Lecture On RBC
Lecture On RBC
Krzysztof Makarski
• Frisch elasticity εF with logarithmic preferences u(c, n) = log c + φ log(1 − n) from un = uc w we get
φc
n=1−
w
∂n w φc w φc 1 1−n
εF = = 2 = =
∂w n w n w n n
which given that n ≈ 0.3 gives the estimate of Frisch elasticity ≈ 2.33.
• Additionally, recent studies show that correcting the Solow residual estimates for mismeasurements of
inputs and inappropriate assumptions about market structure lowers volatility of technology shocks.
• The Solow residual measure from simple Cobb-Douglas technology very spurious.
• Since the RBC model requires large and volatile technology shocks this ndings could be interpreted
as negative falsication of the RBC model.
Assumptions
• Hansen (1985) modies the standard (Prescott) RBC model by introducing labor indivisibility.
• Economy is populated by innitely many households (of measure 1) indexed by i ∈ [0, 1].
• The representative rms operates a CRS technology.
1
Indivisible vs.Divisible
Divisible labor
Labor Indivisible Labor
Fluctuations in aggregate hours worked in the economy are due to changes in both the number
of hours people choose to work (intensive margin) and the number of people entering and leaving
the work force (extensive margin)
Hansen uses quarterly, post war data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics and nds that 55% of
the variance of total hours worked is due to variation in the number of people at work, while 20%
is due to variation in the average hours worked.
Since most of the variation in total hours worked is due to individuals either working or not
working, this supports modeling of RBC with indivisible labor.
Fitting a standard RBC model with divisible labor requires very high elasticity of substitution
between leisure across time periods for households, which is inconsistent with panel data.
In a RBC model with indivisible labor elasticity of substitution for households is low, while the
elasticity for the representative agent is innite since, it is independent of the utility function
implied by the individual household.
• Note. We still should model both intensive and extensive margin (as uctuations along both are
observed in the economy)
Firms
• Producers hire labor nt and capital kt to produce output yt . They have access to the CRS technology
yt = zt ktα nt 1−α . Real wage is denoted as wt and the rental rate for capital rk,t (it is not the interest
rate)
2
Households
• We assume that consumers earn income from labor wt nt and capital rental rk,t kt which they spend
either on consumption ct or investments xt . Additionally, household receive dividends from rms
(which are zero in equilibrium) Πt . Hence the consumer budget constraint has the following form
ct + xt ≤ wt nt + rk,t kt + Πt (1.2)
• Instantaneous utility function (felicity function) is given by the following function u(ct , nt ) and each
consumer maximizes the lifetime utility subject to the sequence of budget constraints
∞
hX i
max ∞ E0 β t u(ct , nt ) (1.4)
{ct ,nt ,kt }t=0
t=0
subject to ct + xt ≤ wt nt + rk,t kt + Πt
kt+1 = xt + (1 − δ)kt (1.5)
nt ∈ [0, 1] , kt ≥ 0
Market clearing
• Markets clear when demand and supply are equal.
• Labor market and capital rental market clearing conditions are introduced notationally (the same n in
the rm problem as in the consumer problem).
• {ct , xt , nt , kt }∞
t=0 solves the consumer problem given prices
∞
" #
X
t
max E0 β (log ct + φ log(1 − nt ))
{ct ,xt ,kt+1 ,nt }∞
t=0
t=0
sb. to ct + xt = wt nt + rk,t kt + Πt
kt+1 = xt + (1 − δ) kt
nt ∈ [0, 1]
Πt = max yt − rk,t kt − wt nt
(yt ,nt ,kt )
• markets clear
ct + xt = yt
3
First Order Conditions
Maximization of
∞
X
Et β t+τ (log ct+τ + φ log(1 − nt+τ ))
τ =0
Substituting we get
ct+τ + kt+1+τ = wt+τ nt+τ + (rk,t+τ + (1 − δ))kt+τ + Πt+τ
To solve we construct the following Lagrangian
∞
X
L = Et β t+τ (log ct+τ + φ log(1 − nt+τ ))
τ =0
− λt+τ (ct+τ + kt+1+τ − wt+τ nt+τ − (rk,t+τ + (1 − δ))kt+τ − Πt+τ )
ct : Et [β t uc,t − λt ] = 0
nt : Et [β t un,t − λt wt ] = 0
kt+1 : Et [λt − λt+1 (rk,t+1 + 1 − δ)] = 0
Simplifying
ct : β t uc,t = λt
nt : β t un,t = λt wt
kt+1 : λt = Et [λt+1 (rk,t+1 + 1 − δ)]
Solving
un,t = uc,t wt
uc,t = βEt [uc,t+1 (rk,t+1 + 1 − δ)]
φct = wt (1 − nt )
ct
1 = βEt (rk,t+1 + (1 − δ))
ct+1
wt = At (1 − α) ktα n−α
t
rk,t = At αktα−1 n1−α
t
yt = At ktα n1−α
t
4
The market clearing condition
ct + xt = yt
with
kt+1 = xt + (1 − δ) kt
Summarizing the following equations characterize the economy
Euler
uc,t = βEt [uc,t+1 (rk,t+1 + 1 − δ)] (1.8)
wt = At (1 − α) ktα n−α
t (1.10)
yt = At ktα n1−α
t (1.12)
• Market clearing
ct + kt+1 = At ktα n1−α
t + (1 − δ)kt (1.13)
Properties
Next, we check whether a competitive allocation is ecient. First, we need to dene what ecient means.
