Chapter 8 - Economic Development
Chapter 8 - Economic Development
Development
Jennifer V. Lu
Jennica C. Maquilang
Health and education are important objectives of development. Health is central to well-being,
and education is essential for a satisfying and rewarding life. Education plays a key role in the
ability of a developing country to absorb modern technology and to develop the capacity for self-
sustaining growth and development. Moreover, health is a prerequisite for increases in
productivity, and successful education relies on adequate health as well.
Health and education are also important components of growth and development – inputs in the
aggregate production function. Their dual role as inputs and outputs gives health and education
their central importance in economic development.
There has been a very dramatic improvements in world health and education over past half
century. First is the child mortality. During 1950, child mortality was 280 per 1000 births in
developing world. In 2002, it was 120/1000 in low-income countries and 37/1000 in middle -
income countries. Second, major childhood illnesses are largely controlled. These include rubella
and polio through the use of vaccines. And lastly, the significant improvement in literacy rates
and basic education to majority of people in developing countries.
Despite these achievements, the developing world still faces challenges in improving health and
education of its people. The distribution of health and education within countries is as important
as income distribution.
So in this chapter, we will examine the roles of education and health in economic development
and how these two human capital issues are treated together because of their close relationship.
Greater health capital may improve the returns to investments in education because health is an
important factor in school attendance. Also, healthier students tend to learn more effectively. A
longer life raises the rate of return to education. Thus, healthier people have lower depreciation
of education capital.
On the other hand, greater education capital may improve the returns to investments in health.
These include public health programs need knowledge learned in school since many health
programs rely on basic skills often learned at school, including personal hygiene and sanitation,
not to mention basic literacy and numeracy which are taught in school. Education is needed for
the training of health personnel. Education also leads to delayed childbearing, which improves
health.
8.1 Improving Health and Education: Why Increasing Incomes Is Not Sufficient
Health and education much higher in high-income countries. Causality might runs in both
directions:
– With higher income, people and governments can afford to spend more on education and
health
– With greater health and education, higher productivity and income are possible.
Because of these relationship, development policy needs to focus on income, health, and
education simultaneously which is parallel on the conclusion in chapter 5. Evidence shows
clearly that increases in income often do not lead to substantial increases in investment in
children’s education and health. There is a low estimated income elasticity of demand for
calories for low income households. Policies to increase income of poor w/o focus on how they
are spent may not lead to improved health, and successful development more generally. This is
due to two factors: (1) Income is spent on other goods besides food. (2) Part of the increased
food expenditures is used to increase food variety without necessarily increasing the
consumption of calories. There is a considerable evidence that the better educated mothers tend
to have healthier children at any income level. There are still opportunities for improving health
through simple activities in school that have not been utilized.
Better health status and nutrition affects school performance. It leads to earlier and longer school
enrollment, better school attendance, and more effective learning. To improve effectiveness of
schooling and enrollments, health of children should be improve in developing countries.
Significant market failures in education and health require policy action such as:
– Spillover benefits to investment in one’s health or education
– Cannot count on market to deliver socially efficient levels of health and education
WHO (2000) concluded in its 2000 World Health Report that ultimate responsibility for the
performance of a country’s health system lies with government.
8.2 Investing in Education and Health: The Human Capital Approach
The analysis of investments in health and education is unified in the human capital approach.
Human capital is the term economists often use for education, health, and other human
capacities that can raise productivity when increased. The impact of human capital investments
in developing countries can be quite substantial.
The illustration shows the age-earnings profiles by levels of education in Venezuela. The chart
shows how incomes vary over the life cycle for people with various levels of education.
Child labor is a widespread phenomenon. The problem may be modeled using the
“multiple equilibria” approach. Sometimes this shift can be self-enforcing, so active intervention
is only needed at first. Assumptions of the Child Labor Multiple Equilibria Model:
• Luxury Axiom: A household with sufficiently high income would not send its children to work
• Substitution Axiom: Adult and child labor are substitutes, in which the quantity of output by a
child is a given fraction of that of an adult: QC =γQA, 0<γ<1.
Child Labor as a Bad Equilibrium
To summarize, as long as the wage is above wH, the supply curve is along AA′; if the wage is
below wL, the supply curve is along TT′, and in between, it follows the S-shaped curve between
the two vertical lines.
