Skeptics Guide To Modern Monetary Theory PDF
Skeptics Guide To Modern Monetary Theory PDF
By N. Gregory Mankiw*
Harvard University
macroeconomics, dubbed Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) by its proponents. MMT burst on
the scene in an unusual way. From its name, one might guess that it arose at top universities, as
prominent scholars debated the fine points of macroeconomic theory. But that is not the case.
Instead, MMT was developed in a small corner of academia and became famous only when some
This history is enough to make academics like me skeptical, but it is not sufficient to
reject the theory. Even ideas that arise in unusual ways can be right. So I recently tried to figure
out what MMT was all about. I wanted to identify the key differences between this new approach
Fortunately, there was an ideal vehicle for this endeavor. In 2019, Red Globe Press
published a new textbook, simply titled Macroeconomics, written by three MMT proponents:
William Mitchell and Martin Watts (both of University of Newcastle, Australia) and L. Randall
Wray (Bard College). This brief essay explains what I have learned about MMT from this
textbook treatment.
At the outset, I should admit that I found the task of figuring out MMT to be vexing. As I
studied it, I was often puzzled about what precisely was being asserted. I hasten to add that the
problems I had could have been of my own making. Perhaps after forty years in the profession, I
am too steeped in mainstream macroeconomics to fully appreciate MMT. I raise this possibility
because MMT proponents may say that I missed the nuances of their approach. But what follows
1
MMT begins with the government budget constraint under a system of fiat money.
According to Mitchell, Wray, and Watts (hereafter MW&W), the standard approach, which
relates the present value of tax revenue to the present value of government spending and the
government debt, is misleading. They write, “The most important conclusion reached by MMT is
that the issuer of a currency faces no financial constraints. Put simply, a country that issues its
own currency can never run out and can never become insolvent in its own currency. It can make
all payments as they come due.” (MW&W, p. 13) As a result, “for most governments, there is no
When reading these words, my reaction alternates between languid concession and
vehement opposition. To be sure, a currency-issuing government can always print more money
when a bill comes due. That ability might seem to release the government from any financial
constraints. Certainly, if an individual were granted access to the monetary printing press, his or
her financial constraints would become much less binding. But I am reluctant to reach a similar
First, in our current monetary system with interest paid on reserves, any money the
government prints to pay a bill will likely end up in the banking system as reserves, and the
government (via the Fed) will need to pay interest on those reserves. That is, when the
government prints money to pay a bill, it is, in effect, borrowing. The money can stay as reserves
forever, but interest accrues over time. An MMT proponent will point out that the interest can be
paid by printing yet more money. But the ever-expanding monetary base will have further
ramifications. Aggregate demand will increase due to a wealth effect, eventually spurring
inflation.
2
Second, if sufficient interest is not paid on reserves, the expansion in the monetary base
will increase bank lending and the money supply. Interest rates must then fall to induce people to
hold the expanded money supply, again putting upward pressure on aggregate demand and
inflation.
Third, the increase in inflation reduces the real quantity of money demanded. This fall in
real money balances, in turn, reduces the real resources that the government can claim via money
creation. Indeed, there is likely a Laffer curve for seigniorage. A government that acts as if it has
no financial constraints may quickly find itself on the wrong side of this Laffer curve, where the
Faced with these circumstances, a government may decide that defaulting on its debts is
the best option, despite its ability to create more money. That is, government default may occur
This discussion brings us to the theory of inflation. I have been adopting the mainstream
view, explained most simply by the quantity theory of money, that a high rate of money creation
is inflationary. Proponents of MMT question that conclusion. They assert that “no simple
proportionate relationship exists between rises in the money supply and rises in the general price
This assertion overstates the case against the mainstream view. In U.S. decadal data since
1870, the correlation between inflation and money growth is 0.79. Cross-country data exhibit a
theoretic reasoning. They stress that money demand can be unstable, that distinguishing
monetary and nonmonetary assets is difficult in a world of rapid financial innovation, that
3
expected future money growth can influence current inflation when people are forward-looking,
and that various factors beyond monetary policy influence aggregate demand and inflation. They
also acknowledge that, under current policy arrangements, central banks target interest rates in
the short run and inflation in the longer run and that monetary aggregates play a small role. But
these ideas refine the quantity theory of money rather than refute it.
MMT proponents advance a very different approach to inflation. They write, “Conflict
theory situates the problem of inflation as being intrinsic to the power relations between workers
and capital (class conflict), which are mediated by government within a capitalist system.”
(MW&W, p. 255) That is, inflation gets out of control when workers and capitalists each
struggle to claim a larger share of national income. According to this view, incomes policies,
such as government guidelines for wages and prices, are a solution to high inflation. MMT
advocates see these guidelines, and even government controls on wages and prices, as a kind of
Mainstream theories of inflation emphasize not class struggle but excessive growth in
aggregate demand, often due to monetary policy. This idea also appears in MMT. Its proponents
admit that “all spending (private or public) is inflationary if it drives nominal aggregate demand
above the real capacity of the economy to absorb it.” (MW&W, p. 127)
The advocates of MMT, however, make this possibility seem more hypothetical than real.
