Unit III Answers To Extra Practice Questions
Unit III Answers To Extra Practice Questions
CHAPTER 9
1. Define the consumption and saving schedules.
2. Explain how consumption and saving are related to disposable income in the
aggregate expenditures model.
Since saving is income not spent, it is also directly related to income and will be
an increasing proportion of income as income rises. At very low levels of
income when consumption exceeds income, saving will be negative or
dissaving occurs. [text: E pp. 152-153; MA pp. 152-153]
3. Complete the following table assuming that (a) MPS = 1/5, (b) there is no
government and all saving is personal saving.
Level of output
Level of output
275 280 –5
300 300 0
325 320 5
350 340 10
375 360 15
400 380 20
Level of output
Level of output
160 160 0
190 180 10
220 200 20
250 220 30
6. What are the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) and marginal propensity
to save (MPS)? How are the two concepts related? How are the two concepts
related to the consumption and saving functions?
(b) If income rises to $10,000 and they plan to save $2,800, what are MPS and
MPC?
(c) Did the family’s APC rise or fall with their increase in income?
Level of output
and income
(a) Using the below graphs, show the consumption and saving schedules
graphically.
(b) Locate the break-even level of income. How is it possible for households
to dissave at very low income levels?
(c) If the proportion of total income consumed decreases and the proportion
saved increases as income rises, explain both verbally and graphically how the
MPC and MPS can be constant at various levels of income.
Level of output
and income
(b) The break-even level of income is 520 where saving equals zero.
Households dissave by borrowing or by dipping into accumulated savings. [text:
E pp. 153-155; MA pp. 153-155]
(c) The MPC and MPS represent the slopes of the consumption and savings
schedules respectively. The fact that MPC and MPS are constant means that
the schedules will be straight-line graphs. However, the slope can be constant
and still not be a constant proportion of income as represented on the
horizontal axis. In fact, the only time the MPC and the APC would be the same
would be along lines emanating from the origin.
Level of output
and income
(a) What is the break-even level of income? How is it possible for households
to dissave at very low income levels?
(b) If the proportion of total income consumed decreases and the proportion
saved increases as income rises, explain how the MPC and MPS can be
constant at various levels of income.
Level of output
and income
(GDP = DI) Consumption Saving APC APS MPC MPS
(a) The break-even level of income is 125 where saving equals zero.
Households dissave by borrowing or by dipping into accumulated savings. [text:
E pp. 152-155; MA: pp. 153-155]
(b) The MPC and MPS represent the slopes of the consumption and savings
schedules, respectively. The fact that MPC and MPS are constant means that
the schedules will be straight-line graphs. However, the slope can be constant
and still not be a constant proportion of income as represented on the
horizontal axis. In fact, the only time the MPC and the APC would be the same
would be along the 45-degree line where the slope is equal to 1 and the ratio of
spending to income is equal to 1 at all levels.
10. List five factors that could shift the consumption schedule.
11. What is the effect of increase in wealth on the consumption and saving schedules?
When wealth increases, it shifts the consumption schedule upward as people consume more at each level
of disposable income. There is an opposite effect on saving. The saving schedule shifts downward at
each level of disposable income because people save less. [text: E pp. 156-157; MA pp. 156-157]
New 12. (Consider This) What is a reverse wealth effect? Why did it not have much of an effect on the U.S.
economy during the stock market bubble in the 2000–2002 period?
A reverse wealth effect occurs when there is a significant drop in consumer wealth that will shift the
consumption schedule downward. Even though there was a significant loss of consumer wealth in the
U.S. stock market decline of 2000–2002, there was little or no reverse wealth effect—consumption
spending stayed relatively stable. The reason for this outcome was that there were offsetting factors that
keep consumption spending high even as the stock of wealth declined. Consumer spending was little
affected by the decline in the stock of wealth. These offsetting factors included the flow of income, which
remained high, tax cuts that boosted consumer spending, and lower interest rates. [text: E p. 159; MA p.
159]
13. Other things being constant, what will be the effect of each of the following on
disposable income (or GDP)?
(b) The probable effect of a sharp rise in stock prices would be to increase
shareholder purchases as a result of a rise in wealth, thus shifting the
consumption schedule upward and increasing the equilibrium level of GDP. It
also could encourage business investment with funds gained by issuing new
shares of stock at the now higher prices. This would also tend to increase GDP.
(c) This should increase GDP because of the impact on new investment
spending and possible increased consumer purchases of goods having the new
technology. The consumption schedule will shift upward and real quantity will
rise.
(d) A sharp increase in the real interest rate would limit consumer durables
purchases and also limit investment spending. Both of these events would
cause a downward shift in the consumption schedule causing a decrease in
GDP. One could even argue that higher real interest rates raise production
costs and shift the aggregate supply curve leftward as well, further leading to
the GDP decline. [text: E pp. 156-158; MA pp. 156-158]
14. Explain the difference between a movement along the consumption schedule
and a shift in the consumption schedule.
A movement from one point to another on the consumption schedule is a change in the amount consumed.
It is caused solely by a change in disposable income. By contrast, a shift in the consumption schedule is
the result of a change in one of the nonincome determinates of consumption such as a change in wealth,
expectations, taxation, or household debt. If a household decided to consume more at each level of
disposable income, the consumption schedule will shift upward. [text: E pp. 157-158; MA pp. 157-158]
(c) If in graph B, line B2 shifts to B1 because households save less, then in graph
A, what will happen to line A2?
(d) In graph A, what has caused the movement from point A to point B on
line A2?
(e) If there is a lump-sum tax increase causing line A2 to shift to A1, then in
graph B, what will happen to B2?
(b) If consumption rises at each level of income, then saving must decline at
each level so B2 will shift down.
(c) The situation is the reverse of part (b). Line A2 would rise if B2 falls.
Consumption rises when saving falls.
(d) Since it is a movement along the curve rather than a shift in the curve, the
level of disposable income must have increased.
(e) A tax increase will lower both consumption and saving schedules
because disposable income has been reduced at each level of output. [text: E
pp. 157-158; MA pp. 157-158]
The investment demand curve relates investment to the real rate of interest and
the expected rate of return. Graphically the interest rate and expected rate of
return are measured on the vertical axis and the amount of investment is
measured on the horizontal axis. The investment demand curve has a negative
slope reflecting the inverse relationship between the interest rate (the price of
investing) and the aggregate quantity of investment goods demanded. [text: E
pp. 159-161; MA pp. 159-161]
Cumulative amount
of return (billions)
11% $55
10 75
8 90
5 105
3 150
1 190
(b) If the interest rate was 8%, how much investment would be undertaken?
