Lecture Notes On Industrial Organization (I)
Lecture Notes On Industrial Organization (I)
Lecture Notes on
Chien-Fu CHOU
January 2004
2
Contents
Lecture 1 Introduction 1
Lecture 4 Monopoly 11
1 Introduction
1.1 Classification of industries and products
2M¬Å¼¹™Ä}é, 2M¬ÅW“™Ä}é;
«%Íß%’eé.
Structuralist:
Behaviorist: We can do still better with a richer model that includes intermediate
behavioral links.
Basic Conditions
Supply Demand
Raw materials Price elasticity
Technology Substitutes
Unionization Rate of growth
Product durability Cyclical and
Value/weight seasonal character
Business attitudes Purchase method
Public polices Marketing type
?
Market Structure
Number of sellers and buyers
Product differentiation
Barriers to entry
Cost structures
Vertical integration
Conglomerateness
?
Conduct
Pricing behavior
Product strategy and advertising
Research and innovation
Plant investment
Legal tactics
?
Performance
Production and allocative efficiency
Progress
Full employment
Equity
3
F1 (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ; y1 , y2 , . . . , ym ) = 0
F2 (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ; y1 , y2 , . . . , ym ) = 0
..
.
Fn (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ; y1 , y2 , . . . , ym ) = 0.
Some of the equations are behavioral, some are equilibrium conditions, and some are
definitions.
In principle, given the values of the exogenous variables, we solve to find the
endogenous variables as functions of the exogenous variables:
x1 = x1 (y1 , y2 , . . . , ym )
x2 = x2 (y1 , y2 , . . . , ym )
..
.
xn = xn (y1 , y2 , . . . , ym ).
Endogenous variables: x1 , . . . , xn
Exogenous variables: p1 , . . . , pn , I (the consumer is a price taker)
Solution is the demand functions xk = Dk (p1 , . . . , pn , I), k = 1, . . . , n
Example: Ui = 31 − i, i = 1, 2, · · · , 30.
5
Ui , P
rr
rr
6
rr
rr
The trace of Ui ’s becomes
rr the demand curve.
rr
rr
rr
r rr
rr
rr
rr
rr
rr
rr
rr
- i, Q
P 0 (Q)Q
0 1
M R(Q) = P (Q) + QP (Q) = P (Q) 1 + = P (Q) 1 + .
P (Q) η
R∞
Consumer surplus: CS(p) ≡ p D(p)dp.
A 1
2.4.1 Linear demand function: Q = D(p) = − p or P (Q) = A − bQ
b b
a
T R = AQ − bQ2 , AR = A − bQ, M R = A − 2bQ, η = 1 − ,
bQ
RA (A − p)p
CS(p) = p D(p)dp = .
2b
√ √ √ √
Example: q = f (x1 , x2 ) = 2 x1 + 2 x2 and Π(x1 , x2 ; p, p1 , p2 ) = p(2 x1 + 2 x2 ) −
p 1 x1 − p 2 x2 ,
√ √
max p(2 x1 + 2 x2 ) − p1 x1 − p2 x2
x1 .x2
∂Π p ∂Π p
FOC: = √ − p1 = 0 and = √ − p2 = 0.
∂x1 x1 ∂x2 x2
2 2
⇒ x1 = (p/p1 ) , x2 = (p/p2 ) (input demand functions) and
q = 2(p/p1 ) + 2(p/p2 ) = 2p( p11 + p12 ) (the supply function)
Π = p2 ( p11 + p12 )
SOC:
∂2Π ∂2Π −p
0
∂x2 ∂x1 ∂x2 2x−3/2
1 = 1
∂2Π ∂2Π −p
0
−3/2
∂x1 ∂x2 ∂x21 2x2
is negative definite.
7
Example: a producer produces two outputs, y1 and y2 , using one input y3 . Its
technology is given by the transformation function (y1 )2 + (y2 )2 + y3 = 0. Its profit
is Π = p1 y1 + p2 y2 + p3 y3 . The maximization problem is
To solve the maximization problem, we can eliminate y3 : x = −y3 = (y1 )2 + (y2 )2 > 0
and
max p1 y1 + p2 y2 − p3 [(y1 )2 + (y2 )2 ].
y1 ,y2
The solution is: y1 = p1 /(2p3 ), y2 = p2 /(2p3 ) (the supply functions of y1 and y2 ), and
x = −y3 = [p1 /(2p3 )]2 + [p1 /(2p3 )]2 (the input demand function for y3 ).
3 Competitive Market
Industry (Market) structure:
Short Run: Number of firms, distribution of market shares, competition decision vari-
ables, reactions to other firms.
Long Run: R&D, entry and exit barriers.
p p
6 S1 S2 S 6 S1 S2 S
@
@
@
@
@
@
p∗ @
@
-Q @D - Q
Q∗1 Q∗2 Q ∗
Formally, suppose there are n firms. A state of the market is a vector (p, Q1 , Q2 , . . . , Qn ).
An equilibrium is a state (p∗ , Q∗1 , Q∗2 , . . . , Q∗n ) such that:
1. D(p∗ ) = S(p∗ ).
2. Each Q∗i maximizes Πi (Qi ) = p∗ Qi − Ci (Qi ), i = 1, . . . , n.
3. Πi (Q∗i ) = p∗ Q∗i − ci (Q∗i ) ≥ 0.
9
p
3.2.1 Example 1: C1 (Q1 ) = Q21 , C2 (Q2 ) = 2Q22 , D = 12 −
4
p p 3p
p = C10 (Q1 ) = 2Q1 , p = C20 (Q2 ) = 4Q2 , ⇒ S 1 = , S2 = , S(P ) = S1 +S2 = .
2 4 4
p∗ 3p∗
D(p∗ ) = S(p∗ ) ⇒ 12− = ⇒ p∗ = 12, Q∗ = S(p∗ ) = 9, Q∗1 = S1 (p∗ ) = 6, Q∗2 = S2 (p∗ ) = 3.
4 4
p p
6 S1 S2
S 6
@ @
@
@
@
@
@
@
12
@ c @ S
@ @
@ @
@ D @ D-
@ -Q @ Q
9 Q∗
A A
If ≤ c then Q∗ = 0. If > c then Q∗ = A − bc > 0.
b b
A competitive equilibrium:
A combination of a price system p̄ = (p̄1 , . . . , p̄n ) and an allocation ({x̄i }i=1,...,I , {ȳ j }j=1,...,J )
such
Pthat
1. i x̄i = ω + j ȳ j (feasibility condition).
P
Existence Theorem:
Suppose that the utility functions are all quasi-concave and the production transfor-
mation functions satisfy some theoretic conditions, then a competitive equilibrium
exists.
4 Monopoly
A monopoly industry consists of one single producer who is a price setter (aware of
its monopoly power to control market price).
d2 π
The SOC is = MR0 (Q) − MC0 (Q) < 0.
dQ2
Long-run existence condition: π(Qm ) ≥ 0.
Pm − C 0 D(P ) 1
⇒ D(P ) + P D 0 (P ) = C 0 (D(P ))D 0 (P ) ⇒ =− 0 = .
Pm D (P )P ||
Pm − C 0
Lerner index: . It can be calculated from real data for a firm (not necessarily
Pm
monopoly) or an industry. It measures the profit per dollar sale of a firm (or an
industry).
12
P P P
6 6 6
@
A @ @
A
A@ MC @ MC=S A@ MC
Pm AA@@ @
@
A @
A @
A @ P∗ @ A @
A @ @ A @
MC A @ @ A @
A @ @ A @
AMR @D - Q @D - Q AMR @D - Q
Qm Q∗ Qm Q∗
1 + 2b 1 q1 a
FOC: a − 2bq1 = q1 + q2 = α − 2βq2 ⇒ =
1 1+ 2β q 2 α
q1 1 a(1 + 2β) − α
⇒ = .
q2 (1 + 2b)(1 + 2β) − 1 α(1 + 2b) − a
SOC: −2b − 1 < 0 and ∆ = (1 + 2b)(1 + 2β) − 1 > 0.
p
6 MC
MC = MR1+2 ⇒ Qm , MC∗
aa
Q MC∗ = MR1 ⇒ q1∗
@ Qa
@Qaaa
MC∗ @QQ aa MC∗ = MR2 ⇒ q2∗
@ Q aa
Q aa
@ Q aa
@ Q a MR1+2
@ Q
Q
@ Q
@ Q
Q MR2
@ MR1 Q- q
q1∗ q2∗ Qm
The profit maximizing quantity is the same as the competition case, Qm1 = Q∗ . How-
U (Q∗ )
ever, the price is much higher, Pm1 = = AU > P ∗ = U 0 (Q∗ ). There is no
Q∗
inefficiency. But there is social justice problem.
P
6
H
@
A HH
r
A@ HH
Pm1 AA@@ HH HH AU
A @
P∗ A @ C 0 (Q)
A @
AMR @ D = M U
A @ -Q
Qm Q∗ = Qm1
P P P
6 6 6
D2 D2 D2
Q Q Q
Q Q Q
Q Q Q
D1 Q D1 Q D1 Q
@ Q @ Q @ Q
@ B Q @ Q @ Q
Q Q Q
@ Q @ Q @ Q
A @ C Q @ Q @ Q
@ Q
Q- Q @ QQ- @ QQ
-Q
Q
By self selection principle, P1 Q1 = A, P2 Q2 = A + C, Π = 2A + C is maximized when
Q1 is such that the hight of D2 is twice that of D1 .
P1 − C10 R2
1 |22 | + 21
⇒ P P 1 = R 1
.
0
2 − C2 11 22 − 12 21 | | + R1
11 12
P2 R2
max p1 D1 (p1 ) − C1 (D1 (p1 )) + δ[p2 D2 (p2 ) − C2 (D2 (p2 ), D1 (p1 ))].
p1 ,p2
16
where R(qt ) is the revenue at t,R0 > 0, R00 < 0, r is the interest rate, Ct = C(wt ) is
the unit production cost at t, C 0 < 0, and wt is the experience accumulated by t.
√ 1
Example: R(q) = q and C(w) = a + .
w
4.5.2 É•.“
The monopoly faces the same demand function P = 100 − Q in each period. The
monopoly profit maximization implies that MR = 100 − 2Q = 0. Therefore,
P1R = P2R = 50, π1R = π2R = 2500, ΠR = π1R + δπ2R = 2500(1 + δ),
4.5.3 “i
We use backward induction method to find the solution to the profit maximization
problem. We first assume that those consumers who buy in period t = 1 do not resale
their used cars to other consumers.
FOC⇒ q1s = 200/(4+δ), P1s = 50(2+δ)2 /(4+δ), Πs = 2500(2+δ)2 /(4+δ) < ΠR = (1+δ)2500.
When a monopoly firm sells a durable good in t = 1 instead of leasing it, the monopoly
loses some of its monopoly power, that is why Πs < ΠR .
Coase conjecture (1972): In the ∞ horizon case, if δ→1 or ∆t→0, then the monopoly
profit Πs →0.
The conjecture was proved in different versions by Stokey (1981), Bulow (1982), Gul,
Sonnenschein, and Wilson (1986).
