Barton, Simko, 2002
Barton, Simko, 2002
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.
Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aaasoc.
Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
American Accounting Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
Accounting Review.
http://www.jstor.org
THEACCOUNTING REVIEW
Vol. 77
2002
Supplement
pp. 1-27
I. INTRODUCTION
W x e examine the extent to which GenerallyAcceptedAccountingPrinciples
(GAAP)andtheirimplementation guidelinesconstrainmanagersfromoptimis-
ticallybiasingearnings.Becausethe balancesheet accumulatesthe effectsof
previous accountingchoices, the level of net assets partly reflects the extent of previous
earnings management.We predict that managers'ability to optimisticallybias earnings
decreases with the extent to which net assets are already overstated on the balance
sheet.' To test our prediction, we focus on a particularlystrong earnings management
We use the term "overstated" to describe net assets measured and recorded at values exceeding those that would
have been reported under a neutral application of GAAP, without implying a violation of GAAP.
We appreciate the helpful comments of Katherine Schipper (the editor), an anonymous referee, Linda Bamber,
George Benston, Walt Blacconiere, Paul Irvine, Connie Kertz, Steven Schmitt, Greg Waymire, and seminar partic-
ipants at The University of Alabama, University of Arkansas, Emory University, Georgia State University, Indiana
University, University of Virginia, The Accounting Review Conference on Quality of Earnings, and The University
of Texas at Austin's 2002 BMAS Conference. We also thank Ron Harris and Xiao Lan Wang for research assistance,
the Goizueta Business School for generous funding, and I/B/E/S International Inc. for access to data on analysts'
earnings forecasts.
1
2 The AccountingReview, 2002 Supplement
2
Departing from GAAP may result in substantial costs to managers and their firms (Dechow et al. 1996).
For example, Compaq Computer, Hewlett-Packard, Merck, Sears, Starbucks, and UAL all missed their consensus
analyst forecasts by 1? per share at least once during 1993-1999, and suffered an average size-adjusted cumulative
abnormal return of about -12 percent over the three days surrounding their earnings announcements.
Bartonand Simko-Earnings ManagementConstraint 3
beginning balances of net operating assets relative to sales are less likely to report a pre-
determined earnings surprise. These findings are robust to using alternative econometric
techniques, separating net operating assets into their current and long-term components,
controlling for industry and fiscal-quarter effects, using alternative definitions of earning
surprises, and excluding loss firms or firms reporting special items.
Our paper extends research on earnings management in three ways. First, while we do
not measure directly the amount of financial reporting discretion actually available to man-
agers, our approach provides a basis for doing so in future research. Second, prior research
examines how managers trade off financial reporting discretion available across several
balance sheet accounts when meeting various objectives (e.g., Beatty et al. 1995; Hunt et
al. 1996; Gaver and Paterson 1999). We extend this literature by providing evidence that
the balance sheet accumulates the effects of prior optimism in financial reporting, reducing
managers' ability to optimistically bias future earnings. Therefore, consistent with Hunt et
al. (1996), our findings suggest that managers likely trade off available financial reporting
discretion over time. Last, prior research provides evidence that managing earnings to meet
expectations is widespread (Degeorge et al. 1999; Payne and Robb 2000; Abarbanell and
Lehavy 2001la; Burgstahler and Eames 2001; Matsumoto 2002), but assumes that the ability
to manage earnings is random or even constant across firms. Our results suggest that the
ability to report a predetermined earnings surprise varies across firms as a function of
previous optimism in financial reporting.
Section II develops our main hypothesis. Section III describes our research design.
Specifically, this section explains the sample selection criteria, reports the frequencies and
market reactions associated with various levels of earnings surprise, describes the charac-
teristics of sample firms, discusses our proxy for overstated net asset values, and develops
our regression model. Section IV describes our main empirical results and sensitivity tests.
Finally, Section V offers some concluding remarks.
II. HYPOTHESIS
The accruals basis of accounting requires managers to report the effects of economic
transactions based on expected cash realizations (SFAC No. 1, FASB 1978; SFAC No. 6,
FASB 1985). Although GAAP requires managers to make numerous judgments and as-
sumptions to report their firms' performance under accrual accounting, managers do not
have unlimited discretion in doing so. For example, accounting regulators like the Securities
and Exchange Commission and the Financial Accounting Standards Board, along with
professional groups like the American Institute of Certified Public Accountants, provide
detailed guidelines for implementing measurement, recognition, and disclosure rules. Au-
ditors and the courts help enforce these guidelines.
