0% found this document useful (0 votes)
53 views

Midterm Examination: Economics 210A: November 6, 2013

1) The consumer has a CES utility function. Their Marshallian, indirect, and expenditure functions are derived. The Hicksian demand functions are also found. 2) A 3-good consumer problem is analyzed. Expressions are derived for the amount spent on good 1 and the Marshallian demands. 3) A log utility function is examined. It is not homogeneous but is homothetic. The gradient at a point is calculated and a directional derivative is found.

Uploaded by

thanhpham0505
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
53 views

Midterm Examination: Economics 210A: November 6, 2013

1) The consumer has a CES utility function. Their Marshallian, indirect, and expenditure functions are derived. The Hicksian demand functions are also found. 2) A 3-good consumer problem is analyzed. Expressions are derived for the amount spent on good 1 and the Marshallian demands. 3) A log utility function is examined. It is not homogeneous but is homothetic. The gradient at a point is calculated and a directional derivative is found.

Uploaded by

thanhpham0505
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 5

Name

Midterm Examination: Economics 210A


November 6, 2013
Answer Question 1 and any 3 of the remaining 4 questions. Good luck.

1 ) A consumer has utility function


1
u(x1 , x2 ) = 1 4 .
x1 + x2

A) Find this consumer’s Marshallian demand function for each good.


Answer:
m
x1 (p1 , p2 , m) = 1/2 1/2
p1 + 2p1 p2
2m
x2 (p1 , p2 , m) = 1/2 1/2
2p2 + p1 p2
B) Find this consumer’s indirect utility function.
Answer: You can get your answer by substituting the Marshallian demands
that you found into the definition of indirect utility which is

v(p, m) = u(x1 (p, m), x2 (p, m)).


m
v(p1 , p2 , m) = 1/2 1/2
p1 + 4p1 p2 + 4p2
Another way of writing the same answer is
m
v(p1 , p2 , m) =  2
1/2 1/2
p1 + 2p2

C) Find this consumer’s expenditure function.


Since v(p, e(p, u)) = u, it follows that

e(p1 , p2 , u)
1/2 1/2
=u
p1 + 4p1 p2 + 4p2
and therefore
 
1/2 1/2
e(p1 , p2 , u) = u p1 + 4p1 p2 + 4p2 .

A side remark: To check your answer (and see how these structures are
related), you could notice that the denominator of the indirect utility function is

1
a CES function of the p’s. You might recall from our classroom discussion that
if a utility function is of the form

(c1 xa1 + c2 xa2 )1/a

then the corresponding expenditure function is of the form

(c01 pb1 + c02 pb2 )1/b u.

When this is the case, the elasticity of substitution of the direct utility function
is 1/(1 − a) and the elasticity of substitution of the indirect utility function,
which is 1/(1 − b) must be inverses of each other. That is, 1/(1 − b) = 1 − a.
Solving this equation for b, we have b = −a/(1 − a). In our example, a = −1,
so b = 1/2. Thus the expenditure function is of the form
1/2 1/2
e(p1 , p2 , u) = u(c01 p1 + c02 p2 )2 u.
1/2
We also showed that c0i = cσi = ci , So we would have
 2  
1/2 1/2 1/2 1/2
e(p1 , p2 , u) = p1 + 2p2 u = p1 + 4p1 p2 + 4p2 u.

D) Find this consumer’s Hicksian demand function for each good.


The Hicksian demands are equal to the corresponding partial derivatives of
the expenditure function.
We find
−1/2 1/2
h1 (p1 , p2 , u) = u(1 + 2p1 p2 )
and
1/2 −1/2
h2 (p1 , p2 , u) = u(4 + 2p1 p2 ).

E) Find the income and substitution effects of a change in the price of good 1
on the demand for good 1.
The substitution effect is the partial derivative of h1 (p1 , p2 , m) with respect
to p1 . That is
1/2 −3/2
−up2 p1 .
We may want to express this substitution effect entirely as a function of prices
and income. Thus we would make use of the fact that u = v(p1 , p2 , m). Then
we have the substitution effect is
1/2 −3/2
−mp2 p1
1/2 1/2
p1 + 4p1 p2 + 4p2
The income effect is
∂x(p1 , p2 , m) m
−x1 (p1 , p2 ) = − 2
∂m 1/2 1/2
p1 + 2p1 p2

2
2) A consumer has utility function
1 √
u(x1 , x2 , x3 ) = 1 4 + 2 x3 .
x1 + x2

A) If this consumer has income m and the prices of the three goods are p1 , p2 ,
and p3 , how much of her income will she spend on good 1. (Hint: make use of
part B of your answer to the previous question.)
Answer: If the consumer spends a total of s on goods 3 then she will get s/p3
units of good 3 and will have m − s left to spend on goods 1 and 2. Her utility
will then be
p p m−s
2 s/p3 + v(p1 , p2 , m − s) = 2 s/p3 +  2 .
1/2 1/2
p1 + 2p2