Tirole EX 1.8.
1. A monopoly is the only producer of a durable good in t = 1, 2, 3, . . .. If (q1 , q2 , q3 , . . .)
and (p1 , p2 , p3 , . . .) are the quantity and price sequences for the monopoly product,
the profit is
∞
X
Π= δ t p t qt .
t=1
2. There is a continuum of consumers indexed by α ∈ [0, 1], each needs 1 unit of the
durable good.
α
vα = α + δα + δ 2 α + . . . = : The utility of the durable good to consumer α.
1−δ
If consumer α purchases the good at t, his consumer surplus is
α
δ t (vα − pt ) = δ t ( − pt ).
1−δ
18
3. A linear stationary equilibrium is a pair (λ, µ), 0 < λ, µ < 1, such that
(a) If vα > λpt , then consumer α will buy in t if he does not buy before t.
(b) If at t, all consumers with vα > v (vα < v) have purchased (not purchased) the
durable good, then the monopoly charges pt = µv.
(c) The purchasing strategy of (a) maximizes consumer α’s consumer surplus, given
the pricing strategy (b).
(d) The pricing strategy of (b) maximizes the monopoly profits, given the purchacing
strategy (a).
One way a monopoy of a durable good can avoid Coase problem is price commitment.
By convincing the consumers that the price is not going to be reduced in the future,
it can make the same amount of profit as in the rent case. However, the commitment
equilibrium is not subgame perfect. Another way is to make the product less durable.
(1) P = MC,
1Rq
(2) Ps dx = Cs /q: Average marginal valuation of quality should be equal to the
q 0
marginal cost of quality per unit.
Game theory: the study of conflict and cooperation between persons with differ-
ent objective functions.
2. Moves: decision points in the game at which players must make choices between
alternatives (personal moves) and randomization points (called nature’s moves).
3. A play: A complete record of the choices made at moves by the players and
realizations of randomization.
Once we identify the pure strategy set of each player, we can represent the game
in normal form (also called strategic form).
Normal form:
@ II
@
I @ σ1 ... σn
s1 (a11 , b11 ) ... (a1n , b1n )
.. .. .. ..
. . . .
sm (am1 , bm1 ) . . . (amn , bmn )
22
5.3 Examples
Example 1: A perfect information game
Q R
L
1
2 Q
L
Q2
l @ r @ R
@ @
II
1 9 3 8 @
9 6 7 2 @
I @ Ll Rl Lr Rr
L (1,9) (1,9) (9,6) (9,6)
S1 = { L, R }, S2 = { Ll, Lr, Rl, Rr }. R (3,7)* (8,2) (3,7) (8,2)
Example 2: Prisoners’ dilemma game
L
1
Q R
Q
@ 2 Q
@
L @R L @R
II
4 0 5 1 @
4 5 0 1 @
I @ L R
L (4,4) (0,5)
S1 = { L, R }, S2 = { L, R }. R (5,0) (1,1)*
Example 3: Hijack game
L
Q R
1
Q
L
Q2
@ R
@
−1
2
2
−10
II
@
−2 −10 @
I @ L R
L (-1,2) (-1,2)*
S1 = { L, R }, S2 = { L, R }. R (2,-2)* (-10,-10)
Remark: Each extensive form game corresponds a normal form game. However,
different extensive form games may have the same normal form.
23
2. A Nash equilibrium: A strategy pair (si∗ , σj∗ ) such that ai∗j∗ ≥ aij∗ and bi∗j∗ ≥
bi∗j for all (i, j). Therefore, there is no incentives for each player to deviate from
the equilibrium strategy. ai∗j∗ and bi∗j∗ are called the equilibrium payoff.
The equilibrium payoffs of the examples are marked each with a star in the normal
form.
Remark 1: It is possible that a game does no have a pure strategy Nash equilib-
rium. Also, a game can have more than one Nash equilibria.
Remark 2: Notice that the concept of a Nash equilibrium is defined for a normal form
game. For a game in extensive form (a game tree), we have to find the normal form
before we can find the Nash equilibria.
3. Also, each pure strategy of a player induces a pure strategy for every subgame.
All the equilibria, except the equilibrium strategy pair (L,R) in the hijack game, are
subgame perfect.
Remark: The concept of a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium is defined only for an
extensive form game.
Kuhn’s Theorem: In every extensive game with perfect recall, a strategically equiva-
lent behavior strategy can be found for every mixed strategy.
However, in a non-perfect recall game, a mixed strategy may do better than be-
havior strategies because in a behavior strategy the local strategies are independent
whereas they can be correlated in a mixed strategy.
0
HH
1/2 HH1/2 A 2-person 0-sum non-perfect recall game.
1 1 1 1
HH2
u ∗ ∗
11 NE is (µ 1 , µ 2 ) = ( ac ⊕ bd, A ⊕ B).
a @ b @ 2 2 2 2
@ A
@B µ∗1 is not a behavioral strategy.
A
@ u12 @
A
1 c Ad c Ad −1
−1 A A 1
2 0 −2 0
−2 0 2 0
5.5.3 Reduction of a game
Redundant strategy: A pure strategy is redundant if it is strategically identical to
another strategy.
Reduced normal form: The normal form without redundant strategies.
Equivalent normal form: Two normal forms are equivalent if they have the same
reduced normal form.
Equivalent extensive form: Two extensive forms are equivalent if their normal forms
are equivalent.
Equivalent transformation:
(1) Inflation-Deflation;
1 1
A A
r r
A A
2 A 2 A
A
@ A @ A
@ @ A
A
A
1 @ A1 @ 1 A
A A A A
A A A A A A
A A A A A A
25
1 1
A A
r r
A A
2 A 1 A
A A
@ A @ A
@ @
A
A
1 @ A1 2 @ A1
A A A A
A A A A A A
A A A A A A
Duopoly game:
There are two sellers (firm 1 and firm 2) of a product.
The (inverse) market demand function is P = a − Q.
The marginal production costs are c1 and c2 , respectively.
Assume that each firm regards the other firm’s output as given (not affected by his
output quantity).
The situation defines a 2-person game as follows: Each firm i controls his own output
quantity qi . (q1 , q2 ) together determine the market price P = a − (q1 + q2 ) which in
turn determines the profit of each firm:
Π1 (q1 , q2 ) = (P −c1 )q1 = (a−c1 −q1 −q2 )q1 and Π2 (q1 , q2 ) = (P −c2 )q2 = (a−c2 −q1 −q2 )q2
The FOC are ∂Π1 /∂q1 = a − c1 − q2 − 2q1 = 0 and ∂Π2 /∂q2 = a − c2 − q1 − 2q2 = 0.
The reaction functions are q1 = 0.5(a − c1 − q2 ) and q2 = 0.5(a − c2 − q1 ).
The Cournot Nash equilibrium is (q1∗ , q2∗ ) = ((a − 2c1 + c2 )/3, (a − 2c2 + c1 )/3) with
P ∗ = (a + c1 + c2 )/3. (We have to assume that a − 2c1 + c2 , a − 2c2 + c1 ≥ 0.)
The problem of finding the maxmin mixed strategy (to find p∗ to maximize
t(p)) can be stated as
X X X
max t subj. to pi ai1 ≥ t, . . . , pi ain ≥ t, pi = 1.
p
i i i
7. Duality: It turns out that player 2’s minmax problem can be transformed sim-
ilarly and becomes the dual of player 1’s linear programming problem. The
existence of a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium is then proved by using the
duality theorem in linear programming.
1 0
Example (tossing coin game): A = .
0 1
To find player 2’s equilibrium mixed strategy, we solve the linear programming prob-
lem:
max x1 + x2 subj. to x1 ≤ 1 x2 ≤ 1.
x1 ,x2 ≥0
@ @
@ @
@r @r
@ @
1 1
@ @
@ @
@ @
@ - x1 @ - y1
1 1
28
Player 1’s equilibrium mixed strategy is obtained by solving the dual to the linear
programming problem:
min y1 + y2 subj. to y1 ≥ 1 y2 ≥ 1.
y1 ,y2 ≥0
S1 = { S, N }, S2 = { S, N }.
There are two pure strategy NE: (S, N ) and (N, S).
There is also a mixed strategy NE. Suppose player 2 plays a mixed strategy (q, 1 − q).
If player 1 plays S, his expected payoff is Π1 (S) = 0q + (−3)(1 − q). If he plays
N , his expected payoff is Π1 (N ) = 3q + (−9)(1 − q). For a mixed strategy NE,
Π1 (S) = Π1 (N ), therefore, q = 32 .
The mixed strategy is symmetrical: (p∗1 , p∗2 ) = (q1∗ , q2∗ ) = ( 23 , 13 ).
Consider the case of a 3-person game. There are 8 subsets of N = {1, 2, 3}, namely,
φ, (1), (2), (3), (12), (13), (23), (123). Therefore, a characteristic form game is deter-
mined by 8 values v(φ), v(1), v(2), v(3), v(12), v(13), v(23), v(123).
Super-additivity: If A ∩ B = φ, then v(A ∪ B) ≥ v(A) + v(B).
An imputation is a payoff distribution (x1 , x2 , x3 ).
Individual rationality: P xi ≥ v(i).
Group rationality: i∈S xi ≥ v(S).
Core C: the set of imputations that satisfy individual rationality and group rational-
ity for all S.
Example: v(φ) = v(1) = v(2) = v(3) = 0, v(12) = v(13) = v(23) = 0.5, v(123) = 1.
C = {(x1 , x2 , x3 ), xi ≥ 0, xi + xj ≥ 0.5, x1 + x2 + x3 = 1}. Both (0.3, 0.3, 0.4) and
(0.2, 0.4, 0.4) are in C.
The Shapley values are (π1 , π2 , π3 ) = ( 13 , 13 , 13 ).
Remark 1: The core of a game can be empty. However, the Shapley values are
uniquely determined.
Remark 2: Another related concept is the von-Neumann Morgenstern solution. See
CH 6 of Intriligator’s Mathematical Optimization and Economic Theory for the mo-
tivations of these concepts.
x∗2
T2
- x1
T1 x∗1
30
5.10 Problems
1. Consider the following two-person 0-sum game:
I \ II σ 1 σ2 σ3
s1 4 3 -2
s2 3 4 10
s3 7 6 8
(a) Find the max min strategy of player I smax min and the min max strategy
of player II σmin max .
(b) Is the strategy pair (smax min , σmin max ) a Nash equilibrium of the game?
(c) What are the equilibrium payoffs?
2. Find the maxmin strategy (smax min ) and the minmax strategy (σmin max ) of the
following two-person 0-sum game:
I \ II σ1 σ2
s1 -3 6
s2 8 -2
s3 6 3
Is the strategy pair (smax min , σmin max ) a Nash equilibrium? If not, use simplex
method to find the mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.
