What Is Privatization
What Is Privatization
The term "privatization" also has been used to describe two unrelated transactions.
The first is a buyout, by the majority owner, of all shares of a public corporation or holding
company's stock, privatizing a publicly traded stock, and often described as private equity.
The second is a demutualization of a mutual organization or cooperative to form a joint stock
company.
Supporting
Proponents[who?] of privatization believe that private market factors can more
efficiently deliver many goods or service than governments due to free market competition.
In general, it is argued that over time this will lead to lower prices, improved quality, more
choices, less corruption, less red tape, and quicker delivery. Many proponents do not argue
that everything should be privatized. According to them, market failures and natural
monopolies could be problematic. However, some Austrian school economists[who?] and
anarcho-capitalists[who?] would prefer that every function of the state be privatized,
including defense and dispute resolution.
The basic economic argument given for privatization states that governments have
few incentives to ensure that the enterprises they own are well run. One problem is the lack of
comparison in state monopolies. It is difficult to know if an enterprise is efficient or not
without competitors to compare against. Another is that the central government
administration, and the voters who elect them, have difficulty evaluating the efficiency of
numerous and very different enterprises. A private owner, often specializing and gaining
great knowledge about a certain industrial sector, can evaluate and then reward or punish the
management in much fewer enterprises much more efficiently. Also, governments can raise
money by taxation or simply printing money should revenues be insufficient, unlike a private
owner.
If private and state-owned enterprises compete against each other, then the state
owned may borrow money more cheaply from the debt markets than private enterprises, since
the state owned enterprises are ultimately backed by the taxation and printing press power of
the state, gaining an unfair advantage.
Increased efficiency-----
Private companies and firms have a greater incentive to produce more goods and services for
the sake of reaching a customer base and hence increasing profits. A public organization
would not be as productive due to the lack of financing allocated by the entire government's
budget that must consider other areas of the economy. (Note: However according to the
Samuelson Condition, public organizations tend to produce more of a public good or service.
Also, since private firms provide goods and services according to the marginal private benefit
curve, private firms have an incentive to produce less.)
Specialization----
A private business has the ability to focus all relevant human and financial resources onto
specific functions. A state-owned firm does not have the necessary resources to specialize its
goods and services as a result of the general products provided to the greatest number of
people in the population.
Improvements----
Conversely, the government may put off improvements due to political sensitivity and special
interests — even in cases of companies that are run well and better serve their customers'
needs.
Corruption-----
Accountability-----
Civil-liberty concerns-----
A company controlled by the state may have access to information or assets which may be
used against dissidents or any individuals who disagree with their policies.
Goals.-----
A political government tends to run an industry or company for political goals rather than
economic ones.
Capital-----
Privately held companies can sometimes more easily raise investment capital in the financial
markets when such local markets exist and are suitably liquid. While interest rates for private
companies are often higher than for government debt, this can serve as a useful constraint to
promote efficient investments by private companies, instead of cross-subsidizing them with
the overall credit-risk of the country. Investment decisions are then governed by market
interest rates. State-owned industries have to compete with demands from other government
departments and special interests. In either case, for smaller markets, political risk may add
substantially to the cost of capital.
Security-----
Governments have had the tendency to "bail out" poorly run businesses, often due to the
sensitivity of job losses, when economically, it may be better to let the business fold.
Poorly managed state companies are insulated from the same discipline as private companies,
which could go bankrupt, have their management removed, or be taken over by competitors.
Private companies are also able to take greater risks and then seek bankruptcy protection
against creditors if those risks turn sour.
Natural monopolies-----
The existence of natural monopolies does not mean that these sectors must be state owned.
Governments can enact or are armed with anti-trust legislation and bodies to deal with anti-
competitive behavior of all companies public or private.
Concentration of wealth-----
Ownership of and profits from successful enterprises tend to be dispersed and diversified
-particularly in voucher privatization. The availability of more investment vehicles stimulates
capital markets and promotes liquidity and job creation.
Political influence-----
Nationalized industries are prone to interference from politicians for political or populist
reasons. Examples include making an industry buy supplies from local producers (when that
may be more expensive than buying from abroad), forcing an industry to freeze its
prices/fares to satisfy the electorate or control inflation, increasing its staffing to reduce
unemployment, or moving its operations to marginal constituencies.
Profits-----
Corporations exist to generate profits for their shareholders. Private companies make a profit
by enticing consumers to buy their products in preference to their competitors' (or by
increasing primary demand for their products, or by reducing costs). Private corporations
typically profit more if they serve the needs of their clients well. Corporations of different
sizes may target different market niches in order to focus on marginal groups and satisfy their
demand. A company with good corporate governance will therefore be incentivized to meet
the needs of its customers efficiently.
