Heterogeneous Firms and Aggregate Prices: Instructor: Thomas Chaney Econ 357 - International Trade (PH.D.)
Heterogeneous Firms and Aggregate Prices: Instructor: Thomas Chaney Econ 357 - International Trade (PH.D.)
1
1 Ghironi and Melitz (2005)
2
Balassa (1964) and Samuelson (1964), since there was also a massive
migration of workers into California. This migration of workers arguably
dampened the e¤ect of a rise in prices. However, the productivity in gold
mining in California was so high that the e¤ect still persisted.
Ironically, the initial dream of John Sutter, that came to a quick end
with the discovery of gold, was partially similar to the gold rush. Sutter
had bet on the high productivity of agriculture in California, much higher
than in most of the world. Since agricultural goods are, to some extent,
a tradeable good, this high productivity must have initially increased
the prices in California. For some reason, California keeps …nding new
tradeable sectors where the Californian productivity is much higher than
anywhere else (agriculture, gold, movies, information technologies, sandy
beaches), so that Californian prices basically have stayed pretty high
ever since the arrival of John Sutton. Palo Alto, Orange County or
San Francisco are arguably still among the places where life is most
expensive.
The French writer Blaise Cendrars wrote a marvelous novel in 1925,
L’Or (Sutter’s Gold, 1926, for the English translation), on the tragic
character of John Sutter, the Swiss immigrant who built an empire which
was destroyed overnight when it was discovered that this empire stood
on a pile of gold.
3
Unlike the initial Melitz (2003) model, this model is fully dynamic
(not only steady state dynamics).
4
Note that in the absence of endogenous entry (due here to the ex-
istence of …xed costs of entry), none of these channels would exist.
Absent endogenous entry, home (e¤ective) labor would actually
depreciate. If the number of …rms were …xed, the higher produc-
tivity at home would lead to more demand for foreign goods, hence
an excess demand for (e¤ective) foreign labor, and therefore an ap-
preciation of foreign labor.
Note also that in this model, strictly speaking, all goods are po-
tentially tradeable. In equilibrium, only a subset of goods will
be actually traded though. So this model is able to explain why
the price of tradeable goods increases following an increase in the
productivity in the tradeable sector, which we observe in the data
(empirically, it is not only the price of non tradeable goods that
increases following an increase in productivity). If one were to add
an exogenously non tradeable sector in this economy, the prices in
that sector would obviously increase (this is the traditional Bal-
assa/Samuelson model). This would complement the increase in
the price of tradeable goods described here.
5
– With …xed overhead cost of for domestic production, not all
domestic …rms survive. Assume that following a reduction in
overall productivity, the threshold for survival (domestically)
will …rst jump, and then gradually go down, to a higher level
than before the productivity shock.
– At each point along the transition, the distribution of surviv-
ing …rms is not simply a truncation of the underlying produc-
tivity distribution at birth. The lower tail of the distribution
of survivor has been shaped by the entire history of entry
since the initial productivity shock.
– When an entrepreneur contemplate whether or not to enter,
she has to form expectations of her future pro…ts. The pro…ts
she would earn at each point in time depends on whom she
may have to compete against. This depends both on who will
enter the market in the future (forward looking expectation),
but also on the entire history of who has entered the market
(which determines the distribution of …rms at each point in
time). So when making an entry decision, an entrepreneur is
both looking forward, and looking backward.
– Even numerically, this makes this problem intractable (or
computationally to heavy). The theorist has to guess not
only a path for future variables (prices, so simple numbers),
but also a path for the expectations of each cohort, which
itself depends (in a complicated fashion) on the guess for the
path of prices. Recursive methods do not work here.
The model:
Let us go rather quickly over the model. The model basically fol-
lows Melitz (2003) very closely, using the same trick of de…ning special
averages which simplify the analysis greatly.
6
actually consumed (accessible) in period t will be determined in
equilibrium.
pt (!)
ct (!) = Ct
Pt
0 111
Z
with Pt = @ pt (!)1 d! A
!2 t
P
with Qt "t Ptt the real exchange rate, and "t the nominal exchange
rate.
