Itallian Regulatory Authority
Itallian Regulatory Authority
LQ,WDO\
5HJXODWRU\5HIRUPLQWKH7HOHFRPPXQLFDWLRQV
,QGXVWU\
ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION
AND DEVELOPMENT
Pursuant to Article 1 of the Convention signed in Paris on 14th December 1960, and which came
into force on 30th September 1961, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)
shall promote policies designed:
to achieve the highest sustainable economic growth and employment and a rising standard of
living in Member countries, while maintaining financial stability, and thus to contribute to
the development of the world economy;
The original Member countries of the OECD are Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, France,
Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden,
Switzerland, Turkey, the United Kingdom and the United States. The following countries became Members
subsequently through accession at the dates indicated hereafter: Japan (28th April 1964), Finland (28th
January 1969), Australia (7th June 1971), New Zealand (29th May 1973), Mexico (18th May 1994), the
Czech Republic (21st December 1995), Hungary (7th May 1996), Poland (22nd November 1996), Korea
(12th December 1996) and the Slovak Republic (14th December 2000). The Commission of the European
Communities takes part in the work of the OECD (Article 13 of the OECD Convention).
© OECD 2001
Permission to reproduce a portion of this work for non-commercial purposes or classroom use should be
obtained through the Centre français d’exploitation du droit de copie (CFC), 20, rue des Grands-Augustins,
75006 Paris, France, tel. (33-1) 44 07 47 70, fax (33-1) 46 34 67 19, for every country except the United
States. In the United States permission should be obtained through the Copyright Clearance Center, Customer
Service, (508)750-8400, 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923 USA, or CCC Online:
www.copyright.com. All other applications for permission to reproduce or translate all or part of this book
should be made to OECD Publications, 2, rue André-Pascal, 75775 Paris Cedex 16, France.
Regulatory reform has emerged as an important policy area in OECD and non-OECD countries. For
regulatory reforms to be beneficial, the regulatory regimes need to be transparent, coherent, and
comprehensive, spanning from establishing the appropriate institutional framework to liberalising network
industries, advocating and enforcing competition policy and law and opening external and internal markets to
trade and investment.
This report on Regulatory Reform in the Telecommunications Industry analyses the institutional set-
up and use of policy instruments in Italy. It also includes the country-specific policy recommendations
developed by the OECD during the review process.
The report was prepared for The OECD Review of Regulatory Reform in Italy published in 2001.
The Review is one of a series of country reports carried out under the OECD’s Regulatory Reform
Programme, in response to the 1997 mandate by OECD Ministers.
Since then, the OECD has assessed regulatory policies in 16 member countries as part of its
Regulatory Reform programme. The Programme aims at assisting governments to improve regulatory quality
— that is, to reform regulations to foster competition, innovation, economic growth and important social
objectives. It assesses country’s progresses relative to the principles endorsed by member countries in the
1997 OECD Report on Regulatory Reform.
The country reviews follow a multi-disciplinary approach and focus on the government's capacity to
manage regulatory reform, on competition policy and enforcement, on market openness, specific sectors such
as electricity and telecommunications, and on the domestic macroeconomic context.
This report was principally prepared by Wonki Min, of the Directorate on Science, Technology, and
Industry, with the participation of Dimitri Ypsilanti of the Directorate on Science, Technology, and Industry.
It has benefited from comments provided by colleagues throughout the OECD. It benefited from extensive
comments provided by colleagues throughout the OECD Secretariat, as well as close consultations with a
wide range of government officials, parliamentarians, business and trade union representatives, consumer
groups, and academic experts in Italy. The report was peer-reviewed by the 30 member countries of the
OECD. It is published under the authority of the OECD Secretary-General.
BIBLIOGRAPHY ........................................................................................................................................ 50
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Tables
Figures
The telecommunications industry has undergone significant regulatory reform over the last decade. By the beginning of
2001, 27 OECD Member countries have liberalised their telecommunications market, including voice telephony,
infrastructure investment and foreign investment in the telecommunications service industry. The success of the
liberalisation process depends on the presence of a transparent and effective regulatory regime that enables the
development of fair competition in the marketplace. Together with the transparent and effective regulatory regime, the
regulator’s readiness and willingness to apply pro-competitive regulatory measures in favour of promoting competition
play a key role in making a smooth transition of the telecommunications sector from monopoly to full competition. In
this context, this report analyses the effectiveness of the Italian telecommunications regulatory regime together with the
evaluation on the performance of the regulatory bodies.
By and large, the telecommunications market liberalisation in Italy has been driven by the European Commission’s
efforts to liberalise the European telecommunications market. Indeed, in most important policy issues such as
interconnection, licensing, universal service, etc., EU Directives have played a key role in moulding the Italian
regulatory framework. The Italian government has made many important policy decisions to promote competition since
the mid 1990s. Now, with the completion of the implementation of EU Directives into national legislation, Italy has a
fairly comprehensive regulatory regime enabling it to promote competition in the telecommunications sector.
Furthermore, for certain regulatory measures such as the coverage of carrier pre-selection, monitoring service of quality
and the unbundling of the local loop, the Italian regulatory regime has one of the most pro-competitive approaches
amongst all OECD member countries.
Italy, as regards the structure of the regulator (AGCOM or Autorità per le garanzie nelle comunicazioni), has a unique
regulatory system among OECD countries. In particular, the regulator has the responsibility to supervise the
telecommunications sector as well as the broadcasting sector and the press. This can enable the regulator to make
technologically neutral regulatory decisions and take consistent regulatory approaches for the whole communications
sector. At the same time, the regulator has demonstrated its willingness to promote competition through successive
regulatory rulings and new legislation.
However, there are a number of issues, which need to be promptly addressed in order to expedite the level of
competition in the marketplace. First of all, the AGCOM needs to have the necessary staff to exercise its regulatory
power appropriately and in a timely manner. In spite of the full empowerment of regulatory responsibility by law,
currently the AGCOM still shares regulatory powers with the Ministry, partially due to a lack of adequate staffing. This
regulatory power sharing has created confusion for market players in trying to determine which is the relevant regulatory
body governing specific issues such as spectrum management and numbering. At the same time, there is a need to
change regulations so that they are more user-friendly and market oriented. For example, the licensing regime is still
very complicated, and included up to the beginning of 2001 the use of concessions. In addition, the government’s golden
share in the incumbent creates uncertainty in the marketplace.
The incumbent still has a largely dominant market share in the access and local call market and leased line markets. The
dominance of the incumbent in the local market highlights the importance of the role of the regulator in the Italian
telecommunications market since there would not be fair competition unless the regulator ensures a non-discriminatory
and cost-oriented access regime.
The reform of telecommunications markets in Italy has initially been driven by European Union
(EU) policies. Since the release of the 1987 “Green Paper on the Development of the Common Market for
Telecommunications Services”, the European Commission has played an important role in promoting the
liberalisation of the EU telecommunications market through successive liberalisation directives and
harmonisation directives.
Unlike the UK and Scandinavian countries, which undertook national initiatives to liberalise their
markets ahead of the EU efforts, the EU directives have mostly guided Italy’s liberalisation of the
telecommunications market. In fact, the liberalisation of the Italian telecommunications market can be best
described as the adoption of EU directives into national legislation, a process in which Italy has barely met
deadlines and was often late in keeping the EU’s deadline. In recent years the situation has improved and
liberalisation deadlines are being met with more regularity.
The late liberalisation of the market has helped the incumbent to maintain a dominant position in
the access and local voice market as well as the leased line market. Since there is practically no CATV
networks in Italy, the incumbent’s local loop is and will remain an essential facility for new entrants to access
end customers until wireless local loop (WLL) is in place. It implies that all new entrants need to interconnect
with the incumbent’s local loop to terminate their fixed to fixed and mobile to fixed phone calls unless they
have an agreement for local loop unbundling (ULL) with the incumbent. This emphasises the importance of
the role of regulator because the only way for new entrants to access end customers is through the
incumbent’s local loop.
Most OECD countries allow telecommunications operators to follow a legal proceeding through the
courts when they are not satisfied with the regulator’s ruling, and telecommunication operators, in particular,
incumbents use this recourse as a means of slowing down implementation of new rules. Nevertheless, it is
extraordinary that in Italy the incumbent, Telecom Italia, has gone to court against almost all regulatory
rulings made by the regulator. Of particular importance the dispute on the completion of rebalancing which
resulted in the regulator and the incumbent taking different positions on most regulatory issues such as
pricing regulation, and unbundling.
Telecom Italia is subject to “golden share regulation” based on the “Golden Share Decree1” issued
on 11 February 2000 and Telecom Italia’s constitution. According to the Golden Share Decree, the Italian
government can use its special powers to block an acquisition of Telecom Italia in order to protect the vital
interests of the State and the public. Although the Italian government did not exercise its special power when
Deutsche Telekom and Olivetti competed to take over Telecom Italia (Olivetti finally succeeded), the
existence of a “golden share regulation” means that the Italian government still is empowered to intervene in
the case of an acquisition of the incumbent.
Even after the liberalisation of telecommunication markets, a large number of OECD countries still maintain measures to
control ownership of the incumbent, in addition to asymmetric regulation based on telecommunications regulations and
general competition rules.
One way this has been done is by maintaining a majority shareholding of the incumbent or by imposing “golden share”
regulation. Since privatisation of the incumbent is not included in WTO commitments or in EU directives as a condition
of market opening, some governments such as the Netherlands and Germany still have a majority shareholding in the
incumbent. In particular, the Dutch government also has a “golden share” of KPN. In Italy and Spain, in spite of the fact
that the government does not hold enough shares to control the incumbent, the government can influence certain
activities of the incumbent through a “golden share”.
On the other hand, there are a number of countries such as Japan and France, which have a special law for supervising
the incumbent. In many cases, this special law requires a minimum percentage of government ownership and imposes
foreign ownership and/or individual ownership restrictions.
