The Competitive Issues in Credit Card Markets: July 2020
The Competitive Issues in Credit Card Markets: July 2020
net/publication/342763666
CITATIONS READS
0 384
1 author:
Hongru Tan
Sichuan University
8 PUBLICATIONS 14 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
All content following this page was uploaded by Hongru Tan on 13 July 2020.
Hongru Tan†
Abstract
This paper considers competitive issues raised in credit card markets. Among others, the
issues are mainly regarding to welfare effects of no surcharge rule (NSR) clauses or more general
non-discriminatory provisions (NDPs), and the regulation of interchange or merchant fees. This
paper develops a theory of platform competition tailored to credit card markets, and finds
abundant meaningful results. First of all, we find that the welfare implication of NDPs hinges
on relative distortions induced by market power of networks and merchant internalization (MI).
When MI overwhelms market power, the ban is likely to increase social welfare, and vice versa.
Another impressive finding is that both cardholder consumers and merchant consumers obtain
zero benefit from using a credit card when NDPs is in place. This is because platforms are able
to extract all of consumer surplus via an inflated price of product which embodies excessive
merchant fees. Lifting the NDPs will unambiguously increases surplus of both cardholders and
merchants. Moreover, we find that retaining the NSR and applying tourist test regulation will
yield the identical results as when surcharges are allowed and optimally capped.
Keywords: Credit Card Markets; No Surcharge Rule; Non Discriminatory Provisions.
JEL classification: G21, G28, L52
∗
We would like to thank Julian Wright for helpful discussion and comments. Hongru Tan gratefully acknowledges
the National Social Science Foundation for Young Scholars of China (No. XXXXXXX). All errors are ours.
†
School of Economics, Sichuan University, China; [email protected]
1
1 Introduction
This paper presents a theory of platform competition to discuss the competitive effect of no-
surcharge rule (NSR) clause or more general non-discriminatory provisions (NDPs), and related
regulatory issues in credit card markets. The NSR is a business clause which prohibits merchants
from imposing extra charges on payments via a particular credit card than any other methods of
payments, including another credit card, debit cards or cash. The NSR is enacted and enforced
by credit card companies (Visa or MasterCard) and is one of the prerequisites that merchants
adopt the credit card services. An even stronger constraint is anti-steering restraint or NDPs in
case of American Express (AmEx) which forbid merchants from encourage customers to use any
other payment means by monetary and non-monetary methods, including revealing the very cost
of merchants.
The often called credit card industry is precisely referred to as the market of General purchase
credit and charge (GPCC) cards.1 Typically, two types of networks provides the GPCC payment
service. They are closed system as AmEx and open system as Visa or MasterCard, which is shown in
Figure 1. In a closed system, AmEx directly serves both consumers and merchants, while Visa in an
open system indirectly serves the both end-user groups via issuers (or issuing banks) and acquirer (or
acquiring banks). The fee collection is also different. AmEx directly charges customer and merchant
fee ( or often called merchant discounts in practice) to consumers and merchants respectively.
Visa charges two network service fee to issuers and acquirers. Merchants and consumers pay the
1
See definition in the file U.S. v. American Exp. Co., 88 F. Supp. 143,204 (2015).
2
merchant fee and customer fee to acquirers and issuers respectively. Finally, acquirers pay issuers
an interchange fee (IF). Moreover, the open systems also experience a structure transition. Both
Visa and MasterCard went for Initial pubic offerings (IPOs) during the decade legislation,2 which
turns themselves from not-for-profit associations into for-profit companies. Before IPOs, Visa
or MasterCard collects no fees and the IF was collectively determined by their member banks.
Afterwards, they make a profit from the two network service fees.
The NSR clauses are at issue in the lawsuit against Visa and MasterCard – In re Payment Card
Interchange Fee and Merchant Discount Antitrust Litigation; and NDPs are the centre dispute
in lawsuit against AmEx – State of Ohio et al., v. American Express, 585 U.S. [2018]. The
non-monetary NDPs have also been applied by Visa or MasterCard before 2010. However, both
networks agreed to remove all the non-monetary NDPs, and merely AmEx insisted to keep them
and was willing to confront a litigation. In the case of Visa and MasterCard, merchants accused
the two credit card companies and banks of colluding to inflate their interchange fees and cause the
high fees borne by merchants and prohibiting from using surcharges to steer consumers towards
other payment of methods. In the case of AmEx, the plaintiffs including Department of Justice
(DOJ) and several states accused that NDPs “short-circuit the ordinary price-setting mechanism in
the network services by removing the competitive ‘reward’ for networks offering merchants a lower
The litigation of AmEx attracts great attention because its seminally applied the canonical
“rule of reason” to a two-sided platform, and explicitly treated two-sidedness as the key in analysis.
After years of hearing, AmEx finally won the case, and the courts conclude that plaintiffs have not
dismissed the burden to show anti-competitive effects of NDPs in the first step of rule of reason
analysis, given the relevant market is defined as the market of card transactions. Alternatively,
the courts think plaintiffs failed to show the anti-competitive effects of NDPs when both sides
of market are considered. Standing in contrast with the court’s decision, theory of this article
shows the opposite: when two sides of the markets are taken into account, NDPs adversely affects
competition and leads to surplus losses to both consumers and merchants. The same conclusion
also applies to the NSR clause of Visa or MasterCard when two networks competes and two sides
3
In particular, this article considers a two-sided monopolistic platform model to mimic the case
of AmEx, and oligopolistic platform competition model for the case of Visa and MasterCard. Each
platform provides the intermediation service to both consumers (or cardholders) and merchants. In
the case of multiple networks, either provides identical card services to both sides, and compete in
quantity as Cournot competition. Both consumers and merchants benefit from the consummated
transaction via card payments. The merchant is a monopolist in selling a product (or goods).
Consumers decide to buy a product or not, and the use of a particular payment means. MI prevails
among merchants when NDPs3 are in place. It indicates merchants, out of strategic consideration,
have to take and accept card payments despite bearing excessive merchant fees – the “must take”
phenomenon as in Vickers (2005). These excessive fees are eventually borne by consumers when they
are built into the price of products. The consumers, who pay with other alternatives, also pay part
of the fees. Alternatively, it indicates merchants internalize the consumer surplus when decide to
take the card payments or not. So, it is called merchant internalization. MI incurs an over-provision
of transaction services because it leads to consumers who do not enjoy the service cross-subsidize
those who use it. Notably, NDPs, which handicap merchants from truthfully revealing the costs
and renders a uniform price of product to all consumers, are the prerequisites to the existence of
Our model finds abundant meaningful results. First, we find that the welfare implication of
NDPs hinges on relative distortions induced by market power of networks and MI. When the market
power is strong, it more than offsets the effect of MI and under-provision equilibrium occurs. In this
case, a ban of NDPs withdrawing the over-provision is likely to incur an under-provision equilibrium
with a declined social welfare. When market power is weak, the distortion of MI will dominate
and lead to a massive over-provision. When ban the NDPs, a less under-provision is realized since
only distortion of market power exists. Consequently, a positive welfare impact is inclined to occur.
Another impressive finding is that both consumers and merchant obtain zero benefit from using a
credit card when NDPs is in place. This is because platforms are able to extract all of consumer
surplus via an inflated price of product which embodies excessive merchant fees. Lifting the NDPs
In addition, we find that retaining the NDPs and applying tourist test regulation will yield the
3
This is also the case with NSR clause. Since NDPs includes NSR clauses, we will only mention NDPs for brevity
if it can be applied to both.