7
Pro…ts: A …rm with productivity z earn pro…ts, dt (z), that it
redistributes to the owners of the …rm as dividends. The total
pro…ts come from two potential sources: pro…ts on the domestic
market dD;t , and pro…ts from exporting, dX;t (z),
8
>
> dt (z) = dD;t (z) + dX;t (z)
>
< dD;t = 1 1
(D;t (z) Ct
Qt 1 wt fX;t
>
> (z) Ct if …rm exports,
> X;t
: dX;t (z) = 0 otherwise Zt
d~t dD;t (~
zD ) + [1 G (zX;t )] dX;t (~
zX;t )
8
and compare it to the cost of entry, wt fE;t =Zt . The free entry
condition implies that, provided that at time t, some …rms enter,
then,
v~t = wt fE;t =Zt
The total number of home …rms at time t is the sum of the …rms
that have survived the exogenous death shock from the previous
period, and the new entrants,
9
Budget constraint and Euler equations: Consumers earn in-
come from their labor (inelastically supplied), from the shares they
own in the mutual fund, and from the bonds they hold. They spend
their income on consumption, buy shares in the mutual fund, and
buy riskless bonds,
with xt the fraction of all shares in the mutual fund held by house-
holds. The …rst order conditions for consumption give the following
Euler equations,
Ct = (1 ) Et Ct+1
" #
Ct+1
and v~t = (1 ) Et v~t+1 + d~t+1
Ct
Bt+1 = Bt = 0
xt+1 = xt = 1
) Ct = wt L + ND;t d~t NE;t v~t
Solving for the equilibrium: Ghironi and Melitz list all the
equilibrium conditions, and all the unknown variables. This is in
essence a dynamic problem, agents are forward looking, and one
ought to solve for the entire path of future prices and quantities
along the equilibrium path (whether stationary steady state or
not). The stationary equilibrium is rather "simple" to solve for, it
10
is merely an extension of Melitz (2003) with asymmetric countries.
The non stationary equilibrium has to be solved numerically. All
numerical simulations are shown in the paper.
~ 1t
Q = (2sD 1) TOLt
(1 sD ) ~zX;t ~zX;t (tt tt )
1 ND
+ sD ND;t NX;t ND;t NX;t
1 ND + NX
with T OL "t (Wt =Zt ) (Wt =Zt ) the "terms of labor", and sD;t
1
ND;t ~D;t the share of spending on domestic goods.
There are 3 e¤ects through which an increase in productivity at
home will lead to an appreciation of the real exchange rate.
11
barriers ,consumers spend more income on domestically pro-
duced goods than on foreign goods. The prices of non traded
goods at home relative to abroad go up, so that the real ex-
change rate appreciates.
Note that up to here, we have not looked at the endoge-
nous change in the set of actually traded good. Unlike in
the original Balassa-Samuelson model, there is however an
appreciation of the real exchange rate despite the fact that
productivity of both traded and non traded goods went up.
In the Balassa-Samuelson model, if the productivity of both
sectors goes up, there will be no e¤ect on the real exchange
rate. The di¤erence here is that we have assumed free en-
try of …rms. Because …rms are allowed to enter, an increase
in domestic productivity will put some upward pressure on
domestic wages, and because some goods are non traded in
equilibrium, domestic prices go up.
2. This increase in the domestic wages will also change endoge-
nously the set of domestic exporters. Because domestic wages
have gone up, it becomes harder for domestic …rms to export,
and symmetrically it becomes easier for foreign …rms to ex-
port. The productivity cuto¤ for exports at home goes up,
the cuto¤ abroad goes down. Hence, domestic consumers now
consume on average more expensive imports (they start im-
porting expensive goods from low productivity new foreign
exporters), whereas foreign consumers now consume on av-
erage cheaper imports (they stop importing expensive goods
from low productivity domestic …rms that stop exporting).
Note that this is not a statement about the total volume of
exports: there are more …rms at home, so potentially home
exports more. It is a statement about the composition of ex-
porters. Among those (more numerous) domestic …rms, only
the most productive ones export. This increase in the average
price of imports, and reduction in the average price of exports
will further increase the real exchange rate.
