Growth and Models
Growth and Models
Introduction
Despite the obvious interest in economic growth from the outset, the
first widely applied model of growth was the Harrod – Domar Model,
named after the separate writings of Roy Harrod (1948) and Evsey
Domar (1946). Keynes biographer, the Cambridge economist Roy –
Harrod asked whether an economist Evsey Domar a professor at
Brandels University independently investigated the circumstances
under which a growing economy could sustain full employment. The
resulting Harrod – Domar Model focused on “dynamic theory on the
relations between savings, investment and output”. Essentially, the
model argued that the national savings rate (the fraction of income
saved) had to be equal to the product of the capital – output ratio and
the rate of growth of the effective labour force if the economy was to
keep its stock of plant and equipment in balance with its supply of
labour so that the steady growth could occur.
Harrod and Domar tried to put together two of the key features of the
keynessian economics i.e. the multiplier and the accelerator in one
model that explained the courses of long run economic growth. The
model rose out of necessity of ensuring long term full employment
equilibrium in developed economies. Both of them mere interested in
discovering the rate of income growth necessary for a smooth and
uninterrupted working of the economy. In their analysis they
assigned a key role of investments in the process of economic
growth. They did consider capital accumulation a dual role to play in
investments. First investments creates incomes and secondly it
arguments the existing productive capacity by increasing its capital
stock i.e demand and supply effects.
To illustrate the Harrod – Domar model let’s assume that there are
two factors of production i.e. labour and capital combined in fixed
proportions to produce a single good (L & K). The fixed proportion
assumption (which is an equivalent to L-shaped isoquants) means
that the ratio of capital to labour used in production is given and
invariable. Also it is assumed that the economy is a closed one so
that any output that is not consumed is given over purely for capital
investments introducing as the proportion of output saved in each
period and as δ as the rate of depreciation of capital (0≤ δ ≤ 1)
allows us to state the evolution of capital stock.
Ќ = I – δK
Ќ = SY – δK (1)
Ќ = SY – δK (2)
K K K
Ќ =S
K V
Gw = S
V
The major stumbling block of the Harrod Domar model is that long
run equilibrium growth can only be attained if the warranted and
natural rates are equal. If this is not the case of economy will be
subject to prolonged periods of escalating unemployment (gn < gw).
However, S, v, n and & are all exogenous to the model and there is
little reason to believe that they will just happen to all take the
necessary values so that gw and gn will equate!
Several methods of extending the Harrod Domar model were
proposed so that the achievement of steady state growth might
become the norm instead of the exception Nicholas Kaldor (1962)
suggested that the saving rate was in fact an endogenous variable,
whose value would fluctuate until the Harrod Domar consistency
condition for steady state growth (gw = gn) was achieved. To outline
the mechanism through which this may occur consider the saving
rate, s, to be a weighed average of the saving rate of (poor)wage
earners and (richer) profit earners. If the natural growth rate is
initially greater than the warranted rate, the economy will experience
growing unemployment with the consequence that wage fall relative
to profit. This is equivalent to a proportional shift in the distribution of
income in favour of profit earners, which itself will lead to an increase
in this manner until the warranted growth rate equals the natural rate.
The classical economists would surely have been inclined to suggest
a different solution, one in which the natural rate of growth is
endogenous. Malthus (1978) argued that population growth has a
natural tendency to outstrip the food supply leading to ‘misery and
vice’. This will result in population reduction through two
mechanisms, (1) a falling fertility rate as per capita income falls (i.e.
rising fertility rate with prosperity), and (2) extreme population –
reducing disasters (such as famine and pandemics). The reason that
growth have seemed reluctant to incorporate Maltus’ideas is probably
because of empirical evidence that shows that the fertility rate is in
fact negatively related to income (except at very low income levels)
and also because the processes of industrialization and technical
progress have to date, allowed many countries to escape Malthus’
pessimistic predictions. However, his theory still seems to have
some relevance today for less developed countries (LDCs) as
regretfully evidenced by recent famines in Africa. To incorporate
Malthus’ ‘iron Law of Wages’ into the Harrod Domar model, again
assume that the natural rate initially exceeds the warranted rate.
Above, we saw how an endogenous saving rate may fluctuate in
order to obtain the consistency condition. In this case, however,
excess population growth reduces the wage rate, which leads to
falling fertility and increasing mortality until the natural and warranted
rates are once again equal.
Harrod and Domar also make the untenable assumption that labour
and capital are used in fixed proportions. Generally labour can be
substituted for capital and the economy can move more smoothly
towards a path of steady growth. In fact, unlike Harrod’s mode, this
path is not so unstable that the economy should experience chronic
inflation or unemployment if the rate of growth of output in given
period of time does not coincide with the warrant rate of growth of
output does not coincide with the ‘warrant rate of growth’ or the full
capacity rate of growth of income.
The Harrod Domar models are based on the assumption that there is
no government intervention in economic activities which is not
applicable to underdeveloped countries, which can not develop
without government help. In such countries, the state plays the role
of “pioneer entrepreneur in starting large industries and regulating
and directing private enterprise.
This paper first presents the model (Solow’s Growth model) then
gives a detailed assessment of it and outlines the assumptions on
which it is based.