In principle, in a liberalised telecommunication service market where there are an increasing number of market players
and where capacity is being traded as a commodity, it does not make much sense to maintain special regulations on the
incumbent in addition to regulation based on general competition principles. In particular, considering the rapid
development of alternative infrastructure such as cable television networks and wireless networks, there is no reason to
impose special regulations on the incumbent other than regulations based on concepts of market power or essential
facilities. In any event, all countries have special requirements for national emergencies that they can use to impose
requirements on the incumbent.
1.2. General features of the regulatory regime, telecommunications market and market participant
In Italy, until 1992, telecommunications services were provided directly by the State through the
ASST (Telephone Services State Agency) and the Posts and Telegraphs Administration (PT), or indirectly
through several concessionaires such as SIP, ITALCABLE, TELESPAZIO, SIRM, and TELEMAR.2
In 1992, the Italian government decided to give management of all telecommunication services
to the concessionaires (Law No.58/92). In 1994, recognising that the division of telecommunication
operations weakened the overall development of the Italian telecommunications industry, the Italian
government merged all concessionaires into a single company, Telecom Italia, with the exception of
TELEMAR. A year later Telecom Italia Mobile was established, and in 1997 Telecom Italia was incorporated
into STET (Societá Finanziaria Telefonica), following which STET changed its name to Telecom Italia.
In 1995, all telecommunications services were liberalised except fixed voice telephony, mobile and
satellite services and network installations. In 1997, networks and services by satellite were liberalised by
Decree-Law 11 February 1997, No. 55. On 31 July 1997 the Italian Parliament enacted Law No. 249 on the
“creation of the telecommunications National Regulatory Agency (AGCOM – Autorità per le Garanzie nelle
Comunicazioni)” and provisions on telecommunications and broadcasting systems. The Presidential Decree
of 19 September 1997, No. 318 completed full liberalisation of the telecommunications market.
In the mobile market, Omnitel, the second mobile operator commenced services in 1995 and Wind,
the third mobile operator commenced operation in March 1999. Blu S.p.a., which obtained a licence as the
fourth national operator on August 4 1999, began providing a DCS 1800 service in the summer of 2000.
Before 1992: Provision of radio and telecommunications services by the State either directly or through
concessionaires.
1992: The responsibility to provide all telecommunications services was given to the concessionaires.
1994: All concessionaires were merged into a single company, Telecom Italia, with the exception of TELEMAR.
1995: Liberalisation of telecommunications services except voice telephony, mobile and satellite services and
network provision.
Telecommunications market
At the end of 1999 Italy’s telecommunications market size is estimated at USD 32.9 billion,3 the
sixth largest telecommunication service in the OECD (and 4th largest among EU Member countries).
In particular, Italy’s mobile market was the third largest in the OECD in terms of revenue (USD 12
billion) and the number of subscribers (2nd and 1st in the EU respectively). The rapid growth of mobile
services is largely due to the introduction of prepaid card services. After the introduction of prepaid card
service in 1996, Italy’s mobile penetration rate ranking jumped from 12th to 8th among OECD member
countries between 1996 and 1997. Approximately 82% of TIM customers, as of 31 December 1999 used
prepaid cards. The only other OECD country, which has a comparable pre-paid card subscription percentage
with Italy, is Portugal.
(percentage)
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 June 1999
Ranking 17 14 14 14 12 12 12 8 6 7
Source: OECD.
At the end of 1999, the incumbent operator, Telecom Italia, was the world’s seventh largest fixed
telecommunications operator with approximately 26.5 million fixed lines including ISDN, and its subsidiary
TIM was the largest mobile operator in Europe and the third largest in the world with 18.5 million mobile
customers.4
As of the end of 1999, there were approximately 448 000 lines (points of entry of data network)
leased to business customers of which 240 000 related to data transmission. In addition, there were almost
25 000 digital leased lines related to backbone networks and almost 8 500 digital lines for interconnection
with the Telecom Italia network leased to other domestic telecommunications operators.
In Italy, cable television networks have not developed due to the rapid development of analogue
terrestrial television, which was completely liberalised in 1976. As of 30 November 1999, there were
11 national terrestrial television channels, over 700 local television broadcasters (analogue) and
1 709 000 subscribers for satellite television.5 TV subscribers can view 57 to 60 terrestrial broadcasting
channels. TI is the largest shareholder of Stream,6 which was the only cable TV service provider in Italy until
the Autumn of 2000, when Canal + reached an agreement with TI to distribute its own channels. Stream
leases its facility from TI and has no plans to install its own networks. As of 30 November 1999 Stream had
about 500 000 customers, of which only 82 000 are served by cable and the others are served via digital
satellite programming.7
In the Internet market, as of the end of 1999, there were 4 930 000 subscribers.8 Telecom Italia Net
(Tin.it), the Internet service provider subsidiary of the incumbent telecommunication operator had the largest
market share with 1 990 000 subscribers. In spring 2000 several providers began marketing broadband
services using ADSL technology which permits fast access to Internet and the use of interactive multimedia
services.
In the fixed voice telephony market, there were 122 licences for PSTN network and/or service
providers as of 1 June 2000. Except for the incumbent, Telecom Italia, major fixed voice telephony service
providers are Infostrada9 (owned by the National Electricity Co. [ENEL]), Albacom, Wind, Tiscali and Tele2.
In the mobile market, TIM is the sole provider of analogue mobile telecommunications services,
which account for about 8% of the mobile market in terms of users Analogue service is based on the TACS
900 standard and began operation in 1990. There are four operators including TIM with licences for GSM
and/or DCS 1800 mobile services. TIM and Omnitel began their GSM services in 1995. Wind had begun to
commercialise GSM/DCS services in March 1999. Wind and Omnitel are the only Italian
telecommunications operators that have both a mobile and a fixed licence. Blu began service in summer
2000, using DCS-1800, with cost-oriented roaming in the 900 MHz band. The late entrance of the third and
the fourth mobile operators gave a competitive advantage to TIM and Omnitel allowing them to obtain the
lion’s share of the market.
In addition 5 UMTS licenses were awarded in November 2000; a ruling allowing trials for wireless
in the local loop services (40.5-42.5 GHz band) shall enter into force soon, as well as licensing in the 24.5-
26.5 / 27.5-29.5 GHz bands.
It is noteworthy that Italian mobile operators do not provide any handset subsidies. Considering the
fact that handset subsidies take a significant portion of mobile operator’s cost structure in other countries, the
lack of handset subsidies enables Italian mobile operators to offer lower service charges on mobile services.
(See Section 3.1)
Mobile Analogue: 1 (TIM). Analogue: TIM - 100% Market share is estimated on the
Digital: 4 (TIM, OPI, Digital: basis of number of subscribers as of
WIND and BLU). -TIM - 48.7%. Sept. 2000 in GSM/DCS market
-OPI - 38.7%. (some 35.5 million total
-WIND - 11.1%. subscribers).
-BLU - 1.5%.
CATV 2 Stream: 100%; TELE+ (operation
started in October 2000).
Source: AGCOM.
The AGCOM, based in Naples, is the regulator in the telecommunications sector while the Ministry
of Communications (Ministry) has the responsibility of policy making in the sector.10 The AGCOM was
established by Law No.249 of 31 July 1997 and became operational from 22 July 1998. According to Law
No. 249 the AGCOM is fully independent and has authority on all regulatory issues in the
telecommunications sector (See Box 1). In addition, the AGCOM has investigative powers as well as the
authority to impose sanctions on operators who do not comply with their directives and resolutions.
- Regulations on interconnection.
- Market entry: granting licences and issuing authorisations. This competence has been transferred to the Ministry of
Communications as from 26 March 2001.
- Price regulation.
The horizontal regulatory competency over the whole communication sector (broadcasting,
telecommunications, and press) provides the AGCOM with one of the most comprehensive regulatory roles
in the OECD area. The AGCOM is one of five regulators11 in the OECD, which has regulatory power both in
the telecommunications sector and the broadcasting sector. Furthermore, the AGCOM is the only regulator
whose organisational structure is not based on specific services, such as telecommunications, broadcasting
and press, but structured on the basis of more general framework such as networks and services. Accordingly,
The organisational structure of the AGCOM consists of a council and two commissions (Network &
Infrastructure Commission and Services & Products Commission) which have specific regulatory
responsibilities in their own areas. Each commission is a collegial body made up of the president of the
AGCOM and four commissioners. The council consists of the president and all the commissioners.
The Senate of the Republic and the Chamber of Deputies each elect four commissioners, the
president of the AGCOM is appointed by the President of the Republic upon proposal of the Prime Minister
in agreement with the Minister of Communications, after a parliamentary hearing. AGCOM’s first year
operating expenditure was covered by a 0.35 per thousand levy, (rising to 1 per thousand for following years)
on revenues of national operators (except new entrants operating for less than two years) in the sectors under
its responsibility as well as administration fees such as licence fees, numbering fees, etc. According to the
law, the number of AGCOM’s permanent staff cannot exceed 260 persons. Currently there is about 200 staff
at the AGCOM.
There is a concern in the telecommunications industry that the nomination of commissioners is too
political. It is very important for the regulator to ensure its independence from all interested parties if there is
to be fair competition in the marketplace. In this regard, it is useful that the AGCOM publish not only its
regulatory decisions, but also the reasoning for its regulatory decisions.
Although the new law gave most of regulatory power to the AGCOM, lack of staff has meant that
the AGCOM has taken some time to become fully operational. In fact, the AGCOM has carried out a number
of tasks jointly with the Ministry under a bilateral agreement,12 which was supposed to expire in December
1999. However, the AGCOM and the Ministry extended this joint operation by renewing the agreement. This
joint operation has sometimes created confusion among market players in that they are not sure which
organisation is responsible for specific regulatory issues, such as spectrum allocation. The two year period
required for the transfer of full regulatory power from the Ministry to the regulator, the fact that AGCOM
was not fully operational when the market opened to competition and difficulties in recruiting professional
staff have all acted to slow implementation of appropriate regulatory safeguards in some market segments
The Ministry and the AGCOM have taken a public consultation approach (Green Paper approach)
for important decision making process. In particular, since 1999 the Ministry and the AGCOM have started to
use the Internet for public consultations, such as those on UMTS, wireless local loop and the general
authorisation regime. The consultative approach in decision-making is widely welcomed by the industry since
it helps to enhance transparency of decisions.