∞
X
max E0 β t ln ct
{ct ,kt+1 ,nt }∞
t=0
t=0
p.w. ct + kt+1 = At ktα n1−α
t + (1 − δ)kt
nt ∈ [0, 1] , given k0
∞
X
Et β t+τ (log ct+τ + φ log(1 − nt+τ ))
τ =0
α
ct+τ + kt+1+τ = At+τ kt+τ n1−α
t+τ + (1 − δ)kt+τ )
∞
X
L = Et β t+τ (log ct+τ + φ log(1 − nt+τ ))
τ =0
α
− λt+τ (ct+τ + kt+1+τ − At+τ kt+τ n1−α
t+τ − (1 − δ)kt+τ )
5
ct : Et [β t uc,t − λt ] = 0
nt : Et [β t un,t − λt (1 − α)At+1 kt+1
α
n−α
t+1 ] = 0
α−1 1−α
kt+1 : Et [λt − λt+1 (αAt+1 kt+1 nt+1 + 1 − δ)] = 0
Simplifying
ct : β t uc,t = λt
nt : β t un,t = λt (1 − α)At+1 kt+1
α
n−α
t+1
α−1 1−α
kt+1 : λt = Et [λt+1 (αAt+1 kt+1 nt+1 + 1 − δ)]
Solving
un,t = α
uc,t (1 − α)At+1 kt+1 n−α
t+1
α−1 1−α
uc,t = βEt [uc,t+1 (αAt+1 kt+1 nt+1 + 1 − δ)]
φct = α
(1 − α)At+1 kt+1 n−α
t+1 (1 − nt )
ct α−1 1−α
1 = βEt αAt+1 kt+1 nt+1 + (1 − δ)
ct+1
Furthermore, we have the transversality condition
yt = Aktα n1−α
t (1.17)
Next we have
Theorem 2. First Welfare Theorem: Under certain conditions any competitive allocation is ecient.
Proof. First we simplify equations (1.7) − (1.13). Substituting from (1.10) − (1.11) into (1.7) − (1.8) we get
Thus competitive allocation satises equations (1.14) - (1.18). Note, that those equations are the same as
equations characterizing an ecient allocation. Hence, any competitive allocation is ecient.
and
Theorem 3. Second Welfare Theorem: Under certain conditions any ecient allocation can be decentralized
as a competitive allocation.
Proof. {c , n , k , y }
Consider an ecient allocation
∞
t
∞
(1.14) − (1.18)
t t t t=0 that satises equations . Construct
prices {wt , rk,t }t=0 using (1.10) − (1.11). Then the ecient allocation and the prices is a competitive equi-
librium, since they satisfy equations (1.7) − (1.13).
6
Both theorems are important. The rst one tells us that no resources are wasted in competitive equi-
librium. And the second tells us that any ecient allocation can be decentralized as an ecient allocation.
Furthermore, they are technically useful, since one does not need to nd an equilibrium directly, instead one
can nd an ecient allocation rst, and then prices using equations (1.10)− (1.11). Thus, one can just solve
the benevolent social planner problem to get an equilibrium.
Furthermore they reveal the informative role of the prices in the competitive economy. And any time the
price system is disturbed, it leads to an inecient outcome.
Assumptions
• Indivisibility of labor is modeled by restricting the labor supply possibilities set so that individuals can
work either full time, denoted by h̄ or not work at all.