She will choose s to maximize this. At an interior maximum, the derivative


of this expression with respect to s must be zero. Then
 2
1/2 1/2
(sp3 )1/2 − p1 + 2p2 =0

and so  4
1/2 1/2
p1 + 2p2
s= . (1)
p3
and total expenditure on goods 1 and 2 is
 4
1/2 1/2
p1 + 2p2
m−s=m− (2)
p3
B) Write down the consumer’s Marshallian demand function for each good.
(Hint: make use of your answer to parts A of this question and the previous
question.)
Answer: The consumer will choose to allocate the expenditure m − s between
goods 1 and 2 in such a way as to maximize utility subject to p1 x2 +p2 x2 = m−s.
So we can just apply the Marshallian demand functions from Problem 1 with
income m − s These are:

  4 
1/2 1/2 !
m−s p1 + 2p2 1
x1 (p1 , p2 , m) = = m −
 
1/2 1/2 p3
 1/2 1/2
p1 + 2p1 p2 p1 + 2p1 p2

  4 
1/2 1/2 !
2(m − s) p1 + 2p2 2
x2 (p1 , p2 , m) = = m −
 
1/2 1/2 p3
 1/2 1/2
2p2 + p1 p2 2p2 + p1 p2

3
An excellent answer would also note that there will be an interior solution if
and only if   4 
1/2 1/2
p 1 + 2p2
m −  > 0.
 
p3

If this inequality is reversed, there will be a corner solution in which the con-
sumer consumes only good 3.

3 ) Consider the function

f (x1 , x2 , x3 ) = ln x21 + x22 + x23 .




Explain your answers do each of the following questions:


A) Is the function f homogeneous? If so, of what degree?

Answer: No. f (tx) = ln t2 f (x) = 2 ln t + f (x). A function is homogeneous


if and only if f (tx) = tk f (x) for all t and some k. There is no value of k such
that 2 ln t + f (x) = tk f (x).
B) Is the function f homothetic?

Answer: Yes. f (x) is a strictly increasing function of the homogeneous


function x21 + x22 + x23 .
C) Find the gradient vector of f at the point (x1 , x2 , x3 ) = (1, 3, 5).

The gradient is (2/35, 6/35, 10/35).


D) At the point (1, 3, 5), find the directional derivative of f in the direction
(2/9, −2/9, 1/9).

Answer: For the directional derivative in the direction of a vector x, we need


to takepthe inner product of the gradient with the normalized vector x/|x| where
|x| = x21 + x22 + x23 . In our case, x/|x| = (2/3, −2/3, 1/3)
The directional derivative is
1 2
(2 × 2 − 6 × 2 + 10 × 1) = .
3 × 35 105

2 ) Ada and Bo both have have convex preferences defined on a set X, but
their preferences are not identical.
A) Let x be a commodity bundle in X. Let A be the set of bundles that both
Ada and Bob like better than x. Is A necessarily a convex set? If so, prove it.
If not, show a counterexample.
Answer: If Ada and Bob both have convex preferences, then the sets A and
B are both context sets. The set of bundles that both like better than x is the
set A ∩ B. The intersection of two convex sets is a convex set. (A good answer
would also prove this last claim.)

4
B) Let x be a commodity bundle in X. Let C be the set of bundles such that if
z ∈ C, then z = yA + yB for some yA ∈ X and yB ∈ X, z = yA + yB such that
Ada prefers yA to x and Bo prefers yB to x. Is C necessarily a convex set. If
so, prove it. If not, show a counterexample.
Answer: This is true. Let z and z 0 be two points in C. Then z = yA + yB
for some yA ∈ A and some yB ∈ B and z 0 = yA 0
+ yB0 0
for some yA ∈ A and
some yB ∈ B. Now for any λ between 0 and 1, and any two points z and z 0 in
0

C, let z(λ) = λz + (1 − λ)z 0 . Then


0 0
z(λ) = (λyA + (1 − λ)yA ) + (λyB + (1 − λyB )) .
0
Since A and B are convex sets, it must be that λyA + (1 − λ)yA ∈ A and
0
λyB + (1 − λyB ) ∈ B. Since
0 0
z(λ) = (λyA + (1 − λ)yA ) + (λyB + (1 − λyB )) ,

it must be that z(λ) ∈ C and hence C is a convex set.

5) Will’s preferences are represented by the utility function


1/2 1/2
u(x1 , x2 ) = min{x1 x2 , x2 }.

A) Draw a couple of indifference curves for Will.


Answer: Let good 1 be on the horizontal axis and good 2 on the vertical
axis. To draw a typical indifference curve for Will, take a point (x, x) on the
diagonal. The indifference curve through this point includes a straight horizontal
line extending to the right of true point (x, x) and above and to the left of (x, x)
is the locus of points (x1 , x2 ) satisfying the equation x1 x2 = x.
B) Find Will’s Marshallian demand functions for goods 1 and 2.
Answer:
If p1 ≤ p2 , x1 (p1 , p2 ) = x2 (p1 , p2 ) = m/(p1 + p2 ).
If p1 > p2 , then x1 = m/(2p1 ) and x2 = m/(2p2 ).

You might also like