Governance - Sound Development Management PDF
Governance - Sound Development Management PDF
Development Management
Governance: Sound
Development Management
August 1995
Published by Asian Development Bank, 1999
ISBN: 971-561-262-8
Publication Stock No.: 090699
Contents
Executive summary v
Introduction 1
Good governance defined 3
The elements of good governance 7
Accountability 8
Participation 9
Predictability 10
Transparency 11
Interlinkages among the elements of governance 12
The Bank’s concern with governance quality 15
Policy context of the Bank’s project lending 15
Focus on equity and development performance 16
Project quality 17
The East Asian experience 18
Outlook for the future 19
The Bank’s approach to governance issues 21
The Bank’s charter and governance activities 21
Need for flexible country-specific approaches 24
Promoting the elements of good governance in Bank operations 25
Building governance capacity 26
Participatory development processes 33
Legal frameworks 38
Information openness 42
The Bank’s modalities for enhancing governance in DMCs 45
Resource implications 49
Reporting arrangements 51
iii
Abbreviations
iv
Executive summary
(iii) Although policy aspects are important for development, the Bank’s
concept of good governance focuses essentially on the ingredients
for effective management. Irrespective of the precise set of
economic policies that find favor with a government, good
governance is required to ensure that those policies have their
desired effect. In essence, it concerns norms of behavior that help
ensure that governments actually deliver to their citizens what
they say they will deliver.
(iv) Similarly, the experience so far, especially within the region, shows
that successful development has taken place in countries with
different political systems. However, the common features that
stand out in respect of the high-performing economies are stability
in broad policy directions, flexibility in responding to market
signals, and discipline in sticking with measures necessary for
v
meeting long-term objectives despite short-term difficulties, all
hallmarks of sound development management, i.e., good
governance.
vi
elements of good governance and, on the other, the specific areas
of action (e.g., public sector management), in which they could
be promoted or their existence enhanced.
(ix) Accordingly, and building upon the approach of the World Bank,
the Bank has identified four basic elements of good governance:
accountability, participation, predictability, and transparency.
(x) The Bank’s interest in governance issues has intensified, over time,
as a result of several factors. These include (a) the growing
recognition of the importance of the policy environment in which
development takes place, (b) an increasing focus on equity issues
and development performance, (c) the lessons highlighted by the
Task Force on Improving Project Quality, and (d) the experience
of the high-performing economies of the region.
vii
Accountability (building government capacity)
• public sector management
• public enterprise management and reform
• public financial management
• civil service reform
(xiv) The Bank will integrate governance dimensions into its operations.
To the extent possible, Bank-supported programs and projects
will be designed such that they raise governance quality in the
sectors concerned (e.g., through inclusion of appropriate policy
measures, project components, or technical assistance [TA]). In
addition, the Bank will provide, on request, advisory TA for
specific governance-oriented policy studies, seminars, and
training. In all cases, the guiding principle for the Bank will be to
act on the basis of DMC requests, rather than to seek loan
conditionalities.
viii
relate to staffing, staff training, staff consultants, business travel,
and loan and TA resources. With respect to staffing, the Bank
would need to strengthen in-house expertise in various aspects
of governance and institutional development. However, given the
current constraints on the budget, any new staff positions required
would have to be accommodated through ongoing redeployment
efforts within the Bank. Necessary trade-offs with other activities
of lower priority would be worked out. Similarly, insofar as the
other resource implications are concerned, these would be
adjusted so as to be accommodated within the relevant budget
allocations.
(xvii) Two years after Board approval of the Bank’s operational policy
on governance issues (i.e., in late-1997), a Board paper will be
circulated, analyzing the Bank’s experience with governance
activities, proposing modifications to the operational approach,
as necessary, and indicating more specific resource implications.
ix
Introduction
I
n recent years, there has been increasing concern about gover-
nance issues in the development debate. This has been reflected
in the ongoing discussion within the Bank on the objectives, pri-
orities, and approaches to its operational programs. It received attention,
for example, during the discussions leading to the fifth replenishment
of the Asian Development Fund (ADF VI). The document ADF VI:
Report of the Donors noted “the vital connection between sound and
responsive systems of public administration and the effective and
equitable operation of the economy.”1 In this context, reference was
also made to the need for “participatory and democratic frameworks”
and for strengthening “the legal system and regulatory agencies.” Simi-
larly, during the negotiations concluded last year for the Bank’s Fourth
General Capital Increase (GCI IV), emphasis was placed on governance
and its impact on the effectiveness of Bank operations.2 It was indicated
that the Bank would seek to address governance issues in its operations.
In view of the importance and urgency of the subject, the Presi-
dent issued interim staff instructions on governance in February 1994.
Subsequently, in May 1995, the Board considered a Working Paper on
the subject.3 The present Paper takes into account the views expressed
by the Board at that time and sets out the role, approach, and policy of
the Bank in relation to governance issues.
1 Doc. R230-91, Revision 1, Final, Replenishment of the Asian Development Fund and the
Technical Assistance Special Fund, 16 January 1992. ADF VI: Report of the Donors was an
attachment to this document.
2 Doc. R40-94, Fourth General Capital Increase (GCI IV): (Draft) Report of the Board of
Directors to the Board of Governors, 14 March 1994 (Attachment 1).
3 Doc. Working Paper 1-95, Governance, 15 March 1995.
1
To this end, the chapters that follow (i) define what governance
should mean for the Bank, (ii) identify elements of good governance,
(iii) explain the factors that have intensified the Bank’s concern with
governance issues, (iv) discuss two general considerations that have a
bearing on the Bank’s approach to governance, (v) relate the elements
of good governance to Bank operations, and (vi) indicate specific ways
in which the Bank will address governance issues in its developing
member countries (DMCs). Two concluding chapters deal briefly with
resource implications and the reporting arrangements for the Bank’s
governance activities.
2
Good governance defined
T
he term “governance” means different things to different people.
It is useful, therefore, for the Bank to clarify, at the very outset,
the sense in which it understands the word. Among the many
definitions of “governance” that exist, the one that appears the most
appropriate from the viewpoint of the Bank is “the manner in which
power is exercised in the management of a country’s economic and
social resources for development.”4 On this meaning, the concept of
governance is concerned directly with the management of the devel-
opment process, involving both the public and the private sectors. It
encompasses the functioning and capability of the public sector, as
well as the rules and institutions that create the framework for the con-
duct of both public and private business, including accountability for
economic and financial performance, and regulatory frameworks
relating to companies, corporations, and partnerships.5 In broad terms,
then, governance is about the institutional environment in which citi-
zens interact among themselves and with government agencies/
officials.