As the role of the competition authority has grown in the telecommunications sector, OECD
countries have give more attention to the issue of potential overlap between the sector specific regulator and
the competition authority in order to prevent inconsistent regulatory rulings between the competition
authority and the telecommunications regulator.
In Italy, apart from general informal consultation, the competition authority and the AGCOM are
required to request the opinion of the other institution in specific cases. The competition authority is required
by law to ask for prior non-binding advice from the AGCOM on decisions concerning agreements restricting
competition, abuses of dominant power and mergers involving operators active in the communications sector
(Law No. 249/97, Section 1, Paragraph 6, Letter c), Point 11).
On the other hand, the competition authority is required to issue prior non-binding advice to the
AGCOM, on the identification of telecommunications operators with significant market power, conditions of
interconnection and access to networks, universal service funding, and accounting separation. As mentioned
in the background report to Chapter 3, which examines Competition Policy, a lack of agreement between two
regulators does not give the other agency a veto over action, but it may compel a more complete explanation
of the decision.
While the regulatory relationship and the consultation mechanism between the AGCOM and the
competition authority is well established, some operators complain about the delay in regulatory decisions
resulting from the long consultation period between two regulatory bodies. The AGCOM replies that this
period of time do not normally exceed two months.
Licensing regime
Italy established a general licensing regime when the telecommunications market was liberalised.
The incumbent, Telecom Italia, and the two dominant mobile operators, TIM and Omnitel, initially have
maintained concessions. Telecom Italia’s concession was changed into a licence in November 2000, while the
change of the concessions of TIM and Omnitel took place in March 2001. The special and exclusive rights in
the concessions were, in any event, abolished on 1 January 1998.
Rights of way
Rights of way regulation in Italy is based mostly on several laws. Art. 4, Par. 3 of Law 249/97
stipulates that the licensed operators can lay down backbone networks. However, in terms of territory, which
is controlled by the local municipalities, the local municipalities have the authority to grant rights of way
based on local rules that shall be in line with a ruling issued by the national regulatory authority. If rights of
way cannot be granted to a new operator, AGCOM and the local municipalities can order facility sharing
using existing infrastructures. There is a mechanism to resolve conflict between companies concerning
facility sharing, conflict regarding rights of way between municipalities and telecommunications operators
can be brought to court in the first instance.
Since each local municipality has its own rights-of-way regulation, operators are required to receive
separate permission from municipalities for the construction of local networks. Furthermore, since
municipalities have the regulatory power to grant rights of way in their regional area, the purpose of the
ruling issued by AGCOM is to minimise the risk that operators face different rights of way regulations in
different municipal areas.
In addition, the involvement of local utilities in the telecommunications sector raises a concern of
possible discrimination in granting rights of way.18 It is important that conditions and requirements to attain
rights of way are transparent and non-discriminatory. In this respect, a public consultation is currently
underway for the introduction of a new regulatory framework on rights of way. AGCOM plans to introduce a
new regime by the summer of 2001. In the new rights-of-way regulatory regime, it would be strongly
recommended to give regulatory power to AGCOM to intervene in conflicts between municipalities and
telecommunications operators and to make binding resolutions.
The operators with significant market power have an obligation to meet reasonable requests for
collocation. In particular, with regard to the issuance of the third and the fourth mobile licences, TIM and
Omnitel are required to provide site-sharing agreements at cost-oriented prices to Wind and Blu under the
supervision of AGCOM. In addition, in order to ensure fair competition between Blu and other mobile
operators, the existing mobile operators are required to provide national roaming service to Blu.
For the provision of international cables, licensed operators for public network provision can
construct their own cable landing stations. However, considering the high investment cost to construct a cable
landing station, AGCOM has ensured that access to the incumbent’s cable landing stations is available for
new entrants and covered within the framework of interconnection regulation at the Telecom Italia’s RIO
2000.
Except for a special regulation on Telecom Italia that prohibits it to enter the terrestrial broadcasting
market due to its concession in the telecommunications market, there are no line-of-business restrictions in
Italy. If a cable operator wants to provide telecommunications services on its network it may ask for a voice
telephony licence either when applying for a CATV network licence or at a later stage. Law 249/97 provides
that networks used for broadcasting purposes may be used for the provision of telecommunication services
(provided that accounting or structural separation is assured, depending on whether the broadcaster has a
national or local TV licence).
There are no restrictions on foreign ownership in Italy and on the share holding of a single party.
However as mentioned earlier, Telecom Italia is subject to the golden share regulation. In a liberalised
market, there is no reason to impose special regulations on specific companies.
Following the liberalisation of the telecommunications market, probably the most important
regulatory safeguard to ensure fair competition is the establishment of a fair and transparent access regime.
Indeed, such a fair and transparent access regime is vital if there is no alternative local loop to that of the
incumbent, which is the case in Italy. In particular, the pricing mechanism of the access regime determines
the profitability of new entrants and eventually determines the level of competition in the marketplace. The
AGCOM has made very important regulatory decisions on the access regime recognising the dominance of
Telecom Italia in the local loop market.
Interconnection
Due to the lack of alternative infrastructure in the local loop, it is essential for other operators to
interconnect with Telecom Italia’s local loop in order to terminate their calls.
- Interconnection should be available on the same terms and conditions for competing operators as SMP operators
providing for their own services
- SMP operators are required to keep separate accounting for interconnection services and other telecommunications
services.
Currently Telecom Italia, TIM and Omnitel are designated as operators with significant market
power in the interconnection market by AGCOM’s Determination No. 197/99 of 7.11.99. The AGCOM
makes an annual review to determine SMP operators and relevant markets.
The interconnection framework for fixed networks has been in place since 1998, when the
telecommunications market was liberalised. The Italian interconnection regime is based on a service
competition model with no minimum requirement on interconnection points, and no discrimination in
interconnection charges between facility-based operators and simple resellers. While this service-based
competition model can help new entrants enter the market without a significant economic burden arising from
investing in network installations, in the longer term there is a risk that facility-based competition may not
develop if there is not sufficient incentive for new entrants to build their own networks.
Currently Telecom Italia’s interconnection charges are calculated using a fully distributed
accounting (FDC) model based on historical costs in spite of the fact that Decree of 23 April 1998 requires
the AGCOM to set up a new accounting methodology based on long run incremental cost by 1 January 1999.
Order 10/00/CIR20 committed AGCOM to publish a determination establishing the criteria of an accounting
system based on current costs by May 2000 after a public consultation. Although the results of the
consultation were published in November 2000 no guidelines were published outlining an implementation
process. In addition to cost orientation requirements, SMP operators’ interconnection charges are also
required to meet the EU “best practice guideline” according to the Decree. If SMP operators’ interconnection
charges are higher than those of the EU “best practice guideline”, the burden of proof is on the operator to
Table 7. Comparison of Telecom Italia’s interconnection charges and the upper limits of EU “best practice
guideline” (as of Sep. 1999, Euro cents per min.)
Telecom Italia’s interconnection The upper limit of EU “best practice
charges guideline”
Local switch (fixed to fixed) 1.00 1.00
Local switch (mobile to 1.00 1.00
fixed)
Single tandem (fixed to 1.60 1.60
fixed)
Single tandem (mobile to 1.60 1.60
fixed)
Double tandem (fixed to 2.30 2.30
fixed)
Double tandem (mobile to 2.30 2.30
fixed)
Source: EU, “Fifth report on the implementation of the telecommunications regulatory package”.
In spite of the merits of service competition, which can lead to a rapid introduction of competition, reduction of prices,
and an increase in consumer choice, there is a consensus that in the longer term facility based competition brings more
benefits to consumers. In particular, facility based competition enables competition in the wholesale market, which in
turn stimulates reductions in retail prices and brings new innovative services through competition between infrastructure
providers.
To promote infrastructure competition, some countries have opted for favourable interconnection conditions for facility-
based operators or impose specific interconnection requirements on new licensees. For example, in the United Kingdom,
‘Annex II’ operators, which require ‘significant investment in infrastructure’ including Indirect Access operators have
enjoyed cost oriented interconnection rate while service providers (resellers) have been subject to ‘retail minus’
schemes. A similar approach has been taken also by the United States,21 France,22 Denmark23 and Spain.24 In the United
States, the FCC, on the basis of the 1996 Telecommunications Act, began to regulate local resale rates, and state
regulators have since then maintained a positive difference between wholesale rates, which are set at a discount from
retail rates, and interconnection rates which are cost based. As a result, local resale of telephone services is considered a
low margin business in the United States.25 Under cost-orientation principles, it is not necessary for there to be a
difference in interconnection charges between facility-based operators and service operators if interconnection costs are
the same for the incumbent. However, there is a concern that this would create a disincentive to the incumbent and to
new entrants to invest in infrastructure.
The current Italian regulatory regime concerning the calculation of interconnection charges is based
on the FDC accounting methodology that tends to over-compensate the incumbent by subsidising inefficient
historical costs incurred by the incumbent. As a result, there is a possibility that high interconnection charges
based on the FDC methodology can hamper a new entrant’s ability to compete with the incumbent. Thus,
AGCOM needs to introduce the LRIC accounting model as soon as possible as stipulated in the Decree. The
interconnection procedure allows AGCOM the possibility to determine its interconnection charges either by
accepting the incumbent’s proposal based on the FDC model or to impose “EU best practice” if the proposed
interconnection charge is above EU best practice. The longer term aim should be to attain cost-oriented
interconnection charges as quickly as possible and the best practice methodology for this is the LRIC model.