Because of the reversing nature of accrual accounting, managers' biased estimates and
judgments in one period reduce their ability to make similarly biased estimates and judg-
ments in subsequent periods (Hunt et al. 1996; Abarbanell and Lehavy 2001a). The artic-
ulation between the income statement and the balance sheet ensures that biased assumptions
reflected in earnings are also reflected in net asset values. Therefore, we predict that man-
agers' ability to optimistically bias earnings decreases with the extent to which net assets
are already overstated on the balance sheet, relative to what their values would have been
under a neutral implementation of GAAP.
Prior research shows that overstated assets and revenues are the most common reason
for restatements of financial statements (Palmrose et al. 2001), Securities and Exchange
Commission's accounting enforcement actions (Feroz et al. 1991; Dechow et al. 1996), and
lawsuits against auditors (St. Pierre and Anderson 1984; Lys and Watts 1994). Prior research
4 The AccountingReview, 2002 Supplement
also shows that managers may understate assets temporarily to regain the ability to opti-
misticallybias earningsin futureperiods (Moehrle2002).
Managershave various incentives to bias earnings (see Fields et al. 2001). However,
we focus on one particularlystrongincentive-meeting or beating analysts'earningsfore-
casts. Dechow and Skinner (2000) argue that the bull marketof the late 1990s and the
increaseduse of stock options for managerialcompensationhave increasedmanagers'in-
centives to manipulate earnings to preserve high stock valuations. Consistent with this
argument, Barth et al. (1999) provide evidence that firms with patterns of increasing earn-
ings have higher price-to-earningsratios, and that these ratios decline significantlywhen
firmsbreakthe patternby reportingearningsdecreases.Moreover,Skinnerand Sloan (2001)
report significant negative returns for firms that fail to meet analysts' earnings forecasts.
Finally,evidence also suggests widespreadearningsmanagementto meet or beat analysts'
forecasts (e.g., Payne and Robb 2000; Burgstahler and Eames 2001; Matsumoto 2002).
Based on these findings, we predict that managers will use available financial reporting
discretion to report higher levels of earnings surprises, all else equal. Therefore, we test
the following hypothesis:
Ha: The likelihood of reporting larger positive or smaller negative earnings surprises
decreases with the extent to which net assets are already overstated on the balance
sheet.
TABLE 1
Characteristics of Quarterly Earnings Surprises
TABLE 1 (Continued)
Panel C: Mean Three-Day Cumulative Abnormal Return (CAR) around Quarterly Earnings
Announcement Datea
t-Statistic for
SURPRISE n CAR Ho: CAR = 0 CAR / SURPRISE
Panel B of Table 1 shows that the frequency of firms beating earnings expectations
increased over the sample period, consistent with findings reported in Brown (2001) and
Matsumoto (2002). A Pearson x2 test (not tabulated) rejects the null of no association
between SURPRISE and fiscal year (X2(6odf = 583.73, p < 0.01).
Panel C of Table 1, which presents mean three-day cumulative abnormal returns (CAR)
around the earnings announcement date across levels of SURPRISE, confirms the well-
known positive association between CARs and earnings surprises.4 The mean CAR for
where TOT_ACC is total accruals (i.e., earnings before extraordinary items and discontin-
ued operations less operating cash flows); TA is total assets; AREV is the quarterly change
in revenues; AREC is the quarterly change in accounts receivable; PPE is gross property,
plant, and equipment; and Ql, Q2, Q3, and Q4 are fiscal-quarter indicators. The (AREV
- AREC) term controls for normal working capital accruals related to sales, the PPE term
TABLE 2
Descriptive Statistics for Selected Firm Characteristics and Rank Correlations with Ea
Standard First
Firm Characteristic Mean Deviation Quartile Median
Market value of
commonequity ($) 2,311.9 6,267.0 161.7 459.0
Totalassets ($) 1,811.8 4,397.9 129.1 371.1
Sales ($) 470.9 1,028.1 37.5 111.9
Traded on NASDAQ (%) 44.1 49.7 0.0 0.0
Ratio of fixed assets to total assets (%) 32.5 22.4 14.9 26.5
Ratio of total debt to total assets (%) 61.7 111.9 5.2 38.2
Net income ($) 24.5 78.9 0.8 4.5
controls for normal depreciation and related deferred tax accruals, the TA deflator controls
for scale, and the fiscal-quarterindicatorscontrol for seasonality.
