Introduction and Basic Concepts Economics
Introduction and Basic Concepts Economics
Md.Ahsan Kabir
ECONOMICS
Economics is about making efficient uses of scarce resources. This is about learning
how people in their daily lives make decisions of allocating scarce amount of
resources – time and budget – they possess, to meet their numerous desires.
At occasions many of you may have wished you had more income and more time. For
example, during finals students wish they had more time to prepare for exams.
Unfortunately, income and time are not plenty, they are scarce. But, the number of
wants that one seeks to satisfy from his/her limited income or time are numerous or
unlimited. The scarcity of resources, therefore, forces everyone to make choices from
their long list of wants.
RESOURCES
A fundamental premise in economics is that ‗resources are scarce.‘ Resources are
those goods and services that can be used to produce other goods and services. Mostly
cited examples are labor and human resources (time, skill, and knowledge of labor),
capital resources (physical capital and technology), and land and natural resources.
Very often firms combine these three forms of resources to produce a good or service.
If you accept that resources are scarce, then you must also accept that all goods and
services that are produced by using the scarce resources must also be scarce.
SCARCITY
How does one know whether something – a good, service, or resource – is scarce?
If the quantity or amount of something actually available to you (the supply) is less
than the quantity or amount that you like to have of this thing if made available free-
of-cost (demand), then this thing is ‗scarce‘ for you. On the level of a society or
economy, if the naturally available quantity of a resource falls short of the quantity of
this resource the people in this society or economy like to have at free-of-cost, then
this resource is scarce. Forests are scarce resources. If they were not scarce, we would
not have been concerned with deforestation. Because non-scarcity implies that there
are sufficient numbers of trees to satisfy everybody‘s wish of having trees (for
different purposes).
If you find that people are willing to pay a price for having a good or resource, that is
clearly a signal that the good or resource is scarce. When something is not plenty to
meet everyone‘s demand, a mechanism needs to be implemented to ration the scarce
good among the competing users of the good. In a market economy, money price
functions as a rationing mechanism. For some scarce goods, there could be other
forms of rationing mechanism. For example, A-grade in an academic course is a
scarce commodity; it is rationed based on performances of students in exams,
homeworks, and possibly a bunch of other criteria. To have Stanley cup (a scarce
commodity, there is only one cup available in a year), hockey teams have to play and
win a long series of games.
OPPORTUNITY COST
Every individual, rich or poor, and every country, developing or developed, faces
scarcity of resources. Developed countries or rich individuals may command
relatively higher amount of resources than their counterparts, but their desires or uses
of resources too are greater than their counterparts, creating a situation of scarcity.
There is no individual or nation which is satisfied with what it has. Desires exceed the
current capabilities. Therefore, it is imperative that a choice be made, which among a
long list of desires could or should be fulfilled, and thereby which ones would remain
unfulfilled. If a homeowner chooses to spend two hours on mowing the front and
backyard lawns on any given Sunday (time is a scarce resource), those two hours
obviously could not be spent on watching a movie or visiting a friend. Choosing to
spend a scarce resource on an activity comes at the expense or sacrifice of not being
able to use that resource for another purpose. Such a sacrifice or cost is called
opportunity cost.
MARGINAL ANALYSIS
The word ‗marginal‘ means ‗additional.‘ In real life when an economic agent faces a
decision problem, the agent has to evaluate how the decision changes the agent‘s
current situation or status quo. What additional (marginal) benefits are likely to accrue
to the decision maker and what additional (marginal) costs have to be incurred?
Marginal benefit from drinking a can of cold drink in hot weather is likely to be
higher than the marginal benefit of the same drink if weather is cold. Do you see the
importance of current situation (in this example, the kind of weather)?
Consider another example. Suppose you are currently employed and earn $30,000 a
year. You receive a new job offer of $40,0000 a year, but the new job requires
additional 8 hours of work every week. Would you accept this job offer?
The marginal benefit of new job is $10,000 of earnings ($40,000 minus $30,000)
against its marginal cost of 8 additional hours of work every week. The marginal cost
may also include any additional tax burden associated with higher earning, but for
simplification assume there are no additional taxes involved. Whether you would
accept the new job offer, according to the economizing behavior, depends on whether
the marginal benefit at least exceeds the marginal cost. That is, is the annual
additional amount of earnings of $10,000 worth putting 8 additional hours of work
every week? This kind of analysis (the comparison of marginal benefit of an action
with its marginal cost) is called ‗marginal analysis.‘
As you do more of the same activity or consume more of the same good, its
marginal benefit progressively diminishes.
Hiring one guard is likely to reduce theft worth $4,300. Therefore, the marginal
benefit of first guard is $4,300. Adding one more guard increases the benefit to
$7,100. That is, the marginal benefit or additional theft deterred by the second guard
is $2,800 ($7,100 minus $4,300). Below are the estimates of marginal benefits of
each additional guard, calculated by using the following formula:
MBn TBn TBn1 , where MBn denotes the marginal benefit of the nth guard, TBn
stands for total benefit from n number of guards, and TBn-1 stands for total benefit
from (n – 1) number of guards.
What happens to marginal benefit as more guards are hired? The marginal benefit
progressively diminishes. In other words, the estimates above exhibit the law of
diminishing marginal returns.
If for some reason the department store had employed three guards, the above analysis
suggests that it should lay off one guard. On the other hand, if the store had only one
guard, it should employ more guards. In other words, the store needs to keep hiring
guards until marginal benefit does not drop below marginal cost. Based on this
example, the rule of economizing behavior (the rule of maximizing total net benefit)
can be stated as:
4
3 MC
2
1 MB
0
0 1 2 3 4 Number of Guards
If guards can be hired part-time, the above graph suggests that additional net benefits
can be obtained by hiring a third guard part-time, where MB intersects (becomes
equal to) MC. Note that the MB curve is downward-sloping because of diminishing
marginal returns.