This e¤ect was altogether absent in the Balassa-Samuelson
model, where the tradedness of goods was exogenously pos-
tulated. In this model with endogenous tradedness of goods,
changes in
3. The last e¤ect is a corollary to the increase in the number of
domestic …rms. Because consumers value variety, as the va-
riety of goods available at home relative to the variety avail-
12
able abroad increases, domestic consumers will switch their
expenditure towards domestic goods. Because domestic va-
rieties are more expensive (due to the increased labor cost),
this further increases the price of the consumption basket of
domestic consumers. This is that last e¤ect through which
the real exchange rate appreciates.
Note that the endogenous entry of …rms is key to derive those pre-
dictions. Absent entry of domestic …rms which drive the domestic
wages up, a productivity gain at home would actually depreciate
e¤ective domestic labor: workers become more e¢ cient at produc-
ing goods, they ‡ood the world market with domestic goods, this
drives down the relative wage of domestic goods (provided that we
are not considering a small open economy that would not have any
impact on world prices). In units of e¤ective labor, wages would
go down.
Ghironi and Melitz also make the important remark that the be-
havior of "real exchange rates" does not re‡ect movements in rel-
ative ideal price indices. If one were to take into account the
impact of variety on ideal price indices, the increased availability
of domestic varieties at home would unambiguously dominate the
increase in average prices, so that the domestic ideal price index
would decrease relative to the foreign one.
13
over space, we will typically observe catastrophic agglomeration. Fur-
thermore, history matters, in the sense that agglomerations of workers
are typically self-sustainable, so that historical accidents can explain the
observed patterns of the geographic distribution of production facilities.
I will not go into the details of these models, but only sketch Krug-
man’s argument for agglomeration forces, developed among others in
Krugman 1991. Consider a simple model with two potential locations,
and with some initial distribution of workers between the two locations.
Those two locations are separated by trade barriers. In the location
with more workers, more goods are produced. Because of the existence
of trade barriers, welfare will be higher in the location with more goods.
That means that real wages are higher in the location with more work-
ers. Absent any force that keeps the workers in the unfavored location,
workers will emigrate towards the better location. As more and more
workers move towards the crowded location, real wage di¤erentials keep
increasing, so that workers keep moving. Eventually, we converge to a
"core-periphery" system, where all workers are in the core, and no one is
left in the periphery. One interesting pattern is that if initially the two
locations are exactly identical, any small shock will trigger a catastrophic
agglomeration.
Since that pioneering paper, a whole literature has developed that
tries to explain the patterns of specialization of countries/region, and
more generally the patterns of the geographic distribution of production
across space. The key insight of this literature is to take into account
the fact that in the presence of trade barriers, real wages will generically
di¤er across country, which gives rise to some incentive for workers to
change location.
14
2.2 Stylized facts about international relative prices
Beyond the PPP puzzle, Atkeson and Burstein (2005) list some
stylized facts of international aggregate prices time series. Those
stylized facts are not trivially understood with a simple model of
open economies. They develop a model with endogenous pricing
to market to explain qualitatively those facts. They then go one
step further, calibrate their model and try to match quantitatively
those facts. They do a pretty good job at matching those facts
quantitatively, and in addition are able to tell which assumption
crucially matters for getting each fact right.
The main two stylized facts (in addition to departures from even
relative PPP) that Atkeson and Burstein focus on are the following:
First, the terns if trade in the manufacturing sector are less volatile
than the relative prices of manufacturing goods.
Second, the ‡uctuations of the relative prices of tradeable con-
sumption goods are almost as volatile as the ‡uctuations of the
relative prices of all consumption goods.
Let’s go in more detail over each stylized fact, and why they may be
surprising, or not trivial:
PPI EP I PPI IP I
=
eP P I IP I EP I eP P I
| {z } | {z } | {z } | {z }
relative prices manuf. manuf. over import over foreign
of manuf. TOT export prices manuf. prices
15
Atkeson and Burstein …nd that the relative price of manufacturing
goods is much more volatile than the manufacturing terms of trade.
By construction, it must therefore mean that the relative price of
domestically produced goods exported and sold domestically also
move, and/or that the relative price of foreign produced goods
imported and sold abroad move as well.