• Each period, instead of choosing labor hours, households choose a probability of working ηt .
• A lottery then determines whether or not the household actually works.
• Markets are complete (households can trade state contingent bonds in order to insure themselves
completely from the risk of being unemployed, we will not include that into equations to simplify
notation).
• Since all households are the same they will choose the same probability of working h̄, ηt .
• Even though everyone ex ante chooses the same ηt the outcomes of each lottery will be dierent, so
each household will dier ex post.
The lottery guarantees that the consumption possibilities set will is convex (important from the
technical point of view).
The lottery also makes individuals better o because it increases the available choices. (Otherwise
they could only choose = 0 or 1).
• Therefore, only the utility function changes (the rest remains the same).
Labor indivisibility
• ηt - probability of working in period t by any agent (lottery). If she works, she works h̄ hours, with
0 ≤ n̄ ≤ 1.
u(ct, nt ) = ln ct − φ̃nt
• Note that while individual Frisch elasticity is zero the macro one is innite (linear utility).
7
The new household problem
• Instantaneous utility function (felicity function) is given by the following function u(ct , nt ) = ln ct − φ̃nt
and each consumer maximizes the lifetime utility subject to the sequence of budget constraints
∞
hX i
max E0 β t u(ct , nt ) (1.21)
{ct ,xt ,nt ,kt }∞
t=0
t=0
subject to ct + xt ≤ wt nt + rk,t kt + Πt
kt+1 = xt + (1 − δ)kt (1.22)
nt ∈ [0, 1] , kt ≥ 0
• {ct , xt , nt , kt }∞
t=0 solves the consumer problem given prices
∞
" #
X
t
max E0 β (ln ct − φ̃nt )
{ct ,xt ,kt+1 ,nt }∞
t=0
t=0
sb. to ct + xt = wt nt + rk,t kt + Πt
kt+1 = xt + (1 − δ) kt
nt ∈ [0, 1]
Πt = max yt − rk,t kt − wt nt
(yt ,nt ,kt )
• markets clear
ct + xt = yt
∞
X
Et β t+τ (log ct+τ − φ̃nt+τ ))
τ =0
Substituting we get
ct+τ + kt+1+τ = wt+τ nt+τ + (rk,t+τ + (1 − δ))kt+τ + Πt+τ
To solve we construct the following Lagrangian
∞
X
L = Et β t+τ (log ct+τ − φ̃nt+τ ))
τ =0
− λt+τ (ct+τ + kt+1+τ − wt+τ nt+τ − (rk,t+τ + (1 − δ))kt+τ − Πt+τ )
8
1
ct : Et [β t − λt ] = 0
ct
nt : Et [−β t φ̃ − λt wt ] = 0
kt+1 : Et [λt − λt+1 (rk,t+1 + 1 − δ)] = 0
plus the TVC
lim β t+τ Et [λt+τ kt+1+τ ] = 0
τ →∞
Simplifying
1
ct : βt = λt
ct
nt : β t φ̃ = λt wt
kt+1 : λt = Et [λt+1 (rk,t+1 + 1 − δ)]
Solving
1
β t φ̃ = βt wt
ct
1 1
βt = β t+1 Et [ (rk,t+1 + 1 − δ)]
ct ct+1
φ̃ct = wt
ct
1 = βEt (rk,t+1 + (1 − δ))
ct+1
The producer problem is the same as earlier.
wt = At (1 − α) ktα n−α
t
rk,t = At αktα−1 n1−α
t
yt = At ktα n1−α
t
Euler
ct
1 = βEt (rk,t+1 + (1 − δ)) (1.24)
ct+1
and the transversality condition
1
lim β t+τ Et [β t+τ kt+1+τ ] = 0 (1.25)
τ →∞ ct+τ
• The producer problem
wt = At (1 − α) ktα n−α
t (1.26)
yt = At ktα n1−α
t (1.28)
• Market clearing
ct + kt+1 = At ktα n1−α
t + (1 − δ)kt (1.29)
9
Log-linearization a a xt
xt
It is based on xat = xa xat x−a = xa elog xt −log x = xa ea log x = xa eax̂t ≈ xa (1 + ax̂t ), where x̂t = log x ).