3. Find the (mixed strategy) Nash Equilibrium of the following two-person game:
I \ II H T
H (-2, 2) (2, -1)
T (2, -2) (-1,2)
4. Suppose that two firms producing a homogenous product face a linear demand
curve P = a−bQ = a−b(q1 +q2 ) and that both have the same constant marginal
costs c. For a given quantity pair (q1 , q2 ), the profits are Πi = qi (P − c) =
qi (a − bq1 − bq2 − c), i = 1, 2. Find the Cournot Nash equilibrium output of
each firm.
6. A singer (player 1), a pianist (player 2), and a drummer (player 3) are offered
$ 1,000 to play together by a night club owner. The owner would alternatively
pay $ 800 the singer-piano duo, $ 650 the piano drums duo, and $ 300 the piano
alone. The night club is not interested in any other combination. Howeover,
the singer-drums duo makes $ 500 and the singer alone gets $ 200 a night in a
restaurant. The drums alone can make no profit.
(a) Write down the characteristic form of the cooperative game with side pay-
ments.
(b) Find the Shapley values of the game.
(c) Characterize the core.
32
Definition of a Cournot equilibrium: {P c , q1c , q2c } such that P c = P (Qc ) = a−b(q1c +q2c )
and
π1 (q1c , q2c ) ≥ π1 (q1 , q2c ), π2 (q1c , q2c ) ≥ π2 (q1c , q2 ), ∀(q1 , q2 ).
The first order conditions (FOC) are
∂π1 ∂π2
= a − 2bq1 − bq2 − c1 = 0, = a − bq1 − 2bq2 − c2 = 0.
∂q1 ∂q2
In matrix form,
c
2b b q1 a − c1 q1 1 a − 2c1 + c2
= , ⇒ = .
b 2b q2 a − c2 q2c 3b a − 2c2 + c1
c
(a − 2c1 + c2 )2
c 2a − c1 − c2 c a + c 1 + c2 π1 1
Q = , P = , = .
3b 3 π2c 9b (a − 2c2 + c1 )2
If c1 ↓ (say, due to R&D), then q1c ↑, q2c ↓, Qc ↑, P c ↓, π1c ↑, π2c ↓.
FOC is
∂πi X X X
= a−b qj − bqi − ci = P − bqi − ci = 0, ⇒ N a − (N + 1)b qj − cj = 0,
∂qi j j j
P P P
X N a − j cj a + j cj c P − c i a + j cj − (N + 1)ci
⇒ Qc = qjc = , Pc = , qi = = .
j
(N + 1)b N +1 b b(N + 1)
Symmetric case ci = c:
a−c a + Nc N a−c
qic = , Pc = , Qc = .
(N + 1)b N +1 N +1 b
When N = 1, it is the monopoly case.
a−c
As N → ∞, (P c , Qc ) → (c, ), the competition case.
b
c c
X (a − c)2 N + 0.5N 2
W (N ) = CS (N ) + πj = .
j
b (N + 1)2
(a − c)2 X
lim W c (N ) = lim CSc (N ) = , lim πj = 0.
N →∞ N →∞ 2b N →∞
j
P
6
@
@
@
CS @@
Pc @
π1 π2 π3 @
c @
@
@- Q, qi
q1 Qc
34
The consequence is that when choosing q2 , firm 2 already knows what q1 is. On
the other hand, in deciding the quantity q1 , firm 1 takes into consideration firm 2’s
possible reaction, i.e., firm 1 assumes that q2 = R2 (q1 ). This is the idea of backward
induction and the equilibrium derived is a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium.
At t = 1, firm 1 chooses q1 to maximize the (expected) profit π1 = π1 (q1 , R2 (q1 )):
a − c2
max[a−b(q1 +R2 (q1 ))]q1 −c1 q1 = [a−b(q1 + −0.5q1 )]q1 −c1 q1 = 0.5(a+c2 −bq1 )q1 −c1 q1 .
q1 2b
The FOC (interior solution) is
q2
6
A
A R1 (q2 )
A
A
A
H A
HHA
q2c HAH
q2s A HH R2 (q1 )
H
A H - q1
q1c q1s
will chooses a large enough q2 to make market price zero. This is an incredible threat
because firm 2 will hurt himself too. However, if firm 1 believes that the threat will
be executed, there can be all kind of equilibria.
6.2.2 Extension
The model can be extended in many ways. For example, when there are three firms
choosing output quantities sequentially. Or firms 1 and 2 move simultaneously and
then firm 3 follows, etc.
π1e (q1 , q2e ) = (a − bq1 − bq2e )q1 − c1 q1 , π2e (q1e , q2 ) = (a − bq1e − bq2 )q2 − c2 q2 .
In matrix form,
(2 + λ1 )b b q1 a − c1
= ,
b (2 + λ2 )bq2 a − c2
q1 1 (a − c1 )(2 + λ2 ) − (a − c2 )
⇒ = .
q2 [3 + 2(λ1 + λ2 ) + λ1 λ2 ]b (a − c2 )(2 + λ1 ) − (a − c1 )
If λ1 = λ2 = 0, then it becomes the Cournot equilibrium.
Assumption: Consumers always choose to buy from the firm charging lower price.
When two firms charge the same price, the market demand divided equally between
them. Let Q = D(P ) be the market demand.
0 p1 > p2 D(p2 ) p1 > p2
q1 = D1 (p1 , p2 ) = 0.5D(p1 ) p1 = p2 q2 = D2 (p1 , p2 ) = 0.5D(p2 ) p1 = p2
D(p1 ) p1 < p2 , 0 p1 < p2 .
P p1 p2
6 6 6
D(P ) D1 (p1 , p2 ) D2 (p1 , p2 )
@
@
r r
@
@ p2 p1
@ @ @
@ @ @
@ @ @
@ -Q @ - q1 @ - q2
Bertrand game:
π1 (p1 , p2 ) = (p1 − c1 )D1 (p1 , p2 ), π2 (p1 , p2 ) = (p2 − c2 )D2 (p1 , p2 )
Bertrand equilibrium: {pb1 , pb2 , q1b , q2b } such that q1b = D1 (pb1 , pb2 ), q2b = D2 (pb1 , pb2 ), and
π1 (pb1 , pb2 ) ≥ π1 (p1 , pb2 ), π2 (pb1 , pb2 ) ≥ π2 (pb1 , p2 ) ∀ (p1 , p2 ).
We cannot use FOCs to find the reaction functions and the equilibrium as in the
Cournot quantity competition case because the profit functions are not continuous.
37
P
6
t
D(P )
3
2 t
1 t
-Q
1 2 3
Edgeworth Cycle of (p1 , p2 ): (2, 2)→(3, 2)→(3, 2.9)→(2.8, 2.9)→(2.8, 2.7)→ · · · →(2, 2)
Therefore, the is no equilibrium but repetitions of similar cycles.
38
1 1
Given the Cournot equilibrium (q1c , q2c ) = ( , ), we can define a Cournot strategy for
3 3
the repeated game as follows:
c 1
σi,t (Ht−1 ) = qic =
∀Ht−1 , σic ≡ (σi,0c c
, σi,1 c
, . . . , σi,t , . . .).
3
It is straightforward to show that the pair (σ1c , σ2c ) is a Nash equilibrium for the
repeated game.
39
9
6.7.2 (σ T , σ T ) is a SPNE for δ >
17
Proof:
1. At every period t in the cooperative phase, if the opponent does not violate the
cooperation, then firm i’s gain to continue cooperation is
1
Π∗ = 0.5πm + δ0.5πm + δ 2 0.5πm + · · · = 0.5πm (1 + δ + δ 2 + · · ·) = .
8(1 − δ)
3
If firm i chooses to stop the cooperative phase, he will set qt = (the profit max-
8
imization output when qj = 0.25) and then trigger the non-cooperative phase and
gains the Cournot profit of 1/9 per period. Firm i’s gain will be
9 9 9 δ
Πv = + δπic + δ 2 0.5πic + · · · = + πic (δ + δ 2 + · · ·) = + .
64 64 64 9(1 − δ)
1
Π∗ − Π v =
(17δ − 9) > 0.
576
Therefore, during the cooperative phase, the best strategy is to continue cooperation.
2. In the non-cooperative phase, the Cournot quantity is the Nash equilibrium quan-
tity in each period.
The cooperative phase is the equilibrium realization path. The non-cooperative phase
is called off-equilibrium subgames.
40
1
6.7.4 (σ RT , σ RT ) is a NE for δ >
9
Proof:
At every period t in the cooperative phase, if the opponent does not violate the
cooperation, then firm i’s gain to continue cooperation is (same as the trigger strategy
case)
1
Π∗ = .
8(1 − δ)
3
If firm i chooses to stop the cooperative phase, he will set qt = (same as the trigger
8
strategy case) and then trigger the retaliation phase, making 0 profit per period. Firm
i’s gain will be
9 1 9 9δ − 1
Πv = ⇒ Π∗ − Πv = − = > 0.
64 8(1 − δ) 64 64(1 − δ)
Therefore, during the cooperative phase, the best strategy is to continue cooperation.
The retaliation phase is off-equilibrium subgames and never reached. Since the retal-
iation strategy is not optimal, the Nash equilibrium is not subgame-perfect.
9
In summary, if 1 > δ > , then the duopoly firms will collude in a SPNE; if
17
9 1 1
> δ > , then the duopoly firms will collusion in a non-perfect NE. If δ < , then
17 9 9
collusion is impossible.
41
Folk Theorem: When δ→1, every distributions of profits such that the average
payoff per period πi ≥ πic can be implemented as a SPNE.
For subgame-non-perfect NEs, the individual profits can be even lower then the
Cournot profit.
∂Πi ∂Πi
= a − 2bqih − bqjf = 0, = a − 2bqif − bqjh − τ = 0, i = 1, 2.
∂qih ∂qif
In a symmetric equilibrium q1h = q2h = q h and q1f = q2f = q f . In matrix form, the
FOC’s become:
a+τ
h h
2b b q a q 3b ,
= , ⇒ = a− 2τ
b 2b qf a−τ qf
3b
2a − τ a+τ
Q = qh + qf = P = .
3b 3
It seems that there is reciprocal dumping: the FOB price of exports P FOB is lower
than the domestic price P .
a+τ a − 2τ
P CIF = P = , P FOB = P CIF − τ = < P.
3 3
However, since P FOB > MC = 0, there is no dumping in the MC definition of dump-
ing.
The comparative statics with respect to τ is
∂q h ∂q f ∂Q ∂P
> 0, < 0, < 0, > 0.
∂τ ∂τ ∂τ ∂τ
In this model, it seems that international trade is a waste of transportation costs
and is unnecessary. However, if there is no international competition, each country’s
market would become a monopoly.
Demand: P = a − Q.
2 export countries: America and Japan, PA < PJ .
P P P
6
@ 6
@ 6
@
@ @ @
@ @ @
CS0 @ @ φ @
P0 @ CS1 @ P0 @
@ @ β @
γ
PJ T0 @ P1 @ P1 @
@ @ δ @
PA @ @ PA @
@- Q @- Q @- Q
Q0 Q1 Q0 Q1
W1 − W0 = (φ + β + γ) − (φ + β + δ) = γ − δ.
γ: trade creation effect.
δ: trade diversion effect.
W1 − W0 > 0 if and only if γ > δ.
