5 gdes
The upshot is that men have considerably more experience and opportunities for traveling
overseas and to work in the capital city of Port-au-Prince. As seen in chapter 4, seventeen of the
sixty-six men (two missing) interviewed for the Opinion Survey reported having worked in a city
or overseas for at least 30 of the 365 days preceding the interview. Similarly, in a community
sample of forty-one male household heads in Famadou, a typical Jean Rabel farming community,
twenty-one of the respondents had gone to the city to work before they married or entered
consensual union—and only seven had been away since entering into a union.5
Further, eleven of the sixty-six Jean Rabel men interviewed in the Baseline Survey reported
having been overseas, whereas no women reported having ever been abroad. Also, twenty-six
men versus seventeen women reported having visited the capital in their lifetimes (see table
10.5).6
Table 10.5: The most distant place farmers have visited
To put employment into perspective, most men in Jean Rabel would consider themselves very
lucky to land a full-time job for 750 gdes per month (US$44) as a watchman for a local
intervention organization. Rural men and woman scramble to secure a spot on road projects at
the State minimum wage of 30 gdes per day (US$1.78). But it is also important to understand
that this “scrambling” and interest in extra-domestic jobs rests on the expectation that
employment will not impede the carrying out of farming activities. Intervention workers in the
area are often mystified by Jean Rabeliens who, feeling overtaxed by a demanding employer,
simply walk off their jobs in favor of tending to their gardens.
14
14
12
10
10
8
8
6
4
4 4
2 3 3
2
0 1
50 250 450 650 850
Cost of merchandise
Note: Six observations exceed the 1,000 gdes limit visible in the graph.
Figure 10.2: Port-de-Paix Marchanns profits on merchandise (Y = 234, SD = 165, N = 54)
30
25
23
20
18
15
10
5
5
3 2 2
0
50 250 450 650 850
Profit
The most common ventures to urban markets are made to Port-de-Paix and 38 percent of
husbands reported that their wives make the trip at least once per month. The voyage is
invariably made on donkey or mule, since the cost of public transportation would consume too
much of the profits, and the women usually travel in groups with other market women. They set
out for Port-de-Paix in the late afternoon and walk behind their loaded animals all night, fording
streams and winding their way down worn trails, some of which have not changed course since
the Taino Indians trod them five hundred years ago. On a straight, flat stretch of road flanked by
lush banana trees, the women come at last to their final obstacle, Trois Rivie (the Three Rivers).
Normally a wide but meandering, crystal clear, knee-deep lowland stream, rainfall in the
mountains can quickly turn this tranquil creek into a muddy, life-threatening torrent that woman
and animal must wade across to reach the city. Once on the other side of the river, the women
find themselves on the windswept dirt streets of Port-de-Paix. They sell their produce among
decaying vegetable heaps in a bustling, tin-roofed, seaside market. Many then turn around and
head home that very day, without ever having slept and without having purchased anything,
because the Port-de-Paix market has little to offer that cannot be bought more cheaply in Jean
Rabel from the handlers of imported food aid or from the gran marchann, who ply their trade
with Port-au-Prince.
The money that an active market woman can earn compares favorably to male income earnings.
In a sample of fifty-four women interviewed while they were en route from Jean Rabel to Port-
de-Paix, the average woman was found to be carrying 483 gdes (US$28.75) worth of
merchandise to be sold for 717 gdes (US$42.68), yielding an average profit on their merchandise
of 234 gdes (US$13.93).9 The norm, or modal value of merchandise a woman was carrying was
between 100 to 200 gdes (US$5.95 to US$11.90), with a modal profit of 200 to 300 gdes
(US$11.90 to US$17.85). There are no other incidental costs involved that reduce profit because
the women carry their own food and water, and they cut grass along the way or carry fodder
from home to feed their animals. They do not stop to buy cokes or ice cream, and their donkeys
burn no gasoline and eat no store-bought feeds or supplements. The women simply take their
profits and return.
The average number of voyages per woman per month is two (1.9 to be exact) and so an average
market woman makes about 468 gdes (US$27.85) per month as a result of her excursions to
Port-de-Paix. The enterprise requires a total investment time of between four and six days. These
same women also trade in rural markets and sell goods out of their homes. An investigation of
the twenty-four major commodities being sold revealed that the average profit margin for retail
sales within the commune of Jean Rabel was 20 percent (standard error of the mean at 2.4%)
with a 15.6 day average turnover rate for the major commodities. Thus, using an estimated
working capital of 430 gdes—the average value of what women were carrying to Port-de-Paix—
market women are probably earning another 172 gdes per month.
Totaling what an average marchann makes in her Port-de-Paix ventures with profits on the home
front, a woman’s average monthly income from marketing activities is about 640 gdes per month
(US$38.00), more than 2.5 times the salary of the typical rural schoolteacher. The estimated
annual total earnings is US$456, 29 percent greater than the regional income for a family of six
as estimated in 1994 by CARE International (1996; 1997).10 But these are modal and average
income levels. It needs to be understood that as with bosses, some market women are more
successful than others, some have access to greater amounts of capital, and some are simply
shrewder. Six of the women interviewed (11%) are not even reflected in figures 10.1 and 10.2
because they were carrying more than 1,000 gdes worth of merchandise. One woman was
leading 4,410 gdes worth of livestock to market and she was going to make a profit of 1,040 gdes
(US$61)—four times the average rate. Furthermore, as shown earlier, eleven of thirty-one urban-
venturing marchann (35%) travel to the larger cities of Gonaives and Port-au-Prince, where the
most successful women sometimes build their trade revenue up to several thousand Haitian
dollars per month. There are a special few rural women who by virtue of their marketing savvy
have migrated to the village of Jean Rabel and led their entire families into the higher ranks of
the village commercial elite. They buy land for their husbands to farm, they pay other men to
work gardens for them, and they send their children away to urban schools and overseas
universities.
Conclusion
Jean Rabel has a flourishing subeconomy of skilled craftsmen and female marketing specialists.
The money paid for services and local products may appear pittances to outsiders but they are
meaningful within the narrow bounds of the regional subsistence economy. In particular, skilled
craftsmen such as tree-sawyers, masons, and carpenters are among men who have an exceptional
local income-earning opportunity outside of the household means of production. For women, the
most substantial nonfarm income opportunity is marketing, the third most important source of
household income in the region, and an activity that most women strive to master. But whatever
the occupation, a person is already a member of a household, the true foundation of livelihood
and survival in Jean Rabel, a point necessary to understand other sources of income. Without
being a governing member of a functioning household, one is not free to engage in these other
activities. It is through ownership and management of a household that one is free to pursue
other economic activities. But this assumes that someone is left behind to take care of the
household, for the demands of the household as a production and income-generating unit and its
role as the primary assurance against vicissitudes of the market and natural disasters implies
immense labor demands, the subject of the next chapter.
*****
Notes
1. Saddles and saddle blankets are made from banana and plantain stalks, saddle bags and sacks
ranging from quart size to a hundred gallons are woven from palm thatch, baskets are made from
slithers of bamboo, bridles are made from sisal and palm thatch rope and goat skin with scrap
iron used to make the bit, and hats are woven from grasses.
2. The scrap iron is heated over a fire of dry coconut shells, a fuel that burns hotter than regular
woods.
3. The exchange rate used is 16.8 Haitian gdes = one US dollar. Five gdes = one Haitian dollar.
4. Examples of porter opportunities: Carrying fish weirs from the village to Mole St. Nicolas, a
four-hour walk (eight hours round trip). Depending on physical endurance, a person can carry
one to three large weirs at H$6.00 each or three to four small weirs at H$3.00 to H$4.00 each for
a total of H$6.00 to $18.00 per day. Porters in the village get 1 to 2 gdes for carrying and
unloading one 110 lb sack of rice or flour—wheelbarrows are rare. These same porters report
making about 100 gdes a day but abundant work is not often available—usually on the two
village market days, Wednesday and Saturday.
5. It makes no sense to a Jean Rabel woman to go live with a man in a house he gives her if the
man has no gardens or livestock; nor does it make sense to go live with the man’s mother when
the girl can more comfortably stay with her own mother, who will be happy to have the services
of a grandchild. In the absence of a supportive husband, a Jean Rabel woman can begin bearing
children while still living with her parents without suffering shame or ridicule. The higher rates
of males in older age groups is possibly due to women with grown children going to live with the
children in urban areas.
6. The chief advantage of domestic employment is that meals and sleeping quarters are usually
provided by the employer. Some women go to the city for a year or two to earn the money to pay
debts, buy land, or enter into marketing activities.
7. For the same wages as men, women fill some 33 percent of the places on road projects. But
female involvement in roadwork is somewhat misleading because control of the lists is
dominated by a few individuals and these people favor friends and family members. The
outcome is that lists are stuffed with people, some of who never show up for work—a
respectable man or woman of means would never actually work on a road project, although they
might send a younger or less fortunate family member to work for them. When gardens are being
planted, for example, one can expect to find only women working, no matter how many men are
on the lists. In any case, for November 1998 to February 1999, 33 percent (3,289) of the 10,000
participants in a random one in three systematic sample of the AAA food for work lists were
women. On lists made available by PISANO, 21 percent (234) of the 1,121 PISANO road
workers were female although the proportion of females varied widely per habitasyon—between
4 percent and 67 percent female.
8. The most successful women are intermediaries in urban/rural exchange of staples between
Jean Rabel and Port-au-Prince—the staples flow both ways depending on the season. These
women develop extensive networks of local female clientele who depend on them for supplies
that are often provided on credit. Some of them become wealthy by local standards—many
subsequently emigrate. Seven of the fifty-two women reported on in the followup survey
regularly make the trip to Port-au-Prince.
9. The method of selecting women was not highly regimented or the sampling design
sophisticated. Every morning for five days in January 2000, between the hours of sunrise and
about 8:00 a.m., I sat by the roadside coming into Port-de-Paix, in a place called La Saline,
before one arrives at Trois Rivie. All market women were stopped, explained the purpose and
nature of the research and then interviewed regarding the type and quantity of merchandise they
were carrying. Most women were friendly and cooperative. There were six refusals or rather six
women who gave obviously false responses or who simply ignored me. To obtain sales prices in
Port-de-Paix and purchase prices in rural areas, I personally visited the markets, haggled over
prices, and consulted with market women I know as friends.
Concerning investments in pack animals: twenty-three of the women had only one donkey,
seventeen had two donkeys, one woman had three donkeys, one had four donkeys, five women
were on mules, and two were walking. An adult donkey costs about H$250.00 to H$350.00, a
young donkey can be purchased for H$100.00 to H$250.00. A mule goes for H$800.00 to
H$2,000.00, with H$1,200.00 being the most typical price.
10. I have not discussed credit in the main body of the text because I did not think it necessary.
The analysis has to stop somewhere and the issue is how much women have invested and how
much they can make—not how much they owe. Nevertheless, it may interest the reader to know
that there is a well-established if indirect system of money lending. It works as follows: Gran
marchanns (big vendors) and store owners sell sacks of staple foods—most often flour, rice,
corn, and sugar—on credit to small vendors. Many of the small vendors then turn around and sell
the sack or sacks of food for less than cost, using the money to buy and sell more profitable
merchandise. The sellers give women a fixed amount of time to pay for the merchandise, usually
twenty-two days (three market weeks). Some large vendors charge more money per sack but
give as much as a two-month repayment period.
The reason large vendors prefer to give merchandise rather than simply loan money is not clear.
The interest that can be demanded for money is reportedly as high as 100 percent per month. The
interest charged through this “euphemistic” system of credit works out to be about 15 percent for
twenty-two days (and this takes into consideration the loss to the borrower of selling the
merchandise below cost).
*****
Chapter 11
Labor Demands
Introduction
In the previous chapter I showed that in Jean Rabel a dazzling degree of specialization occurs in
both the production of local material goods and the provision of services. For men, skilled
craftsmanship and seasonal agricultural work are sources of additional income and most men at
some point in their lives temporarily migrate to urban areas, overseas, or to the Dominican
Republic, where they work as menial wage laborers in agriculture and construction sectors.
Some women also go to the city and work as maids or cooks. The primary feminine opportunity
is marketing, something that all rural Haitian women eventually engage in and something that
has the potential to put women on economically equal footing with men. But all these activities
presuppose the individual’s participation in a household, for one must be a member of a
household to assure survival in the unpredictable and harsh environment and to be free to engage
in other income-generating activities.
In this chapter I want to show that the labor demands associated with technologically simplistic
and low-risk household livelihood strategies are enormous. In later chapters it will be seen that it
is precisely these demands that explain high fertility and the associated pronatal cultural patterns
seen earlier. The role of household livelihood strategies in the face of an unpredictable economy,
periodic drought, and the tremendous labor demands inherent in accomplishing these strategies is
critical to survival in Jean Rabel. In tending gardens and livestock, fetching wood and water,
cooking, cleaning, and childrearing, households need labor. The labor can be procured in three
ways: (1) it can be purchased, as in hiring local or immigrant labor, (2) it can be traded, as in
reciprocal work groups, and (3) it can be produced, as in pregnancy, childbirth, childrearing, and
child labor (or as will be seen later, a child can also be “borrowed”).
Jean Rabeliens are at a decided disadvantage when it comes to purchasing labor. As shown
previously, Jean Rabel ranks among the poorest areas in Haiti and the pay that cash-poor farmers
can offer workers is too low to attract migrant laborers. Local wage laborers are scarce because
most households have access to land and animals through the tenure arrangements described in
the previous chapter. The result is that even the few Jean Rabeliens who have money available to
pay agricultural laborers frequently complain that labor cannot be found. Moreover, Jean
Rabeliens consider performing chores for another household to be humiliating, and no household
head would ever consider paying anyone to perform these tasks.
Labor can also be obtained through the use of reciprocal labor groups, the only functional
suprahousehold organizations in rural Jean Rabel. Farmers often depend on membership in such
organizations, called kwadi, to prepare fields for planting.1 But as shown previously, agriculture
is only one of the labor demands that must be satisfied to maintain a productive household, and
reciprocal labor groups will not drop by the house to assist in the completion of the daunting
number of chores that must be accomplished daily in every rural Jean Rabel household. For most
labor needs, Jean Rabeliens must depend on themselves and their family.
Household Tasks
In every household, a minimum number of time-consuming tasks must be performed on a daily
basis. Every day the house and yard must be swept (the rolled up and put away and the house
dusted, tasks that take an average of one to two hours to accomplish. Food preparation and
cooking involve starting and tending a fire, snapping beans, peeling plantains and sweet potatoes,
and pounding beans and spices. If the fire is good—i.e., the wood is seasoned and hard—rice or
sweet potatoes can be boiled in about one hour. Beans are a daily staple in virtually all Jean
Rabel households. If fresh, they take only twenty minutes to prepare, but if they are dry they
must be boiled for more than two hours. Under optimal conditions, therefore, a meal can be
prepared in about two hours, but it can and usually does take considerably longer. If the fire is
not hot, because the wood is too green or of a poor quality, cooking a simple meal without meat
can take more than four hours. If meat is cooked it must be washed with sour oranges or limes,
boiled, and then fried, adding another hour to the time it takes to prepare a meal.
Gathering firewood is a task that requires at least one hour per day, and where wood is scarce it
takes as much as three man-hours per day. Triweekly picking of beans and digging sweet
potatoes are also time-consuming endeavors. The average distance from the homestead to a
garden is a forty-six-minute walk, but 45 percent of gardens are located more than ninety
minutes from the house. The actual harvesting takes one to two hours. Water is necessary in the
house for drinking, cooking, and washing dishes and to accomplish these tasks the typical
household uses ten gallons per day, although small households with very young children may get
by on as little as five gallons per day. In effect, someone must make at least one and typically
two or three daily trips to fetch water, at an average of seventy minutes per trip. For bathing and
washing clothes, people usually go to the water sources rather than carry water back to the house,
but this also involves another time-consuming trek. Clothes are washed by hand. Women
typically wash clothes on one in every three days, a task that, depending on the number of people
in the household and the distance to the water, may consume from a half to one full day’s labor
(six to twelve hours). Someone in the household must go to the market at least twice a week, an
average round-trip walking time of three hours per journey (twelve kilometers). Totaled, the
minimum labor demand for a Jean Rabel household is an average of 74.2 adult hours per week,
or 10.6 hours per day. Depending on where the house is located in relation to water, sources of
firewood, and markets, and how many people live in the house, labor demands can exceed 155.4
adult labor hours per week, or 22.2 hours per day. And this is to say nothing about labor
demands associated with livestock and gardens (see table 11.2).2
Table 11.1: Average daily labor requirements for principal household tasks
In reality, a task-by-task tabulation of labor demands does not accurately depict time spent doing
subsistence chores, because some household tasks can be integrated in such a way as to facilitate
the realization of others. For example, one may fetch the water on the way back from the market
or clean the house while breakfast is boiling. But, the primary objective of the analysis is to
begin to illustrate the tremendous time demands required in rural Jean Rabel to accomplish
simple subsistence tasks. A myriad of other routine household tasks not included in table 11.1
must also be accomplished. Goods and messages must be hand carried to other people and young
children must be fed, washed, and supervised. Adults insist on ironing cloths, a task that involves
using a charcoal heated steam iron. Coffee beans must be roasted and pounded into a powder, a
task that may be done once a week but takes up an entire morning. Just making coffee, when one
considers starting the fire, boiling the water, and straining the grounds, takes an hour. Dishes are
always washed after meals and in many households they are washed again every morning as a
sanitary measure—an activity that is virtually a Jean Rabel custom. On Saturdays everything is
hauled out of the house, dusted and scrubbed, another Jean Rabel custom. Other occasional time-
consuming chores not included in the calculations in table 11.1 include weaving rope and
sleeping mats, and repairing thatch roofs and mud walls.
Agriculture Labor Demands
There are two planting seasons per year in Jean Rabel, one in October and November and
another in April and May. Even before the seasonal rains arrive, farmers scramble to begin
working their own plots before daybreak (~5:00 a.m.) and if there is a bright moon, some
farmers may begin working as early as 3:00 or 4:00 a.m. They hoe the soil (tchake) until about
10:00 a.m., take a break, and return to their fields at around 3:00 p.m. when the sun is no longer
directly overhead and the temperature begins to cool. After the soil is turned, and providing the
rains have begun, planting begins. One to two months later, the garden is weeded (sakle), and
after three months the harvests begin (rekolt).3
Table 11.2: Estimated labor inputs for average 5.7 acres of garden: One three- to four-
month planting cycle (eight-hour work day) (see endnote 5)
aE = [B / C], bF = [D * E]
Virtually all rural Jean Rabel households are involved in agriculture. Only 2.5 percent of the
Baseline Survey respondents claimed not to have any gardens. The mean amount of land farmed
was 5.7 acres per household per year.4 What this means to farmers in practical work terms is that
if the gardens are to be planted and harvested, the average farmer will need 319 adult/days of
labor per cycle to do it. Due to the fact that the seasonal rains do not wait for people to finish
planting and that hungry birds do not wait for people to finish harvesting, the farmer will need
access to all of these labor hours concentrated into a few weeks time (see figure 11.1 below).5
Complicating matters for farmers is the regional labor shortage mentioned earlier. Farmers in
Jean Rabel may be poor, but 67.1 percent report owning some land and even this is probably a
large underestimate resulting from the tendency for farmers, in anticipation of assistance, to
portray themselves as totally impoverished. Furthermore, the 32.9 percent percent who
reportedly do not own land enter into fifty/fifty sharecropping arrangements or employ some
other strategy to attain access to a plot of land.6
The consequence is a labor squeeze. Everybody is working on their garden plots at the same
time—hoeing at the same time, weeding at the same time, and harvesting at the same time. In the
rush to get their gardens hoed lest they miss out on a good season, adults and even boys as young
as nine and ten years of age form reciprocal work groups called kwadi. People with the money to
pay local wages frequently complain they cannot find workers.
Fifty-one percent of household respondents reported reciprocal volunteer work groups as the
principal source of garden labor, 25.7 percent reported family as the principal source, and 22.7
percent reported paid labor as the principal source. A time-consuming feature of planting not
accounted for in table 11.2 on labor commitments is getting to the gardens. As farmers say,
“there is mountain and there is plain” (gen monn, gen plenn), meaning that in Jean Rabel, in the
endeavor to avoid crop failure, the farming of multiple garden plots geographically distant from
one another is, in the face of highly variable soil types, altitudes, and rainfall patterns, a practical
and adaptive strategy. The average farmer has 2.8 gardens and, as mentioned earlier, the average
garden is a forty-six-minute walk from the house, with 45 percent of gardens more than ninety
minutes from the house. Some men and women migrate to gardens and stay there during planting
and harvests, sleeping in a small, tent-shaped thatch hut called a joupa, but most make the daily
commute, a round trip average walking time of ninety minutes.7
Hard Times
Yet another issue that should be factored into an understanding of labor demands in Jean Rabel is
periods of climatic stress. A severe regional drought occurs in Jean Rabel on average one in
every eight years. When a drought strikes, demands on household labor increase precipitously,
and the principal feature that determines the success of a household in coping with and surviving
drought is not how few mouths it has to feed, but how many able bodies it can put to work. Crop
failure turns many households to charcoal production and, as a consequence, local wood supplies
dwindle and household members must travel farther and farther to find wood for fuel.11
Most problematic is the water supply. Water sources dry up and people have to travel farther to
fill their buckets. In the followup survey, respondents reported that the temporal distance to and
from the nearest secondary water source is 120 minutes, almost twice as far as during normal
times. All households in the region are experiencing the same stress and this means that the
fewer water sources are being visited by more people. The fewer springsare packed with crowds
of pushing, shoving, and cursing women and children. People get up at midnight so they can
arrive at a distant spring before it becomes too crowded and they spend hours waiting to fill a
single water jug. Some people, particularly young children, return to the house teary-eyed,
trodden and bruised, having failed to procure any water at all. Washing clothes during drought
conditions becomes problematic as well. Women must travel great distances to find clean water
and a vacant place to sit and scrub. Animals have to be watered more frequently since the
desiccated fodder dehydrates them. Fodder itself becomes scarce, so farmers are traveling farther
and farther into remote areas to graze their animals or to cut grass for them and then they must
lead the animals more frequently in the other direction, into more peopled areas, where there are
adequate water sources that have not dried up.
All of this additional effort translates into more labor and the need for more workers because,
rain or no rain, people must eat and they must drink. Food still must be cooked, water found,
clothes washed, and at least some animals must be kept alive so that when the drought finally
does end there will be something with which to start producing again.12
Conclusion
In Jean Rabel, the household is the principal organizational medium for survival and, for the
most part, the only enduring organizational structure. Being a member of a household is a
prerequisite for survival. Virtually all tasks necessary for production and participation in the
regional economy are accomplished within—or dependent on—the household. In this chapter, I
showed that the actual time needed to accomplish the tasks that make a household viable are
tremendous. There is also a feature inherent in the household economy that may not be readily
visible to the casual observer. No matter how few members there are in a household, there is a
minimum level of labor that must be accomplished. Distance to the water and the market does
not change with the number of members in a household, nor does the time required to cook beans
change as a result of the number of people eating them. The fundamental point is that the fewer
people in a household, the more work there is to do for each member. On the other hand, with
increasing numbers of household members, there is a relative decline in the workload required of
each member (this was Chayanov’s Rule). This is assuming of course that the size of the
household is within reasonable limits, meaning that too many people concentrated in a single
household would exhaust local resources.
What exactly is the happy medium between too few and too many household members will be
dealt with shortly. But first, as will be seen in the following chapter, labor intensiveness of
household tasks and the income- generating opportunities available outside the household give
way to a sexual and age division of labor. A woman is usually the focus of the household and the
manager of domestic tasks while men concentrate their energies on animal and garden activities.
Children are a significant source of labor and, while they participate in agriculture, they more
often can be found carrying out easily accomplished but tedious, time-consuming chores such as
retrieving water, gathering firewood, cooking, and tending livestock. The role of children in this
regard sets up the conditions that give way to the particular types of kinship and family structure
found in Jean Rabel
*****
Notes
1. While reciprocal labor groups are important, they are probably less important in Jean Rabel
than in regions where farmers heavily depend on a few crops harvested over a very short period
of time. The primary agricultural labor pinch in Jean Rabel comes during planting season and the
significant advantage of reciprocal labor is that it resolves the need to accomplish particular tasks
quickly, such as clearing a field that is grown over with small trees and brush, or turning the soil
in a field so that it can be planted before weeds start growing. But in reality, there are few
agricultural labor tasks that must involve reciprocal labor groups. Most crops in Jean Rabel are
not harvested all at once, but rather over a long period of time and the few crops that do become
ripe all at once, namely beans and corn, are easily harvested by a few people, typically women,
who can manage the task alone. Furthermore, reciprocal labor groups are ultimately a zero-sum
strategy of capturing labor because households get no more from participating in work teams
than they contribute as members—i.e., one day of work in a neighbor’s field begets one day of
work on the farmer’s own field.
