In-Class Practice Questions For Perfect Competitive Market
In-Class Practice Questions For Perfect Competitive Market
0. Assume that a very large number of firms in an industry all have access to the same
production technology. The total cost function associated with this technology is
TC(q) = 40q – 24q2 + 4q3. If the demand function for the industry’s product is
Q = 19 – P, find numbers of firms when the market is at its LR competitive equilibrium?
P = MC
Profit = 0 => TR = TC => P = AC
Thus, P = MC = AC
1. Poland wants to privatize its farming industry and will therefore allow 10,000 farms to
produce wheat under competitive circumstances. Assume that entry into the wheat-
growing segment of the industry will be easy. Also assume that each wheat farm will
have a total cost function of the following type: TC = q2/2 – 4q + 200, where q is the
farm’s output. At the present, the government planners are setting a price of P = 20 per
bushel for wheat.
a) How much wheat will each farm produce? At the long-run perfectly competitive
equilibrium for the wheat-growing segment of the farming industry, will the price
be lower or higher than the present administered price?
(Hint: remember the long-run conditions?? These conditions will help you find the
competitive price)
q/2 – 4 + 200/q = q – 4
q/2 – 200/q = 0
q2 – 400 = 0
=> q = 20
Therefore, the LR equilibrium output will be 20 bushels of wheat per farm. The LR
equilibrium P = AC = MC, P = q – 4 = 20 – 4 = 16. This price is lower than the present
administered price of P =20.
1
b) If each wheat farm had ten acres before privatization and produced a yield of four
bushels per acre, should the size of these farms be increased or decreased after the
market becomes competitive? In other words, will it be cheaper to grow wheat on
larger or smaller farms when the market is competitive?
Because each farm will produce 20 bushels of wheat at the LR equilibrium and it takes 1
acre to produce 4 bushels, the optimum size for a wheat farm after the industry becomes
competitive will be only 5 acres, compared to 10 acres before privatization.
2. Assume that the taxi industry in the town of New City is perfectly competitive. Also
assume that the constant marginal cost of a taxi ride is $5 per trip and that each taxi is
capable of making 20 trips a day. We will let the demand function for taxi rides each day
be D(p) = 1,100 – 20p.
b) How many ride will the citizens of New City make every day?
Substituting the P into the demand function, we find that the equilibrium numbers of taxi
rides every day is 1,100 – 20*5 = 1,000.
Given that each taxi is capable of making 20 trips a day, the number of taxis needed in
New City is 1,000/20 = 50.
Assume that every taxi that operates in New City has a special license. Therefore, the
number of such licenses is the same as the number of taxis that you calculated in Part c)
of this problem. Further assume that the demand for taxi rides has increased and is now
D(p) = 1,200 – 20p. The cost of operating a taxi is still $5 per ride, and the number of
taxis has not changed.
2
d) Calculate the price that will equate demand with supply
The number of taxi licenses in New City is 50, the same as the number of taxis we
calculated in Part c), which means that the “supply” of taxi rides every day is 1,000.
Equating demand to supply, we find that 1,200 – 20p = 1,000, or p =10. Thus, each taxi
ride costs $10.
e) Calculate the profit that each taxi will earn per day. (each taxi operates at its full
capacity)
Given the cost of each taxi ride is $5 and the fare is $10, the profit each taxi earns on a
ride is $5. The profit per day is 20*5 = $100.
3. Suppose that there is an economy with two firms whose products are completely
independent. By “independent,” we mean that when one firm changes its price, the other
firm’s demand is totally unaffected. The only possibilities for employment in this
economy are a career running firm 1 or firm 2 or a career as an economics professor who
earns $20,000 a year. There are no barriers to entry in these careers, and anyone currently
employed in one occupation can costlessly change to another.
The only input that either firm needs to make its product is seaweed, which costs
$2 a pound. Each firm requires one pound of seaweed to produce one unit of its product.
The cost of the input (seaweed) does not include the cost of an entrepreneur’s time.
There are no costs involved in being an economics professor. The demand for the product
of firm 1 is P1 = 2,002 – 4Q1, and the demand for the product of firm 2 is P2 = 4,004 –
5Q2.
a) If anyone can become an economics professor, what will the long-run equilibrium
prices be for firm 1 and 2.
We can express the two firms’ total cost function as C1= 2Q1 and C2 = 2Q2. When we set
the profit so that it is equal to $20,000 for firm 1, we find that:
3
Solving for P1, we have P1 = 42.83 or 1,961.63, but at price 42.83 firm 1 produces Q1 =
489.8 at the lower average cost. Solving for firm 2 in a similar manner, we find that firm
2 will produce Q2 = 795.4 at a price of $27.
b) Is the price of each firm’s product forced down to the level of the marginal cost of
the seaweed?
No, see the answer to Part a). (still have to consider the opportunity cost of being a
professor)
4.Consider an economy with the supply of soccer balls qs = 4p and the demand for
soccer balls given by qs = 270 – 5p.
First we write both supply and demand having price on the left hand side,
4
c) Calculate both the consumer and producer surplus.
Now suppose the government imposes a sales tax, such that consumers much pay $5 to
the government each time they buy a soccer ball.
Now consumers pay $5 more for each unit of soccer ball that they purchase, there fore
new demand curve is:
e) Draw a graph marking the after tax consumer surplus and producer surplus as
well as the tax revenue
5
f) Calculate the consumer surplus, the producer surplus, and the dead-weight loss.