(c) Why is there an inverse relationship between the rate of interest and the
amount of investment?
(a) The investment demand schedule gives the amount of investment that
would be undertaken at various rates of interest. The rate of interest that an
investor would be willing to pay for any amount of investment will not exceed its
expected rate of net profit. Therefore, the expected rate of profit determines
the interest rate (or price) that investors would be willing to pay for various
amounts of investment and this is the definition of an investment demand
schedule.
(c) The inverse relationship stems from the equality of the expected rate of
profit with the interest rate at each level of investment as explained in part (a).
There are fewer types of investment that yield a large expected net profit and
more and more investments that will yield a lower rate of return. Therefore, at
high rates of interest there is a smaller amount of investment that will be
undertaken because fewer investments yield an expected return high enough
to cover the high interest rate. As the rate declines, more and more investments
will yield enough return to cover the lower rates of interest.
19. List five events that could cause a shift in the investment demand curve.
20. State four factors that explain why investment spending tends to be unstable.
The two basic factors determining the level of investment spending are the
expected rate of return and the real interest rate. Since the former is based on
expectations and the latter based to a large extent on monetary policy, there is
potential for wide variation. Add to this the fact that investment goods are
usually quite durable, and new investment can be postponed depending on
expectations, or once it is made there will be a period of time before the new
capital goods will need to be replaced. Also the fact that innovations occur
irregularly leads to the inability to plan for gradual investment in innovative
technology. Finally, actual current profits are often not as expected, so
businesses can be expected to shift their investment plans from year to year.
[text: E pp. 156-164; MA pp. 156-164]
New22. Whenever there is change in spending real GDP will change by a multiple of the
initial change in spending. Explain this multiplier effect.
New23. Define the multiplier. How is it related to real GDP and the initial change in
spending? How can the multiplier have a negative effect?
The multiplier is simply the ratio of the change in real GDP to the initial change in
spending. Multiplying the initial change in spending by the multiplier gives you
the amount of change in real GDP. The multiplier effect can work in a positive
or a negative direction. An initial increase in spending will result in a larger
increase in real GDP, and an initial decrease in spending will result in a larger
decrease in real GDP. [text: E p. 164; MA p. 164]
New 24. What are two key facts that serve as the rationale for the multiplier effect?
First, the economy has continuous flows of expenditures and income in which income received by one
person comes from money spent by another person who in turn receives income from the spending of
another person, and so forth. Second, any change in income will cause both consumption and saving to
vary in the same direction as the initial change in income, and by a fraction of that change. The fraction of
the change in income that is spent is called the marginal propensity to consume (MPC). The fraction of
the change in income that is saved is called the marginal propensity to save (MPS). The significance of
the multiplier is that a small change in investment plans or consumption-saving plans can trigger a much
larger change in the equilibrium level of GDP. [text: E pp. 164-165; MA pp. 164-165]
New26. What is the relationship between the multiplier and the marginal propensities?
New 27. Describe the relationship between the size of the MPC and the multiplier. How does it compare to the
relationship between the size of the MPS and the multiplier?
The size of the MPC and the multiplier are directly related. The size of the MPS and the multiplier are
inversely related. In equation form, the multiplier = 1 / MPS, or the multiplier = 1/ (1–MPC). [text: E p.
166; MA p. 166]
New 28. Calculate the multiplier when the MPC is .5, .75, .90. What is the relationship between MPC and the
multiplier?
When MPC = .5, the multiplier is 2. When MPC = .75, the multiplier is 4. When MPC = .90, the
multiplier is 10. The relationship between MPC and the multiplier is direct. As the MPC increases, so
does the multiplier [multiplier = 1/ MPC]. [text: E p. 166; MA p. 166]
New 29. Calculate the multiplier when the MPS is .5, .25, .10. What is the relationship between MPS and the
multiplier?
When MPS = .5, the multiplier is 2. When MPS = .25, the multiplier is 4. When MPS = .10, the
multiplier is 10. The relationship between MPS and the multiplier is inverse. As the MPS decreases, so
the multiplier increases [multiplier = 1/ (1-MPS)]. [text: E p. 166; MA p. 166]
New30. How large is the actual multiplier?
The basic multiplier (1/MPS) in the text reflects only the leakage of income into
saving. There can also be other leakages of income from taxes or imports. It is
better to think of the denominator for the multiplier in more general terms as
“the fraction of the change in income which leaks or is diverted from the
income stream.” When all these leakages—saving, taxes, and import
spending—are added to the denominator of the multiplier, they reduce the size
of the multiplier effect. [text: E pp. 166-167; MA pp. 166-167]
New 31. (Last Word) Describe the events “Squaring the Economic Circle” and explain how they illustrate the
multiplier.
Humorist Art Buchwald illustrates the multiplier with this funny essay that shows how the effect of one
economic event on one party has an effect on a second party. These effects on the second party, in turn,
have an effect on a third party, and so forth, creating a ripple throughout the economy. These related and
multiple effects serve to illustrate the multiplier.
Hofberger, a Chevy salesman in Tomcat, VA, called up Littleton of Littleton Menswear & Haberdashery,
and told him that a new Nova had been set aside for Littleton and his wife. Littleton said he was sorry, but
he couldn’t buy a car because he and Mrs. Littleton were getting a divorce. Soon afterward, Bedcheck the
painter called Hofberger to ask when to begin painting the Hofbergers’ home. Hofberger said he couldn’t,
because Littleton was getting a divorce, not buying a new car, and, therefore, Hofberger could not afford
to paint his house. When Bedcheck went home that evening, he told his wife to return their new television
set to Gladstone’s TV store. When she returned it the next day, Gladstone immediately called his travel
agent and canceled his trip. He said he couldn’t go because Bedcheck returned the TV set because
Hofberger didn’t sell a car to Littleton because Littletons are divorcing. Sandstorm, the travel agent, tore
up Gladstone’s plane tickets, and immediately called his banker, Gripsholm, to tell him that he couldn’t
pay back his loan that month. When Rudemaker came to the bank to borrow money for a new kitchen for
his restaurant, the banker told him that he had no money to lend because Sandstorm had not repaid his
loan yet. Rudemaker called his contractor, Eagleton, who had to lay off eight men. General Motors
announced it would give a rebate on its new models. Hofberger called Littleton to tell him that he could
probably afford a car even with the divorce. Littleton said that he and his wife had made up and were not
divorcing. His business, however, was so lousy that he couldn’t afford a car now. His regular customers,
Bedcheck, Gladstone, Sandstorm, Gripsholm, Rudemaker, and Eagleton had not been in for over a month.
