0% found this document useful (0 votes)
43 views

Unit 22 Phases of Feudalism: Structure

The document summarizes two phases of feudalism in Europe from the 9th to 14th centuries. The first phase from the 9th to 11th centuries was characterized by subsistence agriculture with low yields, scarce trade, and a lack of monetary economy. Technology was limited and production was for local consumption, not markets. The second phase from the 11th to 14th centuries saw population growth, expanded cultivation, technical advances, revived trade, a growing monetary economy, and increased social stratification and differentiation between urban and rural areas.

Uploaded by

Anuj Pratap
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
43 views

Unit 22 Phases of Feudalism: Structure

The document summarizes two phases of feudalism in Europe from the 9th to 14th centuries. The first phase from the 9th to 11th centuries was characterized by subsistence agriculture with low yields, scarce trade, and a lack of monetary economy. Technology was limited and production was for local consumption, not markets. The second phase from the 11th to 14th centuries saw population growth, expanded cultivation, technical advances, revived trade, a growing monetary economy, and increased social stratification and differentiation between urban and rural areas.

Uploaded by

Anuj Pratap
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 10

UNIT 22 PHASES OF FEUDALISM

Structure
22.1 Introduction
22.2 Two Main Phases
22.3 First Phase – 9th to 11th Century
22.3.1 Agricultural Production: Means and Methods
22.3.2 Organisation of Agricultural Production
22.3.3 Subsistence Economy
22.4 Second Phase – 11th to 14th Century
22.4.1 Growth of Population
22.4.2 Extension of Cultivation
22.4.3 Changes in Organisation of Agricultural Production
22.4.4 Growth of Economy
22.4.5 Social Stratification
22.5 Summary
22.6 Glossary
22.7 Exercises

22.1 INTRODUCTION
The large empire built by Charlemagne (Charles the Great) began to disintegrate
in the ninth century A.D. The collapse of central authority was accompanied
by external invasions and decline of trade, commerce and the towns. Many of
the military commanders and chiefs became independent rulers of their regions.
During this period a new social formation was emerging in Europe which is
termed as Feudalism. The feudal social formation contained Roman as well
as Germanic elements. Feudalism as a form of political, economic and social
system dominated Europe from around 9th to 14th century A.D. However,
during this entire period the political, economic and social structures were not
static and uniform. A number of changes were taking place and new relations
were emerging. In this Unit we will study these changes in two distinct phases
of feudalism. In each phase we will focus on some unique aspects of agricultural
production, role of technology, agrarian relations and the state of economy.

22.2 TWO MAIN PHASES


In order to appreciate the complexities of the social and economic life in
medieval Europe feudalism has to be treated more as an evolving process than
as a static structure. The idea of two evolutionary phases in feudalism owes
much to the pioneering research of Marc Bloch. According to him, the first
phase, which began with the establishment of the barbarian successor states
on the collapsed political system of the Roman Empire and lasted until the
middle of the eleventh century, substantially preserved the basic social relations
which characterised the late Empire. This phase corresponds to the organisation
of a fairly stable rural territory where trade was insignificant and uncommon,
coins were rare, and a wage-earning class almost non-existent. Ties of vassalage
32 between the greater and lesser elements hierarchically linked the territorial
aristocracies who monopolised both the social means of coercion and the Phases of Feudalism
regulation of jurisdiction. Most of the peasants were either completely unfree
in the eyes of the law or so dependent in various ways on their lords that, if
they were free, their freedom was a mere formality. In this phase the agrarian
economy was producing very little surplus beyond what was necessary to
support the power and position of the landed aristocracy. Production for market
was low; rents tended to be in labour or in kind; there was little money in
circulation; and there was little effective demand for the luxury commodities
of international trade since upper-class incomes were received in produce rather
than in cash. Consequentially, western European life was predominantly rural
and localised.
The second phase, from the mid-eleventh to the early fourteenth century, was
the result of the substantial growth of population, the great land clearances,
the considerable technical progress, the revival of trade, the diffusion of a
monetary economy, and the growing social superiority of the merchant over
the producer. During this period, Bloch argues, the evolution of society and
the evolution of the economy began to move in opposite directions: the former,
which was slowing down, tended to hone the class structure into closed groups,
while the latter, which was accelerating, eventually led to freedom from serfdom
and the relaxation of restrictions on trade and commerce. In the specific context
of Maconnais, Georges Duby places the turning point a century later, about
1160 from when an increase in the agricultural surplus facilitated a greater
involvement in the network of a monetary economy, an increasing
differentiation between urban and rural conditions, and various forms of the
general social upheaval. Jacques Le Goff points out that the shift from the first
to the second feudal age was a remarkably slow and stretched-out process, and
was not evenly or simultaneously accomplished across western Europe.