Incomplete information game: Some players do not completely know the rule of
the game. In particular, a player does not know the payoff functions of other players.
There are more than one type of a player, whose payoff function depends on his type.
The type is known to the player himself but not to other players. There is a prior
probability distribution of the type of a player.
To find the Bayesian equilibrium, we regard the duopoly as a 3-person game with
payoff functions:
FOC are
In matrix form,
−1
p1 α β γ q1 q1 β γ α p1
= − , ⇒ = − ,
p2 α γ β q2 q2 γ β α p2
1 α(β − γ) β −γ p1 a b −c p1
= 2 − ≡ − ,
β − γ2 α(β − γ) −γ β p2 a −c b p2
where
α β γ
a≡ , b≡ , c≡ .
β+γ β2 − γ2 β2 − γ2
If γ = 0 (c = 0), the firms are independent monopolists. If 0 < γ < β (0 < c < b)
the products are substitutes. When β = γ ⇒ p1 = p2 , the products are perfect
substitutable (homogenous).
β
6
γ2
@ Define δ ≡ , degree of differentiation.
@Complemnts Substitutes β2
@ If δ (hence γ, c) → 0, products are
@
us
@
highly differentiated.
eo
@
en
@
m
@ -γ
π1c (q1 , q2 ) = (p1 −c1 )q1 = (α−βq1 −γq2 −c1 )q1 , π2c (q1 , q2 ) = (p2 −c2 )q2 = (α−βq1 −γq2 −c2 )q2 .
In a Bertrand price competition duopoly game, the payoffs are represented as func-
tions of (p1 , p2 ):
π1b (p1 , p2 ) = (p1 −c1 )q1 = (p1 −c1 )(a−bp1 +cp2 ), π2b (p1 , p2 ) = (p2 −c2 )q2 = (p2 −c2 )(a−bp2 +cp1 ).
It seems that Cournot game and Bertrand game are just a change of variables of each
other. However, the Nash equilibrium is totally different. A change of variables of a
game also changes its Nash equilibrium.
47
qi
6
√
dqi γ
= − = −0.5 δ
dqj Rc 2β
i
The larger δ, the steeper the reaction curve.
HH If products are independent, δ = 0,
HH
HH qi is independent of qj .
HHRic (qj )
HH -
qj
48
In a symmetric equilibrium, q1 = q2 = q c , p1 = p2 = pc ,
α α αβ α
qc = = √ , pc = α − (β + γ)q c = = √ ,
2β + γ β(2 + δ) 2β + γ 2+ δ
and π1 = π2 = π c ,
α2 β α2
πc = = √ .
(2β + γ)2 β(2 + δ)2
∂q c ∂pc ∂π c
< 0, < 0, < 0.
∂δ ∂δ ∂δ
Therefore, when the degree of differentiation increases, q c , pc , and π c will be increased.
When δ = 1, it reduces to the homogeneous case.
π1b (p1 , p2 ) = (a − bp1 + cp2 )p1 , π2b (p1 , p2 ) = (a − bp2 + cp1 )p2 .
pi
6
√
dpi
= 0.5 δ
dpj Rb
i
The larger δ, the steeper the reaction curve.
b
Ri (pj ) If products are independent, δ = 0,
pi is independent of pj .
- pj
In a symmetric equilibrium, p1 = p2 = pb , q1 = q2 = q b ,
a a α(β − γ) ab a
pb = = √ = , q b = a − (b − c)pb = = √ ,
2b + c b(2 + δ) 2β − γ 2b − c 2− δ
and π1 = π2 = π b ,
√
b a2 b a2 α2 (β − γ)β α2 (1 − δ)
π = = √ = = √ √ .
(2b − c)2 b(2 − δ)2 (2β − γ)2 (β + γ) β(2 − δ)2 (1 + δ)
∂pb ∂q b ∂π b
< 0, < 0, < 0.
∂δ ∂δ ∂δ
Therefore, when the degree of differentiation increases, pb , q b , and π b will be increased.
When δ = 1, it reduces to the homogeneous case and pb →0.
49
α
pc − p b = > 0, ⇒ q c − q b < 0.
4δ −1 − 1
As δ→0, pc →pb and when δ = 0, pc = pb .
From the above example, we can see that in a quantity game firms prefer to be
the leader whereas in a price game they prefer to be the follower.
50
Assume that every existing and potential producer produces identical product and
has the same cost function.
TCi (qi ) = F . P =A−Q
Assume that there are n firms in the industry. The n-firm oligopoly quantity compe-
tition equilibrium is (see 6.1.2)
2
A A
qi = = P, ⇒ πi = − F ≡ Π(n).
n+1 n+1
If Π(n + 1) > 0, then at least a new firm will enter the industry. If Π(n) < 0, then
the some of the existing firms will exit.
In LR equilibrium, the number of firms n∗ will be such that Π(n∗ ) ≥ 0 ≥ Π(n∗ + 1).
2
∗ A ∗ A
Π(n ) = −F ≥0 ⇒n = √ − 1.
n+1 F
Π
6
Π(n∗ ) > 0 and Π(n∗ + 1) < 0.
-n
n∗ n∗+1
The model above can be modified to consider the case when firms produce differ-
entiated products:
!
X X X
pi = A−qi −δ q j , πi = A − q i − δ qj qi −F, ⇒ FOC: A−2qi −δ qj = 0,
j6=i j6=i j6=i
where 0 < δ < 1. If there are N firms, in Cournot equilibrium, qi = q ∗ for all i, and
2
∗ ∗ A ∗ A
q =p = , π = − F.
2 + (N − 1)δ 2 + (N − 1)δ
The equilibrium number of firms is
∗ A 2 1 A 1
N = √ +1− = √ −1 +1− .
δ F δ δ F δ
51
FOC is
1
α−1
∂L λpi I −1 −1
= α(qi )α−1 − λpi = 0 ⇒ qi = = P −α
pi1−α = Api1−α .
∂qi α pj1−α
j
52
∂A 1
As N is very large, ≈ 0 and the demand elasticity is approximately |η| = .
∂pi 1−α
The cost function of producer i is TCi (qi ) = F + cqi .
1
The monopoly profit maximization pricing rule MC = P (1 − |η|
) means:
|η| c c(1 − α)
p∗i = c = , πi = (p∗i − c)qi − F = qi − F.
|η| − 1 α α
αF I (1 − α)I
qi∗ = , N∗ = ∗ ∗ = .
(1 − α)c pq F
Horizontal differentiation: Different consumers have different tastes w.r.t. the dif-
ferentiated character, eg., P0, ¯.
τ is the transportation cost per unit distance. |x − a| (|x − (L − b)|) is the distance
between x and A (B).
The marginal consumer x̂ is indifferent between buying from A and from B. The
location of x̂ is determined by
L − b + a PA − P B
−PA − τ |x − a| = −PB − τ |x − (L − b)| ⇒ x̂ = − . (1)
2 2τ
The location of x̂ divids the market into two parts: [0, x̂) is firm A’s market share
and (x̂, L] is firm B’s market share.
d r̂ d
A’s share - B’s share -
0 a x L−b L
Therefore, given (PA , PB ), the demand functions of firms A and B are
L − b + a PA − P B L − a + b PA − P B
DA (PA , PB ) = x̂ = − , DB (PA , PB ) = L−x̂ = + .
2 2τ 2 2τ
Assume that firms A and B engage in price competition and that the marginal costs
are zero. The payoff functions are
L − b + a PA − P B L − a + b PA − P B
ΠA (PA , PB ) = PA − , ΠB (PA , PB ) = PB + .
2 2τ 2 2τ
L − b + a 2PA − PB L − a + b PA − 2PB
− = 0, + = 0. (2)
2 2τ 2 2τ
The equilibrium is given by
τ (3L − b + a) τ (3L − a + b) 3L − b + a 3L − a + b
PA = , PB = , QA = x̂ = , QB = L−x̂ = .
3 3 6 6
τ (3L − b + a)2 τ (2L + d + 2a)2 τ (3L − a + b)2 τ (2L + d + 2b)2
ΠA = = , ΠB = = ,
18 18 18 18
where d ≡ L − b − a is the distance between the locations of A and B. the degree of
product differentiation is measured by dτ . When d or τ increases, the products are
more differentiated, the competition is less intensive, equilibrium prices are higher
and firms are making more profits.
55
Note: 1. In this model, we can not invert the demand function to define a quan-
tity competition game because the Jocobian is singular.
2. The degree of homogeneity δ = βγ is not definable either. Here we use the distance
between the locations of A and B as a measure of differentiation.
3. The result that firms in the Hotelling model will choose to minimize product
differentiation is so far only an approximation because the location of the marginal
consumer x̂ in (7) is not exactly described. It is actually an upper-semi continuous
correspondence of (PA , PB ). The reaction functions are discontinuous and the price
competition equilibrium does not exist when the two firms are too close to each other.
See Oz Shy’s Appendix 7.5.
@
@
@
@
@
@ @ @
@ @ @
@ @ @
@dd @d @d
@A B A @ @ B
x̂
6
Consumers in [0, a] move together. L
L−b H
HH
Consumers in [L − b, L] move together. HH
HH
a H
d d 0 - PA
0 a L−b L PB − (L − a − b)τ PB + (L − a − b)τ
For a ≤ L/4, the reaction functions intersect at PA = PB = τ L. When a > L/4, the
reaction functions do not intersect.
ΠA PB RA PB
6 6 6 RA
RB
RB
- PA - PA - PA
PB − dτ PB + dτ Case: a ≤ L/4, P ∗ = τ L, Case: a > L/4, no equilibrium.
7.4.4 Quadratic transportation costs
Suppose now that the transportation cost is proportional to the square of the distance.
−PA − τ (x − a)2
if x buys from A.
Ux =
−PB − τ [x − (L − b)]2 if x buys from A.
57
In the linear transportation case, the 2nd effect dominates. In the quadratic trans-
portation case, the 1st effect dominates.
Also, x̂ is differentiable in the quadratic case and the interior solution to the profit
maximization problem is the global maximum.
Welfare comparison:
d d d d
A B A B
0 x̂ = L/2 L 0 L/4 x̂ = L/2 3L/4 L
Equilibrium transportation cost curve Social optimum transportation cost curve
58
d r d d
i−1 i i+1
−L/N x 0 L/N
As in the linear city model, each consumer needs 1 unit of the product. The utility
of consumer x, if he buys from firm j, is
U (x) = −Pj − τ |x − lj |, j = i − 1, i, i + 1,
where lj is the location of firm j. To simplify, let L = 1. Given the prices Pi and
Pi−1 = Pi+1 = P , there are two marginal consumers x̂ and −x̂ with
P − Pi 1 P − Pi 1
x̂ = + , ⇒ Qi = 2x̂ = + .
2τ 2N τ N
d r id r d
i−1 i+1
−1/N −x̂ 0 x̂ 1/N
P − Pi 1 c + P − 2Pi 1
Πi = (Pi − c) + − F, ⇒ FOC: + = 0.
τ N τ N
In equilibrium, Pi = P ,
τ τ
P =c+
, Π = 2 − F.
