Hirsch & Mueller 2020 - Ilrr - Firm Wage Premia Germany
Hirsch & Mueller 2020 - Ilrr - Firm Wage Premia Germany
KEYWORDs: firm wage premium, industrial relations, trade unions, works councils, bargaining power, rent
sharing, wage inequality, Germany
persistent firm wage premia are at odds with a competitive labor market in
which firms consider wages as given. Instead, the premia point at substantial
employment rents that are split between workers and firms.
Differences in firm wage premia may stem, on the one hand, from
differences in the firms’ surpluses to be shared between workers and firms
and, on the other hand, from differences in firms’ bargaining power in the
wage-formation process. Such differences in bargaining power, in turn, may
be shaped by firms’ industrial relations regime. Specifically, we expect
workers’ bargaining power to be higher when unions are present or when
worker codetermination exists through works councils. Conditional on the
amount of rents to be shared among the firm and its workforce, the exis-
tence of these institutions should thus yield higher firm wage premia. We
would arrive at the same predictions using an efficiency wage model, such
as Shapiro and Stiglitz’s (1984) canonical shirking model. In such a setting,
unions and works councils are expected to protect workers from being
dismissed by employers (as is found empirically for works councils by
Hirsch, Schank, and Schnabel 2010), thereby forcing employers to pay
higher efficiency wages in order to incentivize workers to exert effort. We
consider this effect of union and works council existence to be an improve-
ment in workers’ implicit bargaining position. We therefore regard this set-
ting as similar in spirit to the rent-sharing setting with explicit bargaining
whereby union presence or works council existence are expected to
strengthen workers’ bargaining power directly via collective action.
Evidence on the sources of firm wage premia in general and, more spe-
cifically, on the role of bargaining power is still sparse, however. In particu-
lar, we lack evidence on how firm wage premia differ between firms bound
by collective agreements and uncovered firms and on how plant-level code-
termination affects wage premia. One notable exception is Card, Heining,
and Kline (2013; CHK hereafter) who applied the AKM approach to West
German data. They were not only the first to document that rising disper-
sion in firm wage premia or, as they put it, rising workplace wage inequality,
is a major contributor to increasing wage inequality in West Germany, but
they also provided some suggestive evidence that the dispersion of premia is
larger among those firms that are unbound by collective agreements. The
rising dispersion of firm wage premia over time may thus reflect the falling
prevalence of collective agreements or works councils provided that these
institutions compress the premia distribution, which seems plausible. That
said, we lack evidence whether bargaining coverage or worker codetermina-
tion exerts a differential impact on firm wage premia along the premia dis-
tribution. Another study, by Goldschmidt and Schmieder (2017), found
that domestic outsourcing of cleaning, security, and logistics services led to
more dispersed firm wage premia that, in turn, explained 9% of the rise in
overall wage inequality in Germany. Changes in jobs’ industrial relations
regime triggered by outsourcing may to some extent be the source of this
finding.
FIRM WAGE PREMIA, IR, AND RENT SHARING IN GERMANY 1121
workers, may select into uncovered plants that are more flexible when
deciding on plant wage premia. Or, workers may sort into covered plants if
these have larger rents to be distributed.
Moreover, since collective agreements are predominantly concluded at
the sectoral level, they not only allow plants to save on transaction costs
(and thus to save on total labor costs despite higher wage bills) but also
offer plants employing workers with high bargaining power the opportunity
of hiding behind the average employer in collective wage negotiations. On
account of this ‘‘hide effect,’’ plants that employ workers with high
bargaining power may even pay lower wage premia when covered by a col-
lective agreement, thereby hiding behind the collective wage.2 We thus
expect the impact of collective bargaining coverage to be less pronounced
(or even negative) in the upper part of the wage premium distribution than
in the lower part, thereby compressing the premium distribution.
Investigating plant wage premia instead of wages permits us to test for these
possibilities.
Beyond collective bargaining typically conducted at the sectoral level, the
second backbone of Germany’s dual system of industrial relations is defined
by worker codetermination at the plant level through works councils, the
German counterpart of the workplace union in other countries. Works
councils are mandatory but not automatic in all plants with at least five per-
manent workers, since setting up a works council requires three workers or
a union representative to initiate an election procedure in the plant. In
2015, 42% of workers in West Germany worked in the 9% of plants with a
works council (Ellguth and Kohaut 2016).
Although works councils are formally independent of unions, in practice
most works councilors are union members (Behrens 2009). The size of the
works council is an increasing function of the plant’s employment level, and
the entire cost of the works council apparatus is borne by the employer,
with works councilors being exempted from work once certain plant size
threshold levels are reached. Yet, works councils are absent in many eligible
plants. Because actions by employers to block the introduction of a works
council are legally prohibited, since works councilors enjoy additional
employment protection, and since the time spent on work as a works coun-
cilor counts as regular working time, this absence implies that introducing a
works council imposes some cost on workers. This cost comprises, for
instance, the costs of becoming exposed as a works councilor, as many
employers have reservations against works councils, as well as the costs of
actively representing one’s colleagues’ interests and being personally
responsible for the negotiation outcomes. For a recent discussion of the
2
This possibility of hiding behind a sector-level collective agreement oriented toward less productive
and usually smaller employers in an industry has been recognized before in the industrial relations litera-
ture (e.g., Kohaut and Schnabel 2003). In a case study of a large firm in the German metalworking
industry, Arrowsmith, Marginson, and Sisson (2003) reported that the firm is committed to sector-level
bargaining because it feels that the powerful metalworkers’ union would achieve more otherwise.