Among the above cost items, room and board and personal expenses do not constitute
a part of opportunity cost of college education, because these costs would have been
incurred any way, irrespective of whether one is taking education in college or is
employed at a work and is not going to college. On the other hand, the remaining
items in the above list are not the only components of opportunity cost. When a
person chooses to go to college for four years, she forgoes potential income that could
have been made during those four years. Therefore, foregone income is also a
component, generally the largest component of opportunity cost. The list below
presents the different components of the opportunity cost:
Tuition and fees $56,000
Books, stationary, and supplies 4,800
Transportation to and from school 4,400
Forgone income ($16,000 a year) 64,000
TOTAL 129,200
A flight is almost due for departure from Denver to Seattle and is only 60 percent
booked. A passenger offers $120 to the airlines for a seat in that flight, when the
regular airfare is $230. What do you think is the airlines‘ opportunity cost of flying
this passenger to Seattle? Should the airlines accept the passenger‘s offer, if there
remains sufficient time to board the passenger without delaying the flight‘s departure
schedule?
I hesitate to visit my doctor unless very necessary, because I need to take half-day off
from work, which pays me $20 an hour. What is the opportunity cost of my time to
visit doctor? Besides spending time, I also have to pay $35 insurance co-payment.
What is the full opportunity cost (monetary cost plus time cost) of a doctor visit?
2. The table below shows total costs and marginal costs associated with different
levels of output of a competitive firm. The output of the firm sells at $7 per unit; that
is, revenue per unit of output or the marginal benefit to the firm is $7 at any level of
output. What level of output will maximize profit or net benefit of the firm?
3. Sally enjoys ice cream. In the table below she has expressed her enjoyment of ice
cream in equivalent dollar terms.
5. There are numerous instances of people who have sacrificed precious years of their
life for freedom struggles to liberate their countries from colonial rulers or dictators.
In the process many of them got imprisoned, tortured, and even killed, when in fact
they could have led a more comfortable life and might have even been rewarded
handsomely by dictators if they chose to embrace dictatorial regimes. Is economizing
behavior consistent with the choice of such individuals to engage in freedom struggle?
Before answering this question, read the following:
A press reporter asked a freedom fighter, in whose leadership his country had
just successfully overthrown the dictatorial regime of a monarch, “Why did
you choose to remain imprisoned for 12 long years, when you could have
secured a comfortable life outside prison by accepting the dictatorial regime
of the monarch?”
The freedom fighter replied, “If I had submitted to the dictatorial regime of
the monarch, I would have definitely been released from imprisonment. But, I
couldn’t have slept during nights having known that I betrayed the faith of my
people and my own deeply-held beliefs in democracy and human rights. It was
better for me to live in prison and be at peace with myself.”
6. A news piece appeared in the Rocky Mountain News of July 4, 2006 that Arizona
was considering boosting voter turnout by awarding a $1 million prize to one
randomly selected voter; Arizona Voter Rewards Initiative is up for voting in
November 2006 in Arizona. Is this plan likely to boost voter turnout? What are the
marginal benefit and marginal cost of voting from an individual voter‘s perspective?
(Registered voters in 2002 in Arizona: 2,229,180; actual voting 1,255,615 or 56.33%
in 2002; the national average voter participation 49.2%)
FUR coats have fallen from grace in many parts of the world, but chilly northern
nations continue to farm millions of mink for their pelts. The animals are housed in
barren cages that provoke controversy and protest from animal lovers, but fur farmers
insist that mink are completely adapted to life behind bars. What do the animals
themselves feel about their surroundings?
To answer this, Georgia Mason of Oxford University and her colleagues have applied
a little economic theory. Animals, like human consumers, have to make the most of
limited resources. Instead of money, they trade physical exertion and time. The things
they want depend on the environment they evolved in. Wild mink swim, roam, delve
into tunnels and hunt, so their commodities presumably include water, space, tunnels
and prey. Caged mink, claim animal advocates, are frustrated without these resources,
and suffer as a result. Fur supporters contend that such ―wild‖ urges have been bred
out.
To settle the debate, Dr Mason and her colleagues treated their animals to life with a
water bath, tunnel, chewable toys and an extra straw-lined bed in addition to their
normal cage. They regarded the mink as consumers, recording how often they visited
the extra cages containing each of the ―treats‖. The mink had to pay for their treats by
pushing against heavy doors to gain access. By varying the weights of the doors, the
researchers could measure microeconomic variables such as consumer surplus and
reservation price, which reveal how much consumers value a commodity. Their
results are published in this week‘s Nature.
Water, it turned out, matters the most to mink—and not merely to drink. They refused
to be thwarted by increasingly heavy weights, and continued to force doors open in
order to swim. In human terms, the mink deemed the water bath to be a staple such as
bread, for which consumers continue to pay the asking price even when the cost goes
up. By contrast, the tunnel was more readily forsaken by the mink when the going got
tough, much as a person might forgo restaurant meals when prices rise. The other
treats were intermediate in the value placed on them.
Fur farmers with a conscience have one idea still to cling to. Meaningful economic
decisions are possible only when consumers are familiar with the available
commodities. Exposure to the treats may have activated desires in the experimental
mink that would otherwise have lain dormant. Farmed mink, on the other hand, never
know any alternative. For them, swimming may be ―out of sight, out of mind‖.
Government plays a role of a neutral referee in this system, who sets the rules of the
game, like protection of private property rights, law and order, etc. It does not
interfere in the consumption or production decisions of households and firms. Most
Western economies are close to this type of economic organization. Hong Kong is
considered the freest market economy in the world.