Equation(1) scales abnormalaccrualsby lagged TA, so we unscalethemby multiplying
the regression residuals by their corresponding lagged TA before accumulating them back-
ward in time. To avoid inducing a spurious correlation between prior cumulative (unscaled)
abnormal accruals and NOA, we rescale the cumulative abnormal accruals by sales for
quartert - 1, the same deflatorin NOA.
Table3 reportsmean levels of (rescaled)abnormalaccrualsaccumulatedover the prior
4, 8, 12, 16, and 20 quarters, across quintiles of adjusted NOA. Consistent with the esti-
mation of Equation (1), we adjust NOA only in this table by subtracting the mean NOA
in the same two-digit SIC code and fiscal year. The table shows that abnormal accruals
accumulated over up to 20 previous quarters are larger (at the 0.10 significance level or
better) for firms in the upper quintile of adjusted NOA than for firms in the lower quintile.
These results suggest that prior optimistic accounting choices are associated with larger
levels of net operatingassets relativeto sales.
Model
We consider two issues in developing a model to test Ha. First, recall that we define
SURPRISEas actualEPS less the consensusEPS forecast.Because we measureSURPRISE
in pennies, treatingit as an ordinalvariable,we use an estimationmodel specifically de-
signed for ordinaldependentvariables.Second, we suspect that the effects of the indepen-
dent variables vary across various earnings surprise benchmarks; for example, managers
may have less accounting discretion or weaker incentives to beat expectationsby 50 or
more than to beat expectationsby just 10. Our model thus allows the parametersof the
independentvariablesto vary across predeterminedearningssurprisebenchmarks.We in-
corporate both of these design choices using the following generalized ordered logit model,
derived in the Appendix:
where the left-hand-side expression is the odds of reporting an earnings surprise of at least
k0, a predetermined benchmark; SURPRISE is the signed EPS surprise; NOA is our proxy
for overstated net assets already on the balance sheet; CONTROLS is a vector of control
variables;Ps are parametersallowed to vary with k; and i and t denote firm and quarter.
For m categories in SURPRISE, Equation (2) yields m - 1 uniquely identified equations
that can be estimated jointly through maximum likelihood techniques.5 Thus, because we
coded SURPRISE using 11 categories (i.e., -5, -4, -3,..., 3, 4, 5), our empirical imple-
mentation of Equation (2) will yield a set of parameter estimates for each of ten uniquely
identified equations.
Ha predicts a negative association between SURPRISE and NOA. Therefore, we expect
the coefficients on NOA to be negative in all ten equations. For example, consider k = 0,
a zero earnings surprise. For k = 0, a negative coefficient P1,0on NOA implies that higher
values of NOA are associated with lower odds of a zero or positive earnings surprise.
Equation (2) also allows us to estimate how changes in the independent variables affect the
5 Forfurtherdetailson
generalizedorderedlogit modelsandtheirestimation,see Clogg andShihadeh(1994, 146-
147) and Fu (1998).
TABLE 3
Average Prior Cumulative Abnormal Accruals across Quintiles of Net Operating Assets
*** and * denotesignificantat the 0.01 and0.10 levels, respectively,based on one-tailedtests. The t-statisticsfor differencesin
arebasedon unequalvariancesacrossquintiles.
The initial sampleconsistsof 35,950 firm-quarters pertainingto 3,649 firmsincludedin both the Compustatand I/B/E/S dat
tests over 1993-1999, excludingutilitiesandfinancialservicesfirms(two-digitSIC codes 49 and60-67). Of these firm-quart
abnormalaccrualsover a particularaccumulationperiod.NOA is net operatingassets (i.e., shareholders'equityless cash and m
beginningof quartert, scaledby sales for quartert - 1. Consistentwith the estimationof Equation(1) below, we adjustNOA
NOA in the same two-digitSIC code and fiscal year.We estimateabnormalaccrualsfor firmi in quartert using the residualfr
two-digitSIC code and fiscal yearusing 1988-1999 data (see Jones 1991; Dechow et al. 1995; Han and Wang 1998):
TABLE 3 (Continued)
where:
The abnormalaccrualsfrom Equation(1) are implicitlyscaled by lagged TA, so we unscale them by multiplyingthe regress
TA beforeaccumulatingthembackwardin time. To avoidinducinga spuriouscorrelationbetweenpriorcumulativeabnormalacc
abnormalaccrualsby sales for quartert - 1, the same deflatorin NOA. The tabulatedamountsare mean levels of (rescaled
prior4, 8, 12, 16, and 20 quarters,acrossquintilesof adjustedNOA.