1124 ILR REVIEW
On the other hand, if workers facing a powerful employer, who are arguably
to be found in the lower part of the premium distribution, use plant-level
codetermination to ensure a minimum premium level, works council exis-
tence will compress the premia distribution from below. We regard it an
empirical question which of these two effects dominates.
3
The IAB Establishment Panel is among the first large-scale establishment surveys in Germany. As the
first wave of a newly established survey may suffer from a variety of issues, such as inexperienced
interviewers and interviewees and uncertainty regarding the extent of non-response, we decided against
using the first wave in our analysis. Including it, however, leaves our regression results qualitatively
unchanged.
1126 ILR REVIEW
allow us to merge the plant fixed effects from CHK, which will be our mea-
sure of plant wage premia (as detailed below). We further make use of the
administrative data to construct a consistent sector classification as put for-
ward by Eberle, Jacobebbinghaus, Ludsteck, and Witter (2011) and use the
information on plant age and detailed plant location contained in these
data. To minimize the impact of possible outliers in the survey data, we
truncate the bottom and top 1% of the distributions of value added per
worker and capital costs per worker within any two-digit industry–year cell.
For the same reason, we truncate the top 1% of the distribution of the wage
bill per worker and, similar to CHK, dropped plants that pay less than e 10
per worker as daily wage in the administrative data.
The IAB Establishment Panel oversamples large plants in all waves of the
survey. Because the number of sampled plants rises over time, and since this
rise is attributable to increased numbers of medium-sized and small plants,
the extent of oversampling of large plants drops over time. This change not
only leads to a drop in average plant size but also affects other plant
characteristics as, for example, smaller plants are on average less productive
and pay lower wages than do larger plants. For this reason, we present
results from population-weighted samples only. Besides, information on
plants’ wage cushions and on the distinction between sector-level and firm-
level bargaining, which would be of potential interest for our investigation,
is not available for some early waves of the survey data.4 Lest we lose too
many observations, we do not use this information.5
4
Information on collective bargaining coverage and works council existence is available for the first
wave of the IAB Establishment Panel but is missing in some of the following waves. Since both variables
are highly persistent over time, we imputed missing values with the value of adjacent observations for the
same plant provided that these are unchanged. A minor complication arises because in the 1993 wave,
which we use together with the 1995 wave to impute missing information on wage bargaining in the
1994 wave, the survey asked for the existence of collective agreements at the sector but not at the firm
level. Because of the very high prevalence of collective wage bargaining in sectors having a collective
agreement in 1993 and since we condition on an unchanged collective wage bargaining status in 1995,
we believe that our imputation strategy does not introduce serious measurement error, in spite of the
imprecise question in the 1993 wave.
5
As suggested by a referee, we checked whether our results change when we exclude from our sample
the small number of plants in which collective agreements were negotiated at the firm level. As shown in
the final robustness check in Online Appendix C, our results did not change.
FIRM WAGE PREMIA, IR, AND RENT SHARING IN GERMANY 1127
ð2Þ QR = VAD xN rK
where VAD denotes the plant’s value added, that is, sales net of the value of
intermediates; x denotes workers’ outside wage; N denotes the plant’s num-
ber of workers; r denotes the competitive rental price of capital, which we
compute from the plant’s capital stock and in so doing distinguish between
prices for debt and prices for equity at the sector level; and K denotes the
plant’s capital stock.6
6
The IAB data do not contain information on debt and equity financing at the plant level. We there-
fore use the sector-level information provided by Aswath Damodaran at http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/
~adamodar/. Specifically, we assess data on the ‘‘costs of capital by industry sector’’ for Europe issued on
January 5, 2016. Using additional data on the long-run treasury bond rate for Germany gives an average
rental rate of capital of 10.8% during 1994–1996, 9.2% during 1997–2002, and 8.1% during 2003–2009.
In contrast to the quasi rent definition in Equation (2), workers and employers may split rents before
deducting the capital costs. Following the approach outlined in Card, Devicienti, and Maida (2014), we
did not find evidence for bargaining over the competitive returns to capital, which is in line with their
findings for Italy.