The capacity of this institutional environment is important for
development because it helps determine the impact achieved by the
economic policies adopted by the government. It has been observed
that, while many governments have undertaken broadly similar reform
packages, the outcomes have varied significantly across countries.
There are several factors underlying these differences, but clearly one
is the quality of governance in the countries concerned; in other words,
4 Webster’s New Universal Unabridged Dictionary, London: Dorset & Baber, 1979.
5 Managing Development: The Governance Dimension, World Bank, June 1991.
3
the ability of governments to implement effectively the policies they
have chosen. Hence, “getting policies right” may not, by itself, be suf-
ficient for successful development, if standards of governance are poor.
It is for this reason that improving governance, or sound development
management, is a vital concern for all governments.
Although policy aspects are important for development, the Bank’s
concept of good governance focuses essentially on the ingredients for
effective management. In other words, irrespective of the precise set
of economic policies that find favor with a government, good gover-
nance is required to ensure that those policies have their desired effect.
In essence, it concerns norms of behavior that help ensure that gov-
ernments actually deliver to their citizens what they say they will deliver.
Similarly, the experience so far, especially within the region, does
not establish any direct correlation between the political environment,
on the one hand, and rapid economic growth and social development,
on the other. Successful development has taken place in countries with
different political systems. However, the common features that stand
out in respect of high-performing economies are stability in broad policy
directions, flexibility in responding to market signals, and discipline in
sticking with measures necessary for meeting long-term objectives
despite short-term difficulties, all hallmarks of good governance.
A basic issue that arises in relation to governance is the proper role
of government in economic management. The growing consensus
among development specialists in this regard is that, with the limited
access of governments to information, markets generally allocate
resources more efficiently. In market economies, production and con-
sumption decisions are based essentially on the price mechanism.
However, even in such economies, governments are expected to per-
form certain key functions. These include (i) maintaining macroeco-
nomic stability, (ii) developing infrastructure, (iii) providing public
goods, (iv) preventing market failures, and (v) promoting equity.
Without macroeconomic stability, business prospects are uncer-
tain and investment risks are high. Inflation and external imbalances
do not provide a healthy environment for rational business decisions.
An important dimension of macroeconomic stability is the link with
equity. While the adverse effects of inflation are felt economy-wide, it
4
is the lower-income groups that are usually the hardest hit, since they
have limited scope for reducing consumption in response to price
increases. Thus, macroeconomic instability militates against equity in
the distribution of economic welfare, a stated objective of most
governments.
By developing infrastructure, governments can create conducive
conditions for private investment in commercial activities. However,
given the fiscal constraints of most governments, the role of the private
sector in infrastructure development is likely to increase. The challenge
for governments is to devise a policy and institutional framework that
allows wider participation to the private sector in infrastructure devel-
opment and management, while safeguarding the public interest at
the same time.
Public goods are those that are jointly demanded and whose
consumption by one individual does not diminish their availability to
others. Education and health care are common examples of public
goods. In most countries, governments assume responsibility for the
provision of public goods, with fiscal resources being channeled in a
preferential manner to ensure their supply. This also contributes to
improving equity in the economy (although user fees may be levied to
promote cost recovery where feasible).
In a market-oriented economy, the government has the obligation
to see to it that markets function efficiently and that the playing field is
level for all participants. This requires mobility of factors of produc-
tion, free flow of information regarding prices and technology, and
competition among buyers (for outputs) and sellers (for inputs). Market
regulation by the government should ensure that the operating rules
do not discriminate between individual participants or interest groups.
This implies wide publicity for legislation and administrative rules and
their fair and transparent application.
A key responsibility of government is ensuring that the benefits of
economic growth are equitably distributed across society. Taxation and
expenditure measures are prominent instruments for this purpose.
While taxes should not be excessive (so as not to discourage produc-
tion and growth), they should be collected effectively to provide
adequate revenue for essential services (and help maintain fiscal bal-
ance). The latter consideration also requires that public spending avoid
5
excessive debt-service burdens, and subsidies for low priority activities
be phased out. This underscores the close relationship between equity
and macroeconomic stability.
Given the role of government as economic development manager,
as outlined above, policies that best suit these responsibilities need to
be followed. Once those policy choices are made, however, good gov-
ernance is required to make sure that implementation is effective and
consistent. As a development partner, the Bank has a clear and direct
interest in the capacity of borrowing governments to fulfill their eco-
nomic role by implementing the associated policies. More specifically,
the success of the Bank’s project investments depends crucially on the
efficacy of the institutional framework in DMCs and the consequent
capability for purposive implementation.
6
The elements of
good governance
A
number of multilateral organizations (e.g., the United Nations
Development Programme [UNDP] and the Organisation for
Economic Cooperation and Development [OECD]) have reflected
on the elements of good governance, and on their relation to develop-
ment. As the ethos and experience of these organizations vary, so, too,
do their perceptions of what constitutes good governance. Insofar as
the Bank is concerned, though, it is the approach taken by the World
Bank—drawn from its global experience with project and adjustment
lending—that is the most relevant. The World Bank’s interest in gover-
nance stems from its concern with the effectiveness of the develop-
ment efforts it supports. From this perspective, sound development
management, in the broadest sense of the phrase, is critical for ensur-
ing adequate returns and efficacy of the programs and projects financed,
and for the World Bank’s underlying objectives of helping countries
reduce poverty and promoting sustainable growth. Hence, the World
Bank’s emphasis in recent years has shifted from its own interventions
to the overall country context (i.e., the governance climate) within
which those interventions take place. In doing so, it has been guided
by the nature of its operations and the opportunities for action that
these offer. Accordingly, the key dimensions of governance identified
by the World Bank are (i) public sector management, (ii) accountabil-
ity, (iii) legal framework for development, and (iv) transparency and
information.
7
The Bank also regards governance as synonymous with sound
development management. It therefore relates governance to the
effectiveness with which development assistance is used, the impact
of development programs and projects (including those financed by
the Bank), and the absorptive capacity of borrowing DMCs. 6
Accordingly, like the World Bank, the Bank, too, is concerned directly
with the manner in which the public sector is managed in DMCs, and
with the legal framework for development. However, in formulating
an analytical framework for addressing governance issues, the Bank
prefers to draw a distinction between, on the one hand, elements of
good governance and, on the other, the specific areas of action (e.g.,
public sector management) in which they could be promoted or their
existence enhanced. In line with this reasoning, and building upon
the approach of the World Bank, the Bank has identified four basic
elements of good governance: (i) accountability, (ii) participation,
(iii) predictability, and (iv) transparency.