[text: E p. 167; MA p. 167]
CHAPTER 10
New 1. What are the simplifications used in this chapter?
The chapter first assumes that there is a “closed” private economy with no international trade. The chapter
then turns to an economy with international trade, or an “open” private economy. Finally, government is
included in the final sections of the chapter. When government is included, then the economy will be a
mixed economy with both public and private sectors and also an open economy. [text: E p. 172; MA p.
172]
New 2. What is the difference between the investment-demand curve and the
investment schedule for the economy?
The investment-demand curve shows the relationship between the real interest
rate and the level of investment spending. The relationship is an inverse one—
the lower the interest rate, the greater the investment spending—which means
that the investment-demand curve is downsloping. This curve can also be
shifted by five factors that can change the expected rate of return on
investment.
The equilibrium level of output is the level of output whose production will
create total income and spending which is just sufficient to purchase that
output. [text: E pp. 173-174; MA pp. 172-173]
New 4. Whenever there is change in spending, there will be a change in real GDP.
Explain why this is so.
If GDP is not in equilibrium, then aggregate expenditures will exceed real GDP or
vice versa. If aggregate expenditures exceed real GDP, then businesses will find
their inventories reduced below the planned level of inventories. Businesses will
therefore expand production to replenish inventories and the economy will not
be in equilibrium until the level of planned inventories is met.
On the other hand, if real GDP exceeds aggregate expenditures, then business
inventories will be above the level planned. In order to bring inventories down
to their planned level, production and output will be reduced until the real GDP
is equal to planned aggregate expenditures. [text: E pp. 174-175; MA pp. 174-
175]
The 45-degree line traces out the points where the economy is in equilibrium.
That is, it shows where real GDP is equal to private spending. [text: E pp. 175-
176; MA pp. 175-176]
New 7. Use the graph below to explain the determination of equilibrium GDP by the
aggregate expenditures-domestic output approach. At equilibrium C + Ig =
Real GDP ($550 + $50 = $600). Why does the intersection of the aggregate
expenditures schedule and the 45-degree line determine the equilibrium GDP?
Equilibrium occurs where C + Ig = GDP. There is a direct relationship between
aggregate expenditures and the level of GDP, but they are equal only where
the AE schedule intersects the 45-degree line which shows equality of
expenditures and GDP. Where aggregate expenditures exceed GDP, the AE
line is above the 45-degree line and output will continue to expand. If
aggregate expenditures fall below GDP as would occur at levels above 600,
then GDP will contract until the expenditures-output equality is restored.
The 45-degree line in the aggregate expenditures model represents all of the
points where aggregate expenditures are equal to real GDP; all of the possible
equilibrium levels. [text: E pp. 175-176; MA pp. 175-176]
It is based on the fact that saving is income not consumed. Saving therefore
represents a “leakage” or diversion of potential spending from the income-
expenditures stream. Consumption falls short of total output by the amount of
saving. However, investment spending can be viewed as an “injection” into this
income-expenditures stream. If planned investment is equal to the amount of
saving at a particular level of GDP, then leakages equal injections and GDP will
be in equilibrium. [text: E pp. 176-177; MA pp. 176-177]
New10. Explain the difference between planned and actual investment in the
economy. Why is the distinction important?
Actual investment consists of both planned investment and changes in
inventories. Unplanned changes in inventories act as a balancing item which
equates the actual amounts saved and invested in any period. At above
equilibrium levels of GDP, saving is greater than planned investment, and there
will be an unplanned increase in inventories. At below equilibrium levels of GDP,
planned investment is greater than saving, and there will be an unplanned
decrease in inventories. Equilibrium is achieved when planned investment
equals saving, and there are no unplanned changes in inventories. [text: E pp.
176-177; MA pp. 176-177]
New11. What is the relationship between actual investment, planned investment, and
saving in an economy? What conditions among these concepts produce
equilibrium?
12. What is the effect of net exports, either positive or negative, on equilibrium GDP?
Positive net exports increase aggregate expenditures beyond what they would be in a closed economy and
thus have an expansionary effect. The multiplier effect also is at work. Positive net exports will lead to a
positive change that is greater than the amount of the initial change. Negative net exports decrease
aggregate expenditures beyond what they would be in a closed economy and thus have a contractionary
effect. The multiplier effect also is at work here. Negative net exports lead to a negative change in
equilibrium GDP that is greater than the initial change. [text: E pp. 179-180; MA pp. 179-180]
13. Explain why exports are added to, and imports are subtracted from, aggregate
expenditures in moving from a closed to an open economy.
14. Evaluate the statement that “for an open economy the equilibrium GDP always
corresponds with an equality of exports and imports.”
This statement would be true only by coincidence, if ever. Equilibrium GDP (in
the absence of government) exists when aggregate demand equals
aggregate supply (GDP). Aggregate private demand consists of three
components: C, Ig, and net exports. There is no reason why net exports must
equal zero. The only requirement is that the sum of the three components, C, Ig,
and (X – M ) sum to the same value as aggregate supply. At that point GDP will
be in equilibrium. C or Ig or X or M or any or all of these can adjust in a situation
where disequilibrium exists, but equilibrium doesn’t necessitate net exports of
zero. [text: E pp. 179-180; MA pp. 179-180]
15. When international trade is considered, explain how net exports could be either
positive or negative additions to aggregate demand. In which case would the
impact of net exports be expansionary? Explain.
When exports exceed imports, net exports are a positive addition to aggregate
expenditures. When imports exceed exports, net exports are a negative
addition to aggregate expenditures because more money is being spent on
products from other countries than foreigners are spending on products made
in the United States. Rather than adding to aggregate expenditures this latter
situation is a leakage from total expenditures. In the case where net exports are
positive and growing, their impact would be expansionary. [text: E pp. 179-180;
MA pp. 186-188]
16. How does the fact that imports vary directly with GDP affect the stability of the
domestic economy?
Actually this fact should help stabilize the domestic economy. During
inflationary periods of rapid growth, rising imports should dampen that growth in
domestic aggregate demand. During recessionary periods, the decline in
imports should help to offset falling domestic demand as net exports should rise.
In other words, a smaller M makes the (X – M ) balance grow. [text: E pp. 179-
180; MA pp. 179-180]
17. The data in the first two columns below are for a closed economy. Use this
table to answer the following questions.
(b) Including the international trade figures for exports and imports, calculate
net exports and determine the equilibrium GDP for an open economy.