Job gains-----
As the economy becomes more efficient, more profits are obtained and no government
subsidies and less taxes are needed, there will be more private money available for
investments and consumption and more profitable and better-paid jobs will be created than in
the case of a more regulated economy.[8][unreliable source?]
Opposing
Opponents of privatization[who?] dispute the claims concerning the alleged lack of incentive
for governments to ensure that their public services are well run, on the basis of the idea that
governments are proxy owners answerable to the people. It is argued[by whom?] that a
government which runs nationalized enterprises poorly will lose public support and votes,
while a government which runs those enterprises well will gain public support and votes.
Thus, democratic governments do have an incentive to maximize efficiency in nationalized
companies, due to the pressure of future elections.
Opponents of certain privatizations believe that certain public goods and services should
remain primarily in the hands of government in order to ensure that everyone in society has
access to them (such as law enforcement, basic health care, and basic education). Likewise,
private goods and services should remain in the hands of the private sector. There is a
positive externality when the government provides public goods and services to society at
large, such as defense and disease control. As for natural monopolies they are by their nature
not subject to fair competition and better administrated by the state.
The controlling ethical issue in the anti-privatization perspective is the need for responsible
stewardship of social-support missions. Market interactions are all guided by self-interest,
and successful actors in a healthy market must be committed to charging the maximum price
that the market will bear. Privatization opponents believe that this model is not compatible
with government missions for social support, whose primary aim is delivering affordability
and quality of service to society.
Many privatization opponents[who?] also warn against the practice's inherent tendency
toward corruption. As many areas which the government could provide are essentially
profitless, the only way private companies could, to any degree, operate them would be
through contracts or block payments. In these cases, the private firm's performance in a
particular project would be removed from their performance, and embezzlement and
dangerous cost-cutting measures might be taken to maximize profits.
Some[who?] would also point out that privatizing certain functions of government might
hamper coordination, and charge firms with specialized and limited capabilities to perform
functions which they are not suited for. In rebuilding a war torn nation's infrastructure, for
example, a private firm would, in order to provide security, either have to hire security, which
would be both necessarily limited and complicate their functions, or coordinate with
government, which, due to a lack of command structure shared between firm and
government, might be difficult. A government agency, on the other hand, would have the
entire military of a nation to draw upon for security, whose chain of command is clearly
defined. Opponents would say that this is a false assertion: numerous books refer to poor
organization between government departments (for example the Hurricane Katrina incident).
Although private companies will provide a similar good or service alongside the government,
opponents of privatization are careful about completely transferring the provision of public
goods, services and assets into private hands for the following reasons:
Corruption. Government ministers and civil servants are bound to uphold the highest ethical
standards, and standards of probity are guaranteed through codes of conduct and declarations
of interest. However, the selling process could lack transparency, allowing the purchaser and
civil servants controlling the sale to gain personally.
Accountability. The public does not have any control or oversight of private companies.
Goals. The government may seek to use state companies as instruments to further social goals
for the benefit of the nation as a whole.
Capital. Governments can raise money in the financial markets most cheaply to re-lend to
state-owned enterprises.
Strategic and Sensitive areas. Governments have chosen to keep certain companies/industries
under public control because of their strategic importance or sensitive nature.
Natural monopolies. Privatization will not result in true competition if a natural monopoly
exists.
Concentration of wealth. Profits from successful enterprises end up in private, often foreign,
hands instead of being available for the common good.
Political influence. Governments may more easily exert pressure on state-owned firms to help
implementing government policy.
Downsizing. Private companies often face a conflict between profitability and service levels,
and could over-react to short-term events. A state-owned company might have a longer-term
view, and thus be less likely to cut back on maintenance or staff costs, training etc., to stem
short term losses. Many private companies have downsized while making record profits.
Profit. Private companies do not have any goal other than to maximize profits. A private
company will serve the needs of those who are most willing (and able) to pay, as opposed to
the needs of the majority, and are thus anti-democratic. The more necessary a good is, the
lower the price elasticity of demand, as people will attempt to buy it no matter the price. In
the case of price elasticity of demand is zero (perfectly inelastic good), demand part of supply
and demand theories does not work.
Privatization and Poverty. It is acknowledged by many studies that there are winners and
losers with privatization. The number of losers —which may add up to the size and severity
of poverty—can be unexpectedly large if the method and process of privatization and how it
is implemented are seriously flawed (e.g. lack of transparency leading to state-owned assets
being appropriated at minuscule amounts by those with political connections, absence of
regulatory institutions leading to transfer of monopoly rents from public to private sector,
improper design and inadequate control of the privatization process leading to asset stripping.
[9]
Job Loss. Due to the additional financial burden placed on privatized companies to succeed
without any government help, unlike the public companies, jobs could be lost to keep more
money in the company.