FIRM WAGE PREMIA, IR, AND RENT SHARING IN GERMANY 1129
separately for each of the three time intervals 1994–1996, 1997–2002, and
2003–2009, for which CHK provide worker and plant effects that can be
wage
merged to the establishment survey data. In Equation (3), N s is the aver-
age plant-level wage per worker in the respective one-digit sector, aj is the
average CHK worker effect (log wage component) in plant j, a s is the aver-
age CHK worker effect in the one-digit sector, us10 is the 10th percentile of
the distribution of the CHK plant effects in the one-digit sector, and u s is
the average CHK plant effect in the one-digit sector.7
In Equation (3), the term aj a s captures the deviation (in logs) in
worker quality between plant j and the sector average and thus accounts for
unobserved ability differences of employers’ workforces. Yet, note that CHK
estimate worker and plant effects separately for male and female workers
and thus the level of both worker and plant effects cannot be meaning-
fully compared across the genders. As a consequence, computing average
plant-level worker (plant) effects by simply averaging over the worker
(plant) effects at the plant level would not account for differences in the
gender composition of the workforce, and thus such an aggregation
would be uninformative on the average worker (plant) effect that mirrors
the average workforce ability (the plant wage premium). We therefore
purge within each year–gender cell the year–gender mean of the worker
(plant) effect from the individual worker (plant) effect and use these
demeaned CHK effects when computing the average worker (plant)
effect at the plant level.
Besides, CHK calculate worker effects for full-time workers only. Hence,
aj a s is unknown for part-time workers, who make up 14% of the workers
in our sample. Under the assumption that full-time workers and part-time
workers holding jobs at the same plant did not differ in aj a s , that is
aj a s FT = aj a s PT , our measure of workers’ outside options would
not depend on the share of part-time workers in the plant’s workforce. We
impose this assumption in the following, and we provide additional
explanations and checks of robustness in Online Appendix A.
The outside options of plants’ workers also depend on the wage premia
paid by possible future
employers. In Equation (3), subtracting the term
s us10 from log wage
u N + aj a s means subtracting the spread between
s
the average CHK plant effect in the respective one-digit sector and the 10th
7
As we discussed, previous studies typically use average industry wages, that is, the first component in
Equation (3), as their measure of workers’ outside options and thus account for neither the differences
in the quality of workforces nor the spread of plant wage premia in the respective sector.
1130 ILR REVIEW
8
One objection to our approach is that some bargaining models consider receiving unemployment
benefits rather than holding alternative jobs as the relevant outside option available to workers. Note,
however, that the wage cut induced by subtracting u s us10 in Equation (3) roughly mimics the gap
between continued wage payments and receipt of unemployment benefits. At the end of our observa-
tional window, the replacement rate of the German unemployment insurance was 60–67% of the net
wage in the previous employment, which corresponds well with the average u s us10 of –0.37 in our
sample.
FIRM WAGE PREMIA, IR, AND RENT SHARING IN GERMANY 1131
existence WOCOj , on plant j’s quasi rent QRj calculated as in Equation (2)
to control for plant performance, and on a rich set of additional plant-level
controls.9 Our baseline specification is thus given by
9
As an alternative measure of the plant wage premium, we also experimented with using the differ-
ence between the average plant-level wage bill per worker net of the plant-level outside options of
workers. Note that this alternative measure is highly correlated with the CHK plant wage effect and using
it as alternative regressand did not change any of our conclusions. For the sake of comparability with the
existing literature, such as CHK, though, we decided against using this alternative measure in our main
specifications.
10
Apart from these controls, other plant characteristics contained in the IAB Establishment Panel
might be of potential interest, such as information on plants’ export activity, foreign ownership, the wage
cushion, or whether there exist formal profit-sharing agreements. Yet, including these variables would
lead to a massive drop in observations and is thus not viable in our application as some of them have a
considerable extent of missing values and others were completely absent in some of the waves of the sur-
vey. As stressed by a referee, though, exporters have been shown to pay higher wages compared to
nonexporters (e.g., Schank, Schnabel, and Wagner 2007, as well as Macis and Schivardi 2016) so that not
controlling for exporter status in the plant wage premia regressions may arouse concerns. Reassuringly,
running OLS wage premium regressions that control for exporting activity on the reduced sample where
this piece of information is available leaves the coefficients of the industrial relations dummies and the
quasi rent almost unchanged compared to Table 4. We therefore think that neglecting this control is
unlikely to introduce bias in the estimates of interest.
1132 ILR REVIEW
Notes: IAB Establishment Panel, 1994–2009, West Germany. Final regression sample. Weighted using
sample weights. SD, standard deviation.
Table 2. Standard Deviations of the Plant Wage Effects in CHK and LIAB Data
CHK (worker level, male workers only) 0.172 0.194 0.230 0.058
LIAB (plant level, final sample, weighted) 0.202 0.221 0.262 0.060
Notes: The first row refers to table III in CHK. The second row refers to our final sample for West
Germany encompassing the years 1994–2009 that aggregates male and female plant wage effects from
CHK at plant level in the LIAB data and weights the data using the sample weights of the IAB
Establishment Panel. CHK, Card, Heining, and Kline (2013); LIAB, Linked employer–employee data
set of the Institute for Employment Research.
the premia as well as their first and ninth deciles and their median on the
same set of regressors as in Equation (4).
Sample Description
For selective descriptive statistics on our final regression samples in the
three time intervals 1994–1996, 1997–2002, and 2003–2009, for which CHK
provide separate plant wage effects, see Table 1. We see a strong decline in
union coverage and, less so, in works council prevalence. Table 2 compares
the dispersion of the CHK plant wage effects at the worker level, that is, as
FIRM WAGE PREMIA, IR, AND RENT SHARING IN GERMANY 1133
Notes: IAB Establishment Panel, 1994–2009, West Germany, and CHK plant wage effects provided by
Card, Heining, and Kline (2015). Final regression sample; weighted using sample weights. Numbers
shown are dispersion measures of the plant wage effects. For example, the 90–10 gap refers to the
difference between the ninth and the first decile of the distribution of the CHK plant wage effects.