(c) What will happen to equilibrium GDP if exports were $5 billion larger at
each level of GDP?
(d) What will happen to equilibrium GDP if exports remained at $10 billion, but
imports dropped to $5 billion?
18. The data in the first two columns below are for a closed economy. Use this
table to answer the following questions.
(b) Including the international trade figures for exports and imports, calculate
net exports and determine the equilibrium GDP for an open economy.
(c) What will happen to equilibrium GDP if exports were $10 billion larger at
each level of GDP?
(d) What will happen to equilibrium GDP if exports remained at $15 billion, but
imports rose to $15 billion?
19. Explain the relationship between net exports and the following factors:
prosperity abroad, tariffs on American exports abroad, depreciation of the
American dollar on foreign exchange markets.
Prosperity abroad improves net exports because it means foreigners will buy
more U.S. exports.
Tariffs on American exports abroad will initially decrease net exports as it makes
American products more expensive to foreigners. (If the U.S. later retaliates with
tariffs of its own, the effect is less certain.)
21. Identify the relationship between GDP, taxes, and disposable income.
22. “If taxes and government spending are increased by the same amount, there
will still be a positive effect on equilibrium GDP.” Explain.
23. Compare and contrast the recessionary gap and the inflationary gap.
24. If there is a recessionary gap of $100 billion and the MPC is 0.80, by how much
must taxes be reduced to eliminate the recessionary gap?
If the MPC is 0.80, then the MPS is 0.20 and the multiplier is equal to 5. Thus to
reduce a gap of $100 billion, taxes must be reduced by $25 billion, which is
equivalent to saying that disposable income rises by $25 billion. An increase in
income of $25 billion will cause an initial change in spending of $20 billion (or 0.8
× $25) and this multiplied by 5 will result in an increase in GDP of $100 billion
which is the amount of the recessionary gap. [text: E pp. 185-187; MA pp. 185-
187]
25. Assume the level of investment is $8 billion and independent of the level of total
output. Complete the following table and determine the equilibrium level of
output and income which the private sector of this closed economy would
provide:
(a) If this economy has a labor force of 140 million, will there be a
recessionary or inflationary gap? Explain the consequences of this gap.
(b) If the labor force is 110 million, will there be an inflationary or recessionary
gap? Explain the consequences of this gap.
(c) What are the sizes of the MPC, MPS, and multiplier in this economy?
(d) Using the multiplier concept, give the increase in equilibrium GDP that
would occur if the level of investment increased from $8 billion to $10 billion.
90 130 130 0
(c) Consumption changes by $8 billion for every $10 billion change in DI.
Therefore, the MPC is 8/10 or 0.8. MPS = 0.2. Multiplier will be 1/.2 = 5.
(d) If investment spending rises by $2 billion, then equilibrium GDP should rise
by 5 x $2 billion or $10 billion. [text: E pp. 185-187; MA pp. 185-187]
26. Assume the level of investment is $8 billion and independent of the level of total
output. Complete the following table and determine the equilibrium level of
output and income which the private sector of this closed economy would
provide:
50 $ 80 $ 83 $___
60 90 90 ___
70 100 97 ___
(a) If this economy has a labor force of 110 million, will there be a
recessionary or inflationary gap? Explain the consequences of this gap.
(b) If the labor force is 80 million, will there be an inflationary or recessionary
gap? Explain the consequences of this gap.
(c) What are the sizes of the MPC, MPS, and multiplier in this economy?
(d) Using the multiplier concept, give the increase in equilibrium GDP that
would occur if the level of investment increased from $8 billion to $10 billion.
50 $ 80 $ 83 $−3
60 90 90 0
70 100 97 3
80 110 104 6
90 120 111 9
(c) Consumption changes by $7 billion for every $10 billion change in DI.
Therefore, the MPC is 7/10 or 0.7. MPS = 0.3, multiplier will be 1/.3 = 3 1/3.
(d) If investment spending rises by $2 billion, then equilibrium GDP should rise
by 3 1/3 x $2 billion or $6 2/3 billion. [text: E pp. 185-187; MA pp. 185-187]
27. Refer to the following table to answer the questions.
(a) If full employment in this economy is 65 million, will there be an inflationary or recessionary gap?
What will be the consequence of this gap? By how much would aggregate expenditures in column 3 have
to change at each level of GDP to eliminate the inflationary or recessionary gap? Explain.
(b) Will there be an inflationary or recessionary gap if the full-employment level of output is $250 billion?
Explain the consequences. By how much would aggregate expenditures in column 3 have to change at
each level of GDP to eliminate the inflationary or recessionary gap? Explain.
(c) Assuming that investment, net exports, and government expenditures do not change with changes in
real GDP, what are the sizes of the MPC, the MPS, and the multiplier?
(a) A recessionary gap. Equilibrium GDP is $300 billion, while full employment GDP is $350 billion.
Employment will be 10 million less than at full employment. Aggregate expenditures would have to
increase by $10 billion (= $350 billion – $340 billion) at each level of GDP to eliminate the recessionary
gap.
(b) An inflationary gap. Aggregate expenditures will be excessive, causing demand-pull inflation.
Aggregate expenditures would have to fall by $10 billion (= $260 billion – $250 billion) at each level of
GDP to eliminate the inflationary gap.
(c) MPC = .8 (= $20 billion/$25 billion); MPS = .2 (= 1 –.8); multiplier = 5 (= 1/.2).
[text: E pp. 185-187; MA pp. 185-187]
Real GDP C
$500 $495
510 504
520 513
530 522
540 531
550 540
560 549
(a) What is the size of the multiplier in this economy?
(b) If taxes were zero, government purchases were $5, investment is $3, and
net exports are zero, what is the equilibrium GDP?
(c) If taxes are $10, government purchases are $10, investment is $6, and net
exports are zero, what is the equilibrium GDP?
(d) Assume investment is $50, taxes are $50, and net exports and government
purchases are each zero. The full-employment level of GDP is $545. How much
of a reduction in taxes is needed to eliminate the recessionary gap?
(e) Assume that investment, net exports, and taxes are zero. Government
purchases are $30 and the full-employment GDP without inflation is $530. By
how much must government spending be reduced to eliminate the inflationary
gap?
(a) To find the MPC compare the change in C with the change in GDP to get
9/10 or 0.9; this means the MPS is 0.1 and the multiplier will be 1/.1 or 10.