4
identical results as when allow surcharges and impose an optimal surcharge cap. This is to say, the
two scenarios will lead to same levels of surplus to all interested parties. The impact of total social
welfare of each policy could go both directions, hinging on both distortions mentioned above. We
also mimic the competition between AmEx and Visa (or MasterCard), and their different business
models. We manage to establish an equilibrium where AmEx focuses on a sector with higher
evaluation of transaction services, and with consumers spend heavily (as for charge cards), and
Visa serve both this high value sector and another low value sector, but could earn a profit of
interests from outstanding balance. Interestingly, the asymmetrical business models leaves some
consumer surplus under the NDPs. Other comparison are similar to the above analysis.
This article adds to the literature on antitrust and regulatory issues in credit card markets.
Rochet and Tirole (2002) is the pioneer study on the NSR clause. They first draw comparison be-
tween distortions due to market power and MI, but in a model with a single not-for-profit network
and Hotelling merchants. Competition between networks which should have been discussed but
not in their article. The assumption of Hotelling merchants also has a drawback – no excessive sur-
charges occur when the clauses are removed. In reality, excessive surcharge behavoirs are robust as
observed in Australia. Tan and Deng (2020) provide an explanation of these surcharging behavoirs.
We update the model by assuming competing for-profit networks to reflect the governance change
in the industry. This article also assume monopolistic merchants which could capture the excessive
surcharging behavoirs when the clauses are removed. Wright (2003) discusses the NSR clause, but
does not consider “must take” argument or effect of MI, yet the competition between networks.
Schwartz and Vincent (2006) suggest that competitive effect of NSR clauses hinges on the propor-
tion of cash and card using consumers, and it is determined exogenously in the model. Carlton
and Winter (2018) examine the NSR clauses in a traditional market approach. They regard it as a
vertical most-favored-nation (vMFN) restraint, and find that it suppresses competition upstream,
and it is a mechanism to expropriate consumer surplus. They also suggest that the litigation on
a two-sided market issue should follow the practices in a conventional case. Schwartz and Vincent
(2019) apply a model with competing networks, but do not manage to provide an answer to the
competitive effect. As claimed by authors the article rather provides a basis to understand the
competition between two platforms, and mechanism in setting fees. Edelman and Wright (2015)
generalize the analysis of NSR clause into broad issue of price coherence in two-sided markets.
5
They focus on the incentive to improve consumer side benefit. Their main finding is that “this
(price coherence) leads to inflated retail prices, excessive adoption of the intermediaries’services,
over-investment in benefits to buyers, and a reduction in consumer surplus and sometimes welfare.”
Another stream of related literature is on regulatory issues. Baxter (1983) first provides a
theory and justification in setting an interchange fees (IF). He finds that setting IF according
to banking costs could internalize the negative externality from consumers onto merchants under
certain condition, and therefore resolve a market failure. Schmalensee (2002) demonstrates that
the IF is a mechanism to balance the fees charged to both sides, but does not find a workable
theory to guide policy enforcement. Rochet and Tirole (2011) invent the tourist test to regulate
the IF, and find that the tourist test will maximize the social welfare or at least consumer surplus
when merchants are homogeneous. Wright (2012) establishes that tourist test is valid in a broader
setting including merchants are heterogeneous. Bourguignon et al. (2019) show that tourist test is
necessary and optimal with NSR clauses, and no regulation is needed when surcharges are allowed
and subject to an optimal limit. Aurazo and Vasquez (2019) consider how tax evasion advantage
with cash payments affect the threshold of tourist test in developing countries. Reisinger and Zenger
(2019) examine how tourist test affect the incentives of investment, finding that the test will yield
a too low incentive to invest under a total welfare standard, but an approximately optimal level of
incentive under a total user surplus standard. Bourreau and Verdier (2019) discuss how IFs affects
All these literature assume networks as not-for-profit associations and a pass-through logic in
setting IFs. That is to say, a linear relationship exists between the fees, and IFs work as a hook to
the fees borne by end users. An increase in the IF will rise the merchant fee and lower the customer
fee accordingly. However, Visa and MasterCard become for-profit companies post IPOs, and the
mechanism in setting IF charges as well. We modify the model to reflect this change and revisit the
very issue on IFs. More generally, Rysman and Wright (2014) survey the literature on credit card
markets and note that there is no study explaining the various surcharging behaviors in Australia
and other countries. Tan and Wright (2018) and Tan and Wright (2020) discuss optimal pricing
structures in general two-sided markets and its application to credit card markets.
6
2 Model
This section introduces the models. We start with a monopoly platform model to mimic the situa-
tion of AmEx. In doing so, we will explain the intuition regarding NDPs. We then consider duopoly
platform competition and the more general case of oligopoly platforms for the case of Visa and Mas-
terCard. Since we apply a Cournot model unlike most of previous literature, I shall first elaborate
on its plausibility. “Cournot” means that the two platforms provide identical transaction services
and compete in quantity. In practice, consumers can hardly tell the difference between a Visa card
and a MasterCard card, except for their names or logos. Both brands historically charge the same
rate of interchange fees,4 and offer similar rewards scheme to consumers. We also think AmEx
provides the identical transaction services as Visa or MasterCard. AmEx argued that it provides
a higher class of services than Visa and MasterCard, by offering better consumers reward program
with greater benefit, but at the expense of a significant higher swipe fee to merchants. However,
the fundamental service provided by AmEx is nothing more than a means of payments, and the
only difference with Visa and MasterCard is the price level and structure charged to consumers
and merchants. Price level means the total prices borne by end-user groups, and price structure
means the decomposition of price level. In short, the transaction services that AmEx provides is
still the same as that of Visa and MasterCard. So, Cournot model is a proper representative of
We assume both consumers and the merchant have their own transaction benefits, bB and bS .
Platforms charge customer fee pB and merchant fee pS to consumers and merchants. Consumers
have an option to choose their method of payments. Merchants also have a choice regarding accept
cards or not. The platforms provide the infrastructure that enables consumers and merchants
making transactions with cards. By accepting credit cards rather than cash, merchants enjoy
various transaction benefits, including fraud protection, accounting facilities, time savings at the
counter, and transaction enablement through credit or float. Likewise, consumers enjoy their own
transaction benefits by paying with credit card rather than cash, i.e., conveniences related to
eliminating the need to carry cash, the need to count cash, and the risk of losing cash, and etc.
The assumption on merchants is critical, and it shall capture two elements of realities in credit
4
See David S. Evans, 2011, Interchange Fees: The Economics and Regulation of What Merchants Pay for Cards
p.63
7
card markets. First, the must-take argument as in Vickers (2005) and MI as in Rochet and Tirole
(2002) and Farrell (2006) should prevail under NDPs. Second, excessive surcharges should be the
case as the observations in various counties, which are documented in the report “Review of Card
Surcharging: A Consultation Document” June 2011, Reserve Bank of Australia. To meet the two
requirements, we adopt the monopoly merchant setting as in Wright (2012). Hotelling (including
the Hotelling-Lerner-Salop) differentiated product competition also satisfies the two features, if we
assume the transportation cost is sufficiently large, t > vB (pB )DB (pB ), as introduced immediately.