The following sections consider briefly the relevance of the four
elements of good governance to the development process.7
Accountability
Accountability is imperative to make public officials answerable for
government behavior and responsive to the entity from which they
derive their authority. This may be achieved differently in different
countries or political structures, depending on the history, cultural
milieu, and value systems involved. The mechanisms employed may
vary from audit covenants, at one level, to broadly elected legislatures
or more narrowly conceived consultative committees, at another.
Accountability also means establishing criteria to measure the per-
formance of public officials, as well as oversight mechanisms to ensure
that the standards are met. The litmus test is whether private actors in
the economy have procedurally simple and swift recourse for redress
of unfair actions or incompetence of the executive authority. Lack of
accountability tends in time to reduce the state’s credibility as an
economic partner. It undermines the capacity of governments to sustain
6 Doc. R158-94, ADF VI: Progress Report, 7 April 1994 (para. 92).
7 The specific areas of action in which these elements of good governance will be applied are
dealt with in the chapter “Promoting the elements of good governance in Bank operations”.
8
the long-term business confidence essential for growth-enhancing pri-
vate sector investment. Looked at from this angle, accountability can
help reduce sovereign risk.
The accountability of public sector institutions is facilitated by
evaluation of their economic and financial performance. Economic
accountability relates to the effectiveness of policy formulation and
implementation, and efficiency in resource use. Financial accountabil-
ity covers accounting systems for expenditure control, and internal
and external audits.
Participation
The principle of participation derives from an acceptance that people
are at the heart of development. They are not only the ultimate benefi-
ciaries of development, but are also the agents of development. In the
latter capacity, they act through groups or associations (e.g., trade
unions, chambers of commerce, nongovernment organizations [NGOs],
political parties) and as individuals (e.g., through letters to newspaper
editors, participating in radio and television talkshows, voting). Since
development is both for and by people, they need to have access to
the institutions that promote it (e.g., representative bureaucracies).
Participation is often related to accountability, but not necessarily
so. In representative democracies, where citizens participate in gov-
ernment through the electoral process, public officials are, indeed,
accountable ultimately to the electorate. This may not be the case,
however, in other political systems (although accountability is still
important). For all economies, though, the benefits of participatory
approaches can be considerable. These include improved performance
and sustainability of policies, programs, and projects, as well as
enhanced capacity and skills of stakeholders.
At the grass roots level, participation implies that government struc-
tures are flexible enough to offer beneficiaries, and others affected,
the opportunity to improve the design and implementation of public
programs and projects. This increases “ownership” and enhances
results. At a different level, the effectiveness of policies and institu-
tions impinging on the economy as a whole may require the broad
support and cooperation of major economic actors concerned. To the
9
extent that the interface between public agencies and the private sector
is conducive to the latter’s participation in the economy, national eco-
nomic performance (comprising the combined contributions of the
public and private sectors) will be enhanced.
Participation in economic life by agents other than the state would
cover not only the role of the private sector, but also the activities (grow-
ing in recent times) of NGOs. These elements of civil society offer an
alternative means of channeling the energies of private citizens. They
can be helpful in identifying people’s interests, mobilizing public opin-
ion in support of these interests, and organizing action accordingly.
Being close to their constituents, NGOs can provide governments with
a useful ally in enhancing participation at the community level and
fostering a “bottom-up” approach to economic and social development.
Predictability
Predictability refers to (i) the existence of laws, regulations, and poli-
cies to regulate society; and (ii) their fair and consistent application.
The importance of predictability cannot be overstated since, without
it, the orderly existence of citizens and institutions would be impos-
sible. The rule of law encompasses both well-defined rights and duties,
as well as mechanisms for enforcing them, and settling disputes in an
impartial manner. It requires the state and its subsidiary agencies to be
as much bound by, and answerable to, the legal system as are private
individuals and enterprises.
The importance of rule-based systems for economic life is obvi-
ous. They are an essential component of the environment within which
economic actors plan and take investment decisions. To the extent,
therefore, that legal frameworks help ensure that (i) business risks can
be assessed rationally, (ii) transaction costs are lowered, and (iii) gov-
ernmental arbitrariness is minimized, they should prove conducive to
risk taking, growth, and development. In the opposite scenario, the
capricious application of rules generates uncertainty and inhibits the
growth of private sector initiatives. Regulatory uncertainty also tends
to raise the cost of capital by increasing the risk of investment.8
10
Besides legal and regulatory frameworks, consistency of public
policy is also important. Government policies affect the investment
climate directly, and economic actors require reasonable assurance
about the future behavior of key variables such as prices, the exchange
rate, and employment levels. However, consistency does not mean
rigidity. Governments do need to respond flexibly to changing cir-
cumstances and to make midcourse corrections, as necessary. Also,
when governments change, the successor administration will, under-
standably, want public policy to reflect its priorities, rather than those
of its predecessor. Barring such situations, though, consistency in the
broad directions of government policy is valuable (with modifications
being limited, as far as possible, to fine-tuning).
Predictability can be enhanced through appropriate institutional
arrangements. For example, it has been argued that an autonomous
central bank could lead to more predictable monetary and exchange
rate policies. Many governments face the challenge of regulating money
supply, while pursuing expansionary fiscal policies to encourage
investment. In such situations, if monetary policy is too accommodat-
ing, inflationary pressures can put investor confidence at risk, thus
defeating the very objective of the fiscal policy. In some countries,
managing the fiscal deficit may be made more difficult by compul-
sions to bail out a politically manipulated banking sector. Granting
greater autonomy to the central bank is one way that governments can
signal investors that macroeconomic policy will be prudent and sound.
Insulating economic ministries from political pressures can have simi-
lar benefits, but may be even more difficult to achieve.
Transparency
Transparency refers to the availability of information to the general
public and clarity about government rules, regulations, and decisions.
Thus, it both complements and reinforces predictability. The difficulty
with ensuring transparency is that only the generator of information
may know about it, and may limit access to it. Hence, it may be useful
to strengthen the citizens’ right to information with a degree of legal
enforceability. For similar reasons, broadly restrictive laws that permit
public officials to deny information to citizens (e.g., an Official Secrets
11
Act) need to provide for independent review of claims that such denial
is justified in the greater public interest.