A contentious interconnection issue in Italy relates to the linkage introduced by AGCOM in retail
charges and wholesale charges. AGCOM believes that changes in retail tariffs should be reflected by changes
in interconnection charges. The incumbent argues that this in effect imposes a fixed margin between
interconnection charges and retail charges and is thus a distortion of the cost-orientation principle and a
disincentive to competition. However, until interconnection charges are deemed to be cost-oriented, and until
there is an adequate level of competition, the danger remains that the incumbent can use changes in retail
prices to squeeze the profits of new entrants by maintaining high interconnection prices. The difficulty for the
regulator is to determine when it is appropriate to withdraw from such direct price intervention. It would, in
this context be useful for the regulator to draw up some general guidelines indicating the circumstances under
which it would streamline its price intervention.
In September 1999, TIM and Omnitel were designated as SMP operators in the interconnection
market. This meant that in principle TIM and Omintel should have been subject to general obligations of
SMP operators in the interconnection market like Telecom Italia. In practice, a charge-cap was applied to
fixed to mobile interconnection charges while no specific regulation was imposed on mobile to mobile
interconnection charges. In June 1999, the AGCOM set up a charge cap for TIM and Omnitel’s fixed to
mobile interconnection charges (360 Lit/min). Since TIM and Omnitel are allowed to differentiate
interconnection charges based on the retail charging mechanism, in practice fixed to mobile interconnection
charges differ between peak (430 LL/min) and off-peak (190 LL/min).
The AGCOM’s decision to change the charging structure of fixed to mobile phone calls and to
designate TIM and Omnitel as SMP operators in the interconnection market was a right decision which
resulted in an important reduction (average reduction of 29%) on fixed to mobile interconnection charges.
This decision is based on the assessment of an international best practice as identified by an external auditor
into an investigation conducted by the DG Competition of the European Union. Nevertheless the charge cap
imposed on TIM and Omnitel is higher than the one recommended by the competition authority. Currently
there is no regulation on mobile to mobile interconnection charges. In practice, a reciprocal interconnection
accounting scheme has been in place between mobile operators since January 1999.
With the development of electronic commerce and high speed Internet application services, there is
a growing demand for direct access to end customers in order to provide value added services such as Internet
services and cable television services as well as voice telephony services. In this context, regulators have
given priority to unbundling of the local loop (ULL) in many OECD member countries.
AGCOM has formed a monitoring group of the implementation of ULL in order to ensure the rapid
development of ULL in the Italian telecommunications market. Currently fifteen new entrants who plan to
use ULL for their service provision are participating in the monitoring group. Telecom Italia’s RIO for ULL
has been reviewed by the AGCOM, which has set the following charges for the local loop: monthly rental Lit.
22 200 for POTS, ISDN lines; 24 300 for ADSL enabled lines; the one-off set up fee is 174 400 Lit; the
monthly fee per fibre loop is Lit 1 145 400.
The implementation of ULL is especially important in Italy for new entrants since, due to the lack
of cable television networks and delays in introducing the regulatory framework for WLL services, there are
no alternative infrastructures. However, there is no doubt that the real issue, which will determine the success
of ULL regulation, is the level of price for ULL offerings. There is concern regarding Telecom Italia’s price
for ULL agreed to by AGCOM. Telecom Italia’s fixed line prices will increase over 2001 to Lit 20 700 in
July for residential customers. The price for ordinary unbundled loop will be Lit 22 200,26 that is Lit 1 500
higher than the monthly residential charge. However, the price for ULL is lower than the retail offer of
Telecom Italia for ADSL and ISDN, and business subscriber lines, which are expected to be the main
services offered by new entrants using ULL. AGCOM needs to remain vigilant to ensure that ULL prices
provide an incentive to new entrants to obtain direct access to end customers.
Importance of rebalancing
To ensure effective competition, it is essential to have a fully rebalanced tariff structure, which reflects the cost structure
of an efficient operator’s telecommunications services both in retail and wholesale markets. Thus, fixed costs resulting
from the provision of subscriber lines need to be fully recovered by fixed line rental charges and connection charges, and
variable costs caused by the conveyance of calls should be recovered by per usage charges. At the same time, the
incumbent needs to rebalance its usage charges between local and long distance calls reflecting underlying costs of
delivering services. When fixed costs, so called non-traffic sensitive costs, are not fully recovered through fixed line
rental charges and connection charges, an access deficit results. In particular, this can happen when a monthly line rental
charge is subject to special price regulation in the context of universal service provision. At the same time, the regulation
of local call charges can prevent an incumbent from rebalancing its usage charges. It is essential for the regulator to
allow full rebalancing of the incumbent’s prices in order to ensure effective competition in the telecommunications
market. In addition, if there is economic loss due to the lack of rebalancing, this should be compensated through a
competitively neutral funding mechanism which neither distorts competition nor penalises a specific user group.
Rebalancing in Italy
In order to conform to EU directives, which require the completion of rebalancing by the end of 1999, the AGCOM has
taken a series of rebalancing measures. In December 1998, AGCOM reduced Telecom Italia’s national long distance
(7%) and international (9.6%) calls, while increased line rental charges (3%). AGCOM did not make any change in local
call charges. In June 1999, a specific charge for calls within the same district was introduced along with a further
reduction on long distance and international call charges. In addition, AGCOM decided to introduce a “per-second”
billing system by the end of 1999. In July 1999, price-cap regulation was introduced to regulate Telecom Italia’s voice
telephony services. While AGCOM announced that tariff rebalancing has been completed in compliance with the EU
deadline, Telecom Italia insists that it still has access deficits due to insufficient rebalancing. According to the
Presidential Decree of 19 September 1997 (DPR No. 318), if there had been any access deficit until 31 December 1997,
the access deficit would have been financed by charging an additional amount on the interconnection fees. Based on this
regulation, for the year 1997 AGCOM recognised an access deficit (for tariff rebalancing purposes) of ITL 5 477 billion
(Telecom Italia had claimed a network access deficit of ITL 5 477 billion). The audit carried out by the independent
auditor (KPMG) on behalf of the AGCOM confirmed the existence of an access deficit on the basis of 1997 data. For
1998 Telecom Italia has claimed an access deficit of ITL 4 117 billion and has filed with AGCOM a claim for a deficit
of ITL 3 330 billion for 1999. The AGCOM pointed out that the access deficit, audited by the independent advisor can
be gradually recovered by 2002 within the current price-cap mechanism.
In 1998 the Commission of the EC opened an infringement procedure against Italy concerning rebalancing of tariffs of
voice services, in particular those of access services. In September 2000 this procedure led to a “reasoned opinion” of
the Commission stating that the existing price cap regime would not allow a complete rebalancing of the price of access
services by the end of the present price cap scheme. In December the Competition Directorate of the EC Commission
indicated that the existing sub-cap on the monthly subscription charge should be modified, allowing for an increase of
+6%. AGCOM answered to this allegation with Decision 847/00/Cons (11 December 2000), which introduced the
requested modification, thus allowing the Commission to lift the procedure.
TI’s local charges are constrained by the existing price cap on local call charges (RPI+0%); in fact, prices in the local
call market provide a limited margin for new entrants. Italy is not an exception in this context (see Figure 1).
10
9
Ratio (retail charges/IC charges)
8
7
6
Local
5 Long distance
4
3
2
1
0
Ire y
ay
G n ce
K
Fi rk
ly
s
Be r ia
Fr d
nd
he an
Sw in
it z e n
nd
D ium
an
nd
an
U
Ita
a
a
w
st
la
Sw e d
la
Sp
m
m
a
lg
rla
a
nl
or
Au
er
en
J
er
N
et
N
Note: 1. The local interconnection charges are a weighted average of using 80% of the 5-kilometre charge and 20% of the 20-
kilometre charge.
Note 2. The long distance interconnection charges are a weighted average, using 10% of the 5-kilometre charge, 30% of the 20-
kilometre charge and 60% of the 50% kilometre charge.
Note 3. For the long distance retail charges, using the tariff that applies to a 100-kilometre call as a proxy for long distance.
Note 4. For the retail charges, using the time of day call profiles to average the charges into peak and off peak.
Note 5. For the retail charges, including call set-up charges assuming a call duration of 2.5 minutes but not minimum call charges.
Note 6. For the retail charges, excluding tax charges.
Source: Ovum “Interconnect: Quarterly Update October 1999”.
Based on the AGCOM’s instructions in December 1998 and June 1999, in November 1999 Telecom
Italia introduced per second billing, with a call set-up charge.27
In terms of mobile tariffs, operators are free to set tariffs except in the case of TIM’s analogue
services. Mobile operators are only required to provide 30 day prior notice to the AGCOM before launching
new tariffs. In the case of TIM’s analogue services, the “Contratto di Programma” between TIM and the
Previously fixed to mobile call charges were determined by mobile operators in Italy. Since no
regulation was imposed on setting fixed to mobile charges, TIM and Omnitel were charging very high prices
for fixed to mobile services. In fact, these two companies were found guilty and fined by the competition
authority, for colluding to set identical prices on fixed to mobile calls. When the EC decided to investigate
fourteen cases in July 1998, where the situation indicated a possible distortion of market conditions between
fixed and mobile networks, Italy was, along with Germany, one of two countries, which were investigated in
all three categories; mobile to fixed termination rates, fixed operator’s retention on fixed to mobile calls and
mobile termination rates.
As a consequence, in January 1999, the AGCOM established the principle that the operator from
whom the call is originated should determine prices. After two interim decisions in March and September
1999, the AGCOM approved the new pricing scheme on fixed to mobile calls and the corresponding mobile
termination charges (see Box 8).