In particular, the merchant is a monopolist in selling a product to consumers who are located
in an unit distance interval. Consumers are uniformly spread over the interval. Each consumer
obtains utility u from purchase the product, and incurs a transportation cost t per unit distance
to merchant’s store. The consumer only realizes her benefit bB from using cards after going into
the store. bB is drawn from the uniform distribution over [0, 1]. We assume the full coverage of
the product market. With NDPs, the monopoly merchant will set the price of product p equal
to p = u + vB (pB )DB (pB ) − t—the utility of consuming the product u plus the consumer surplus
from using cards minus the transportation cost of the consumer who is located at x = 1. The term
average consumer surplus vB (pB ) is defined as vB (pB ) = E (bB | bB ≥ pB ) − pB .5 vB (pB )DB (pB )
is the total consumer surplus of consumers. When NDPs are removed and surcharges are allowed,
a monopoly merchant sets the price of product purchased in cash as pcash = u − t, and sets the
price of product purchased with credit cards as pcard = u − t + s. The term s is the level of
surcharge. Consumer’s demand for transaction services is given by DB (pB ) = 1 − pB with NDPs,
MI implies the merchant is able to extract all consumer surplus of using cards vB (pB )DB (pB )
by inflating the price of product. However, consumers with realized benefit less than the price
bB < pB would not purchase the product, even with cash. These consumers (consider the one
located at x ) will obtain net utility from purchase with cash is u − p − tx, where the price of
product p = u + vB (pB )DB (pB ) − t. Then, they obtain net utility −vB (pB )DB (pB ) + t − tx. If
instead of not purchasing, they would incur a transportation cost of tx or net utility of −tx. These
consumers will purchase if condition t > vB (pB )DB (pB ) holds. Consequently, MI also holds. It
R∞
5 pB (bB −pB )dF (bB )
Mathematically, the term is given by vB (pB ) = E (bB | bB ≥ pB ) − pB = R∞ , where F (bB ) is the
pB dF (bB )
cumulative distribution function of bB .
8
is worthy mentioning that the full coverage of the market implies that the demand of product is
inelastic. This is to say, the inflated price of product does not affect the demand. Condition of MI
can also be met when the demand is elastic as explained in the appendix A of Wright (2012). For
The timing of platform is given as follows. First, platforms or networks set the per transaction
fees pB and pS to consumers and the merchants, and determine whether to adopt the NDPs. In a
closed system, AmEx sets pB and pS directly. In an open system, the IFs and two network services
fees are set by credit card companies and their affiliated banks. Once the three fees are set, pB
and pS are determined consequently. Second, merchants makes a choice to accept the card or not,
given pS . Third, each consumer first goes to a store and realizes her transaction benefits bB . If
she finds the merchant store accepts card payment, she then decides to use a card or not given
pB .6 We use backward induction to solve the game. In the first stage of game, the platform sets
pB and pS ; In the second stage, the merchant makes an option to card services and set the prices
of product, and consumers decide to purchase and the means of payments. Notably, there are two
markets. One is the market of the product, and another is the market for credit card transaction
services. Consumers have their preferences over both the product and transaction service. Under
our assumption, there is no interdependence between the two markets, i.e., the price of transaction
service does not affect the consumption of product, and vice versa. In this way, we could focus on
credit card markets, without losing the practical background of product market.
This section discusses the case with monopoly platform. We start by discussing the merchant’s
decision of card adoption and pricing behaviors. The equilibrium condition for a monopoly merchant
under the NSR is well introduced and proposed in the proposition 1 of article Rochet and Tirole
(2011) and the appendix A in Wright (2012). For brevity, I shall use their results directly and
explain the intuitions behind each equation. For a given pS , the merchant has two options – either
6
Notably, we omit the card adoption decision of consumers, which reflects the majority of consumers do carry
a card in the real world. Alternatively, we can understand as the consumers compare both membership and usage
fees with excepted realized benefits for each transaction, and membership fees are evened out for each purchase.
Moreover, membership fees, which account for around 1.5 percent of networks and banks revenue, is insignificant
compared to 15 percent for usage fees. Although, networks may incur some cost to acquire an consumer, but the
cost is still neglected, compared to an average $ 400 yearly revenue from each household. For the above reasons, we
assume every consumer has a certain type of credit cards.
9
accept the NDPs and card transactions, or decline cards and merely accept cash.
If the merchant accepts the NSR clause, she will set the uniform price of product as
Intuitively, u − t is maximum price the merchant can charge for the product to ensure the consumer
located at furthest spot purchase the product. The merchant will charge vB (pB )DB (pB ) more on
top of “pure” product price to fully extract the consumer surplus. If the merchant declines card
p=u−t (2)
bS + vB (pB ) ≥ pS (3)
The merchant will obtain transaction benefit of bS and extra average consumer surplus vB (pB ) for
each transaction, and pay a cost of merchant fee pS if accepts cards. If the net benefit is greater
than the cost, the merchant will accept. The merchant could also refuse card payments, and the
ability to decline is referred to as merchant resistance. For a given pS , some merchants will accept,
while other turn it down. The extent of merchant resistance hinges on the amount of consumer
surplus can be expropriated, and her own transaction benefit bS . The equation (3) is the condition
of MI, implying the merchant fully consider the consumer surplus when accept a card payment.
Taking into account the merchant’s reaction, the platform will set the highest merchant fee pS such
pS = bS + vB (pB ) (4)
In doing so, the platform ensures merchant weakly prefer to accept cards, and at the mean time
seizes all consumer surplus extracted by the merchant. Without loss of generality, we assume
merchants accept cards when she is indifferent between payments by cards and cash. Therefore,
10
the monopoly platform profit maximization is given by
max π N = (1 − DB + bS + vB (1 − DB ) − c) DB (6)
DB
When NDPs are removed and surcharges are allowed, the merchant will accept cards regardless,
because she cannot only pass through the cost onto consumers but also impose excessive surcharges.
In this situation, the merchant will set cash price as pcash = u−t, and card price as pcard = u−t+s.
Given pB and pS , the merchant select a surcharge to maximize her profit, and the solution is given
by
1 − bS − pB + pS
s= (9)
2
1
pB + s = 1 − DB = (1 − bS + pB + pS ) (10)
2
pB + pS = 1 + bS − 2DB (11)
Notably, since the merchant always pass the cost onto consumers, the fee structure becomes neutral
as discussed in Gans and King (2003), and only the fee level matters. This point can be verified
11
in equation (10), in which the final price borne by consumer pB + s is determined by the fee level
The solutions to platform’s problems under either case, i.e., (6) and (12), can be easily obtained,
1
DB = 1 + bS − c, pB = c − bS , pS = bS + (1 + bS − c) , π M = 0 (13)
2
1 1
πN = (1 + bS − c)2 , CSCard = 0, T SCard = (1 + bS − c)2 (14)
2 2
1 1 1
DB = (1 + bS − c) , pB + pS = (1 + bS + c) , π M = (1 + bS − c)2 (15)
4 2 16
1 1 7
πN = (1 + bS − c)2 , CSCard = (1 + bS − c)2 , T SCard = (1 + bS − c)2 (16)
8 32 32
With NDPs, we observe that consumer surplus is zero. This is because the inflated price of
product extracts all of the surplus, and the extraction depends on the assumption of inelas-
tic demand of product, and significant sunk cost of transportation. Once a consumer visits
one store, she will purchase either with a card or with cash, due to a sufficient high reserve
price u and significant transportation cost. Cash-using consumers also pay the inflated price
p = u + vB (pB )DB (pB ) − t compared to the otherwise price p = u − t. In this way, cash users
cross-subsidize card users, at the expense of their benefit from consuming product by amount of
(1 − DB (pB ))vB (pB )DB (pB ). Card users obtain total transaction benefits as vB (pB )DB (pB ), and
they pay the total extra fee via inflated price as DB (pB )vB (pB )DB (pB ). The net benefit of card
users gained is (1 − DB (pB ))vB (pB )DB (pB ), which is exactly equal to the loss of cash users. As
a result, the total surplus of all consumers is zero. Expecting the merchant’s full expropriation
of consumer surplus, the platform charges a merchant fee such that all the surplus is transferred
7
In fact, the profit of merchant is given by π M = u − t − d, which is the total profit from both product and card
market. For illustrative purpose, we only list the profit in card market in this article.