K = sY (1)
Where K stands for dK/dt
Output is produced by capital and labour. The production function is
hence given as:
Y = F(K,L) (2)
K = sF(K,L) (3)
The model takes into account the fact that population grows
exogenously and that labour force increases exponentially at a
constant rate n. The available supply of labour at time t (L9t) ) is
dependent on the compound rate of growth of labour force from one
period to another.
Loent Thus
The above equation gives the time path that capital accumulation K
must follow if labour is to remain fully employed. Once the time path
of the capital stock and of the labour force are known, the
corresponding time path of real output can be computed from the
production function.
R = sF(r,1)-nr
From the above equation, the rate of change of capital labour ratio ®
is the difference of two terms, one representing the increment of
capital (sF(r,1) and the other increment in labour (nr). The economy’s
behaviour when capital labour ratio is changing can be illustrated
diagrammatically as ;
The line nr which has a slope of n shows how fast the capital output
ratio would be declining for a given rate of growth of the labour force
if savings were zero. While the line sF(r-1), which has a slope s
shows how fast the capital output ratios would be growing as a result
of capital accumulation if the labour force were not growing. If both s
and n are non zero, the actual value of r is the difference between nr
and sF(r-1), represented by the vertical distance between the two
lines.
When the capital labour ratio (r) = 0 (constant), the capital stock
expands at the same rate as the labour force (n). Assuming constant
returns to scale, real output would also grow at the same relative rate
(n). Once an equilibrium capital – labour ratio r1 is established, it will
be maintained. The equilibrium r1 is stable and any divergence from
r1 would lead to movements towards r1, if r < r1 it would mean that nr
> sF(r, 1), which imply that capital accumulation outweighs population
growth and r will be positive, leading to an increase in r towards r1. If
on the other hand r > r1 would mean that nr>sF(r, 1), which imply that
population growth outweighs capital accumulation and r will be
negative, leading to a decrease in r towards r1. Hence at r1 there will
be balanced growth equilibrium also referred to as the balanced
growth path where each variable (capital and labour) grows at a
constant rate. This equilibrium exists if the production function ins
Cobb-Douglas because the slope of sF(r, 1) is infinite at the origin
and falls steadily as r increases.
Solow’s model could not address all the above concerns within its
simplified form and assumptions. Solow (1970) recognizes the
limitation of his simplified model in addressing all aspects of
economic life. Nevertheless, his model is an improvement of the
Harrod Domar’s model as he develops a continued production
function in which capital and labour can be varied to allow for steady
stage growth and steady state growth paths.
Solow recognizes that may inputs i.e capital (investment) labour and
technological innovations can create output. Hence the model
provided a basis for measuring what factors were contributing to
growth. He further recognizes the importance of technological
progress and increasing returns to scale. When capital/output ratio is
constant, the capital/labour ratio must be constant, however, with
introduction of technological progress, capital and output could both
rise through time faster than employment. Hence, continues
innovation staves off the effect of diminishing returns and allows
economy to experience rise in capital and output per man. The
model further shows that with variable technical coefficient, there
would be a tendency for capital – labour ratio to adjust in the direction
of equilibrium ratio. If initial ratio of capital to labour is more, capital
and output would grow more slowly than labour force and vice versa.
The model indicate that the long run rate of growth is determined by
an expanding labour force and technical progress, thus, differences in
income levels between rich and poor countries are due primarily to
differences in rates of investment in physical and human capital over
long periods of time and that if all economies have similar parameters
and access to common pool of technology, all countries would
eventually converge with rich countries. This applicable in the case
of some poor countries, which grew fast to be on the level with the
developed countries in the 20th century. It is however worth noting
that some poor countries have however remained poor despite world
wide technological progress mainly due to other factors such as civil
plagues etc.
Solow points out that may possibilities of growth exist. He shows
more possibilities; one where the economy is highly productive and
increment in capital is realized faster than the growth of labour force,
thus resulting in full employment; and the other where the economy is
highly unproductive thus resulting in full employment path that leads
to diminishing per capita income.
Some major deficiencies in the model are that; it does not include any
fixed natural resources such as land and the problem of growing
population pressing against a fixed supply of land and other
resources; it has no investment function and does not take into
account the role of future entrepreneurial expectations; the model has
no monetary sector and ignores impact of interest rates thus the
problems of possible instabilities caused by the behaviour of demand
and supply of money is not handled; the assumption of homogeneous
capital is unrealistic as capital goods are highly heterogeneous and
thus pose problem of aggregation and determination of steady growth
path; lastly, the model ignore the problems of inducing technical
progress through the process of learning, investment research and
capital accumulation.
This model claims that there exist two societies in the world – rich
and poor. There are also existing and persisting divergence on
several levels between rich and poor countries, as well as rich and
poor people (e.g slums next to luxurious mansions) on several levels.
Those two different kinds of society are not independence from each
other but integrated. NO “trickle down effect” of progress from rich to
poor can be observed.
Growth = ∆O = I x ∆O
O O I
Growth = ∆O = ∆L + ∆(O/L)
O L (O/L)
Note: with the above shortcomings the use of other social and
economic indicators represent an advance on the crude
measurement of GNP.
There are two principal reasons for this. The first Engel’s law. In the
19th century Evrst Engel discovered that as incomes of family’s nose,
the proportion of their budget spent on food declined. Since the main
function of the agricultural output would not grow as rapidly as
demand for industrial goods. The relationship holds for all countries
that have experienced sustained development.