22.3 FIRST PHASE – 9th TO 11th CENTURY


Although technology never remains static, in this period it was extremely labour
intensive and yields were low. Trade though scanty was never completely
absent, but it was not the economy’s driving force. Production was largely for
consumption rather than for the market.

22.3.1 Agricultural Production: Means and Methods


From the present-day point of view, the productivity of land remained highly
restricted in this phase owing to the limited effectiveness and inadequacy of
the tools and of farming techniques. As a result, very limited returns were
produced. The practice of ploughing three or four times was common as the
heavy clay soils, the most fertile when properly worked, put up a stiff resistance.
It was necessary to use hands, forks, sickles, spades and harrows for breaking
clods, cutting thistles and weeds, and digging up the field deeply. Artificial
chemical fertilisers were unknown and the available natural fertilisers were
very limited. Soil exhaustion was a constant problem owing to the extensive
practice of the slash and burn agriculture or the cultivation of burnt patches.
The peasants lacked pesticides and used to keep pigeons and doves that would
not only eat insects, but also provide a small but highly concentrated amount
of fertilizer for use in the gardens. In the absence of herbicides weeds often
posed a serious difficulty since the system of letting land lie fallow was the
33
Feudalism most common measure to recover the fecundity of land. Technical shortcomings
of subsistence agriculture kept it still highly vulnerable to bad weather. Wet
springs could reduce ploughing time, rot seed in the ground, and so diminish
the harvest. Fall rains could wet the grain before harvesting and make it
impossible to dry and thresh.
Ploughing did not go deep enough. The symmetrical (plough) share of the
ancient swing-plough sometimes tipped with iron but usually made of wood
hardened in fire, scratched rather than cut through the soil. In this respect, the
introduction of the heavy plough with an asymmetrical share and a mouldboard
with a movable wheeled front pulled by a stronger team represented a definite,
considerable advance. By the sixth century it was introduced into the Po valley
of Northern Italy (most probably from the Slavic lands) and by the eighth it
was in use in the Rhineland. The wheels allowed the ploughshare to be matched
to the furrow being ploughed. The mould-board turned over the sod. The iron
ploughshare could make deep furrows and thus made more soil minerals
possible and the traditional criss-cross double ploughing of fields unnecessary.
Furthermore, it exposed much of those root systems of weeds in arable land to
the open air and thus inhibited their growth. It was essential in the efficient use
of the rich, heavy, often wet soils of northwestern Europe. Its use allowed the
area’s forests and swamps to be brought under cultivation. Open fields ploughed
in long furrows were able to absorb great amounts of water, and because of the
shape of the furrow, drainage caused little erosion. This tended to protect the
rich, heavy croplands of northern Europe from heavy rains.
The problem with using a heavy plough was that it involved a great deal of
tractive power. Since it took from four to eight animals to pull a full-sized
mouldboard plough, few individual farmers could own the necessary number
of oxen to pull this heavy plough. Le Goff also calls attention to the fact that
the size and strength of medieval work-animals were noticeably inferior to
those of the modern animals. Around the year 1000 a group of technical
advances were popularised which allowed men to make better use of animal
traction, to increase the work-output of the beasts and finally to replace the ox
with the horse as the major draught and plough animal. These innovations
included horseshoes, which protected the horses’ hooves, and the new harness
with horse collars that allowed the animal to carry the traction on the shoulders
and did not compress the chest, thus permitting it to breathe more freely.
Tandem harnessing also developed during the same time, which allowed as
many horses as one had to be hitched to the same vehicle. This provided the
medieval peasants greater tractive power and made possible the extensive use
of the heavy plough. However, although horses were faster, had greater
endurance than oxen and did not need an additional man in the plough team to
guide it with a sharp pole (as was the case with oxen), ploughing with horses
did not become rapidly or evenly popular because of the high nominal price of
the animal and the difficulties of having to feed it on oats. As late as the
thirteenth century the employment of oxen and donkeys remained unchallenged
in many fields of southern France and the Mediterranean region.