Figure 1. Kernel Density Plots of the Demeaned CHK Plant Wage Effects in West Germany
in the 1994–1996, 1997–2002, and 2003–2009 Periods
in the original CHK article, with the dispersion in our final regression sam-
ple (using the sample weights of the IAB Establishment Panel). Notably, the
dispersion of the CHK plant effects at the plant level is similar to their dis-
persion at the worker level. Further, at both levels of aggregation their stan-
dard deviation rises by approximately 6 log points, or roughly one-third,
during our observational window, which reflects the rise in workplace wage
heterogeneity at the heart of CHK’s contribution.
The rise in the dispersion of wage premia over time is also evident in
Figure 1, which shows kernel density plots of the demeaned wage premia
for the three time intervals. Notably, not only does the spread of premia
increase over time but also the lower tail of the distribution seems to widen
more than its upper tail. This latter finding is further substantiated by Table
3, which reports several dispersion measures of the wage premia and their
1134 ILR REVIEW
Notes: IAB Establishment Panel, 1994–2009, West Germany, and CHK plant wage effects provided by
Card, Heining, and Kline (2015). Weighted using sample weights. The regressand is the CHK plant
wage effect. The control variables consist of 32 district dummies (Regierungsbezirke), 62 two-digit sector
dummies, four plant-size dummies, four plant-age dummies, a dummy for a single plant (as opposed to
a plant belonging to a multi-branch company), and the percentages of women as well as part-time
workers in the plant’s workforce. Standard errors (in parentheses) are clustered at the plant level. OLS,
ordinary least squares.
***; **; * indicate statistical significance at the 1; 5; 10% level.
evolution over time. What emerges is that in all three time intervals the pre-
mium inequality is stronger in the lower part of the premium distribution
than in the upper part, as is reflected by the larger 50–10 gap vis-á-vis the
90–50 gap. Further, all measures of wage premia dispersion rise steadily
over time, with dispersion at the lower part of the distribution increasing
most. Between the 1994–1996 and the 2003–2009 intervals, the 90–10 gap
widens by 13.5 log points, with 8.1 log points originating in the rising 50–10
gap, but just 5.4 log points in the increasing 90–50 gap. These observations
suggest that candidate explanations for the rising wage premia dispersion
are likely to be found among those factors influencing the lower tail of the
premium distribution.
Results
OLS Wage Premium Regressions
Table 4 presents the core results of a group of OLS regressions in which we
regress the CHK plant wage effect on dummies for collective bargaining
coverage and works council existence, on the plant’s quasi rent to control
for the surplus to be split between the employer and the workers, and the
additional controls detailed above. When pooling observations for the
entire observation period 1994–2009, works council existence is associated
with a sizeable increase in the premium that is statistically significant at the
1% level.11 In plants with a works council, the wage premium is 5 log points
11
Note that plant wage premia are estimated by CHK using the universe of German plants (rather
than a mere sample). Hence, sampling error is not a concern in our application and we thus do not have
to correct the standard errors of our regression coefficients.
FIRM WAGE PREMIA, IR, AND RENT SHARING IN GERMANY 1135
larger, holding constant quasi rents and the other controls included. The
association between collective bargaining coverage and the wage premium
is less pronounced and only statistically significant at the 5% level. Plants
bound by a collective agreement pay an additional premium of 1.9 log
points, ceteris paribus, which is a bit more than one-third of the works coun-
cil effect.
Turning to our control for plant performance, the relation between the
wage premium and the quasi rent is statistically significant at the 1% level.
An increase in the quasi rent per worker by e 100,000 is associated with a
rise in the wage premium by 6.3 log points, which means that a rise in the
quasi rent by one standard deviation (i.e., roughly e 40,000 per worker)
comes along with an increase in the premium by just one-ninth of a stan-
dard deviation (i.e., approximately 2.5 log points). Or, to make our result
more comparable to existing studies on rent sharing, one may note that the
average quasi rent per worker is about e 22,000 so that a 1% increase in the
quasi rent is associated with an increase in the plant wage premium by
0.014% for the average worker. This rent-sharing elasticity is at the lower
end of the range of estimates of earlier studies surveyed by Card et al.
(2018). Yet, one should keep in mind that those studies analyzed wages
rather than wage premia and may thus suffer from worker sorting, thereby
producing upward-biased rent-sharing elasticities (Card et al. 2018).