12 The AccountingReview, 2002 Supplement
odds of a given earnings surprise. For instance, an increase of 8 in NOA changes the odds
of meeting or beating expectationsby 100[exp(8 x B1,O)- 1] percent. We derive the
expressionfor the percentagechange in odds in the Appendix.6
The vector CONTROLS includes variables capturingother constraintson earnings
management, managerial incentives to meet or slightly beat forecasts, and firm performance
and size. We discuss these in turn.
One constrainton earningsmanagementis the numberof sharesoutstanding.Managers
of firmswith more sharesoutstandingmay find it more difficultto manageearningstoward
expectations, because a penny short in EPS translates into more dollars of actual earnings
for a firm with more shares outstanding than for a firm with fewer shares outstanding. To
capture this effect, we include the weighted average number of common shares outstanding
during quarter t (SHARES), the denominator of basic EPS, and expect its coefficients to
be negative.7
Anotherconstrainton earningsmanagementis auditquality.Firmswith Big 5 auditors
have lower levels of abnormal accruals (Becker et al. 1998; Payne and Robb 2000). How-
ever, Libby and Kinney (2000) find that few Big 5 auditors expect a client to correct
otherwise quantitatively immaterial income-increasing misstatements if such corrections
would result in the client missing earnings forecasts. Therefore, we include an indicator
variablecoded 1 (0 otherwise)if the firmhas a Big 5 auditor(BIG5) in quartert, but make
no predictionaboutthe sign of its coefficients.
Managersare more likely to reportearningsthatmeet or beat expectationsif they have
strong incentives to do so-when their firms have a high price-to-book ratio (Skinner and
Sloan 2001), high litigation risk (Soffer et al. 2000; Matsumoto 2002), a large analyst
following (Johnson 1999), or a previous pattern of meeting or beating expectations.8 We
measure the price-to-book ratio (PB) as the market value of common equity divided by the
book value of shareholders'equity,both at the end of quartert. We measurelitigationrisk
(LTGN-RISK) as an indicatorvariablecoded 1 (0 otherwise)if the firm is in one of four
industries identified in prior research (e.g., Francis et al. 1994; Ali and Kallapur 2001) as
most susceptible to securities litigation-pharmaceuticals/biotechnology (SIC codes 2833-
2836, 8731-8734), computers (3570-3577, 7370-7374), electronics (3600-3674), and re-
tail (5200-5961). We measure analyst following (ANALYSTS) as the number of analysts
in the I/B/E/S consensusEPS forecastfor quartert. Last, we measurethe previousearnings
surprise pattern (PREV_MB) as an indicator variable coded 1 (0 otherwise) if, based on
I/B/E/S, the firm reported a nonnegative earnings surprise (i.e., SURPRISE - 0) in quarter
t - 1. We expect the coefficientson these variablesto be positive.
Managers are more likely to report earnings that miss expectations if the expectations
are imprecise (Payne and Robb 2000). We measure this imprecision by the coefficient of
6
The advantageof interpretingeach variable'seffect in termsof a percentagechangein oddsratherthana discrete
or marginalchangein probabilitiesis thatthe changein odds for thatvariabledoes not dependon the levels of
othervariablesin the model.
7
Alternatively,managersmay meet or beat expectationsby reducingthe denominatorof EPS throughshare
repurchases.We do not distinguishbetweenthese two reasonssince they both predictnegativecoefficientson
SHARES.
8
Includingthe firm'sprice-to-earningsratioinsteadof its price-to-bookratioyields similarresults.