12
into her profit. Therefore, the merchant earns no benefit from the card market. All the surplus is
Proposition 1. When the NSR clause is in place and MI prevails, a monopolistic platform will
inflate the price of product by vB (pB )DB (pB ), such that cash users cross subsidize card users by
amount of (1 − DB (pB ))vB (pB )DB (pB ), which results in the platform seizes all surplus in card
Interestingly, the price pB = c − bS effectively implies a first best solution (i.e., summed benefit
of marginal users equals the cost bB + bS = pB + bS = c) and social welfare is maximized. The
card service is therefore just provided, and neither under- nor over- provision exists. The existence
condition. The platform does not bear the infra marginal loss when increases the output, and she
The caveat is that some rents are transferred from product market into the card transaction
market. Given consumer’s insensitive product demand response to the inflated prices, the NDPs
and excessive merchant fees render a shift of welfare of consumer’s surplus (cash users in particular)
from products into the rent of card transaction market which is ultimately absorbed by networks.
The shift of the surplus subsidizes the infra marginal loss due to the decrease in price pB , and the
platform does not suffer a loss of infra margin, when expand its output.
It is counter intuitive that a monopolist will profitably lowering price to the cost and expand-
ing output to social optimal level. But, it is the case in a two-sided credit card market where
NDPs short-circuit the ordinary pricing setting mechanism. This countering intuition is not well
understood among academia, let along policy makers. Proposition 2 summarizes this finding.
Proposition 2. When NDPs are in place and MI prevails, a monopolistic platform will profitably
lower price to the cost and expand output to social optimal level, and social welfare is maximized.
When NDPs are removed, MI goes away since the merchant always accept cards and is able
to impose a surcharge. In this situation, the two-sided credit card market turns into a one-sided
one. The fee structure is neutral. The platform does not concern about how to adjust the fee
structure to balance two-sides of the markets, and all it need to worry about is the fee level, which
determines its profit. The model is thus turning into a simple vertical supply chain story. We
13
can see the point from the fact that inverse demand pB + s is solely determined by the price level
pB + pS . By rearranging the profit functions of merchant and platform (e.g., plugging equations
(9) and (10) into equations (8) and (12)), we can see both functions are determined by the price
level as well.
The results without NDPs show that consumers obtains positive surplus, both platform and
merchant earns a positive profit from the card market. It is a simple double marginalization story of
a vertical supply chain. The platform is the upstream supplier and the merchant is the downstream
seller, and each impose a margin onto the cost of card services. Although the surcharge cannot
be solved due to indetermination of fee structure, we can still obtain an expression of excessive
surcharge as
1 − bS − pB + pS 1 − bS − pB − pS 1 − bS − 12 (1 + bS + c) 1 − 3bS − c
s−pS = −pS = = = (17)
2 2 2 4
3
The extra charge is part of fee borne by consumers: the total fee borne is pB + s = 4 (1 + bS − c),
and total fee borne minus the extra charge equals price level, i.e., pB + s − (s − pS ) = pB + pS . The
sign of extra charge is ambiguous, but with a higher likelihood to be positive when the maximum
transaction benefit of consumers is greater than the transaction benefit of merchants. After banning
the NDPs, we can see that: (a) the card demand decreases; (b) the price level remains the same;
(c) merchant’s profit increases; (d) platform’s profit decreases; (e) Consumer surplus from using
cards increase; (f) total surplus, including the consumer surplus, merchant’s and platform’s profits,
Proposition 3. When a monopolistic platform provides card transaction services, the prohibition
of NDPs will decrease card usage, level off price level of platform, leading to an increase of consumer
surplus and merchant’s profit, and a drop of platform profit and social welfare.
The removal of NDPs eliminates the concern of price structure, and paralyzes one side of the
market. It disables platform’s perfect expropriation of consumer surplus via an excessive high
merchant fee and hence the inflated price of product. At the mean time, it allows the merchant
to impose a surcharge. No matter how a second margin adversely affect the efficiency, it will not
absorb all the consumer surplus. Although total surplus decreases afterwards, both consumers and
the merchant gain benefits from the injunctive relief. The conflict between platform and merchant
14
is obvious: the merchant’s profit increase afterwards, while the profit of platform decreases. The
conflict in profitability can be manifested from lawsuits in the U.S., whereby merchants are on
plaintiff side, and platforms are defendant. It is the conflict in profitability, not the claimed social
welfare or consumer surplus, that brings about the past or current lawsuits in practice.
The findings of the monopolistic platform can be applied to analyse AmEx’ NDPs. Specifically,
the findings give full theoretical support to plaintiffs in State of Ohio et al., v. American Express,
585 U.S. [2018] . In this lawsuit, both Appeal and Supreme Courts conclude that plaintiffs have
not dismissed the burden to show anti competitive effects of NDPs in the first step of rule of reason
analysis, given the relevant market is defined as the market of card transactions.
The Supreme court decides in favor of AmEx primarily relies on the following grounds. First
of all, it claimed that the district court ” wrongly focuses on only one side of the two-sided credit-
card market”. Second, it pointed that plaintiffs failed to provide preponderant evidence that the
price of card transactions was higher than competitive level. Third, the experienced expanding
output and quality counter proved the existence of market power, and that the NDPs had stifled
competition. However, our model shows, in a two-sided market scenario, NDPs harm both merchant
and cardholder consumers, despite the fact that they boost the demand of card transactions, which
To fit the model into discussion of NDPs of AmEx, we could regard AmEx as a monopoly in
providing premium charge card transaction service as in travel and entertainment (T & E ) or
corporate cards sectors, and regards the alternative means as the Visa or MasterCard cards or
other payment means. The merchant fees charged by the alternative platforms are normalized to
zero. AmEx managed to charge a premium over its rivals’ all-in prices to merchants, and it is
called premium pricing strategy. The model shows that this strategy would inflate the price of
goods overall, resulting in a full extraction of consumer surplus on cardholder side. The alternative
cardholders cross subsidize the AmEx cardholders. Likewise, the merchants obtain no benefit from
card transaction service, despite that total social welfare in maximized. Nevertheless, nothing is
enjoyed by the consumers of both sides, even in the events that card usage is expanded.
The Supreme court also thinks that the higher merchant fees collected by AmEx could be used
15
to fund the innovation to improve cardholder’s benefit. Our theory indicates that whether the
NDPs affects innovation on cardholder benefit is a pseudo-question. So long as all the created
benefits of cardholders are taken away, it does not matter how much benefits are realized from
innovation. The courts also discuss the issue of entry barriers in the industry. They recognized
that “the credit-card industry continues to be characterized by formidable barriers to entry. These
barriers arise because of the nature of the industry and requirements a network must fulfill before
entering it.” But what they do not understand is that NDPs are the vital premise to foster the
nature of formidable barriers. In particular, NDPs bestows the credit card markets the nature of
two-sidedness. An entrant enters the market has to accord both sides, and conquer the critical mass
or chichen & egg problem. Once NDPs are prohibited, merchants always accept card payments.
The market degenerates into a one-sided one, and entry is relative easier. So, NDPs do increase
In this section we will apply a model of Cournot platforms to mimic the competition between Visa
and MasterCard. Since it is the NSR clauses at issues in case of Visa or MasterCard, we will only
mention NSR clauses in this section. We first consider the case where issuing and acquiring banks
are both perfect competitive, and then relax this later on. Both type of banks then play no real
role in the game, and the game of platform competition is similar to that of monopolistic platform.