Access to accurate and timely information about the economy and
government policies can be vital for economic decision making by the
private sector. On grounds of efficiency alone, such data should be
freely and readily available to economic agents. While this is true across
all areas of the economy, it is especially relevant in the case of those
sectors that are intrinsically information intensive, such as the finan-
cial sector in general and capital markets in particular.
Transparency in government decision making and public policy
implementation reduces uncertainty and can help inhibit corruption
among public officials. To this end, rules and procedures that are simple,
straightforward, and easy to apply are preferable to those that provide
discretionary powers to government officials or that are susceptible to
different interpretations. However well-intentioned the latter type of
rule might be in theory, its purpose can be vitiated in practice through
error or otherwise.9
In practice, though, it may sometimes be necessary to place limits
on the principle of transparency. In doing so, it may be helpful to dis-
tinguish information as a commodity from information as a process.
For example, intellectual property rights may need to be protected in
order to encourage innovation and invention; but decision making on
the establishment of intellectual property and rights thereto (i.e., to
whom they are granted and why) should be transparent.
Interlinkages among
the elements of governance
Conceptually, the four elements of governance indicated above tend
to be mutually supportive and reinforcing. Accountability is often
related to participation, and is also the ultimate safeguard of predict-
ability and transparency. In the absence of accountability to affected
groups, even predictable decision making of autonomous government
agencies may result in the latter placing agency interests above those
9 For example, a uniform tariff rate (where merchants know exactly what customs duty pay-
ment is required) is preferable, on this ground, to multiple tariff rates that offer customs
officials discretion over the classification of goods.
12
of the former. Similarly, transparency and information openness can-
not be assured without legal frameworks that balance the right to dis-
closure against the right of confidentiality, and without institutions that
accept accountability. Again, predictability in the functioning of the
legal framework would be helpful for ensuring the accountability of
public institutions. At the same time, predictability also requires trans-
parency, because without information about how similarly placed
individuals have been treated, it may be difficult to ensure adherence
to the rule of equality before the law. Finally, a transparent system
facilitates governmental accountability, participation, and predictability
of outcomes.
13
14
The Bank’s concern with
governance quality
A
s mentioned, for the Bank (and the World Bank), governance is
synonymous with development management. Given its involve-
ment in the development of DMCs, the Bank has a legitimate
and direct interest in governance issues. However, several factors have,
over time, intensified the Bank’s interest in the field of governance. These
include (i) the growing recognition of the importance of the policy envi-
ronment in which development takes place, (ii) an increasing focus on
equity issues and development performance, (iii) the lessons highlighted
by the Task Force on Improving Project Quality (TFIPQ),10 and (iv) the
experience of the high-performing economies of the region.
15
financing activities. Economic and sector work provides the analytical
underpinning for policy dialogue and for program and project design,
as well as for the more holistic approach to lending systematized in
the strategic country planning documents (i.e., country operational
strategy studies and country assistance plans). These efforts at helping
DMCs “get policies right” are now commonplace in the Bank, and have
led it to take greater interest in the capacity of borrowing governments
for policy formulation and implementation. While the policy objective
in a particular DMC sector might be clear enough, knowledge of the
institutional framework and its capability will be helpful in the design
of reform measures. In such cases, the Bank seeks to work with the
DMC concerned to ensure that the institutional configuration is appro-
priate for giving effect to the sector policy objectives as agreed upon.
16
a system of governance that ensures that money spent to improve the
social infrastructure is indeed used to benefit the sectors targeted. Equally
important, a government’s ability to effectively foster economic growth
and implement social programs is conditional on its institutional and
administrative capabilities. While implementation capacity is crucial across
the board, it is particularly so in the case of programs and projects
addressing social concerns. Thus, the Bank’s growing emphasis on equity
issues (e.g., poverty reduction, women in development, environment)
has highlighted the need to focus on government capacity.
The ADF VI understandings also intensified the focus on develop-
ment performance. It was indicated that the Bank would emphasize
development performance as a criterion for the allocation of ADF
resources.15 For this purpose, development performance was defined
broadly as comprising (i) sound economic management; (ii) efforts
towards growth with equity, and poverty reduction; and (iii) efforts
towards sustainable economic and social development. This balanced
concept of development (combining considerations of efficiency,
equity, and sustainability) is assessed in terms of (i) economic man-
agement, and (ii) progress on “crosscutting concerns.” The Bank now
carries out such performance assessments of DMCs, annually for the
major borrowing countries and once every two years for other
DMCs.16 By their nature, these assessments reflect, to a considerable
degree, the quality of governance in the countries concerned.
Project quality
One of the major themes identified by the TFIPQ was the importance
of institutional capacity in DMCs and project “ownership” by execut-
ing agencies and potential beneficiaries.17 In view of this, it was
emphasized that the Bank should help strengthen DMC capacities for
policy analysis, formulation, and management. A related priority was
assisting DMCs to reform and strengthen public sector management,
particularly in its functions of establishing and maintaining public
15 Doc. R230-91, Revision 1, Final (para. 28). It was also noted (para. 3) that many of the
understandings concerning ADF operations should apply, where relevant, to operations
financed from ordinary capital resources as well (though such application would be the
subject of separate proposals to the Board, in due course).
16 Bank Operations and Country Performance, 1 September 1992.
17 Report of the Task Force on Improving Project Quality, January 1994.
17
infrastructure, the delivery of public services, the mobilization and man-
agement of domestic resources, and the creation and enforcement of
an appropriate legal framework. It was also recommended that the
Bank encourage governments to shed roles and functions that could
be fulfilled by the private and nongovernment sectors with greater
efficiency and effectiveness. This would be conducive not only to
sustainability, but also to wider participation in the development pro-
cess in DMCs (which was highlighted as being a value in itself).18
18
Table 1: East Asias Development Performance
Japan Mauritius
5 Indonesia
Malaysia
GDP growth per capita (percent)
Thailand
4
Italy Brazil
Austria
3 Spain
France
Belgium
United Kingdom
Australia Colombia
2 Sri Lanka
Switzerland Philippines
Pakistan Mexico Kenya
Venezuela
1 India
Malawi Nepa l Chile Argentina
Bolivia Peru
Bangladesh
0 Cote dIvoire
Mauritania
Ghana
Sudan
-1
Zambia
-2
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
Income inequality
Note: Income inequality is measured by the ratio of the income shares of the richest 20 percent
and the poorest 20 percent of the population.