Bartonand Simko-Earnings ManagementConstraint 13
*** and * denotesignificantat the 0.01 and 0.10 levels, respectively,based on one-tailedtests for signed predictionsand two-
The sample consists of 35,950 firm-quarters pertainingto 3,649 firms includedin both the Compustatand I/B/E/S databa
excludingutilitiesandfinancialservicesfirms(two-digitSIC codes 49 and 60-67). The variablesare definedas follows:
SURPRISE= I/B/E/S actualEPS for quartert less the consensusforecastfor quartert, both roundedto the nearestp
of analysts'most recentEPS forecastsfor quartert availableon I/B/E/S priorto the earningsannouncem
< -5? into one categoryand SURPRISE - 5? into another;
NOA = net operatingassets (i.e., shareholders'equity less cash and marketablesecurities,plus total debt) at the b
quartert - 1;
SHARES= weightedaveragenumberof commonsharesoutstandingduringquartert;
BIG5 = indicatorvariablecoded 1 if the firmhas a Big 5 auditorin quartert, 0 otherwise;
PB = marketvalue of commonsharesdividedby shareholders'equity,both at the end of quartert;
LTGN-RISK= indicatorvariablecoded 1 if the firm is in one of the following industries:pharmaceuticals/biotechno
computers(3570-3577, 7370-7374), electronics(3600-3674), or retail(5200-5961), 0 otherwise;
ANALYSTS= numberof analystsin the I/B/E/S consensusEPS forecastfor quartert;
PREV_MB = indicatorvariablecoded 1 if, basedon I/B/E/S, the firmreporteda nonnegativeearningssurprise(i.e., SUR
CV_FORECAST= coefficientof variationin analysts'most recentforecastsfor quartert;
DOWN_REV= indicatorvariablecoded 1 if at least one of the firm's analystsrevisedhis or her forecastdown priorto t
announcementdate for quartert - 1, 0 otherwise;
SALES_GRW= sales for quartert dividedby sales for quartert - 4, less 1;
ROE = net income for quartert dividedby shareholders'equity at the end of quartert;
AROE= ROEfor quartert less ROEfor quartert - 1; and
MKT_CAP = naturallogarithmof marketvalue of commonsharesat the end of quartert.
16 The AccountingReview, 2002 Supplement
remaining variables are significant at conventional levels. Untabulated analyses reveal that
rank correlations between most independent variables also are significant at conventional
levels.
Regression Results
Table 5 reportsestimationsresults for Equation(2). Recall that the model allows the
effects of the independent variables to vary across levels of predetermined earnings surprise
benchmarks, k. Because SURPRISE consists of 11 categories coded -5 through 5, we
obtain ten sets of uniquely identified parameter estimates, one for each k ranging from -4
through 5.10We estimate the model using the generalized ordered logit regression technique
described in Fu (1998). The test statistics for all coefficients are heteroscedasticity-
consistent and, because our sample includes multiple observations for most firms, they are
adjustedfor residualcorrelationamong observationsfor the same firm.
Panel A of Table 5 presentscomplete estimationresults when the dependentvariable
is the odds of at least meeting earningsexpectations,that is, when k = 0. For each inde-
pendent variable,the last column of Panel A presentsresults of Wald tests proposedby
Brant (1990) for the null hypothesisthat the coefficients on the independentvariableare
constant across levels of k. These tests reject the null at the 0.01 level for all variables
except BIG5. Therefore,we also reportsummaryresults for all values of k. Specifically,
PanelB shows the percentagechangesin odds for each variableacrossk.11For a continuous
variable, the change in odds is based on a standard-deviation increase in the variable; for
indicators,it is based on a change from 0 to 1 (see the Appendix).
Panel A of Table 5 shows that the coefficient on NOA is negative (p < 0.01). A
standard-deviation increase in the beginning balance of net operating assets relative to sales
decreases by 7.7 percent the odds of at least meeting the consensus forecast, all else equal.
That is, consistent with Ha, the likelihood of meeting or beating analysts' earnings forecasts
by optimistically biasing earnings decreases with the extent to which net assets are already
overstated on the balance sheet.
With respect to the control variables, the coefficient on SHARES is negative (p
< 0.01), suggesting that the odds of at least meeting expectations decrease with shares
outstanding. The insignificant coefficient on BIG5 suggests that our proxy for audit quality
is unrelated to the odds of at least meeting analysts' expectations. The coefficients on PB,
LTGN_RISK, ANALYSTS, and PREV_MB are positive and, except for LTGN_RISK,
significant at the 0.10 level or better. These results suggest that the odds of at least meeting
expectations are increasing in the firm's price-to-book ratio, its record of meeting or beating
forecasts in the previous quarter, and the size of its analyst following. The coefficients on
CV_FORECAST and DOWN_REV are negative (p < 0.01), suggesting that the odds of
at least meeting expectations decrease with the dispersion in analysts' forecasts and with
the presence of downward forecast revisions. Finally, the coefficients on SALES-GRW,
ROE, AROE, and MKT_CAP are positive (p < 0.01), suggesting that the odds of at least
meeting expectations increase with the firm's performance and size.