N N
In a free entry/exit long run equilibrium, N is such that
√
r
∗ τ 1
Π(N ) ≥ 0, Π(N + 1) ≤ 0 ⇒ N = , P ∗ = c + τ F , Q∗ = .
F N
@
@ Aggregate transportation costs:
@ 1 τ τ
@ T (N ) = N ( )= .
@ 2N 2N 4N
@
@ Aggregate Fixed Costs = N F .
@
@
@
−1/2N 0 1/2N
Equilibrium transportation cost curve
59
Since each consumer needs 1 unit, TVC = c is a constant. The total cost to the
society is the sum of aggregate transportation cost, TVC, and fixed cost.
r
τ τ s τ
SC(N ) = T (N ) + c + N F = + c + N F, FOC: − + F = 0, ⇒ N = 0.5 .
4N 4N 2 F
The conclusion is that the equilibrium number of firms is twice the social optimum
number.
Assume that there are 3 firms and they enter the market (select locations) sequen-
tially. That is, firm 1 chooses x1 , then firm 2 chooses x2 , and finally firm 3 chooses
x3 . To simplify, we assume that firms charge the same price p = 1 and that x1 = 1/4.
We want to find the equilibrium locations x2 and x3 .
2. If firm 2 chooses x2 ∈ (x1 , 3/4) = (1/4, 3/4), then firm 3 will choose x3 = x2 + .
π2 = x2 − (x2 + x1 )/2 = (x2 − x1 )/2 < 1/4.
xd1 x2dx
d3
0 1 π2 = (x2 − x1 )/2 < 1/4.
1/4 3/4
3. If firm 2 chooses x2 ∈ [3/4, 1], then firm 3 will choose x3 = (x2 + x1 )/2.
π2 = 1 − 0.5(x2 + x3 )/2 = (15 − 12x2 )/16.
xd1 xd3 xd2
0 1 π2 = (15 − 12x2 )/16.
1/4 3/4
The subgame perfect Nash equilibrium is x2 = 3/4, x3 = 1/2 with π1 = π2 = 3/8 and
π3 = 1/4.
60
Nash Equilibrium: (PAn , PBn ) such that PAn maximizes ΠA = PA nA and PBn maximizes
Π B = P B nB .
Proof: 1. If PAn − PBn > T , then ΠA = 0, firm A will reduce PA . Similarily for
PBn − PAn > T .
2. If |PAn − PBn | < T , then firm A will increase PA .
3. If |PAn − PBn | = T , then both firms will reduce their prices.
In choosing PA , firm A believes that if PA is too high, firm B will undercut its
price to grab A’s consumers and vice versa.
There is a undercut proof equilibrium: nuA = N0 , nuB = NL ,and (PAu , PBu ) satisfies
(N0 + NL )(N0 − NL )T
∆P = PBu − PAu = , ∆P ≷ 0 if N0 ≷ NL .
N02 + NL2 + N0 NL
In the symmetric case, N0 = NL and PAu = PBu = 2T .
PA PA PA
6 6 RB (PA ) 6
firm B will RA (PB ) firm A will
not undercut
undercut t
UE
firm B will not
firm A will
undercut - PB undercut - P - PB
B
62
Õ2D‚â5É[;
\úÕ2í„; 1. òQßã: #„}j, ö¼¯9
2. Š¢HS¦ªÒ®×G¨
i = 1, 2, . . . , N , Q = q 1 + q2 + · · · + q N .
qi
Market shares: si ≡ × 100%, s1 ≥ s2 ≥ s3 ≥ · · · ≥ sN .
Q
I8 ≡ 8i=1 si .
P
I4 ≡ s 1 + s 2 + s 3 + s 4 ,
PN
Herfindahl-Hirshman Index: IHH ≡ i=1 s2i .
1 P N Pj 1 PN
Gini coefficient: G ≡ j=1 i=1 si = (N − i)si .
N N 1
PN
Entropy: IE ≡ 1 si ln si .
IHH (1 + λ)
If λi = λ for all i, then L = .
P Q
Q−i 1
The case of collusion λi = : FOC is MR = MCi and Li = L = .
qi P Q
8.2 Mergers
Mergers, takeovers, acquisitions, integration.
3 types:
Horizontal mergers: between the same industry
Vertical mergers: between upstream industry firms and down stream industry firms
Conglomerate mergers: other cases.
Purpose: (1) reduce competition, (2) IRTS, (3) differences in the prospective of
firms between sellers and buyers,
(4) managers’ intension to enlarge their own careers, (5) the insterests of the
promoters.
A B B
A ¯9 ⇒
A A1
A
?
U A ? ?
1 2 2
Assumption: The upstream was originally in Bertrand competition and the down-
stream was in Cournot competition.
Downsteam market demand: P = α − q1 − q2 . MC1 = c1 , MC2 = c2 .
α − 2ci + cj (α − 2ci + cj )2 2α − c1 − c2 α + c1 + c2
⇒ qi = , πi = ; Q= , P = α−Q = .
3 9 3 3
Upstream: Assume MCA = MCB = 0. Bertrand equilibrium: pA = pB = c1 =
c2 = 0.
Pre-merge Equilibrium:
α α2 α 2α
q1 = q 2 = , π1 = π 2 = , πA = πB = 0; P = , Q = .
3 9 3 3
Post-merge: Assume that A1 does not sell raw material to 2. B becomes an upstream
monopoly. We ignore the fact that 2 is also a downstream monopsony.
c2 (α − 2c2 + c1 ) pB (α − 2pB ) α
πB = c 2 q 2 = = , max πB ⇒ pB = c2 = .
3 3 pB 4
Post-merge Equilibrium:
5α α 5α 7α 25α2 α2 α2
qA1 = , q2 = , P = , Q= , πA1 = P qA1 = , = π2 = , πB = P B q 2 = .
12 6 12 12 144 36 24
The effects of merge: P ↑, q1 ↑, q2 ↓, π2 ↓, πB ↑, πA + π1 ↑, πB + π2 ↓.
Firm 2 and consumers are the losers.
Market demand: Qs = α − Ps = α − Px − Py , Qx = Qy = Qs .
Pre-merge:
Πx = Px Qx = Px (α − Px − Py ), Πy = Py Qy = Py (α − Px − Py ).
α α α2
⇒ Px = Py = , Qs = Q x = Q y = , Πx = Π y = .
3 3 9
Post-merge:
α α2
Πs = Ps Qs = Ps (α − Ps ), ⇒ Ps = Qs = , Πs = .
2 4
The effects of merger:
α 2α α α α2 2α2
Ps = < Px + Py = , Qs = > Q x = Q y = , Πs = > Πx + Πy = .
2 3 2 3 4 9
Therefore, one monopoly is better than two monopolies.
6. Other advantages
(A − c)2
In quantity competition with free entry/exit model, N ≈ √ :
bF
√
10, 000 bF ∂IHH
IHH = = 10, 000, > 0.
N A−c ∂F
r
τ F
In the circular city model, N = , IHH = 10, 000.
F τ
Πm − if no entry
A B 0 do not enter
Π = Π =
− B enters, − B enters,
where Πm is the monopoly profit and is the sunk cost.
B
@
Enter Stay
@ out
@ ∗
Πm −
−
− 0
Proposition: As long as 0 < < Πm , there exists only one subgame perfect equilib-
rium, i.e., B stays out.
Conditions: 1. A and B produce homogeneous product with identical marginal cost.
2. Post-entry market is a Bertrand duopoly.
3. A cannot retreat.
If A can resale some of its investments, say, recover φ > 0. The game becomes
B
@
Enter Stay
@ out
@m
A
@
Π −
@
Stay in Exit
@ 0
∗
− φ−
− Πm −
The only subgame-perfect equilibrium is that B enters and A exits. However, the
result is just a new monopoly replacing an old one. The sunk cost can be regarded
as the entry barrier as before.
Notice that there is a non-perfect equilibrium in which A chooses the incredible threat
strategy of Stay in and B chooses Stay out.
Π1 (x1 , x2 , y1 , y2 ), Π2 (x1 , x2 , y1 , y2 ),
where (x1 , y1 ) is firm 1’s strategy variables and (x2 , y2 ) is firm 2’s strategy variables.
π1 (x1 , x2 ) = Π1 (x1 , x2 , f (x1 , x2 ), g(x1 , x2 )), π2 (x1 , x2 ) = Π2 (x1 , x2 , f (x1 , x2 ), g(x1 , x2 )).
The FOC is
∂π1 ∂Π1 ∂Π1 ∂f ∂Π1 ∂g ∂π2 ∂Π2 ∂Π2 ∂f ∂Π2 ∂g
= + + = 0, and = + + = 0.
∂x1 ∂x1 ∂y1 ∂x1 ∂y2 ∂x1 ∂x2 ∂x2 ∂y1 ∂x2 ∂y2 ∂x2
∂Π1 ∂Π2
Since = = 0, the FOC becomes
∂y1 ∂y2
∂π1 ∂Π1 ∂Π1 ∂g ∂π2 ∂Π2 ∂Π2 ∂f
= + = 0, and = + = 0.
∂x1 ∂x1 ∂y2 ∂x1 ∂x2 ∂x2 ∂y1 ∂x2
Compare the FOC of the sequential game with that of the simultaneous game, we
can see that the equilibria are not the same. In t = 1, both firms try to influence
the t = 2 decisions of the other firms. For the simultaneous game, there is no such
considerations.
∂Π1 ∂g ∂Π2 ∂f
and are the strategic consideration terms.
∂y2 ∂x1 ∂y1 ∂x2
Entry deterrence application: In t = 1, only firm 1 exists:
Π1 (x1 , y1 , y2 ), Π2 (x1 , y1 , y2 ).
Firm 1 is the incumbent and tries to influence the entry decision of firm 2.
(1 − k1 )2
∂π2 1 − k1 1 − k1 1 − k1
= 1−k1 −2k2 = 0, ⇒ k2 = , π2 = 1 − k1 − −E = −E.
∂k2 2 2 2 4
69
(1 − k1 )2
If − E < 0, firm 2 will choose not to enter. Therefore, firm 2’s true reaction
4
function is
√
1 − k1
if k1 < 1 − 2 E
k2 = R2 (k1 , E) = 2 √
0 if k1 > 1 − 2 E.
k2
6
1
H
2 HH k2 = R2 (k1 ; E)
HH
√ - k1
1−2 E
In t = 1, firm 1 takes into consideration firm 2’s discontinuous reaction function.
√ 1 1 1
If 1 − 2 E ≤ (⇒ E ≥ ), then firm 1 will choose monopoly output k1 = and
2 16 2
firm 2 will stay out. This is the case of entry blockaded.