22.3.2 Organisation of Agricultural Production


The village operated as a ploughing cooperative because the cost of plough
and draught animals was too high to be borne by a single household. In flat or
34 gently undulating country with good soils there were open fields, surrounding
the big nucleated village, in which the strips of land that made up individual Phases of Feudalism
family holdings were intermixed, and over which, once the grain was harvested,
village gleaners could first work and subsequently village animals graze, with
no distinction being observed between one person’s land and the next. Beyond
the arable fields usually lay the woodland and the waste, available to the village
community for gathering timber, nuts and fruits, chasing rabbits and hare, and
giving extra grazing to their animals. Each household had to observe a common
routine of sowing and fallowing in the open field. It had to agree on the rules
determining gleaning and concerning access to the commons. Rodney Hilton
identifies this as the practical basis of village common action which eventually
underlay the manorial system. We must keep in mind that there were many
variations of open-field agriculture and neither strict rotational schemes
characterised all of them nor were peasants’ holdings always distributed evenly
over the main divisions of the arable. But generally, each household owned
portions in both of the two fields into which the arable lands of the village
were grouped. One of the fields was ploughed in the early spring and planted
in grain. The other field was then ploughed, but left unplanted to let the air and
sunshine restore some of its fertility. Weeds were allowed to grow as they
diverted some of the attention of insects and provided pasture for the animals
that would manure the field as they grazed. Just before the weeds in the fallow
field were ready to seed, the field was ploughed a second time and the weeds
turned under. Though effective to some extent in restoring fertility and holding
back weeds, this system carried a heavy price. For practical purposes, the
villagers could utilise only half of their land each year while expending the
effort of ploughing fallow land.
Field utilisation reached a new height in the ninth and tenth centuries when
many villages began to divide their two fields into three, and plant them in a
rotating sequence of beans, winter wheat, summer wheat, and fallow. With
good planning, this could result in three annual harvests in place of the
traditional one. The replacement of the biennial crop rotation with triennial
rotation succeeded in leaving land infertile one year out of three rather than
one year out of two, or rather in using two-thirds of the cultivable surface area
instead of only half. The villages had been primarily organised for the growing
of grain – wheat in most places, but also oats, rye, barley or whatever the soil
and climate permitted. Peasants started using peas and beans as a complement
to their grain crops. Legumes restored nitrogen to the soil and vines choked
out weeds, provided a source of protein to the humans as well as an excellent
fodder for the winter stock feed. Vines also kept the soil friable and thus made
ploughing easier. To the improved method of crop rotation and limited
diversification of crops, one must add the increasing utilisation of iron and the
remarkable spread of windmills. There were certain other related changes in
agriculture as well. To escape the problem of turning several teams and a rather
cumbersome heavy plough around when the peasant got to the end of the field,
the method of strip farming – or long-acre farming – came into vogue in the
north. This distinguished the northern agriculture from the older Mediterranean
variety that had always used smaller, square fields.