The only difference is that platform competition in quantity in first stage nails down the price
borne by consumers. In particular, under the NSR clauses, the two platforms set the merchants fee
according to equation (4), The monopoly merchant accepts cards and sets the price of the product
as equation (1). On the consumer side, the two platforms compete according to Cournot game.
Take into account the effect of MI , the profit maximization of two platforms, denoted by I and J,
are given by
max π I = 1 − q I − q J + bS + vB (pB ) − c) q I
(18)
qI
max π J = 1 − q I − q J + bS + vB (pB ) − c q J
(19)
qJ
where q I and q J are the quantities of card service provided by each platform. q I + q J is the total
industry sale, which is equal to DB (pB ). Likewise, the platform’s problems under surcharging
16
regime are given by
max π I = 1 + bS − 2 q I + q J − c q I
(20)
qI
max π J = 1 + bS − 2 q I + q J − c q J
(21)
qJ
We can easily solve problems expressed by equation (18) to (21), and the results under NSR clauses
4 4 1 2
DB = (1 + bS − c), pB = (c − bS ) − , pS = bS + (1 + bS − c) , π M = 0 (22)
3 3 3 3
4 4
πI + πJ = (1 + bS − c)2 , CSCard = 0, T SCard = (1 + bS − c)2 (23)
9 9
and the results when surcharges are allowed are given by:
1 1 1
DB = (1 + bS − c) , pB + pS = (1 + bS + 2c) , π M = (1 + bS − c)2 (24)
3 3 9
1 1 5
πI + πJ = (1 + bS − c)2 , CSCard = (1 + bS − c)2 , T SCard = (1 + bS − c)2 (25)
9 18 18
The results show that the consumer surplus and merchant’s profit from card market remain zero
under the NSR clauses. All the surplus are accrued to the two platforms equally. Interestingly, it
can be easily verified that the zero surplus result for both consumers and merchant holds regardless
of how many platforms compete. Due to the ability in extraction of consumer surplus, each platform
knows she will not bear the infra marginal loss due to an increase in output, and competes in a more
aggressive way compared to the situation otherwise. The degree of competition among platforms
will not change the fact of depletion in users surplus, so long as MI prevails. We formally conclude
Proposition 4. When the NSR clauses is in place and MI prevails, competing platforms absorb
Compared to the case with a monopoly platform, less total surplus are realized, because the
competition between platforms is unable to internalize the negative externality from one’s sale to
another. The card service is over provided, exceeding first best solution. In the monopoly case, the
over provision distortion from MI is fully offset by the under provision distortion due to market
power of platform. In the duopoly case, the effect of MI dominates that of market power, which
17
leads to an over provision result.
Under the surcharging regime, it is still a double marginalization story. Compared to the case
of monopoly platform, more total surplus is realized, both consumer surplus and merchant’s profit
increase, and the total platform profits decrease. The competition upstream suppresses down the
whole sale price, and both merchant and consumers gain a benefit from it. The welfare implication
discussion remains the same as in last section. The collusive equilibrium of this Cournot game is
equivalent to those of monopolistic platform setting, and welfare implication remains unchanged.
Proposition 5. When duopoly platforms provide card transaction services, the prohibition of NSR
clause will decrease card usage leading to an increase of consumer surplus and merchant’s profit,
The analysis can be easily extended to oligopolistic competition between platforms. The com-
petitive effects for consumers and merchant remain the same: lifting NSR clauses will unambigu-
ously benefits both consumers and the merchant. However, the social welfare may go up when the
competition between platforms is sufficiently vigorous. It can be proved that when N ≥ 4, ban of
NSR clause will increase social welfare. This is because MI strongly overwhelms the market power
which declines as the number of platforms increases, and it incurs a much higher over provision in
This section will relax the assumption of perfect issuing competition and discuss its implication. In
particular, we assume the issuing banks retain a constant margin m for each transaction. That is, a
consumer will bear a final price of pB +m with NSR clauses, and the demand of card services is then
given by DB (pB ) = 1−pB −m. Under surcharging regime, the demand is DB (pB ) = 1−pB −s−m.
The duopoly platforms will set their fees, taking into account the issuing margin. Their problems
max π I = 1 − m − q I − q J + bS + vB (pB ) − c) q I
(26)
qI
max π J = 1 − m − q I − q J + bS + vB (pB ) − c q J
(27)
qJ
18
where q I and q J are the quantities of card service provided by each platform. q I + q J is the total
industry sale, which is equal to DB (pB ). Likewise, the platform’s problems under surcharging
max π I = 1 + bS − 2m − 2 q I + q J − c q I
(28)
qI
max π J = 1 + bS − 2m − 2 q I + q J − c q J
(29)
qJ
4 4 1 m 2
DB = (1 − m + bS − c), pB = (c − bS ) − + , pS = bS + (1 − m + bS − c) , (30)
3 3 3 3 3
4
π M = 0, π I + π J = (1 − m + bS − c)2 , (31)
9
4m
CSCard = 0, π Issuer = (1 − m + bS − c) , (32)
3
4 4m
T SCard = (1 − m + bS − c)2 + (1 − m + bS − c) (33)
9 3
From the results, we can see that the markup of issuing banks increases the customer fee, decrease
card provision, and brings down the merchant fee. Neither consumers nor the merchant benefits
from the card services. All the surplus is still accrued to platforms and issuing banks. The effect
of markup on the total surplus is ambiguous. It depends on to what extend the distortion due
to the issuing markup corrects the over provision due to the MI. As we can see that, the markup
indeed weakens the distortion of MI, which is manifested from the lowered merchant fee. The
markup increases customer fee borne by consumers and lowers the realized consumer surplus, and
platforms have to lower the merchant fee when they expect the lower surplus can be expropriated
via the inflated price of product. The effect of issuing markup when surcharges are allowed is
straightforward and the solution are given as below. From the results, we can see that issuing
markup lowers the demand, consumer surplus, profits of merchant and platforms and total surplus.
1 1
DB = (1 − m + bS − c) , pB + pS = (1 − m + bS + 2c) , (34)
3 3
1 m
πM = (1 − m + bS − c)2 , π Issuer = (1 − m + bS − c) , (35)
9 3
1 1
πI + πJ = (1 − m + bS − c)2 , CSCard = (1 − m + bS − c)2 , (36)
9 18
19
5 m
T SCard = (1 − m + bS − c)2 + (1 − m + bS − c) (37)
18 3
In the presence of market power of issuing banks, thee distortions exist under NSR clauses,
including the market powers of platforms and issuing banks, and the MI. The presence of issuing
market power will weaken the dominant effect of MI, and decrease the likelihood that ban will
Proposition 6. When duopoly platforms provide card transaction services and issuing banks pos-
sess market power, the prohibition of NSR clause will decrease card usage leading to an increase of
consumer surplus and merchant’s profit, and a drop of platform profit and social welfare.
The merchant resistance describes the extent to which merchants could decline the card services.
The higher degree of resistance, the less intention to “must-take” a card. Alternatively, it refers
to the ability of merchants to refuse the card services. The resistance hinges on two factors –
the transaction benefit and the degree of MI. The higher value of transaction benefit, the less
likelihood for merchants to turn down card services for a given merchant fee. Similarly, the more
consumer surplus from card services can be extracted through an inflated price of product, the less
willingness for a merchant to decline card services. Since the transaction benefit is fixed, the major
source of merchant resistance arises from MI. Next, we will examine how the degree of MI affects
card provision. Suppose, the merchant can merely expropriate α portion of consumer surplus.