1
Next, we consider the case E < . If firm 1 chooses monopoly output, firm 2 will
16 √
enter. Firm 1 is considering√ whether to choose k 1 ≥ 1 − 2 E to force firm 2 to give
up or to choose k1 < 1 − 2 E and maximizes duopoly profit. √
1. entry deterrence: If firm 2 stays out (k1 ≥ 1 − 2 E and k2 = 0), firm 1 is a
monopoly by deterrence:
√
π1d (E) = max√ k1 (1 − k1 ) = kE (1 − kE ), where kE ≡ 1 − 2 E.
k1 ≥1−2 E
√
2. entry accommodate: If firm 2 enters (k1 < 1 − 2 E and k2 > 0), firm 1 is the
leader of the Stackelberg game:
1 1 1 1
π1s (E) = max√ k1 (1−k1 −k2 ) = k1 (1−k1 ), ⇒ π1s = k s (1−k s ) = where k s ≡ .
k1 <1−2 E 2 2 8 2
π1d π1d 1 π d
1 1
6 E < 0.00536 60.00536 < E < 6 E>
r
16 r 16
1
r
π1s = π1s π1s
8
r r - k1 r r - k1 r r - k1
ks kE k s kE kE k s = k m
Entry accommodate Entry deterred Entry blockaded
√ √
p
1 (1 − 1/2)2
π1d (E) = (1 − 2 E)[1 − (1 − 2 E)] ≷ π1s (E) = if E ≷ ≈ 0.00536.
8 16
In summary, if E < 0.0536, firm 1 will accommodate firm 2’s entry; if 0.00536 < E <
1
, firm 1 will choose k1 = kE to deter firm 2; if E > F 116, firm 1 is a monopoly and
16
firm 2’s entry is blockaded.
70
0 if q1 ≤ k̄
MC1 = c
c if q1 > c
- q1
k̄
In t = 2, Firm 1’s FOC is 1 − 2q1 − q2 = MC1 . Its reaction function is
1 − q2
if q1 ≤ k̄ (1 − q2 )/2 if q2 ≥ 1 − 2k̄
q1 = R1 (q2 ) = 2 = k̄ if 1 − c − 2k̄ < q2 < 1 − 2k̄
1 − c − q2
if q1 > k̄
(1 − c − q2 )/2 if q2 < 1 − c − 2k̄.
2
1 − c − q1
Firm 2’s reaction function R2 (q1 ) = has nothing to do with k̄.
2
Firm 1’s reaction function is affected by k̄.
Therefore, the Cournot equilibrium in t = 2 is affected by k̄.
71
q2 q2
q1
16
@ R1 (q2 )
16
@ R1 (q2 )
6
1−c @ @
2 @ @ @
@ @ @
k̄ @ è™ú| ⇒ @ 1−c @
XXXr
@ 2 XX
@ XXXR2 (q1 )
@ @ @ XX
@ @ @
@ - q2 @ - q1 @ - q1
1 k̄ 1−c
k̄ 1−c
2 2
1−c (1 − c)2
(1) k̄ ≤ q c ≡ : q1 = q2 = q c , π1∗ = π c ≡ , i.e., Cournot equilibrium.
3 9
1+c 1 − c − k̄ 1 + c − k̄
(2) q c < k̄ < q̄ ≡ : q1 = k̄, q2 = , p= , π1 = (p − c)q1 =
3 2 2
(1 − c − k̄)k̄
.
2
1 − c − q̄ 1 + c − q̄ ∗ (1 − c − q̄)q̄
(3) q̄ ≤ k̄: q1 = q̄, q2 = ,p= , π1 = pq̄ − ck̄ = − c(k̄ −
2 2 2
q̄).
q2 q2 q2
16
@ R1 (q2 ) 16
@ R1 (q2 ) 16
@ R1 (q2 )
@ @ @
@ @ @
@ @
1−c @ @
@
@Xr X
1−c
XXrX
2 XXX XXX XXX @
r R2 (q1 )
1−c X 2 XXX@
3 @ XXR (q1 )
X2X
X R2 (q1 )
@ XXX
1−c−q̄ XX
@XX
2
@ @
@@ - q1 @ - q1 - q1
k̄ 1−c 1−c
k̄ 1−c q̄ k̄
3 2 2
π1 π1
6 6
@
1 1
c> 5
c< 5
@
@
@ @
@ @
@ @
- k̄ - k̄
qc q1s q̄ qc q̄ q1s
In Stackelberg model, firm 1 can choose any point on firm 2’s reaction curve R2 (q1 )
to maximize π1 . In Dixit model, firm 1’s choice is restricted to the section of R2 (q1 )
such that k̄ ∈ [0, q̄]. When q̄ ≥ q1s , the result is the same as Stackelberg model. When
q̄ < q1s , firm 1 can only choose k̄ = q̄.
In both cases q1 = k̄. Therefore, firm 1 does not over-invest (choose k̄ > q1 ) to
threaten firm 2’s entry.
t = −1, 0, 1, 2, 3, . . ..
In each period t, if only one firm has capital, the firm earns monopoly profit H.
If both firms have capital, each earns duopoly profit L.
Each firm can make investment in each period t by paying F .
Denote by Rti (Cti ) the profit (cost) of firm i in period t.
∞ 0 no capital
X
t i i i i 0 no invest (NI)
Πi = ρ (Rt − Ct ), Rt = L duopoly Ct =
F invest (INV).
H monopoly
t=0
Assumption 1: An investment can be used for 2 periods with no residual value left.
Assumption 2: 2L < F < H.p
Assumption 3: F/H < ρ < (F − L)/(H − L).
Firm i’s strategy in period t is ait ∈ {NI, INV}. Assume that a1−1 = INV. We
consider only Markov stationary equilibrium.
If firm 2 does not exist, firm 1 will choose to invest (INV) in t = 1, 3, 5, . . .. Given the
threat of firm 2’s possible entry, in a subgame-perfect equilibrium, firm 1 will invest
in every period and firm 2 will not invest forever.
The symmetrical SPE strategy is such that an incumbent firm invests and a potential
73
100 − pI pI ≤ p e k pe < pI
I e
q = q =
100 − k − pI pI > pe 0 pe ≥ pI
(100 − k)2
Firm 1 will accommodate firm 2 if πAI > πD I
, or if ≥ pe (100 − pe ), whence
4
π e = pe k > 0.
If firm 2 chooses a small k and a large enough pe , firm 1 will accommodate.
πI
6
πAI
I
πD pe (100 − pe )
-k
Accommodate -
74
(100 − k)2
max pe k subject to ≥ pe (100 − pe ).
4
Example: Suppose that firm 1 has a Chinese restaurant C and a Japanese restaurant
J in a small town, both are monopoly.
There are two consumers (assumed to be price takers), c and j.
β − PC β − λ − P C dine at C
c dine at C j
U = J U = β > λ > 0,
β−λ−P dine at J, β − PJ dine at J,
β is the utility of dinner and λ is the disutility if one goes to a less preferred restau-
rant.
Monopoly equilibrium: P C = P J = β, π1 = 2β.
Suppose now that firm 2 opens a Chinese restaurant in the same town.
1. If firm 1 does not close its Chinese restaurant, the equilibrium will be P C = 0,
P J = λ, π1 = λ, π2 = 0.
2. If firm 1 closes its Chinese restaurant, the equilibrium will be P C = β = P J ,
π1 = β = π 2 .
Contestable market: In certain industries entry does not require any sunk cost. In-
cumbent firms are constantly faced by threats of hit-and-run entry and hence behave
like competitive firms (making normal profits).
Comments: 1. If there are sunk costs, the conclusions would be reversed. See Stiglitz
(1987) discussed before.
2. If incumbents can respond to hit-and-run entries, they can still make some positive
profits.
Π1 = Π1 (K1 , x1 , x2 ), Π2 = Π2 (K1 , x1 , x2 ).
Π1 = Π1 (K1 , x∗1 (K1 ), x∗2 (K1 )), Π2 = Π2 (K1 , x∗1 (K1 ), x∗2 (K1 ),
∂Π1 ∂Π2
where x∗1 (K1 ) and x∗2 (K1 ) are the NE at t = 2, given K1 , = = 0.
dx1 dx2
top dog (»−, _5T‘): be big or strong to look tough or aggressive.
puppy dog ({ü, Qm‘): be small or weak to look soft or inoffensive.
lean and hungry look (_|Ï.ñ÷.§, ü−): be small or weak to look tough or
aggressive.
fat cat (]ý×j): be big or strong to look soft or inoffensive.
76
and underinvest in case of soft investment (lean and hungry look _|Ï.ñ÷.§
íšä, U entrant JÑÌ‚ªÇ).
2. Tough investment with positive R20 : “puppy dog” strategy, be small or weak to
look soft or inoffensive. Qm‘, .bK@ entrant Jnù–¬.
∂Π2 dx∗1
3. Soft investment > 0 with negative R20 : “lean and hungry look” strat-
∂x1 dK1
egy, be small or weak to look tough or aggressive. _|Ï.ñ÷.§íšäJH
U entrant =−.
4. Soft investment with positive R20 : “fat cat” strategy, be big or strong to look
soft or inoffensive. ]ý×jJî¸ entrant ı/.
top dog: ı%v9Ê,Þí%, Xº6.
puppy: AŠí*üä, IAnÀí/A.
fat cat: (\ö5) ½bí’ŒA, À3. ‹‘5×A. A)<ícA.
77
p = 5, q1 (c1 = 4) = 1, q2 = 4, π1 (c1 = 4) = 1, π2 = 16 − 9 = 7.
p
0
@
@ 1-p
1a
XX @1b
X XX
XXX
X X
X1X XX
p1 = p1 = 5 XXX p1 =X4XXX
X
7
A
1 1
2 2 X 2 X
A A A A A
E AN E AN E AN E AN E AN E AN
A A A A A A
0 0 34 46 0 0 38 50 0 0 37 49
10 18
0 0 6 14
0 0 1 9
0 0
7 0 −1.9 0 7 0 −1.9 0 7 0 −1.9 0
There is a separating equilbrium p11a = 4, p11b = 7 and firm 2 chooses not to en-
ter (N) if p11 = 4 and enter (E) if p11 ∈ {7, 5}.
For p > 7/8.9, there is also a pooling equilbrium p11a = p11b = 5 and firm 2 chooses
not to enter (N) if p11 ∈ {5, 4} and enter (E) if p11 = 7.
79
@
I2F I2A @ I2s @
F @ A
F @ A
F @ A
@ a−1 @ a @ 2a
@ −1 @ b @ 0
−2 −1 0 −1 0 0 a−1 a 0
−1 −1 b b 0 0
−1 b −1 b −1 b
2-period game
Paradox: When T is large, the incumbent is tempered to fight to try to deter entry.
The SPNE above is counterintuitive.
p0 p0
P rob[“tough”|F ] = = q̄ ⇒ β = .
p0 + β(1 − p0 ) (1 − p0 )b
p0 + (1 − p0 )β = p0 (b + 1)/b.
T > 3: Entrants will stay out until t = k such that p0 < p̄k .
When δ = 1: (a) q 0 < a/(1 + a), I will accommodate at first entry and reveal
its type. Hence, limT →∞ π/T = 0.
(b) q 0 > a/(1 + a), there exists an n(p0 ) such that I will fight until there are no more
than n(p0 ) entrants remaining. Hence, limT →∞ π/T = (1 − q 0 )a − q 0 .