Source: The East Asian Miracle-Economic Growth and Public Policy (World Bank, 1993)
20
The Bank’s approach to
governance issues
T
he Bank’s approach to governance issues will be guided by two
general considerations. These are (i) the provisions of its Charter
as they relate to governance, and (ii) the need for flexible (i.e.,
nondoctrinaire) and country-specific approaches.
21
of Political Activity: The International Character of the Bank.” In view
of its importance in this context, the Article is reproduced in full below.
“1. The Bank shall not accept loans or assistance that may in any way
prejudice, limit, deflect or otherwise alter its purpose or functions.
“2. The Bank, its President, Vice-President(s), officers, and staff shall
not interfere in the political affairs of any member, nor shall they
be influenced in their decisions by the political character of the
member concerned. Only economic considerations shall be
relevant to their decisions. Such considerations shall be weighed
impartially to achieve and carry out the purpose and functions of
the Bank.
“3. The President, Vice-President(s), officers, and staff of the Bank,
in the discharge of their offices, owe their duty entirely to the
Bank and to no other authority. Each member of the Bank shall
respect the international character of this duty and shall refrain
from all attempts to influence any of them in the discharge of
their duties.”21
21 Op cit.
22
of “economic considerations” would exclude the Bank from engaging
in some of the programming considered most important by its mem-
bers; for example, programs that focus on the environment, educa-
tion, or the position of women. While such programming may be
viewed as “social,” the Bank finances such programs on the basis of a
clear consensus that they are based on direct linkages to economic
development and that they can be justified on the basis of the eco-
nomic effects of such noneconomic “social” factors. Therefore, while
Article 36 prevents certain types of political activities, it does not prohibit
the Bank from taking into account demonstrable and direct economic
effects of noneconomic factors as part of the “economic considerations”
on which the Bank must base its decisions. The economic effects of such
noneconomic factors must, however, be clearly established before the
Bank finances programs focusing on such noneconomic factors.
The Bank’s internal processes, in which the Economic and Devel-
opment Resource Center and the Office of the General Counsel are
involved, provide adequate and reasonable assurance that the provi-
sions of Article 36 are not violated and that Bank financing in respect
of apparently noneconomic factors is justified on “economic consider-
ations,” i.e., the demonstrable and direct economic effects of such non-
economic factors. A further safeguard against the Bank basing its
decisions on noneconomic and political considerations is provided by
Article 14(iii) of the Charter, under which the DMC concerned has the
final say over financing of any undertaking in its territory.22
It is pertinent to mention that governance activities of the type con-
templated in this Paper are carried out by the Bank’s sister institutions,
especially the World Bank, under charters with almost identical prohi-
bitions on political activities and provisions directing that decision
making should be on the basis of economic considerations alone.
Accordingly, the Bank will steer clear of overtly political goals, such
as parliamentary democracy and human rights (however desirable these
may be, for their own sake). That being said, however, it also needs
stressing that, in many ways, the Bank’s operations are conducive, albeit
indirectly, to the pursuit of these goals (e.g., through wider participa-
tion in development activities, raising living standards, expanding
22 An exception is the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, whose Charter
embodies political considerations.
23
access to public goods and services, women in development). Hence,
though the Charter provisions explicitly preclude any role for the Bank
in the political aspects of governance, efforts to enhance the quality of
economic governance in DMCs (i.e., management of resources for
development) could well redound to the benefit of the former.
T
he elements of good governance set out in an earlier chapter are
abstract and conceptual in nature. To make them operationally
relevant, the Bank needs to translate them into specific catego-
ries or areas of action. To this end, this chapter indicates ways in which
these elements will be pursued in the context of Bank operations. As
will be seen, in most of these areas, the Bank is already contributing to
governance quality, and has been doing so for some time. The areas in
question are the following.
25
(iii) Predictability (legal frameworks)23
• law and development
• legal framework for private sector development
(iv) Transparency (information openness)
• disclosure of information
The succeeding sections of this chapter deal with each of the above
areas of action.
23 Although legal frameworks are related directly to Predictability and are dealt with here
accordingly, it needs to be recognized that they are overarching in scope and thus relevant
also for Accountability, Participation, and Transparency.
26
Right from the start, therefore, lending to the public sector has been
accompanied by TA for institutional strengthening. Progressing from
the provision of ad hoc advisory inputs (attached to loans or other-
wise), the Bank shifted to more focused, long-term support to specific
DMC institutions, often in the context of repeat loans. Moving on, the
Bank is now undertaking a strategic approach to capacity-building
activities. These will become an important element of country strate-
gies and will be reflected accordingly in country assistance plans. To
this end, the Bank’s economic and sector work will seek to identify
underlying weaknesses and suggest remedial measures.24 As always,
the primary responsibility for developing institutional and organiza-
tional capacity rests with the DMCs themselves, but the Bank has—
and will continue to have—a substantial role to play in assisting their
efforts in this regard.
Box 1 describes a recent example of the Bank’s strategic approach
to capacity building.
I n Indonesia, the Capacity Building Project in the Water Resources Sector (1994)
takes a holistic approach to improving the management of a critical natural resource.
It will help (i) establish a national body to monitor demand, supply, and allocation
nationwide and by province, undertake policy reviews, introduce new policies as
appropriate, and coordinate allocation; (ii) set up water management committees,
hydrometeorological networks, and quality control systems in selected provinces; and
(iii) strengthen the capacity of the Directorate General of Water Resources Develop-
ment for policy review, general and project management, human resources manage-
ment and development, and technical support to the regional agencies, as well as to
the private sector. By strengthening water policies and water quality standards, and
establishing a database at the national level, the Project will result in allocation of
water among competing users on a sustainable and economic basis, smoother project
implementation with reduced delays, greater participation of beneficiaries, and bet-
ter quality construction of water resources infrastructure.
24 Doc. IN.161-94, Bank Support for Capacity Building in Developing Member Countries,
7 September 1994.
27
Public enterprise management and reform
At a fundamental level, public enterprise reform should begin with
consensus-building in respect of an appropriate role for the state in a
market-friendly economy. Downsizing the public sector may not be
an end in itself, but is likely to result from an unbiased examination of
which goods and services are provided better by private institutions.