2. A common mistake for development workers in the region is to assume that the limiting factor
on meals is food availability, when in fact it is often time needed to cook meals.
The same observations were made in both the baseline survey of 1,586 households and the
followup subsurvey of 138 households, in which the exact average was 67.19 minutes.
The estimates for distance to and between markets was based on the average cartographic
midpoint of eight kilometers between markets. Four kilometers were added for altitude change
and the fact that when it comes to traveling in rugged Jean Rabel, the shortest distance between
two points—in this case the household and the market—is never a straight line.
3. The fall season is the highest yielding of the various seasons at low altitudes while the spring
planting season is the highest yielding in the mountains.
4. This is a reference to total land farmed—not necessarily owned—and includes sharecropped
property (see endnote 7 below). Seventy-six percent of all garden plots are .5 kawo (1.6 acres) or
smaller, indicating the data is skewed by a few relatively large gardens.
5. Information is based on inputs per ¼ kawo, called ka and measured in Jean Rabel as sink kout
chen (five lengths of a standardized surveyor’s chain = 28 feet per chain length). The table below
assumes 24 bout per ka (16 square gol per bout; 1 gol ~ 9 ft; or another measure is bras which is
about 5.5 five feet; 1 bout = 7 – 10 bras) . In the conclusion here and in the main text, the
measure has been translated to acres for convenience (30 bout to an acre). Planting here includes
all crops; harvesting only includes bean, corn and millet, crops that are harvested all at once.
Farmers—and it is usually women farmers who do this task—harvest sweet potatoes, beans, and
other crops the entire year round, making these difficult tasks to estimate. They have been
included in household tasks. Thus, in this calculation, harvesting involves uprooting beans and
millet or picking corn. Drying time is not included in processing; only threshing. Total time may
be slightly overestimated because some gardens are not planted in grain or beans but rather in
crops for which little processing is necessary (such as plantains). On the other hand, time
devoted to plants subsequently intercropped is not included. Many tasks should have been
measured in hours, such as processing crops, because people perform them until they are tired
and then do something else, thus distributing the task over a longer period of time. The
appropriate adjustments were made based on eight hour working days, typical during hoeing.
The total labor input per garden acre is fifty-six adult/days—the estimate below is in units of ka
¼ kawo and there are 3.19 acres per kawo, .80 acres per ka.
Table 11.5: Estimated labor inputs for average 1/4 kawo garden
6. Almost one third of respondents, 413 households, reported owning no land; 87.7 percent of
households own 2 kawo or less; and a mere 1.1 percent of households claimed to own more than
5 kawo of land. This should not, however, be interpreted to mean that ownership of land is
concentrated. The largest landholder in the sample owned only 12 kawo and the now infamous
gran dons (big landowners) of Jean Rabel—who have been alleged by the Haitian State to have
played a role in the 1987 massacre and who controlled much of the local irrigated State land—
long ago gave this land in sharecropping arrangements to local farmers and more recently have
disappeared from the scene (at least two are in prison for accusations relating to the massacre).
There are people who control and collect rent for this land in the name of the families, but their
influence is fading and with the recent presence of INARA—the agricultural reform arm of the
new Haitian Government—the days of the gran dons appear to be drawing to a close.
7. Some development workers in the region explain the fragmentation of garden land as a
consequence of inheritance, i.e., families dividing land into ever smaller parcels for the
inheritors. That land is fragmented through inheritance is undeniable. But land could also be
aggregated through sales and trades. Over 50 percent of gardens in the baseline survey were
reportedly purchased, and even though much of this land was purchased from family—meaning
it was still a type of inheritance—it nevertheless indicates the opportunity to aggrandize land.
But there appear to be practical reasons why Jean Rabel farmers prefer instead to hold on to a
multiplicity of small fragmented holdings rather than aggregating them into a single large
garden: in the Opinion Survey not one of the sixty-eight male farmers interviewed explained land
fragmentation as a result of inheritance; virtually all the farmers explained the multiplicity of
garden plots as an adaptation to variable ecological zones, i.e., soil and rainfall patterns (which in
Jean Rabel change dramatically over distances of only a few kilometers). None mentioned
heredity or lack of market access; thirty-eight respondents (56%) mentioned the importance of
different soil types or the position of the garden plot—such as bottom land versus plateau—and
thirty respondents (44%) emphasized rainfall patterns.
It is also interesting to note that the number of gardens per household in Jean Rabel is identical to
the national average (RONCO 1987), and the size of gardens as well as the number of gardens
planted per household does not appear to have changed in at least the past fifty years (see the
1950 census). With all technological factors being equal, therefore, there appears to be a
limitation on the amount of land and number of gardens that an average household can work.
The mean garden size is .59 kawo (see table ); about 50 percent larger than the national average
of .5 hectares (1 kawo = 1.29 hectare). However, 75.5 percent of all gardens are .5 kawo or
smaller.
8. With regard to tenured livestock, the Baseline Survey turned up many more people looking
after animals for others (tenured in) versus people giving animals to other people to look after
(tenured out). A logical explanation for the “missing” animal owners might be that people who
tenure animals out are fewer but wealthier—meaning a few tenure to many. However, a look
only at the most highly tenured animals—cows (26.1% vs 3.8%), hogs (14.2% vs 1.1%), sheep
(11.8% vs .7%), and goats (10.3 vs. 1.1%)—suggests this is not the case: assessing only
households that have tenured animals, tables and below reveal the mean number of animals
tenured in (1.58) is actually greater than the mean number of animals tenured out (1.11).
This is probably a result of the way in which livestock tenure was measured: tenure was not
recorded for every animal but rather the primary means of tenure by which households came into
possession of each species of livestock. For example, if a household head reported being
responsible for six donkeys, the question on tenure was “what is the primary means by which
you have these donkeys?” Another reason for the disparity between people who “tenure out”
versus “tenure in” animals is that many town-dwellers tenure animals out to people living in the
countryside, thus they are not captured in the equation. The survey did not sample the village of
Jean Rabel, which would have helped to clarify this point.
9. Damage done to gardens by roaming livestock is a principal source of conflict among farmers.
Farmers who find goats or sheep foraging in their gardens sometimes exercise the right to kill the
animal. The head is kept by the gardener, but the rest of the carcass is strung up in the nearest
tree for the animal owner to come collect. Pigs found foraging in the neighbor’s gardens are
usually not killed for their crime, but owners must pay for damages. Pigs suffer, however, in
cases where the owner refuses to indemnify the victim—a pig belonging to the author was once
macheted to death by a woman fed up with the procine’s repeated and uncompensated invasions
of her kitchen (the pig had been “tenured out” to another neighbor). Roving cattle are never
killed. However, owners must pay indemnities for damages to gardens. Failure to compensate for
persistent intrusions into a neighbor’s garden sometimes results in a machete wound across the
rump of the animal or the severing of its tail. Roving donkeys, horses or mules are, compared to
other animals, a rare sight, and seldom are the animals intentionally injured for their
depredations. Owners must pay for damages to gardens.
10. As elsewhere, I want to document here a series of ethnographic observations that are relevant
here, that might be important to other researchers but for which there is no place in the main text.
In Jean Rabel, there is system of rights regarding browsing livestock that is in various stages of
evolution. In decades past, livestock in most areas was free ranged. In some areas today,
particularly in the dry coastal region, farmers continue to free range goats and sheep on
communal grazing lands owned by the State. Pigs are allowed to forage freely in seaside
settlements and in large villages where there are no gardens to destroy. In other areas people are
not allowed to free range livestock, but by consensus tether animals on any land not planted with
crops. In still other areas landowners appear to be in the process of rebelling against free-
tethering and are asserting their property rights by cutting loose livestock they find tied on their
land. In more than 50 percent of communities—an educated guess—farmers now exclusively use
private property to browse livestock.
11. Charcoal is bagged and sold to intermediaries who ship the product on trucks or by boat to
urban centers, most notably Port-au-Prince. Rural Jean Rabeliens generally do not use charcoal
themselves—they use wood. In almost any region one finds an ongoing production of charcoal
with a handful of specialists and intermediaries engaged in the industry and they are considered
among the poorest, lowliest people in an area, although the money earned at charcoal production
can compare favorably to other occupations (see chapter 8). But for most individuals charcoal
production is something that occurs when a special need arises, as when someone wants to build
a house or finance a new garden, and charcoal production is most conspicuously bound with
times of drought and crop failure. Makab, for example, is a shipping point for charcoal and there
are usually several dozen sacks stacked on the beach. But during the 1996–1997 drought, the
entire beach was covered with thousands of sacks of charcoal stacked as high as the houses.
12. The same increased labor demand associated with crises is true of marginal regions. The
poorest people usually live in the most marginal areas, which in Jean Rabel are by definition
those areas farthest from water and markets, thus increasing household labor requirements.
*****
Chapter 12
Gender- and Age-Based Divisions of Labor
Introduction
In meeting the demands associated with maintaining a Jean Rabel household there is a sexual
and age division of labor. Men perform tasks associated with gardening and livestock and
women tend to focus on household chores such as cooking, carrying water, and marketing.
Women are the focal point of households; they are thought of as the managers and they are more
likely than men to cross the gender lines and perform tasks that fall in the sphere of men,
particularly with regard to agriculture. Children are major contributors to household labor
demands, particularly with regard to retrieving water and cooking fuel, and Jean Rabeliens
recognize and emphasize the role that children play in assuring the survival of the household.
Indeed, children and their contributions are so important to survival that, as will be seen, the
drive to produce large numbers of offspring in order to meet domestic labor demands largely
determines the structural organization of the Jean Rabel family, patterns of conjugal union, and
the sociocultural fertility complex discussed earlier.
No. We need each other. The man plants gardens and the woman, it is she who must harvest
what the man plants. It is the woman who must sell the harvest too. It is the woman too who must
wash clothes.1 (thirty-seven-year-old father of three)
I can’t do it because if I need a garden, it is my husband who must get to work. If I build a house,
it is my husband who does it for me. You see, we need each other.2 (forty-year-old mother of
five)
I cannot live without a woman. There are several circumstances, problems that women resolve. I
cannot enter into some affairs. I cannot whip up a meal. I cannot wash clothes. 3 (thirty-eight-
year-old father of seven)
No. One enters into the other. Water enters into the sugar. Sugar enters into the water. You
cannot throw out just the water. They are a single mixture.4 (thirty-eight-year old father of
seventeen)
Women take care of the house, clean, wash clothes, make meals, carry water, and purchase basic
foods and necessities at the market. As shown earlier, women also sell garden produce, they sell
staples out of the house, and they often work as itinerant traders who extend household revenues
by rolling cash reserves over in retail marketing ventures. A woman with a husband who is
present will typically not participate in preparing fields or weeding, but women are considered
indispensable in planting and, more importantly, for the daily picking of produce and seasonal
harvests. Indeed, harvesting is considered to be the exclusive domain of women and is typically
coordinated by the ranking woman of the house. Men who do not have a wife will rely on their
mother, sister, or a daughter to harvest and sell produce.
Men work in the gardens, care for livestock, make charcoal for sale to villages, towns, and cities,
and gather firewood for their own households. The heaviest tasks, like hoeing (voye wou) and
digging holes for plantain trees (voye pikwa/fouye twou) are considered to be men’s work while
light garden work, such as covering holes and collecting the debris from a weeded garden, are
thought of as women’s work. Men help process the food, such as flaying millet, beans, and corn
or pulverizing the seeds with bat and bucket-size mortar and pestle. Men build houses, and all
jobs involved in the building of a house, such as carpentry and masonry, are male jobs. The only
task related to household construction that women do is plaster houses with white mud or lime—
if the mud is not white then plastering house walls is men’s work. As seen earlier, men, and to a
far lesser extent women, migrate to the city in pursuit of temporary wage opportunities.
Perhaps the most significant and telling feature of the gender division of labor, and a point that
will also be important later in understanding marriage patterns, is that men rarely engage in
female chores while women can and sometimes do perform the full range of male activities. Men
do not wash clothes, make meals, clean the house, or go to the market. Men seldom carry water.
Women on the other hand can and often do tend livestock, weed gardens, and search for
firewood. Some women, particularly older, economically independent women, hoe the soil and,
in a few rare instances, dig holes for plantain trees. This versatility in job performance reflects
the fact that women are more important than men in the day-to-day functioning of homesteads.
Indeed, households are thought of as belonging to women and, as discussed in a later chapter,
Jean Rabeliens are fond of saying, “men don’t have houses” (gason pa gen kay), and people will
typically refer to the homestead, even when a productive male is present, as belonging to the
woman, as in “Ma Benita’s place” or “Lili’s house.”
Oh, you must have children. If you don’t have any you are in bad shape. You have too much to
do.5 (fifty-four-year-old mother of six)
That is the biggest illness. I can’t do it. I just can’t live without children.6 (sixty-two-year-old
father of eleven)
No. I can’t live without children. . . . It’s them that work, that give me water, fetch wood, make
food.7 (sixty-two-year-old father of fifteen)
No. You can’t do it. You need children. You need children. You understand? You need children to
help you.8 (fifty-four-year-old father of ten)
Children of both sexes participate in every type of labor activity (see table 12.2).10 In over 70
percent of households visited—including households with only toddlers or infants—children
(primarily girls) carry water, cook, and perform housework. In over 50 percent of households,
children (primarily boys) reportedly help in the garden and with livestock; in some 32 percent of
households, girls, boys, or both, market produce; and in over 30 percent of households, children
(mostly girls) sell livestock.
30
Count
29
20
10
8 8
0
Man Woman Children
60
59
50 54
Count
40
30
20
10
7
0 4
Man Woman Children Other
20
Count
19
10
3
0
Man Woman Children Other
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
0 1 2 3 4 5 6
Number of children
Figure 12.6: Gardens by children per household (n = 106; children seven- to twenty-five
years of age)
6
Number of gardens
2
0 1 2 3 4 5 6
Number of chidren
Table 12.3: Number of children resident in house by whether or not woman is engaged in
marketing (n = 132; children seven to twenty-five years of age)
*****
Statistical Results for Test of the Number of Household Gardens by the Number of Seven-
to Twenty-Five-Year-Olds Controlling for Age of the Head of the Household
Table 12.4: Gardens by the number of seven- to twenty-five-year-olds controlling for age of
the head of the household: R-square
Table 12.5: Gardens by the number of seven- to twenty-five-year-olds controlling for age of
the head of the household: ANOVA
.
Table 12.6: Gardens by the number of seven- to twenty-five-year-olds controlling for age of
the head of the household: coefficients
*****
Statistical Results for Test of the Number of Household Animals by the Number of Seven-
to Twenty-Five-Year-Olds, Controlling for Age of the Head of the Household
Table 12.7: Animals by the number of seven- to twenty-five-year-olds, controlling for age of
the head of the household: R-square
Table 12.8: Animals by the number of seven- to twenty-five-year-olds controlling for age of
the head of the household: ANOVA
Table 12.9: Animals by the number of seven- to twenty-five-year-olds, controlling for age of
the head of the household: Coefficients
*****
Table 12.10: Gardens by the number of seven to twenty-five years olds by household head
age categories
Table 12.11: Animals by the number of seven to twenty-five year olds by household head
age categories
Conclusion
The value of child labor is evident in the correlations between the quantity of household
livestock and gardens and the number of children resident in a particular household. Although, as
shown, children participate in virtually all household and productive activities, the increased
number of livestock and gardens may not be so much a result of children directly participating,
as the result of contributions children make by carrying out small, time-consuming tasks such as
fetching water, cooking, cleaning, and tending animals, contributions that free adults to focus on
productive income generating activities such as gardening and commerce.
But none of this unequivocally demonstrates that children are a net asset to household livelihood.
It is unlikely, given the data, that households with greater numbers of children are more
impoverished than households with fewer children. However, the argument could just as easily
be made that more children simply increases the demand for food and additional income,
translating to the need for more gardens, more animals tended, and more wage-labor and market
ventures. Thus, the question is, do children increase household prosperity? And very importantly,
how are those contributions related to high fertility, the pronatal sociocultural fertility complex
and particular values associated with Jean Rabel’s sexual moral economy? These issues are the
subject of the following chapter.
*****
Notes
1. Non. Nou toudè bezwenn lòt. Si gason ap travay, fi a menm se li pou ranmase rekolt ki gason
ap fet. Rekolt ki fet la tou, se fi a menm ki pou al van ni. Se fi a tou pou al lave.
2. M pa kapab paskè si m bezwenn nan jaden an, se mari-m pou al travay. Si m-ap monte yon
kay la , se mari mwen pou fe pou mwen. Ou we yon bezwenn lòt.
3. M pa ka viv san fi. Sa-k pase m pa ka viv san fi, gen yon seri de sikonstans, pwoblem se fi pou
fe, paskè se pa tout bagay m ka antre andan. Ma pa ka nan fe ti manje rapid, m pa ka lave.
4. Non. Yon antre nan lòt. Dlo antre nan sik la. Sik antre nan dlo a. Sa di, ou pa ka jete dlo a. Sa
di, se yon dosaj fet.
5. O, fo ou gen ti moun. Si ou pa genyen ou pa bon. Ou anbarase twop. Kounye-la m vin pran dlo
la, oswa m sot nan jaden lè m rive se mwen pou mete ponyet atè, se mwen pou al nan dlo. Lè m
vini, pou al nan bwa.
6. Pi gwo maladi, m pa kapab. . . . Telman m pa ka viv san ti moun.
7. Non. M pa ka viv san ti moun. Bondieu ba-m pitit la, se li ki bay ou travay, ki ba-m ti dlo,
chèche ti bwa, vin fe manje.
8. Non. Ou pa kapab. Paske ou bezwenn ti moun, ou bezwenn ti moun, ou konprann. Ou
bezwenn pou ti moun yo ed-o.
9. Non. Ti moun se tout eleman andedan kay.
10. Only 5.4 percent of households (85 of the 1,523 reporting) had no children—compared to 12
percent of households with no adult woman present full time and 23 percent of households with
no adult male present full time. Fifty-seven percent of these childless households (forty-seven of
eighty-three for which the data is available) were in yards with other houses that do have
children indicating that only 36 of 1,523 houses (2.4% of the total) are actually homesteads
having no children. Only seven of these latter households had a woman as household head.
11. There are obviously other factors that also determine the number of gardens and animals a
household may own, specifically wealth. Differential access to land and capital and other sources
of revenue such as remittances and money earned through skilled craftsmanship and marketing
are clearly determinant of the number of animals and gardens a person can purchase. The
periodic sale of animals and garden land to cover medical expenses and costs associated with
funeral and wedding ceremonies are also prominent factors determining the number of animals
and gardens a household might have at any given time. But the point regarding children and
prevailing social and economic conditions in Jean Rabel is that they provide the next most
important ingredient, the labor to manage gardens and animals.
12. The Baseline Survey included the same data needed to test the relationship between the
number of children present in the household and the number of animals and gardens the
household tended. The relationship is significant, even when controlling for age of the household
head—which has no statistical influence—but as described in chapter 1, it was discovered too
late that respondents in the Baseline Survey were tending to include in their enumeration of
household members children who were away at school in the village or in the city. Because of
drought conditions, there was also a problem with reporting on the number of animals. To
address these shortcomings, the smaller survey used here was carried out in two Jean Rabel
communities. This survey, called the Livestock and Gardens Survey, was conducted by a
supervisor from the Baseline Survey (see the introduction).
Below are data from the Baseline Survey regarding the number of children reported as present in
the household versus number of gardens and controlling for age of the household head. (The ages
five to nineteen years was used in this test rather than the seven- to twenty-five-year-old range
used in the other test. The decision was arbitrary.)
Table 12.12: Child present in house by number of gardens, model summary (Baseline
Survey)
Model Summary
St d. Error
Adjusted of the
Model R R Square R Square Estimat e
1 .141a .020 .018 1.57
a. Predictors: (Constant), Age, Number of 5 to 19
y ears-olds in hshld
Table 12.13: Child present in house by number of gardens, ANOVA (Baseline Survey)
ANOVAb
Sum of Mean
Model Squares df Square F Sig.
1 Regression 71.944 2 35.972 14.646 .000a
Residual 3551.589 1446 2.456
Total 3623.533 1448
a. Predictors: (Const ant ), Age, Number of 5 t o 19 y ears-olds in hshld
b. Dependent Variable: Number of Gardens Planted
Coeffi ci entsa
St andardi
zed
Unstandardized Coef f icien
Coef f icients ts
Model B St d. Error Beta t Sig.
1 (Constant) 2.589 .128 20.262 .000
Number
of 5 to 19
.115 .022 .139 5.312 .000
y ears-olds
in hshld
Age -1.51E-03 .002 -.018 -.676 .499
a. Dependent Variable: Number of Gardens Plant ed
*****
Chapter 13
What Parents Have to Say about the Economic Utility of Children
Introduction
In the previous chapter it was shown that children are important contributors to the labor-
intensive household livelihood strategies that prevail in Jean Rabel. Children do household
chores, they cook, they clean, they go for water and to market, they work in the garden, and they
tend livestock. More children appear to translate into greater economic security and relatively
greater household prosperity, i.e., more animals and more gardens, and greater resources to
survive drought. The statistics may or may not convince the skeptical reader. However, in this
chapter it will be seen that Jean Rabel farmers need no convincing. During the Opinion Survey,
farmers overwhelmingly emphasized the fact that children are not just helpful, they are
necessary; and they are necessary because they work.
Why does a person have children? To help. Right now for example, I would have to go get water.
But I don’t have to. It is here. I would have to go get wood. But I don’t have to. It’s right here.2
(forty-year-old mother of five)
If I did not have them, things would be worse for me. You need a little water, they go to the
water. You need a little fire wood, they go get wood. The boys work in the garden for you. They
look after the animals.3 (thirty-three-year-old mother of eight)
Children are the biggest necessity. If you need something you tell a child. Like right now, I can
say, “go look for some fire wood,” or “some embers from the neighbor’s house.” “Go to the
market.”4 (twenty-seven-year-old father of three)
Why did I have children? I don’t understand what you are saying. Children are there to help
you. Your children do your work. I don’t know who takes care of things at your house.5 (sixty-
year-old father of thirteen)
The need for children is conceptualized first and foremost not in terms of love, companionship,
or the security that grown children can provide to aging parents; the need for children is
conceptualized first in terms of labor. When asked if they could live without children, only 4 of
the 136 respondents (3%), 2 women and 2 men, replied “yes,” yet 14 percent of respondents said
they could live without a spouse. Almost without exception and without hesitating, 97 percent of
men and women replied to the question in the manners exhibited in the following examples:
If you don’t have children, dogs will eat you. If you have no children to fetch a little water and
get some fire for you. If you hurt something or you are sick, you’re finished.6 (fifty-five-year-old
father of seventeen)
No. Children are protection. You need children to help you work. It is children who save the
household7 (thirty-two-year-old mother of five)
Oh, a big never. Children don’t tire. Children are animals. Children are never worn out. They do
all the work. They go to the water. They do all the work.8 (forty-year-old mother of four)
No. I cannot live without children. . . . If I need one to go to the village, I send him. If I need one
to go for wood, I send him. They can’t tell me no . . . . Not one of them can stand in front of me
and say no. We pull together.9 (thirty-nine-year-old father of six)
Me! Times the way they are? Me! If I didn’t have children I wouldn’t stick around here for a
minute. I would leave. I would go play a different lottery. I would go look for another type of
work. The type of work where they would pay me money.10 (forty-year-old mother of five)
Only 7 percent of respondents indicated they wanted children for reasons of affection and only
14 percent indicated children were valuable foremost as adults (i.e., when the children are
grown) to provide support during old age. This should not be interpreted to mean people in rural
Jean Rabel do not love their children, nor should it be interpreted to mean that when their parents
become aged, children are not at some level considered valuable sources of security. Farmers
emphasized that children’s support should be reciprocated; children “do” for adults and adults
have a responsibility to “do” for the children.11 Interviewers regularly received comments like
Yo itilite o. Ou pran reskonsab yo (They make themselves useful to you and you feed and care
for them) and Ti moun ka ede-m. M ka ede ti moun yo (Children can help me. I can help
children). Beyond feeding and clothing children, the most important thing adults can do for
children is put them in school. School is the single greatest nonsubsistence expense for Jean
Rabel households and the second biggest reason for selling livestock (see chapter 7). Also, to
some extent, school is thought of as an investment in the future security of parents: 25 percent of
parents said they sent their children to school primarily so the child could better care for them in
the future.12
But the point that farmers made more emphatically than any other is that it is the work children
perform in their youth rather than after they are grown that is foremost in importance. Thus,
children are important to their parents as they age but not for the reasons outsiders tend to
anticipate—that they will provide for their parents—but rather for the contributions they make to
the household labor pool in their youth and for the grandchildren they will provide as they
mature, grandchildren who will also run errands and do the time-consuming and labor-intensive
chores necessary for survival in Jean Rabel. This fact came through most clearly in the question,
“If you had not yet borne children, and someone came along and promised you $500 per month,
every month, for your entire life, with the single condition that you do not bear/father children,
would you agree?” Respondents had no problem understanding the question, nor did they have a
problem answering. Only five women and eight men said “yes,” they would take $500 a month
(an enormous sum for the farmer) for life rather than bear children. The other 123 respondents
(90%) responded with an emphatic “no.” The variety of responses revealed the appreciation with
which people in Jean Rabel regard their children, especially young children, and the logic
underlying this appreciation. In the following comments, take particular note of the importance
of children versus money; the limitations of money; and the emphasis on young, rather than
grown, children who can be sent on errands:
They give you $500 a month. OK. You are in the house by yourself. Fever takes you. And while
you are sick, who is going to look after you? 13(forty-year-old father of three)
No. I would not agree. That couldn’t help you at all. If I am getting $500 a month and I do not
have a child to say, go there, take this gallon, go get some water for me. Look at me, I’d be
making $500 dollars a month and all the time things would be getting worse. Not better. No. Not
better. Worse. Things would be getting worse.14 (fifty-one-year-old father of two)
No. Children are worth more than money.15 (forty-year-old mother of three)
No. Because it doesn’t make sense. . . . I would rather have children. As the old people say,
children are the wealth of the poor.16 (thirty-eight-year-old mother of seven)
No. Because I need children. I can tell you, you have money in your hand and you can’t send it
to do a single errand. Sometimes you have money with you and you lose it.17 (fifty-year-old
father of six)
Why don’t I agree? Something happens. I get to the house. I lie there. I’m sick. Money? I can’t
send it to do anything for me. I can die lying there on it. It’s something that can’t do anything for
me. It is a person you need to take the money, go with it, buy what I need and bring it to me. And
if I don’t have any children to give the money to? 18 (fifty-six-year-old father of one)
No. If I need a little water, money can’t give it to me. I cannot send money on an errand.19
(thirty-four-year-old mother of five)
No. Because I know that if I had no child, tomorrow, by God, I am sick, I would not find a child
to help me.20 (twenty-eight-year-old mother of two)
Ah, you can have money in the house but if you do not have children to do for you? A person can
have money and you can lie down and die. If you do not have a child to stand there and do things
for you that money can not do. Money! You can sleep on a pile of money. It cannot work for you.