This can be the case for a monopoly merchant when transportation cost is not sufficient high, i.e.,
t = αvB (pB )DB (pB ). For Hotelling merchants, this situation arise when consumers are not fully
informed of card acceptance policy as in Rochet and Tirole (2002). When α portion of consumer
2(1 + bS − c) 2(1 + bS − c)
DB = α , pB = 1 − , πM = 0 (39)
3(1 − 2 ) 3(1 − α2 )
20
2 1
CSCard = 0, T SCard = π I + π J = (1 + bS − c)2 (40)
9 (1 − α2 )
From the results we can see that the demand, merchant fee, platform’s profits and the total surplus
decrease compared to the fully MI case. The low degree of MI does not yields any “leftover” surplus
to either consumers or merchants. Both groups still earn zero surplus from card transaction. The
platforms will extract any surplus they spot in credit card markets, and it is does not matter how
much they have spotted. Since MI does not exist under the surcharging regime, the results remain
unchanged.
The regulation of interchange fees (IF) in open systems and merchant fees in closed system is
another critical issue in policy enforcement. Two main theories exist on this regulatory issue. First
is the cost-based approach initiated in Baxter (1983) and reinforced in Tan (2020), by which the
interchange (or merchant) fees should be set according to issuing and acquiring costs. Baxter points
out an appropriate level of IF can solve a market failure due to negative externality imposed by
consumers onto merchants. Tan (2020) advances Baxter’s idea with heterogeneous consumers and
merchants. It also points out that tourist test is an invalid approach when regulate the IFs or
merchant fees in a closed system with heterogeneous merchants. These two pieces discuss the very
issue in a model with single network, without considering the case with compete networks.
The second is tourist test approach introduced by Rochet and Tirole (2011), which is aimed
at capping IFs such that merchants do not have to bear excessive fees because of strategic con-
sideration. It is in merchant’s interest to accept the cards ex ante to attract customers to their
stores, and steer to other payments method ex post to avoid an excessive high merchant fee due
to business strategic consideration. The tourist test insures merchants have the same incentive to
take cards both ex ante and ex post. Bourguignon et al. (2019) suggests that it would be optimal
to either keep the NSR clause and regulate IFs according to tourist test, or abandon the NSR and
free IFs. In these two literature, the networks are assumed to be a not-for-profit association, which
maximizes the transaction volume through its network. While, we assume networks are for-profit
companies. In what follows, we will examine the optimality of IFs and merchant fees with compet-
ing networks and under either the NSR or surcharging regime in attempt to see the optimal policy
intervention.
21
For illustrative purpose, we will discuss in context of duopoly platforms model. First of all,
the regulation of fees under surcharging regime is not an issue since the price structure is neutral.
The only regulatory issue is with NSR clauses. Intuitively, the outcomes when fees are limited
according to tourist test with NSR clause is identical to the outcomes when surcharges are allowed
and capped by net merchant’s cost – merchant fee minus transaction benefit. This is because, in
either case, only the distortion due to networks’ market power exists, which leads to an identical
provision and social welfare in the card market. Therefore, we have the following proposition:
Proposition 7. Regulating the interchange (or merchant ) fees by tourist test under the NSR
clause, yields the identical outcomes in consumer surplus, merchant profit, and platform’s profits
Since 2013, surcharges are allowed in U.S. within both Visa and MasterCard networks, with a
cap equal to the least of average merchant’s fees and a 4% of transaction value. In Canada 2017, Visa
and MasterCard agreed a settlement to modify their restraint of NSR clause, and allow merchants
to surcharge. Likewise, the excessive surcharges were banned since 2017 in Australia. No standard
of the cap has been stipulated (like 4% in the U.S.). Instead, the guidelines of Competition and
Consumer Amendment (Payment Surcharges) Act of 2016 suggests that the cap should be based on
merchant’s cost to accept card payments. Theory suggests that a cap equal to net merchant’s cost
is optimal. In practice, the cap is set according to gross merchant’s cost to accept card payments,
which does not net out merchant’s benefit. So, the mandatory cap leave some profit margin to
merchants, and they will make a positive profit under the surcharging regime.
As mentioned in theory, consumers earn no benefit with NSR clauses, and ban of it will unam-
biguously improve consumer surplus, regardless of curbing surcharges or not. Merchant also make
no profit under the NSR, and make a positive under otherwise. The cap on surcharges will lower
its profit but improve the consumer surplus. The profit of networks decrease after the ban. Total
surplus could go both directions. According to the above proposition, the conclusion on welfare
implication of NSR clause also applies to the impact of tourist test. Specifically, tourist test in-
creases consumer surplus in certain. Merchants, however, gains nothing from it, and always make
zero profit. The network’s profits decrease. The total surplus remains ambiguous. Therefore, we
Proposition 8. The regulation of the interchange (or merchant ) fees with tourist test under NSR
22
clauses will increase consumer surplus, decrease platform’s profits, and level off merchant’s profit.
Whether application of tourist test (equivalently ban of NSR clauses and impose optimal sur-
charge cap ) improves the total social welfare hinges on the relative forces between market power of
networks and merchant internalization. This point is clearly demonstrated in the model of oligopoly
networks. We can easily extend the model of duopoly competition into oligopoly competition with
N networks. For brevity, we omit the process of derivation, rather states some of results. when
N = 1, the monopoly network will supply Q = 1+bS −c unit of services and the price is pB = c−bS ,
which is the social cost to provide the service. In this case, the market power distortion of network
fully offsets the distortion of MI, and the card provision is optimal and social welfare is optimized. If
(1+bS −c)
the fees are curbed by tourist test, the quantity is Q = 2 and the price has pB > c − bS . The
tourist test curbs the over-provision of MI and renders an under provision result. When N = 2, the
market power distortion is weaker than that of MI, and card services is over provided with industry
4(1+bS −c)
level quantity as Q = 3 , and price being pB < c − bS . After applying tourist test, the
2(1+bS −c)
quantity is given by Q = 3 , and price has pB > c − bS , which indicates an under provision.
The test eliminates MI and over corrects the distortion causing over provision, leading to a result
of under provision. The social welfare remains the same due to negative and positive displacements
away from the optimal quantity are the same. When N = 3, the test will unambiguously improve
social welfare. This is because MI strongly overwhelms the market power which declines as the
number of networks increases, and it incurs a much higher provision quantity compared to the un-
6(1+bS −c) 3(1+bS −c)
der provision if MI is curbed. The quantities are Q = 4 without a cap, and Q = 4
1+bS −c
with a tourist cap. The former suggests an over provided quantity of Q = 2 , and the latter
1+bS −c
indicates an under provided quantity of Q = 4 . So, we see an increase in social welfare.
More than 30 countries and regions either had conducted or are conducting antitrust and regula-
tory investigations against Visa and MasterCard on NSR clauses. For example, the Reserve Bank
of Australia (RBA) removed NSR clauses on both networks since 2003, and imposed a limit onto
surcharges as of 2017, which is mandated in the Competition and Consumer Amendment (Payment
Surcharges) Act of 2016. In Canada, the Competition Bureau challenged NSR clauses in 2010, but
23
failed in the case – The Commissioner of Competition v. Visa Canada Corporation and Master-
Card International Incorporated, 2013 Comp.Trib.10. But, the plaintiffs consisting of independent
retailers in five major provinces won and successfully removed the NSR clause in a 2011 class-action
case. Moreover, the Department of Finance imposed a reduction onto interchange fees which takes
effected in 2020.