(b) Find the point where aggregate expenditures equals GDP. Aggregate
expenditures will include C plus investment and government purchases which
together equal $8. Adding $8 to C at every level gives an equilibrium GDP of
$530 (= 522 + 8).
(c) If taxes are $10, GDP is reduced by $10 at every level to result in
disposable income. Since the MPC is 0.9, we can calculate C at every level by
reducing each level of C by $9 (.9 x $10). This will result in aggregate
expenditures of $520 (504 + 10 + 6) and an equilibrium GDP of $520.
(d) If taxes are $50 and the MPC is 0.9, C will be reduced at every level by
$45. Currently, the equilibrium GDP will be $500 (495 – 45 + 50 = AE). To increase
it by $45 will require an increase in consumer spending of $45. To achieve an
increase in consumer spending of $45 requires an increase in disposable income
of $50. Therefore, taxes must be reduced from $50 to zero.
(e) In this case the equilibrium nominal GDP will be $560. To reduce it to $530,
aggregate expenditures must be reduced by $30, hence government
purchases must be reduced by $30. [text: E pp. 174-187; MA pp. 174-187]
$300 $290
310 298
320 306
330 314
340 322
350 330
360 338
(b) If taxes were zero, government purchases were $10, investment $6, and
net exports are zero, what is the equilibrium GDP?
(c) If taxes are $5, government purchases are $10, investment is $6, and net
exports are zero, what is the equilibrium GDP?
(d) Assume investment is $50, taxes are $50, net exports and government
purchases are each zero. The full-employment level of GDP is $340. How much
of a reduction in taxes is needed to eliminate the recessionary gap?
(e) Assume that investment, net exports, and taxes are zero. Government
purchases are $30 and the full-employment GDP without inflation is $330. By
how much must government spending be reduced to eliminate the inflationary
gap?
(a) To find the MPC compare the change in C with the change in GDP to get
8/10 or 0.8; this means the MPS is 0.2 and the multiplier will be 1/.2 or 5.
(b) Find the point where aggregate expenditures equals GDP. Aggregate
expenditures will include C plus investment and government purchases which
together equal $16. Adding $16 to C at every level gives an equilibrium GDP of
330 (= 314 + 16).
(c) If taxes are $5, GDP is reduced by $5 at every level to result in disposable
income. Since the MPC is 0.8, we can calculate C at every level by reducing
each level of C by $4 (.8 x $5). This will result in aggregate expenditures of $310
(294 + 10 + 6) and an equilibrium GDP of $310.
(d) If taxes are $50 and the MPC is 0.8, C will be reduced at every level by
$40. Currently the equilibrium GDP will be $300 (290 – 40 + 50 = AE). To increase
it by $40 will require an increase in consumer spending of $40. To achieve an
increase in consumer spending of $40 requires an increase in disposable income
of $50. Therefore, taxes must be reduced from $50 to zero.
(e) In this case the equilibrium nominal GDP will be $360. To reduce it to $330,
aggregate expenditures must be reduced by $30, hence government
purchases must be reduced by $30. [text: E pp. 174-187; MA pp. 174-187]
First, although the model can account for demand-pull inflation, it does not
indicate how much the price level will rise when aggregate expenditures are
greater than the productive capacity of the economy. Second, the aggregate
expenditure model does not explain why demand-pull inflation can occur
before the economy reaches its full-employment level of output. Third, the
aggregate expenditures model does not explain why the economy can
expand beyond its full-employment level of output. Fourth, the aggregate
expenditures model does not account for cost-push inflation. [text: E pp. 187-
188; MA pp. 187-188]
32. (Advanced analysis) Suppose that the linear equation for consumption in a
hypothetical economy is C = 50 + 0.9 Y. Also suppose that income (Y ) is $400.
Determine the following: (a) MPC; (b) MPS; (c) level of consumption; (d) APC;
(e) APS.
MPC = 0.9; MPS = 0.1; At Y = 400, C = $410; At Y = $400, APC = 410/400 = 1.025;
and APS = (–.025). [text: E pp. 177-178; MA pp. 177-178]
33. (Advanced analysis) Assume the following output-income and saving data for
the private sector of the economy.
$240 $244
260 260
280 276
300 292
320 308
340 324
360 340
380 356
400 372
(c) Assuming net investment of $15 billion and independent of the level of
GDP, what will be the equilibrium level of GDP?
(d) Using your answers to (a) and (b), find the size of the multiplier.
(e) Check your answer using the MPC embodied in these data.
(a) C = 60 + 0.8Y
(e) The MPC would be 0.8 or 4/5 because C changes by 20 when GDP
changes by 25. Therefore MPC = 20/25 or 0.8 and the MPS = 0.2 which makes
the multiplier 1/.2 or 5, the same result found in part (d). [text: E pp. 173-178; MA
pp. 173-178]
34. (Advanced analysis) Assume the consumption schedule for the economy is
such that C = 50 + 0.8Y. Assume further that investment and net exports are
autonomous or independent of the level of income and gross investment is 40
and net exports equal –10. Recall that in equilibrium, Y = C + Ig + Xn.
(b) What will happen to equilibrium Y if gross investment falls to 20? What
does this tell us about the size of the multiplier?
(b) If gross investment falls by 20, GDP will fall by 100 because the multiplier is
1/.2 or 5 and 5 x 20 = 100 decline. The new equilibrium would be 300. [text: E
pp. 179-180; MA pp. 179-180]
35. (Advanced analysis) Assume that without any taxes the consumption schedule
for an economy is as shown in the table:
$ 200 $ 240
400 400
600 560
800 720
1,000 880
1,200 1,040
1,400 1,200
(a) Graph the consumption schedule and note the size of the MPC and
multiplier using the below graph.
(b) Assume a lump-sum regressive tax of $10 billion is imposed at all levels of
GDP. Calculate the tax rate at each level of GDP and graph the resulting
consumption schedule. Compare the MPC and the multiplier with the pretax
consumption schedule. MPC and the multiplier are unchanged.
(a) The size of the MPC = 160/200 = 0.80. See graph below.
(b) The tax rate will be regressive: At $400, 2.5%; at $600, 1.67%; at $800, 1.25%;
at $1000, 1%; at $1200, 0.835%; at $1400, 0.71%.
(c) A proportional or progressive tax system would not take such a big bite
out of low incomes as a regressive tax system does, and as incomes rose it
would take out more proportionately than a regressive, lump-sum tax does.
Thus, proportional or progressive taxes leave more disposable income for
spending during low-income periods and would reduce disposable income and
spending during expansionary phases. See graph below. [text: E pp. 182-185;
MA pp. 182-185]
New37. (Last Word) “If production results in income and income is the source of
spending, it would seem that the production of a full-employment economy
would automatically guarantee enough spending to sustain itself. How, then,
can unemployment occur?” Explain.
