0% found this document useful (0 votes)
139 views

CH 08

This document summarizes key concepts around international trade policy and tariffs from Chapter 8 of an International Economics textbook. It discusses partial and general equilibrium analysis of tariffs, the theory of tariff structure including effective rates of protection, the Stolper-Samuelson theorem on factor prices, and the concept of an optimal tariff for large countries to influence terms of trade. Tariffs can benefit domestic producers but reduce overall national welfare through deadweight losses.

Uploaded by

Riuben
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as DOCX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
139 views

CH 08

This document summarizes key concepts around international trade policy and tariffs from Chapter 8 of an International Economics textbook. It discusses partial and general equilibrium analysis of tariffs, the theory of tariff structure including effective rates of protection, the Stolper-Samuelson theorem on factor prices, and the concept of an optimal tariff for large countries to influence terms of trade. Tariffs can benefit domestic producers but reduce overall national welfare through deadweight losses.

Uploaded by

Riuben
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as DOCX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 10

Part Two: International Trade Policy

Chapter 8
Trade Restrictions: Tariffs
“To prohibit by a perpetual law the importation of foreign corn and cattle, is in reality to
enact, that the population and industry of the country shall at no time exceed what the
rude produce of its own soil can maintain.”
Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations, Book IV, Chapter II.

I. Chapter Outline

8.1 Introduction
8.2 Partial Equilibrium Analysis of a Tariff
8.2a Partial Equilibrium Effects of a Tariff
8.2b Effect of a Tariff on Consumer and Producer Surplus
8.2c Costs and Benefits of a Tariff
8.3 The Theory of Tariff Structure
8.3a The Rate of Effective Protection
8.3b Generalization and Evaluation of the Theory of Effective Protection
8.4 General Equilibrium Analysis of a Tariff in a Small Country
8.4a General Equilibrium Effects of a Tariff in a Small Country
8.4b Illustration of the Effects of a Tariff in a Small Country
8.4c The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem
8.5 General Equilibrium Analysis of a Tariff in a Large Country
8.5a General Equilibrium Effects of a Tariff in a Large Country
8.6b Illustration of the Effects of a Tariff in a Large Country
8.6 The Optimum Tariff
8.6a The Meaning of the Concept of Optimum Tariff and Retaliation
8.6b Illustration of the Optimum Tariff and Retaliation

II. Chapter Summary and Review

A tariff is one form of commercial policy, also known as trade policy, which
has been used by nations to influence international commerce. A tariff is simply a
tax on imports (import tariff) or exports (export tariff), although in the United
States, export taxes are unconstitutional. Tariffs, like any tax, can be ad valorem
69
International Economics, Twelfth Edition Study Guide

(a fixed percentage of the value traded), specific (a given dollar amount per unit
traded), or compound (a combination of ad valorem and specific tariffs).

Economists generally view import tariffs as harmful to the overall welfare


of a nation. The popular appeal of tariffs is due to the benefits they confer on
special interest groups within the nation imposing the tariff. Very simply, a net
buyer of a product is hurt by an increase in prices because purchases of the
product exceed production of the product. An importing nation is a net buyer
(buying more domestically than it is domestically producing) from the rest of the
world, so a tariff that raises the price of goods may produce gains to sellers, but
those gains are exceeded by the losses to buyers.

The Stolper-Samuelson theorem states that as the price of a good or


service increases, the real return to the factor that is used intensively in the
production of that good or service increases. A tariff on the imports of a good will
increase the price of the good, so for a nation that imports labor-intensive goods,
the Stolper-Samuelson theorem states that a tariff on the labor-intensive imports
will increase the real wages earned by labor. Consequently, although a tariff
reduces national welfare, labor would gain at the expense of greater losses for
the rest of society.

The conclusion that a tariff hurts national welfare assumes that a nation is
too small to affect world prices (the terms of trade). If, however, a nation is a
large buyer of goods from other countries, where "large" means the ability to
affect world prices (the terms of trade), then import tariffs could provide some
benefits. A nation imposing a tariff reduces its imports (demand for foreign
products), which for a large importer, will lead to a reduction in the prices
charged for the imports by foreign producers. The import tariff, by reducing the
price of imports, shifts some of the burden of the import tariff onto the foreign
producer. Foreign producers pay part of the tariff by being forced to accept lower
prices for the products they export to the nation imposing the import tariff.
Domestic consumers will still face higher total prices due to the import tariff, but
the shifting of import taxes to foreign producers in the form of lower prices may
more than offset these losses.

If a nation can affect the terms of trade through import tariffs, it does not
follow that import tariffs should always be higher. If a tariff is too high it will
prohibit all imports (a prohibitive tariff) so no import taxes can be shifted to
foreign producers. There is, therefore, an optimum tariff for a large nation
somewhere between zero and a prohibitively large tariff. Nevertheless, even if a

70
Chapter 8 / Trade Restrictions: Tariffs

large country can estimate the optimum import tariff, there is still a risk in
imposing a tariff on other nations. The danger is that trading partners will retaliate
by imposing their own tariffs, which further reduces the overall volume of trade
and makes both countries worse off. Also note that even if the optimum tariff can
be successfully applied, the tariff is optimum only for the country that imposes the
tariff. From a global perspective, the tariff is sub-optimal because some
production has been shifted by the tariff from low-cost producers to high-cost
producers. A tariff produces a sub-optimal allocation of resources, so the gains to
the nation imposing the optimum tariff are more than offset by the losses to the
rest of the world.