In terms of leased line services, a tariff approval system is applied to Telecom Italia’s leased line
charges. In 1999 the incumbent was still the sole supplier of leased lines. Competition is now developing in
long-distance and backbone services provided by alternative operators. The incumbent still dominates the
local and short-distance markets. The AGCOM’s Decision amending the RIO 2000 imposes the inclusion of
terms and conditions for the provision of half circuits for interconnection, for circuits of 64 Kbits, 2 Mbits
and 34 Mbits, 2 km and 5 km long. In assessing the corresponding economic conditions, the AGCOM will
take account of the price ceiling indicated in the Commission Recommendation on leased lines
interconnection pricing. Data for July 2000 indicate that the situation with regard to international leased lines
has improved, with a significant fall in tariffs from 1999 to 2000. With regard to 2 Mbit/s half circuits,
reductions of about 40% are reported for a line to the US, and about 30% for distant and near EU lines. With
regard to 64 kbit/s half-circuits, tariffs for a line to the US have decreased by about 30%; the reduction is
about 19% for lines to distant and near EU. However, tariffs remain significantly above the EU average for
all kinds of leased lines, except for 2 Mbit/s lines to the USA (which are below the average), and for 2 Mbit/s
lines to far EU (just above the average). The EC had in the first half of 2000 concluded that Italy’s leased line
prices (for 64 Kbit/s and 2 Mbit/s) were above EU average so that recent changes are important in bringing
Italy’s prices into line with EU best practice. However, on 31 October 2000 AGCOM approved new prices
for leased lines offered by Telecom Italia. The new offer provides for a reduction of 23.7% in prices of
national leased lines, together with a more transparent pricing system consisting of a new method for the
calculation of distance based on the actual distance between switches and in the elimination of the difference
among local and long distance circuits.
- Retention share of Telecom Italia: A price cap is applied to the retention share of Telecom Italia (ITL 110/min,
down from ITL 172/min). Telecom Italia may differentiate its retention share into two different price "profiles"
(residential and business) and differentiate it in two price bands (peak and off-peak) corresponding to the current
ones for national calls, but is not forced to do so.
- Mobile termination rates: A price cap is applied to TIM and Omnitel’s mobile termination rates (ITL 360/min, down
from respectively, ITL 475/min and ITL 500t/min). Like Telecom Italia’s retention, TIM and Omnitel are allowed
to differentiate their termination rates in two price-bands (peak and off-peak) corresponding to the current ones for
local calls. WIND and Blu’s termination rates are subject to commercial negotiation with Telecom Italia.
2 0000
1 8000
1 6000 1996
1 4000
1 2000 1997
Lit.
1 0000
8000 1998
6000 1999
4000
2000
0
l
al
S)
)
n)
ca
ce
nt
pa
U
..
Lo
an
re
l(
3.
Ja
Fr
na
(>
ly
l(
l(
th
io
ce
na
na
on
at
an
io
rn
io
M
at
st
te
at
rn
di
In
rn
te
ng
te
In
In
Lo
Note: Except monthly rental charges, other charges are based on a three-minute call including call set-up charges and excluding
VAT.
Source: AGCOM.
The Presidential decree of 19 September 1997, No. 318 (Art.1, par 1, letter z) defines “universal
service” as a minimum set of services of a specified quality, which is available to all users independent of
their geographical location at an affordable price.
The Ministry of Communications, General Directorate for Planning and Frequency Management, is
responsible for spectrum planning in telecommunications. Spectrum planning and allocation is very
complicated in Italy. In practice, the Ministry is responsible for spectrum planning for telecommunications
and spectrum allocation for broadcasting. On the other hand, the AGCOM is responsible for spectrum
allocation for telecommunications and spectrum planning for broadcasting.
UMTS auctions in Europe have led to considerable debate, in particular because of the high licence
fees that have resulted from this process. One view has been that a high licence fee resulting from the auction
process would stimulate the quick delivery of the UMTS service. A view has also been expressed that the
high licence cost will eventually be transferred to end customers, thus having a negative impact on the rapid
take-up of broadband mobile services. At this stage it is not clear how high licence fees will affect the future
of UMTS services. However, it is clear that the use of auction has enhanced transparency and efficiency in
the allocation of scarce resources such as frequencies. The final cost per UMTS license deriving from the
Italian 3G auction process is well above the licence cost in the Netherlands and Spain but lower than in
Germany and the UK.29
According to the Authority Deliberation 6/00/CIR (National Numbering Plan and rules for its
implementation), numbering resources are granted to licensed operators for the provision of fixed and mobile
telecommunication networks and services. There are four different sets of numbers (special national services,
mobile services, geographic services and non-geographic services) which have specific rules for the
management and allocation of numbering resources.30 In principle, numbers are allocated by a ‘first come
first served’ basis. Operators are required to pay annual numbering fees for the use of numbers per number
basis and the use of carrier selection codes. Compared to other OECD countries, the level of Italy’s
numbering fees appears reasonable.31
The rapid development of competition in the Italian telecommunications sector with the increasing
number of new facility based carriers has highlighted the importance of numbering policy in Italy. In
recognising the importance of numbering policy, together with the pressure to meet the EU deadline to
implement carrier pre-selection and number portability, the Italian government has made a series of
regulatory decisions.
In terms of number portability, in fixed voice telephony services, the AGCOM’s Deliberation
4/CIR/99 introduced both geographic numbers within the local call zone and non-geographic numbers such as
toll free, shared cost and premium services. While number portability for non-geographic numbers started in
May 2000, number portability for geographic numbers, although expected to become very important with the
implementation of the unbundling of the local loop, which is supposed to be implemented by the end of 2000
is already in place in the form of service provider portability.
According to the original plan, number portability in mobile should have been implemented by July
1999, but it was postponed. As a transitional measure until number portability for mobile is in place, the
AGCOM has introduced the obligation for mobile operators to provide an automatic message indicating the
The three main mobile operators in Italy do not favour number portability. These mobile operators
argue that the introduction of number portability in mobile services would not only impose significant
economic burden on operators but also make it difficult for them to maintain new services such as “ON-
NET”, since these services are based on specific numbers. Nevertheless, considering the dominant position of
TIM and Omnitel in the mobile market, especially in the business market, and the late entrance of Blu, the
introduction of number portability seem essential to ensure fair competition in the marketplace. Furthermore,
there is no doubt that the introduction of number portability will give more choice to customers to select their
service providers.
Ensuring equal access to customers is one of the most important roles of the telecommunications
regulator since the incumbent still has a dominant position in the local loop market. Before the introduction of
ULL, carrier pre-selection was the only regulatory measure, which allowed new entrants to obtain direct
access to end customers. It still is often considered one of the most effective regulatory measures for ensuring
equal access.
In Italy, call by call carrier selection was introduced for long distance and international calls on
1 January 1998. On 15 July 1999, the AGCOM expanded the coverage of carrier selection to calls within the
same national destination code. From the 1 January 2000, the AGCOM introduced carrier selection also for
local calls.
From February 2000, customers can make inter-district, international calls and calls to mobile
networks using a pre-selected carrier, as an alternative to Telecom Italia. Calls within a district may be made
with carrier pre-selection starting from May 2000 in Milan, June 2000 and in Rome and July 2000 in other
local call areas. The comprehensive coverage of the Italian carrier pre-selection scheme, in particular the
inclusion of carrier pre selection for local calls and mobile networks is helping to promote competition in the
marketplace.
Specific codes dedicated to Internet service access were introduced by the AGC in the new
numbering plan decision of 8 June 2000 (Decision 6/00/CIR).
In summary, the AGCOM has made sound regulatory decisions with regard to numbering policy.
The supervision of quality of service is the responsibility of the AGCOM. However, currently the
Ministry and the AGCOM share the responsibility based on their bilateral agreement. A consumer council
(Consiglio Nazionale degli Utenti) was established at the AGCOM in May 1999. This is made up of eleven
members appointed by the AGCOM and selected among experts in the telecommunications and audio-visual
sectors on the basis of lists drawn up by consumer associations. In addition, the AGCOM has established a
couple of working groups for the quality of interconnection traffic and the transparency of telephony charges.
The EU ONP Directive (95/62/EC) requires EU Member State NRAs to establish and publish
targets for a number of technical elements. Italy has taken regulatory measures to meet EU ONP
requirements, but also taken regulatory action to protect consumer interests in the evolving
telecommunications market where increasing attention is paid to quality of service aspects and to customer
care beyond the traditional technical assessments (line quality, number of faults, etc.).
As a result of the market opening measures, foreign telecommunications companies are able to
establish new network infrastructure inside Italy and become facilities-based carriers providing cross-border
services or resale carrier services. In addition, foreign telecommunications companies have access to the same
interconnection rights as local telecommunications companies.
With regard to the application of competition principles, Italy has very pro-competitive regulatory
bodies, which are willing to apply regulatory measures to ensure fair competition. In terms of the sector
specific regulator, the most significant measures taken by the AGCOM were the designation of TIM and
Omnitel as providers with significant market power in terms of cellular service, interconnection, and the
definition of new pricing for fixed to mobile communications. While it is the norm to designate the
incumbent as an operator with significant market power, there are only a few countries, which designate
mobile operators as operators with significant market power in the interconnection market.
In April 1998, Telecom Italia was identified as an operator having significant market power in the
markets of fixed telecommunications networks, fixed public voice telephony services, leased lines and
interconnection services. In April 1998, TIM was identified as having significant market power in the mobile
On the other hand, the competition authority is very active in applying competition rules in the
telecommunications market (see Table 11). For example, in October 1999, the competition authority fined
TIM ITL 100.5 billion, and Omnitel ITL 47.0 billion after finding both guilty of price fixing and of co-
ordinating strategies to compete with other telecommunication companies. While, both companies appealed
to the Lazio regional administrative court, the court rejected the appeal on 31 May 2000; in December 2000
the national supreme administrative court (Consiglio di Stato) partially accepted the companies’ view and
discharged them from the collusion charge, reducing the fine to TIM and Omnitel to, respectively, ITL 38
billion, and ITL 18 billion.
1994 Case GSM- cellular The competition authority ruled that this Sip’s GSM service promotion activities
telephone market (pre- constituted an abuse of dominant position.
emption of the mobile GSM
market)
1995 Case Assistal-Sip The competition authority ascertained an abuse of dominant position by Sip S.p.a. on the
(illegitimate competitive private switching systems installation and maintenance markets.
advantage)
1995 Case Telsystem-Sip (refusal The competition authority ordered Sip to immediately supply Telsystem with the links.
to deal)
1997 Case Albacom-Telecom Following the observations made by the competition authority, Telecom Italia undertook to
Italia - Servizio Executive offer its competitors the same discounts that were available to its own customers, as from
(discrimination practices) 1 July, 1997 and to guarantee them the best possible conditions in terms of quality
standards and promptness in bringing lines into operation.