Although statistically significant, we conclude that the association between
plants’ quasi rent and the plant wage premium is insignificant from an eco-
nomic point of view. Overall, whereas plant performance seems to exert just
a minor influence on the level of plant wage premia, plants’ industrial
relations regime plays a much larger role, in particular plant-level worker
codetermination through works councils.12
Since the influence of industrial relations on the average wage premium
is conditional on the plant’s quasi rent, our findings suggest that union
presence and works council existence increase workers’ bargaining power
in that they raise the share of the surplus going to workers.13 An alternative
12
As suggested by a referee, we also checked whether the association between the mean plant wage
premium and the quasi rent changes with plant’s industrial relations regime by interacting the dummies
for works council existence and collective bargaining coverage with the demeaned quasi rent. Doing so
had no impact on the estimated coefficients of the two dummies, so that the impact of industrial
relations is the same as before for plants with an average quasi rent (for results, consult Online
Appendix D). We further found that the interaction terms are negative and similar in magnitude, albeit
modest in size, suggesting that the impact of works councils and collective bargaining agreements on the
plant wage premium is somewhat smaller in plants in which there are more rents to be distributed.
Because these plants are plants with higher wage premia, this result is consistent with our later findings
that both institutions seem to ensure a minimum wage premium level in low-premium plants, as
reported in our RIF wage premium regressions section.
13
As we previously discussed, a similar explanation could be given based on efficiency wage models in
which union presence or works council existence forces employers to pay higher efficiency wages to
incentivize workers, who are thus in a better implicit bargaining position. We regard this explanation as
similar in spirit to one based on explicit bargaining between the employer and the workforce whereby
the existence of both institutions increase workers’ bargaining power directly via collective action.
1136 ILR REVIEW
explanation for employer wage premia pursued in the literature are com-
pensating wage differentials, although the conventional view is that compen-
sating differentials are rather unimportant (e.g., Hornstein, Krusell, and
Violante 2011). That said, a recent study by Sorkin (2018) building on the
AKM framework to measure the employer wage components argued that
compensating wage differentials are one important source of employer
wage premia. Could our findings, then, reflect compensating differentials
rather than differences in workers’ bargaining power related to the indus-
trial relations regime?
According to the exit–voice model of unionism by Freeman and Medoff
(1984), plant-level unions and thus works councils as their German counter-
part play two distinct roles. On the one hand, they act as a collective-voice
institution that enables workers to safely express their dissatisfaction with
certain working conditions instead of quitting the job. If the employer, in
turn, listens to workers’ voice and improves on working conditions accord-
ingly, costly turnover will be avoided, worker morale will be higher, and
labor productivity may rise. On the other hand, works councils raise
workers’ bargaining power and may engage in rent-seeking activities at the
detriment of the employer.
In line with works councils’ collective-voice role, several studies have
documented that quits are lower in plants in which a works council is pres-
ent (e.g., Hirsch et al. 2010, as well as Pfeifer 2010), suggesting that working
conditions are better in these plants and that works councils positively influ-
ence workers’ job satisfaction. In light of this evidence, it seems implausible
that works councils give rise to positive compensating differentials, implying
that the positive influence of works council existence on employer wage
premia found may even understate its impact on workers’ bargaining
power. The same line of argument applies to union presence, although we
have the impression that compensating differentials are even less plausible
when it comes to collective bargaining that is typically conducted at the sec-
toral level as opposed to plant-level worker codetermination through works
councils.
In the subset of plants in our sample for which we have information on
average working hours, we also checked whether higher hours accompany
higher plant wage premia, which would then arguably compensate workers
for long working hours. In line with earlier evidence for Portugal by Card
et al. (2016), we found no significant relationship between working hours
and wage premia. We see this non-finding as further evidence that compen-
sating differentials are unlikely to be of much importance for our main
estimates, particularly because our regression controls for an extensive set
of covariates, such as sector and plant location, that are likely to pick up a
large part of the possible differences in compensating differentials across
plants.
When we run separate regressions for the three time intervals 1994–1996,
1997–2002, and 2003–2009, for which CHK provide separate plant wage
FIRM WAGE PREMIA, IR, AND RENT SHARING IN GERMANY 1137
effects, we find that the impact of works council existence and collective
bargaining coverage on the plant wage premium is largest in the latest
2003–2009 interval. Specifically, the additional wage premium when work-
ing for a plant bound by a collective agreement is near zero in the earlier
intervals and amounts to 3.5 log points in this latter period, which turns out
to be statistically significant at the 1% level. Similarly, the additional wage
premium associated with a works council rises somewhat over time, as does
the relation between the plant’s quasi rent and the wage premium, which
nevertheless remains very small in magnitude. Besides, the potential impact
of the increase in the quasi rent coefficient on the evolution of premia
inequality is balanced to some extent by a drop in the dispersion of quasi
rents across plants, which is lowest (roughly 20% less compared to the inter-
mediate 1997–2002 interval) at the end of our observational window.
In summary, we find that plants with a works council and plants bound
by collective agreements pay larger wage premia conditionally on plants’
quasi rent, which suggests that these institutions raise workers’ bargaining
power thereby allowing them to extract a larger share of a given surplus.
Our results further show that the influence of industrial relations on the
average plant wage premium rises over time and is most pronounced at the
end of our observational window. In terms of the level of the plant wage
premium, where one is working thus gains in importance over time.
As plant wage premia have also become more dispersed over time, our
findings, in turn, lead to the question of whether recent trends in industrial
relations, such as the rise of the so-called codetermination-free zone
with neither collective bargaining nor works councils (for details, see
Oberfichtner and Schnabel 2019), may have contributed to the steady rise
in the dispersion of wage premia across plants observed by CHK and also
present in our data (see Tables 2 and 3). But before we turn to this ques-
tion, we have to check how industrial relations relate to the wage premia
dispersion.