• Get more children into school (as in Millennium Development Goals), e.g. new village schools;
and enrollment incentives for parents such as in PROGRESA
• Consider child labor an expression of poverty, so emphasize ending poverty generally (a
traditional World Bank approach)
• If child labor is inevitable in the short run, regulate it to prevent abuse and provide support
services for working children (UNICEF approach)
• Ban child labor; or if impossible, ban child labor in its most abusive forms (ILO strategy;
“Worst Forms of Child Labor Convention”)
• Activist approach: trade sanctions. Concerns: could backfire when children shift to informal
sector; and if export sector growth slows
8.4 The Gender Gap: Discrimination in Education and Health
Closing the educational gender gap by expanding educational opportunities for women, a key
plank of the Millennium Development Goals, is economically desirable for at least three reasons:
1. The rate of return on women’s education is higher than that on men’s in most developing
countries. [This may partly reflect that, with fewer girls enrolled, the next (marginal) girl
to enroll is likely to be more talented on average than the marginal boy.]
2. Increasing women’s education not only increases their productivity (and hence also
earnings) in the workplace but also results in greater labor force participation, later
marriage, lower fertility, and greatly improved child health and nutrition, thus benefiting
the next generation as well. The latter is because a mother’s education directly increases
knowledge that can help child survival, nutrition, education, and indirectly by making
possible higher earnings for the family—noting in particular that mothers generally spend
a somewhat larger fraction of an additional dollar on their children than do fathers.
3. Because women carry a disproportionate burden of poverty, any significant
improvements in their role and status via education can have an important impact on
breaking the vicious circles of poverty and inadequate schooling.
The Political Economy of Educational Supply and Demand: The Relationship between
Employment Opportunities and Educational Demands
On the demand side, the two principal influences on the amount of schooling desired are
(1) a more educated student’s prospects of earning considerably more income through future
modern-sector employment (the family’s private benefits of education).
(2) the educational costs, both direct and indirect, that a student or family must bear. The amount
of education demanded is thus in reality a derived demand for high-wage employment
opportunities in the modern sector. This is because access to such jobs is largely determined
by an individual’s education.
On the supply side, the quantity of school places at the primary, secondary, and university levels
is determined largely by political processes, often unrelated to economic criteria. Given
mounting political pressure throughout the developing world for greater numbers of school
places at higher levels, we can for convenience assume that the public supply of these places is
fixed by the level of government educational expenditures. These are in turn influenced by the
level of aggregate private demand for education.
The amount of schooling demanded that is sufficient to qualify an individual for modern-sector
jobs appears to be related to or determined by the combined influence of four variables: (a) the
wage or income differential, (b) the probability of success in finding modern-sector employment,
the direct private costs of education, and the indirect or opportunity costs of education.
As employment opportunities diminish (for given level of education) demand for higher
education increases putting pressure on government to expand educational facilities at the higher
level..
– Widening gap between social and private costs at higher levels of education
• Stimulates even greater demand for higher education.
– More resources misallocated to educational expansion (in terms of social costs) means
diminished potential for creating new jobs.
– Provide education up to where marginal social costs equal marginal social returns
• Basic education? Secondary education?
– Devote resources for expanding education system to rural public works or on increasing quality
of basic education in rural areas.
C. Distribution of Education
Unequal distribution of education in developing countries. Just as we can derive Lorenz curves
for distribution of income (see Chapter 5), we can also develop Lorenz curves for the distribution
of education.
. The closer the Lorenz curve is to the 45-degree line, the more equal the distribution of
education.
As can be seen from the figure, South Korea had a much more equal distribution of education
than India.
– When quality (teaching, facilities, curricula, etc.) is considered, inequality much greater
– Quantity and quality differentials explains differential earnings and productivity (Behrman and
Birdsall, 1983).
8.6 Health Measurement and Disease Burden
The World Health Organization (WHO), the key UN agency concerned with global health
matters, defines health as “a state of complete physical, mental, and social well-being and not
merely the absence of disease and infirmity.” An alternative measure of health promoted by the
WHO is the disability-adjusted life year (DALY).
In 2012, nearly 7 million children under the age of 5 died in developing countries. This means
that under-5 child deaths accounted for about 12% of all deaths worldwide. Because most of
these children died of causes that could be prevented at very low cost per child, it has been
rightly claimed that their real underlying disease is poverty.
HIV/AIDS
Human immunodeficiency virus (HIV) - The virus that causes the acquired immunodeficiency
syndrome (AIDS).
The AIDS epidemic has been threatening to halt or even reverse years of hard-won
human and economic development progress in numerous countries. Close to 70 million people
have been infected with the HIV virus; and about half of them—about 35 million people—have
already died of AIDS.
In Figure 8.11a, we see that there has been a global fall in numbers of people newly infected with
HIV, beginning around the late 1990s.
In Figure 8.11b, we see that globally, the number of people living with HIV began leveling off
around the turn of the century. In part, this corresponded to some infected people dying.
Now in the last few years, globally the number of adult and child deaths due to AIDS has been
actually falling, as seen in Figure 8.11c.