It is people who stand up and work for you.21 (sixty-five-year-old mother of nine)
Oh. Children are wealth. If you don’t have children, a dog is better than you. No. I would rather
have children. Children are help. This morning, if you send one out there, he does his job, it’s
you who benefits.22 (fifty-four-year-old mother of six)
I would not agree. Ahh, children. Money can’t do anything for me. If I am sick, I need to take
care of something, the children, if they are there, they will take care of it. If I am sick, I can’t
send money to do errands.23 (forty-five-year-old mother of five)
No. Why. Because children are the wealth of the poor. Children are wealth.24 (fifty-year-old
mother of four)
Oh no. Children are wealth. It is children who are, who are the wealth of the poor. Money is not
wealth.25 (forty-two-year-old mother of three)
No. Because let’s say you have money. You go find someone to do something for you. He doesn’t
do it. But children. As soon as I am sick, look at my child making food for me, washing clothes
for me, doing things for me. And if it was money, it wouldn’t be doing anything for me.26 (thirty-
year-old father of four)
I would ask for the chance to have one child. I find children necessary.27 (forty-year-old mother
of three)
Three would be better. Because things are hard nowadays. Education. Things are hard. It was not
a long time ago you could have children. . . . Now, if you have ten children, you have to put all
ten in school.30 (fifty-year-old mother of four)
Three. If I had six, put all six in school, I would spend more money. But if I have three, I spend
less. It is there you find the advantage. But if God gives you six, you are obliged to put all six in
school. It is not in your interest. But if God takes care of you, it can be in your interest. There are
people who have ten children. They are no help at all because their parents have nothing to
stand on, they don’t have any way to get by. And then there are those who have fifty children and
they are better for it.31 (twenty-nine-year-old father of nine)
Three would be better. Because sometimes you have all these children, the times are so bad you
can not keep them in school.32 (thirty-five-year-old father of five)
Better you have six children. But you cannot educate all of them.33 (thirty-four-year-old father of
six)
In contrast, responses in favor of six children were usually clear and adamant declarations in
favor of six.
When you have six it is better for you. More people, more work, more things getting done. The
work gets done faster.34 (forty-year-old mother of three)
Six. Because if for example you are going out this morning, you are going to work in the garden
or the market, you take three with you and you leave three to do the work at the house.35 (forty-
three-year-old father of three)
When you have six children it is better for you. Why? Because this morning, you are all by
yourself, you send each child somewhere to do a job for you. Each job gets done at the same
time.36 (thirty-five-year-old father of six)
All six are important. All six. You send one to the left, one to the right, and the rest in all four
cardinal directions.37 (forty-seven-year-old father of seven)
The girls are better. Why? I could fall for one, this guy could fall for another. You yourself could
fall for another. You understand? Prepared food. Women have more luck than men.38 (thirty-
eight-year-old father of three)
When a daughter lands in a good situation, she’s likely to come gather you up. You can be pale
and all washed up. In three days you're another color. . . . Girls are cooked food.39 (thirty-two-
year-old father of three)
Cooked food. . . . If you have a daughter and she takes a man, she takes the man and she goes
and lives with him. She lives with the man, and that man regards you better than he regards his
own father.40 (sixty-two-year-old father of eleven)
A guy who has daughters, he lives better. Because girls are prepared food. . . . If a jitney is
coming down the road, the driver will put him in the front seat.41 (seventy-five-year-old father
of five)
Moreover, adult daughters take their mothers in to live with them at a much higher ratio than
they take fathers in and they do so at a much higher ratio than their brothers do.42 Of the
seventy-eight parents identified as living in a household headed by one of their children, fifty-
nine of them were mothers, and in forty-six of these cases the host was a daughter (see table 13.4
below).43
But while mothers might occasionally live in homes with their daughters, the reason they favor
them arguably has to with more immediate rewards. While some observers may object to a crass
materialist approach, mothers themselves reported that the reason they prefer girls is because
they are a tremendous source of help around the homestead: 62 percent of mothers gave this as
the reason.
The value of girls means that women are eager to take in nieces, younger female cousins, and, in
an institution known as restavek, less fortunate female offspring of other families—although the
value of young girls also means they are seldom successful in procuring them. Girls learn young
how to care for the household and how to perform tasks of the mother. By the age of twelve or
thirteen years, Jean Rabel country girls can do everything their mothers can: cook, clean, take
care of younger children, and sell in the market. Indeed, when arriving at homesteads in Jean
Rabel, one often finds not the mother but a young teenage girl left in charge.
Conclusion
The bottom line is that despite a few concerns about school costs, farmers in Jean Rabel want
children. They see children as valuable economic assets and more children are better than fewer
children. Furthermore, while concerns that may be associated with old age, such as illness, are
important, farmers were not referring to adult offspring. When a sixty-five-year-old Jean Rabel
woman says she can not live without children, that she needs someone to do errands for her,
especially when she is sick, someone to fetch water and run to the market, she is not referring to
her adult children. She is talking about her grandchildren, nieces, godchildren, or the children of
neighbors, something that, as will be discussed shortly, is critical to understanding high birth
rates in Jean Rabel. Thus, statements like “children are the wealth of the poor” (pitit se byen
malere) and “it is children who save the homestead” (se ti moun ki sove kay la) are direct
references to the tasks that young children perform. These are burdensome time-consuming tasks
thought of as humiliating for an adult, but tasks that, nevertheless, must be accomplished to
maintain a viable and productive household and to free adults to engage in outside income-
earning endeavors. Both mothers and fathers prefer daughters over sons and while the most
immediate reason is for the labor contributions and greater involvement in the household,
another reason discussed shortly is that daughters are capable of having more children, thereby
contributing further to the household labor pool. In the following chapter, I show how the high
demand for children that derives from their economic utility conditions kinship, conjugal union,
and the rights, duties, and expectations associated with rearing children and benefiting from their
labor.
*****
Notes
1. In sixty-eight of the households the ranking male household member was interviewed and in
sixty-eight of the households the ranking woman was interviewed. Unintelligible responses were
omitted.
2. Pou kisa yon moun fe ti moun, se pou li ka ed-o. Kounye-a la lè ou we-m pati se mwen k-ap al
nan dlo-a, min lè ou we-m vini, mwen jwen dlo-a. Se mwen t-ap al nan bwa, lè m vini ke mwen
jwenn bwa-a.
3. Bon dieu, Bon Dieu. Se pa mwen te vle fe yo, Bon Dieu. Tout ou jwenn sa, Bon Dieu fe yo.
(Wi men gen anpil moun ki bezwenn fe ti moun). Wi. (Kouman ou ta santi si ou pa ta genyen).
Si m pat genyen li t-ap pi mal pou mwen. (Men pou ki rezon ou we ou gen yo?) Ou bezwenn ti
dlo, yo al nan dlo. Ou bezwenn ti bwa, yo al nan bwa. Ti gason yo al travay nan jaden pou ou.
Yo fe bet pou ou, y-al lonje yo, al mare yo nan jaden.
4. Ti moun nan se yon bagay ki nesesè. Pase ou bezwenn voye ou ka di, ‘ pitit, koulye-a, pou
mwen, al chèche yon ti difè pou mwen,’ ‘al chèche yon ti bwa,’ ‘al nan mache.’
5. Pou ki sa m fe ti moun? Mwen pa konprann. Ti moun la pou sevi . Tout kondi sevis pa-ou. Pa-
ou, kondi sevis pa ou. M pa ka konprann sa-k mennen lakay ou.…
6. Si ou pa gen ti moun, chyen k-ap manje ou. Si ou pa gen ti moun yon kote pou bay ou yon ti
dlo, pou ba ou yon ti dife. Si ou fe sa obyen ou gen yon bagay k-ap fe ou mal, moun fin ou ye.
7. Non, paske se yon pwotejman ti moun yo ye. Paske ti moun yo bezwenn ede o nan travay. Se
ti moun ki sove kay la.
8. O gran janme. Ti moun an pa janm bouke. Ti moun se bet. Ti moun an pa janm fatigue. Y-ap
fe tout travay. Yo t-al nan dlo. Y-ap fe tout travay.
9. Non, m pa ka viv san ti moun. Ou pa ka viv nan kay ou sel… Ti moun pa-m mwen. Yon m
bezwenn nan bouk, m voye li. M bezwenn nan dlo, m voye li. M bezwenn nan bwa, m voye yo.
Li pa ka di-m non. Alo, yè egzakmwen, ki zanimo mare la m voye al chanje, si m gon pitit yo
chanje li. Yon pa ka kanpe devan mwen pou di-m non. En sel lavi grandi.
10. Mwen menm? Pou vi tann sa a? Mwen? Si m pa ta gen ti moun menm, m pa ta fe isit menm.
M t-ap pati, m tap al deyè lòt boulet, ke m tap al chèche lot travay ke m fe pou yo peye-m kob.
11. Actually, farmers expressed favoritism for girls (see chapter 15).
12. Adults expressed this debt to children, owed in the form of education;
“Me? I need children all the time because it is all the time that children are working for me .
[But] What I am going to tell you is no lie. In the month of October I send all five of these
children to school. Then, lunch pail in hand, I take the hoe, and I set to weeding all by myself. I
go the whole day without decent food. I weed the garden. It’s the truth. No lie. Because these
days children can’t make it without school.” (forty-four-year-old mother of five)
(Mwen menm, m bezwenn ti moun tout tann paskè mwen menm se tout tann ti moun yo fe
travay pou mwen . Sa m di ou se pa manti. Nan mwa oktob m voye tou le sink ti moun sa lekol.
Kounye-a manje nan min um, m pran wou a, met sakle, kounye-a m oblije pase jounen san manje
net, m-ap sakle. Vreman, se pa manti. Kounye-a la, pliskè ti moun an pa ka leve san li pa
lekol…)
“School is the number one thing a parent can do for a child. [But] It was not a long time ago it
was livestock that was best to give your child.” (thirty-one-year-old father of five)
(Lekol se premiè byen ke yon paran ka fe pou yon ti moun. Se pa lontan se yon bet ou te bay ti
moun ke fe yo byen.)
The data used in the main text to illustrate the importance of school was actually a subsample of
eighty-four Opinion Survey respondents. The reason for the “subsample,” and not the entire
sample, was that question was added after the survey had begun. Twenty-five of the eighty-four
respondents (30%) said they sent children to school only to help the child when he or she was
grown and thirty-eight respondents (45%) indicated that educating children was in the interest of
both parents and children.
13. Y-ap bay ou 500 dola pa mwa, OK, ou nan kay ou sel o e lè lafyev pran ou e lè maladi pran
ou, sa ka okipe ou?
14. Non. M pa ka dako, sa pa ka itil ou anyen. Wi, eskè m-ap touche 500 dola le mwa, epi m pa
gen yon moun pou m di ale la, al pran ti gallon, al pran empè dlo pou mwen. Ala m-ap touche
500 dola le mwa, ala se pa desann m-ap desann, se pa grandi m-ap grandi. Tout tann,, m pap
desann? . . . Premiè byen yon moun se pitit-o. Chyen ap manje o.
15. Non. Pitit gen valè pase lajan.
16. Non. Pase, li pa fe sans . . . M tap pito pitit, paske gran moun kon di, pitit se byen pou
malere.
17. Non. Pase m bezwenn ti moun nan. M ka d-ou, ou gen lajan min ou pa ka voye lajan. Ou gen
kob la, pa fwa, epi lajan asanm av-ou ou pedi yo.
18. Pou ki rezon m pa t-ap dako? Gen yon mwayen, m rive, m kouche la, m malad. Kob la m pa
ka voye li, m-ap mouri sou li. Bagay ki pa ka fe anyen pou mwen. Se moun pou pran kob la, ki
prale, achte avek, e pran sa m merite. E m pa gen ti moun pou met nan kob la.
19. Non. Si m bezwenn yon ti dlo la, kob la pa ka ba-m mwen. Mwen pa ka voye lajan.
20. Non. Paske mwen si m pa fe ti moun, demen si dieu vle, lè m malad m pa ta jwenn moun pou
ede-m.
21. Ah, ou met gen lajan nan kay la min si ou pat gen moun pou fe pou ou. Ou met gen lajan.
Kounie-a ou met kouche mouri, si se pa pou yon moun kanpe fe yon bagay pou ou, lajan pa ke
fe. Lajan, ou met domi sou lajan, pa ka fe pou ou, se moun ki pou kanpe fe pou ou.
22. O, pitit-la se byen o li ye. Si ou pa fe pitit, chyen pi miyo pas-o. Non. M pito pitit la. Pitit la
se yon ed pou ou. Maten a si voye pitit la la, li jwenn lavi se ou menm ki jwenn lavi.
23. M pa t-ap dako. E pitit la, kob la pa fe anyen pou mwen, non. Si m malad, m-ap regle yon
bagay, ti moun nan si li la l-ap fe yo. E si m malad m pa ka voye lajan.
24 Non. Sa-k fe sa? Paskè pitit se byen pou malere. Pitit se byen.
25. O, non. (PKS). Lajan pa byen, se pitit ki ye, ki byen pou malere. Lajan pa byen.
26. Non. Paskè ou gen lajan la, si ou al jwenn yon moun pou fe yon bagay pou ou, li rete la. Min
ti moun an, depi m malad la, gade pitit um ap bouye pou mwen, ap lave pou mwen, ap bagay pou
mwen. E te lajan li te ye li pa tap fe anyen pou mwen.
27. M ta mande yon chans pou fe yon ti moun, m jwenn ti moun nesesè. M pa ta dako. Ti moun
itil.
28. There was also some reluctance to respond to any questions about children. Some
respondents refused to give children’s names and some refused to divulge how many children
they have or gave false information. Some responded easily to questions about adult activities
and then clammed up when the issue of children was introduced. The most widespread fear
among farmers is that the identities of their children may be recorded and the children sacrificed
in rituals of black magic, sold to demons, or put in a jakout (grass storage sack) and subsequently
eaten. There is even a widely recounted myth of a white boogeyman called “three buckets” (twa
ti bokit) who goes around gathering children up, cutting them into pieces, and then carries them
back to the city to eat with his white friends.
29. Translation from: Tout bon! (M d-ou twa m d-ou sis, fok ou di-m sa-k pi bon nan yo). Eh, si,
eh. Bon. Nòmal. Sou afe ti moun nan, si bon dieu ba ou twa ti moun, li pa bay ou anko, w-ap rete
sou sa bondieu ba ou-a. (Wi w-ap rete sou sa li ba ou, min se yon kesyon m-ap poz-o) Mwen la
tou bon madanmmwazel. (Wi, m konprann, ‘tout bon’. Min m t-ap mand-o, sou kesyon, twa sis,
sak pi bon nan yo? Fok ou we si se twa obyen sis la). [Silans] Sis la. (pou ki sa). Li la, l-ap ba-m
yon ed. (Min twa ka bay ou ed tou, min sis la?) Sis la, sis la ap ba ou ed. Gen sa-k kap al nan
jaden., y-ap al nan dlo, y-ap al lave. (Silans). En ben, twa.
30. Twa ta pi bon. Paskè bagay la di kounye-a. Preparasyon. Bagay la di. Se pa lontan, lè lontan
ou te ka fe ti moun. . . . Kounye-a si ou gen dis pitit, pou ou met tout lekol.
31. Twa. En ben, si m gen sis, mete tou le sis lekol, m ta depanse plis kob. Min si m gen twa, m
depanse mwens kob. Se la avantay li ka genyen. Min si bon dieu bay ou sis la, ou oblije mete tou
le sis lekol, li pa nan avantay ou. Min si bon dieu pran swenn ou, yo ka nan avantay. Gen moun
ki fe dis, yo pa itil yo menm paskè pye yo pa bon, pa gen kote pou pase. Gen ki fe 50 pou yo ede
paran.
32. Twa t-ap pi bon. Paskè dè fwa ou gen tout ti moun sa epok sitelman pa bon ou pa jwenn
posibilite pou ou ka kontiue ti moun lekol.
33. Pito sis ti moun min ou pa ka fe edikasyon pa yo.
34. Lè ou gen sis la li pi bon pou ou. (Pou ki sa?) Plis moun, plis sevis, plis okipasyon. Travay la
mache pi vit.
35. Sis. Paske si petet maten an w-wap pati, ou al nan travay, ou pat a twa, lòt twa rete lakay la
ap ede lakay la.
36. Lè ou gen sis ti moun nan li pi bon pou ou. (Pou ki sa?) Pou ki sa? Kounie-a maten-a, ou sel
la, kounye-a ou voye chak ti moun yon kote, fe yon sevis pou ou, kounye-a tout sevis regle
ansanm.
37. Tou le sis toujou impotan (Non, si ou ta gen twa o di mwen sis, kies nan yo ki tap plis
impotan?). Tou le sis. (Eskè se sis k-ap impotan obyen eske se twa k ap impotan). Tou le sis ap
impotan w-ap voye yon adwat yon agoch, tou le kat fasad.
38. Fi yo pi bon. Pou ki rezon? Sa vle di, mwen menm m gen dwa we nan yon pitit fi nan yo.
Myseu sa gen dwa we yon nan yo. Ou menm ou gen dwa we nan yon nan yo. Ou konprann.
Manje pare. Fi gen plis chans pase gason.
39. Lè ou we pitit fi-a tonbe yon kote, li ka ranmase ou. L-ap ranmase ou. Ou te met blanch
konsa, nan dè twa jou la-p vin yon lòt koulè. . . . Fi se manje kwit.
40. Manje kwit . . . Si ou gon pitit fi li pran gason, li pran myseu li rete ave. Lè lì rete a myseu,
myseu a regade papa pi mal pase bopè.
41. Neg ki gen sink ti fi viv pi byen. (Pou ki sa?) Pou ki sa? Paskè, fi se manje tou pare. . . . Si se
yon machinn ki sou wout, chofè ap monte-m mete-m devan.
42. Indeed, looking at residence patterns in table 13.4, in which it is seen that only two fathers
are hosted by daughters, it is difficult to understand why fathers favor daughters and not sons.
43. As mentioned earlier, 12 percent of teat songs put together by female dance troops included
refrains praising their mother and designating gifts and money meant for the mother, the most
common of which has the girl returning home after going away, “If you see me carrying a gift, it
is for my mother, Manman come it” (Si ou we m pote yon kado se pou fe manman-m kado,
Manman vin pran nan min). Fidelity to mothers in this respect is one of the most conspicuous
principles of a good daughter.
*****
Chapter 14
Raising Children and Control Over Child Labor Activities
Introduction
In prior chapters I illustrated the all-important role of the household and associated farming
livelihood strategies, the division of labor, the economic utility of children, and the value that
parents attach to children. In this chapter I look at the most immediate costs, behaviors, and
relations that pertain to childbirth, rearing children, and control over children. I will show how
the economic value of children conditions kinship and family patterns and how the nature of this
conditioning hinges on the costs of pregnancy—most importantly in terms of the lost labor
contributions from the mother—and the costs to chape children—meaning to get offspring
through the critical infant and toddler ages.
Birth
When a child is born in rural Jean Rabel, the umbilical cord is tied off and cut. The newborn is
wiped with a damp cloth, and the breast is given almost immediately. Purgatives are not given to
the child, as they are in some other regions of Haiti. The infant stays completely confined in the
house with its mother for the first five days of life. Jean Rabeliens are extreme in their
encouragement of the use of supplements to nourish the newborn. By eleven to fifteen days after
birth—and sometimes earlier—the baby is being given supplements in the form of tea and sugar-
water, and some women even begin feeding a kind of homemade baby food, usually a paste
made from a type of dried plantain called kiyez. Jean Rabeliens believe that girls develop
physically faster than boys, and so at two months a girl is encouraged to sit up, kase, while a boy
is not encouraged to do this until three months of age.
Paternity
The primary expenses associated with childbirth and childrearing come with caring for the
mother. A man is typically expected to assume responsibility for these costs. When a woman
becomes pregnant, and if she is not in union, she is expected to name a father. If a woman does
in fact name a father (and she sometimes does not), and if the man accepts paternity (which he
almost always does), then that man must help support the mother and child. In cases where a
man denies paternity, it is difficult or impossible to force him to support the child. But such cases
are extremely rare. In a review of the May 1999 Jean Rabel birth registry, only 5 of 469 (1%) of
registered births were fatherless (called a deklarasyon mere). Unlike in the United States where
“paternity suit” is synonymous with forcing a man to be responsible for a child, Jean Rabel
paternity suits almost always involve a man suing a woman because he has been denied control
over his child; or, the most common of all, mothers assigning paternity to multiple fathers, one
publicly and one in secrecy.
These are critical points because they highlight the labor value of children seen in previous
chapter, revealing a struggle for control over child labor that gives way to a series of
anthropologically fascinating institutions in rural Haiti. Fathers, even men who know they have
been cuckolded, rarely refuse to accept paternity. The man who is not the real father is said to
have been given a kout pitit, literally translated as having been clobbered with a child. But he
typically accepts the responsibility, if not eagerly, then without objections. Judges in the area
report that this practice occurs commonly. As mentioned in chapter 6, in a farming community
where I lived, 13 percent of men (seven of fifty-two) had at least one child who friends and
neighbors reported was also secretly recognized by another man as his own. I also discussed in
chapter 6 the fictive illness known as perdisyon, whereby gestation is thought to have become
arrested and can remain in suspension for as long as five years, allowing women to dupe their
present and former spouses and lovers into accepting paternity for children sired by other men;
or perhaps, to rephrase, allowing men a face-saving mechanism for accepting paternity for
children who do not biologically belong to them.
Far more common than men denying paternity are cases where a woman and her family do not
approve of a particular father and refuse to recognize him. The family makes this denial legal by
registering the mother’s father (the child’s grandfather) or another male relative as the child’s
natural father. Related to this is control wielded by mother’s mother. As will be seen in greater
detail in the following chapter, many of the first or first several children born in the home of the
maternal grandmother become hers. By virtue of her superior economic position and influence,
she commandeers them. The grandchildren refer to her, and not the biological mother, as
manman or momi.
In the event a named father does not support the child, or the woman has refused him rights, the
woman may accept support from another man during her pregnancy and the nursing period. This
“father” is known as the papa nouriti (the nourishing father), and it is then him who has paternal
rights to the child’s labor and it is him who must be repaid if the biological father wishes to gain
control over his child.
