Entry and Exit: Entrants. Predatory Acts: Entry-Deterring Strategies by
Entry and Exit: Entrants. Predatory Acts: Entry-Deterring Strategies by
6.1 Some Facts About Entry and Exit 6.1.1 U.S. Evidence
Firm F has entered market M if F introduces a Twenty years of U.S. data.
new good or service into M, and
Hypothetical industry in 1996 with 100 firms, and
a. F previously did not exit (entry by a new combined annual sales of $100 m: average
firm), or incumbent has sales of $1 m per year. Then:
b. was not doing business in M previously 1. Entry and exit will be pervasive.
(entry by a diversifying firm).
By 2001, 30–40 new firms, with combined
Acquisition of an existing firm or plant by a sales of $12–20 m in 1996 dollars.
diversifying conglomerate does not necessarily
About 1⁄2 diversified, about 1⁄2 new firms.
introduce a new product into the market.
∴ not really entry. 30–40 existing firms will have left, also about
$12–20 m in annual sales.
Exit occurs either when a firm ceases to operate
altogether, or ceases to operate in the market in About 40% of exiting firms diversified.
question.
∴ 30–40% turnover in firms, about 12–20%
of volume.
2. Entrants and exiters tend to be smaller than
established firms.
Typical entrant about 1⁄3 of typical
incumbent.
Except entry by diversifying firms that build
new plant (5–10% of all entrants); roughly
same size as average incumbent.
Exiting firms about 1⁄3 size of the average
incumbent.
R.E. Marks ECL 6-5 R.E. Marks ECL 6-6
3. Most entrants don’t survive ten years, but 6.2 Entry & Exit: Basic Concepts
survivors grow very quickly.
A profit-maximising, risk-neutral firm should
Roughly 60% of new entrants in 1996–2001
enter a market if the NPV of expected post-entry
will exit by 2006.
profits > sunk costs of entry.
Survivors will nearly double their size
Possible sunk costs: specialised capital equipment,
between 2001 and 2006.
government licences. See below.
4. Entry and exit rates vary across industries.
For post-entry profits, assess post-entry
High rates of entry: apparel, lumber, competition: conduct and performance of firms.
furniture, printing, fabricated metal.
Consider: historical pricing practices, costs,
High rates of exit: apparel, lumber, furniture, capacity, other markets of incumbents.
printing, leather.
What of barriers to entry?
Little entry: food processing, tobacco, paper,
chemicals, primary metals. 6.2.1 Barriers to Entry
Little exit: tobacco, paper, chemicals,
6.2.1.1 Bain’s Typology of Entry Conditions:
primary metals, petroleum, coal.
Barriers to entry: those factors that allow
incumbents to earn positive economic profits,
Four important implications for strategy: while making it unprofitable for new entrants.
• Future planning: the unknown competitor: Structural barriers: when the incumbent has
1
⁄3 of rivals in five years time will be new. natural cost advantages, or marketing advantages,
or favourable regulations.
• Because of their size, diversifying competitors
who build new plants threaten. They benefit the incumbent even when entry is
ignored.
• Most new ventures fail quickly, but have
capital available for expansion. Entry-deterring strategies: barriers from
incumbents’ explicit actions: capacity expansion,
• Know the entry and exit conditions in one’s
limit pricing, predatory pricing.
industry: powerful or not?
Are entry barriers structural or strategic?
Are entry-deterring strategies desirable?
R.E. Marks ECL 6-7 R.E. Marks ECL 6-8
Sleeping patents: patents to products the patent Case: Patent Protection in the Pharmaceutical
holder has no intention of selling: by stopping Industry
competitors from using, to the holder’s cost.
Pharmaceuticals: an expensive and risky venture
Patents may be ineffective: can be “invented to invent and develop new drugs: long R&D times,
around” — is it a new product or an imitation of a long approval times, uncertain demand. Without
protected product? patent protection, no incentive.
Incumbents may file patent protection suits In the late 1960s, Eli Lilly introduced Keflin; in
against entrants whose products are apparently 1971 Keflex: distinct chemical structures, so
different from the incumbent’s. separate patents.
But incumbents may rely on secrecy, not patents, In the ’70s and ’80s top selling prescription drugs
to protect specialised know-how: Coca-Cola exited in the U.S., but others developed distinct chemical
India rather than tell the government its syrup structures and patents too: Merck.
formula.
SmithKline’s Tagamet anti-ulcer drug in 1978 a
best seller, followed by Glaxo’s Zantac in 1984.
When their patents expire soon, both should see a
50% drop in sales as generics compete.
High returns on patented drugs that treat common
Western diseases with few substitutes.
The U.S. F.D.A.’s regulatory requirements meant
a race: patent too soon and the years of effective
monopoly after final approval are reduced, but
patent too late and you might get beaten to the
legal gun by another firm.