22.3.3 Subsistence Economy


In spite of several small innovations, the technical level of agricultural
production, transport and distribution remained quite low and the amount of 35
Feudalism surplus tiny. Human portage remained an essential form of transport. Roads
were in a poor state. Carts and wagons were very few and very expensive.
Even though there was an increase in tonnage in the twelfth and thirteenth
centuries particularly in the north, the number of ships was extremely limited.
The use of the compass became common only after 1280. The quadrant and
the nautical astrolabe were introduced not before the Renaissance. Throughout
the medieval period the human manual work remained the principal source of
energy. And yet, the productivity of the working people was significantly
constrained by their lack of access to appropriate food and proper conditions
of living. Poor food and limited medical knowledge kept life expectancy
remarkably low. Infant mortality was appallingly high. Malnutrition exposed
the poor classes more gravely to the dangers of bad health and untimely death
than the aristocracy. The conventionality and inadequacy of production
techniques, endorsed by the governing ideology, condemned the medieval
economy to stagnation, to the exclusive purpose of subsistence and of ‘prestige
spending by a minority’. Coupled with the relatively small market for
agricultural commodities, it also prevented the scale of production from growing
beyond the limits of a holding which could be worked by a family with at the
most one or two hired hands. As a result the internal stratification of peasant
society was strictly limited during the greater part of the medieval period.

22.4 SECOND PHASE – 11th TO 14th CENTURY


The second phase witnessed a number of dynamic changes in the feudal
structures. The most significant change that took place was phenomenal rise
in agricultural productivity and growth in population. This growth led to the
extension of cultivated area and increased agricultural production. The
organisation of production also underwent change and the community based
production gave way to individual peasant production increasingly destined
for the market. The non agricultural production increased leading to the growth
of economy. The social structures changed and especially growing stratification
of the peasantry was a new element. Let us take account of these changes
starting with the growth of population.

22.4.1 Growth of Population


The growth of population at a noticeable rate is evident from the 11th Century.
This increase continued till the middle of 14th century. Before taking into
account the quantum of over all growth of population it is important to
understand the factors that gave rise to this phenomenon. The main reason
can be traced to the sharp decline in tribal attacks in the tenth century. The
creation of feudal institutions for providing peace and security was also a
contributory factor. Relaxation of legal restraints on peasant households helped
in the process. Another important reason was the gradual improvement in
technology and organisation of agricultural production without which it would
not have been possible to meet the demand of food for growing numbers.
The quantum of growth was impressive. Between the end of the tenth and the
middle of the fourteenth centuries the population in the West doubled. Western
Europe, according to an estimate by J. C. Russell (population in Europe, 500
– 1500), went from 22.5 million inhabitants in about 950 to 54.5 million on
the eve of the Black Death in 1348 while Europe as a whole, according to
36
another estimate by M. K. Bennett, had 42 million inhabitants in 1000 and 73
million in about 1300. The rise in population most probably steeped around Phases of Feudalism
1200. The population of France, it would seem, rose from 12 to 21 million
between 1200 and 1340, that of Germany from 8 to 14 million, and that of
England from 2.2 to 4.5 million. This period of growth came between two
periods of demographic recession when the population of Europe fell from
about 67 million in about 200 AD to about 27 million around 700, and from
the 73 million reached around 1300 to about 45 million around 1400.