The man is expected to begin helping to provide for the mother as soon as her pregnancy
becomes apparent. When the baby is born, the paternal grandmother brings ginger, plantains, and
chickens or a goat to be slaughtered and fed to the postpartum mother. When mother and infant
emerge from the customary five days of postpartum confinement, the “mother-in-law” again
brings plantains and meat (a goat is brought and killed if none was slaughtered at the occasion of
the birth). For the next two to three months the woman remains in semi-confinement and does
little work. During this period, the man is expected to provide extra amounts of meat, and other
nourishing foods.3 The father must also plant a garden for the mother and child and allocate
animals to them—animals that he cares for and the proceeds from which will go to help the
mother chape the child (see below). When a child begins primary school, it is also the father who
is expected to pay the 345 gdes a year (US$20.53) needed for tuition and the obligatory school
uniform.4
The Working Child
The working child is, as seen, an important and necessary factor in household livelihood
security. The most important stage in child development is that point when he or she becomes
more of a benefit than a cost, a point denoted by the term chape (literally, “to escape”). A child is
considered to chape “when he can do for himself” (li ka fe pou kont li), “when he can wash his
own clothes” (lè li ka lave rad pa li), “when he can ‘get by’” (lè li ka boukannen),5 and “when he
can go to the water by himself” (lè li ka al nan dlo pou kont li).6 The word is also inverted to
apply to the act and cost of bringing a child to the point where he can not only take care of his
own needs, but also make contributions to the survival of the household. The notion of chape
was mentioned recurrently during the followup survey as in the examples given below:
Oh, why does a person have children? You have children. You struggle to chape them. . . .You
raise them. They chape. Tomorrow God willing, if you need a little water, the child can get it for
you. If you need a little firewood, he can carry it for you.7 (fifty-five-year-old father of seventeen
children)
I had children, now I have a problem, now the children can solve the problem. Tomorrow God
willing I cannot help myself, it is on the children I will depend. Today I chape them. Tomorrow
God willing we struggle with life together.8 (forty-one-year-old mother of four children)
In rural Jean Rabel, children as young as two and three years of age do small chores like fetching
utensils and carrying messages to the neighbors. At three to four years of age they are going to
the water with other children and returning with a gallon jug awkwardly balanced on their head.
At five to eight years of age the child will chape, for it is at these ages he/she begins to go by
himself to the water, start a fire, wash clothes, tend animals, find food in the garden, and go
alone to make small purchases in the market. By the age of seven, boys are typically trusted to
tend goats and sheep without supervision by an adult or older child. By the age of eleven a boy
can hoe a garden and may even participate in reciprocal work groups composed of other
prepubescent and teenage boys. Similarly, by eight or nine years of age a girl can sell goods
during short absences of her mother, both in the market or the home, and she can wash most
clothes—except for large bulky items like pants, which require considerable strength to wring
out. By ten or eleven years of age most girls have already had the experience of taking the family
donkey on a twenty- to thirty-mile trek to and from a market to make purchases for the
household. At this age, the girl does not go alone but in groups with other young girls or with a
neighbor. As seen above, by the age of twelve or thirteen, Jean Rabel country girls can do
everything their mother can, making the labor value of girls, coupled with their ability to bear
additional children, significant factors in parents favoring daughters over sons (see previous
chapter).
I would ask my co-mother or my co-father if I could get a child. That means, I would ask if I
could take the child as mine because a godchild is the same thing as a child.11 (thirty-one-year-
old father of five children)
Table 14.1: Child residence patterns: Relationship of child household members to head of
household (Missing = 86; children under nineteen years of age)
People sometimes jokingly say, Kale, kale, kale. Ti moun fet pou kale (Whip! Whip! Whip!
Children are born to be whipped!). But the whipping a child receives is generally no joke. The
child is usually held by the hand and whipped about the bare legs with a raso (braided rope
whip), a rigwaz (a strip of dried bull testicles also used on mules and horses), or a fret (a thin,
flexible branch taken from a bush or tree). By Western standards the whipping is brutal. The
child typically does much screaming and begs for mercy. Blood is sometimes drawn and many
children bear scars on their legs. “Children” as old as their late teens and even into their early
twenties are whipped across the palms by schoolteachers or made to kneel for hours at a time as
punishment for not turning in homework or for speaking disrespectfully. Young women are
sometimes switched severely for consorting with men of whom their parents disapprove (see
Murray 1977: 172; and Metraux 1951 for descriptions of severity with children).15
Conclusion
Maternity, paternal obligations to support a pregnant woman or mother with a child who has yet
to chape, earned paternal rights, and godparentage define who controls the labor activities of a
child. These are reciprocal relationships in that everyone involved must also contribute to the
child’s growth and education. But the most significant feature of the relationships, the one that
takes precedence above all else, is that the child must work, he must do as he is told by those
who have a right to control his activities, and the recourse to corporal punishment assures that he
or she will in fact cooperate. In this way the relationships described are conditioned by the
distribution of rights over the control of child labor. In the following chapter the presence of
children and control over their productive labor activities are shown to be principal factors in
consecrating a conjugal union and defining rights and duties between spouses.
*****
Notes
1. The most common baby formula is made with a banana-like plantain called a kiyez. Milk may
be added as well as smashed crackers.
2. Even in the very worst case scenario when antibiotics, antifungal agents, antimalaria pills and
antacid are called for, clinicians report that costs should not exceed 58 gdes (US$3.50). A
Caesarean can cost as much as 1,000 gdes (US$60.00).
3. The duration of semi-confinement is the only custom discovered that bears on the difference
between boys versus girls. If a woman has given birth to a boy she will not begin to do
significant chores again and she will take extraordinary care not to immerse her body in cold
water or expose herself to the cold for approximately three months. If the child is a girl, the time
is usually two months. The explanation is that carrying and birthing a boy is harder on a woman.
Similarly, girls will be encouraged to sit up (kase) at a younger age than boys—the same two
versus three months.
4. The typical cost for primary school in rural Jean Rabel for the 1999–2000 school year was 35
gdes first payment, 25 gdes per month, and 75 to 100 gdes to make a school uniform, a school
year total of 345 gdes (US$20.53).
5. “Lè li ka boukannen’”(when he can barbeque) is an expression that derives from children
digging up and cooking sweet potatoes, something young children, especially boys, often do, and
it signifies a child’s ability to look after himself.
6. The term chape literally means to escape and in this literal sense of the word a person can
chape a danger on their own or someone can chape them—save them. Similarly the term chape
can be used to describe that point at which a child “escapes” the dangers of infant and childhood
disease and, in this way, people in Jean Rabel sometimes use chape as a synonym for weaned.
Chape can also be used to describe a child who has managed to finish school and find a well-
paying job; such a person has chaped the “small” life of an impoverished farmer. By the same
token, a mother may go barefoot to chape, in this instance to educate, her older children. But the
most common connotation of the term chape and one that all adults interviewed were in
agreement with denotes that point when a child is more of a benefit than a cost. In addition to the
quotes already given in the body of the text, others include Lè ou ka pran ti moun an e mete li
kinpot kote epi l-ap viv (when you can put a child anywhere and he will survive), Lè li konnen
kouman pou mande pou manje (when he knows how to ask for food), lè li gen lespri (when a
child achieves common sense), lè li ka rete nan kay la pou kont li (when he can get by without
constant adult supervision ), and lè li ka retire min ni nan difè (when he will take his hand out of
the fire).
7. O, pou ki yon moun fe ti moun? Ke vle di, ou fe ti moun nan. W-ap bat pou chape yo. . . L-ap
grandi yo. L-ap chape. Demen si dieu vle, si ou bezwen ti dlo li ka ba ou. Si ou bezwenn ti bout
bwa li ka pote li pou ou. Ou bezwenn ni konn ed.
8. Mwen fe ti moun, kounye-a m vin gen yon pwoblem, kounye-a ti moun ka redi pwoblem.
Demen si dieu vle, m vin pa kapab, se sou kont ti moun m-ap vini. Kounye-a map chape yo.
Demen si dieu vle yo ka bat ave-m.
9. The second question a person in Jean Rabel asks, right after “Do you have any children?” is
“Are your parents alive?” (Mama ou la? Papa ou la?). Then, “Where are they?” (Kote yo ye?)
“Do they miss you?” (Yo pa sonje ou?), and finally, “Are you going to visit them?” (Lè ou al lòt
bo eskè ou pral vizite yo?).Woe to those who reply that they do not visit their mother or send her
money, “You should go see her. She misses you. She is the one who made you. You seem to be a
bad person” (Fo ou al we mam’o. L’ap sonj’o. Se li ki fe ou. Ou gen lè pa bon moun.).
10. Ou met kale li jan ou vle sof ou pa ka touye li—pou sa y-ap mete ou prizon.
1. Pa fwa ou we ou pa gen ti moun konsa, m te kapab fe deman a makomè oswa makompè epi
pou m te ka jwenn ti moun sa. Ke vle di, pou li ka sevi-m. Paskè yon fiyel se yon pitit.
12. M ale nan min moun, m pran dè ti moun. M mete yo tou dè lekol anko. Pou ki, pou ki?
Telman m pa ka viv san ti moun. . . . M bezwenn dlo-a, kounye-a m te gen yon isit ave-m, li al
lakay pou yo voye dlo pou mwen. Demen si dieu vle li al lekol la, m toujou bat pou li gen sandal
li avek rad pou mete, ni pou li manje.
13. The restavek institution is a rural-village and rural-urban phenomenon; rural farmers loan
children to town and city people to gain sociopolitical and commercial contacts in village and
urban areas and to attain educational opportunities for their children.
14. Lè yo di yon ti moun krent fret se pa lè yo we fret yo krie, non, se lè yo toujou panse sou fret
nan tout bagay yap fe. Se sa ki fe ti moun yo mache dwat.
15. In contrast to whipping a child about the bare legs, slapping is considered brutal. There was
an incident in the village in 1998 when a French nurse, scurrying two children out of an area
where they were not supposed to be playing, slapped the child of a school supervisor on the side
of the head. Within the hour, an outraged crowd of upper-level Jean Rabel school administrators,
including the boy’s father who had been in an nearby meeting, had gathered outside where the
nurse was working. When the nurse tried to leave, they blocked her, harangued her, and
ultimately convinced her to settle the issue by permitting the child to slap her in the face. One of
the nurse’s Haitan coworkers, a man who was also a Jean Rabelien, arrived just in time to
witness the nurse being slapped and he entered into what nearly became a badly outnumbered
brawl between himself and the crowd of school authorities. The incident continued on the radio
with the school supervisor using the nurse’s behavior as an example of how offensive foreigners
sometimes behave toward Haitians. The French NGO directors were equally outraged by what
they saw as a forced and public humiliation of the nurse. There were calls to ministers and much
complaining. In the end, the incident passed, nobody lost their jobs, there were no official public
reprimands, nor did any apologies come from either side.
Chapter 15
Conjugal Union and the Formation of the Household
Introduction
It was seen in the previous chapter that labor value of children gives way to a rigid defining of
how children are treated and who has control over them. In this way the value of children as
contributors to the household labor pool is a primary conditioner of consanguineal and fictive
relations—such as godparentage. This important role of children and the institutionalized control
over them is embedded in the petty farming and autonomous regional marketing economy seen
in earlier chapters, and in the following chapter I show how children free women to engage in
marketing. But particular emphasis must first be placed on the household because it is there that
children make their primary contributions. In this chapter it will be seen that the indispensable
role of children in household production couples with the infrastructural requisites of
establishing a household to also determine the rules and expectations associated with conjugal
union.
To illustrate the rights and duties that derive from demand control over household production, I
draw on interviews with judges, farmers, and actual cases, in addition to survey data. In many
instances, decisions made by judges in the Jean Rabel courthouse differ from official Haitian
civil law, and in some instances, decisions handed down in the village courthouse differ from the
expectations and actual behavior of locals. Child support, for example, is a paternal statutory
duty whether the mother and father are married, living together, or not in union at all. Jean Rabel
judges recognize this legal duty and even insist that they enforce it. But in practice a Jean Rabel
woman rarely summons a man to court for child support and, if she does, the court cannot
enforce a decision ordering a man to pay child support (more common are men who summon
women to court because they are angry that the woman has assigned paternity, and hence rights
of control over a child, to another man). Thus, where official civil law and local legal procedure
differ, I have emphasized the local procedure; where local legal procedure and practice differ, I
have emphasized the practice. I begin with the definition of a child to show how the status of
child and concept of a household and control over production are, in the minds of rural Haitians,
inextricably bound.
All other property is divided equally or according to the original purchaser. After the birth of a
child the rules change. Even if a man and woman no longer wish to have sexual relations and
separate, everything in and around the house remains with the household. It is in this sense that
people in Jean Rabel say that a woman is the owner of the house in the name of her children. The
woman is sou dwa pitit li (literally, on the rights of her children), and she has a right to remain in
the house undisturbed by her husband or his family so long as she continues to care for the
children and so long as she does not openly engage in a relationship with another man. As
already mentioned, the man must continue to provide for the household by raising livestock and
planting gardens that the wife will harvest, selling the produce in the local market to pay for
household subsistence needs and to engage in further marketing activities. If the man fails to
plant a garden, the woman may take over this role using his land.
I showed in earlier chapters that a household is the single most important unit of production in
Jean Rabel. A household means food and shelter today, tomorrow, next year, and the years after.
It is through ownership of a household and the presence of the working children that a man and
woman are freed to engage in outside income-generating activities.
In this chapter I showed how the ability to reproduce and control over children give women
institutionalized control over the household. The man and the woman aside, there are two
ingredients for the formation of a de facto contractually complete conjugal union: a house—
which is built by the husband—and children—produced by the woman and fathered, reputedly,
by the man. In this way the conjugal contract in Jean Rabel can be thought of as a woman ceding
a man partial rights over her reproductive capacity and domestic services in exchange for a
house. Men subsequently must plant gardens and tend livestock. Women must subsequently
manage the household and sell the garden produce and livestock, the proceeds from which are
used to meet household subsistence expenses and to raise the children to the point where they
become contributing members of the household. When their husbands are complying with their
customary obligations, women are bound to absolute sexual fidelity. On the other hand, a man
may engage in union with other women and father “outside” children without losing his rights in
the original homestead—so long as he continues to provide financial support. In concluding,
these may appear to be unfavorable conditions for women; a woman must abide faithfully by her
spouse while men can do as they please. Anthropologists have commented on this and in the
following chapter it will be seen that Haiti has often been represented as one of the most
repressive countries for women on the planet. But with respect to rural Haiti this is an error.
Control over households, obtained through their natural position as mothers, engenders a control
over the local economy and individual autonomy that arguably puts women in a position of
power superior to their spouses.
*****
Notes
1. In a review of the commune of Jean Rabel’s birth registry for May 1999, only 27 percent of
469 births were to legally married parents (enfant legitime) and 337 (72%) were born to
unmarried parents (enfant natiral). Only 5 (1%) of the 469 children born did not have a man
attesting to having fathered the child (deklarasyon mè).
2. Madanm marie ak fi ki gen ti moun gen menm fòs pou goume and alternatively, Fi ki gen pitit
ak fi marie se menm bagay: Tou dè gen menm kouray pou goumen.
3. A man who has not built a house for a woman has no recourse to complain should the woman
entertain other suitors—her response would likely be, “well build me a house.”
4. Harvesting in Jean Rabel is thought of as a woman’s right and most women will claim in the
name of her children any garden not being planted in the name of another woman, so that even if
a man were to attempt to plant a garden independent of his wife—married or plasaj—he must do
so secretly for if she gets wind of it she is likely to show up for harvest time and there may be
much cursing if he tries to stand in her way.
5. Although it is rare for a man to actually succeed in depriving his wife of her children, farmers
and local judges are unanimous in insisting that a man has this right in the event of the woman’s
sexual infidelity. Also in theory, if a woman should leave the house in anger, she must go stay
with her mother-in-law or her husband’s otherwise closest relative and if she fails to do so, even
if she goes to the house of her own mother, she has, according to local judges, legally committed
adultery.
*****
Chapter 16
Polygyny, Progeny, and Production Introduction
In the preceding chapters I tried to show how the importance of child labor with respect to
household livelihood strategies—specifically the negotiation and sharing of access between
genders, parents, and friends to control over child labor—conditions childrearing practices,
kinship, family patterns, and even gender roles and division of labor. Here I want to bring
together the preceding observations to show how it is that these customs and behaviors, as well
as the pronatal sociocultural fertility complex seen in chapter 5 and the values associated with
the sexual moral economy described in chapter 6 come about, how they are perpetuated, whose
interests they serve, and how they relate to the subsistence strategies and the regional economy. I
begin with a look at another misunderstood issue in Haiti, female repression; then I use
polygyny, an institution considered by many advocates and aid workers to be a defining indicator
of female repression but which in Haiti arguably works to the economic advantage of women;
and ultimately I show how the importance of household-based production and the child labor
upon which it is based mean that middle-aged women play a determinant role in perpetuating the
relations of production and reproduction.
Definition of Polygyny
Polygyny in Jean Rabel is not legal but it is different from the “extramarital affair” in that (1) it
is public, (2) efforts are made to produce children in all of the unions, (3) the man continues to
perform his role as provider, planting gardens and tending livestock for all of the women, and (4)
the women are expected to remain sexually faithful to the man.3
All Jean Rabeliens recognize the institution of polygyny, and all women engaged in union with a
particular man are referred to as his wives (madanm). There are, in fact, three interchangeable
terms for women who share a husband—matlot, rival, and koleg—meaning co-wives or co-wife.
Co-wives usually live in separate homesteads and the houses of the different wives are usually at
least several kilometers one from the other. Among fishermen however, it is not unusual for
wives to live in the same small hamlet. In Makab, for example, three fishermen had two or more
of their wives living in the hamlet itself. Bokor (healers/shaman) are also an anomaly among
polygynous men; they are notorious for having multiple wives living in the same compound and
sometimes even in the same household and being able to maintain peace among all of them. The
ability of bokor to manage this type of situation is something that even fishermen do not
accomplish and that never ceases to amaze other Jean Rabeliens.4
Frequency of polygyny
At any given time, 11 percent of male Jean Rabel household heads are engaged in a conjugal
union with more than one woman (Table 16.1). This may not seem like a large number of men,
but with age the likelihood that he is or has been engaged in a polygynous union increases. Forty
percent of men over the age of fifty have been polygynous at least once in their lives (table
16.2).5
Economic Independence
While wealth appears to facilitate polygyny, the most important determinant of polygyny is not
wealth, per se, but rather whether or not a man has a source of income beyond the control of his
first wife. Skilled workers build houses and collect their pay with no participation from their
wives. Bokor do not depend on their wives to help serve their clientele. Schoolteachers instruct
students and collect their pay independently and fishermen are not dependent on their wives for
fishing or even for the sale of fish in the market.8
The most productive male farmers were also found to maintain multiple families, but a closer
looks shows that here too the issue is not only the increased wealth of the man, but wealth
beyond control of his first wife. A large landowner typically cannot and does not plant all of his
land. More often, the man rents and sharecrops parcels of the land to less fortunate individuals,
something that allows him to move beyond the influence of, and dependency on, a single wife. In
contrast, the average farmer does not have multiple wives. Even men who reported owning
irrigated and “fat” land—high-yield garden plots the ownership of even a small parcel of which
unquestionably places a household in the category of economically elite farmers—were not
found to be unusually polygynous until the amount of their reported landholdings reached levels
beyond the control of a single household (see table 16.4). Thus, it appears that men are
polygynous when they can get away with it. But again, this does not necessarily mean that
polygyny is an institution in the best interest of men, a point evident when I asked them.
Table 16.4: Polygynous males by the amount of “fat” and irrigated land owned
Ahh, there is no advantage. Men don’t understand, it brings you down financially. It’s just one
little wife who truly pushes you ahead.9 (fifty-year-old father of twelve)
When you have several wives it is a bunch of work. . . . Right now this morning, if you work this
wife’s garden, you have to go work the other garden for the other wife.10 (seventy-five-year-old
father of seven)
Yes, there are advantages, because there are people who have several wives. But if it is food, or
whatever, I don’t know.12 (forty-year-old father of five)
No there are no advantages. Because you must plant gardens for both of them so you can send
them both to the market. There is no advantage.13 (fifty-three-year-old father of nine)
So why have more than one wife? In the subsample taken of ten polygynous men, nine of the
men explained that having more than one wife serves either to compensate for the absence of the
first wife, such as when she is away on marketing trips, or to provide an alternative to spending
time with an argumentative first wife. 14
When your wife is not getting along with you . . . you have somewhere else you can go eat and
drink.15 (fifty-five-year-old father of seventeen)
If the first one is not good, you have to look for another.16 (twenty-nine-year-old father of nine)
If one wife is not there, the man he goes, he goes to the head of the other house who left a little
food for him . . . he goes and eats it. It is this, and after this it is a drain.17 (forty-five-year-old
father of five)
Even then, when men took second wives they rarely left the first one. Only one of the seven
polygynous men in the Opinion Survey was no longer with his first wife (see table 16.5).
Table 16.5: Men who have ever been polygynous by men who have left their first wife
(missing = 16)
In summary, it is not clear why some Jean Rabel men take second and even third or fourth wives.
If we base conclusions on what men say, then perhaps the best explanation is because they feel
they must, the first wife or wives are not living up to her/their end of the conjugal contract and
the man having no means of forcing her to do so. In any case, a more illuminating issue is why
women put up with the behavior in the first place.
Table 16.7: A man takes a second wife, may first wife be unfaithful (missing male
responses=15)
What seems to be an attitude of passive toleration may arguably be consequences of norms that
militate against female infidelity. There are not many choices open to a woman who refuses to
accept her husband's taking another wife. She can leave her husband and return to her parent’s
house, but if she does so she sacrifices her own house and her right to claim support from her
husband. If the woman engages in an affair with another man she may be required to give up
considerably more than the house and support for, as seen in an earlier chapter, doing so would
give the man the right to throw her off the property and keep the children, or at least give them to
his mother.
Moreover, no matter how tolerant of polygyny women say they are, the ethnographic reality is
that a Jean Rabel woman is likely and even expected to react strongly to her husband taking
another spouse. She may go no further than harsh words. But with a woman who is bandi (a
scrapper)—as many Jean Rabel women pride themselves on being—violence is common.
Displaying little or no aggression toward the husband—indeed, wooing and sweet-talking him in
private—a Jean Rabel wife will make violent statements to others of intent to physically attack
the other woman. She will curse her in the street and in the market. It is not unusual for this wife
to go to the other woman’s house and stand outside screaming insults at her. She may stalk her.
She may wait at crossroads and on paths to ambush and beat her. She may throw rocks at her,
scratch her, or try to bite the other woman’s lip in order to disfigure her face.
So it might be said that women are pushed into a situation where they have little choice but to
conform to their husband’s philandering. When a man is no longer economically dependent on
the labor contributions of his first wife there is a great probability that he may enter into conjugal
union with another woman and take on a second family. In this way it does appear that women
are repressed victims of a patriarchal familial system. However, there is another side to it: Men
need women more than vice versa.
Thus, to vulgarize the analysis, as, in fact, a Jean Rabelien might do, the simple truths are (1)
getting a wife is the most materially rewarding alliance a Jean Rabel man can form with another
person and (2) men do not fight over women because they know that what stands between them
and a wife is not other men, but their own ability to provide.
Women understand the need men have for a wife, and, like men, they too think that a husband is
in greater need of his wife than vice versa. Only 13 percent of women reported that a wife needs
her husband more, but 23 percent of women reported that a husband is in greater need of his wife
(table 16.8). When asked, “can you get by without your spouse?” 96 percent of men interviewed
said no, in comparison to 77 percent of women interviewed who responded no (table 16.9
below).
Moreover, women, much more so than men, chose their spouse for material reasons: forty-five of
sixty-four men said they chose their spouse because of love; only twenty-seven of sixty-eight
women said so. Twenty-six of the sixty-eight women said they chose their spouse because he
was a good worker; only one man said so. Thirteen of the sixty-four male respondents said they
chose their wife because it was the only one they could find; four of sixty-eight women said so.