Variance
Collective wage agreement –0.013*** –0.015 0.001 –0.014*
(0.005) (0.014) (0.007) (0.008)
Works council 0.018*** 0.003 0.020** 0.016*
(0.005) (0.011) (0.009) (0.008)
Quasi rent per worker (in e 100,000) –0.010** –0.007 –0.009** –0.013
(0.004) (0.008) (0.004) (0.010)
First decile
Collective wage agreement 0.051** 0.004 0.010 0.071**
(0.024) (0.068) (0.050) (0.035)
Works council 0.007 0.022 –0.017 0.051*
(0.019) (0.048) (0.040) (0.027)
Quasi rent per worker (in e 100,000) 0.069*** 0.057 0.067 0.081**
(0.023) (0.056) (0.048) (0.035)
Median
Collective wage agreement 0.020** –0.002 0.018 0.037***
(0.008) (0.023) (0.012) (0.011)
Works council 0.071*** 0.056** 0.060*** 0.077***
(0.011) (0.027) (0.017) (0.013)
Quasi rent per worker (in e 100,000) 0.057*** 0.054*** 0.054*** 0.071***
(0.010) (0.018) (0.015) (0.013)
Ninth decile
Collective wage agreement –0.004 –0.037 0.012 0.012
(0.008) (0.028) (0.010) (0.011)
Works council 0.076*** 0.029 0.056*** 0.070***
(0.015) (0.032) (0.019) (0.023)
Quasi rent per worker (in e 100,000) 0.052*** 0.015 0.022** 0.072***
(0.011) (0.017) (0.010) (0.017)
Observations 3,829,441 495,880 1,508,950 1,824,611
Plants (unweighted) 9,054 1,273 4,977 6,079
Notes: IAB Establishment Panel, 1994–2009, West Germany, and CHK plant wage effects provided by
Card, Heining, and Kline (2015). Weighted using sample weights. The regressand is the respective
parameter of the distribution of the CHK plant wage effects. The control variables consist of 32 district
dummies (Regierungsbezirke), 62 two-digit sector dummies, four plant-size dummies, four plant-age
dummies, a dummy for a single plant (as opposed to a plant belonging to a multi-branch company),
and the percentages of women as well as part-time workers in the plant’s workforce. Standard errors (in
parentheses) come from a block bootstrap at plant level with 500 replications. RIF, recentered
influence function.
***; **; * indicate statistical significance at the 1; 5; 10% level.
14
Our finding of a positive within-group effect of both collective agreements and works councils at the
first decile of the wage premium distribution aligns with our earlier results that suggest mean wage
premia are less influenced by these institutions in plants with more rents to be distributed. If unions and
works councils ensure a minimum wage premium level, we expect them to have a larger impact in plants
with small rents that, in turn, are paying low wage premia.
15
Matano and Naticchioni (2017) found a decreasing rent-sharing intensity along the wage distribution
in Italy.
FIRM WAGE PREMIA, IR, AND RENT SHARING IN GERMANY 1141
Conclusions
Linking employer survey data to administrative data for West Germany for
the years 1994–2009, we have investigated how the level and the dispersion
of wage premia across plants depend on their industrial relations regime,
conditional on plant performance. To measure wage premia, we used the
plant wage effects of CHK that stem from an AKM-type two-way fixed-effects
decomposition of individual workers’ log wages. Hence, our wage premium
measure gives the wage premium enjoyed by every worker employed by a
certain plant and accounts for worker sorting on unobservable worker
16
We thank one of our referees for pointing out this problem and for suggesting the two-step
approach by Firpo et al. (2018) as a remedy.
1142 ILR REVIEW
Notes: IAB Establishment Panel, 1994–2009, West Germany, and CHK plant wage effects provided by
Card, Heining, and Kline (2015). Weighted using sample weights. Oaxaca–Blinder decomposition
based on recentered influence function (RIF) regressions of the wage effects variance with 2003–2009
as the reference period, following Firpo, Fortin, and Lemieux’s (2018) two-step approach that performs
the RIF decomposition after reweighting the distribution of covariates in the earlier period to that of
the later period. The control variables consist of 32 district dummies (Regierungsbezirke), 62 two-digit
sector dummies, four plant-size dummies, four plant-age dummies, a dummy for a single plant (as
opposed to a plant belonging to a multi-branch company), and the percentages of women as well as
part-time workers in the plant’s workforce. The estimated propensity score for the reweighting is
obtained from a logit model including all these covariates as well as additional interactions of these with
the industrial relations dummies. Standard errors (in parentheses) come from a block bootstrap at
plant level with 500 replications.
***; **; * indicate statistical significance at the 1; 5; 10% level.
characteristics into plants that may have contaminated prior studies based
on workers’ individual wages rather than plant wage premia. In our econo-
metric analysis, we regressed the plant wage premium on dummies for the
existence of collective agreements and a works council, which mirror the
plant’s industrial relations regime, the plant’s quasi rent per worker as a
performance measure, and a rich set of control variables. As we did for our
wage premium measure, we assessed plant performance such that worker
sorting on unobservable worker characteristics into plants is accounted for
in that we based the quasi rent per worker on the outside options available
to a plant’s workforce making use of both the plant and the worker wage
effects of CHK.