Equation for capital accumulation
From
kt+1 = (1 − δ) kt + xt
In the steady state
δk = x
Log-linearizing
k 1 + k̂t+1 = (1 − δ) k 1 + k̂t + x (1 + x̂t )
k 1 + k̂t+1 = (1 − δ) k 1 + k̂t + δk (1 + x̂t )
Euler
From
βEt ct c−1
t+1 (rk,t+1 + (1 − δ)) = 1
Wage equation
From
wt = At (1 − α) ktα n−α
t
10
Log-linearizing
w(1 + ŵt ) = A(1 + Ât ) (1 − α) k α (1 + αk̂t )n−α (1 − αn̂t )
Simplifying
rk (1 + r̂k,t ) = A 1 + Ât αk α−1 1 + (α − 1) k̂t n1−α (1 + (1 − α) n̂t )
Simplifying
(1 + r̂k,t ) = 1 + Ât 1 + (α − 1) k̂t (1 + (1 − α) n̂t )
Production function
From
yt = At ktα n1−α
t
Simplifying
(1 + ŷt ) = 1 + Ât 1 + αk̂t (1 + (1 − α) n̂t )
Feasibility
Market clearing conditions replace balance of payments equation. Feasibility
ct + xt = yt
In the steady state
c+x=y
Log-linearizing
c (1 + ĉt ) + x (1 + x̂t ) = y (1 + ŷt )
Simplifying
c x
ĉt + x̂t = ŷt
y y
11
Steady state
First
ct
βEt (rk,t+1 + (1 − δ)) = 1
ct+1
gives
rk = β −1 − (1 − δ)
furthermore since rk = Aαk α−1 n1−α
k α−1
β −1 − (1 − δ) = Aα
n
k β −1 − (1 − δ) α−1
1 βAα 1
1−α
= =
n Aα 1 − β (1 − δ)
Substituting for
rk,t kt = At αktα−1 n1−α
t · kt = αAt ktα n1−α
t = αyt
we get
rk k = αy
k α α
= = −1
y rk β − (1 − δ)
Next, from
kt+1 = (1 − δ) kt + xt
we have
δk = x
thus
x k αδ βαδ
= δ = −1 =
y y β − (1 − δ) 1 − β (1 − δ)
and since
ct + xt = yt
we have
c x βαδ
= 1− =1−
y y 1 − β (1 − δ)
1 − β (1 − δ) − βαδ
=
1 − β (1 − δ)
(1 − β) + βδ (1 − α)
=
1 − β (1 − δ)
k α
φ̃c = w = A(1 − α)
n
α
A(1 − α) βAα 1−α
c=
φ̃ 1 − β (1 − δ)
From feasibility
c xk k α
+ =A
n kn n
c k α k
=A −δ
n n n
c
n= α
A nk − δ nk
12
k
Substituting for c and
n
α
1−α
A(1−α) βAα
φ̃ 1−β(1−δ)
n= α
1−α 1
1−α
βAα βAα
A 1−β(1−δ) −δ 1−β(1−δ)
Solution method
• Models is solved in dynare (codes attached) by local approximation around the steady state.
12 0.04
5
10 0.03
8 4 0.02
6 0.01
3
4 0
2 2 -0.01
0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40
6 5 10
4 4 5
2 3 0
0 2 -5
0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40
4 5 4
3 0 2
2 -5 0
0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40
13
Model data t
US data Divisible labor Indivisible labor
st.dev. corr(·,y) st.dev. corr(·,y) st.dev. corr(·,y)
• Indivisible labor increases the volatility of the stochastic growth model for a given stochastic process
for the technology shock.
• The indivisible labor model generates improves the model data t (hours and to lesser extent invest-
ments).
• Indivisible labor generates a highly procyclical productivity, while U.S. data shows that productivity
is only moderately procyclical.
Summary
• We highlighted the issue.
• Results.
Assumptions
• In the standard RBC there is weak amplication, therefore model almost behaves as technology shocks.
• After a positive technology shock the initial increase in output is only due to better technology and
higher labor supply (wages go up as well).
• Including,capacity utilization allows to intensify the use of capital in response to TFP shocks.
δ(ut ) = δuω
t
Capacity utilization
• δ - depreciation rate of capital.