Atkeson and Burstein take this fact as an indirect evidence of "pric-
ing to market". As shocks hit the home and the foreign economy,
both domestic and foreign exporters adjust the price they charge
PPI
abroad relative to the price they charge at home, so that both EP I
IP I
and eP P I move.
Pricing to market: Pricing to market corresponds to the fact
that exporters set di¤erent prices for the same good sold at home
or abroad, and that they adjust the relative price that they charge
in each market depending on the condition on each market. Dorn-
busch (1987) and Krugman (1987) developed early models of pric-
ing to market.
Obstfeld and Rogo¤ (2001) describe 2 extreme scenarios for the
pricing strategy of …rms. If exporters set the nominal price of
their exports …xed in the domestic currency (that is an price equal
or at least proportional to the price they set domestically), then
PPI
neither EP I
nor ePIPPII will move, and the manufacturing terms
of trade will move exactly one-for-one with the relative prices of
manufacturing goods. The other extreme corresponds to a case
where exporters set the nominal prices of their exports …xed in the
PPI
foreign currency. In that case, then both EP I
and ePIPPII will move
one-for-one with the relative prices in manufacturing. In that case,
the terms of trade will move one-for-one with the relative prices of
manufacturing, but in the exact opposite direction. The reality is
somewhere in between those two extreme cases.
It is not trivial to derive a model that would have such character-
istics (the simple Krugman model of trade wouldn’t for instance).
However, composition e¤ects in the Melitz (2003) model would give
similar predictions at the aggregate, and so would the Dornbusch,
Fischer and Samuelson model with trade barriers (maybe, I’m not
sure though...).
16
indices at home and abroad (normalized for the nominal interest
rate). If we call the CPI at home P , and abroad P , and if we call
the consumption price index of only tradeable goods P T at home
and P T abroad, we can decompose the consumption based real
exchange rate into 2 components,
P PT P=P T
RER =
eP eP T P =P T
= RERT RERN
Atkeson and Burstein …nd that relative prices of the tradeable part
of consumption goods is almost as volatile as the relative prices of
overall consumption goods. This is true despite the fact that more
than half of consumption goods are non tradeable.
The fact that the prices of tradeable goods moves as much as the
prices of non tradeable goods seems to suggest that at the ag-
gregate level, trade arbitrages only play a minimal role. If trade
arbitrages were large, the relative prices of tradeable goods would
not move as much. They may still move if there are some trade
barriers that prevent full arbitrage of price di¤erentials, but unless
trade barriers are large, they shouldn’t move too much. In the
end, the theoretical answer put forward by Atkeson and Burstein
to that "puzzle" is indeed that trade barriers are large, so that
for most tradeable goods, arbitraging price di¤erentials between
countries is not worth it.
Note however that reality is micro and not macro. For some goods,
trade arbitrages do take place (to some extent). But since most
goods are not actually traded, those arbitrages do not have a large
impact.
17
of tradeable goods cTi , and a composite of non tradeable goods cN
i ,
they derive a utility ci ,
1
ci = cTi cN
i
1
Pi = PiT PiN
cN
i = yijN dj
0
Z 1 1
1
1
PiN = PijN dj
0
!
yijN PijN
=
cN
i PiN
yijN = N
qijk
k=1
!11
X
K
1
N N
Pijk = Pijk
k=1
!
N N
qijk Pijk
=
yijN PijN
18
Assumption:
1< <
This means that goods are more substitutable within sectors than
they are between sectors (and then, the elasticity of substitution
between tradeable and non tradeable goods is simply equal to 1).
N " (s) W
Pijk (s) = N
" (s) 1 zijk
"Bertrand (s) = s + (1 s)
with 1
"Cournot (s) = (s 1 + (1 s) 1
)
1
!1
N N N N
Pijk qijk Pijk Pijk
and sN
ijk = PK = PK 1 =
N N
l=1 Pijl qijl
N PijN
l=1 Pijl
Atkeson and Burstein very cleverly use the properties of the CES
preferences. It turns out that a …rm with a market share s will
charge a constant mark-up over its marginal cost. The mark-up
that this …rm charges depends on some theoretical elasticity of
substitution. If …rms compete Bertrand, this elasticity is exactly
the demand elasticity that this …rm faces (which indeed depends
on its market share). If …rms compete Cournot, it’s a similar
elasticity.