81
NØ 23%, lœ 18%, Úä 10%, »“ 9%, ë¹, ˘“, ˆ, ]E, ×- < 1%
Production and cost functions are black boxes created by economists. Investigat-
ing R&D processes helps us to open the boxes.
The distinction is not essential. A process innovation can be treated as the creation
of new intermediate products that reduce the production costs. On the other hand,
a product innovation can be regarded as an innovation that reduces the production
cost of a product from infinity to a finite value.
P P
6 6
@ @
@r
@ @
@ r Pm (c)
P0 = c 0 @ @
@ @
c @ c @
@ @
@ @
@ -Q @ -Q
Q0 Qm
82
2 Cases:
a+c
Drastic innovation (large or major innovation): If Pm (c) ≡ < c0 = P0 , then
2
the innovator will become a monopoly.
a+c
Non-drastic innovation (small or minor innovation): If Pm (c) ≡ > c0 = P0 ,
2
then the innovator cannot charge monopoly price and has to set P = c0 − .
P P
6 6
c0 @r
@ Drastic innovation @ Non-drastic innovation
r @r
@
@
@ r
P = Pm (c) @
Pm (c)
π @ P = c0
@
π @@
c c
@ @
@ @
@ -Q @ -Q
Qm Q
A drastic innovation will reduce the market price. A non-drastic innovation will not
change the Bertrand equilibrium price. In both cases the innovator makes positive
profits.
Assumptions:
4. The probability of firm i innovating the product is α. The events of firms being
successful is independent.
5. If only one firm successes, the firm gains $ V. If both success, each gains 0.5 V.
If a firm fails, it gains 0.
6. The entry is sequential. Firm 1 decides first and then firm 2 makes decision.
1 firm I α(2 − α)
Eπ2 (2) = 0 or =
V 2
2 firms
-α
I/V I/V
6
I 6
Eπ s (1) = 0 or =α
V
(I)
1 firm
(II)
s s I
2 firms Eπ (1) = Eπ (2) or = α(1 − α) (III)
-α V -α
(I): Social optimal is 1 firm, the same as market equilibrium number of firms.
(II): Social optimal is 1 firm, market equilibrium has 2 firms.
(III): Social optimal is 2 firms, the same as market equilibrium number of firms.
∞
2
X 1
ET (2) = α(2−α)+(1−α) α(2−α)2+. . . = α(2−α) (1−α)2(t−1) t = < ET (1).
t=0
α(2 − α)
(100 − 2ci + cj )2
Πi (ci , cj ) = − TCi (xi ).
9
Substituting the unit cost functions, we obtain the reduced profit function of t = 1:
[50 + (1 + β)x]2 x2
Πi = Πj = Π(x) = − .
9 2
Then they decide the level of x to maximize Π(x). FOC is
1. Πc > Πnc .
When β > 0.5, consumers will be better off to allow R&D cooperation; social welfare
will definitely increase. When β < 0.5, consumers will be worse off to allow R&D
cooperation; but the social welfare also depends on the change in firms’ profits.
9.4 Patents
êp5òQgM: “¨Þß6‚⣾‘6”ì
êp5ÈQgM: óêhêp, ªœ.q©¾
ù‚: þ}#êpð5Ñ{, àJ2¥“h
ù‚¨AÖ´, Ou³ù‚„†³—DÓÄV2¥êp
Êù‚„|Û5‡, êpðÉ?à\òíj¶V\ˆAÐí‚ 9õ,, ÛHíêpð?
à\òíj¶V¦)ªù‚yÅíÖ´‚â
Wà, Stradivarius Violin, Coca Cola
da Vinci †Ñ_AE7êp
ù‚Å: 1Å 17 , r¹ 20 , «É 20
Dù‚Å.° bçt.?C~ù‚, Oª\ò Ú7,ñ˘k
½æ: ù‚ÅbÖýn?Ê2¥“hDÖ´’Ä…5Ȧ)|_~¬?
Innovator’s problem:
T
X 1 − ρT 1 − ρT x2
max π(x : T ) = ρt−1 M (x)−TC(x) = M (x)−TC(x) = (a−c)x− .
x
t=1
1−ρ 1−ρ 2
1 − ρT 1 − ρT
FOC: (a − c) − x ⇒ x = (a − c).
1−ρ 1−ρ
∂x ∂x ∂x ∂x
Comparative statics: > 0, > 0, < 0, > 0.
∂T ∂a ∂c ∂ρ
Social optimal duration of patents:
" T # " ∞ #
X X x2 (a − c)x 1 − ρT x2
W (T ) = ρt−1 M (x) + ρt−1 DL(x) − = − .
t=1 t=T +1
2 1 − ρ 1 − ρ 2
(a − c)x 1 − ρ2 x2 1 − ρT
max − subject to x= (a − c).
x,T 1−ρ 1−ρ 2 1−ρ
Eliminating x:
2 2
(a − c) 1 − ρT 1 − ρ2 1 1 − ρT (1 − ρT )3
a−c T
max (a−c)− (a − c) = 1−ρ − .
T 1−ρ 1−ρ 1−ρ 2 1−ρ 1−ρ 2(1 − ρ)
ln(1 − z)
Make change of variable z ≡ 1 − ρT , or T = . The problem becomes
ln ρ
z3 3z 2 p
max z − FOC: 1 − = 0, ⇒ z ∗ = 2(1 − ρ)/3
z 2(1 − ρ) 2(1 − ρ)
p
ln(1 − 2(1 − ρ)/3)
⇒ T∗ = .
ln ρ
C. Chou and O. Shy (1991) “Optimal duration of patents,” Southern Economic Jour-
nal: If R&D has DRTS, optimal duration of patents may be finite. There are also
many nonsymmetrical factors, eg., some products are competitively priced, demand
elasticities are different, etc.
88
a − c + 2x a−c−x a + 2c − x
q1 = , q2 = , P = ,
3 3 3
(a − c + 2x)2 (a − c − x)2
π1 = , π2 = π̄2 = .
9 9
E(Ti ) = [h(xi )]−1 , h(xi ) > 0, h0 (xi ) > 0, h00 (xi ) < 0.
Prob{T̂ > T } = Prob{T1 > T, T2 > T } = e−h(x1 )T e−h(x2 )T = e−[h(x1 )+h(x2 )]T .
h(x1 )
Firm 1’s winning probability: Prob[T1 = T, T2 > T |T̂ = T ] = :
h(x1 ) + h(x2 )
T2
6
A {T̂ ∈ (T, T + dt)} = A ∪ B ∪ C
T +dt A = {T1 ∈ (T, T + dt), T2 ≥ T + dt}
C B
T B = {T2 ∈ (T, T + dt), T1 ≥ T + dt}
C = {T1 , T2 ∈ (T, T + dt)}, Prob[C] ≈ 0.
- T1
T T +dt
[2h(x)+r][h0 (x)V −r]−[h(x)V −rx]h0 (x) = h(x)h0 (x)V +rh0 (x)(x+V )−2rh(x)−r 2 = 0.
Therefore, the equilibrium R&D level is greater than the social optimal level.
Comparing the payoff functions reveals that firm 2’s payoff function is essentially the
same as that of the basic model. Further comparison between firm 1 and firm 2’s
payoff functions reveals that firm 1’s incentives are different in two ways:
Efficiency effect: Πm (c) − Πd1 (c̄, c) ≥ Πd2 (c̄, c), firm 1 has more incentives to win
the race. and therefore x1 tends to be greater than x2 in this aspect.
The net effect depends on which one dominates. Following are two extreme cases:
Drastic innovation: Πd1 (c̄, c) = 0 and Πd2 (c̄, c) = Πm (c). No efficiency effect and
x1 < x 2 .
10.0.3 3 concepts
1. Compatibility (1ñ4): .°ÉKªJ²Uà (øu°™Ä)
Standardization (™Ä“): FÉK·ªJ²Uà
ª1ñß¹5W: ßà ¯
.ª1ñß¹5W: ÎóœœñDŸå ¯
<8”, ª1ñß¹$Aø__üÕÈ, ÕÈqѵI:_¼
VHS vs β, òœ, CD player, DVD, MO, etc.
ASCII Ñ 7-bit ™Ä“å{
Extended ASCII Ñ 8-bit ³™Ä“å{ (rÖ.°™Ä)
94
A\B α β
α (a, b) (c, d)
β (d, c) (b, a)
1. If a, b > max{c, d} (battle of the sexes), then (α, α) and (β, β) are both NE. They
choose the same standard (™Ä“).
2. If c, d > max{a, b}, then (α, β) and (β, α) are both NE. They choose the dif-
ferent standards (®Wwu).
1
p If 0 < p < , then there are two
6 4
possible marginal consumers,
√
U x̂<0 U x̂<0 1 ± 1 − 4p
2 x̂ ↓ x̂ ↓ x̂ = . The smaller is
2
9 2
U x̂>0 unstable. The diagram uses p =
9
b - b
x̂ ↑
- x to illustrate.
0 1/3 2/3 1
The phone company maximizes its profits:
2 2
max px̂ = x̂2 (1 − x̂), FOC: 2x̂ − x̂2 = 0, ⇒ x̂∗ = , p∗ = .
x̂ 3 9
rstable
f (nt )
r
unstable
◦
45 - nt
n∗∗ n∗
96
0 prefer A a prefer B 1
2 brands/standards, A (à¬G) and B (à˝G).
a > 0 consumers prefer A-standard.
b = 1 − a > 0 consumers prefer B-standard.
xA : number of consumers using A-standard.
xB : number of consumers using B-standard.
δ: the disutility of using a less prefered standard.
A xA use A-standard B xA − δ use A-standard
U = U =
xB − δ use B-standard, xB use B-standard.
Consumer distribution: (xA , xB ) such that xA , xB ≥ 0 and xA + xB = 1.
A-standard distribution: A distribution such that (xA , xB ) = (1, 0).
B-standard distribution: A distribution such that (xA , xB ) = (0, 1).
Incompatible AB-standards distribution A distribution with xA , xB > 0.
Equilibrium: (xA , xB ) such that none wants to switch to a different brand/standard.
Proposition 10.3: If δ < 1, then both A-standard and B-standard are equilibrium. If
δ > 1, then both A-standard and B-standard are not equilibrium.
Proof: If δ > 1 and every one chooses the same brand (either A or B), then none
wants to switch to a different brand. If δ < 1, then the cost of switching to a preferred
brand is less than the benefit and therefore a single standard equilibrium cannot exist.
1−δ
Proposition 10.4: If a, b > , then (xA , xB ) = (a, b) is an equilibrium.
2
Proof: Given the distribution (xA , xB ) = (a, b), the utility levels are
A a use A br. B a − δ = 1 − b − δ < b use A br.
U = U =
b − δ = 1 − a − δ < a use B br. b use B br.
Therefore, none will switch to a different brand.
b
6
@
1−δ r
@
@ 2-standard equilibrium
@
@
@ range
@
1−δ @
@
@
2 @
r
@
@ -a
1−δ
2
1−δ
97
Remark: When a > b and δ < 1, the social optimal is A-standard. However, both
the incompatible standards and B-standard can also be equilibrium.