The issue of NSR clauses in the U.S. is brought about in a separate class-action case in 2005
– In re Payment Card Interchange Fee and Merchant Discount Antitrust Litigation. Merchants
accused the two credit card companies and banks of colluding to inflate their interchange fees and
cause the high fees borne by merchants, and prohibiting from using surcharges to steer consumers
towards other payment of methods. Around 12 million merchants joined in the plaintiff side of the
case, and it lasts more than a decade. In 2013, Visa and MasterCard along with banks (including
JP Morgan Chase & Co, Citigroup and Bank of America) initially agreed to a historical record high
$ 7.25 billion settlement. However, a federal appeals court vetoed the deal in 2016 on the ground
that, among others, the prospective injunctive relief is not met the requirement on behalf of the
representative merchants. The case was finally settled in 2019. In the settlement, both companies
agreed to allowing merchants to impose surcharges, but subject to a limit. In the decade long
process, a number of merchants refused to reach the deal, and some others (like Amazon.com) even
Our theory suggests that NSR clauses are detrimental to both cardholder consumers and mer-
chant consumers; and the optimal scheme should be either removing NSR clauses and imposing an
optimal cap on surcharges, or keeping the clauses and imposing tourist test on merchant fees. Our
findings provides solid and yet updated theoretical basis for antitrust practices in various countries.
Although the total welfare implication is ambiguous, the damages to both groups of consumers is
sufficient to pin down the court decision. The only issue remained is to determine the optimal cap
3 Conclusion
NDPs and NSR clauses have been widely used in a number of markets, for example online shopping,
but received particular attention in credit card markets. The credit card industry is of economic
significant. For example, AmEx in the U.S. cards were accepted at about 6.4 million merchants’
24
stores, compared to the number around 9.4 million for Visa and MasterCard cards(U.S. v. American
Exp. Co., 88 F. Supp. 143, 204, 2015). Likewise, according to the National Retail Federation report,
merchants together with consumers pay $ 50 billion swipe fees a year, amounting to a $ 400 charge
for each household. Globally, around $ 10. 8 trillion value transactions were paid by credit cards,
which accounts more than 10 percent of the world’s gross domestic product (HSN Consultants
2016, p.9).
To understand the competitive effects of these practices is critical among the discussion of public
policies, especially when the ruling in State of Ohio et al., v. American Express, 585 U.S. [2018]
which seminally applies the theory of two-sided markets into the canonical rule of reason analysis
will generate profound influence to similar litigation in other two-sided markets. Unfortunately,
our theory goes against the court’s decision in favor of AmEx. We find that when two sides of the
markets are taken into account, NDPs unambiguous stifle competition and leads to surplus losses
to both cardholder consumers and merchant consumers. The same conclusion also applies to NSR
Our model findings are profound. First of all, we find that the welfare implication of NDPs
hinges on relative distortions induced by market power of networks and merchant internalization
(MI). Previous literature have also identified these two effects. But, we move one step forwards to
characterize the determinants of comparison between theses two effects, especially in an updated
model. We also find both consumers and merchant obtain zero benefit from using a credit card
when NDPs is in place. Lifting the NDPs will unambiguously increases surplus of both consumers
and merchants.
In addition, we find that retaining the NDPs and applying tourist test regulation will yield the
identical results as when allow surcharges and impose an optimal surcharge cap. We also mimic
the competition between AmEx and Visa (or MasterCard), and their different business models
which are shown in the appendix. We manage to establish an equilibrium where AmEx focuses
on a sector with higher evaluation of transaction services, and with consumers spend heavily (as
for charge cards), and Visa serve boht this high value sector and another low value sector, but
could earn a profit of interests from outstanding balance. Interestingly, the asymmetrical business
models leaves some consumer surplus under the NDPs. Other comparison are similar to the above
analysis.
25
References
Aurazo, J. and Vasquez, J. (2019). Merchant’s card acceptance: An extension of the tourist test
for developing countries. Technical report, Graduate Institute of International and Development
Baxter, W. F. (1983). Bank interchange of transactional paper: Legal and economic perspectives.
Bourguignon, H., Gomes, R., and Tirole, J. (2019). Shrouded transaction costs: must-take cards,
Bourreau, M. and Verdier, M. (2019). Interchange fees and innovation in payment systems. Review
Carlton, D. W. and Winter, R. A. (2018). Vertical most-favored-nation restraints and credit card
Edelman, B. and Wright, J. (2015). Price coherence and excessive intermediation. The Quarterly
Farrell, J. (2006). Efficiency and competition between payment instruments. Review of Network
Economics, 5(1).
Gans, J. S. and King, S. P. (2003). The neutrality of interchange fees in payment systems. Topics
Reisinger, M. and Zenger, H. (2019). Interchange fee regulation and service investments. Interna-
Rochet, J.-C. and Tirole, J. (2002). Cooperation among competitors: Some economics of payment
Rochet, J.-C. and Tirole, J. (2011). Must-take cards: Merchant discounts and avoided costs.
Rysman, M. and Wright, J. (2014). The economics of payment cards. Review of Network Economics,
13(3):303–353.
26
Schmalensee, R. (2002). Payment systems and interchange fees. The Journal of Industrial Eco-
nomics, 50(2):103–122.
Schwartz, M. and Vincent, D. R. (2006). The no surcharge rule and card user rebates: Vertical
Schwartz, M. and Vincent, D. R. (2019). Platform competition with cash-back rebates under no
Tan, H. (2020). The regulation of mercant fees in credit card markets. Journal of Regulatory
Economics, 57(3):258–276.
Tan, H. and Deng, Z. (2020). The no-surcharge rule and surcharging behaviors in credit card
Tan, H. and Wright, J. (2018). A price theory of multi-sided platforms: Comment. The American
Tan, H. and Wright, J. (2020). Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms. Working Paper.
Verdier, M. (2011). Interchange fees in payment card systems: A survey of the literature. Journal
Vickers, J. (2005). Public policy and the invisible price: competition law, regulation and the
Wright, J. (2003). Optimal card payment systems. European Economic Review, 47(4):587–612.
Wright, J. (2012). Why payment card fees are biased against retailers. The RAND Journal of
Economics, 43(4):761–780.
Thus far, we have discussed the monopoly and symmetrical duopoly cases. This subsection will
apply an asymmetrical competition model to mimic the differentiated business strategies between
AmEx card and Visa (or MasterCard). Historically, AmEx distinguishes itself with its “spend-
centric” business model, in which consumers spending heavily are attracted to its network, and the
27
main source of revenue is collected from the merchant discount fees. A majority of AmEx products
are charge cards, and it has built up an reputation with its best known Green, Gold, and Platinum
charge cards. Charge cards enable consumers to spend up to a limit, and pay back the balance in
full after a grace period with no interests. Even if passes a due day of the repayment, a consumer
will be mostly received a reminder of bill payment, and without worrying about monetary penalty.
AmEx cards’ spending limits vary from cards, and also hinges on consumer’s personal financial
status. Carrying an AmEx card is a social status symbol. On the contrary, Visa and MasterCard
carry a “lend-centric” model, with which around half revenue of networks and their issuing banks
are collected from interests of outstanding balance. Although AmEx’s merchant discount fees vary
from sectors, i.e. airlines, hotels, grocery stores, online retailers and among others, AmEx charges
the same level of merchant discount fees to every type of its cards for transaction in a particular
sector. Merchant discount fees of Visa (or MasterCard) credit cards varies across different types of
cards, with a higher merchant discount fees charged to cards with a greater reward program.