FIRM WAGE PREMIA, IR, AND RENT SHARING IN GERMANY 1143
works council existence widens the distribution at the top. Our reading of
these findings is that collective agreements are primarily used to settle mini-
mum terms and thus yield additional premia in low-premium plants,
whereas workers in plants that pay nontrivial wage premia, who arguably
possess high bargaining power from the outset, use plant-level codetermina-
tion through works councils to foster rent extraction.
Our findings suggest that the widening of the plant wage premium distri-
bution over time observed in our data cannot plausibly be related to
changes in the dispersion of performance across plants or to the drop in
works council prevalence over time. Among the factors we consider in this
study, only the fall in collective bargaining coverage contributes to
explaining the rise in the wage premium dispersion across plants. Our
decomposition analysis documented that falling collective bargaining cover-
age can account for 40% of the part of the rising variance in wage premia
attributable to changing plant characteristics and thus explains 14% of ris-
ing premia dispersion. This finding lends support to the view expressed in
the earlier discussion on the drivers of rising wage inequality that changes
in labor market institutions may be an important part of the story (e.g.,
DiNardo et al. 1996; Card and DiNardo 2002). Yet, we also saw that the
larger part of the rise in the wage premia variance remains unaccounted for
despite the detailed set of explanatory variables in our regressions. Clearly,
further research is needed to shed more light on the likely reasons for the
rising dispersion of wage premia across employers.
References
Abowd, John M., and Laurence Allain. 1996. Compensation structure and product market
competition. Annales d’Économie et de Statistique 11(41/42): 207–17.
Abowd, John M., Francis Kramarz, and David N. Margolis. 1999. High wage workers and high
wage firms. Econometrica 67(2): 251–333.
Abowd, John M., and Thomas Lemieux. 1993. The effects of product market competition on
collective bargaining agreements: The case of foreign competition in Canada. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 108(4): 983–1014.
Abowd, John M., Paul A. Lengermann, and Kevin L. McKinney. 2003. The measurement of
human capital in the U.S. economy. LEHD Program Technical Paper No. TP-2002-09.
Suitland, MD: U.S. Census Bureau.
Addison, John T. 2009. The Economics of Codetermination: Lessons from the German Experience.
New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Addison, John T., Claus Schnabel, and Joachim Wagner. 2001. Works councils in Germany:
Their effects on establishment performance. Oxford Economic Papers 53(4): 659–94.
Addison, John T., Paulino Teixeira, and Thomas Zwick. 2010. German works councils and
the anatomy of wages. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 63(2): 247–70.
Alda, Holga, Stefan Bender, and Hermann Gartner. 2005. The linked employer–employee
dataset created from the IAB Establishment Panel and the process-produced data of the
IAB (LIAB). Schmollers Jahrbuch 125(2): 327–36.
Arrowsmith, James, Paul Marginson, and Keith Sisson. 2003. Externalisation and
internalisation of collective bargaining in Europe: Variation in the role of large compa-
nies. Industrielle Beziehungen 10(3): 363–92.
FIRM WAGE PREMIA, IR, AND RENT SHARING IN GERMANY 1145
Baumgarten, Daniel, Gabriel Felbermayr, and Sybille Lehwald. 2020. Dissecting between-
plant and within-plant wage dispersion — Evidence from Germany. Industrial Relations,
forthcoming.
Behrens, Martin. 2009. Still married after all these years? Union organizing and the role of
works councils in German industrial relations. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 62(3):
275–93.
———. 2013. Arbeitgeberverbände – auf dem Weg in den Dualismus? WSI-Mitteilungen
66(7): 473–81.
Biewen, Martin, and Matthias Seckler. 2019. Unions, internationalization, tasks, firms, and
worker characteristics: A detailed decomposition analysis of rising wage inequality in
Germany. Journal of Economic Inequality 17(4): 461–98.
Bryson, Alex. 2014. Union wage effects: What are the economic implications of union wage
bargaining for workers, firms, and society? IZA World of Labor 1(35): 1–10.
Card, David, Ana Rute Cardoso, Jörg Heining, and Patrick Kline. 2018. Firms and labor mar-
ket inequality: Evidence and some theory. Journal of Labor Economics 36(S1): S13–S70.
Card, David, Ana Rute Cardoso, and Patrick Kline. 2016. Bargaining, sorting, and the gender
wage gap: Quantifying the impact of firms on the relative pay of women. Quarterly Journal
of Economics 131(2): 633–86.
Card, David, Francesco Devicienti, and Agata Maida. 2014. Rent-sharing, holdup, and wages:
Evidence from matched panel data. Review of Economic Studies 81(1): 84–111.
Card, David, and John E. DiNardo. 2002. Skill-biased technological change and rising wage
inequality: Some problems and puzzles. Journal of Labor Economics 20(4): 733–83.
Card, David, Jörg Heining, and Patrick Kline. 2013. Workplace heterogeneity and the rise of
West German wage inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics 128(3): 967–1015.