If a nation imposes a tariff either for reasons associated with the optimum
tariff argument and/or due to pressure from special interest groups, it is important
to distinguish between the nominal tariff and the rate of effective protection. If
a nation imposes a 10% tax on an imported finished good, then the nominal tariff
is 10%. If, however, an input in the production of a good also bears an import
tariff, then the import tariff on the input is indirectly a tax on domestic producers
because they face higher production costs directly due to the import tariff on the
input. Thus, the nominal tariff of 10% on the imported finished good may not
indicate the degree to which the domestic industry is "effectively protected" by
import tariffs. A measure of domestic economic activity that includes both outputs
and inputs is domestic value added. Domestic value added is the difference
between the value of the finished good and the value of imported inputs. By
calculating the effect of tariffs on domestic valued added, in percent terms, both
the effect of the tariff on the finished good and the effect of the tariff on the
imported input are considered. This percent change in domestic value added due
to tariffs on the good and its inputs is a measure of the effective rate of
protection. If high tariffs are imposed on imported inputs and low tariffs imposed
on finished goods, then domestic value added may actually be reduced as a
result of this structure of tariffs.

III. Questions

1. Fig. 8.1 shows the effect of an import tariff.

a) Is the tariff shown in Fig. 8.1 an ad valorem tariff or a specific tariff?

b) What is the dollar amount of the tariff per unit?

71
International Economics, Twelfth Edition Study Guide

c) Is the analysis in Fig. 8.1 partial equilibrium analysis or general equilibrium


analysis?

d) According to Fig. 8.1, how does the tariff affect the world price of good X?

Figure 8.1
PX

SX

$12
b d
$10

DX
X
80 100 130 140

e) By how much does the tariff affect the price to consumers in the importing
country?

f) After all adjustments, what happens to the price of domestic production of good
X as a result of the import tariff?

g) Is the demand curve in Fig. 8.1 the demand by domestics or the demand for
domestic products?

2. Using the numbers given in Fig. 8.1, indicate the following:

a) Consumption effect of the tariff

b) Production effect of the tariff

c) Trade effect of the tariff

d) Revenue effect of the tariff

3. Continue to use the numbers given in Fig. 8.1 to answer the following

72
Chapter 8 / Trade Restrictions: Tariffs

questions:

a) What is the dollar value of the welfare cost (loss in consumer surplus) of the
tariff to consumers?

b) What is the dollar value of the welfare benefit (gain in producer surplus) of
the tariff to producers?

c) What is the dollar value of the total benefits of the tariff? What is the dollar
value of the total costs of the tariff?

d) Subtract the total dollar costs you found in part c of this question from the total
dollar benefits you found in part c of this question in order to get the total net
benefit of the tariff. How does this total net benefit compare to the deadweight
loss shown as areas b and d in Fig. 8.1?

e) Directly calculate the size of areas b and d in Fig. 8.1 to verify your answer to
part d of this question.

4. Determine the size of the nominal tariff relative to the effective rate of
protection under the following conditions:

a) There are no imported inputs and the tariff on a finished good is 10%

b) A country imposes a 10% tariff on all finished goods and inputs, and imports
50% of the inputs it uses in the production of a finished good

c) A country imposes a 10% tariff on finished goods, a 20% tariff on inputs, and
imports 50% of the inputs it uses in the production of a finished good

d) The tariffs on finished goods and inputs are as in part c of this question, but
imported inputs make up 70% of the inputs used in the production of a finished
good

5. The general equilibrium effects of a tariff for Country A are shown in Fig. 8.2.

a) What is the relative price of good X before the imposition of a tariff on good X?

73
International Economics, Twelfth Edition Study Guide

b) What is the relative price of Good X for domestic consumers and producers
after the imposition of a tariff on good X?

c) From a national perspective, what is the relative price of Good X after the
imposition of the tariff?

Figure 8.2
Y

d e
c
II
P1
P1 ’
P2 P2 ’ I
X

d) After the imposition of the tariff, what is the quantity of good X imported and
the quantity of good Y exported?

e) Using the letters along the trade triangle bce, how much is collected in tariff
revenues?

f) Why does consumption end up along price line P2' rather than along P2?

g) Why must consumption occur at the intersection of lines P1' and P2'?

h) What is the net effect of the tariff on the welfare of country A?