19
cost. This mark-up depends on how substitutable goods between
industries are. It is simply the Dixit-Stiglitz mark-up, 1 .
In the other extreme case of in…nitely many …rms within a given
sector on the other hand, each individual …rm does not a¤ect the
price index in that sector. It will therefore charge a constant mark-
up over marginal cost. This mark-up depends on how substitutable
the goods are within this sector. It will therefore charge the Dixit-
Stliglitz mark-up 1 .
In the intermediate case of a …rm with only some market share,
the …rm will have to take into account the impact it has on aggre-
gate prices. It will charge a mark-up in between the two extreme
cases. A larger …rm takes into account the impact it has on sec-
toral prices. It mainly has to compete against other sectors, and
therefore charges a mark-up close to 1 . A smaller …rm on the
other hand mainly has to compete against other …rms in the sec-
tor. The fraction of income that consumers spend on goods from
that sector depends on the aggregate price index of goods in that
sector. A small …rm has only a negligible impact on this aggregate
price. Taking the prices set by its competitors as given, it there-
fore takes as given the share of income consumers spend on goods
from that sector. The only impact of changing the price of its
own variety will be that the …rm loses market shares against other
…rms in the same sector, not that the entire sector loses market
shares against other sectors in the economy. Since goods are more
substitutable within the sector than between sectors, it will charge
a lower mark-up, close to 1 .
The very cute …nding of Atkeson and Burstein is that the mark-up
charged by a …rm exactly corresponds to the mark-up a …rm would
charge if it faced a demand elasticity equal to a weighted average
of the within sector and the between sector elasticity.
Atkeson and Burstein versus BEJK: BEJK considered an-
other case of imperfect competition. Their …nding was a much
cruder strategy for the …rm: either competition from other …rms
in the sector binds, and a …rm charges a cost equal to the marginal
cost of the second lowest cost in the sector; or the competition of
…rms within the sector doesn’t bind, and the …rm charges a mark-
up equal to the Dixit-Stiglitz mark-up. In Atkeson and Burstein,
we have an intermediate case where both the competition of …rms
within the sector and of …rms in other sectors always matters. It’s
not one or the other. Whether the competition of …rms within the
sector of …rms in other sectors matters more depends on the size
20
of the …rm. Large …rms care more about the competition from
other sectors, small …rms from the competition within the sector.
Formally, BEJK simply corresponds to the extreme case where
= +1.
21
Incomplete pass through: The fact that …rms pass on to foreign
consumers only part of their productivity shocks (or exchange rate
shocks) comes from the endogenous mark-ups charged by …rms.
If …rms in a country are hit by a negative productivity shock (in
partial equilibrium, this is equivalent to an appreciation of the
exchange rate), they will increase their prices by less than their
productivity shock. The reason is that …rms adjust their mark-up
in response to a negative productivity shock. When a …rm is hit
by a negative productivity shock, it faces higher per unit costs.
In a pure Dixit-Stiglitz world, such a …rm would raise its price
one for one with the increase in the unit cost of production. In
this setting with endogenous mark-ups though, as the …rm loses
some market share, it will try to alleviate the shock by reducing
its mark-up. This is because it takes into account the fact that
by increasing the price it sets, not only does it lose market shares
against other competitors in the same sector, but it also loses mar-
ket shares against …rms in other sectors. Taking that into account,
the price set abroad increases by less than the increase in the cost
of production. The …rm bears part of the shock by reducing its
mark-up.
So after an appreciation of a country’s exchange rate, exporters will
not increase the price they charge abroad by as much as the in-
crease in the exchange rate. In order to protect their market share
abroad, they will reduce their mark-up, so that prices increase by
less than the exchange rate.
22
competitors are hit by the same shock. At home on the other
hand, all domestic …rms are hit by the same negative productivity
shock, but only a small share of foreign exporters are not.