Table 16.10: Why men versus women chose their spouse (missing=4)
I am gonna be angry because I will lose some of what he gives me.18 (thirty-five-year-old
mother of four)
I am not going to be comfortable because he is going to be giving the other woman money.20
(thirty-three-year-old mother of eight)
But the fact is that the average wife of the average husband in Jean Rabel is not especially
worried about the prospect of their husband entering into a union with another woman. Going
back to the greater female vs. male tolerance of polygyny, the common response women gave to,
“does your husband have another or other wives?” was not a simple, “No,” but rather, “No, he is
too poor” (Non, pase li malere). The average farmer’s wife knows her husband cannot afford
another wife, and perhaps more importantly, she knows he needs her and the children, and this
was evident in responses many women gave when asked what they would do in the event their
husband took another woman:
I would talk to him. I would not curse him because if the guy had something, if he had a good
paying job, I would raise hell, I would have a serious little chat with him. But the guy has no job,
he has no education, he has nothing.22 (thirty-two-year-old mother of five)
Ah well, I would not do anything, it is not me who made him do it . . . He’ll be back, he’ll be sick
and to the house he’ll be coming. There is not anyone before me. It is me who is first.23 (fifty-
year-old mother of seven)
If he finds a woman who is brave, he goes and spends a couple days with her, let him go with the
girl because he is not a child, you can’t beat him.24 (thirty-four-year-old mother of three)
If it is strength he feels, if he feels strong, I won’t stop his strength.25 (sixty-five-year-old mother
of nine)
I would not do anything. If he listens to me, if I tell him “No, times are not good, you can not
have two wives. For example, like today, it is only a single two dollars you have there, and if
there are two of us, you can not give us each only a dollar.” Ah, he can’t do it.26 (twenty-seven-
year-old mother of five)
He cannot abandon me completely. He has to come sit there and help me chape [raise] the
children.27 (forty-year-old mother of four)
Just so long as I have a path to go down I would not pay any attention. I would look after my
children. Especially with him, I can’t leave him. We are married, I cannot leave him. It is an
engagement we have together. I have a bunch of children with him.28 (sixty-five-year-old
mother of nine)
It is here with the women’s tolerance of their husbands’ infidelity that the argument merits
returning to another factor that enters into the decisions made by women regarding the choice of
a spouse: male wealth, for it is precisely male wealth that makes polygyny an attractive
institution; but for women in pursuit of economic independence achieved throughout
childbearing.
Table 16.11: Women vs. men in union per five-year age group
Reproductive Reluctance and the Matriarch
Despite everything seen above, there is one catch: young Jean Rabel women are often not so
eager to begin their childbearing career. As was seen in chapter 5, girls pregnant for the first time
often disavow their condition right up until the time their bulging stomachs make denial
impossible. Others tie ribbons around their stomachs to conceal their condition. Others try to
abort pregnancies, taking desperate measures that sometimes end in death. But entrance into a
childbearing career is not something that women decide by themselves. Elder women in control
of homesteads frame the conditions that make pregnancy likely or, to put it another way, almost
impossible to avoid.
In earlier chapters it was shown that children are highly valued and that slightly more than half
of all farmers would prefer to have six rather than three children. But when the respondents were
broken down by sex and age group, it was overwhelmingly women, and specifically middle-age
and elder women, who most favored large numbers of children. Women over fifty were far more
inclined than any other male or female age category to choose the couple with six versus three
children: Fully 87 percent (twenty of the twenty-three women) chose the couple with six children
(see table 13.1). The reasons have to do with the economic benefits that accrue to older women.
With greater numbers of children, women begin to plant their own gardens and to raise more
animals, activities that free a woman from dependency on men (see table 16.12; see also
Schwartz 2000: 153–57). The women who said they could live without a man were precisely
those with children in the ages when they made contributions to the household.
What makes me say I can live without a man? What I need to do to come up with a sack of food I
can accomplish with my four children.32 (thirty-year-old mother of four).
If I have children, I don’t need my husband at all. Children, hey! hey! I would like to have ten
children. I don’t need my husband.33 (forty-one-year-old mother of seven).
Why can I live without a man? I arrive at an age like this. All my affairs are in order. I don’t
need my husband anymore.34 (fifty-six-year-old mother of eight)
But younger women often do not see these advantages. Moreover, the older woman who controls
the activities of her nubile daughters is keenly alert not only to the importance of her daughter
bearing children relatively early on in life for the sake of the younger woman’s household and
marketing career but also to the advantages that accrue to herself, as the grandmother.
Table 16.13: Union type by household residents under thirty years old (but over fourteen)
who are not the head or spouse of head
Everyone, especially the mother’s mother, is able to benefit. As seen in an earlier chapter, in the
event a daughter becomes pregnant while living in mother’s home, it is her mother, the child’s
grandmother, who assumes the role of mother. While the real mother only breastfeeds the child
or does mundane tasks such as cleaning up after him, the grandmother refers to the child as her
own. The child is taught to call her manman (mother), not gran (grandmother), while the mother
is called by her first name as if she were the child’s sister. Even after the mother has moved out
to plase with a man, the grandmother often keeps the grandchild or several of the
grandchildren.35
I want to make clear that the concern parents display regarding the sexual activities of their
daughters and the emphasis I have put on the economic aspects of paternity should not be
interpreted as intrusive or even unusual. Like parents elsewhere in the world, parents in Jean
Rabel want their daughters to make practical decisions regarding mates, and they encourage
them to bear children with men who can support the young women economically and who will
help pay for the cost to chape offspring. Moreover, as seen in chapter 13, daughters are a critical
source of labor for the household. They tend to be the most productive, they can take over the
role of mother, and both mothers and fathers significantly favor daughters over sons. A
daughter’s pregnancy represents a critical disruption in her life in that it reduces her labor
contributions to the household. Yet, 49 percent (1,046 of 2,135) of women over fourteen but
under thirty years of age and still living in their mother’s home had born at least one child (figure
16.1); and twenty-two percent (237 of 1,078) of young women under the age of thirty who were
reported during the baseline as being in the formative phase of a conjugal union—meaning they
identified themselves as being in union with a man but had not yet acquired an independent
homestead—were in fact still living in the home of their mother, father, or another relative (table
16.13). It is at this juncture that parents, particularly mothers, play a determining role in
polygyny. As a civil judge in Jean Rabel explained:
A lot of the time it is the parents themselves who plase girls. Sometimes the parents, they are so
interested in money, their daughter loves a young man who is the same age as her, they could
marry, but the parents don’t accept it. They see that at that time in the young man’s life he can
not do anything. He cannot give money. Then the parents see by the way the girl is acting that
she is going to plase with a married man. But the fact that the married man can give money
causes them to close their eyes so the daughter can take the money from him. It is like this.
Adults are behind it.36 (Civil judge in Jean Rabel)
Figure 16.1: Children under thirty years old (but over fourteen), who have children of their
own but still living in parent’s household (N = 2,135)
People having borne children
60%
50%
49
40%
30% 30
20% M Fe
al m
e al
e
Gender
******
Whether the dynamics described above are to be construed as mothers exploiting daughters or as
a partnership in the mutual interest of both mother and daughter is a matter of opinion. As seen,
daughters revere their mothers, loyalty to mother is among the highest values, and the
subsistence alliance between mother and daughter and the role of the mother in guiding a girl’s
sexual conduct are celebrated in teat songs, as in the following:
Conclusion
Gender relations in Jean Rabel are not at all what they first seem to be. Men are more dependent
on their wives than vice versa. After obtaining a homestead and entering a union, it is the woman
who dominates the domestic affairs of the household. Women are more aggressive, they
violently attack other women who try to engage in relationships with their husbands, and, while
male violence against women does occur, the ethnographic reality is that Jean Rabel women—
through their own efforts or a coalition of family members—more often hurt men than vice
versa. As for polygyny, men might have the socially condoned option of having multiple wives
but many women engage in outside relations, and they most often convince their husbands to
accept as their own children sired by other men. Why men accept them is because they too are
heavily dependent on the child labor that makes households productive.
As for why men take other wives, and why, if women are so powerful they are able to do so, it
was seen that men in Jean Rabel are not really sure. The best answers any of them could come up
with had to do with neglect by their first wife. Women, on the other hand, understood very well
why they chose their husbands. Whether the man already had a wife or not, the principal reason
women gave was to obtain labor, financial support, and children. As one woman explained, “He
gives me money for the children, that is what makes me prefer having him around” (twenty-
seven-year-old mother of five). 37
It is children and the labor they provide, more than husbands and wives, who are the most
important component of household livelihood strategies. And it is here that both an
understanding of the superior control of women and the female role in determining polygyny
begins to become apparent, for in the gender and age division of labor there is another critically
important difference between men and women: by virtue of woman’s ability to reproduce, her
control over children, and the sharing of that capacity with men, she is able to gain
institutionalized control over homesteads.
In conclusion, Jean Rabel women are best viewed not as bearing and rearing large numbers of
children primarily to secure economic support from men, but rather as securing economic
support from men primarily so they can bear and raise large numbers of children. Were all or
even most Jean Rabel women to do otherwise, were they to behave like Hutterites and abide by
ideals of chastity and monogamous Western marriage, many would be deprived of their principal
avenue to economic autonomy: establishing a household. Jean Rabel women, as is typical of
people who live so close to the margin of survival, make no pretensions about the raw material
logic of conjugal unions and raising children:
If a person marries, why does she marry? She does not marry to be a big shot or anything like
that. It is so she can have children… Why does a person want children? It is to help…to go to the
water…to go get wood.38 (forty-year-old mother of five)
What I am telling you is when you are young, you need a husband. What I mean is, if you haven’t
had children yet. So you can make a child.39 (forty-two-year-old mother of three)
And so it all comes back to the prosaic fact that in the harsh and unpredictable environment of
rural Haiti, children are extremely useful, a fact echoed in the poignant words of another woman:
The whole country can be full of money for women. But money is useless, because they will eat it
all and take it. One little thing someone does for you because he knows you have no children, it
can cost one hundred dollars. . . . In order for money to work you must have children. If you
have no one, money can’t work for you. Ahh, you can pay people to work. But if it ain’t your
child they will take all you have. They will load you up with lies. They will load you up with a
bunch of things that are no good. But when it’s your child, you always succeed.40 (fifty-three-
year-old mother of nine)
****
Notes
1. All the scholars cited in the main text did research touching on the division of labor in rural
Haiti.
2. In over four years of following life in Makab, seventeen violent conflicts were documented. In
only three of the conflicts did a woman suffer blows from a man and in an equal number of cases
a man was beaten by a single woman or a group of women. The most brutal beatings involved
women beating men or women and men beating a man on behalf of a woman.
Four of the seventeen conflicts involved men only, and five of the conflicts involved only
women. In the eight remaining conflicts the principal combatants were a man and a woman. In
three instances the woman was slightly injured. In one instance the fight turned into a small war.
In another instance a woman kicked and slapped her drunken ex-lover and physically threw him
out of her house. Another incident involved a relatively weak cuckolded man who tried to beat
his wife but was hit by a large stick wielded by a neighbor woman who subsequently marched
the man off to the police station. In another instance, a man was severely beaten and stabbed by
his wife and four sisters-in-law. In another incident a man allegedly struck a woman and was
immediately clubbed and kicked nearly to death by about a quarter of the village population.
Here are the most interesting cases, beginning with the oddest: A very aggressive and physically
ugly woman aged thirty-two had stripped naked and flaunted herself before her mother-in-law
whom she was angry with for having taken a fish given to her by her son—the angry woman’s
husband. Cursing and parading herself back and forth in front of her mother-in-law, the angry
wife stopped, bent over and, slapping her naked buttocks, showed her anus to her offended
mother-in-law. The wife’s brother-in-law—another son of the now indignant mother-in-law—
had been standing by looking on and he attacked his naked, buttock slapping sister-in-law,
knocking her to the ground. (The son-in-law/husband was present and also took offense to his
wife’s behavior but he did not enter into the conflict, maintaining neutrality which is probably all
that kept the incident from becoming a brawl between his and his wife’s family.)
In five of the cases of physical conflict in the village, several women together, or several women
and men, engaged in some configuration of combat. The most severe case occurred in the house
in which I had recently been staying. The man’s name was Rimmie (not his real name),
undisputedly the strongest swimmer and deepest diver in the village. The conflict began over a
bicycle. Rimmie had arrived in the village riding the bicycle, which belonged to his other wife—
one that did not live in Makab. Two of his daughters, aged seven and eleven, borrowed the
bicycle and went for a joy ride, which ended with the seven-year-old screaming and crying with
a banged knee. An aunt came along (Rimmie’s sister-in-law) and spanked both the girls. She
then punctured the front tire of the bicycle with a thorn, making sure there were to be no more
joy rides and undoubtedly also intending to make a statement about her feelings toward her
brother-in-law’s other wife. When Rimmie discovered what had been done, a screaming and
shoving match erupted between him and his tire-poking sister-in-law. Being the stronger,
Rimmie pushed his sister-in-law down and jumped on top of her. Unfortunately for Rimmie, his
estranged wife and three other sisters-in-law had been standing by watching. The first sister-in-
law to strike was the youngest, a fourteen-year-old girl, who with both hands lifted a small
boulder over her head and hurled it into Rimmie’s back. The other two sisters-in-law and the
wife followed, slamming rocks into Rimmie’s back. Rimmie’s children, also witnesses to the
unfolding events, danced around spastically in circles, little arms flailing, shrieking hysterically
while their aunts and mother stoned their father. The sister-in-law who had originally been
attacked managed to stab Rimmie in the cheek with a fork she had been holding, causing blood
to pour down his face. My unfortunate friend was eventually saved by a neighbor who entered
the fight and shielded Rimmie from his sisters-in-law while other neighbors pulled him to safety.
Another instance occurred on a brisk Sunday morning and it involved Pol, thirties, strong but a
heavy drinker and a reputed cat burglar. (On at least two occasions while I was in the village,
people awoke to find Pol tiptoeing across the floor of their thatch roofed huts and each time Pol
got away by fleeing into the bush.) Pol was in a dispute with a women in her sixties, Maximine,
to whom he owed money for rum he had bought from her. Maximine cursed Pol as he walked
past her kitchen. Pol replied. More words were exchanged and Pol, who had been drinking kleren
(rum), stepped into the kitchen and according to his subsequent assailants, slapped the older
woman. It is questionable whether Pol really slapped Maximine because if he did, it was a very
stupid thing to do. Pol has only one sister—she is cross eyed. His mother has mental problems,
no one is sure who his father is, and Pol, by virtue of his thievery, is a near outcast in the village,
albeit a tough one. In contrast, Maximine is a near matriarch. She is a mother of eight, and she
lives in the middle of a cluster of houses in which also reside one of her sons and his six
children, a brother in-law and his four children, a sister and her nine children, a daughter and her
three children. Maximine also has a husband and two grown children living with her in her own
house. And most unfortunately for Pol, one of these children, an Amazon-sized twenty-three-
year-old daughter, was standing in the kitchen with her mother when Pol entered. She was
pounding coffee with a pestle as big as a baseball bat and the first thing to hit Pol was reportedly
that pestle. In moments, sons, nieces, nephews, grandchildren, and in-laws were kicking,
pummeling, and clobbering Pol with whatever object they could find. I was not physically
present and have not seen Pol since the incident, but people report he was almost killed.
The male versus female incident mentioned earlier in the main text, the one that became a small
war, began when a twenty-year-old man slapped a thirteen year-old girl, thus instigating a battle
between two lakous (family compounds). The thirteen year-old girl, Little-Bridget (Ti-Brijet),
was filling her water bucket at the village spigot. Hot and thirsty from a just finished soccer
game, Little-Demon (Ti-Djab), the obnoxious and insolent younger brother of the buttock-
slapper mentioned above, came to get a drink of water. He rudely told Little-Bridget to get out of
his way, and Little-Bridget, equally infamous for being insolent, just as rudely told him no.
Little-Demon slapped her, knocking her to the ground. Standing only a few feet away was Little-
Bridget’s comparatively weak eighteen-year-old brother who leapt on Little-Demon, whereupon
several other young men entered the fray. The fight might have passed had Little-Bridget’s
mother not launched a rock into the crowd, hitting yet another young man in the face. Very
coincidentally—or perhaps not so coincidentally—the young man who was hit was the deadbeat
father of another of the woman’s daughters—Little-Bridget’s sister. The man had not only
neglected to care for the child but shortly after its birth had brought another woman, an outsider
from the island of La Tortue, into the village. The new woman was also pregnant and she died
giving birth to the child. Virtually everyone who was not immediately related to or good friends
with Little-Bridget’s mother agreed that she had killed her daughter’s rival with sorcery. And
now, after years of hushed accusations and seething hatred, Little-Bridget’s mother had hit her
estranged “son-in-law” in the face with a rock. As the people in the village said, guere pete—war
exploded. The son-in-law’s family, led by three sisters—three of the same four sisters who had
stoned and stabbed Rimmie above—and accompanied by four brothers, bombarded Little-
Bridget, her mother, and her two brothers with rocks. Little-Bridget’s family did what they could
to hold the attackers off, returning fire with stones and hurling threats of sorcery and retribution.
But they eventually had to take refuge inside their house. The bombardment went on for some
twenty minutes. The doors and shutters of the house were splintered by stones. The family stayed
indoors that night. The next morning Little-Bridget’s mother tried to pretend as if nothing had
happened, coming out of the house, sweeping the yard, and then heading over to the water
spigot. No such luck. The oldest sister in the opposing family had assembled a pile of rocks and
was waiting. Seeing Little-Bridget’s mother, she launched another all-out assault, hitting the
older woman several times with rocks. Her sisters and brothers joined her in the attack and
together they drove the entire family out of the village. Little-Bridget’s mother subsequently
secured a police mandate ordering the other family to allow her and her children to live
peacefully in the village, but up to this day, three years later, the family has not been able to
return.
Carol Anne Truelove, a missionary nurse with thirty years of experience in the region, reports
having treated three men versus one woman for severed lips, a distinctively feminine form of
retribution in Jean Rabel: biting her adversary on the lip in an effort to disfigure his or her face.
The source of fights is almost without exception not that the man has another woman but the
division of resources or the perceived loss of money, often after a period of financial familial
neglect on the part of the man. Even in the other cases, those not between men and women,
typically the source of the conflict is a struggle for financial access to a man. One fight erupted
between a mother-in-law and one of her sons’ wives over the ownership of a fish the man had
caught. Another fight erupted over the presence of three nubile women who were competing for
the financial attentions of men in the hamlet. In all but one of the seventeen cases—those
involving men and women—the root of the fight was a conflict between men and women over
resources.
In Haitian urban areas, domestic violence against women is widespread. I believe this is a
consequence of the relative absence of family—parents, brothers, sisters, uncles, and cousins—
who can protect or even seek revenge for the woman. I do not believe, nor do my personal
experiences suggest, that violence against women occurs in rural areas to anywhere near the
same degree. Indeed, as seen, women appear more violent than men. I believe this lower
occurrence of domestic violence against women is a consequence of the exact opposite
conditions found in the city: (1) women have higher economic status vis-a-vis men than their
urban counterparts, and (2) family members are present and they often respond to violence
against their daughters, sisters, mothers, and cousins.
Two community focus group studies revealed that men who beat their wives—and get away with
it—are not your average male farmer but overwhelmingly men who have a source of income
outside of the household mode of production and are wealthy compared to those around them. In
one community, two of the four men who reportedly beat their wives were successful bokors,
one was an employee for an international development organization and one of the wife beaters
was the owner of a US$18,000.00 dump-truck—making him one the richest rural inhabitants in
all of Jean Rabel. Carol Ann Truelove, mentioned else where, identified five men in her area
who beat their wives. Two are bosses (skilled workers), one is a schoolteacher, one is mentally
ill, and only one is a farmer. In short, three of five have income derived from a source
completely independent of the household—and one is crazy.
Other stories that relate to domestic violence in rural farming areas include the story of Marco
and Selest (given in chapter 15) in which Marco was eventually beaten severely by his wife’s
sister, her brother, and her brother’s wife; and a Mare Rouge woman beaten by her husband and
who subsequently repaid the abuse by feigning submission, feeding her husband dinner and then,
while he was eating, throwing a pot of scalding water on him. Nobody defended the husband and
he reportedly did not beat his wife again—or, at least, not yet. (For a similar discussion of the
aggressiveness of rural Haitian women versus men see Murray 1977: 173).
Something that deserves mention here is the practice in rural Haiti of woman eating apart from
men. Women typically eat in the kitchen, which is built apart from the house, and men eat at a
table in the dining room of the house. Simpson (1942) took this as an indication of repression
and surely many contemporary observers make the same assumption—I did. But this is probably
a classic case of seeing an alien custom through one’s own cultural lens. In developed Western
countries, eating meals, particularly dinner, seated at a table in the company of others, has great
symbolic value. We “break bread together” and “enjoy the family meal together,” and the idea of
eating in the kitchen while others are eating in the dining room smacks of discrimination. But in
rural Haiti there is little value assigned to sitting around the table. Women make the food and
they simply eat it in the kitchen. Why not? Why wait? In a country where most people do not get
enough to eat, alone in the kitchen is a good place to be.
3. This description of the defining features of polygyny in Haiti was inspired by Gerald Murray
et al. (1998)
4. There was a bokor in Makab with two wives in separate compounds, who both lived in the
hamlet, and the bokor had also borne children with a mentally unstable sister of one of the wives.
The sister lived in the same compound with the bokor and the wife, and they unashamedly
explained the situation as necessary because the sister could not find a spouse with whom to bear
children.
5.
Table 16.14: Ever-polygynous men in Kinanbwa Haiti
.
6. Data were gathered on all skilled workers (bosses) in both regions. There were forty-one in all.
The argument that fishermen enjoy a higher income level is based on my own experiences and
corroborated by data from CARE’s 1994 baseline study in the northwest region, which found
that fishermen enjoy on average ten times the income of local farmers (1996: 99). This latter
observation does not reflect the fact that fisherman also spend much more on equipment, but the
point nevertheless stands. Fishermen are relatively wealthier than farmers.
7. The value of a woman’s sexuality is so closely linked to material exchange and house building
that in cases of rape, marriage between victim and assailant is a possible penalty, particularly if
the parties are young and particularly if the man is of higher socioeconomic status. In a case that
occurred in a community where I was living, a twenty-five-year-old man was convicted of raping
a fourteen-year-old girl. His punishment: to buy the girl a gold chain, earrings, and to promise
marriage. The parents took the chain and earrings but citing the man’s poverty “that good for
nothing cannot provide anything for our child” (sansave sa pa ka regle anyen pou pitit pa nou),
they insultingly sent the man a female dog in their daughter’s stead. If the man is already
married, a financial indemnity is the usual outcome. If the woman is married or in a consensual
union with another man, the situation is different, and rare. The rapist is considered to have
threatened the continuation of the marriage as the husband may leave his wife. Severity is the
rule and the assailant will be going to prison—if the girl’s family does not manage to kill him
first—and his family will have to pay the woman and her husband a sum that according to local
judges may include the loss of all or most of the man’s property.
8. Fishermen are typically beset with marketing women whenever they reach shore with a fresh
catch, which they sell immediately.
9. Eh, li pa gen avantay. Desann gason pa konprann li desann ou, wi. Se en sel ti madanm ki
vreman pouse ou monte.
10. Ah, lè ou gen pliziè madanm, se yon paket afè. . . . Kounye-a maten-a, si ou travay jaden sa
pou madanm sa, fo ou travay lòt jaden pou lòt madanm.
11. Li pa gen avantay. Se yon desanvantay.
12. Wi gen avantay paskè gen moun ki gen plizyè madanm. Si se pou manje bagay sa yo m pa
konnen.
13. Non, li pa gen avantay. Pasè fo ou ka fe jaden pou tou le dè, fo ou ka voye tou le dè nan
mache. Li pa nan avantay.
14. Only one polygynous man gave the expected and long-favored anthropological explanation
for polygyny in rural Haiti: that a man can benefit from multiple wives because wives help him
with the harvest and sale of garden produce. The man explained,
The advantage is, if you have the means, you work this little garden really hard, if it yields, you
are working at the other woman’s house on 2 or 4 kawo of land. If this harvest is good too, you
have a money advantage. There is an advantage when days are good. But when days are not
good, now you don’t have jack and you have to give to both of them.
(Avantay li gen ladan, si mwayen pèmet ou, ou travay telman travay ti kawo tè, si li bon, ou
travay kay lòt fi-a dè o yon kat kawo tè. Si rekolt la repete, ou gen avantay kob la. Li gen avantay
lè jou bagay yo bon. Lè jou pa bon, kounye-a ou sou jak. Bay fo ou bay tou le dè.)
15. Lè moun pa vin alez ave ou . . . ou gen kote ou ka al manje bwe.
16. Si premiè ba ou yon defo, ou oblije chache yon, min se pa avantay li ye.
17. Si gen yon madanm pa te la. Li ale, li ale kay lòt la, li al tet lòt la ki te kite yon ti mòso manje
pou li, li al jwenn ni, li al manje li. Se sa, apre de sa se dekouraj. Apre de sa, pa gen avantay.
18. M-ap fache paskè w-ap pedi nan sa l-ap ba ou.
19. Map sere kob mwen paskè lap pran ladan pote li ale.
20. M pap alez paskè lap bay lot fi kob.
21. M-ap joure mari-m paske lap fe-m fe defisi.
22. M-ap pale ave li. M pap joure ave li pase si neg la gen yon bagay, gen yon djob nan min ni,
m ka fe yon tenten, m ta ka fe ti dialog ave li. Min neg la pa gen djob nan min, li pa nan fe klas,
li pa ka fe anyen.
23. En ben, m pa ka fe anyen, se pa mwen ki fe sa. . . . L-ap vini, l-ap malad, se andedan kay la l-
ap vini. Se pa lòt la ki devan. Se mwen k-ap devan.