The statement is a restatement of Say’s law. The fallacy in this statement is that
not all income has to be spent during the production period. Just because it is
a source of spending does not mean it will all be spent. Some may be saved
and although some of this saving might be channeled back into spending
through investment in capital goods, this investment may not occur during the
same time period if investors do not expect to make an economic return on
their investment. [text: E p. 177; MA p. 177]
New38. (Last Word) What two events undermined the theory that supply creates its own
demand?
First, the Great Depression of the 1930s resulted in a sharp decline in production
and high rates of unemployment over a ten-year period. This event was
inconsistent with the classical theory that suggests that unemployment is only
temporary. Second, John Maynard Keynes developed an aggregate
expenditures theory that countered Say’s law and explained why
unemployment and underspending can occur in an economy. Keynes’
modern employment theory suggests that the macroeconomy was inherently
unstable and subject to fluctuations in output and employment because of the
downward inflexibility of wages and prices and lack of synchronization between
investment and saving decisions. [text: E p. 177; MA p. 177]
New39. (Last Word) Contrast the classical and Keynesian views of unemployment.
The classical view theorizes that unemployment will not persist because prices
and wages are flexible. If a temporary surplus occurs in one sector of the
economy, prices of that sector’s goods will fall until the quantity demanded is
brought into equilibrium with the quantity supplied again. If necessary, wages in
that sector will also fluctuate in response to the change in demand, falling when
demand is down and rising when demand increases.
The Keynesian view, on the other hand, believes that full employment is by no
means a consistent result of the market system. Cyclical unemployment is likely
to persist without intervention from the government to raise aggregate
expenditures. This view counteracts the classical view by stating that wages
and prices are not flexible in a downward direction. Also, saving and
investment plans can be at odds and can result in fluctuations in total output,
total income, employment, and the price level. [text: E p. 177; MA p. 177]
CHAPTER 11
1. Why is there a need for an aggregate demand and aggregate supply model of the economy? Why can’t the
supply and demand model for a single product explain developments in the economy?
The basic reason for an aggregate model is that there are thousands of individual products in an economy.
Single product supply and demand model does not explain: (1) why prices in general rise or fall; (2) what
determines the level of aggregate output; and (3) what determines changes in the level of aggregate output.
The aggregate model is needed to explain these changes. It simplifies the analysis of prices by combining
the prices of all individual goods and services into one aggregate price level. It simplifies the analysis of
quantities by combining the equilibrium quantities of all individual goods and services into a singe entity
called the real domestic output. [text: E pp. 193-206; MA pp. 193-206]
2. What is the aggregate demand curve? What is the characteristic its slope?
The aggregate demand curve shows the relationship between the price level
and real domestic output (real GDP). It shows the amounts of real output that
domestic consumers, businesses, government, and foreign buyers collectively
desire to purchase at each price level. As the price level increases, the amount
of real domestic output purchased will decrease, so the aggregate demand
curve is downsloping. [text: E pp. 193-195; MA pp. 193-195]
3. What is the difference in the explanation of the shape of the aggregate demand curve and a single product
demand curve? After all, both demand curves show an inverse relationship between price and quantity.
The aggregate demand curve shows an inverse relationship between the price level (the general level of all
prices) and real domestic output (the equilibrium quantity of all products). The explanation of this inverse
relationship is based on the real-balances effect, the interest-rate effect, and the foreign-purchases effect.
In this case, as the price level rises, the quantity of real domestic output decreases.
The supply and demand model for a particular product shows an inverse relationship between the price of
that product and the quantity of that product. The explanation for the inverse relationship between price
and quantity in the demand for a single product is based on the substitution and income effects. The
substitution effect is not applicable to the aggregate case because there is no substitute for all products in
the economy. Also, the income effect is not applicable to the aggregate case because income now varies
with aggregate output. [text: E pp. 193-195; MA pp. 193-195]
4. Explain the three reasons given for the downward slope of the aggregate
demand curve.
The three reasons given are the real-balances effect, the interest-rate effect,
and the foreign purchases effect.
The real-balances effect refers to the idea that a higher price level will reduce
the purchasing power of the population’s accumulated financial assets.
Because of the decline in value of such assets, people will feel poorer and will
reduce their spending. Conversely, as the price level falls the opposite will
occur.
The interest-rate effect assumes that as the price level rises so will interest rates,
and rising interest rates will reduce certain kinds of spending such as
consumption spending on durable goods and investment spending.
The foreign purchases effect assumes that if the price level rises in the U.S.
relative to that in foreign countries, Americans will increase spending on imports
at the expense of domestically produced goods and services, and foreigners
will reduce purchases of U.S. goods. In other words, net exports decline. [text: E
pp. 193-195; MA pp. 193-195]
5. The determinants of aggregate demand “determine” the location of the
aggregate demand curve. Explain three of the four basic determinants of
aggregate demand.
The four basic determinants of aggregate demand are found in Figure 11.2 in
the text. They are a change in consumer spending, a change in investment
spending, a change in government spending, and a change in net export
spending. Explanations for each follow.
Net export spending can change for two nonprice-level-related reasons such as
rising or falling national incomes in other countries and exchange rate changes
unrelated to domestic price levels. [text: E pp. 195-197; MA pp. 195-197]
6. Identify the ways in which each of the following determinants would have to
change if each was causing a decrease in aggregate demand: consumer
wealth, consumer expectations, business taxes, national income in countries
abroad, exchange rates.
To decrease aggregate demand, consumer wealth would have to fall. For
example, a decline in real estate values or a stock market decline would cause
a decrease in consumer wealth. If consumers expected prices to fall in the
future, or a recession which creates insecurity about jobs, they might cut back
on spending now. If business taxes were raised, or some present tax breaks
eliminated or reduced, this could reduce business investment spending which,
in turn, reduces aggregate demand. When national income abroad is falling,
U.S. exports will decline, which reduces the net export spending component of
aggregate demand. A dollar appreciation will cause a decline in net exports
as U.S. exports become more expensive to foreigners and foreign imports
become less expensive to holders of American dollars. [text: E pp. 195-197; MA
pp. 195-197]
New 7. Define aggregate supply. Describe the characteristics of the aggregate supply
curve from long-run and short-run perspectives.