At the same time, the ability and willingness of governments to trim
profitable state-owned enterprises could depend on the availability of
other sources of revenue. Where this is the case, enlarging the tax base
would help smooth the path of public enterprise reform. While prob-
lems in the management of public enterprises can occur anywhere,
they may be particularly acute in the former centrally planned econo-
mies that are undertaking the transition to market-oriented systems
and in South Asian DMCs.
The reassessment of the rationale of a public enterprise and its
economic prospects could result in a confirmation of its continued
validity or in a recommendation for reform. If the former, the focus
would be on ensuring more effective operations. This may require
increased autonomy in day-to-day functioning (say, through conver-
sion to a joint stock company), on the one hand, and greater account-
ability (to its principal shareholder, the government), on the other.
Reconciling these twin goals may involve shifting from ex ante (or
input-oriented) controls to ex post (or output-oriented) ones. Further,
as a rule of thumb, state-owned enterprises serving commercial ends
could be made to maximize profits, while those that are monopoly
providers could concentrate on minimizing costs instead.
Reform of public enterprises could follow several directions. In
some cases, liquidation may be the answer, with market mechanisms
taking over the function previously rendered by the enterprise con-
cerned. In others, it may be decided to merge two or more enterprises
and rationalize their operations. For some, privatization may be the
preferred option, though this is often the most difficult decision to
implement, on account of the political and social costs involved. Typi-
cally, the process of privatization takes longer to complete than is origi-
nally anticipated. Nevertheless, an extended, but successful, program
for divestiture is better than an underprepared privatization that fails
or is thwarted. The damage caused by the latter could sap the will of
28
the government to pursue other privatizations, and thus reduce the
momentum for economic liberalization.
Where privatization is the chosen route, experience suggests some
ground rules. Creating a competitive operating environment for the
enterprise concerned should normally take priority over the objective
of increasing government revenues in the short run. Hence, public
monopolies should not normally be replaced by private ones. Enter-
prise sales should be transparent, and assets should be evaluated by
an independent firm to avoid the danger that only political insiders
have accurate assessments of plant capacities and liabilities. Labor
should be invited to participate in the process, to avert subsequent
organized unrest. For the same reason, the proceeds of divestiture could
be used for social safety nets or other social purposes (and/or for pri-
ority investments in physical infrastructure). The sale of shares to local
financial institutions and individuals could also help garner political
support for privatization. Public disinvestment should not crowd out
local capital markets, but be used instead to stimulate them.
The success of the Bank’s efforts to assist public enterprise reform
depends largely on two preconditions: first, the commitment of gov-
ernments to improve public sector operations; and second, movement
towards an appropriate macroeconomic and sector policy framework
(including trade liberalization, exchange rate decontrol, and market-
oriented interest rates, and other basic prices in the economy).
Box 2 provides two examples of the Bank’s activities in the field of
public enterprise reform.
29
but public expenditure as a whole (i.e., both capital and recurrent
expenditures). Also important in this context are budgetary allocations
within and between sectors, and the overall adequacy of the
government’s development expenditures. Although the Bank endeav-
ors to analyze these budgetary issues in DMCs, and to raise them in
policy dialogue as appropriate (e.g., during country programming), it
needs to be recognized that its capacity for full-blown public expendi-
ture reviews is still limited.
I n conjunction with the Sixth Road Improvement Project in the Lao Peoples Demo-
cratic Republic (1993), an advisory technical assistance was provided for the priva-
tization and management of road sector institutions. This institutional support to the
Ministry of Communication, Transport, Post and Construction covers (i) management
assistance to already privatized road transport enterprises, (ii) privatization of the
remaining government-owned road transport organizations, and (iii) privatization of
the government-operated road construction and maintenance industry. The objective
is to focus on maximizing private sector participation within a regulatory framework,
with the Government increasingly adopting the role of supervisor and regulator rath-
er than carrying out operations on its own.
The Water and Power Development Authority of Pakistan is implementing a stra-
tegic plan for privatization of the power sector in the country. Under the proposed
structure for the power sector, a vertically integrated authority such as the Karachi
Electricity Supply Corporation Limited (KESC) would be an anachronism. To deter-
mine the optimal method of privatizing this enterprise, the Bank financed an organiza-
tional and financial restructuring study, which recommended that KESC be restructured
around subsidiary companies encompassing the core business of generation, trans-
mission, and retail distribution. Since the technical and financial conditions of the
enterprise were not attractive, the KESC Sixth Power (Sector Loan) Project (1994)
seeks to rehabilitate the transmission and distribution system, and to finance a further
study for recommending actions for the restructuring and privatization of KESC.
30
concerns are understandable and valid (although, to some extent, mili-
tary expenditures may be supply-driven by armaments exporters from
donor countries). At the same time, governments have a sovereign
duty to protect their citizens and territories, and they act in accordance
with their own perceptions of threat, rather than those of outsiders. To
address these issues in a balanced, coordinated, and effective manner,
funding agencies have used the forum provided by country aid groups
or consortia (usually organized by the World Bank). Thus, in recipient
countries where the military budget seems unduly large, the aid
community usually expresses its concern at the annual consortium
meeting, with the clear implication that the level of the overall aid
commitments reflects that concern. As a member of such aid consor-
tia, the Bank associates itself fully with such expressions of concern,
provided the economic effect of military expenditure on the develop-
ment process in the DMC concerned is unequivocal and demonstrable.
In addition to expenditure matters, the Bank also looks at ways to
help DMC governments improve their domestic resource mobilization
efforts, more directly through enhanced cost recovery by public utili-
ties, but also including TA for policy reforms. Taxation is another aspect.
Indeed, in many ways, the manner and effectiveness with which a
government collects taxes are reflective of the standard of governance
that prevails. Hence, the Bank provides training for tax policymakers,
as well as TA for improving tax collection and administration.
Box 3 provides a flavor of the Bank’s activities for helping improve
public financial management in DMCs.
31
Box 3: Public Financial Management
I n collaboration with the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP), the Bank
has helped institutionalize program budgeting and project monitoring (PBPM) in
Nepal. Under the first phase (1986), a program budgeting system for efficient and
economical allocation of scarce resources in the public sector, and a project monitor-
ing system, were set up in the Ministry of Finance (MOF). The second phase (1986)
improved (i) the program budgeting system by including clear criteria and weights to
accommodate multiple objective considerations when ranking projects in order of
priority; and (ii) the project monitoring system by introducing a quantitative method-
ology, developing appropriate interface points among MOF, line ministries, and other
government bodies, and providing training manuals and workshops. In the final phase
(1989), PBPM systems in MOF were improved further and extended to line ministries
with the long-term objective of making PBPM the basis for an integrated government
system.
