Parameters of MP
Parameters of MP
Lecture by Dr Y V Reddy, Deputy Governor of the Reserve Bank of India, at the 88th Annual
Conference of The Indian Econometric Society at Madras School of Economics, Chennai,
15 January 2002.
Dr Y V Reddy is grateful to Dr D V S Sastry, Shri Deepak Mohanty, Shri Indranil Bhattacharyya and Shri Kaushik
Bhattacharya for their assistance
* * *
Friends
It is a great honour to be asked to deliver an invited lecture at the annual conference of the Indian
Econometric Society and I am grateful to the organisers for this opportunity. For obvious reasons,
including the growing interest in monetary policy, I intend presenting before you the parameters of
monetary policy in India. In the first part of this lecture, I propose to give a general overview of the
parameters of monetary policy. In the second part, I would touch upon the international experience in
this regard with a particular focus on changing contours. The third part contains a description of
evolving parameters of monetary policy in India beginning with a brief description of the process of
policy making. The fourth part would highlight the impressive gains made dring the reform period so
far, in regard to statutory preemptions, deregulation of interest rates, financial and external stability
despite the persisting fiscal deficits and large market borrowing programmes. The concluding part sets
forth immediate tasks before the Reserve Bank of India in its conduct of monetary policy.
Objectives
It is generally believed that central banks ideally should have a single overwhelming objective of price
stability. In practice, however, central banks are responsible for a number of objectives besides price
stability, such as currency stability, financial stability, growth in employment and income. The primary
objectives of central banks in many cases are legally and institutionally defined. However, all
objectives may not have been spelt out explicitly in the central bank legislation but may evolve through
traditions and tacit understanding between the government, the central bank and other major
institutions in an economy.
Of late, however, considerations of financial stability have assumed increasing importance in monetary
policy. The most serious economic downturns in the recent years appear to be generally associated
with financial instability. The important questions for policy in the context of financial instability are the
origin and the transmission of different types of shocks in the financial system, the nature and the
extent of feedback in policy and the effectiveness of different policy instruments.
Transmission Mechanism
Monetary policy is known to have both short and long-term effects. While it generally affects the real
sector with long and variable lags, monetary policy actions on financial markets, on the other hand,
usually have important short-run implications. Typical lags after which monetary policy decisions begin
to affect the real sector could vary across countries. It is, therefore, essential to understand the
transmission mechanism of monetary policy actions on financial markets, prices and output. Central
banks form their own views on the transmission mechanism based on empirical evidence, and their
monetary strategies and tactics are designed, based on these views. However, there could be
considerable uncertainties in the transmission channels depending on the stages of evolution of
financial markets and the nature of propagation of shocks to the system.
The four monetary transmission channels, which are of concern to policy makers are: the quantum
channel, especially relating to money supply and credit; the interest rate channel; the exchange rate
channel, and the asset prices channel. Monetary policy impulses under the quantum channel affect
the real output and price level directly through changes in either reserve money, money stock or credit
aggregates. The remaining channels are essentially indirect as the policy impulses affect real activities
through changes in either interest rates or the exchange rate or asset prices. Since none of the
Operating Procedures
Operating procedures refer to the choice of the operational target, the nature, extent and the
frequency of different money market operations, the use and width of a corridor for market interest
rates and the manner of signaling policy intentions. The choice of the operating target is crucial as this
variable is at the beginning of the monetary transmission process. The operating target of a central
bank could be bank reserves, base money or a benchmark interest rate. While actions of a central
bank could influence all these variables, it should be evident that the final outcome is determined by
the combined actions of the market forces and the central bank.
The major challenge in day-to-day monetary management is decision on an appropriate level of the
operating target. The success in this direction could be achieved only if the nature and the extent of
interaction of the policy instruments with the operating target is stable and is known to the central
bank. As the operating target is also influenced by market movements, which on occasions could be
International Experience
In the conduct of monetary policy, although the experiences and the choices made by individual
countries vary, recent surveys highlight a number of common features, viz.,
• First, at the macro level, there is now widespread concern about the potential harmful effects
of persistently high fiscal deficits as it may lead to excessive monetisation.
• Second, there have been significant reductions in the reserve ratio to relieve the pressure on
the banking sector and reduce the costs of intermediation. In fact, a number of countries now
have no reserve requirement;. And, in some countries, the level of minimum deposit at the
central bank has fallen to such low levels that it is no longer considered an active monetary
instrument.