24 Si li jwenn yon fi ki brav, li al fe 2 jou a li, kite li al a fi akoz se pa ti moun li ye. Ou pa ka
kale li.
25. M pa ta di anyen. Si se kouray li santi, si li santi kouray-a, m pap rete lakouraj li la.
26. M pap fe anyen. Si li koute-m, si m di non, moman pa bon li pa ka gen 2 fi. Tank si se jodi-a,
se yon sel di goud li jwenn, e si se nou dè, li pa ka ba nou chak sink goud. E li pa kapab.
27. M-ap swiv neg la, paskè m gentan gen pitit ave-li. Li pa ka abandone ni net. Fo-k li vin chita
la pou ede-m chape ti moun yo.
28. Depi m gen wout pou pase, m pa okipe-ou. M-ap okipe pitit. Sitel li menm, m pa ka lag-o.
Nou marie ansanm, m pa ka lag-o. Se yon angajman nou gen ansanm. M gen ban pitit.
29. The unnaturally higher rates of males in the 50 to 64 year age group is possibly due to
women with grown children going to live with the children in urban areas.
30. It makes no sense to a Jean Rabel woman to go live with a man in a house he gives her if the
man has no gardens or livestock; nor does it make sense to go live with the man’s mother when
the girl can more comfortably stay with her own mother who will be happy to have the services
of grandchildren. Furthermore, as seen, in the absence of a supportive husband, a Jean Rabel
woman can begin bearing children while still living with her parents without suffering shame or
ridicule.
31. This is an inference drawn from the gender differences in age at entry into union, the
differential rates at which women versus men separate from their first spouse, and the imbalance
in the sex ratios (see chapter 5).
32. En ben, ki fe-m ka viv san gason? Sa-m bezwenn m ka leve yon sak manje, se a kat ti moun
um m ka rive.
33. Si m gen ti moun m pa bezwenn mari-m menm. Ti moun, hoy, hoy. M ta reme dis pitit, m pa
bezwenn mari.
34. Pou ki rezon fe-m ka viv san gason. Ko-m rive nan laj konsa. Tout afe-m mache. M pa
bezwenn mari-m anko.
35. The tension between the desire to have a contributing “son-in-law” and the need for
grandchildren is manifest in rare but ideologically prominent and widely talked about incidences
where impatient parents surprise eligible men copulating with their daughter. In local lore,
parents found in such a situation do not run the man off their property with shotgun blasts of rock
salt to his disappearing backside as a stereotypical U.S. farming father might be expected to do.
That type of violence or even aggressive behavior against male suitors is rare. Instead, in local
lore, the ideal Jean Rabel farmer will barricade the man into the house with his daughter, locking
the doors and sending for the young man’s parents and a pastor. With threats of violence and
sorcery, the farmer tries to force the man to marry his daughter.
Two incidences of young men being locked in houses were recorded from reliable informants
and I believe these incidences really do occur. But more salient is the ideology or the
commonality with which people talk about such incidences. The image of rural parents eagerly
waiting to trap a man in their house and force him to marry their daughter is very much a part of
Jean Rabel lore. People will say things such as, “yea those people in La Montagne will call the
preacher and marry you right there in your shorts” (Y-ap rele pastor epi marie ou nan bout chòt).
In an interview with the Jean Rabel judge, he spontaneously began talking about marriages
where men in rural areas were forced to marry at midnight and then challenged the legitimacy of
the marriages in court. According to the judge, the marriages are not binding (but I have to add,
midnight marriages probably never occur, people in the area would consider such behavior fit for
demons).
36. Gen anpil fwa se parann menm ki plase ti moun yo, ki plase yo. Gen dè fwa parann menm,
telman se lajan ki interese-l, pitit fi konn reme avek yon gason ki gen menm laj ave li. Yo te ka
marie. Li pa asepte. Pase lè gason sa li we li pa ka fe anyen, li pa ka bay lajan, etsetera. Pi devan
li we ajè li pou plase a yon mouchè marie. Min de fe li konn mouchè marie sa ka bay lajan, gen
lajan, li femen je-l pou pitit la ka pran lajan nan min zom sa pote ba li. An Ayiti se sa ki genyen
kounie-a. Se granmoun kap minnin.
37. L-ap ba-m di goude pou ti moun, se sa k fe m ta reme sa.
38. Si yon moun marie, pou ki sa li marie? Li pa marie ni pou chef ni pou anyen. Se pou li ka fe
dè ti moun. . . . En ben, pou kisa yon moun fe ti moun? Se pou li ka ed-o. . . al nan dlo-a . . . al
nan bwa.
39. Non. Lè yon moun jenn, bagay sa m-ap di, ou bezwenn yon mari, komsi m di, si ou poko
enfante, ou ka enfante yon ti moun.
40. Ou met gen tout peyi se lajan pou danm, lajan se unitil, paskè y-ap manje tout pran ni. Yon ti
bagay moun t-ap fe pou ou konsa paskè li konnen ou pa gen pitit, bagay la ka koute ou 100 dola.
. . . Pou lajan travay fok se pitit pou ou gen pou travay. Si ou pa gen moun lajan pap travay. AH,
ou ka gen moun lajan ap travay, min depi se pa pitit ou y-ap pran tout. Y-ap vin chaje ou ak
manti. Y-ap chaje ou anpil bagay ki pa bon. Min lè se pitit ou, ou toujou ap reyisi.
*****
Chapter 17
Caribbean Family Patterns
Introduction
In the introductory chapter of this book I pointed out that the anthropology of the Caribbean has
been called “the battle ground for competing theories regarding family structure” (D’Amico-
Samuels 1988: 785). Anthropologists were confounded by a distinct regional family structure
similar to that seen in Jean Rabel—including, late age at marriage, high rates of births to single
women, matrifocality, child dispersal, de facto polygyny, serial monogamy, and severe beting of
children. Early scholars dismissed these patterns as “disintegrate” (Simey 1946), “uncivilized”
(Matthews 1953: 302), “normless,” “distorted” (see Smith 1996: 35, 54), “promiscuous,” and
“dysfunctional” (see Smith and Mosby 2003). Subsequently, no comprehensive and satisfactory
explanation for the patterns was ever achieved.
In this chapter I revisit the literature and illustrate how the same patterns seen in Jean Rabel can
be identified elsewhere in the Caribbean ethnographic record and can be explained with similar
arguments, most importantly the value of the household in surviving a harsh natural and
economic environment; the role of women as managers of these households; and the role of
children as laborers in making them productive. It is this later point, the economic utility of even
very young children—a point I demonstrated that many scholars documented but largely
neglected and even denied—that completes the insights other scholars have made and makes
Caribbean family patterns logical. In reinserting the importance of children into the analysis I
believe that I can explain Caribbean family patterns as a logical outcome of the basic material
challenges that face impoverished people of the region.
The discovery is greeted with noisy upbraiding, the girl is severely beaten, and in many cases
turned out of the house. In the second stage the girl takes refuge with a neighbor or kinswoman.
After a period, which may be quite short, the kinsfolk and neighbours intercede with the mother
on her behalf, and the girl is taken back into her mother's home for the birth of her child.
It was precisely these types of seemingly contradictory behaviors—keeping girls in the dark
about the mechanics of pregnancy, encouraging male sexual aggressiveness, and beating
daughters when they did get pregnant—that early scholars were referring to when they described
Caribbean family patterns as “dysfunctional.” But what I try to show in the rest of this chapter is
that in the context of the importance of households, children, and the challenges confronted by
impoverished people of the Caribbean, these practices were anything but dysfunctional. On the
contrary, the view of them as dysfunctional was the consequence of a presumption by social
scientists that children were a material burden. For impoverished people of the Caribbean, quite
the opposite was the case. As was seen in Jean Rabel, it was of the greatest importance that a
woman have children. In St. Vincent it was believed that a woman who cannot have children is
“tragic, sad, and pitiable” and similarly, “a man who could not have children is equally scorned,
and his masculinity and virility are called into question” (Gearing 1988: 235). In Jamaica, “a
child is God’s gift,” “nothing should be done to prevent the birth of a child,” and “no woman
who has not proved that she can bear a child is likely to find a man to be responsible for her”
(Clarke 1966: 95–96). In summarizing the results of 1,600 interviews from the extensive Women
in the Caribbean project (WICP 1979–1982), Senior (1991: 68) noted that “childless women are
scorned,” they are “mules” and “beyond the pale of society.”
The “dysfunctional” behaviors described above evolved not as an aversion to high fertility, but
as a mechanism of guaranteeing it. By keeping young women in the dark about the mechanics of
reproduction, making them afraid of birth control, and encouraging male promiscuity, one could
argue that impoverished people of the Caribbean, especially mothers, were setting up the
conditions that made pregnancy unavoidable. By intentional design or simply the consequences
of radical pronatalism, daughters were rendered defenseless against the processes that initiated
their reproductive careers. As for the beatings mothers were arguably not punishing daughters so
much as they were assuring their control of the newborn child. Indeed, as will be seen,
throughout the Caribbean, elder mothers deliberately tried to commandeer the offspring of their
nubile daughters. Similar to Jean Rabel, the behavior of parents can ultimately only be
understood with respect to dependency on households, female control over those households, and
the value of child labor in making the household productive. To begin assessing the pattern, I
want to look at how changes in the plantation economy that dominated the region for more than
four hundred years gave way to the primacy of the Caribbean household as a unit of production
and survival.
An integral part of the social pattern that emerged was that men were expected to use migration
as a source to underwrite the establishment of a family and homestead. Richardson (1975: 398)
would write that in Carriacou “often a young man is not considered an appropriate suitor by
parents of a prospective bride unless he has completed a sojourn working overseas”; and in
Guyana, R. T. Smith (1956) reported that “if men wanted to fully participate in adult social life
they often had to migrate.” The outstanding manifestation of this trend was male house building.
Caribbean low-income households may sometimes have passed generation to generation in a
matrilineal fashion, as with Solien’s (1959) “consanguineal female headed households,” but they
came into being and only came into being in association with a union between a man and
woman. Caribbean men were always the ones who underwrote the construction of the house and
they held titular right to the homestead for life. The pattern was so consistent that we can elevate
it to the status of a rule: in a review of twenty Caribbean ethnographies for twenty different
Caribbean countries, Keith Otterbein (1965) found that in every case for which there was data
(fifteen of twenty islands), the primary ingredient for conjugal union was that men provided a
house (see also R. T. Smith 1956: 146; M. G. Smith 1961: 465; Philpott 1973: 120–21, 142;
Sutton and Makiesky-Barrow 1970: 310).
Thus, what anthropologists found when they began studying family patterns in the mid 20th
century was the consequence of over 150 years of adaptation to the weakening of the plantation
economy, the importance of the household in surviving a harsh natural and economic
environment, and the importance of male wage migration as a means to financially underwrite
the household. These are points upon which anthropologists have always agreed. After all, it was
not an argument; it was a description of Caribbean island economies. After that point, however,
consensus crumbled such that social scientists were never able to agree on the determinants of
Caribbean conjugal patterns and kinship.
I believe that I can show why scholars never agreed—and in the final chapter of this book I
attempt to do so—but for the remainder of this chapter I want to show how seemingly
dysfunctional behaviors such as keeping girls ignorant of the mechanics of pregnancy,
encouraging male sexual aggressiveness, and ritual daughter beating, are linked to the plantation-
peasant-migration economy, specfically through the critical role of children labor. The important
thing is to keep our eye on the household. But in doing so, in showing the causal connection
between the Caribbean household and the value of children in making it productive and family,
courtship, and childrearing practices, it is also necessary to dispel a series of academic myths that
have emerged over the more than fifty years of anthropological study in the region.
There is a saying—I’ve heard it a lot: ‘Mothers-in-law break up most marriages.’ The mother be
tellin’ the man he forgettin’ her! And the wife be tellin’ the man “when you going to grow up and
cut the apron strings!”
As in most societies, the man’s mother usually lost. Thus, similar to Jean Rabel, Caribbean
parents found their interests best focused on daughters. Where scholars measured preference for
daughters versus sons, daughters came out way ahead. In Jamaica, for instance, Sergeant and
Harris (1992) found that 79 percent of mothers interviewed preferred to give birth to a daughter.
As in Jean Rabel, the reason girls were favored was because they were a more dependable source
of labor and physical assistance. Also, as in Jean Rabel, daughters were a source of child laborers
(i.e., grandchildren), arguably the most important determinant of Caribbean kinship and family
patterns. These are points taken up soon. But first, I want to finish with this other important
issue, that of money from men, and the fact that the most efficacious way of getting it was via a
daughter.
Parents, especially mothers, took a keen interest in prospective sexual partners of their daughters.
Parents in Jamaica instructed the girl to, “tell her mother of his advances . . . he will then be
investigated . . . and subsequently either be accepted or rejected” (Blake 1961: 69). In Barbados,
men were selected at “meet-hims,” church socials where parents could censor suitors. Upon
approval, they subsequently had sex in the girl’s home (Handwerker 1989: 62). Similarly,
according to M. G. Smith, “Under the Carriacou regulation of mating, young girls may not reply
to the addresses of their suitors without the permission of their parents or household heads” (M.
G. Smith 1961: 468).
So important were financial contributions from men that there emerged what appeared to
outsiders a type of institutionalized prostitution. As in Jean Rabel, women and their families
conceptualized female sexuality as a commodity and were unwilling to allow daughters to
engage in even casual relationships with men who could not afford to give them money or
material gifts (Handwerker 1993: 45; 1989: 77,87; Hill, 1977: 279–80, 282, 305; Ashcraft 1968:
67-68; Freilich 1968: 52; Otterbein 1966: 105; M. G. Smith, 1962: 93,110–22, 226, 234–35;
Stycos and Back 1964: 161).
The material demand attached to a girl’s sexual acquiescence often meant that girls engaged in
their first relationship with older men. Blake found that in her sample of sixty-five Jamaican
women, at least ten of the first female sexual experiences were with a man from five to fifteen
years older than the girl; in an additional eight cases the man was at least fifteen to twenty years
older; and in thirteen cases Blake could not ascertain the age difference but nevertheless,
“whereas for instance, she was only 14 or 15,” the man was “already trained in a trade,” “an
itinerant laborer,” “domiciled with another woman,” “had many women,” “and so on” (Blake
1961: 90–91). The pattern prevailed throughout the Caribbean, where men were on average six
years older than their spouses (Roberts, 1957: 206–7; Massiah 1983).
On the other side of the equation, if men wanted to enter into relations with a woman or, as seen
earlier, to establish a homestead with a woman, they had to find money. To do so they fished,
raised animals, foraged, cultivated agricultural plots, built houses, and pursued virtually any
gainful opportunity available to them. But as seen, wage migration presented itself as a fast way
to bypass poverty on home islands and obtain the money to build a house and begin raising a
family. Parents were primary agents in making this a norm; they often refused to allow their
daughters to go with men who had not yet been abroad (R. T. Smith 1953: 108; see also Hill
1977: 281; Philpott 1973: 120–21; Ashcraft 1968: 67–68; M. G. Smith 1961, 1962: 113, 117;
Wilson 1961b; Otterbein 1965; Kundstadter, 1963). And so, as seen, men migrated. They
migrated such that by the latter 20th century Aaron Segal (1987: 44) could describe the
Caribbean as having “borne the deepest and most continuous impact from international migration
of any region in the world.”
Thus, the reluctance to tell daughters or younger counterparts about the mechanics of pregnancy,
the lack of censure of sexually aggressive males, and the beatings upon discovery of a first
pregnancy and even male migration itself were arguably related to financial contributions from
men. Children were an indispensable part of the equation in that it was the birth of a child that
assured the continued flow of money. Suggestions of “secrecy” aside (Handwerker 1989: 62),
parents were fully aware of what to expect when they allowed men to hang around their
daughter: according to Senior (1991: 75), “pregnancy is expected.” A Vincentian woman in her
mid-thirties recalled, “'the fella went home and speak with them so they expect anything.
Because if somebody come home and you allow that child to go out with that person, you expect
anything to happen” (Senior 1991: 75). “In other words,” Senior clarifies, “if they allow the girl
to go out with a boy they are tacitly acknowledging that she is a woman and ripe for womanly
experience” (Senior 1991: 75).
Parents allowed girls to go out with specific suitors, but as seen, they did so with an eye toward
his ability to provide. When girls did get pregnant, the parents, especially mothers, wanted to
know who was responsible so they could demand support. Senior (1991) found that among the
1,600 WICP informants, it was the “greatest disgrace” that a father could not be named:
It’s terrible, one of the worst things in life, it’s a shame you having sexual intercourse with so
many men and the next thing you get pregnant and you don’t know who the father.
Yes, she called names. Names! A child got to have names. Somebody got to be the father. (Senior
1991: 79)
In effect, one reason mothers beat daughters upon discovery of pregnancy was so the girl would
name a father. This tendency fed another anthropological myth, that of the deadbeat Caribbean
father. But naming a father was not as difficult as some Caribbeanists have suggested, for,
feminist critiques of the traditionally negligent Caribbean male aside, men were eager to claim
paternity.
Figure 17.1: Plot of female household heads by sex ratios (Legend: A = 1 observation; B = 2
observations; N = 15)
50 +
|
| B A
| A
| A A
40 + A A
Female |
Headed | A
House- | A
holds |
30 +
|
| A
| A A A
| A
20 +
---+-------------+-------------+-------------+--
600 800 1000 1200
Sex Ratios
\
Table 17.3: Analysis of variance “female-headed household by sex-ratio” using Yves
Charbit (1984: 32) and adding widowhood ratio from Massiah (1983:19)
Autonomous Caribbean Households Controlled by Women and the Importance of
Children
It is with women and their role as decision makers in Caribbean households that it becomes clear
how and why the value of child labor played a determinant role in Caribbean marriage and
kinship patterns. In Anguilla, “the woman is the family manager; she is subordinate to her
husband, but not subservient” (Walker 1968: 114); In Guyana, “the mistress of the house
receives money and garden produce . . . she is solely responsible for its management once it has
been handed over to her” (R. T. Smith 1956: 138). In Barbuda, “within the household, women
take over exclusive management. . . . There are no tasks for men within the physical confines of
the house” (Berleant-Schiller 1978: 259, 264). In Jamaica, “of most importance to a woman is
her own yard” (Durant-Gonzalez 1976: 39). Even in Barbados, where Handwerker drove home
the authority of the father, “authority . . . was not accompanied by men’s participation in
household affairs” (Handwerker 1989: 81). In summary, there really was something going on in
terms of the prominence of Caribbean women in the domestic sphere: as a consequence of male
migration and de facto absenteeism, women were left in control of households.
On many islands women also controlled local exchange. As in Jean Rabel where the madanm
sara and marchann dominated both retail and intermediate exchange, female “higglers” and
“hucksters” and small vendors from Jamaica to Guyana dominated both retail marketing of farm
produce and much of wholesale interisland trade (Mintz 1955, 1971, 1974; Walker 1968; Pollock
1972; Massiah 1983: 12–17; Griffith 1985; Lagro 1990; Lagro and Plotkin 1990; Mantz 2007).
And it is here that we can see the significance of children enter into the equation, for the critical
component in the adaptation being described was child labor.
In St. John, “women were able to play such an active role in the extra-domestic activities partly
because children were used as labor power as soon as they were old enough” (Olwig, 1985: 118–
19). In Jamaica, “children lighten the work of adult women . . . by assisting in the easier tasks
such as sweeping, watering the animals, collecting kindling, hauling water, picking fruit from the
trees, and going to the neighborhood shop” (Davenport, 1961: 436–37). In Barbuda, “by the time
a girl is eleven or twelve she can run a household and often does” (Berleant-Schiller 1978: 259).
Even in the case of land-scarce Barbados, “growing children help reduce the woman’s work
load, and most women are well aware of this fact” (Greenfield 1966: 107).
Female control of the exchange economy was favorable in lieu of male absenteeism and wage
migration. But as in Jean Rabel, what underwrote this particular configuration of marketing and
male wage migration was the household; women were free to control the local retail marketing
economy and men to migrate because membership in a productive household guaranteed their
security, and what freed them from the tasks of the household were children and the labor
contributions they made. Moreover, as seen in chapter 2, rather than being a commonsensical
observation accepted by anthropologists, the importance of child labor to women is perhaps the
most overlooked and consistently denied aspect of Caribbean family patterns, one that has led to
a misunderstanding of the process. The point is thrown into stark light when one considers
another behavior that social scientists considered “maladaptive” and “dysfunctional”: violence
exercised against children, largely by mothers.
Beating the Hell out of Children
As in Jean Rabel, the physical beating of children was common. In Jamaica Clarke (1966: 156)
reported, “there was hardly a case where our informant did not expatiate upon what he called the
‘floggings’ he or she had received in childhood.” In Suriname, “No part of a child’s body is safe
from blows. . . . In some yards it is not uncommon even for older children (especially boys) to be
suspended naked by the arms from the branch of a tree and given a thrashing with a stick”
(Buschkens 1974: 239). This violence against children has been called “repressive, severe, and
abusive” (Leo-Rhynie 1997; Sharpe 1997) and “developmentally inappropriate” (Sloley 1999;
see Smith and Mosby 2003 for a summary), but it too was part of adapting to harsh living
conditions and it was a direct outgrowth of the critical role of children in household livelihood
strategies.
In Curacao, “when a child reaches the age of five or six, parents begin to impose behavior by
directing the child’s chores and by using a belt or switch” (Hill 1977: 297). In St. Vincent,
children are considered to misbehave if they are “lazy and shirk work,” they receive “corporal
punishment . . . discipline is taken seriously” (Gearing 1988: 194). In Barbados, “as the children
grow older they help the mother with many of her duties. By the age of five, children have
‘chores,’ the neglect of which is punishable by beating” (Greenfield 1966: 107). In Haiti it was
seen that the objective was for the child to be “thinking about the switch in everything he does.”
In an anthropological projection of Western ideals, the Caribbean father was sometimes depicted
as the sterner disciplinarian (Clarke 1966: 107, 159; R. T. Smith 1956: 134; Handwerker 1989:
86). But just as it was women who controlled the homesteads, it was women who most often
disciplined children. In the Bahamas, “mothers are often the providers of discipline” (Bethel
1993: 7). Among the Black Carib, “the woman had the responsibility of raising the children,
caring for their needs, disciplining them” (Solien 1959: 57). In Anguilla4 “child discipline is in
the hands of women” (Walker 1968: 114). In Suriname, “it is chiefly mothers who mete out
punishments” (Buschkens 1974: 239). In Guyana, “fathers beat their children very infrequently
and certainly much less frequently than do mothers and mother substitutes” (R. T. Smith 1956:
13). In Jamaica, “in all aspects of home training the mother is the principal actor . . . the authority
of the mother is never questioned any more than the child’s duty of obedience to her” (Clarke
1966: 118–20); and “this part of training is carried out almost exclusively by the mother” (Cohen
1956: 671). In Bermuda, “wives-mothers carry out the most part of the socialization of the
children . . . and are also the disciplinarian figures” (Paul 1983: 100).
As the managers of households, women commanded children and they did so with the objective
of making the household productive. Similar to Jean Rabel, what underwrote survival was the
link between the household, female career as manager of a productive household, and the labor
of children. Moreover, just as was seen in Jean Rabel, older women were at the height of their
economic power as market women and heads of mature and productive homesteads stocked with
working children. It was these older women who had the greatest interest in the reproductive
behavior of their nubile daughters and in assuring the replenishment of the household labor
supply.
Older Women
The stability of Caribbean economies and continuation of the homestead depended most heavily
on the women who managed them. Because women also often controlled the local retail
marketing economy of produce, because this economy was based on household production, and
because children were a critical source of labor, they, children, were most critical to women. And
they were most critical not as adults, as most researchers addressing the issue have argued
(Handwerker 1989: 88; Smith 1962: 236; Otterbein 1963: 170; Philpott 1973: 123; Brittain 1990:
57; Murray 1977); they were most important as children. It is this issue of children that makes
the rest of “dysfunctional” Caribbean family patterns understandable. Radical pronatalism, a
complex of cultural beliefs and behavior from keeping girls in the dark about the mechanics of
pregnancy to sending them off alone or leaving them in the house with sexually aggressive but
financially capable older men, the entire complex is ultimately underwritten by the fact that
children were not the burdens so often presented in the literature.
Even in the case of the mother’s ritual beating upon discovery of a daughter’s pregnancy, seen
earlier, close examination reveals that what ethnographers where witnessing was more than
simply assuring the identification of the father and procurement of child support; it was, as in
Jean Rabel, part of an institutionalized struggle between mother and daughter for control over
children. In Suriname, Buschkens (1974: 226) wrote of the grandmother’s “refusing to part with
these grandchildren, which she has come to regard as her property.” In Trinidad, there was a
custom for the first child of a marriage to “belong to the grandparents,” something that Stewart
(1973: 98) tells us “ensured the continued membership of young workers in each household” (see
also Rodman 1971: 82). While calling the grandmother “ma” or “ mama” or “muma,” the
children were taught to refer to their own mother by her pet name, as if she were another sibling
(see Buschkens 1974: 226; Durant-Gonzalez 1976; Greenfield 1966; R. T. Smith 1956: 144–45).