———. 2015. CHK effects: Version 2. FDZ-Methodenreport 06/2015. Nuremberg: Institute
for Employment Research.
DiNardo, John E., Nicole M. Fortin, and Thomas Lemieux. 1996. Labor market institutions
and the distribution of wages, 1973–1993: A semiparametric approach. Econometrica 64(5):
1001–44.
Dustmann, Christian, Johannes Ludsteck, and Uta Schönberg. 2009. Revisiting the German
wage structure. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(2): 843–81.
Dustmann, Christian, Bernd Fitzenberger, Uta Schönberg, and Alexandra Spitz-Oener. 2014.
From sick man of Europe to economic superstar: Germany’s resurgent economy. Journal
of Economic Perspectives 28(1): 167–88.
Eberle, Johanna, Peter Jacobebbinghaus, Johannes Ludsteck, and Julia Witter. 2011. Genera-
tion of time-consistent industry codes in the face of classification changes: Simple heuris-
tic based on the Establishment History Panel (BHP). FDZ-Methodenreport 05/2011.
Nuremberg: Institute for Employment Research.
Ellguth, Peter, and Susanne Kohaut. 2016. Tarifbindung und betriebliche Interessenver-
tretung: Ergebnisse aus dem IAB-Betriebspanel 2015. WSI-Mitteilungen 69(4): 283–91.
Ellguth, Peter, Susanne Kohaut, and Iris Möller. 2014. The IAB Establishment Panel – Meth-
odological essentials and data quality. Journal for Labour Market Research 47(1–2): 27–41.
Firpo, Sergio, Nicole M. Fortin, and Thomas Lemieux. 2009. Unconditional quantile
regressions. Econometrica 77(3): 953–73.
———. 2018. Decomposing wage differentials using recentered influence function
regressions. Econometrics 6(2): 68–107.
Freeman, Richard B., and James L. Medoff. 1984. What Do Unions Do? New York: Basic Books.
Goldschmidt, Deborah, and Johannes F. Schmieder. 2017. The rise of domestic outsourcing
and the evolution of the German wage structure. Quarterly Journal of Economics 132(3):
1165–217.
Gürtzgen, Nicole. 2009. Rent-sharing and collective bargaining coverage: Evidence from
linked employer–employee data. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 111(2): 323–49.
Hirsch, Boris, and Claus Schnabel. 2014. What can we learn from bargaining models about
union power? The decline in union power in Germany, 1992–2009. Manchester School
82(3): 347–62.
1146 ILR REVIEW
Hirsch, Boris, Thorsten Schank, and Claus Schnabel. 2010. Works councils and separations:
Voice, monopoly, and insurance effects. Industrial Relations 49(4): 566–92.
Hornstein, Andreas, Per Krusell, and Giovanni L. Violante. 2011. Frictional wage dispersion
in search models: A quantitative assessment. American Economic Review 101(7): 2873–98.
Jung, Sven, and Claus Schnabel. 2011. Paying more than necessary? The wage cushion in
Germany. Labour 25(2): 182–97.
Kohaut, Susanne, and Claus Schnabel. 2003. Zur Erosion des Flächentarifvertrags: Ausmaß,
Einflussfaktoren und Gegenmaßnahmen. Industrielle Beziehungen 10(2): 193–219.
Macis, Mario, and Fabiano Schivardi. 2016. Exports and wages: Rent sharing, workforce com-
position, or returns to skills? Journal of Labor Economics 34(4): 945–78.
Matano, Alessia, and Paolo Naticchioni. 2017. The extent of rent sharing along the wage dis-
tribution. British Journal of Industrial Relations 55(4): 751–77.
Mueller, Steffen. 2008. Capital stock approximation using firm level panel data. Jahrbücher für
Nationalökonomie und Statistik 228(4): 357–71.
———. 2011. Works councils and firm profits revisited. British Journal of Industrial Relations
49(s1): s27–s43.
———. 2012. Works councils and establishment productivity. ILR Review 65(4): 880–98.
Mueller, Steffen, and Jens Stegmaier. 2017. The dynamic effects of works councils on plant
productivity: First evidence from panel data. British Journal of Industrial Relations 55(2):
372–95.
———. 2020. Why is there resistance to works councils in Germany? An economic perspec-
tive. Economic and Industrial Democracy, forthcoming.
Oberfichtner, Michael, and Claus Schnabel. 2019. The German model of industrial relations:
(Where) does it still exist? Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 239(1): 5–37.
Pfeifer, Christian. 2010. Works councils, union bargaining and quits in Germany. Economic
and Industrial Democracy 32(2): 243–60.
Schank, Thorsten, Claus Schnabel, and Joachim Wagner. 2007. Do exporters really pay
higher wages? First evidence from linked employer–employee data. Journal of International
Economics 72(1): 52–74.
Shapiro, Carl, and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1984. Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline
device. American Economic Review 74(3): 433–44.
Sorkin, Isaac. 2018. Ranking firms using revealed preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics
133(3): 1331–93.
Van Reenen, John. 1996. The creation and capture of rents: Wages and innovation in a
panel of U.K. companies. Quarterly Journal of Economics 111(1): 195–226.