22.4.2 Extension of Cultivation


This sharp rise in population was the main stimulus for the great economic
venture of land clearance during the eleventh and twelfth centuries. In most of
the regions the available food resources could not keep pace with the
demographic expansion, and in spite of considerable emigration the pressure
on land was not effectively reduced. According to Le Goff, the focus of the
new agricultural concern was a quantitative increase in the cultivable area
(largely through land clearances) rather than a qualitative shift in the methods
of enhancing productivity or improving tools. Enormous stretches of wilderness
began to be settled after the first millennium. A great number of deserted tracts
were irrigated and colonised in Spain and parts of southern France; large forests
were cleared in Wales and eastern Germany, and a laborious reclamation of
land from sea was successfully undertaken in Flanders. Duby chooses to see
this wave of land clearance as both a pressure from below and a sanction from
above: while the peasants found it necessary to bring new lands under the
plough to provide for the additional population, the lords were equally alive to
the necessity of increasing their resources. Land clearances also radically
transformed the layout of the farmland by shifting the focus of extensive tillage
from the central parcels of arable lands closer to houses to the ‘assarted’ or
cleared area on the perimeter. Cattle farming was organised more methodically.
Famines did not altogether disappear but considerably decreased in scale and
frequency by the end of the twelfth century.

22.4.3 Changes in Organisation of Agricultural Production


Large scale extension of land under the plough and improved technology for
cultivation and irrigation was bound to change the organisation of agricultural
production. Duby contends that improved equipment now enabled the farmers
to gradually withdraw from collective organisation of farming and promoted a
rudimentary form of agrarian individualism. The creation of the free zones
and ‘sanctuaries’ (where immigrants could be sure of enjoying clearly defined
privileges, of being treated as ‘burgesses’, and of benefiting from the tax-
relief by virtue of living there) forced lords of ancient estates to relax their grip
to some extent and to curtail their demands. Hence freedom of a sort gradually
percolated through the rural world. It was essential to make and respect large
promises to those involved in the agricultural expansion. Except in certain
regions such as the countryside of southern Gaul and northwestern Germany,
the manse finally disintegrated and disappeared in the twelfth century and two
new types of tenure – for rent and for crop-sharing payments – were becoming
more usual on plots of land recently brought into cultivation on the margins of
the existing arable. The annual rental was either fixed or proportionate to the
harvest respectively. Precipitated by population growth, higher agricultural
yields, and land clearances, the process was certainly helped by the relaxation
37
Feudalism of seigneurial burdens. During the second half of the twelfth century, the lords
frequently agreed to codify customary usages, regularise their fiscal powers
and thus loosen the strongest bonds of servitude because such concessions
helped to increase the number of peasant families subject to their authority
and enabled the rural population to accumulate more cash. On the one hand,
demographic growth led to the fragmentation and multiplication of agricultural
holdings, and on the other, to the increased mobility of the rural population.
An abundance of unoccupied land and a remarkable shortage of agricultural
labour had marked the early medieval economy. Since landed property was
valueless without the labour of the peasantry, the propertied class took special
care to impose heavy restrictions on the mobility of the workforce. During the
twelfth and thirteenth centuries increased amounts of cultivable lands with
higher productivity and an increased supply of labour accelerated the process
of manumission and placed large areas of farmland into the hands of the non-
nobles.