The Committee for Planning and Cooperation (CPC) is responsible for strategy
and investment planning, management of foreign investment, and coordination of ex-
ternal assistance. Since CPC is constrained by shortages of skills and experience, UNDP,
in cooperation with the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank, pro-
vided technical assistance (TA) for taxation and customs reform, privatization, foreign
investment promotion, and public investment planning. The Bank provided comple-
mentary assistance in macroeconomic planning (1990). Under a follow-on project of
the Government, UNDP, IMF, and the Bank (1993), an integrated framework is being
introduced for the planning, programming, budgeting, and financing (PPBF) process.
The Banks contribution would strengthen the capacity of CPC and selected line min-
istries to undertake macroeconomic planning, policy analysis, formulation, and coor-
dination, and help establish a public investment programming system that is integrated
effectively into the PPBF process.
The Philippines introduced a value-added tax (VAT) in 1988, in replacement of a
variety of sales taxes. Although, since then, the VAT emerged as a dynamic compo-
nent of tax revenue, its potential yield (levied at 10 percent) seemed much larger than
the amount of VAT actually collected (less than 1 percent). The Bank has, therefore,
assisted the Bureau of Internal Revenue (BIR) to improve the VAT assessment, collection and
planning systems, and computerization of these systems (1991). The major outputs of this
TA were (i) an integrated final Information Systems Plan, as the basis for computerization of
all the taxes administered by BIR and (ii) a detailed VAT information system. Together, these
systems would help ensure a more uniform and widespread implementation of tax laws.
Financial accountability is a particular concern of the Bank in the Pacific developing member
countries (DMCs). Although this problem is not unique to these DMCs, it is exacerbated by
the lack of qualified auditors and the dearth of systematic training. The Bank, therefore,
financed a program of audit manpower development workshops for the South Pacific DMCs
to introduce updated audit techniques and to upgrade the technical skills of the participants
(1989). This was followed by an audit training program for the same DMCs, covering two
workshops: one on financial audit management and supervision, and the other on computers
in the audit process (1994). The workshops emphasized in-house training and development
of informal regional support networks for national audit offices.
32
A professional and accountable civil service that can administer
rules, maintain standards and competition, and respect property rights
is critical for private sector confidence in the government’s efforts at
economic reform. What is needed, therefore, is to move progressively
towards public administration systems that provide clear career paths,
adequate compensation and benefits, and incentives that tie
advancement in the civil service more closely to staff performance and
productivity. While downsizing operations should facilitate such
improvements, it will not by itself obviate the requirement for more
sophisticated management and control systems.
Reforms of this nature, especially action to tackle salary erosion
and wage compression, should also impact favorably on the incidence
of corruption. So, too, should market-friendly economic reforms in
general, by reducing the discretionary powers of public officials. In
addition, however, effective oversight mechanisms can help prevent
government agencies from serving their own interests and, thus, reduce
corruption. The Bank’s region offers several good examples of such
institutionalized oversight (especially in Hong Kong, China; Republic
of Korea; and Singapore). By familiarizing policymakers with what has
worked elsewhere, the Bank could help DMCs design tailor-made over-
sight systems to fit their own civil service environments. However, in
this—as in other areas—the Bank will proceed on the basis of requests
made by the DMCs concerned.
Box 4 outlines a modest initiative taken by the Bank in the field of
civil service reform.
33
Box 4: Civil Service Reform
35
Box 5: Beneficiary Participation
36
corruption.25 A notable feature of the successful economies of East Asia
is that most developed effective government-business deliberation
councils, fostering rule-bound decision making by government, and
rendering it harder for government to renege on agreements made.
Their example suggests that, designed properly, consultative mecha-
nisms can increase not only participation and accountability, but also
transparency and predictability in policy formulation and implementation.
25 Once actions of civil servants are open to the scrutiny of consultative councils, secret deals
between officials and preferred clients become more difficult to arrange.
37
will provide TA for analyzing these and other issues related to decen-
tralization, and thus help smooth its implementation.
Legal frameworks
Law and development
A legal environment conducive to development is essential for all DMCs.
It would cover the traditional concept of the rule of law, the existence
of a stable and predictable legal system, as well as law reform for eco-
nomic development. It would also imply effective and efficient admin-
istration of law. This legal framework impacts the entire process of
development and is, therefore, directly relevant to efforts for promot-
ing the latter. This is seen most clearly in the need for market-friendly,
26 The Bank’s policies already permit provision of TA to NGOs.
38
Box 6: Cooperation with NGOs
40
Another consequence of a poorly functioning legal apparatus is
growth of the informal sector, which in turn further undermines the
legal order. Informal enterprises function in the shadow of the law
and, lacking access to formal dispute settlement procedures, have to
resort to extra legal methods. By encouraging such entrepreneurs to
register their operations, reform of the legal environment enhances
the sustainability of the liberalization process by expanding the size of
the formal sector. It also enlarges the government’s revenue base.
Box 7 provides examples of Bank assistance in the field of legal
frameworks.
(i) review the existing institutional and legal framework in order to formulate a plan to
coordinate all future foreign assistance to the legal sector;
(ii) review existing business and commercial laws, with particular attention to the impact of
such laws on the countrys industry sector;
(iii) identify the legislative action required to make the legal system more suited to a market
economy, and assist in the drafting of the necessary legislation; and
(iv) enhance the capacity of the institutions concerned by appropriate training, and strengthen
the resource base for legal training, including the establishment of a clearing-house for
legal information and a center for translation assistance.
41
As another regional TA, the Bank is financing a comprehensive,
comparative, and integrative study of regulations governing securities
market operations and supervisory practices in Bangladesh; Hong
Kong, China; India; Republic of Korea; Malaysia; Philippines; Singapore;
and Taipei,China (1992). The study also reviewed the results of earlier
Bank-financed studies on People’s Republic of China, Indonesia,
Pakistan, Sri Lanka, and Thailand. Based on this review and compara-
tive study, a rationalization plan for each DMC is being prepared, in
consultation with the government concerned, to cover gaps in policy
and improve the quality and degree of regulation and supervision. A
blueprint for implementing the recommended changes will also be
finalized. In addition, specific proposals and areas for future Bank
assistance will be identified.