• Depreciation rate of capital is a function of capital utilization ut , δ(ut ) is strictly increasing and strictly
0 00
convex, δ (·), δ (·) > 0. The law of motion of capital becomes
14
The new household problem
• Instantaneous utility function (felicity function) is given by the following function u(ct , nt ) = ln ct +
log(1 − nt ) and each consumer maximizes the lifetime utility subject to the sequence of budget con-
straints
∞
hX i
max E0 β t u(ct , nt ) (1.30)
{ct ,xt ,ut ,nt ,kt }∞
t=0
t=0
subject to ct + xt ≤ wt nt + rk,t ut kt + Πt
kt+1 = xt + (1 − δ(ut ))kt (1.31)
nt ∈ [0, 1] , kt ≥ 0
• {ct , xt , nt , ut , kt }∞
t=0 solves the consumer problem given prices
"∞ #
X
t
max E0 β (ln ct + φ ln(1 − nt )
{ct xt ,ut ,kt+1 ,nt }∞
t=0
t=0
sb. to ct + xt = wt nt + rk,t ut kt + Πt
kt+1 = xt + (1 − δ(ut )) kt
nt ∈ [0, 1]
Πt = max yt − rk,t κt − wt nt
(yt ,nt ,κt )
1−α
sb. to yt = zt κα
t nt
• markets clear
ct + xt = yt
κt = ut kt
∞
X
Et β t+τ (log ct+τ + φ log(1 − nt+τ ))
τ =0
subject to the budget constraint
ct+τ + kt+1+τ = wt+τ nt+τ + rk,t+τ ut+τ kt+τ + (1 − δ(ut+τ ))kt+τ + Πt+τ
To solve we construct the following Lagrangian
∞
X
L = Et β t+τ (log ct+τ + φ log(1 − nt+τ )))
τ =0
− λt+τ (ct+τ + kt+1+τ − wt+τ nt+τ − (rk,t+τ ut+τ kt+τ + (1 − δ(ut+τ ))kt+τ − Πt+τ )
15
First order conditions
1
ct : Et [β t − λt ] = 0
ct
1
nt : Et [−β t φ + λt wt ] = 0
1 − nt
kt+1 : Et [λt − λt+1 (rk,t+1 ut+1 + 1 − δ(ut+1 )] = 0
0
ut : λt (rk,t kt − δ (ut )kt ) = 0
Simplifying
1
ct : βt = λt
ct
1
nt : βtφ = λt wt
1 − nt
kt+1 : λt = Et [λt+1 (rk,t+1 ut+1 + 1 − δ(ut+1 ))]
0
ut : rk,t = δ (ut )
Solving
1 1
βtφ = βt wt
1 − nt ct
1 1
βt = β t+1 Et [ (rk,t+1 ut+1 + 1 − δ(ut+1 )]
ct ct+1
0
rk,t = δ (ut )
and
kt+1 = xt + (1 − δ(ut )) kt
Beware E(XY ) 6= E(X)E(Y ).
φct
= wt
1 − nt
ct
1 = βEt [ (rk,t+1 ut+1 + 1 − δ(ut+1 )]
ct+1
0
rk,t = δ (ut )
kt+1 = xt + (1 − δ(ut )) kt
−α
wt = At (1 − α) κα
t nt
rk,t = At ακα−1
t n1−α
t
1−α
yt = At κα
t nt
16
• The consumer problem Labor
φct
= wt (1.32)
1 − nt
Euler
ct
1 = βEt [ (rk,t+1 ut+1 + 1 − δ(ut+1 )] (1.33)
ct+1
Rental rate
0
rk,t = δ (ut ) (1.34)
2
where δ(u) = δ0 + δ1 (u − 1) + δ2 (u − 1) and the transversality condition
1
lim β t+τ Et [β t+τ kt+1+τ ] = 0 (1.36)
τ →∞ ct+τ
−α
wt = At (1 − α) κα
t nt (1.37)
Steady state 0
Since rk,t = δ (ut ) and δ(ut ) = δuω
t we get in the steady state
rk = δωuω−1
Next, from
ct
1 = βEt [ (rk,t+1 ut+1 + 1 − δ(ut+1 ))]
ct+1
in the steady state
1 = β (rk u + (1 − δuω ))
Substituting rk = δωuω−1
1 = β δωuω−1 u + 1 − δuω
β −1 − 1
uω =
δ(ω − 1)
Multiplying denominator and numerator by β
1 − β ω1
u=
βδ(ω − 1)
So from rk = δωuω−1
ω−1
1−β ω
rk = δω
βδ(ω − 1)
17
furthermore since rk = Aακα−1 n1−α = Aα(uk)α−1 n1−α
k α−1
rk = Aαuα−1
n
1
k r u α−1
k
=
n Aαuα
k
If we have
n we can get
k α
w = A(1 − α)(uk)α n−α = A(1 − α)uα
n
Substituting for
rk uk = Aα(uk)α−1 n1−α · (uk) = Aα(uk)α n1−α = αyt
we get
rk uk = αy
k α
=
y rk u
Next, from
kt+1 = (1 − δuω
t ) kt + xt
we have
x = δuω k
thus
x k αδuω
= δuω =
y y rk
and since
ct + xt = yt
we have
c x αδuω rk − αδuω
= 1− =1− =
y y rk rk
φct
Finally, from
1−nt = wt we get
c 1 wn
φ = (1 − n)
y n y
Since w · n = A(1 − α)(uk)α n−α · n = (1 − α)A(uk)α n1−α = (1 − α)y
c 1
φ = (1 − α)(1 − n)
y n
Solving for n we get
c
φ n + (1 − α)n = (1 − α)
y
(1 − α) (1 − α)
n= c
= <1
φ y + (1 − α) (1 − α) + φ rk −αδu
ω
rk
k w(1−n) y 1
Which allows to nd k (using
n ), c= φ , y= c ·c= c ·c and κ = uk .