22.4.4 Growth of Economy


The areas of dense population saw the most rapid development of towns and
of the political importance of their inhabitants. Technological innovations not
only increased production, but also increased the peasants’ productivity to
such a degree that a smaller portion of the population had to be directly engaged
in the raising of food and a number of people could now devote themselves to
the full-time pursuit of non-agricultural activities. As we have already
mentioned, the towns in late medieval Europe were sharply distinguished from
those of the classical world in their emphasis on the non-agricultural functions.
In these towns the merchants, the craftsman, the moneychangers, the doctors,
the notaries, and the like did not have to acquiesce in an inferior social position
when they acquired wealth. Over the course of time they emerged as the
politically, socially and culturally dominant urban group. Many drew their
income from banking and mortgaging land, which could raise considerable
sums when the members of nobility and upper clergy were running into financial
difficulties. Particularly the Jews, who were not bound by the Christian
prohibitions on usury, played a central role in these activities. There also
developed large-scale manufacture and long-distance trade. The three major
items of export for this trade were slaves (taken by the Germans on their eastern
border or by the Vikings, and particularly in demand by the Cordoba caliphate),
Flemish cloths and woollens (increasingly manufactured from English wool
in the towns of Bruges, Lille, Bergues, and Arras) and silver from Saxony.
Through Italy and the inland waterways of Russia these goods were traded for
luxuries from the east (particularly silks and spices) which were at once valuable
and relatively easy to transport.
Loans for consumption was the main, if not the only, form of loan during most
of the feudal period. Loans for production remained almost non-existent. Interest
made on loans for consumption was forbidden between Christians and was
considered as usury, which was strongly condemned by the Church. The strong
economic pressures against credit opposed all accumulation indispensable for
economic progress. The lay aristocracy usually squandered its surpluses in
gifts and alms and in shows of munificence in the name of the Christian ideal
of charity and of the chivalric ideal of largesse whose economic importance
38
was considerable. The dignity of honour of lords consisted in spending without
counting the cost; the consumption and waste used up almost all of their income. Phases of Feudalism
When there was any accumulation at all, it took the non-creative economic
form of hoarding. Precious vessels and hoards of money, which were melted
down or put into circulation in the hours of catastrophe or crisis, came to satisfy
bare survival at difficult moments, and did not feed a regular, continuous
productive activity. The higher clergy similarly used up its revenues on
unproductive expenditure like construction and adornment of churches and in
liturgical pomp. However, a sizeable part of the revenue of the church was
also used for the subsistence of the poor who were reduced to the living
minimum by seigneurial exactions.
Money, historians now agree, never entirely disappeared from use in medieval
west. Apart from the Church and the nobles, who always had a certain supply
of money at their disposal to acquire luxuries, even the peasants often had
some little amount of money with which they bought things such as salt, which
they could neither produce nor receive and only rarely buy by barter. But the
monetary circulation, as a whole, was weak and inelastic. The existence of
non-metallic currency, such as oxen, cows, pieces of cloth, and especially
pepper was common. In the first feudal age, money was appreciated not because
of its theoretical value, but for the real value of the precious metal which it
contained. During the thirteenth century Le Goff notices a ‘monetary
renaissance’, or a return to the striking of gold coins. This coincided with the
striking of the silver groat in Venice, Florence, Flanders, England, France and
Bohemia. The strong pull exerted by the Muslim centres of production in the
south prolonged a phase of raised prices right up to the start of the eleventh
century which coincided with the end of the period of the monetary economy.
The eleventh century and the first half of the twelfth saw a fall in prices,
indicative of a phase of natural economy, the preceding phase having
accomplished the demonetarisation of the Christian kingdoms. From the middle
of the twelfth century, on the other hand, a phase of monetary economy evolved
again when the quickening circulation of money encouraged the lords to extend
the role that money played in rent. The small fines imposed in the private
courts where the master settled disputes between himself and his tenants over
services, ‘new rents’ to replace ‘champarts’, and cash payments to buy off
labour services, drew into the manorial household a larger share of the cash
which passed through the peasant hands. Nevertheless, the proportion of feudal
money income remained small.