Panel B of Table 5 shows that the percentage changes in odds for NOA are negative
(p < 0.01) across all k. A standard-deviation increase in the beginning balance of net
10The odds of SURPRISE> -50 can be recoveredfromthe odds of SURPRISE> -40 throughtediousalgebra.
Interestedreadersmay contactus.
1 We
reportpercentagechangesin oddsbecausethey captureboththe sign andrelativeeffect of eachindependent
variable.Therefore,unlikecoefficients,percentagechangesin odds arecomparableacrossindependentvariables.
TABLE 5
Regression Results for Generalized Ordered Logit Model
Model:
Pr(SURPRISEi, - k)/Pr(SURPRISEt, < k) = exp((,8k + P,kIVOAt, + 32kSHARES,,+ 3,kBIGi,, + 34,
+ 6,ANALYSTS,, + 37,kPREV_MBit+ P8,kCV_FOREC
+ 3,o0kSALES_GRWi + 11I,PkOEit+ 312,kgROEit
+ P13,kKT_-CAPit + it)
Panel A: Regressicon Results for k = 0?, i.e., Odds of Meeting or Beating vs. Missing Analysts' Forecasts Pr(SUR
Independent Predicted Ch
Variable Sign Coefficient z-statistic Od
Independent Predicted Ch
Variable Sign Coefficient z-statistic Od
MKT_CAP + 0.156 10.17***
Likelihoodratio X2(130 df 8,105.612**
MaximumlikelihoodR2 0.20
Panel B: Percentage Change in Odds of Reporting SURPRISE - k, Given a Change in the Independent Variabl
P'red. k
Independent
Variable Ssign -4? -3? -2? -1? O0 1A 2?
NOA - -6.2*** -6.8*** -7.0*** -7.9*** -7.7*** -7.9*** -7.5***
SHARES - -0.6 -1.1 -1.1 -6.2** -11.3*** -13.1*** - 14.2***
***,**, and * denote significantat the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.10 levels, respectively,based on one-tailedtest for signed predicti
statisticsare heteroscedasticity-consistent
and adjustedfor residualcorrelationamongobservationspertainingto the same firm
* denotes significant at the 0.10 level or better, based on two-tailed tests, but opposite to our predicted sign.
a The percentagechangein odds is the effect of a changein the independentvariableon the odds of reportingSURPRISE : k
predetermined earnings surprise benchmark. For continuous variables, the percentage change in odds is 100[exp(sj3j,k) - 1],
of variable j (reported in Table 4) and Pj,kis the estimated regression coefficient for variable j with respect to earnings surp
the percentage change in odds is 100[exp(pj,k) - 1].
b The Brant
X2 statistic tests the null hypothesis that odds for the independent variable are proportional, i.e., that the coefficients
across k (Brant 1990).
The sampleconsists of 35,950 firm-quarters
pertainingto 3,649 firmsincludedin both the Compustatand I/B/E/S database
over 1993-1999, excluding utilities and financial services firms (two-digit SIC codes 49 and 60-67).
The variables are defined in Table 4.
20 The AccountingReview, 2002 Supplement
operating assets relative to sales decreases the odds of reporting a larger positive or smaller
negative earnings surprise by 5.7 to 7.9 percent. These results further support Ha.
Panel B of Table 5 also shows that some of the independent variables have a consistent
pattern across all k. For example, the percentage changes in odds for BIG5 are not signif-
icant at conventional levels for any value of k, suggesting that our proxy for audit quality
is unrelated to earnings surprises. The percentage changes in odds for PREV_MB,
SALES_GRW, and MKT_CAP are positive (p < 0.01) across all values of k, suggesting
that the odds of reporting larger positive or smaller negative earnings surprises are increas-
ing in the likelihood of a nonnegative earnings surprise in the previous quarter,sales growth,
and firm size. The percentage changes in odds for DOWN_REV are negative (p < 0.01)
across all k, suggesting that the odds of reporting larger positive or smaller negative earnings
surprises decrease when analysts make downward forecast revisions.