Because domestic …rms are hit by this negative productivity shock,
but foreign …rms aren’t, exporters will lose some market shares
both at home and abroad, and in response to that will reduce the
mark-up they charge both at home and abroad. But because only a
subset of …rms actually export, an exporter will lose more market
share abroad than it does at home, and it will therefore reduce
the mark-up it charges abroad more than it reduces the mark-up
it charges domestically. This prediction of the model corresponds
to the (aggregate) fact that over the business cycle, the price of
exports relative to goods sold domestically moves up and down
PPI
( EP I
moves).
Symmetrically, when the domestic …rms are hit by a negative pro-
ductivity shock, foreign exporters will increase their mark-up for
exports more than for goods sold domestically ( ePIPPII moves).
23
the relative movements in mark-ups charged by exporters.
Such an e¤ect would be present in a simpli…ed version of the Melitz
(2003) model even without endogenous mark-ups.
Composition e¤ects, in Atkeson and Burstein and in Ghi-
roni and Melitz (2005): Note however that this composition
e¤ects going in this exact direction crucially depends on the fact
that we consider a partial equilibrium version of the Melitz model,
that is a version without free entry of …rms. The Ghironi and
Melitz model points out that once the free entry of …rms is taken
into account, the composition e¤ect may actually be reversed alto-
gether. We have seen in the Ghironi and Melitz model that when
the home country is hit by a negative productivity shock, there will
be exit of …rms (or not entry, or more precisely no entry of new
…rms at home, so exit by death, and entry of …rms abroad). This
exit of …rms will actually drive down the productivity threshold for
exports. So the average price of exports will actually go up, once
endogenous entry and exit is taken into account. This mechanism
was at the heart of the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson e¤ect.
Short run versus long run price adjustments: The conclu-
sion of that note is that depending of what time horizon one looks
at, di¤erent e¤ects may play di¤erent roles. In the very short run,
without entry and exit of …rms neither on the domestic market, nor
on the export market, only the mechanism described by Atkeson
and Burstein (endogenous mark-ups, incomplete pass-through and
pricing to market) will be present: in response to a negative pro-
ductivity shock at home, domestic exporters increase their prices
at home more than abroad. Over a slightly longer horizon, with
no entry or exit of …rms on the domestic market, but with entry
and exit of …rms on the export market, on top of the Atkeson and
Burstein paper, there will be a composition e¤ect: in response to
a negative productivity shock, high price domestic exporters stop
exporting, so that average export prices increase. Over an even
longer horizon, the mechanism described in Ghironi and Melitz
starts kicking in: domestic …rms exit, foreign …rms enter, so that
the productivity cuto¤ for exports decreases at home and increases
abroad, so that the average price of exports actually goes up. In
a model with free entry and endogenous mark-ups, whether the
Ghironi and Melitz e¤ect or the Atkeson and Burstein e¤ect dom-
inates depends (I guess) on the speci…c assumptions of the model
(the distribution of productivity shocks, the size of trade barri-
ers, the number of …rms per sector, the elasticities of substitution
24
within and between sectors). In the end, it is an empirical question,
for which I don’t know the answer.
References
[1] Balassa, B. (1964), “The Purchasing Power Parity Doctrine: A Reap-
praisal”, Journal of Political Economy, 72, 584-96.
[2] Cendrars, Blaise (1925), L’Or.
[3] Dornbusch, Rudiger (1987) “Exchange Rates and Prices” American
Economic Review, vol. 77, March.
[4] Harrod, Roy. (1933), "International Economics". London: Nisbet and
Cambridge University Press.
[5] Krugman, Paul (1987), “Pricing to Market When the Exchange Rate
Changes,” in S. W. Arndt and J. Richardson, eds., Real Financial
Linkages Among Open Economies (London: MIT Press)
[6] Krugman, Paul (1991), "Increasing Returns and Economic Geogra-
phy," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 99(3), pages 483-99, June.
[7] Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth S. Rogo¤ (2001), “The Six Ma-
jor Puzzles in International Macroeconomics: Is There a Common
Cause?”NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, Ben S. Bernanke and
Kenneth S. Rogo¤, eds. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2001), pp.
339–390.
[8] Rogo¤, Kenneth S. (1996), “The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle,”
Journal of Economic Literature, XXXIV (1996), 647–668.
[9] Samuelson, Paul (1964), “Theoretical Notes on Trade Problems”,
Review of Economics and Statistics, 23, 1-60.
25