Information openness
Disclosure of information
Information flows between the government and the private sector con-
tribute greatly to the efficiency of market-oriented economies. Since
the actions of governments are considered in the risk calculations of
private enterprises, the latter value accurate information about gov-
ernment regulations and decisions. Publicly available knowledge also
reduces information asymmetry between lenders and borrowers,
thereby moderating interest rates to a commensurate extent. Govern-
ments, too, must have access to reliable information from the private
sector, as an aid for effective economic decision making. The principal
barrier to such information flows from the private sector is fear of
opportunistic behavior by government officials. A cooperative, rather
than adversary, relationship between government agencies and their
constituencies helps the two-way exchange of information, facilitating
constructive decisionmaking. Governments can also help private firms
by supplying market intelligence as a public service (especially useful
to exporters and small businesses, which may initially find it too costly
to make the necessary investment in information).
The ready availability of high-quality information brings many
advantages. Openness and competition are mutually reinforcing.
42
Institutions that facilitate dialogue between regulator and regulated
serve as safeguards against corruption, since open participation in rule
making is the most effective oversight of all. At the same time, the civil
service is insulated from the pressures of powerful firms and individu-
als. Thus, two-way information flows between the private and public
sectors not only ensure transparency, but also contribute to account-
ability, participation, and predictability. As in the case of legal reform,
the Bank will serve as a clearinghouse for knowledge on best practice
within the region and elsewhere, and will assist, upon request, in the
evaluation of different consultative mechanisms.
43
44
The Bank’s modalities
for enhancing governance
in DMCs
T
he Bank has always contributed significantly to increasing the
quality of governance in its DMCs. This has been especially true
since the adoption (in 1992) of the Bank’s medium-term strategic
frameworks and the pronounced emphasis on the equity and
sustainability aspects of economic development. But even before 1992,
indeed, from their very inception, the Bank’s operations have had an
impact, to a greater or lesser degree, across the full range of the areas
of action indicated in the previous chapter. Given the nature of the
Bank’s activities, however, the categories of action that have benefited
most directly have been public sector management and participatory
development processes. This is likely to be the case in the future also,
although the other areas mentioned will be targeted as well. As its
focus on governance issues sharpens, the Bank will ensure that this
dimension of its development assistance is highlighted appropriately.
This will be achieved by identifying systematically, in consultation with
the DMCs concerned, the opportunities for promoting quality gover-
nance in individual operations and procedures.
In making its approach to governance operational, the Bank will
build on the experience gained thus far. As mentioned, Bank opera-
tions have contributed generally to improving governance standards
in DMCs. More specifically, the manner in which the Bank has
addressed “crosscutting” concerns (e.g., environmental protection)
45
offers a useful analogy. Together, these considerations suggest that
the Bank should integrate governance dimensions into its operations.
This means ensuring, to the extent possible, that Bank-supported pro-
grams and projects are designed such that they raise governance qual-
ity in the sectors concerned (e.g., through inclusion of appropriate
policy measures, project components, or TA). In addition, the Bank
will provide, on request, advisory TA for specific governance-oriented
policy studies, seminars, and training. In all cases, the guiding prin-
ciple for the Bank will be to act on the basis of agreement with the
DMC concerned.
Given this approach, the Bank’s focus on governance improve-
ment will cover, as appropriate
27 Doc. IN.161-94, Bank Support for Capacity Building in Developing Member Countries,
7 September 1994.
28 The commitment of DMCs to improving development performance was highlighted in the
recent Regional Workshop on Improving Project Quality (28 November–1 December 1994).
47
48
Resource implications
E
nhancing the governance dimension of its development
assistance will have resource implications for the Bank. These
would cover (i) staffing, (ii) staff training, (iii) staff consultants
(for economic and sector work), (iv) business travel, and (v) loan and
TA resources, which are discussed briefly below.
The Bank will need to build up its own institutional capacity for
analyzing, assessing, and addressing governance issues in DMCs. This
will require strengthening of the in-house expertise available to the
Bank in the various aspects of governance and institutional develop-
ment. However, given the current budgetary constraints, any new staff
positions required would have to be accommodated through the
ongoing redeployment efforts within the Bank. The Strategy and Policy
Office (SPO), which has been designated as the Bank’s interim focal
point for capacity building in DMCs,29 and the Office of the General
Counsel (OGC) will be responsible for formulating policy and guide-
lines on governance matters.
Current staff, as well as new staff, in the operational departments/
offices will have to be sensitized to and trained in the various aspects
of governance related to Bank activities. The Bank has already started
conducting staff training seminars on topics such as (i) strategies for
institutional development, (ii) privatization and market regulation,
(iii) incorporation of participatory approaches into project design and
implementation arrangements, (iv) cooperation with NGOs, and
(v) legal issues of operational interest to the Bank.30 These programs
29 Doc. IN.161-94.
30 Training and Development Handbook, 1994.
49
will continue, and new ones will be added as the focus on governance
sharpens. As is the case at present, Bank staff will serve as resource
persons, to the extent feasible; nevertheless, there will continue to be
a need for external consultants, especially for the more specialized
subjects. In order to cater to these requirements within the Bank’s train-
ing budget, activities of lower priority will have to be reduced.
The Bank’s governance initiatives will be articulated through the
Bank’s existing modalities and activities, i.e., country and sector docu-
ments, and loan and TA projects. Addressing governance aspects in
these contexts may add to lead times and complexity, as do other issues
of Bank concern, such as women in development and environmental
protection. It is difficult to estimate the resource increases necessary to
do so. However, in several areas, the Bank is already carrying out the
work involved (e.g., participatory approaches to project design and
implementation), and, in some cases, has been doing so for a long
time (e.g., public enterprise reform). Hence, any extra expenditure, in
terms of staff time, business travel, and loan and TA resources would
be adjusted and reflected in the relevant allocations made in the Bank’s
three-year rolling work program and budget implications.
50
Reporting arrangements
T
o monitor (and coordinate) the Bank’s efforts with respect to gov-
ernance issues in DMCs, departments and offices concerned
would be requested to provide SPO and OGC (in respect of legal
frameworks and legal issues of relevance to other areas of action) with
periodic reports on governance-related activities. SPO and OGC would
then collate the information received, serve as the clearinghouse on
best practice, and offer suggestions for further work.
Two years after Board approval of the Bank’s operational policy
on governance issues (i.e., in late-1997), a Board paper will be circu-
lated, analyzing the Bank’s experience with governance activities, pro-
posing modifications to the operational approach as necessary, and
indicating more specific budgetary and other resource implications.
51