In practice, both AmEx’ charge cards and Visa’s credit cards are categorized into a single
relevant market in the antitrust enforcement. In the State of Ohio et al., v. American Express,
585 U.S. [2018] , the relevant market is defined as the market of General purchase credit and
charge (“GPCC”) cards. The district court agreed with the two-sidedness of GPCC card market,
and regarded it consists of at least two separate, but highly interdependent, markets. The two
separate markets include a card issuing market, in which card networks compete over expenditure
basis of cardholders, and a network services market, in which networks compete over merchant
card acceptance. However, the district court applies the rule of reason analysis only on the network
services market. The Appeal and Supreme court think the relevant market should be the card
transactions market, which is two-sided market and compose of cardholder and merchant consumers.
So, we will investigate the competition between AmEx and Visa(or MasterCard) in two-sided
and discuss the competitive effects of business clause in question and consequence of enforcement
practices.
Practically, we observe that AmEx charges the average merchant fee around 3 percent transac-
tion value as of August 2019, about 50 percentage higher than Visa (or MasterCard) does.8 Most
8
Data sources: Visa USA Interchange Reimbursement Fees published on April 13, 2019; MasterCard 2019–2020
U.S. Region Interchange Program and Rates; and Wells Fargo Payment Network Qualification Matrix published on
28
consumers having an AmEx card also carry a Visa or MasterCard card, and around 6.4 million
merchants accept AmEx cards in the U.S., despite that around 3 million merchants, who accept
Visa and MasterCard, chooses to decline AmEx cards.9 To mimic the practice, we assume two
two separate sectors, sell products to two groups of consumers. In the sector bH
S , consumers also
and pay back the outstanding balance at the end of each grace period, as with charge cards. So,
revenue from its lending business with its credit cards, but AmEx is unable to do so because it
mainly issues charge cards which do not carry a credit function. In this setting, each network has
two options. First, set a low merchant fee and serve two sectors. Second, set a high merchant fee
and serve one sector. The trade off between the two options is a higher margins in sector bH
S , and
business is sufficient high such that Visa is always willing to serve the sector bL
S , and hence both
sectors. Notably, this portion profit out of interest does not explicitly enters into the model. But it
will work as an valve in discussion below to sustain an asymmetrical equilibrium, in which AmEx
strategically selects a higher merchant fee and therefore only serve the sector bH
S , and Visa chooses
to serve both sectors. In this situation, AmEx and Visa will charge a merchant fee respectively as
AmEx : pS = pH H H H
S = bS + vB pB (41)
V isa : pS = pH L L L L
S = pS = bS + vB pB (42)
That is to say, Visa charges the merchant fee according to the acceptance condition in sector bL
S,
sector, only visa serves and acts as a monopolist. The solutions with the NSR clause are given as
in quantity. AmEx sets a merchant fee internalizing the consumer surplus in sector bH
S , while Visa
29
has to set a merchant fee accounting for the consumer surplus from the sector bL
S . Their profit
where
L
1
vB pL L
B = (1 + bS − c) (45)
2
H
B I
vB pH
B = (q + q J ) (46)
2
The solutions are listed in column one of Table 1. AmEx charges a higher merchant fee than Visa
H pH = 1 (1 + 6B + 4bH + 3bL − 7c), and it
does, and this can be seen from results below where vB B 12 S S
L pL = 1 (1 + bL − c) given B > 1 and bH > bL . However, due to the no steering
is greater than vB B 2 S S S
H
pH H H L L L H
p = u − t + DB B (σvB pB + (1 − σ)(vB pB + bS − bS )) (47)
qI
Where σ = q I +q J
is the ratio of AmEx’s demand to total demand. As the no steering constraint
clauses imposed, the merchant is unable to price differently steering purchases towards the least
costly payment means, and she has to charge a uniform price of product such that the extra cost
H pH for its sale with
is evened out for each transaction. The merchant will bear extra cost of vB B
L pL + bL − bH for the sale with Visa cards. Therefore, she
AmEx cards, and bear extra cost of vB B S S
AmEx, expecting that the merchant’s acceptance, charges a merchant fee such that the consumer
surplus is fulled absorbed. But the Visa charges a lower merchant fee to secure the customers in
sector bL
S , and it makes the fully extraction not occur. AmEx is in a better position to absorb the
surplus from merchant side. This implies that it has lower cost in providing services on consumer
side, and in turn suggests that it will provide a higher quantity of services than Visa does. Solving
30
From the results in the sector bH
S , we can easily verify that, compared to its counterpart, AmEx
π I > π I . The consumer surplus above stands for the total realized surplus in sector bH
S . A part
by consumers for each unit purchase of payment. Interestingly, the asymmetrical equilibrium
from business models of networks yields some “left over” surplus to consumers – a better position
compared to the case of symmetrical case, where consumer surplus is fully extracted. The consumer
sectors. 10
Under the surcharging regime, both merchants accept credit card payments. The duopoly
platforms compete upstream subject to surcharges imposed by the monopoly merchant in each
sector. Specifically, each platform set the same quality to sell to each sector, since it can not
distinguish between the two sectors. The inverse total demands in each sector are given as
1
pH H
B +s = (B − q I − q J ), pL L I
B +s =1−q −q
J
(48)
B
1 − bL
S − pB + pS B − bH
S − pB + pS
sL = , sH = (49)
2 2
Plugging the above two equations into profit function, we have platform’s problem as
max π I = B + bH I J
− c q I + 1 + bL I J
− c qI
S − 2B q + q S −2 q +q (50)
qI
max π J = B + bH I J
− c q J + 1 + bL I J
− c qJ
S − 2B q + q S −2 q +q (51)
qJ
31
It can be easily verified that both networks earns higher profits under the NSR clause. The
merchant earns positive profit under surcharging regime compared to zero under otherwise. Con-
the comparison of total surplus remains unclear, and they are an empirical questions. However,
with the modeling above, practitioners can easily compare the welfare with those parameter values.
Sector bH
S NSR SR
IH 1
(6B + 8bH L 1
1 + B + bH L
q 6B S − bS − 5c − 1) 6(1+B) S + bS − 2c
q JH 1
(1 − 2bH L 1
1 + B + bH L
3B S + 3bS − c) 6(1+B) S + bS − 2c
pIH
S bH 1 H
S + 12 (1 + 6B + 4bS + 3bS
L
− 7c) NA
pJH L 1 L
S bS + 2 1 + bS − c NA
pH
B
1
6B
(−1 − 4bH
S − 3bL
S + 7c) NA
H
ρ NA B + bH
S − 2BDB
π IH 1
72B
(6B − 1 + 8bH L
S − 3bS − 5c)2 NA
JH
π 1
9B
(−1 + 2bH L
S − 3bS + c)
2
NA
MH
2
π 0 B
9(1+B)2
1 + B + bH L
S + bS − 2c
2
CS H 1
72B 3
(1 + 6B 2 + 4bH L
S + 3bS − 7c)
2 B
18(1+B)2
1 + B + bH L
S + bS − 2c
Sector bL
S NSR SR
IL 1
1 + B + bH L
q 0 6(1+B) S + bS − 2c
q JL 1
− 2bH L 1
1 + B + bH L
3B
(1 S + 3bS − c) 6(1+B) S + bS − 2c
pIL
S NA NA
pJL bL + 12 bL
S S 1+ S −c NA
pL
B c − bL
S NA
ρL NA 1 + bL
S − 2DB
π IL 0 NA
JL
2
π 1
2
1+ bL
S −c NA
ML
2
π 0 B
9(1+B)2
1 + B + bH L
S + bS − 2c
2
CS L 0 1
18(1+B)2
1 + B + bH L
S + bS − 2c
Calculated and simulated by the authors. “NA” implies either the results are not applicable, or the
expression equations are too long to fix it the table.
32