Other independent variables have a consistent pattern across only part of the range of
values for k. For example, the percentage changes in odds for AROE are positive (p
< 0.10) when k : -1, suggesting that the odds of reporting larger positive surprises are
increasing in AROE, but the odds of reporting earnings surprises lower than -1? are un-
related to AROE. The percentage changes in odds for SHARES are negative (p < 0.05)
when k - -1, suggesting that more shares outstanding decrease the odds of reporting
larger positive surprises, but have no effect on the odds of missing expectations by more
than 10. The percentage changes in odds for LTGN_RISK are negative (p < 0.10) when
k - 1, suggesting that litigation risk decreases the odds of larger positive surprises, but has
no effect on the odds of missing expectations.
Finally, the pattern of some variables switches signs around positive earnings surprises
of 10 or 20. For example, the percentage changes in odds for PB, ANALYSTS, and ROE
are positive (p < 0.10) when k < 1 but negative (p < 0.10) when k > 1. These results
suggest that firms with high price-to-book ratios, large analyst following, and high returns
on equity are more likely to miss expectations by smaller amounts than by larger amounts,
and they are less likely to beat expectations by larger amounts than by smaller amounts.
In contrast, the percentage changes in odds for CV_FORECAST are negative (p < 0.01)
when k < 2 but positive (p < 0.10) when k > 2, suggesting that firms with imprecise
forecasts are more likely to miss expectations by larger than smaller amounts, and are more
likely to beat expectations by more than 20.
In sum, the results reported in Table 5 are consistent with H, showing a negative
association between earnings surprises and our proxy for overstated net asset values. We
interpret these results as evidence that the likelihood of reporting larger positive or smaller
negative earnings surprises decreases with the extent to which net assets are already over-
stated on the balance sheet. That is, prior optimism in financial reporting accumulates on
the balance sheet, and reduces managers' ability to optimistically bias earnings in future
periods, if managers want to stay within GAAP and its implementation guidance. The
results also indicate that the relationship between earnings surprises and the independent
variables is complex. The presence of a Big 5 auditor is consistently unrelated to earn-
ings surprises. However, none of the remaining variables measuring constraints on earnings
management, managerial incentives to meet or beat analysts' forecasts, firm performance,
and size has a constant effect across earnings surprise levels.
Sensitivity Analyses
Alternative Econometric Techniques
We use a generalized ordered logit regression of SURPRISE on NOA and CONTROLS
because SURPRISE is an ordinal dependent variable and because we allow the coefficients
on all independent variables to vary across levels of SURPRISE. Using ordinary least
Bartonand Simko-Earnings ManagementConstraint 21
squares (OLS) or "regular" ordered logit regressions constrains the coefficients on each
variable to be constant across levels of SURPRISE, yielding only one set of coefficient
estimates. Moreover, OLS regression treats SURPRISE as a continuous dependent variable.
To assess the robustnessof our resultsunderalternativeeconometricspecificationsthat
constrainthe coefficients on each variableto be constantacross levels of SURPRISE,we
regress SURPRISE on NOA and CONTROLS using OLS and "regular"orderedlogit
regressions. The coefficient on NOA is -0.053 (t = -8.54, p < 0.01) based on OLS
regression;it is -0.028 (z = -4.31, p < 0.01) based on "regular"orderedlogit regression.
Thus, the results bearing on our hypothesis are robust to these alternativespecifications.
However, OLS and "regular"ordred logit regressionslead to substantialchanges in the
coefficients on some of the other independentvariables.
Model:
Pr(SURPRISEi, - k)/Pr(SURPRISEi, < k) = exp(yo,k + y,kWCil + y2,FIXED_ASSETSi, + 3,kOTHER_
+ y3,kBIGSi,+ y6,PBi, + y7LTGN_RISKi, + y8ANALYSTS
+ y,okCV_FORECASTi, + y,,kDOWN_REV,i + y2,~ALES_
+ Y4,kROEit + y5,lMKT_CAPit + vi)
WC FIXED ASSETS
Predicted Change in Change in
k Sign Coefficient z-statistic Odds (%)a Coefficient z-statistic Odds (%)a Co
*** and**denotesignificantat the 0.01 and 0.05 levels, respectively,based on one-tailedtest for signed predictionsand two
and adjustedfor residualcorrelationamongobservationspertainingto the same firm.
heteroscedasticity-consistent
a The percentage change in odds is the effect of a change in the independent variable on the odds of reporting SURPRISE 2 k
predetermined earnings surprise benchmark. For continuous variables, the percentage change in odds is 100[exp(sjPj,k) - 1],
of variable j (reported in Table 4) and 3j,kis the estimated regression coefficient for variable j with respect to earnings surp
the percentage change in odds is 100[exp(ij k) - 1].
b The Brant
X2statistic tests the null hypothesis that odds for the independent variable are proportional, i.e., that the coefficients
across k (Brant 1990).