In the basic model, A-computers and B-computers are incompatible in the sence
that A-computers use only A-software and B-computers use only B-software. The
model can be generalized to the case when computer firms design their machines in
such a way that some fraction of B-software can be used in A-machines and vice
versa.
Let ρA (ρB ) be the proportion of B-software (A-software) that can be run on A-
computers (B-computers).
Incompatibility: ρA = ρB = 0.
Mutual compatibility: ρA = ρB = 1.
One-way compatibility: ρA = 1, ρB = 0 or ρA = 0, ρB = 1.
(1 − ρA ρB )δA EA (1 − ρA ρB )δB EB
⇒ NA = , NB = . (6)
k(1 − ρB ) k(1 − ρA )
As in the basic model,
√
v !
u
1 − δ̂ NB u 1 − δ̂ (1 − ρB )EB
= √ =t ,
δ̂ NA δ̂ (1 − ρA )EA
1 − δ̂ (1 − ρB )EB (1 − ρB )(Y − PB )
⇒ = = .
δ̂ (1 − ρA )EA (1 − ρA )(Y − PA )
Other things being equal, if firm A increases the degree of compatibility ρA , the
number of software pieces run on A-computers will decrease and hence its market
share δA = δ̂ will also decrease.
100
AS4 3 consumers: AA, AB, BB. You need an X and a Y to form a system S.
2 situations:
1. Incompatibility: A and B’s products are not compatible. You have to buy XA YA
or XB YB .
2. Compatibility: A and B’s products are compatible. There are 4 possible systems:
XA YA , XA YB , XB YA , and XB YB .
10.3.1 Incompatibility
There are only 2 systems: A-system (XA YA ) and B-system (XB YB ).
PA = PAx + PAy , PB = PBx + PBy : Price of system A and system B, respectively.
1. (PAI , PBI ; qAI , qBI ) = (λ, 2λ; 2, 1). AA and AB purchase A-system and BB pur-
chases B-system, ΠA = ΠB = 2λ, CS = λ, social welfare is 5λ.
101
2. (PAI , PBI ; qAI , qBI ) = (2λ, λ; 1, 2). AA purchases A-system and BB and AB pur-
chase B-system. ΠA = ΠB = 2λ, CS = λ, social welfare is 5λ.
3. (PAI , PBI ; qAI , qBI ) = (2λ, 2λ; 1, 1). AA purchases A-system and BB purchases B-
system. AB chooses to do without. ΠA = ΠB = 2λ, CS = 0, social welfare is
4λ.
10.3.2 Compatibility
4 systems: AA-system (XA YA ), AB-system (XA YB ), BA-system (XB YA ), and BB-
system (XB YB ).
c c c c c c c c
Equilibrium: (PAx , PAy , PBx , PBy ; qAx , qAy , qBx , qBy ) such that
c c c c
1. (Pix , Piy ) maximizes Πi (Pix , Piy ; Pjx , Pjy ).
c c c c c c c c
2. (qAx , qAy , qBx , qBy ) are the aggregate demand of the consumers at price (PAx , PAy , PBx , PBy ).
c c c c
Proposition 10.14. There exists an equilibrium such that PAx = PAy = PBx = PBy =
c c c c c c AA AB BB
λ, qAx = qBy = 2, qAy = qBx = 1, ΠA = ΠB = 3λ, U = U =U = 0, and social
welfare is 6λ.
10.3.3 Comparison
1. Consumers are worse off under compatibility.
11 Advertising
Advertising is defined as a form of providing information about prices, quality, and
location of goods and services.
2% of GNP in developed countries.
vegetables, etc., < 2% of sales.
cosmetics, detergent, etc., 20-60 % of sales.
In 1990, GM spent $63 per car, Ford $130 per car, Chrysler $113 per car.
Nelson:
Search goods: Quality can be identified when purchasing. ⇒ .Ûµ
Experience goods: Quality cannot be identified until consuming. ⇒ µª àÛb
√ √ √
Q = 64 AP −2 , P = 8A1/4 Q−1/2 , ⇒ P m = 2, Qm = 16 A, Am = 64, Π = 16 A,
√ √
Z 16 A Z 16 A √ √
⇒ CS(A) = P (Q)dQ − P m Qm = 8A1/4 Q−1/2 dQ − 32 A = 32 A.
0 0
√
Social welfare: W (A) ≡ CS(A) + Π(A) − A = 48 A − A.
24
Social optimal: W 0 (A) = 0 = √ − 1, ⇒ A = 242 = 576 > Am = 64.
A
Remark: 1. Does CS(A) represent consumers’ welfare? If it is informative adver-
tising, consumers’ utility may increase when A increases. However, if consumers’ are
just persuased to make unnecessary purchases, the demand curve does not really re-
flect consumers’ marginal utility.
2. Crowding-out effect: Consumption for other goods will decrease.
3. A can be interpreted as other utility enhancing factors.
Consumers often rely on information for their purchases. The problem is whether
there is too little or too much informative advertising.
If p/A > 1/δ, ⇒ π(1) > 0, ⇒ at least one firm will choose to advertise.
If p/A > 2/[δ(2 − δ)], ⇒ π(2) > 0, ⇒ both firms will choose to advertise.
p/A
6
π(2) > 0,
2 firms in equilibrium.
1
fir
m
2/[δ(2 − δ)]
π(1) < 0, 0 firm q 1/δ
-
δ
1
Welfare comparison:
δ(2 − δ)m − 2A ≡ W (2) if 2 firms advertise.
EW = δm − A ≡ W (1) if only one firm advertises.
0 if no firm advertises.
m 1
If > , ⇒ W (1) > 0, ⇒ social optimal is at least one firm advertises.
A δ
m 1
If > , ⇒ W (2) > W (1), ⇒ social optimal is both firms advertise.
A δ(1 − δ)
105
market failure
W (1) > 0
q - q -
W (1) < 0
δ δ
1 1
µxXTòU δ Ó‹ When δ → 1, one firm would be enough. However, if m/A > 1,
both firms will advertise.
AS2: Informative advertising attracts only the experienced consumers who are ori-
ented toward the advertised brand, i.e., if firm 1 (firm 2) chooses I, θE ((1−θ)E)
experienced consumers will purchase brand 1 (brand 2).
firm 1 \ firm 2 P I
P (N/2, N/2) (N, (1 − θ)E)
I (θE, N ) (θE, (1 − θ)E)
106
θ
N/E
16@
H
@ H N/2E
@ H (I, P )
@ HH
@ H
(I, I) (I,P
@ HH (P, P )
)&(P,I)
@ H
HH
@ HH
(P, I) HH1 − N/2E
1 − N/E@ HH- N/E
1 2
Negative points:
1. Lack of objectivity.
2. Deception and consumer confusion due to information overload.
Telser (1964) “Advertising and Competition,” JPE. Very little empirical support for
an inverse relationship between advertising and competition.
ad
6
- concentration ratio
if Q ≤ Q∗
cH Q a1 − Q if advertising
Cost: TC(Q) = Demand: P =
cL Q if Q > Q∗ , a0 − Q if not advertising.
12 Quality
12.1 Vertical Differentiation in Hotelling Model
Quality is a vertical differentiation character.
2-period game:
At t = 1, firms A and B choose the quality levels, 0 ≤ a < b ≤ 1, for their products.
At t = 2, they engage in price competition.
The marginal consumer x̂ is indifferent between buying from A and from B. The
location of x̂ is determined by
PB − P A
ax̂ − PA = bx̂ − PB ⇒ x̂ = . (7)
b−a
The location of x̂ divids the market into two parts: [0, x̂) is firm A’s market share
and (x̂, 1] is firm B’s market share.
r̂
A’s share - B’s share -
0 x 1
Assume that the marginal costs are zero. The payoff functions are
PB − P A PB − P A
ΠA (PA , PB ; a, b) = PA x̂ = PA , ΠB (PA , PB ; a, b) = PB (1−x̂) = PB 1 − .
b−a b−a
Both profit functions increase with b − a. Moving away from each other will increase
both firm’s profits. The two firms will end up with maximum product differentiation
a = 0 and b = 1 in equilibrium.
Modifications: 1. High quality products are associated with high unit production
cost.
2. Consumer distribution is not uniform.
The high-quality monopolist has to reduce its quantity to convince consumers that
the quality is high.
If the information is perfect, he does not have to reduce quantity.
The quantity reduction is needed for signalling purpose.
Grossman (1980), “The Role of Warranties and Private Disclosure about Product
Quality,” Journal of Law and Economics.
A comprehensive analysis of a monopoly that can offer a warranty for its product.
111
13 Pricing Tactics
13.1 Two-Part Tariff
Oi (1971), “A Disneyland Dilemma: Two-Part Tariffs for a Mickey Mouse,” QJE.
In addition to the per unit price, a monopoly firm (amusement parks Y—Ò, sports
clubs U™E—¶) can set a second pricing instrument (membership dues ‘) in order
to be able to extract more consumer surplus.
√
max Πa (φ) = φ subject to I − φ + 2 K > I = I0 ,
φ
√
⇒ φ∗ = 2 K = Π a > Π m .
Using annual membership dues, the monopoly extracts all the consumer surplus,
like the 1st degree price discrimination.
m m
6 6
I raa Ir
66 aa 6
Πm
? aar
aa φ3
ra
φ ∗ aa
aa U1 ? U1
ara
a am − φ3 + P4 (Q − Q3 ) = I
r
m + Pm Q = I
? aa
a aa U4
U-0 aa U-0
a
Q Q
K Q3 Q4 = K
113
Therefore, the monopoly offers a “package” of Q3 < K and annual fee φ3 < φ∗ .
In addition, the monopoly offers an option to purchase additional quantity for a price
P4 .
FOC:
MRH (QH ) = c + r, MRL (QL ) = c, QL < QH = K.
AH + c + r AL + c
⇒ PH = > PL = .
2 2
Regulation for efficiency: P H = c + r > P L = c.
r
n-period case: MRH (QH ) = c + , MRL (QL ) = c.
n
Modification: Substitutability between high- and low-seasonal demand.
114
Tying: Firms offer for sale packages containing at least two different (usually com-
plementary) products.
Examples: Car and car radio, PC and software, Book and T-shirt.
The monopoly in this case uses bundling tactics to extract all the consumer surplus.
2 computer firms, X and Y, and a monitor firm Z (compatible with X and Y).
2 consumers i = 1, 2 with utility functions
3 − Px − Pz buys X and Z 1 − Px − Pz buys X and Z
U1 = 1 − Py − Pz buys Y and Z U2 = 3 − Py − Pz buys Y and Z
0 buys nothing, 0 otherwise,
Assume that firm X buys firm Z and sells X and Z tied in a single package.
-foreclosure equilibrium:
Pxz = 3 − , Qxz = 2, Py = , Qy = 1, Πxz = 2(3 − ), Πy = .
Consumer 2 buys one X&Z and one Y and discards X.
116
where Pks (Pkns ) are the price with service (without service) in country k, k = 1, 2,
and σ > 0 is the additional value due to service.
AS1 B1 > B2 .