[edit] Intermediate viewsOthers don't dispute that well-run for-profit entities with sound
corporate governance may be considerably more efficient than an inefficient governmental
bureaucracy or NGO, however many implementations of privatization can - in practice - lead
to the fire sale of public assets, and/or to inefficient or corrupt - for profit management.
[edit] Developed or minimally corrupt economiesA top executive can readily reduce the
perceived value of an asset – due to information asymmetry. The executive can accelerate
accounting of expected expenses, delay accounting of expected revenue, engage in off
balance sheet transactions to make the company's profitability appear temporarily poorer, or
simply promote and report severely conservative (e.g. pessimistic) estimates of future
earnings. Such seemingly adverse earnings news will be likely to (at least temporarily) reduce
sale price. (This is again due to information asymmetries since it is more common for top
executives to do everything they can to window dress their earnings forecasts). There are
typically very few legal risks to being 'too conservative' in one's accounting and earnings
estimates.
When the entity gets taken private - at a dramatically lower price - the new private owner
gains a windfall from the former top executive's actions to (surreptitiously) reduce the sales
price. This can represent 10s of billions of dollars (questionably) transferred from previous
owners (the public) to the takeover artist. The former top executive is then rewarded with a
golden handshake for presiding over the fire sale that can sometimes be in the 10s or 100s of
millions of dollars for one or two years of work. (This is nevertheless an excellent bargain for
the takeover artist, who will tend to benefit from developing a reputation of being very
generous to parting top executives).
When a publicly held asset, mutual or non-profit organization undergoes privatization, top
executives often reap tremendous monetary benefits. The executives can facilitate the process
by making the entity appear to be in financial crisis - this reduces the sale price (to the profit
of the purchaser), and makes non-profits and governments more likely to sell.
Ironically, it can also contribute to a public perception that private entities are more
efficiently run reinforcing the political will to sell of public assets. Again, due to asymmetric
information, policy makers and the general public see a government owned firm that was a
financial 'disaster' - miraculously turned around by the private sector (and typically resold)
within a few years.
Of course, corrupt governments can also extract corrupt rents quite efficiently in other ways -
particularly by borrowing extensively to engage in spending on overly favorable contracts
with their backers (or on tax shelters, subsidies or other giveaways). Generations of
subsequent taxpayers are then left with paying back the debt incurred for corrupt transfers
made decades previously. Naturally, this may lead to the sale of public assets....
In the end, the public is left with a government that taxes them heavily, and gives them
nothing in return. Debt repayment is enforced by international agreements and agencies such
as the IMF. Infrastructure and upkeep is sacrificed - leading to a further decay in the
economic efficiency of the country over time.
[edit] Outcomes This article has multiple issues. Please help improve it or discuss these
issues on the talk page.
Literature reviews [10][11] find that in competitive industries with well-informed consumers,
privatization consistently improves efficiency. Such efficiency gains mean a one-off increase
in GDP, but through improved incentives to innovate and reduce costs also tend to raise the
rate of economic growth. The type of industries to which this generally applies include
manufacturing and retailing. Although typically there are social costs associated with these
efficiency gains[12], many economists argue that these can be dealt with by appropriate
government support through redistribution and perhaps retraining.
In sectors that are natural monopolies or public services (such as, say, passenger rail in the
United States), the results of privatization are much more mixed, as a private monopoly
behaves much the same as a public one in liberal economic theory. The government is
actually seen as a more natural provider of public goods and services. However, the
efficiency of an existing public sector operation can be put into question requiring changes to
be made. Changes may include, inter alia, the imposition of related reforms such as greater
transparency and accountability of management, an improved cost-benefit analysis, improved
internal controls, regulatory systems, and better financing, rather than privatization itself.
Regarding political corruption, it is a controversial issue whether the size of the public sector
per se results in corruption. The Nordic countries have low corruption but large public
sectors. However, these countries score high on the Ease of Doing Business Index, due to
good and often simple regulations, and for political rights and civil liberties, showing high
government accountability and transparency. One should also notice the successful,
corruption-free privatizations and restructuring of government enterprises in the Nordic
countries. For example, dismantling telecommunications monopolies has resulted in several
new players entering the market and intense competition with price and service.
Also regarding corruption, the sales themselves give a large opportunity for grand corruption.
Privatizations in Russia and Latin America were accompanied by large-scale corruption
during the sale of the state-owned companies. Those with political connections unfairly
gained large wealth, which has discredited privatization in these regions. While media have
reported widely the grand corruption that accompanied the sales, studies have argued that in
addition to increased operating efficiency, daily petty corruption is, or would be, larger
without privatization, and that corruption is more prevalent in non-privatized sectors.
Furthermore, there is evidence to suggest that extralegal and unofficial activities are more
prevalent in countries that privatized less.