The sampleconsists of 35,950 firm-quarterspertainingto 3,649 firmsincludedin both the Compustatand I/B/E/S database
over 1993-1999, excludingutilitiesand financialservices firms(two-digitSIC codes 49 and 60-67). The variablesare define
NOA = net operatingassets (i.e., shareholders'equity less cash and marketablesecurities,plus total debt) at t
for quarter t - 1;
WC = currentassets less cash, marketablesecurities,andcurrentliabilities,plus currentdebt, all at the beginn
t - 1;
FIXEDASSETS = property, plant, and equipment, net of accumulated depreciation, at the beginning of quarter t, scaled b
OTHER_LTASSETS = NOA less WC less FIXED_ASSETS.
All other variables are defined in Table 4.
24 The AccountingReview, 2002 Supplement
V. CONCLUSION
Because the balance sheet accumulates the effects of previous accounting choices, the
level of net operating assets partly reflects the extent of previous earnings management. We
present evidence consistent with the hypothesis that managers' ability to optimistically bias
earnings decreases with the extent to which net asset values are already overstated on the
balance sheet.
Using 1993-1999 quarterly data for a sample of 3,649 nonfinancial, nonregulated firms,
we estimate a generalized ordered logit model relating the level of a firm's earnings surprise
to our proxy for the degree of overstatement in net asset values, other constraints on earn-
ings management, managerial incentives to meet or beat analysts' earnings forecasts, and
firm performance and size. We measure the degree of overstatement in net asset values
using the beginning balance of net operating assets relative to sales, a proxy that additional
analysis shows is associated with prior optimistic bias in financial reporting.
Our empirical analysis shows that the likelihood of reporting larger positive or smaller
negative quarterly earnings surprises decreases with the beginning balance of net operating
assets relative to sales, suggesting that managers' ability to optimistically bias earnings
decreases with the extent to which net asset values are already overstated on the balance
sheet. Sensitivity tests suggest that our findings are robust. Nevertheless, our evidence
should be interpreted with caution given the limitations of our study. In particular,our study
focuses on only one incentive to manage earnings-meeting or beating analysts' earnings
forecasts. However, managers have other incentives to manage earnings, some of which
Bartonand Simko-Earnings ManagementConstraint 25
may lead to pessimistically rather than optimistically biased earnings. Our study does not
control for these other incentives.We leave this for futureresearch.
APPENDIX
We derive Equation(2) by assuming that the cumulativeprobabilityof reportingan
EPS surpriseof less than k? is:
Pr(SURPRISE< k I x) = F(-xPk),
To ensure that the sum of cumulative probabilities across all k equals 1, we impose the
constraint-xpik -XP,k-1 for all k. The odds of reporting an earnings surprise of at least
k? instead of less than k? are:
That is, the odds change by 100[exp([x2 - xl]Pk) - 1] percent. If only one variable, say
Xjwith parameterpj, changes by 8, then the odds of reportingan earnings surpriseof at
least k? will change by 100[exp(6 x j,k) - 1] percent, all else equal.
REFERENCES
Abarbanell,J. S., and V. L. Bernard.1992. Tests of analysts'overreaction/underreactionto earnings
informationas an explanationfor anomalousstock price behavior.The Journal of Finance 47
(July): 1181-1207.
, andR. Lehavy.2001a. Biased forecastsor biasedearnings?The role of earningsmanagement
in explainingapparentoptimismand inefficiencyin analysts'earningsforecasts.Workingpaper,
The Universityof NorthCarolinaat ChapelHill, NC.
, and . 2001b. Differencesin commercialdatabasereportedearnings:Implicationsfor
inferencesconcerninganalyst forecast rationality,the associationbetween prices and earnings,
and firm reportingdiscretion.Workingpaper,The Universityof North Carolinaat ChapelHill,
NC.
AccountingPrinciplesBoard (APB). 1973. InterimFinancialReporting.APB OpinionNo. 28. New
York,NY: APB.
Ali, A., and S. Kallapur.2001. Securities price consequencesto the Private Securities Litigation
ReformAct of 1995 and relatedevents. TheAccountingReview76 (July):431-460.
26 The AccountingReview, 2002 Supplement