The law can provide longer effective protection ,
but simplify testing requirements, and lead to
greater competition.
R.E. Marks ECL 6-11 R.E. Marks ECL 6-12
6.2.1.2.2 Economies of Scale and Scope But there are two costs:
When EOS are significant, incumbents operating • the direct costs of advertising and employing
at or beyond the MES will have a cost advantage and training the sellers;
over smaller entrants
• when the incumbents lose market share to the
entrant, their MCs will fall, → a fall in market
$/unit P.
• EOS in marketing, from the substantial up- 6.2.1.2.3 Marketing Advantages of Incumbency
front expenditures on advertising for a new
Umbrella pricing, when a firm sells different
entrant to establish a minimum level of brand
products under the same brand name, is a special
awareness.
case of economies of scope.
An incumbent has already obtained brand-
Reduces an incumbent’s sunk costs of a new
name awareness, and may be able to use
product introduction, because less need to
existing production and distribution facilities
advertise and product promote to develop
for the new product.
credibility in the eyes of consumers, retailers, and
EOS and economies of scope force a minimum distributors.
scale or product variety on new entrants to achieve
But would not protect against a “lemon” of a new
AC parity with incumbents.
product: few repeat purchases, and fewer first
This is a barrier to the extent that the up-front purchases, after adverse reputation.
entry costs become sunk.
Risk that a lemon new product might:
If they were not sunk, we could see “hit-and-run”
• lead to lower quality perception for the
entry HARE: an entrant comes in at a large scale,
incumbent’s existing range of products;
undercuts incumbents’ prices, and if they retaliate
it exits and recovers its entry costs — leaves • lead rival managers to see the failure of the
incumbents vulnerable to entry even if MES new venture as a sign of the incumbent’s
implied only a single firm in the market. weakness.
Such a situation is rare, and usually significant The umbrella effect might also help with the
sunk up-front commitments necessary to achieve vertical chain of distributors and retailers, and of
cost competitiveness with incumbents means that suppliers.
entry is unattractive to potential entrants, even
though incumbent firms may be profitable.
R.E. Marks ECL 6-15 R.E. Marks ECL 6-16
Both incumbents and new entrants alike may face Case: The Japanese Brewing Industry
high entry barriers when introducing new
Highly concentrated: four firms have 98% of the
experience goods (Lecture 5-43). To get wary
market, and after-tax returns on assets of 3–4%,
consumers to sample their wares:
which is good in Japan with low infration.
• set low introductory prices,
Entry barriers in Japan, as in the U.S. and
• dispense free samples, Australia, are the strong brand identities.
• distribute money-saving coupons Until 1994, a further barrier to entry was
government requirement that a new brewery
• invest heavily in brand identity
produce at least 2 m litres annually.
If a product is high quality, then firms expect
After a reduction in the minimum to 60 k
much repeat business, which will repay the costs
litres/year in 1994, many microbreweries have
of heavy introductory advertising.
opened.
Thus consumers are more willing to sample new
Will cut the big four’s shares and profits, as will
products extensively advertised, correctly
changes in retailing practices:
perceiving them to be of higher quality.
• half of the beer is sold in bars and restaurants,
with loyalty
• most remaining sales in corner bottle shops
• recently, discount liquor shops have cut prices
by 25% below corner shops, and have also
stocked imported beers, at 2⁄3 the cost of
domestics
• entry by imports, and the growth of new retail
channels, will → the big four to lower prices,
lose share, or both
R.E. Marks ECL 6-17 R.E. Marks ECL 6-18
6.3.1.2 So When does Limit Pricing Make Sense? An incumbent with MC = $1, may reason
strategically:
If limit pricing occurs, do firms set prices
irrationally? “If we set P = $5.25, then the entrant will not
know whether we are low or high MC and
Or two types of uncertainty:
might not enter.”
• about the incumbent’s objectives (see Predatory
Because a high-MC incumbent can disguise this, a
Pricing below);
low-MC firm would have to price sufficiently below
• about the incumbent’s costs or the level of $5.25 that an entrant would know that only a
market demand. low-MC firm could price so low: a credible signal.
Then the post-entry price forecasts can be But then a high-MC firm cannot disguise itself,
influenced by the incumbent’s pricing strategy. and should price at PM and accept entry.
Limit pricing may enable the incumbent to If the entrant is uncertain about the level of
influence the entrant’s estimate of its costs, and so demand as well as the incumbent’s MC, then an
the entrant’s expectations of post-entry equilibrium:
profitability.
a. the incumbent’s P < PM and
Incumbent MC of $1 → post-entry Cournot entrant
b. the lower the incumbent’s MC, the lower its
π = $5.
P — signals that MC and/or market demand
Incumbent MC of 50¢ → post-entry Cournot may be low: either sufficient to deter entry.
entrant π of –$10.60.