1997 Case Albacom-Telecom The competition authority ascertained that Telecom had abused its dominant position in the
Italia-leased lines provision of leased lines.
(discrimination practices-
penalty: ITL 95 million)
1997 Case Telecom Italia-Intesa At the end of an investigation completed in November 1997, the competition authority
(merger not cleared) prohibited Telecom Italia from acquiring control of the company Intesa in the light of the
concentration of market power.
1999 Case TIM-Omnitel (collusive In September 1999, the competition authority ascertained a collusive agreement between
agreement - Penalty: TIM and Omnitel Pronto Italia, the two Italian telecom operators active in the market of
ITL 100.5 billion to TIM and mobile telephony services.
46 billion and
ITL 868 million to Omnitel)
2000 Case AIIP-Telecom Italia- The competition authority ascertained the damage inflicted to ISP in respect of Telecom
Internet Services Italia’s cross subsidisation practices.
(anticompetitive cross
subsidy and discrimination
practices- Penalty: 1 billion
and 240 million ITL. to
Telecom Italia)
2000 Case Tiscali/Telecom Italia On August 2000, the competition authority ascertained the abuse of dominant position of
(Reverse Interconnection) Telecom Italia in the market for reverse interconnection services.
2000 Case Telecom Italia/SEAT The competition authority authorised upon conditions the concentration pursuant to which
PAGINE GIALLE Telecom Italia acquires control over SEAT, laying down the measures aimed at preventing
The rapid convergence taking place between broadcasting, content and communications technology
and services is bringing into focus the need for “next generation regulations”. For regulators, the trend in
technology and service convergence requires looking beyond current regulatory frameworks to consider how
to facilitate the process of convergence, maximise the benefits of competition among traditionally different
sectors and ensure that their economic benefits from convergence through the development of new services,
such as electronic commerce. Italy has an institutional advantage in meeting these challenges since the
AGCOM not only is responsible for telecommunications, broadcasting and press, but is designed to respond
communications issues in a technologically neutral way.
The AGCOM is the only regulator whose internal administrative structure is designed to reflect
convergence in the communications sector. This advanced structure supports the AGCOM in dealing with
regulatory issues in a technologically neutral way, which is essential for promoting fair competition
throughout the entire communications sector.
The aim of regulation is to increase industry efficiency and to increase consumer benefits.
Reductions in tariffs, introduction of new services and the increase in service quality are often used as
measures to assess the result of regulatory reform. However, in consideration of the difficulties in measuring
the direct impacts of regulatory reform, perhaps the best way to assess the result of regulatory reform is to
analyse the intensity of competition in the marketplace, because eventually strong competition is the key
driving force which will bring benefits to consumers. In this section, the status of competition in the Italian
communications market and its performance in the OECD region will be analysed.
In the fixed telecommunications market, there has generally been a clear demarcation between
local, long distance and international services. This demarcation has also been used in telecommunication
regulations in many Member countries, in particular for granting licences. Italy has also used this
demarcation for licensing, although there is no restriction for applicants to hold both national and local
licences. When competition was first introduced in the telecommunications market, the normal scenario has
been that new entrants first enter the long distance and international markets, since the lack of rebalancing
means that these market segments are much more lucrative for new entrants, and the investment costs of
This general principle applies to the development of competition in the Italian fixed voice telephony
market. However, due to the lack of rebalancing and alternative access networks, there has not been much
competition as yet in the local market. In the access market, the fact that CATV networks are virtually non-
existent, and Telecom Italia’s control of the major cable network service provider, Stream, means that there
will not be any meaningful competition in the access network market until WLL services are introduced. It is
likely that some competition in the local call market will result from the inclusion of local calls in carrier pre-
selection and the introduction of ULL. In fact, as of September 2000, over eighteen operators are offering
local calls through carrier-selection and eleven operators had signed carrier pre-selection agreements with
Telecom Italia. Furthermore, operators like Infostrada have introduced new services like “Tempozero” which
offers unlimited local and national long distance calls with fixed monthly fees. However, Telecom Italia is
also allowed to introduce similar services for its customers, so the success of new entrants depends on the
level of tariffs they can offer customers. This implies that meaningful competition can only develop if
Telecom Italia’s interconnection charges and charges for ULL allow for a sufficient margin for new entrants.
In this respect, the success of competition in the local call market largely depends on the AGCOM’s
regulatory vigilance to ensure cost-oriented prices for the access to Telecom Italia’s local loop.
While there is no meaningful competition in the local access market, the introduction of new prices
during the first half of 2000, such as Infostrada’s “Tempozero” and Telecom Italia’s “Teleconomy NoStop”,
demonstrates that consumers are already enjoying the benefits of competition even in the local call market,
considering the fact that these unmeasured local call services were not available previously (see Table 12).
Table 11. Fixed voice telephony services offered by Telecom Italia and Infostrada (Euro per minute, VAT included)
In fact, Figure 3 shows that Italy’s national business tariffs, which had been fairly static prior to competition,
have declined significantly with the introduction of competition in 1998. Nevertheless, Figure 4 and Figure 5
show that the Italian fixed voice telephony service charges are still higher than the average for OECD
countries. This indicates that there still is an incentive for new entrants to enter the market.
Figure 3. OECD National Business Tariff Basket, 1991-98 (Index 1990 = 100)
140
Greece
130
120 Italy
110
Belgium
100
90 Netherlands
80
UK
70
OECD
60
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998
3 00 0
Fixed Usage
2 50 0
2 00 0
1 50 0
1 00 0
50 0
0
Mexico
Czech Rep .
Ital y
Hun ga ry
USA
OECD avera ge
Swi tzerl an d
Fran ce
Irel an d
S pa in
P ortu ga l
No rway
G erman y
Tu rkey
Can ad a
Ja pa n
Po la nd
UK
Ice la nd
S wed en
Lu xe mbo urg
Finl an d
Austr ia
Gree ce
Au stral ia
Ne w Ze al an d
Korea
Be lg ium
Den ma rk
OECDaverage
Ireland
Gr eece
UK
Denmark
Germany
Turkey
Hungar y
Czech Rep.
Luxembourg
Canada
Spain
Mexico
Poland
USA
Belgium
Netherlands
Italy
Portugal
Iceland
France
Finland
Korea
Japan
Australia
Switzer land
New Zealand
Nor way
Sweden
Austria
AGCOM’s decision to change the pricing mechanism of fixed to mobile phone calls together with
the inclusion of fixed to mobile phone calls for carrier pre-selection has made it possible for new fixed
operators to compete in this market. However, considering the fact both Telecom Italia’s retention charges
and TIM and Omintel’s interconnection charges are subject to a charge cap mechanism, new entrants need to
offer retail prices which are lower than prices set up by the AGCOM. It implies that new operators’
competitiveness largely depends on access costs to Telecom Italia’s network. The AGCOM’s regulatory role
is necessary here to ensure cost-oriented access charges, which are a vital factor to determine the level of
competition in this market segment.
Mobile market
The start of Blu’s cellular mobile services in the second half of 2000 has increased competition in
the Italian mobile market. In fact, Figure 6 shows that Italy’s mobile tariffs are already cheaper than the
OECD average. However, considering that there are no handset subsidies in Italy, which traditionally account
for a large portion of mobile operator’s costs in other countries, it seems clear that there is room for
improvement.
800
600
500
400
300
200
100
OECD average
Denmark
Czech Republic
Finland
Iceland
Luxembourg
Greece
Canada
Ireland
Poland
France
Italy
Ger many
Turkey
Hungary
Belgium
Portugal
Spain
Korea
Japan
Mexico
USA
Nether lands
New Zealand
Austria
Australia
Norway
Switzerland
Sweden
UK
Note: The basket includes 50 minutes per month and excludes international calls. VAT is excluded.
Source: OECD and Teligen.
In the leased line market, Telecom Italia has a 100% market share. This lack of competition in the
leased line market has meant that leased line tariffs have remained high in spite of the tariff approval system
that applies to Telecom Italia’s leased line charges. The Fifth Implementation Report indicated that, with
regard to 2 Mbit/s national circuits prices of a 50 km and 200 km circuit in 1998 and 1999 were above the EU
average. Following an investigation of the provision of leased lines, in July 2000 the AGCOM instructed the
incumbent to reduce its prices for urban and inter-urban lines by an average of 23.7%. The modified tariffs
have been approved and published on 31 October 2000. The decision also includes measures to increase the
transparency of the offer (calculation of the actual distance on air instead of electrical distance and
elimination of the difference between local and long-distance circuits), to change the terms of the Service
Level Agreement offered by Telecom Italia (improving the timing of delivery and of repair and introducing
an automatic refunding mechanism for delays and delivery and of repair), and widen the range of services
offered. Figure 7 indicates that 64K leased line charges are higher in Italy than the OECD average.
In September 2000, the European Commission had noted that "excessive prices" were being
charged in Italy for 34 Mbps and 155 Mbps national leased lines in addition to the “discriminatory delays in
the provision of leased lines”.
1200 64 K
1000
800
600
400
200
0
OECDaverage
Greece
Denmark
Turkey
Germany
Por tugal
Iceland
Luxembourg
Ireland
Canada
France
Mexic o
Poland
Spain
Japan
UK
Italy
Hungary
Belgium
New Zealand
Korea
USA
Netherlands
Sweden
Austria
Australia
Norway
Switzerland
Source: OECD.
Internet
In Italy healthy competition in the Internet Service Provider market has helped in placing pressure
for lower Internet access charges using the PSTN. The level of Telecom Italia’s PSTN charges for Internet
access charges is relatively low compared to other OECD countries. Although the number of Internet
subscribers had increased more than 60% from 1998 (2.5 million) to the end of 1999 (4.1 million), Italy still
trailed behind the OECD average with nine subscribers per 100 population compared to an OECD average of
11 per 100 population.34 This performance may be improved during 2000 given that the more attractive prices
were introduced at the end of the first half of 2000. One of the reasons for growth in number of subscribers
was the introduction of the “Freeserve” model by Tiscali35 (Tiscali has over one million subscribers to its
FreeNet service).