y
18
Log-linearization a a xt
xt
It is based on xat = xa xat x−a = xa elog xt −log x = xa ea log x = xa eax̂t ≈ xa (1 + ax̂t ), where x̂t ≡ log x ).
Rental rate for capital
From
0
rk,t = δ (ut )
Since δ(ut ) = δuω
t we get
rk,t = δωuω−1
t
δuω k = x
Log-linearizing
k(1 + k̂t+1 ) = 1 − δuω − δωuω ût k(1 + k̂t ) + δuω k(1 + x̂t )
1 − δuω (1 + ωût+1 )]
1 = βEt [(1 + ĉt − ĉt+1 )(rk u(1 + r̂k,t+1 + ût+1 ) + 1 − δuω − δuω ωût+1 )]
Substituting rk = δωuω−1
1 = βEt [(1 + ĉt − ĉt+1 )(δωuω + δωuω r̂k,t+1 + δωuω ût+1 + 1 − δuω − δuω ωût+1 )]
19
Since β −1 = rk u + (1 − δuω )
Wage equation
From
−α
wt = At (1 − α) κα
t nt
Simplifying
(1 + r̂k,t ) = 1 + Ât (1 + (α − 1) κ̂t ) (1 + (1 − α) n̂t )
1 + r̂k,t = 1 + Ât + (α − 1) κ̂t + (1 − α) n̂t
r̂k,t = Ât + (α − 1) κ̂t + (1 − α) n̂t
Production function
From
1−α
yt = At κα
t nt
20
In the steady state
y = Aκα n1−α
Log-linearizing
y (1 + ŷt ) = A 1 + Ât κα (1 + ακ̂t ) n1−α (1 + (1 − α) n̂t )
Simplifying
(1 + ŷt ) = 1 + Ât (1 + ακ̂t ) (1 + (1 − α) n̂t )
1 + ŷt = 1 + Ât + ακ̂t + (1 − α) n̂t
ŷt = Ât + ακ̂t + (1 − α) n̂t
Feasibility
Market clearing conditions replace balance of payments equation. Feasibility
ct + xt = yt
In the steady state
c+x=y
Log-linearizing
c (1 + ĉt ) + x (1 + x̂t ) = y (1 + ŷt )
Simplifying
c x
ĉt + x̂t = ŷt
y y
Capital services
Since
κt = ut kt
in the steady state κ = uk and
Dynare
• Code
• IRF
• Moments
21
Impulse Response Function of a positive technology shock
0.01 0.03
4
0.008
0.02
0.006 3
0.01
0.004
2
0.002 0
0 1 -0.01
0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40
6 6 4
4 4 2
2 2 0
0 0 -2
0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40
1 -5 0
0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40
Model data t
US data Standard RBC Capacity Utilization
st.dev. corr(·,y) st.dev. corr(·,y) st.dev. corr(·,y)
• Similar volatility for the lower value of the standard deviations of technological innovations.
Summary
• We raised two (of number of ) issues:
22
labor elasticity
• We showed that with some modications to the original model those issues can be resolved.
• In each case:
we dene equilibrium
we compute FOCs
we simulate the moments to compare against data (evaluate model data t).
23