In Barbados, if the grandparents fostered the child, the couple was “relieved” of responsibility
but they also “relinquished their parental rights” (Handwerker 1989: 63). Even Clarke (1966),
who like many of her contemporaries saw children as a burden and the entire institution of high
pronatalism, odd marriage patterns, and daughter beating as dysfunctional, went on to explain
that, “we found no instance where the grandmother resented the presence of the child in her
home . . . they ‘gladden the home,’ they are a source of companionship, they are useful” (Clarke
1966: 100, 180; see also Cohen 1956: 668; and see Philpott 1973: 140, for bitter competition
over possession of children for their labor value).
The benefits that accrued to older women who controlled the process are manifest in the sheer
demographic weight of grandchildren. Throughout the Caribbean, young women typically began
bearing children while still living in their parents’ household; 40 to 75 percent of all births on
Caribbean islands are to single women; 25 to 40 percent of children lived in homes where neither
parent is present and most of these were homes of grandparents (Philpott 1973: 137; Clarke
1966: 202–4; M. G. Smith 1961: 457,470–71; Cohen 1956: 668). Moreover, while money from
men is a preeminent issue, the even greater importance of children is evident in the struggle
between mothers and daughters-in-law for support from sons. While mothers tried to break up
union and to get support from sons for themselves, it was the mothers of men’s children—and
the mother’s mothers—who most often prevailed. Everywhere in the Caribbean, the value of
young children to men and women who shared control over them overrode that of contributions
from adult children and sons’ loyalty to their own mothers. All of this brings up the question,
why did men bother to cooperate with the system in the first place?5
Why Men Cooperated
One reason why men so readily conformed to demands of females for support was pressure. As
seen, women and their families promoted a system in which female sexual acquiescence,
motherhood, and domestic servitude were associated with remuneration from males. They
selectively encouraged relationships with men who had money; and they attached similar values
to male migration, encouraging if not compelling men to go overseas in search of money to
invest in homesteads and families back home. And so men migrated; they did so in fantastic
numbers; and they did so precisely so that they could give the money to the mothers of their
children and invest in households. Those who did not, lost respect (Handwerker 1989: 80); they
lost rights to inheritance (Philpott 1973: 127); their wives cuckolded them and assigned paternity
for offspring to other men (Otterbein 1966: 70–75, 115); their own children refused to help them
(Handwerker 1989: 91); they were censured (Philpott 1973: 178-179); they suffered “ridicule,”
“isolation” and “abuse” (M. G. Smith 1962: 70; see also Smith 1956: 158; Greenfield 1966: 119;
Rodman 1971: 178; Senior 1991: 8).
But male conformance did not derive from pressure alone. Caribbean males had the option of
never coming home. When away working as migrants, they could have stayed overseas. And
some did. But for the many who returned, the most fundamental reason for conformance was
quite simply because investment in a house back home, in the woman who would manage it, and
in the children who would make it productive was the best shot most had at dignity, liberty,
social security, and financial independence from a system in which corporate plantation
enterprises sought to use them at the lowest possible cost. Industrial agriculture, mining, and
massive building projects might have paid little, but when men migrated from the poorest
regions to distant plantations or construction sites, they were able to save money by sleeping on
the sites and bunking in barracks or sharing houses with other men and, in doing so, were able to
return home with a sizable savings.6
Conclusion
Summarizing, while many young Caribbean women may have been reluctant to begin
childbearing, the ethnographic record suggests that most often older women—and to a lesser
extent their spouses—favored the idea of their daughter’s pregnancy and they sought to arrange
it so that it would happen with men who could and would provide support. These interests were
expressed in the institutionalized complex of behaviors seen above, from encouraging male
sexual aggressiveness, to encouraging migration, to keeping young women ignorant of the
processes that would allow them to avoid first pregnancies, to censoring financially unsuitable
suitors while permitting older, financially capable men to slip through. Moreover, it was
precisely the drive to get money from men and male absenteeism that led to rates of illegitimate
births as high as 70 percent of all births; it also led to “brittle unions” in the form of polygyny
and to serial monogamy; and to the late age at entry into union.
But as we have seen, there was more to it than money. It was ultimately not migration or
childsupport in itself that caused “peculiar” Caribbean family patterns. Money from men does
not explain why women did not stick by one man, especially if the man was away earning money
and sending back remittances. It does not explain why men and women bothered to get married
toward the end of their reproductive careers, after all their children were already born. And it
does not explain the high birth rates that until recently prevailed throughout the region. The
answer to what ultimately drove pronatalism, distinct Caribbean family, kinship, and courting
practices, as well as male conformance, and the pursuit of overseas employment to meet
financial responsibilities associated with women and children was not money or sex, per se, but
rather the same response to poverty seen in Jean Rabel: dependence on a livelihood strategy in
which the household was the foundation and child labor the fulcrum point in making the strategy
successful. It is also this causal concatenation of variables with the importance of children as
labor at the base that explains one of the most counterintuitive phenomena in the demographic
literature, why Caribbean women bore more children when there were fewer men present, i.e.,
fewer men, more babies, the subject of the next chapter.
*****
Notes
1. For the transformation of islands from plantation economies to dual plantation/peasant
economies, see Mintz 1974, 1985, Scarano 1989, Brereton 1989; for Dominica, see Gardner and
Podolefsky 1977; for Martinique, see Baber 1982, Horowitz 1959; for Barbados, see Lowenthal
1957, Henshall 1966; for Carriacou, see Richardson 1975, Heath 1988; for Commonwealth
Caribbean, see Heath 1988: 431, Beckford 1972; for St. Vincent, see Rubenstein 1977,
Grossman 1997; for Antigua, see Augelli 1953; for Barbuda, see Berleant-Schiller 1978, Gaspar
1991.
2. For Caribbean migration, see Lowenthal and Comitas 1962, Foner and Napoli 1978; Frucht
1968; Crane 1971; Pollock 1972; Palmer 1974; Sutton and Makiesky 1975; Taylor 1976; Hill
1977; Midgett 1977; Green 1979; Rubenstein 1977, 1979; Plummer 1985; Perusek 1984; Pollock
1972; Richardson 1975: 396–98; R. T. Smith 1953: 93; McElroy and Albuquerque 1988; for
U.S.-engineered plantations, Balch 1927; Millspaugh 1931; Montague 1966; Williams 1970;
Castor 1971; Lundahl 1983; Perusek 1984; Segal, 1975; Saint-Louis 1988; for Jamaica, see
Griffith 1985; Pollock 1972.
3. George Cumper (1961) surveyed 1,296 households with 5,364 people (a random sample of 2
percent of the population). Cumper broke his sample into eight occupational groups and male-
versus female-headed households. In only two of Cumper's categories of female-headed
households (White Collar and Landless Laborer) did males contribute less than 50 percent of all
income and among male-headed households in only the category of Domestic Labor (58%) did
men contribute less than 75 percent of family income (table 17.4 below).
Table 17.4: Percentage of household income from males: Male- vs. female-headed
households
4. On average, Caribbean women marry younger and live longer than men. Average age for entry
into common law or “consensual union” in the traditional Commonwealth Caribbean occurred at
29.9 for females and 36.4 for males (Roberts 1957; see also Massiah 1983: 14); and Caribbean
life expectancy in 1960 was 66.3 for females versus 62.2 for males. These figures mean that
compared to men, Caribbean women had 10.6 years more of life after union than their spouse.
Congruently, Caribbean households headed by widowed females were high, ranging during the
1960s and 1970s from 11.4 percent in Guyana to 34.1 percent in St. Vincent (Massiah 1983: 19).
5. “These people work abroad for awhile and then return to Anguilla to plant crops, build houses,
and work at whatever comes to hand. Lack of opportunities for employment, droughts and the
slow pace on the island leads to economic need and a restlessness which results in another trip
abroad . . . .
Despite the large disproportion of women on the island the role of the female is quite apparently
subordinate to the man. . . . [But] the total responsibility for day-to-day home cooperation, care
of financial resources and child discipline is in the hands of women. . . . As one respondent said,
‘The woman is the family manager; she is subordinate to her husband, but not subservient’”
(Walker 1968: 114).
6. Wages in Haiti or Jamaica at the turn of the 20th century were ten cents per day, one-tenth to
one-twentieth the one to two dollars per day workers could make migrating to work the Panama
Canal (Petras 1988: 179–80; Plummer 1985; Perusek 1984).
It should also be acknowledged that staying abroad was not always an option. In 1924, a new law
cut off immigration to New York; in the 1930s the depression ended migration; in 1937 Cuba,
the Batista government brutally rounded up and exported Haitians, and in the same year the
Trujillo regime in the Dominican Republic massacred some twenty thousand of them (Balch
1927; Millspaugh 1931; Montague 1966; Williams 1970; Castor 1971; Lundahl 1983; Perusek
1984; Segal 1975; Saint-Louis 1988).
*****
Chapter 18
Fewer Men, More Babies
Introduction
It was seen in chapter 2 that Chayanov’s 1920s investigation of work regimes and birth rates
among Russian small farmers (called “peasants” in the literature) culminated with
anthropological studies of the 1960s and 1970s and Caldwell’s (1982) theory of wealth flows:
when wealth flowed from children to adults, birth rates would be high; when they flowed the
other way, they would be low. Most subsequent scholars took a different course, veering away
from concrete and measurable explanations. Even Caldwell began to talk of religion and culture
as determinants of high fertility. Here I want to show that in one of the most important instances
where social scientists tried to stick to a rigorous application of a mechanical model—in this case
“the proximate and intermediate determinants of fertility”—the model was inconsistent with
ethnographic reality. In doing this, in examining the fewer men, more babies phenomenon, I
believe that I can provide a graphic example of the utility of the argument presented in the
previous chapter while demonstrating the inapplicability of the “proximate and intermediate
determinants of fertility.” I believe that I can also show how the tension between the economic
value of children to women and men and the need to get children through the critical early years
determined the particular values associated with the sexual moral economy in the Caribbean and
high birth rates.1
1.Fecundity—the ability to have sexual intercourse, the ability to conceive, and the ability to
carry pregnancy to term,
2.Exposure to the risk of pregnancy— sexual unions, such as marriage, and the actual time that
partners spend together,
3.Birth control methods—contraceptives, sterilization, coitus interruptus,
4.Abortion.
There were five “intermediate determinants” of fertility, those factors by which the “proximate
determinants” are altered and that fall soundly in the realm of social behavior:
1.Postpartum taboos—such as sexual abstinence for new mothers,
2.Duration of breast feeding—nursing suppresses ovulation,
3.Delayed marriage—many societies have strong norms against young women engaging in
premarital sex,
4.Disruption of union via male out-migration or military service, and
5.Attitudes toward contraceptives and family planning.
Over the ensuing three decades social scientists came to treat the “proximate and intermediate
determinants of fertility” as demographic laws. Social scientists working in the Caribbean were
no exception, particularly regarding male wage migration and the resulting male absenteeism so
widespread in the Caribbean. They frequently assumed and even calculated—without empirical
support—the dampening effect that male out-migration supposedly had on birth rates among the
women staying behind (Murthy 1973; Blake 1961: 249–50, 1954; see also Denton 1979;
Williams et al. 1975; Lowenthal and Comitas 1962: 197; Ibberson 1956: 99; McElroy and
Albuquerque 1990; Brockerhoff and Yang 1994).
The problem is that while seemingly obvious, the assumptions underlying the “proximate and
intermediate determinants of fertility” were based on Western middle and upper class courtship
behavior, where marriage, or at least stable union, was the criterion for sexual reproduction.
They do not always apply in other societies; in the impoverished Caribbean, they do not apply at
all, as illustrated in the fewer men, more babies phenomenon.
Oh, why does a person have children? You have children. You struggle to chape them. . . . You
raise them. They chape. Tomorrow, God willing, if you need a little water, the child can get it for
you. If you need a little firewood, he can carry it for you.4 (fifty-five-year-old father of
seventeen)
I had children, now I have a problem, now the children can solve the problem. Tomorrow, God
willing I cannot help myself, it is on the children I will depend. Today I chape them. Tomorrow
God willing we struggle with life together.5 (forty-one-year-old mother of four)
And to recall women in Jean Rabel commenting on the importance of a husband,
He gives me money for the children, that is what makes me prefer having him around.6 (twenty-
seven year-old mother of five)
What I am telling you is when you are young, you need a husband. What I mean is, if you haven’t
had children yet. So you can make a child.7 (forty-two-year-old mother of three)
If a person marries, why does she marry? She does not marry to be a big shot or anything like
that. It is so she can have children… Why does a person want children? It is to help…to go to the
water…to go get wood.8 (forty-year-old mother of five)
He has to come sit there and help me chape the children.9 (forty-year-old mother of four)
What makes me say I can live without a man? What I need to do to come up with a sack of food I
can accomplish with my four children.10 (thirty-year-old mother of four).
If I have children, I don’t need my husband at all. Children, hey! hey! I would like to have ten
children. I don’t need my husband.11 (forty-one-year-old mother of seven).
Why can I live without a man? I arrive at an age like this. All my affairs are in order. I don’t
need my husband anymore.12 (fifty-six-year-old mother of eight)
If we accept the argument that children were considered critical to household production, that
they were highly desired, that increased availability of money made successful pregnancies and
child survival more likely—and women and their families more inclined to accept male
consorts—then the question is how were women able to bear more children precisely when there
were fewer men. How fertility increased during periods of high male absenteeism was precisely
because of the types of conjugal unions seen in the previous chapter, polygyny and unstable
unions, behaviors that Bongaarts and Potter (1983) and other researchers posited as lowering the
“exposure to the risk of pregnancy,” thereby precipitating a drop in number of births (see Wood
1995 for a review of conflict surrounding this issue).
Polygyny, although never legal in the Caribbean, was long identified as part of an informal
“standard” whereby married men could assume responsibility for additional common-law wives.
In these “extramarital” unions, the women lived in separate homesteads or, in a form not
recognized as a consummated union, remained in the homesteads of their parents (known in the
anthropology of the Caribbean as a “visiting union”). The men performed as de facto husbands,
providing support and fathering children. This nonlegal, or de facto, polygyny made it possible
for a greater number of women to gain socially accepted sexual access to and financial support
from the fewer available but more financially capable men, thereby overcoming imbalanced sex-
ratios caused by male migration (for Haiti, see Herskovits 1937: 114 –15; Simpson 1942: 656;
Murray 1977: 263; for Carriacou, see M. G. Smith 1961: 469; 1962: 117–22, 463–65, 1966:
xviii; Hill 1977: 281; for the Commonwealth Caribbean, see Otterbein 1965; Marino 1970;
Sutton and Makiesky-Barrow 1970: 312–13: for Jamaica, see Clarke, 1966; for Trinidad, see
Greenfield, 1966; for Providencia, see Wilson 1973: 79; for Belize, see Gonzalez 1969: 49; for
St. John, see Olwig 1985: 125; for St. Vincents, see Gearing 1988: 219; for Montserrat, see
Philpott 1973: 116, 119; for British Guyana, see R. T. Smith, 1988).
Greater numbers of births during times of male absenteeism were also made possible through a
series of relationships, what can be called unstable union. Serial mating, or what is sometimes
called serial monogamy (without the emphasis on legal marriage), was socially viable and
acceptable in the Caribbean. Women often began childbearing while still living in the home of
their parents (see Clarke 1966: 99; Blake 1961; Greenfield 1966; Freilich 1968: 52; Senior
1991); they waited to commit to matrimony until toward the end of their reproductive careers
when they were in their thirties and forties (Massiah 1983: 14; Roberts, 1957: 206–7). The trend
was manifest in the fact that up until the 1970s, 40 to 75 percent of all Caribbean children were
born to unmarried women (Senior 1991: 82; Roberts, 1957: 202); and 50 percent of Caribbean
women bore children by two or more partners over the course of their lives (Ebanks et al. 1974;
Ebanks 1973; Roberts, 1957).
The extent to which it was in fact polygyny and serial mating that made increased birth rates in
the Caribbean possible when fewer men were present is evident in the increasing incidence of
illegitimate births during times of heavy male absenteeism, called a Caribbean “structural
principle” by Hill (1977: 281; see also Otterbein 1965; M.G. Smith 1962: 117–22; Roberts 1957:
220). The birth histories of individual Caribbean women also demonstrated the relationship.
Those women with the highest fertility levels were not, as expected in Bongaarts and Potter’s
model, those who remained in stable union. Ebanks et al. (1974) in Barbados and Ebanks (1973)
in Jamaica found that in contrast to conventional demographic theory, the number of children a
woman gave birth to in her lifetime increased with the number of partnerships she had. This was
the case even when the researchers controlled for present age, age at entry into first union, age at
first pregnancy, time spent within sexual union, time spent outside of union, type of union, and
contraceptive use (see also Wilson 1961, for a similar finding in Providencia, and Marino, 1970:
166, who compared age cohorts of women from eight different islands).
Conclusion
In this and the preceding chapter I have tried to show how Caribbean family patterns were a
response to basic economic challenges that confronted impoverished people living in the region.
The costs of households and the need for children to make them productive set up conditions that
would give way to the familial patterns found in the Caribbean. Both women, parents, and,
arguably, men subscribed in principle to elite values of marriage and monogamy. Indeed, in the
Caribbean, female participation in the salaried labor force has been correlated with increased
marriage rates and lower rates of illegitimacy, i.e., when women have a dependable source of
extrahousehold income they marry (Abraham 1993). But it was not historically so easy. As in
Jean Rabel, parents, especially mothers, wanted children and grandchildren, indeed needed them
to make the household productive. But they wanted—and arguably needed—their daughter to
father them with men who could provide income to at least help get the children through the
early period of dependency, that critical zero to five years stage before children became
contributing members of the household. Moreover, as women advanced in their reproductive
careers, they depended on men to underwrite the costs of establishing a new productive
homestead and the beginning of their marketing careers.
Thus, as in Jean Rabel, a particular configuration of a sexual moral economy emerged. Mothers
tightly controlled daughters. They instilled them with fear of contraception and abortion, kept
them in the dark about the mechanics of pregnancy, and monitored their sexual activities. On the
other side of the equation, sons were encouraged to be sexually aggressive and ridiculed for not
conforming. A man was not a man if he did not have premarital and extramarital sex and his
status depended heavily on the number of children he sired. Not warned by mothers, not
protected against men with financial resources, daughters were left defenseless against
pregnancy.
On the part of males, the scarcity of cash and salaried jobs made it difficult for them to find the
means to meet the demands of women and their families and most importantly of all, to finance a
household. The primary way men got the money was by migrating. Wage migration became a
male determinant of parenthood in much of the Caribbean, a veritable rite of passage. If men
wanted to fully participate in adult social life they often had to migrate. But it was emphatically
not an issue of men simply seeking the means to meet financial demands attached to sex. And it
is here that we come back once again to the other side of the issue, the side often ignored in the
literature: the dependency of Caribbean men on women and children, seen earlier; for economic
autonomy, dignity, and respect ultimately accrued to impoverished West Indian men only
through the co-ownership of the most important means of production and mechanism for
survival in the Caribbean, a household.
The frequent absences of men, the increased income of those who were present, and the
increased income through remittances from fathers, brothers, sons, and lovers, in combination
with pressure from elders and ignorance of the mechanisms of childbirth, meant that many
women were more likely not to marry until later in life, to keep options open to them, and to
begin or to intensify their childbearing career during times of high male wage migration—when
men were scarcer but had greater resources—resulting in the counterintuitive phenomenon of
fewer men, more babies discussed in this chapter. When men and women did marry it was to
consolidate exclusive ownership, rights to production, and heredity for an already long
established and productive household—especially important to a woman in lieu of the
probability that her now financially mature husband might engage in extra-marital unions that
result in the birth of “outside” children, i.e. polygyny.
Moreover, although it struck most Western observers as bizarre, the fewer-men-more-babies
phenomenon may be much more widespread than the Caribbean. Ethnographers in Polynesia
(Larson 1981), in Thailand (Kunstadter 1971), in New Guinea (Taufa et al.1990), and in rural
Spain (Reher and Iriso-Napal 1989) all found statistically positive relationships between
increased birth rates and male absenteeism brought about by wage migration. Researchers
analyzing large samples of cross-country data for developing regions have similarly noted that
migration delays the transition to lower fertility (Bilsborrow 1987; Bilsborrow and Winegarden
1985); Bongaarts himself noted that in sub-Saharan Africa—an area characterized by high male
wage migration—fertility-inhibiting effects expected from migration did not come about, the
reasons for which he could only speculate (Bongaarts et al. 1984: 511). Indeed, what perplexed
Bongaarts is an old and apparently much forgotten idiosyncrasy that vexed earlier students of the
demographic transition. Even Kingsley Davis (1963), the original formulator of the proximate
and immediate determinants of fertility and one of the most important demographers of the 20th
century, noted that emigration often offset fertility decline (see also Friedlander 1969; Mosher
1980; Moore 1945: 119; Hawley 1950, particularly chapter 9). But as with so many other
demographic trends that did not fulfill the expectations of social scientists, this issue of migration
offsetting fertility decline was ignored. In the following chapter I want to deal with
understanding why.
*****
Notes
. The landmark study supporting that migration—and hence male absenteeism— disrupted
fertility in Caribbean communities was carried out by McElroy and Albuquerque (1990) who
tested data from ten countries in the Commonwealth Caribbean. Using a Spearman’s rank-order
correlation coefficient, they measured the relationship between out-migration and fertility for the
1960–1965 and the 1965–1970 periods. Their results yielded correlation coefficients of -0.52 and
-0.39 (McElroy and Albuuquerque 1990: 792), respectively. Neither of the tests were statistically
significant at the 0.05 level, the data nevertheless seemed to indicate that out-migration
correlates negatively with fertility decline in Caribbean sending countries—the higher the out-
migration the lower the fertility rate. But, rather than demonstrating that male wage migration
disrupts fertility, their data can be interpreted as demonstrating the opposite.
First, although their argument that emigration during the 1960s is “dominated by females”
(McElroy and Albuquerque cite Marshal, 1985:52), temporary wage migration was clearly
dominated by men. Looking at Marino’s sex ratio chart (in the main text) it can be seen that out
of the ten Caribbean countries for which McElroy and Albuquerque provide data, men were in
the minority in all but one; in most of the cases men were outnumbered by reproductive-age
females three to two and in some cases there were almost twice as many reproductive-age
females as men.
The most significant shortcoming in their argument has to do with attempting to identify the
“independent influence of migration” that McElroy and Albuquerque claimed they had isolated
(1990: 785). The researchers did not account for other variables affecting fertility, such as wage
labor available to women. This neglect is understandable because, as the authors themselves
point out, reliable cross-country socioeconomic data for the Caribbean is scarce (McElroy and
Albuquerque 1990: 785–86). On the other hand, the failure to exercise socioeconomic controls
damages the validity of their argument. And here is why:
Like other areas of the world, the Caribbean during the 1960s was experiencing dramatic
socioeconomic changes. Specifically, in the countries included in McElroy and Albuquerque’s
sample, the percentage of the labor force engaged in agriculture declined by an average of 30
percent; the percentage of population living in urban areas increased by 24 percent; female
enrollment in primary school increased by 44 percent; life expectancy increased by an average of
5.1 years; and in most instances, infant mortality declined precipitously—in Grenada, for
example, infant mortality declined from 77.9 to 34 deaths per 1,000; all factors known to
precipitate or at least be associated fertility transition (Caldwell 1982; Handwerker 1986). And
indeed, congruent with changes in living standards and economic conditions, Caribbean Total
Fertility Rates declined during this period by an average .351 births per women.
Because of the dramatic changes in demographic, health, and socioeconomic conditions, the
measurement of interest for McElroy and Albuquerque should not have been how much
Caribbean out-migration correlated with fertility levels. The relationship that McElroy and
Albuquerque should have measured is how much out-migration detracted from or sped
Caribbean fertility decline, i.e., the average level of migration correlated with the change in
fertility rates. When McElroy and Albuquerque’s data is used to plot the changes in TFR (1970
TFR minus 1960 TFR) against the rate of out-migration, a very different picture emerges than
that proposed by the researchers.
The amount of reduction in fertility levels for individual Caribbean countries correlated with the
average rate of migration for the 1960 to 1970 period indicates an association between small or
absent fertility decline and high levels of out-migration (see table 18.2). A Spearman’s rank-
order correlation coefficient yields a -.340 (without significance below the .05 level). In effect,
the higher the migration the lower the fertility decline. When Puerto Rico is excluded from the
data set, because it is an outlier and was experiencing large-scale economic and social
intervention from the United States during this era, a Spearman’s rank-order correlation
coefficient takes on the value of -.628 (with significance below the .05 level. Thus, rather than
stimulating fertility decline, it could more easily be argued that migration offset fertility decline.