In sub-Saharan Africa, known as the epicenter of the disease with the highest overall HIV
prevalence, the number of people becoming newly infected with HIV fell from 2.4 million to 1.8
million.
MALARIA
Malaria directly causes over 1 million deaths each year, most of them among impoverished
African children. Severe cases of malaria leave about 15% of the children who survive the
disease with substantial neurological problems and learning disabilities.
The WHO’s Roll Back Malaria Partnership seeks to eradicate this disease at its source.
Eradication has been most successful where campaigns have combined better targeted DDT
spraying and draining swamps where malarial mosquitoes are breeding with using mosquito bed
nets, improving nutrition to build resistance, and sealing houses against mosquito entry.
The incidence of debilitating parasitic worms has been vast with some 2 billion people
affected—300 million severely. According to WHO estimates, the disease infects about 200
million people in 74 developing countries, of whom about 120 million are symptomatic and
some 20 million suffer severe consequences, including about 200,000 deaths each year.
Table 8.3 shows the 13 major neglected tropical diseases, ranked by their global prevalence
(number infected).
Productivity
Poor health conditions in developing countries affects the productivity of the adults. Studies
show that healthier people earn higher wages. Careful statistical methods have shown that a large
part of the effect of health on raising earnings is due to productivity differences: It is not just the
reverse causality that higher wages are used in part to purchase better health.
John Strauss and Duncan Thomas found that taller men earn more money in Brazil, even after
controlling for other important determinants of income such as education and experience (Figure
8.12, panels A1 and A2).
In particular, taller people receive significantly more education than shorter people (see Figure
8.12, panels B1 and B2).
Health Systems - All the activities whose primary purpose is to promote, restore, or maintain
health.
Health systems include the components of public health departments, hospitals and clinics, and
offices of doctors and paramedics. Outside this formal system is an informal network used by
many poorer citizens, which includes traditional healers.
Five performance indicators to measure health systems in the 191 WHO member states:
An effective government role in health systems is crucial for at least four important reasons.
First, health is central to poverty alleviation, because people are often uninformed about
health, a situation compounded by poverty. Second, households spend too little on health
because they may neglect externalities (such as, literally, contagion problems). Third, the market
would invest too little in health infrastructure and research and development and technology
transfer to developing countries due to market failures. Fourth, public health programs in
developing countries have many proven successes.
Broad Findings
We conclude that health and education play pivotal roles in economic development, as both
inputs into production enabling higher incomes and outputs directly affecting human well-being.
Many health and education problems plague developing countries, ranging from child labor to
heavy disease burdens. Moreover, the wrong kinds of government policies have sometimes led to
distortions in the educational system that have reinforced inequality; and inequities in health
systems are common. Thus, government plays an essential role in health and education, and in
most developing countries, considerable improvements in policy are needed.
Case Study
The Mexican Program on Education, Health, and Nutrition is widely known by its Spanish
acronym, Progresa, though officially renamed the Oportunidades Human Development Program.
Progresa/Oportunidades
- combats child labor, poor education, and health by ensuring that parents can feed their
children, take them to health clinics, and keep them in school while providing financial
incentives to do so.
- builds on the growing understanding that health, nutrition, and education are
complements in the struggle to end poverty.
- features the promotion of an integrated package to promote the education, health, and
nutritional status of poor families. It provides cash transfers to poor families, family
clinic visits, in-kind nutritional supplements, and other health benefits for pregnant and
lactating women and their children under the age of 5.
- low-income parents are paid to send their children to school and clinics: effective in
sustainably reducing poverty.
- an innovative developing-country- designed integrated poverty program. Its major
architect was Santiago Levy, a development economist who led the design and
implementation of the program in the 1990s while serving as deputy minister of finance.
- affects child nutrition through four program components, called pathways:
1. Cash transfers - which may be used in part for improved nutrition;
2. Nutritional supplements given to all participating children under the age of 2,
pregnant and breastfeeding mothers, and children between the ages of 2 and 5
who show signs of malnutrition;
3. Growth monitoring - which provides feedback to parents; and
4. Other preventive measures - including required participation in regular meetings
where vital information about hygiene and nutrition is taught.
Participating families receive school program payments every other month.
Evaluations of Progresa/Oportunidades indicate that its integrated approach has been highly
successful, with large improvements in the wellbeing of participants. Malnutrition has
measurably declined; family use of health care, including prenatal care, has increased, and
child health indicators have improved; school attendance is up significantly, and the dropout
rate has declined substantially, especially in the so-called transition grades six through nine,
when children either get launched toward high school or drop out.
In conclusion, CCT programs focusing on improving health, nutrition, and education are a
key component of a successful policy to end poverty— although in most cases, they will
need to be part of a broader strategy to be fully effective.