The aggregate supply is a curve that shows the total quantity of goods and
services that will be produced (supplied) at different price levels. In the long
run, the aggregate supply curve is vertical at the full-employment level of
output for the economy because the rise in wages and other inputs will match
changes in the price level. In the short run, the aggregate supply curve is
upsloping because nominal wages and input prices adjust only slowly to
changes in the price level. With this curve, an increase in the price level
increases real output and a decrease in the price level reduces real output.
[text: E pp. 197-198; MA pp. 197-198]
8. Explain the three major factors that can cause a shift in aggregate supply. That
is, explain the three major determinants of supply.
(a) Decrease; (b) Increase; (c) Decrease (unless the increase in antipollution
device production outweighs the decline in production caused by the
increased cost of the regulations); (d) Increase; (e) Increase [text: E pp. 199-
201; MA pp. 199-201]
10. Prepare a list of events that would shift the aggregate supply curve leftward.
Students should list examples that fit the determinants indicated in Figure 11.5.
Some possibilities are a rise in the prices of domestic resources, an increase in
wages beyond any rise in productivity, an increase in the prices of imported
resources, declining rate of productivity without corresponding wage
concessions, rising business taxes, reduction in research and development
efforts, and more government regulation which adds to production costs. [text:
E pp. 199-201; MA pp. 199-201]
11. Prepare a list of government tax or spending policy options that would tend to
shift the aggregate supply curve rightward.
Tax cuts or rebates in any area which would improve productivity. For example,
tax credits for investment in new capital goods or buildings, tax credits for
education and training.
Tax breaks for various types of natural resource exploration and development
especially for resources important in energy and construction industries.
Reducing or eliminating tariffs on imported resources.
Tax penalties for companies which grant inflationary wage increases. [text: E
pp. 199-201; MA pp. 199-201]
12. What determines the equilibrium price level and the level of real domestic
output in the aggregate demand-aggregate supply model?
The interaction of aggregate supply and aggregate demand will determine the
equilibrium. The price and quantity levels where aggregate demand and
aggregate supply are equal will be the equilibrium levels of price and quantity.
In a graphical illustration such as Figure 11.7, it is where the two curves intersect.
[text: E pp. 201-203; MA pp. 201-203]
13. Suppose that a hypothetical economy has the following relationship between its real domestic output and
the input quantities necessary for producing that level of output.
400 800
300 600
100 200
(b) What is the unit cost of production if the price of each input is $2.00?
(c) If the input price decreases from $2 to $1.50, what is the new per unit cost
of production? In what direction would the aggregate supply curve move?
What effect would this shift have on the price level and the level of real
domestic output if the economy is initially operating in the intermediate range?
(d) Suppose that instead of the input price decreasing, the productivity had
increased by 25%. What will be the new unit cost of production? In what
direction would the aggregate supply curve move? What effect would this shift
have on the equilibrium price and output level if the economy?
(a) The level of productivity is 2 output units per input unit.
(b) Since productivity is 2 units of output per input unit, the cost of production
per unit is 2 units/$2 or $1 per unit of output. (Total input cost/output) = PUPC.
[($2 x 400)/800] = $1.
(c) The unit cost will decline from $1/unit to $.75/unit. The aggregate supply
curve has moved rightward and the level of prices has declined while the level
of real domestic output has increased.
(d) If productivity rose by 25%, then there would be 1.25 units produced per
$1 of input costs. The unit cost of production would be $.80/unit. The
aggregate supply curve would move in the same direction with similar effects to
(c) above. However, the cost reduction is not quite as great so the real GDP
would not rise as much as (c) nor would the price level decline by as much as
(c). [text: E pp. 200-201, 205-206; MA pp. 200-201, 205-206]
14. Suppose the aggregate demand and supply schedules for a hypothetical
economy are as shown below:
Amount of real
(a) Use these sets of data to graph the aggregate demand and supply
curves on the below graph.
(b) What will be the equilibrium price and output level in this hypothetical
economy? Is it also the full-employment level of output? Explain.
(c) Why won’t the 150 index be the equilibrium price level? Why won’t the
250 index be the equilibrium price level?
(d) Suppose demand increases by $400 billion at each price level. What will
be the new equilibrium price and output levels?
(b) The equilibrium GDP is $600 billion and price level 200. There is not enough
information given to determine whether or not this is the full-employment level
of output.
(c) At 150, the aggregate demand would exceed aggregate supply and
prices would be bid up. At price level 250, aggregate supply would exceed
aggregate demand and the resulting surpluses would cause prices to be bid
downward toward the equilibrium level of 200.
(d) The new equilibrium price and output level will be 250 and $800 billion
respectively on the schedule shown.
(e) Look at Figure 11.2, Determinants of Aggregate Demand, to help with this
answer. An increase in consumer wealth, expected future inflation, decline in
household indebtedness, or decreased personal taxes could increase the
consumer spending component of aggregate demand. Investment spending
might increase as a result of lower interest rates, expectations of improved
profits in the future, decline in business taxes, new and improved technology, or
decline in excess capacity. Government spending might increase for a variety
of reasons. Net export spending could increase as a result of improved
economic conditions abroad or a depreciation in the American dollar. [text: E
pp. 201-204; MA pp. 201-204]
15. Suppose the aggregate demand and supply schedules for a hypothetical
economy are as shown below:
Amount of real
$ 60 350 $240
300 150 60
(a) What will be the equilibrium price and output level in this hypothetical
economy? Is it also the full-employment level of output? Explain.
(b) Why won’t the 200 index be the equilibrium price level? Why won’t the
300 index be the equilibrium price level?
(c) Suppose demand increases by $120 billion at each price level. What will
be the new equilibrium price and output levels?
(d) List five factors that might cause a change in aggregate demand.
(a) The equilibrium GDP is $180 billion and price level 250. There is not enough
information given to determine whether or not this is the full-employment level
of output, but there is no reason why it should be one way or the other.
(b) At 200, the aggregate demand would exceed aggregate supply and
prices would be bid up. At price level 300, aggregate supply would exceed
aggregate demand and the resulting surpluses would cause prices to be bid
downward toward the equilibrium level of 250.
(c) The new equilibrium price and output level will be 300 and $240 billion
respectively on the schedule shown.
(d) Look at Figure 11.3, Determinants of Aggregate Demand, to help with this
answer. (1) An increase in consumer wealth, (2) expected future inflation, (3)
decline in household indebtedness, or (4) decreased personal taxes could
increase the consumer spending component of aggregate demand, (5)
investment spending might increase as a result of lower interest rates, (6)
expectations of improved profits in the future, (7) decline in business taxes, (8)
new and improved technology, or (9) decline in excess capacity. Government
spending might increase for a variety of reasons. (10) Net export spending
could increase as a result of improved economic conditions abroad or from a
depreciation in the American dollar.