• Third, the deepening of financial markets and the growth of non-bank intermediation have
induced the central banks to increase the market orientation of their instruments. A
consequence of this is a greater activism of central banks in liquidity management.
• Fourth, the greater activism through indirect instruments led to a more intensive use of open
market operations (OMO) through flexible instruments like repo. The OMO can be used for
net injection or absorption of liquidity and can be resorted to irrespective of whether the
operating target works through the rate channel or quantity channel.
• Fifth, the market environment has induced many central banks to focus more on the interest
rates rather than bank reserves in trying to influence liquidity.
• Sixth, increasing evidence of market integration implies that central banks can concentrate
on the very short end of the yield curve. There is growing evidence in favour of co-
movements of interest rates of different maturity. This has simultaneously increased
monetary policy challenges, as central banks have to keep a watchful eye on all markets and
be cautious of any cascading effect or contagion emerging in the domestic economy or
originating in a foreign economy.
• Seventh, at an operational level, while there is increasing transparency on the long-run
strategic objective, central banks may not disclose their tactical considerations as some
maneuverability in influencing the market is required. However, in many cases information is
revealed to the market with a lag. Many central banks also attempt to estimate market
expectations directly through surveys. While market expectations play a major guidepost in
formulating monetary strategies, information management plays a crucial role for short-run
stabilisation.
• Eighth, a notable consequence of recent financial and currency crises has been the
increasing emphasis on the quantity and quality of data dissemination, i.e., adequate, timely
and reliable information in a standardized form.
Transmission Mechanism
The monetary policy framework in India from the mid-1980s till 1997-98 can, by and large, be
characterized as a monetary targeting framework on the lines recommended by Chakravarty
Committee (1985). Because of the reasonable stability of the money demand function, the annual
growth in broad money (M3) was used as an intermediate target of monetary policy to achieve
monetary objectives. Monetary management involved working out a broad money growth through the
money demand function that would be consistent with projected GDP growth and a tolerable level of
inflation. In practice, however, the monetary targeting approach was used in a flexible manner with a
'feedback' from the developments in the real sector.
While the monetary system in India is still evolving and the various inter-sectoral linkages in the
economy are undergoing changes, the emerging evidences on transmission channel suggest that the
rate channels are gradually gaining importance over the quantum channel. The econometric evidence
produced by the Third Working Group on Money Supply (1998) indicated that output response to
policy operating through the interest rate was gaining strength. Similarly, the impact of an
expansionary monetary policy on inflation was found to be stronger through interest rates than the
exchange rate, given the relatively limited openness of the economy.
Operating Procedures
In the pre reform period prior to 1991, given the command and control nature of the economy, the
Reserve Bank had to resort to direct instruments like interest rate regulations, selective credit control
and the cash reserve ratio (CRR) as major monetary instruments. These instruments were used
intermittently to neutralize the monetary impact of the Government's budgetary operations.
The administered interest rate regime during the earlier period kept the yield rate of the government
securities artificially low. The demand for them was created through intermittent hikes in the Statutory
Liquidity Ratio (SLR). The task before the Reserve Bank of India was, therefore, to develop the
markets to prepare the ground for indirect operations.
As a first step, yields on government securities were made market related. At the same time, the RBI
helped create an array of other market related financial products. At the next stage, the interest rate
structure was simultaneously rationalized and banks were given the freedom to determine their major
Modeling Exercises
In addressing a gathering of elite econometricians assembled here, a mention should be made about
developments in monetary modeling. It is well recognized that monetary policy decisions must be
based on some idea of how decisions will affect the real world and this implies conduct of policy within
the framework of a model. As Dr. William White of Bank for International Settlements (BIS) mentioned
in an address recently in RBI, “the model may be as simple as one unspecified equation kept in the
head of the central bank Governor, but one must begin somewhere. Economics may not be a science,
but it should at least be conducted according to scientific principles recognizing cause and effect”.
While reliance on explicit modeling was rather heavy in some central banks, particularly in the 1960
and 1970s, there has been increasing awareness among the policy markers of the limitations of such
models for several reasons. It is difficult to arrive at a proper model for any economy with the degree
of certainty that policy makers want especially in view of observed alterations in the private sector
behaviour in response to official behaviour. Further, data to monitor the economy are sometimes
inadequate, or delayed, and often revised. It is said that in regard to modern economies, not only the
future but even the past is uncertain, due to significant revisions in data. The process of deregulation
coupled with technological progress has led to increasing role for market prices and consequently
more complexities for establishing relationships in an environment where everything happens very
fast, and in a globally interrelated financial world. In brief, there is need to recognize the complexities
in model building for monetary policies and approach it with great humility and a dose of skepticism
but ample justification for such modeling work certainly persists.