Moreover, the studies provided by Marino (1970) and Brittain (1990, 1991a, 1991b) demonstrate
that before the onset of rapid fertility decline in the region, there was a correspondence between
male absenteeism and increased birth rates.
Table 18.2: Correlations in average change in total fertility rate by net migration
2. The fewer men, more babies relationship was also evident in Jean Rabel. With the first coup
d’etat (1991) that deposed democratically elected Jean Bertrand Aristide and the ensuing three
years of international embargo, the migration of men conspicuously intensified. An
unprecedented wave of mostly young males left the area headed for the Dominican Republic,
Jamaica, Suriname, Cuba, Panama, Honduras, Venezuela, Colombia, Mexico, the United States,
and the nearby Bahamas. The migration was such that in 1997, Jean Rabel sex ratios for the
twenty- to thirty-four-year age varied from eighty-five to ninety-two males for every one
hundred females. Most of these missing men had left home in search of employment so they
could remit income primarily to mothers, mothers of their children, wives, and girlfriends.
Moreover, using clinic data from the Bon Nouvel Mission (a clinic in Jean Rabel), and
comparing that data for the periods before and after 1992 suggests that birth rates during this
period markedly increased. Comparing the seven year time period (1985–1992) with the six year
time period (1993–1999), there was a 20 percent decrease in contraceptive use from 6.9 percent
to 5.5 percent; a two-year decline in mother’s age at first birth , from twenty-two to twenty years
of age ( P < .05); and a 5.9 month decline in the average length of a woman’s first inter-birth
interval, from 29.5 to 23.6 months (p > .05 but p < .10).
3. “Lè li ka boukannen” (when he can barbeque) is an expression that derives from children
digging up and cooking sweet potatoes, something young children, especially boys, often do, and
it signifies a child’s ability to look after himself.
4. O, pou ki yon moun fe ti moun? Ke vle di, ou fe ti moun nan. W-ap bat pou chape yo. . . . L-ap
grandi yo. L-ap chape. Demen si dieu vle, si ou bezwen ti dlo li ka ba ou. Si ou bezwenn ti bout
bwa li ka pote li pou ou. Ou bezwenn ni konn ed.
5. Mwen fe ti moun, kounye-a m vin gen yon pwoblem, kounye-a ti moun ka redi pwoblem.
Demen si dieu vle, m vin pa kapab, se sou kont ti moun m-ap vini. Kounye-a map chape yo.
Demen si dieu vle yo ka bat ave-m.
6. L-ap ba-m di goude pou ti moun, se sa k fe m ta reme sa
7. Non. Lè yon moun jenn, bagay sa m-ap di, ou bezwenn yon mari, komsi m di, si ou poko
enfante, ou ka enfante yon ti moun.
8. Si yon moun marie, pou ki sa li marie? Li pa marie ni pou chef ni pou anyen. Se pou li ka fe
dè ti moun. . . . En ben, pou kisa yon moun fe ti moun? Se pou li ka ed-o. . . al nan dlo-a . . . al
nan bwa.
9. M-ap swiv neg la, paskè m gentan gen pitit ave-li. Li pa ka abandone ni net. Fo-k li vin chita
la pou ede-m chape ti moun yo
10. En ben, ki fe-m ka viv san gason? Sa-m bezwenn m ka leve yon sak manje, se a kat ti moun
um m ka rive.
11. Si m gen ti moun m pa bezwenn mari-m menm. Ti moun, hoy, hoy. M ta reme dis pitit, m pa
bezwenn mari.
12. Pou ki rezon fe-m ka viv san gason. Ko-m rive nan laj konsa. Tout afe-m mache. M pa
bezwenn mari-m anko.
Chapter 19
A Reflexive and Critical Look at the Anthropology of the Caribbean
Introduction
At the beginning of this book, I showed how researchers and scholars have largely rejected the
notion that economic benefits of children among small farmers are a significant determinant of
developing country birth rates, kinship, and family and courtship practices. It is a rejection that
permeates the literature; one that does not make sense in light of ethnographers’ rigorous
documentation of the utility of children; and it has impeded an understanding of the determinants
of Caribbean familial patterns. But it was not the only misunderstanding of its kind in the
literature.
Throughout the book, I touched on a series of other issues where scholars did not accurately
appreciate the ethnographic facts. In chapter 8, I showed how estimates of per capita income
were misleading and, in the case of Jean Rabel, based on faulty data collection; in chapter 16, I
showed how scholars projected repression onto Haitian women when in fact rural Haitian
women enjoy a level of economic autonomy that often rivals or exceeds that of their spouses; in
chapter 17, I showed how male absenteeism gave way to inconsistent notions of “matrifocality”
and how this was generalized to an erroneous conclusion that Caribbean women were financially
independent of men; and in the previous chapter I showed how the “proximate and intermediate
determinants of fertility” were projected onto the demographic behavior of impoverished
Caribbean people when in fact they did not fit.
In addressing these issues and pulling together the work of other researchers I hope that I have
shown that the causes of Caribbean family patterns are not complex. They derive from basic
economic costs and benefits inherent in household livelihood strategies. Moreover, I am not the
first to think so. Anthropologists began focusing on Caribbean family patterns in the 1930s, and
among the first of them were scholars like Simpson (1942), who gave candid, economic
explanations for Caribbean value systems and family structure, including recognition of the
importance of the labor of children to the family. As will be seen in this chapter, others followed.
Scholars such as Cohen (1956), Solien de Gonzalez (1961), Kunstadter (1963), and Otterbein
(1965) made attempts to explain Caribbean family patterns according to practical material
conditions, particularly male financial contributions to housebuilding and the male wage
migration so prevalent in the Caribbean. But these explanations and trains of inquiry became
overshadowed. A fog of research agendas, convoluted analyses, proposed ideational and cultural
causes, and myths increasingly obscured the underlying determinants of Caribbean family
structure.
In this chapter I want to present exactly what these research agendas were and I also want to deal
with why. Why did researchers come to favor nonexplanatory explanations? I believe that I can
demonstrate that the answer is that the research and conclusions were usually steeped in political
discourse or government funded campaigns meant, not to understand the behavior of Caribbean
people, but to rationalize, manipulate, exploit, or change it.
Historical Particularism and Civil Rights
Caribbean family patterns made their first entrance into the mainstream literature when Melville
Herskovits—a student of Franz Boas—competed with Franklin Frazier, a sociologist, for what
Freilich (1967: 239) called “The Explanation.” Echoing sentiments of “separate but equal,”
Herskovits explained Caribbean family and kinship as reformulated cultural survivals from
Africa. Upon visiting Harlem he was impressed by a “teeming center of negro life,” complete
with “hospitals and the social service agencies . . . lawyers, and doctors and editors and writers . .
. capitalists, teachers, and nurses and students,” what he called “the same pattern” as white
society “only a different shade” (Herskovits 1925: 368; Gambrell 1997:104). As historian David
Levering Lewis (1981: 116) quipped, Herskovits’ arguments, popular with both white separatists
and the wealthy blacks who dominated the NAACP, earned the white Jewish scholar the title
“honorary New Negro”—a pun on Herskovits’ essay “The New Negro.”
Herskovits’ nemesis, Franklin Frazier, was an African-American professor of sociology at
Howard University and member of the civil rights intelligentsia that came to be known as the
Howard Circle. Frazier insisted on the primacy of the slave experience and subsequent
discrimination, poverty, and exploitation as determinants of Afroamerican/Caribbean family
patterns. He and those close to him viewed Herskovits’ arguments as an extension of that
discrimination, charging that the ideas he promoted lent credence to white racist arguments, and
that wealthy blacks accepted “unconditionally, the values of the white bourgeois world” because
“they do not truly identify themselves with Negroes”—one implication being that they benefited
from their positions as an intermediate elite negotiating the economic and political divide
between whites and blacks (Frazier 1957). Addressing Herskovits in a speech in Harlem, Frazier
summed the political implications of the Herskovits position:
If whites believe that the Negro’s social behaviour was rooted in African culture, they would lose
whatever sense of guilt they had for keeping the Negro down. Negro crime, for example, could be
explained away as an “Africanism” rather than due to inadequate police and court protection
http://www.nbufront.org/html/FRONTalView/ArticlesPapers/ThurgoodMarshallStamp.html1
(Tauheed 2003)
With the successes of the civil rights movement, the Herskovits-Frazier debate transformed.
Afroamericans interested in motivating black ethnicity to politically consolidate power—and
who may earlier have stood on the other side of the issue, that of equal rights and universal
suffrage—soon embraced Herskovits’ ideas. The 1960s was, as Cole (1985: 123) has described
it, “the era of African dress, African hairstyles and adoption of African names”; and “The
renewed interest in Africanisms . . . was clearly associated with the political climate of the Black
Power Movement and the rise of black studies in academic circles” (Cole 1985: 121). The
Africanism perspective of Caribbean family patterns continues among those scholars interested
in identity (Sutton and Makiesky-Barrow 1975: 297; Crahan et al. 1980; Cole 1985; Barrow
1986; Yelvington 2001). But for most anthropologists, they are no longer of major interest.2
The material difficulties of West Indian economic and social development are compounded by
instabilities and fluidities in the family organization on which the society depends both for the
effective socialization of its young and for the adequate motivation of its adult members to
participate vigorously in the social and economic life. These familial conditions affect labour
productivity, absenteeism, occupational aspirations, training and performances, attitudes to
saving, birth control, and farm development, and to programmes of individual and community
self-help, housing and child care, education, and the like. (1957: vi-vii)
In the end, structural functionalists fulfilled the prophecies of the funding agencies so
effectively—finding that the behavior of lower-income Caribbean people was indeed
“dysfunctional,” “uncivilized,” and “disorganized”—that they were arguably a principal force in
the destruction of the paradigm. Structural-functionalism could not survive the onslaught of
“structural-less” and “functional-less” findings. As for the drive to modify the morality of
impoverished denizens of the Caribbean, independence squashed it. Independence for Jamaica
came in 1962; for Trinidad and Tobago, internal self-rule came in 1962 and full independence in
1976; for the Bahamas, internal self-rule came in 1964 and full independence in 1973; and most
of the lesser Antilles’ independence came in the 1960s to 1980s. With the end of the colonial
regimes, came an end to the funding of social science research targeted to turn the impoverished
people of the colonies into happy, ambitious, and legally married tax payers.
Feminists
“Feminists went to the Caribbean to correct ideological distortions by documenting and assessing
women's economic, social and political roles” (Safa 1986: 1). They were funded by organizations
such as USAID’s Women in Development Technical Assistance Project (WIDTECH), a program
deliberately targeted to empower women in the workplace and help them break with traditional
gender roles, a worthy social goal in that many Caribbean economies were experiencing
industrialization and almost all were being transformed by juggernaut growth in the tourist
sector. But it was not conducive to academic understanding.
In analyzing and collecting data, feminists gave ample consideration to material conditions.
Massiah (1983) showed that Caribbean women who head households were economically
disadvantaged. Blumberg (1993) and Dehavenon (1993) both provided materialist models aimed
at accounting for conditions that give way to female-headed households. Abraham (1993)
showed how illegitimacy and marriage rates in Carriacou correlated with female access to wage
employment. Another admirable feminist argument in regard to explaining female-
headed/supported households was that women assume responsibility by default: when men were
undependable providers, either because of marginal income opportunities, migration, or
culturally ingrained apathy, women were forced to assume the role of household head and
provider (Senior 1991: 36–37, 170–71; Massiah 1983: 10–12). A number of feminists, like
Barrow (1986: 170), also documented Caribbean women as employing “strategies” to
“manipulate a man thereby gaining materially and enhancing their economic autonomy” (see
also Senior 1991).
But, while interesting and while they made notable contributions, feminist research was
embedded in the movement to empower women. In pursuit of this endeavor it was eclectic,
yielded no comprehensive explanation for family patterns, distorted the role of women in the
other direction, largely ignoring studies carried out by men and women who preceded them, and
often ignoring the existence of men altogether (see Greene and Biddlecom 2000 for a recent
critique).
An example is the book titled Where Did All the Men Go: Female-Headed/Female-Supported
Households in Cross-Cultural Perspective (1993), edited by Mencher and Okongwu, among the
most notable feminist anthologies of causal investigations into Caribbean family patterns.
Somewhat ironically, none of the authors investigated “where all the men went,” what they were
doing, if or how much money they sent back, or if female-headed households really meant
“female-supported.”
But worse regarding feminist contributions to causal understanding is that ignoring men gave
way to one of the most obscurant myths that came to muddle a causal understanding of familial
dynamics: that Caribbean women were financially and emotionally independent of men. Helen
Safa (1986) a leading feminist scholar, typified the feminists in the Caribbean position when she
declared in the introductory chapter for a major feminist anthology on the West Indies,
“Caribbean low-income women have been fending for themselves and their families for a long
time, and have learned not to depend on men for financial or even emotional support” (13–14).
This poignant and often quoted misstatement was not only giving short shrift to the majority of
impoverished Caribbean men—who in the endeavor to meet the demands women attached to
sexuality and paternity found themselves far from home toiling in sugar cane fields, mines, and
construction sites—it was not supported by research findings, not even, as seen an earlier
chapter, by feminist research findings.
For many students and scholars the notion that Caribbean women were neither emotionally nor
financially dependent on men became erroneously enshrined in the concept of matrifocality. R.
T. Smith (1956; 1988: 8) first used the term to describe familial development sequences marked
by unstable sexual unions, female-headed households, matrilocality, and strong mother-child
bonds. Other scholars adopted the term and “matrifocality” became a widely used
anthropological descriptive for the Caribbean family. But when Gonzalez (1970) tried to figure
out what other scholars meant by “matrifocal” she found little agreement. Researchers used
“matrifocal” to describe situations where women were “somehow” more important than the
observer had expected: that women had influence in spending family income; as a reference to
situations where women were the primary source of income; to designate female-headed
households; to delineate female-dominated decision making in the domestic sphere; and at times
matrifocality became confused with the consanguineal female-headed households (1970: 231–
32, 236; see also Mohammed 1986: 171–72). Eventually, Gonzalez (1984: 8) herself decided that
she was “no longer so sure” of her original distinction between consanguineal and matrifocal
families “in either an etic or an emic sense.” Even R. T. Smith (1988: 7)—who originally coined
the term—came to describe “matrifocality” as “surrounded by a dense fog of misunderstanding,”
only to then admit to “some shifts in the meaning I now attach to it.” Blackwood (2005) summed
up the enduring confusion surrounding the concept when she wrote that during the 1980s the
term “matrifocal” was “allowed to slink offstage without certain issues being resolved” only to
return later in the form of “female-headed household.” 3
In short, feminist studies of the 1980s and 1990s were embedded in a campaign to empower
women—to their credit they often admitted it—but they did little to advance the understanding
of the causes underlying family patterns and kinship in the Caribbean. Indeed, authors such as
Blackwood (2005) have criticized early feminists themselves for having overemphasized
“matrifocality,” thereby perpetuating patriarchic myths.
Contraceptive Campaigns
Many researchers who worked in the Caribbean Basin, especially since the early 1970s, were
caught up in antinatal and contraceptive campaigns. Blake (1961), Stycos and Back (1964),
Murray (1972, 1976, 1977), Ebanks et al. (1973, 1974, 1975), Handwerker (1983, 1986, 1989,
1993), Jennie Smith (1998), McElroy and Albuquerque (1990), Senior (1991), and Maynard-
Tucker (1996) all went to the Caribbean under the tutelage or in association with internationally
sponsored fertility reduction programs. The slant inherent in their research objectives are
reflected in their conclusions: high birth rates are consistently portrayed as illogical and
nonadaptive, the cause of economic hardship and burdensome to women.
As seen in chapter 2, Murray’s (1977) otherwise excellent analysis of the reasons that Haitian
farmers give for having large numbers of children was marred by an inexplicable division of the
category “useful.” Murray split into two separate categories those farmers who gave “useful” as
an explanation for wanting children but did not explain what they meant from those who said
“useful” and then specified “as workers.” By dividing the response “useful,” Murray was able to
present farmers as favoring children for noneconomic ends; had he done otherwise, had he
accepted the implication that “useful” meant to work, the small farmers in Murray’s community
would have overwhelmingly come out in favor of having children for economic reasons.
Similarly, Maynard-Tucker (1996: 1381) inexplicably twisted her observations that Haitian
children were economically useful into them being a burden and then blamed high fertility on
causes such as values left over from slavery. Handwerker (1989,1993) focused on female
repression in the domestic sphere and employment in the formal sector of Antigua and Barbados,
a focus that echoed his earlier highly regarded cross-country test (1986) demonstrating that
female involvement in the work force was the principal determinant of fertility decline
throughout the world; a valid and well supported observation but one that ignored why fertility
was high in the first place or, more specifically, ignored Caribbean women’s traditional careers
as managers of productive households, their roles as market women, and the importance of child
labor in making them successful in these endeavors. Senior (1991: 67–69) blamed high fertility
on causes such as “the need to feel like a woman” and “the biblical injunction to be fruitful and
multiply.” And Jennie Smith (1998: 11), began her discussion by saying that, with regard to poor
Haitian farmers, proponents of contraceptive use “are simply proposing the preposterous!” But
later, in an almost humorous parenthetical and self-reflective moment, she candidly wondered
why she fell into the same trap: her exact parenthetical quote was, “Looking back over the pages
above, I find that I myself, however unwittingly, also seem to hold that underlying assumption”
(Smith 1998: 24).4
Beyond showing the otherwise inexplicable manipulation of categories (Murray), denial of their
own observations (Maynard-Tucker, Smith, Senior), and the over-focus on the formal economy
(Handwerker), it is perhaps impossible to unequivocally demonstrate the link between funding
agendas and the thought processes of the researchers. But it could be argued that in their
conclusions researchers eschewed the obvious importance of child labor contributions because it
was a conclusion that meant funding agencies and the researcher-scholar who hoped to get
another consultancy job could do nothing to change the situation. If impoverished people were
having many children because children were important in the struggle to survive then what
needed to be changed was the entire economic system, not a practical or feasible
recommendation. If, on the other hand, it was only a matter of tradition, values, lack of
knowledge, unavailability of contraceptives, and ineffective healthcare systems, something could
be done about it. Seminars, education, and improved clinics could solve the problem. There is
also the issue of the researchers’ own values. Anthropologists themselves may have eschewed
presenting Caribbean parents as wanting children primarily for work because it was an egregious
violation of our own middle and upper class Western values, a point that brings me to the
international campaign against child labor.
Charities, such as that Cadet represented, pursued the issue with gusto, further inflating figures
and creating an image of Haiti as the largest slave state since Cuban emancipation--an ironic
accolade for the country that evolved out of the only successful slave revolt in history. In the
scramble to solicit donations, Internet sites for organizations like Haitian Street Kids Inc. (HSKI
2007), further inflated the numbers and lumped homeless street urchins with the restavek in even
more absurd and self-contradictory claims such as “There are currently over 400,000 child slaves
as young as 4 years old throughout Haiti,” telling the reader that they “often times are beaten to
death,” and that if one were to go to Haiti—which few readers ever will—they can identify the
restavek by “their torn rags and tattered clothes hanging from their strained and feeble limbs,
often times begging for food and money” (HSKI 2007).
The main point that I am trying to make is that the reaction to child labor and the sensationalism
of the presentations reflect the extremity of the mainstream Western view of children in which
having children for the purpose of exploiting their labor is criminal. The fact is that, as we
already know, Haitian children living with their parents also work, something that likely occurs
among impoverished farmers throughout the world and certainly occurred widely in the 17th to
early 20th century United States. In David Lancy’s (2007: 280) ethnology of child-adult play he
noted that pushing Western values of child-adult play on other societies and impoverished
peoples is “tantamount to a condemnation of the child-rearing beliefs and behaviors of three
fourths of the world’s parents.” Indeed, by definition of the 1956 UN Supplementary Convention
on the Abolition of Slavery, the Slave Trade, and Institutions and Practices Similar to Slavery,
the Haitian parents seen in earlier chapters are in violation of Convention 138 under the Child
Labor Code (Fafo 2002: 33). Thus, the interesting point is not that rural Haitians are hard on
their children or that they do not love their children. The interesting point is that mainstream
Western conventions regarding children are so out of synchrony with the reality of poverty that it
made the childrearing practices and goals of many impoverished peoples of the world illegal.
This ‘discrimination’ has an impact on the social scientist. Members of the Western educated
elite but with a strong tendency toward advocacy on the part of those they study, anthropologists
are subject to a definitive reluctance to bring attention to cultural values that Westerners regard
as disparaging if not criminal. The Western anthropologist who reveals “his people” as thinking
of their offspring first and foremost not in terms of love and companionship, but in terms of labor
and material necessity has, by Western standards, done a disservice to his former hosts. He has
portrayed them in the annals of the ethnographic literature as criminal, calloused and selfish.
In regard to child labor, the degree to which this bias and the pro-Western values that drive it
have penetrated the anthropological literature is evidenced by the five articles of the June 2007
special edition of American Anthropologist focusing on children and reviewing the 20th century
anthropological literature on child studies. There is only one, just one, passing mention of
ethnographies of children at work. That reference was Lancy himself (2007: 277), who tersely
summed up ethnographic references to child work, saying that “the primary reason adults [in the
developing communities studied] are likely to take a jaundiced view of children at play is
because they would rather see them working” (Lancy cited Bock and Johnson 2004; Munroe et
al. 1984; and more specifically, for the Maya, Modiano 1973: 55; for the Yoruba, Oloko
1994:211; and for the Hadza, Blurton-Jones 1993: 317).
Interviewer: Who is better off, a couple with three children or the couple with six
children?
Mother: All children are good.
Interviewer: No. I am asking you, respond three or respond six.
Mother: Eh, if, eh. Okay. Normally, concerning children, if God gives you three children, he
doesn’t give you any more, you just have to live with what God gave you.
Interviewer: Yes. You have to live with what he gave you. But it is a question that I am asking
you.
Mother:I am following you Madanmwazel. Honestly.
Interviewer: Yes. I understand. “Honestly.” But I am asking you, concerning this question, three
or six, which is better? You must decide if it is three or six.
(Silence)
Mother: Six.
Interviewer: Why?
Mother: They are there. They will help you.
Interviewer: Three can help you too. But six?
Mother: Yes, six. Six can help you more. Some will go to the garden. Some to the water. Some
will do laundry.
Interviewer: (Silence)
*****
Notes
1. In his 1957 study, Frazier, himself African American, accused wealthy blacks of accepting,
“unconditionally, the values of the white bourgeois world” because “they do not truly identify
themselves with Negroes.”
2. Herskovits came to be associated with explanations for Caribbean family patterns based solely
on African survivals and Frazier became identified—somewhat unfairly—with a slavery origins
argument. These theoretical positions persist in the literature today. In respect to family patterns,
Barrow (1986), and Sutton and Makiesky-Barrow (1970: 297) emphasize both approaches.
Abraham (1993) recently argued in favor of slavery as a primary condition for the emergence of
modern Caribbean family patterns.
3. The problem with matrifocality and the misuse of the concept is also exemplified in another
prominent work. Safa (1986), an excellent field researcher/anthropologist and a leading feminist
scholar who was seen above saying that “Caribbean women learned not to depend on men for
financial or even emotional support,” expanded on this misrepresentation, subsequently titling a
book Myth of the Male Breadwinner (1995), thus bequeathing to a generation of anthropologists
the enduring image of Caribbean women being historically independent of financial support from
men. She drove the point home in her introductions with sweeping conclusions and claims
regarding the English Caribbean tradition of “matrifocality” as if it were a self-perpetuating
institution, something that had little to do with reality or even with her own findings. Her studies
were not about the historic Caribbean, nor were they about the English or French Caribbean; they
were carried out in the Spanish Caribbean, an area so socioeconomically distinct that Safa herself
is one of the few researchers to have ever made a comparison. Moreover, her studies in the
Spanish Caribbean demonstrated not that there was a historic tradition of “matrifocality”—as she
claimed—but rather the contrary, that “matrifocality” was a response to increasing urbanization
and industrialization. Indeed, given her evidence for nonhistorical causation, a better title for
Safa’s book would have been Myth of Matrifocality (for a similar conclusion regarding
matrifocality and feminism see Branche 2002: 89). As for the “mythical male breadwinner,” it
was seen in chapter 17 that in the traditional Caribbean he really existed. Or at least some version
of him.
4. See Catherine Maternowska (1996) for an excellent investigation of the problems of
insensitive health care workers and contraceptive distribution in the Port-au-Prince slum area of
Cité Soleil.
5. Sub-Commission on the Promotion and Protection of Human Rights Working Group on
Contemporary Forms of Slavery, 25th Session, Geneva.
*******************
Works Cited