We are also told that “capitalist economies are rarely at full employment. Since economies
typically operate with spare productive capacity and often with high rates of unemployment, it is
hard to maintain the view that there is no scope for firms to expand real output when there is an
4
At the risk of seeming like the boy with the hammer who thinks everything is a nail, let
me connect this observation from MMT with mainstream new Keynesian research, some of
Let’s first recall the work on general disequilibrium from the 1970s. (Barro and Grossman,
1971; Malinvaud, 1977) These theories took wages and prices as given and aimed to understand
the allocation of resources when markets failed to clear. According to these theories, the
economy can find itself in one of several regimes, depending on which markets are experiencing
excess supply and which markets are experiencing excess demand. The most interesting regime
is the so-called “Keynesian regime” in which both the goods market and the labor market exhibit
excess supply. In the Keynesian regime, unemployment arises because labor demand is
insufficient to ensure full employment at prevailing wages; the demand for labor is low because
firms cannot sell all they want at prevailing prices; and the demand for firms’ output is
inadequate because many customers are unemployed. Recessions result from a vicious circle of
insufficient demand.
Now fast forward to the next decade. Because so much of the Keynesian tradition
assumed that wages and prices fail to clear markets, subsequent new Keynesian research, mostly
during the 1980s, aimed to explain wage and price adjustment. This literature explored various
hypotheses: that firms with market power face menu costs when changing prices; that firms pay
their workers efficiency wages above the market-clearing level to promote worker productivity;
that wage and price setters deviate from perfect rationality; and that there are complementarities
between real and nominal rigidities. (Yellen, 1984; Mankiw, 1985; Akerlof and Yellen, 1985;
5
There is an important but often neglected relationship between these two lines of new
Keynesian research. In particular, one can view the later work on wage and price setting as
establishing the centrality of the Keynesian regime highlighted in the earlier disequilibrium
research. When firms have market power, they charge prices above marginal cost, so they always
want to sell more at prevailing prices. In a sense, if most firms have some degree of market
power, then goods markets are typically in a state of excess supply. This theory of the goods
market is often married to a theory of the labor market with above-equilibrium wages, such as
the efficiency-wage model. As a result, the Keynesian regime of generalized excess supply is not
just one possible outcome for the economy, but the typical one.
This logic brings me back to MMT. The conclusion that “economies typically operate
with spare productive capacity” can be interpreted as meaning that economies are usually in the
Keynesian regime of generalized excess supply. In that sense, MMT is akin to new Keynesian
analysis.
At this point, it is worth distinguishing the natural level of output and employment from
the optimal level. The natural level is the level where the economy finds itself on average and
toward which the economy gravitates in the long run, whereas the optimal level is the level that
maximizes social welfare. When generalized excess supply is the norm due to pervasive market
Inflation tends to rise when output and employment exceed their natural levels, even if
they remain below their optimal levels. After all, price setters do not aim to maximize social
welfare. They aim to maximize private welfare, and they do so by hitting their target mark-ups of
6
Here is where MMT economists diverge from new Keynesians. An MMT economist
might say that policymakers should aim for the optimum. If price setters are thwarting that goal
by raising prices, policymakers can fix that problem by using price guidelines or price controls.
A new Keynesian would admit that, in a world of pervasive market power, private price setting is
not first-best. But while getting the government involved in price setting might improve the
allocation of resources from the standpoint of simple theory, the complexity of the economy and
the history of price controls suggest that this solution is not practical.
In the end, my study of MMT led me to find some common ground with its proponents
without drawing all the radical inferences they do. I agree that the government can always print
money to pay its bills. But that fact does not free the government from its intertemporal budget
constraint. I agree that the economy normally operates with excess capacity, in the sense that the
economy’s output often falls short of its optimum. But that conclusion does not mean that
policymakers only rarely need to worry about inflationary pressures. I agree that, in a world of
pervasive market power, government price setting might improve private price setting as a matter
of economic theory. But that deduction does not imply that actual governments in actual
economies can increase welfare by inserting themselves extensively in the price-setting process.
Put simply, MMT contains some kernels of truth, but its most novel policy prescriptions
7
References
Akerlof, George A. and Janet L. Yellen. 1985. "A Near-Rational Model of the Business Cycle
with Wage and Price Inertia.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics. Suppl., 100, pp. 823-
838.
Ball, Laurence, and David Romer. 1990. “Real Rigidities and the Non-Neutrality of Money.”
The Review of Economic Studies. 57:2, pp. 183-203.
Barro, Robert J. and Herschel I. Grossman. 1971. “A General Disequilibrium Model of Income
and Employment.” American Economic Review. March, 61:1, pp. 82-93.
Blanchard, Olivier Jean and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki. 1987. “Monopolistic Competition and the
Effects of Aggregate Demand.” American Economic Review. September, 77:4, pp. 647-
666.
Mankiw, N. Gregory. 1985. “Small Menu Costs and Large Business Cycles: A Macroeconomic
Model of Monopoly.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics. May, 100:2, pp. 529-537.
Mankiw, N. Gregory. 2019. Macroeconomics, 10th edition, New York: Worth Publishers.
Mitchell, William, L. Randall Wray, and Martin Watts. 2019. Macroeconomics, London: Red
Globe Press.
8