It is felt that this is an appropriate time to explore more formally the relationship among different
segments of the markets and sectors of the economy, which will help in understanding the
transmission mechanism of the monetary policy in India. With this objective in mind, RBI had already
announced its intention to build an operational model, which will help the policy decision process. An
Advisory Group with eminent academicians like Professors Mihir Rakshit, Dilip Nachane, Manohar
Rao, Vikas Chitre and Indira Rajaraman as external experts and a team from within the RBI were set
up for developing such a model.
The model was initially conceived to focus on the short term objective of different sources and
components of the reserve money based on the recommendations of an internal technical group on
Liquidity Analysis and Forecasting. Though, multi-sector macro econometric models are available,
such models are based on yearly data and hence these may not be very useful for guiding the short
term monetary policy actions of RBI. Accordingly, it was felt that a short- term liquidity model may be
developed in the RBI focusing on the inter-linkages in the markets and then operationalise these
linkages to other sectors of the economy. The Advisory Group met twice and after deliberations felt
that a daily/weekly/fortnightly model would give an idea about short- to medium-term movements but
models using annual data will also be useful to assess the implications of the monetary policy
measures on the real economy. On the basis of the advice of eminent experts in the Advisory Group, it
has been decided to modify the approach.
The current thinking in RBI is broadly on the following lines: the short term liquidity model making use
of high frequency data will be explored. Accordingly, the interaction of the financial markets with
monetary policy have been examined with weekly data focusing mainly on policy measures and
different rates in the financial markets. Observations in the operational framework of the model is
limited as the LAF has been operationalised only a year ago. A crucial aspect in an exercise is the
forecast of currency in circulation.
The intention of RBI is to expedite the technical work in this regard and seek the advice of individual
members of Advisory Group on an ongoing basis both at formal and informal levels. It is expected that
the draft of the proposed model would be put in public domain shortly. RBI would seek the active
Reduction in CRR
Among the unrealized medium-term objectives of reforms in monetary policy, the most important is
reduction in the prescribed CRR for banks to its statutory minimum of 3.0 per cent. The movement to
3.0 per cent can be designed in three possible ways, viz., the traditional way of pre-announcing a
time-table for reduction in the CRR; reducing CRR as and when opportunities arise as is being done in
recent years; and as a one-time reduction from the existing level to 3.0 per cent under a package of
measures.
In the initial years, the first approach was effective but had to be abandoned when the timetable had to
be disrupted to meet the eruption of global financial uncertainties and pressures on forex market.
Hence, the second approach of lowering CRR when opportunities arise has been adopted, and now it
has been brought down to 5.5 percent. However, if it is felt that this approach takes a longer time and
a compressed time-frame is desirable to expedite development of financial markets, it is possible to
contemplate a package of measures in this regard. The package could mean the reduction of CRR to
the statutory minimum level of 3.0 per cent accompanied by several changes such as in the present
way of maintenance of cash balances by banks with RBI. With the lagged reserve maintenance
system now put in place, banks can exactly know their reserve requirements. With the information
technology available with banks and with the operationalisation of Clearing Corporation of India Ltd.
(CCIL) shortly and with the development of repo market, it would be appropriate if CRR is maintained
on a daily basis. However, till banks adjust to such changes in the maintenance of CRR, a minimum
balance of 95 per cent of the required reserves on a daily basis may have to be maintained when CRR
is reduced to 3.0 per cent. The other elements of package have to be worked out carefully.
Concluding Remarks
In this lecture, I have attempted to focus on the conduct of monetary policy and highlighted some of
the immediate tasks. In case, there is interest in an overview of theory and analytics, especially in the
context of role of monetary policy in revitalizing growth in India, I would urge you to refer to the Report
on Currency and Finance 2000-01, released yesterday. The challenges ahead are aptly summarized
in the concluding paragraph of the chapter on Growth, Inflation and the Conduct of Monetary Policy of
the Report, which states “The conduct of monetary policy in India would continue to involve the
constant rebalancing of objectives in terms of the relative importance assigned, the selection of
instruments and operating frameworks, and a search for an improved understanding of the working of
the economy and the channels through which monetary policy operates”.