It is noteworthy that both AGCOM and the competition authority have actively supported
competition in the Internet market. AGCOM is exploring the possibility to assign specific numbering options
to the ISPs (currently operating under general authorisation), while numbering is normally reserved to
operators with an individual licence. On 10 July 1998 the Italian competition authority commenced an
investigation of Telecom Italia on the basis of a claim brought by the Italian Association of Internet
Providers, for potential abuse of dominant position in the Internet market. On 9 September 1999 Telecom
Italia and the Italian association of Internet providers signed an agreement to eliminate discrimination
towards Internet Service Providers and Other Licensed Operators, having positive effects also on
infrastructure costs supported by Internet Service Providers. On 28 January 2000 the competition authority
fined Telecom Italia ITL 1 248 million.
USD PPP
120
80
60
40
20
0
Luxembourg
New Zealand
Czech Republic
Hungary
Netherlands
Norway
Switzerland
Mexico
Canada
Sweden
Portugal
Germany
Denmark
Turkey
Ireland
Greece
Japan
France
Finland
Korea
United Kingdom
OECD
United States
Poland
Spain
Austria
Italy
Iceland
Australia
EU
Belgium
Network development
In Italy, in spite of the steady growth in the number of subscriber fixed lines, in 1999 for the first
time Telecom Italia’s operating revenue from fixed line services decreased from that of the previous year.
This is mainly due to substitute effects between mobile and fixed services and strong competition in the fixed
long distance and international markets. As of the end of 1999, Italy had 46.4 access channels36 per 100
inhabitants which is lower than the OECD average (53.3 in 1999)
Table 12. Telecom Italia’s gross operating revenues from fixed and mobile telecommunications services
(ITL billion)
1998 1999
Fixed voice telephony services 36 292 35 856
Mobile services 11 904 14 425
Source: Telecom Italia “SEC 20F submission”.
In terms of network digitalisation, as of the end of 1999, 99.9% of Telecom Italia’s domestic
telecommunications lines were digital, which is above the OECD average (94.2 in 1999). However it needs to
be mentioned that there are a number of Member countries – Finland, France, Germany, Iceland, Japan,
Luxembourg, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway and the United Kingdom – which already had attained
full digitalisation of fixed networks by 1997. Commercial ISDN service was introduced in 1994 and now
ISDN services are accessible to virtually all parts of Italy. As of the end of 1999, there were approximately
2.5 million basic rate ISDN subscribers and 568 thousand primary rate ISDN subscribers in Italy. In 1997 the
total number of ISDN subscribers in Italy (2.07 millions) was just under that of Germany (2.89 millions) in
the OECD region. In terms of the deployment of fibre optic cables measured by fibre km, at the end of 1999
Telecom Italia had installed approximately 2.9 million Kms. of fibre optic cables.
Source: OECD.
Quality of service
At the end of 1999, 74.0% of the public telephones in service were equipped with phone card
readers. Italy had 6 payphones per 1 000 inhabitants in 1999, a reduction since 1997, whereas in most OECD
countries this ratio has been increasing. However, Italy still had a higher per capita number of payphones than
the OECD average.
By the end of 1999, 98.9% of faults were repaired within 24 hours. The call completion rate of the
local fixed network has steadily increased from 98.2% in 1993 to 99.7% in 1999. Similarly, the call
completion rate of the long distance fixed network increased from 95.4% in 1993 to 99.1% in 1999. In Italy,
the incumbent is obliged to provide the itemised billing service and the caller identification service is
available for all customers.
The incumbent’s productivity, measured by subscriber lines per employee, has been increased
gradually. Italy’s productivity is well above the OECD average and the fourth best among OECD countries in
1997.
Italy has made steady progress in telecommunications market liberalisation in the 1990s in
conformity with the EU Directives. As a result of the Italian government’s efforts to promote competition in
the telecommunications market, Italy has a fairly comprehensive regulatory regime enabling it to promote
competition in the telecommunications sector. In addition, the AGCOM has the responsibility to supervise the
telecommunications sector as well as the broadcasting sector and the press, which enables the AGCOM to
make technologically neutral regulatory decisions over the whole communications sector.
However, there still exist a number of problems, which need to be promptly addressed. In particular,
there have been delays reported in a number of important issues from the full operation of the AGCOM to
implement specific regulatory decisions in the Italian telecommunications sector.
x Advanced structure of regulatory body which enables technologically neutral and consistent regulatory rulings over
the whole communications sector.
As the nature of mobile service changes, from a complementary service to a substitute for fixed
voice telephony, services through the decrease in charges and the introduction of pre-paid cards, the growth
of the Italian mobile sector is bringing real competition to the Italian telecommunications market.
It is noteworthy that, in Italy, the level of PSTN charges for Internet access charges is among the
lowest in the OECD region. This low Internet access charge allows customers to access data services using
the PSTN. At the same time, the low Internet access charges help Internet content providers to benefit from
economies of scale, which is very important for an industry which is largely dependent on advertising
revenues.
x Delay in defining and implementing Long Run Incremental Cost (LRIC) accounting methodology.
While three years have passed since the establishment of the AGCOM in 1998, the AGCOM the
sharing of regulatory powers between the AGCOM and the Ministry based on bilateral contracts has caused
some confusion and inconvenience to the industry.
The Italian licensing regime is complicated and places unnecessary regulatory burdens on the
industry. The change of concessions into licences was finally completed in March 2001. Telecom Italia is
subject to “golden share regulation” based on the “Golden Share Decree38” issued on February 11 2000 and
Telecom Italia’s constitution. According to the Golden Share Decree, the Italian government can use its
special powers to block an acquisition of Telecom Italia in order to protect the privatisation policy. Although
the Italian government did not exercise its special power when Deutsche Telekom and Olivetti competed to
take over Telecom Italia (Olivetti finally succeeded), the existence of a “golden share regulation” means that
the Italian government still has a chance to intervene in the case of an acquisition of the incumbent by a
government-owned undertakings.
Considering the weak market position of new entrants in the mobile sector and the lack of
competition in the local access market, the introduction of mobile number portability and WLL services
should be secured.
The FDC accounting methodology, used at present by the regulator, tends to over-compensate the
incumbent through subsidising the historical inefficiencies. The implementation of interconnection charges,
as well as local loop unbundling access charges, based on forward looking long run incremental costs should
be a priority for the regulator.
Section 3 pointed to some early evidence that market liberalisation and competition are bringing
significant benefits through:
The immediate task is to ensure local competition, noting in particular the need for alternate
infrastructures. A sustained commitment to simplifying the licensing framework will also benefit market
players by reducing the regulatory burden.
In general, in spite of recent regulatory efforts by the AGCOM, there is room for improvement in
the effectiveness of the regulatory system to facilitate the transition from a monopoly to a competitive
telecommunications market. As described in Section 4.1, there still remain a few regulatory issues that need
to be addressed appropriately and promptly if the benefits of competition are to be maximised. High priority
should be given to ensuring that the AGCOM has the necessary resources at its disposal through prompt
recruitment of unfilled posts.
The following recommendations are based on the above analysis, taking into account the “Policy
Recommendations for Regulatory Reform” set out in the OECD Report on Regulatory Reform (OECD, June
1997).
1. Ensure that regulations and regulatory processes are transparent and non-discriminatory and
applied effectively
Ensure that the AGCOM can fully exercise its regulatory responsibilities by ensuring that it has its
full complement of human resource through rapid recruitment of staff
The Italian government needs to take prompt action to enable the AGCOM to meet its legal
responsibilities. The sharing of responsibility between the Ministry and the AGCOM should be terminated as
soon as possible and the AGCOM needs, by hiring appropriate staff, to take full responsibility of the sector.
Mobile number portability and WLL services should be introduced without any delay in order to
promote competition in the mobile market and the local access market.
Considering the weak market position of new entrants in the mobile sector and the lack of
competition in the local access market, the delay in introducing mobile number portability and WLL services
gives an increased advantage to the existing mobile operators and the incumbent. The AGCOM needs to
make regulatory steps to expedite the introduction of mobile number portability and continue to place priority
in expediting the introduction of WLL services.
To promote competition, the present carrier market entry requirements should be made simpler by
transforming individual licences to authorisations.
It is unnecessary to maintain an individual licensing system for fixed voice telephony services since
the regulatory costs exceed the benefits. The expansion of the authorisation system to fixed voice telephony
services, which are currently subject to the individual licensing system, would lift unnecessary regulatory
burden from the telecommunications industry as well as eliminate long lead times to enter the market.
Obligations imposed on providers of public voice networks and services can be integrated in appropriate
regulations. Responsibility for licensing should revert to AGCOM, which has the responsibility for creating
competitive market conditions and is best placed to monitor market developments.
The golden share regulation imposed on the incumbent should be removed in order to allow the
incumbent to carry out its activities unconstrained by the threat of potential government intervention, subject
to the general telecommunications and competition regulations.
In a liberalised market, there is no reason to impose specific regulations on the incumbent rather
than regulation based on market power. The golden share is not necessary in that there is a legal and
regulatory framework that already sets the parameters in which the incumbent can operate.
It is necessary to ensure that the schedule for rebalancing is maintained and completed.
It is important that the access deficits in the provision of the local loop are eliminated by the
rebalancing of retail prices. Price changes in subscriber line charges that took place in early 2001 are
important in this context. Without a completion of rebalancing, there exists a risk of price distortion since the
incumbent needs to recoup this deficit through other prices.
3. Review, and strengthen where necessary, the scope, effectiveness and enforcement of competition
policy
As competition develops, the role of competition law in the telecommunications market should be
strengthened, and sector specific regulation should be reviewed periodically in order to streamline the
regulation.
The AGCOM should forebear from regulation in areas or for activities where sufficient competition
has emerged and conditions will allow the development of effective and sustainable competition between
carriers. Excessive sector-specific regulation on carriers may hamper development of the full benefits of
competition. Periodic reviews of regulation to determine where streamlining can take place should be
undertaken. It is recommended that all market players should be able to request streamlining reviews.