If the entrant knows the incumbent is not acting
strategically, then the entrant can infer the
incumbent’s MC from its price:
PM = $5.50 → MC = $1, and entry profitable
PM = $5.25 → MC = 50¢, entry unprofitable
R.E. Marks ECL 6-27 R.E. Marks ECL 6-28
6.3.3.2 Judo Economics and the Puppy-Dog Ploy. 6.4 Exit-Promoting Strategies
Suppose an entrant could credibly commit to
During price wars firms sometimes argue that
limiting its output, so that P remained high: judo
their rivals are trying to drive them from the
economics or the “puppy-dog ploy” (Lecture 4-26).
market in order to exercise market power later.
In the above example, so long as the incumbent is
Complaints of “unfairly low prices” occur in
convinced that the entrant will produce no more
international trade disputes, when foreign firms
than 10, and so does not expand capacity, then ΠI
are sometimes accused of dumping: of selling at
= $1,400 at QI = KI = 60 and P = $65 with entry,
prices below cost.
instead of ΠI = $950 at KI = 100 and QI = 90
without entry. Case: How Standard Oil Drove Out its
Competitors
The new Braniff Airlines announced that it would
restrict its flights to a small number of cities and John D. Rockefeller’s Standard Oil grew by
only about 3% the passengers of AA, but AA still exploiting scale and scope economies in refining,
triggered a price war that did for Braniff. distribution, and purchasing; careful organisation
of the vertical chain; and a series of shrewd steps
Why?
to destroy rivals.
• Perhaps AA was setting a predatory price to
“Drawbacks” meant that S.O. (Esso!) was paid a
deter later entry by others.
fee by the rails for every barrel of oil sent to NY by
• Perhaps Braniff’s promise was not credible. a rival: subsidised by its rivals.
The puppy dog may not be able to convince others S.O. had near monopsony power in oil refining and
of its commitment to stay small: it will meet distribution.
aggression.
S.O. came to dominate refining by predatory
pricing: by cutting prices until a recalcitrant
refiner was driven from business. Owned 90% of
U.S. refining, and then squeezed profits out of the
vertical chain.
R.E. Marks ECL 6-37 R.E. Marks ECL 6-38
6.5 Effects of Diversification on Entry and Exit 6.5.2 Diversification, entry, and coordinated pricing
Decisions
A diversified firm entering a new market may
choose a pricing strategy different from a new
Diversification may affect the entry costs, post-
firm’s.
entry profitability, and the nature of post-entry
competition. A natural-monopoly market with room for only one
hamburger vendor: two possible entrants:
6.5.1 Diversification and entry costs
1. the incumbent, with a pizza joint already,
Entry by diversified firms: larger plants (three and
times, on average) than startups’, and more likely
2. a startup firm.
to succeed — U.S. evidence.
Who has the stronger incentive to enter the
Several advantages of diversified firms:
hamburger market?
• Larger, and hence smaller risks to lenders —
Depends :
lower cost of credit;
new venture capitalists have reduced the need • Can the incumbent benefit by coordinating the
for startups to turn to exiting firms for capital. pricing of the two products?
Yes.
• Economies of scope in production, distribution,
and marketing. • Will the incumbent be as willing as the entrant
to fight for supremacy?
No, if the products are substitutes; yes, if
complements.
R.E. Marks ECL 6-41 R.E. Marks ECL 6-42
6.6 Evidence on Entry-Deterring Behaviour Case: DuPont’s Use of Excess Capacity to Control
the Market for Titanium dioxide
Apart from antitrust cases, little evidence of firms
While rivals used the sulphate process, DuPont
pursuing entry-deterring strategies, successful or
used the chloride process to produce TiO2 from
not.
ilmenite, and also low-cost rutile.
Scant evidence because:
New pollution laws ended use of sulphate process
• strategic entry deterrence may be commercially plants, which DuPont foresaw.
sensitive information, and may be illegal;
It predicted a rise in demand for TiO2 , and it
• to determine whether a firm was pricing below preempted its rivals by adding 500,000 t of new
its short-term PM necessary to know the firm’s capacity.
MC, its demand curves, the degree of industry
DuPont estimated its costs were 22% lower than
competition, and the availability of substitutes
its rivals, so they wouldn’t go head to head over
— outside antitrust cases difficult to obtain;
capacity and share.
• what would the rate of entry have been, absent
During the construction, DuPont was vulnerable,
the predatory acts? Difficult to say.
but signalled its rivals not to start capacity
expansion:
• announce the scale of its planned expansion
• falsely announced the start of construction of a
new plant
• and limit priced (P < ATC), which its rivals
refused to match
Since DuPont lacked capacity to supply the whole
market, the two-tier pricing structure persisted,
until demand slackened and the rivals caved lest
they lose the market to DuPont.
After reconsideration, DuPont scaled back its
capacity expansion.
R.E. Marks ECL 6-45 R.E. Marks ECL 6-46
CONTENTS
-i-