6. Assume that Country A from Question 5 is labor rich and Good X is capital
intensive. The market for capital and labor in Country A is shown in Fig. 8.3. The
given endowments of capital and labor for Country A are indicated by vertical
supply curves, and the demand curves have the usual shape. The equilibrium
return to capital is r1, and the equilibrium return to labor is w1. Both returns in Fig.
8.3 are measured nominally.

a) What will happen to the nominal return to capital as a result of the tariff on

74
Chapter 8 / Trade Restrictions: Tariffs

Good X in country A?

b) What will happen to the nominal wage rate as a result of the tariff on Good X
in Country A?

Figure 8.3

r w
SK SL

w1
r1

DL
DK
K L

c) The tariff on Good X will increase the price of Good X for residents of Country
A. Assume that the price of Good Y is unchanged as a result of the tariff. In part
b of this question, you should have found that the nominal return to labor
decreases. What must happen to the real wage rate in Country A? (Hint: Labor
spends income on goods X and Y; the price of X increases and the price of Y is
unchanged.)

d) In part a of this question, you should have found that the nominal return to
capital increases. If the price of Good X increases, then the average cost of
production of Good X increases by the same amount. (Price equals average cost
in long-run equilibrium in competitive markets.) If the cost of labor (the nominal
wage rate) decreases, then the cost of capital (the nominal return to capital) must
increase by more than the average cost of production. What does this imply
happens to the real return earned by capitalists in Country A? (Hint: The nominal
return to capital goes up by more than the price of Good X, and the price of Good
Y is unchanged.)

e) Are your answers to parts c and d of this question consistent with the Stolper-
Samuleson Theorem?

f) In questions c and d you should have found that the real wage rate decreases
and the real return to capital increases as a result of the tariff on Good X. Which

75
International Economics, Twelfth Edition Study Guide

change has a larger effect on income? (Hint: What effect does a tariff have on
national income?)

7. a) What happens to the offer curve of Nation 1 in Fig. 8.4 if it imposes a tariff
on imports?

Figure 8.4
Nation 1 Pw (PX/PY)
Y
Nation 2

b) What will happen to the price of X relative to the price of Y as a result of


Nation 1 imposing a tariff on imports?

c) What will be the net effect on the price of X relative to the price of Y if an
import tariff by Nation 1 leads to Nation 2 imposing an import tariff of similar size?

8. a) In Fig. 8.5, explain why Country 2 must be a large country.

Figure 8.5
P1
Pw (PX/PY)
Y 1
G 2
Pw’

A D B
K 2’

0 X
L H

76
Chapter 8 / Trade Restrictions: Tariffs

b) If Country 2 were a small country, how would Fig. 8.5 differ?

c) Fig. 8.5 shows the pre- and post-tariff equilibrium for a large country. The pre-
tariff price is Pw, which is expressed as Px/Py, as you are reminded by the
parentheses in Fig. 8.5. Which good and how much of the good is exported by
Country 2 prior to the tariff? Which good and how much of the good is imported
by Country 2 prior to the tariff?

d) Explain why the offer curve of Country 2 shifts down (from 2 to 2') as a result
of the tariff.

e) Measured at the post-tariff equilibrium, what is the amount of tariff revenues


collected in kind (“in kind” means measured in the quantity of the import good)?
Measured at the post-tariff equilibrium, what is the tariff rate? (The tariff rate is
the tariff as a fraction of the imports received by consumers.)

f) What price do domestic producers and consumers face as result of the tariff?
Indicate whether the tariff has increased or decreased P x/Py for domestic
producers and consumers.

g) Prior to the tariff, if Country 2 exported OK units of Good Y, how much of Good
X could be imported?

h) After the tariff, if Country 2 exported OK units of Good Y, how much of Good X
can be imported if tariff revenues purchase Good X? (This is equivalent to the
assumption that tariff revenues are distributed to members of the private sector,
who use them to buy Good X.)

i) Comparing your answer to g and h, has the tariff made the terms of trade less
or more favorable to Country 2?

j) Is the post-tariff equilibrium necessarily superior or necessarily inferior to the


pre-tariff equilibrium for Country 2?

k) Is the post-tariff equilibrium necessarily superior or necessarily inferior to the


pre-tariff equilibrium for Country 1?

l) What does your answer to part k of this question suggest will be Country 1's
response to the imposition of a tariff by Country 2?

77
International Economics, Twelfth Edition Study Guide

9. Table 1 gives the effect of a tariff on cotton sweaters. (Assume there is no


difference between domestically produced sweaters and foreign-produced
sweaters.)
Table 1
Free Trade With a $4.00
Tariff
World Price of sweaters $42.00 $42.00
Tariff per sweater 0 $4.00
Domestic Price of sweaters $42.00 $46.00
Sweaters consumed domestically (million 60 52
sweaters/year) 12 18
Sweaters produced domestically (million sweaters/year) 48 34
Sweaters imported (million packs/year

a) Using partial equilibrium analysis, estimate the amount domestic consumers


lose from the tariff (give a dollar number).

b) Estimate the net effect on the country's welfare as a result of the tariff (give a
dollar number).

c) Based on the information given in Table 1, would the optimum import tariff on
sweaters be negative, zero, or positive? Why?

78

You might also like