The AGCOM needs to take pro-competitive regulatory measures to ensure fair access to end
customers.
Since there is no competition in the local loop, the role of the AGCOM is critical to ensure fair
access to end customers. To this end, the recent decision on the early introduction of the unbundling of the
local loop is commendable. Nevertheless, there still is a dispute on the price of this service. The AGCOM
should put high priority on this issue so new entrants can obtain direct access to subscribers and compete with
the incumbent on a level playing field.
1. According to the Golden Share Decree, the Italian government may exercise its special powers to prevent
acquisitions of shares of privatised companies such as Telecom Italia if such acquisitions (1) are not
transparent and would not ensure full disclosure with respect to controlling share ownership of the companies
whose shares are being acquired and the objectives and industrial plans proposed by the buyers of the target
companies, (2) compromise liberalisation and market competition or are not in line with the company’s
privatisation goals, or entails situations of conflict of interests which could compromise the company’s
missions with respect to the objectives of public interest, (3) entail objective risks of being affected by
criminal organisations, or involve the company in unlawful activities, (4) jeopardise conservation of the
special powers of the State, or (5) represent a considerable risk of serious harm to the vital interests of the
State described above, including the supply of essential raw materials and goods, the supply of essential
public services and the security of related installations and networks and, further, the development of
advanced technological sector..
2. The ASST provided national long distance calls and international calls in Europe and in the Mediterranean
region and the PT provided telex and telegraph services. The concessionaires provided specific services such
as the installation and management of fixed networks and the provision of national telecommunications
services (SIP), intercontinental services (ITALCABLE), space communications (TELESPAZIO), and
maritime communications (SIRM and TELEMAR).
5. AGCOM.
6. Currently, Telecom Italia owns 35% of Stream. The other shareholders are News Corporation (35%), Gruppo
Gecchi Gori (18%) and SDS (12%).
7. AGCOM.
9. Infostrada had 5.8 million subscribers of which 3.1 million were for voice services and 2.7 million for Internet
services at the end of June 2000.
Actuate the surveillance of the services market and the radio and terminal equipment market in order to
protect the user’s interests.
12 A first set of requirements for formal co-operation between AGCOM and the Ministry is based on the legal
provisions (article 1, paragraph 25 of Law 249/97) which aims to support the gradual transfer of regulatory
responsibility from the Ministry to AGCOM. The collaboration agreement between AGCOM and the Ministry
has been published in the Official Journal of Italian Republic No. 169 of 22/7/98 and is still operating after
being renewed several times.
Quality of services.
13. In the period 1992- March 2000 the Area «Telecommunication» of the Direction Enquiry Activity «A» had
five staff members (three economists and two lawyers). In the same period there were about two staff
members working on deceptive advertising proceedings in telecommunication markets.
Starting April 2000, after a general re-organisation of the Competition Authority, the new Direction D
«Communication», with responsibilities in telecommunication, information technology, radio and TV
broadcasting, publishing, and advertising proceedings has 10 staff members.
15. European Commission (1999), “Fifth Report on the Implementation of the Telecommunications Regulatory
Package”.
16. In addition to the verification of the financial structure and the business plan, the current licensing regime
requires the applicant to satisfy the following requirements:
The establishment as a PLC (public limited company) or as Mutual Limited Ownership (a mutual
company in the form of a public company), in which the assets shall be not less than 10% of the
investment, accounting for net budget loss.
The CEO or legal representative of the applicant company must not have been prosecuted and sentenced.
Respect of essential requirements on operation safety, network integrity, service interoperability and data
protection.
Determine and publish the services to be provided and their terms and quality parameters.
Implement, if necessary, requests for interconnection coming from authorised operators in third countries
having ratified the agreements relevant to the telecommunications liberalisation stipulated with WTO.
Take into account the needs of disabled people when providing public telephone booths.
17. The public concession fee paid for 1997 and for 1998 was on average 3.5% of revenues related to such
services. Concessionaires and individual licence holders whose yearly revenue exceeds 200 billion Lire.
According to the Italian Budget law for 1998, concessionaires and licence holders which fall within the
category pay 3% for 1999, 2.7% for 2000, 2.5% for 2001, 2.0% for 2002 and 1.5% for 2003 from their
revenues. Previously public concession fees were imposed. According to the Ministerial Decree of March 21
2000, the fees should only be applied to revenues from telecommunications networks installation and
provision, voice telephone service and mobile personal services. Licence holders whose yearly revenues are
below 200 billion Lire, unless is at a loss, have to pay 2% up to year 2002 and 1.5% in 2003.
18. European Commission (1999), “Fifth Report on the Implementation of the Telecommunications Regulatory
Package”.
19. The parties are required to submit: 1) the parties’ position in the negotiation, 2) the technical, economic and
juridical reasons supporting the parties’ position and c) an acceptable negotiation breaking off and viable
alternatives.
21. In the United States all incumbent LECs are required to offer for resale any telecommunications service that
the carrier provides at retail to subscribers who are not telecommunications carriers. State commissions are
required to identify marketing, billing, collection, and other costs that will be avoided or that are avoidable by
incumbent LECs when they provide services wholesale and calculate the portion of the retail rates for those
services that is attributable to the avoided and avoidable costs. If a state elects not to implement the
methodology, it may elect, on an interim basis, a discount rate from within a default range of discount rates
established by the FCC. The FCC established a default discount range of 17 – 25% off retail prices, leaving
the states to set the specific rate within that range, in the exercise of their discretion.
22. In France, the difference between interconnection charges for infrastructure operators and charges for service
providers amounts to about 40%. (European Commission, “Fifth Report on the Implementation of the
Telecommunications Regulatory Package”).
24. In Spain, the interconnection charges for service providers are 30% higher than those of facility based
operators. (European Commission, “Fifth Report on the Implementation of the Telecommunications
Regulatory Package”).
25. Thomas Kiessling and Yves Blondeel “Effective competition in European telecommunications” an analysis of
recent regulatory development” Info vol. 1 number 5, October 1999.
26
The price per month for raw copper used to provide ADSL services is 24 300 lire.
27. The price per call set up is ITL. 100 for local calls, ITL 127 for national calls (fixed to mobile and fixed to
fixed) and same area calls and ITL 500 for international calls.
28. The main features of UMTS licensing conditions were the following:
Licensing procedures: procedure carried out in two stages: 1) qualification, for the purpose of pre-
selecting candidates with appropriate technical, financial, and commercial capabilities, and 2) auction by
competitive biddings, starting from of a base of Lit 4 000 billion (¼ELOOLRQ
Spectrum resources: The basic licenses were of 2X10 MHz paired spectrum plus 1X5MHz unpaired
spectrum. Two additional 2x5 MHz blocks were available for new entrants. No transfer of licences to a
third party was permitted.
Licensees' obligations: independently from any obligation voluntarily undertaken in the offer, by end of
30 months' period starting 1 January 2002, licensees will have to cover the regional capital cities; by the
end of next 30 months' period, licensees will have to cover other major cities.
Pro-competitive measures: a detailed regulation adopted by the Authority on 21 June 2000 has set pro-
competitive measures such as roaming obligations, as well as rules on sites, facility and infrastructure
sharing.
For mobile services, operators receive a number of prefix codes and are responsible for the allocation of the
subscriber numbers.
As far as geographic services are concerned, numbering resources are assigned to the requesting operator in
blocks of 10 000 numbers per local area. Operators can specify (and obtain, if available) a preference for the
numbering of the block(s).
Non-geographic services include, inter alia, toll-free numbers, VAS, premium rate services, shared cost
services. According to type of services, numbering resources are assigned in single number or in blocks of
100 numbers. Operators can specify a preference for the single number or the block(s) requested.
31. European Commission (1999), “Fifth Report on the Implementation of the Telecommunications Regulatory
Package”
32. The EU offer commits to complete liberalisation of basic telecommunication services (facilities-based and
resale) across the EU for all market segments (local, long distance and international). The offer also covers,
for instance, satellite networks and services and all mobile and personal communications services and
systems. Restrictions include foreign equity limits by France (20%: radio-based services, direct investment
only) and Portugal (25%). Full liberalisation of public voice telephony and facilities-based services is to be
implemented on a delayed basis only by Spain in December 1998; by Ireland in 2000; by Greece in 2003; and
by Portugal in 2000 for public voice telephony and July 1999 for facilities based services. Liberalisation of
internationally connected mobile and personal communications services is to be implemented on a delayed
basis only by Ireland and Portugal in 1999.
33. In the EU commitment on WTO basic telecommunications services agreement, telecommunications services
are defined as the transport of electromagnetic signals-sound, data image and any combinations thereof,
excluding broadcasting.
35. Internet subscribers do not pay any Internet Service Provider charges under this model. The ISP earns revenue
from advertising and/or from interconnection charges.
36. Access channels includes main lines adjusted for ISDN subscription.
38. According to the Golden Share Decree, the Italian government may exercise its special powers to prevent
acquisitions of shares of privatised companies such as Telecom Italia if such acquisitions (1) are not
transparent and would not ensure full disclosure with respect to controlling share ownership of the companies
whose shares are being acquired and the objectives and industrial plans proposed by the buyers of the target
companies, (2) compromise liberalisation and market competition or are not in line with the company’s
privatisation goals, or entails situations of conflict of interests which could compromise the company’s
missions with respect to the objectives of public interest, (3) entail objective risks of being affected by
criminal organisations, or involve the company in unlawful activities, (4) jeopardise conservation of the
special powers of the State, or (5) represent a considerable risk of serious harm to the vital interests of the
State described above, including the supply of essential raw materials and goods, the supply of essential
public services and the security of related installations and networks and, further, the development of
advanced technological sector.
European Commission (1999), “Fifth Report on the Implementation of the Telecommunications Regulatory
Package”, Brussels.
Kiessling, Thomas and Yves Blondeel (1999), “Effective competition in European telecommunications, an analysis
of recent regulatory development”, Info vol. 1, number 5, October.