22.4.5 Social Stratification


The evolution of the economy enhanced differentiation within the society in
general and stratification within the peasantry in particular. Most peasant
hospites or settlers obtained exemptions and freedoms on the newly cleared
land. A process of liberation occurred over all the landed estates of western
Europe which improved the legal conditions of peasants if not their material
welfare. Seigneurial exactions were restricted by replacing labour services with
a due or census which was often fixed, and a fixed total (a quit-rent or taille
abonnée) of the principal payments was determined by a charter. The lords
were compelled to compound their rights into fixed dues and granted defined
customs to their citizens which in turn accelerated further immigration. At this
time began the commutation of labour services into lump sum cash payment
to the lord. While this enabled the peasant to obtain complete freedom to pursue 39
Feudalism his own dream of either migrating or devoting his entire time to his own piece
of land, it also ensured that the lord obtained liquid cash with which he could
purchase labour in the growing labour market. These processes symbolised
and brought about certain advancement for the higher segment of the peasant
classes, especially for the laboureurs or ploughmen who owned their own teams
and gear as opposed to the less skilled farm-workers. While among many of
the lesser peasants the social dependence and economic inferiority was
accentuated by the process, for many others in that echelon, the opportunities
to rise high were opened up. The increasing gap within the class, itself growing
out of the process of differentiation, redefined the social relations to a great
degree.
Apart from the higher peasants, many burgesses, powerful lords and big town
churches also grew rich at the expense of the poorer and middling members of
the knightly class who had to sell much of their lands as they sank into debt. In
fact, the growing stratification within the class of the lords became an important
feature of the period. It was not simply the division between the milites and
the bellatores – the knights and the lords they served – which was intensified
within the aristocratic class, but also the increasing differentiation between
the banal and the smaller lords. The former increasingly turned to feudal
privileges as a source of their sustenance while the latter can be seen as
attempting to adjust themselves to the demands of the market and producing
for it. The process of differentiation at both levels provided enormous dynamism
to the latter phase of feudal economy and society.
In the late Middle Ages, the social classes underwent a period of fluidity.
Economic conditions favoured the merchant and craft classes, and even the
peasantry could demand better circumstances. Feudal obligations between lord
and vassal were being replaced by contractual agreements based on payments
of money. The economy began expanding from an agricultural base to include
commercial and manufacturing interests. Also, Europe was no longer in a
constant state of warfare and even the Crusades had ceased to be a focus for
the energies of the martial nobility.

22.5 SUMMARY
The feudal system in Europe took roots and survived for almost five hundred
years. In its initial phase it was not very well structured and was mostly confined
to a sort of bond between the Lord and the Vassal. Over the years the bonds
got defined and streamlined with various hierarchical levels. The feudal age
also witnessed growth of new institutions. You must have noticed that the
whole feudal period is not static and witnessed changes. In this Unit we have
discussed them in two major phases – the first from 9th to 11th century and the
second from 11th to 14th century A.D. These phases are not identifiable
distinctly in all regions at the same time. There were variations in developments
in terms of periods and specific areas of change.
You must have noticed these changes in the area of agricultural production,
technology, pattern of cultivation and organisation of production between the
two phases since land was the main source of wealth in feudal system. The
demographic changes during the period influenced economic and social
structures. During the second phase the economic growth was significant and
40 social stratification was pronounced. From the 14th century the process of
decline of feudalism started which would be subject of our discussion in the Phases of Feudalism
next Unit.

22.6 GLOSSARY
Asymmetrical Share : A form of plough with mouldboard etc.
Black Death : Plague epidemic which struck Europe in the
middle of 14th century it is estimated that it killed
between one-fourth and one-third of Europe’s
inhabitants.
Burgess : The town resident contributing towards the
customary payments due to the king from
boroughs; in the late medieval period, however,
“burgess” was frequently used to distinguish one
group of privileged townsmen from a less
privileged group. Burgesses grew in power
during the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries,
gradually building wealth based upon the
commerce and production that took place in the
borough.
Liturgical Pomp : Display of public celebrations of worship or
rituals or ceremonies.
Macconais : A region of trance
Manse : See Glossary in Unit 20
Manumission : The freeing of a slave or serf from indentured
service.
Mould board plough : See Asymmetrical share
Open fields : Arable land with common rights after harvest or
while fallow; usually without internal divisions
by hedges, walls or fences but made up of plough
strips arranged by furlongs.
Rhine Land : Region adjoining to Rhine river in Germany.
Vikings : Scandinavian traders and pirates of 8th – 10th
century
Village gleaners : Poor people in villages who used to collect ears
of corn after the crop was harvested and taken
away by cultivators.

22.7 EXERCISES
1) List main features of two main phases of feudalism.
2) Give a brief description of the changes in the agricultural technology.
3) Write a short note on growth of population and its effect on expansion of
agriculture.
4) Compare the organisation of agricultural production between two phases
of feudalism.
5) List the major changes in economy during the second phase. 41

You might also like