(b) The price level rises sharply while real output and employment increase
(c) The price level falls, but the unemployment rate rises
(d) Real output rises, unemployment rate falls, and the price level rises
(a) The aggregate supply curve has shifted to the left causing the price level
to rise and output and employment levels to fall.
(d) The aggregate demand curve has shifted rightward. [text: E pp. 203-206;
MA pp. 203-206]
17. What is the effect of the multiplier when aggregate demand increases and there is a large increase in the
price level? What happens when there only is a small increase in the price level?
The multiplier effect is weakened with price level changes. In the vertical range of aggregate supply, an
increase in aggregate demand only produces in increase in the price level but no increase in real output. In
the intermediate range, the increase in aggregate demand raises the price level and real output, but real
output does not increase by as much as it would have if there had been no price level increase (as would
be the case in the horizontal range). The conclusion is that the more the price level increases, the less
effect any increase in aggregate demand will have in increasing real GDP. [text: E p. 203; MA p. 203]
18. In the table below are aggregate demand and supply schedules.
(a) On the graph below, plot the aggregate demand curve shown in
columns (1) and (2) in the above table, and label this curve AD1.
(b) On the graph below, plot the aggregate supply curve shown in columns
(1) and (4) in the above table; and label this curve AS.
(c) What is the level of equilibrium real domestic output and price level?
(d) Now assume that aggregate demand changes. Use columns (1) and (3)
to plot the new aggregate demand curve; and label this curve AD2.
(e) What is the new level of equilibrium real domestic output and price level?
(a) What will be the equilibrium price level and quantity of real domestic output?
(b) If the quantity of real domestic output demanded increased by $2000 at each price level, what will be
the new equilibrium price level and quantity of real domestic output?
(c) Using the original data from the table, if the quantity of real domestic output demanded increased by
$5000 and the quantity of real domestic output supplied increased by $1000 at each price level, what
would the new equilibrium price level and quantity of real domestic output be?
20. What are five reasons for the downward price-level inflexibility, especially as it
pertains to wages and prices?
First, wage contracts will fix wages for the length of the contract period, so it is
difficult to cut wages until the contract is renegotiated. Also, wages and
salaries of nonunion workers are typically adjusted just once a year. Second,
some businesses may pay efficiency wages that are designed to get the
maximum work effort out of employees. Cutting such wages may cause morale
problems and reduce productivity, so businesses are hesitant to make these
cuts. Third, the minimum wage sets a legal minimum that employers must pay
for low-skilled workers. Fourth, there are menu costs of changing prices.
Repricing or reprinting prices can be costly and be disruptive to customers.
Businesses are reluctant to make such changes. Fifth, there is the fear of a price
war. If one business starts cutting prices then other businesses can follow suit to
maintain market share. Businesses may decide to maintain prices rather than
risk starting a price war. [text: E pp. 203-205; MA pp. 203-205]
21. Is the downward price inflexibility applicable to today’s economy? Why or why
not?
Some economists give many reasons for the downward price-level inflexibility in
the economy. They note that the price level has not declined since one year in
the 1950s despite the fact that there have been many recessions since then.
Also, there are a number of reasons for price-level inflexibility that include long-
term wage contracts, the payment of efficiency wages, a minimum wage, the
menu cost of making price changes, and fear of price wars.
New22. (Consider This) What is the ratchet effect? How does it apply to price level
changes in the economy as aggregate demand changes?
A ratchet effect allows movement in one direction but not movement back.
Some economists argue that when aggregate demand increases, there will be
an increase in the price level, but when aggregate demand decreases, there is
downward price inflexibility that prevents the price level from falling. They note
that the price level has not declined since one year in the 1950s despite the fact
that there have been many recessions since then. So a higher price level
remains even when aggregate demand falls. [text: E p. 205; MA p. 205]
24. Some economists argue that it is easier to resolve demand-pull inflation than it is
cost-push inflation. Use the aggregate demand and aggregate supply model
to explain this assertion.
However, the factors which cause leftward shifts in the aggregate supply
schedule (see Figure 11.5) are not as easy for government policy to control.
Government cannot quickly change worker demands for higher wages; it
cannot quickly increase productivity which would also bring down production
costs; it cannot control the price of imported resources. These three factors
have contributed much to cost-push inflation in the past, and help to illustrate
the difficulty in controlling cost-push inflation. [text: E pp. 203-205; MA pp. 203-
205]
The answer depends partly on where the economy is at the beginning of this
change. Assuming that inflation was already a problem, then increased
expectations would cause the demand curve to shift further rightward, adding
to the demand-pull type of inflation.
The effect on aggregate supply would also be to worsen inflation from the cost-
push perspective. People would want higher wages and salaries now to
compensate them for the expected inflation of the future. Unless productivity
rose at the same rate, these demands for higher incomes would push up labor
costs of production which would shift the supply curve to the left. As this
happens the new equilibrium would be not only at a higher level of inflation, but
also at a lower level of employment. In other words, this leftward shift could
offset any possible increase caused by the rightward shift in aggregate
demand. The only certainty is that expectations of severe inflation add to the
probability of severe inflation because of the behavior of consumers and wage
earners. [text: E pp. 203-205; MA pp. 203-205]
27. (Last Word) Why was unemployment in Europe so high in recent years?
There are two basic perspectives on the reasons for high European unemployment rates. First, there are
high natural rates of unemployment that is due to frictional and structural unemployment. This results
from government policies and union contracts that increase the costs of hiring and reduce the cost of being
unemployed. Among the policies that affect these high costs are high minimum wages, generous welfare
benefits for the unemployed, restrictions against firings that discourage firms from employing workers,
long periods for paid vacation and holidays, high worker absenteeism that reduces productivity, and the
high costs of paying for fringe benefits that discourages hiring. Second, there is deficient aggregate
demand. European governments worried too much about inflation and have not enacted monetary or
fiscal policies that expand the economy. If such policies had been enacted, aggregate demand would
expand and unemployment rates would fall, without the threat of inflation because there is excess capacity
in the economy. [text: E p. 207; MA p. 207]
C. Appendix Questions
28. How can the aggregate demand curve be derived from the aggregate
expenditures model?
29. Explain the relationship between the aggregate expenditures model in graph
(A) below and the aggregate demand-aggregate supply model in graph (B)
Graph Graph
below. In other words, explain how points 1, 2, and 3 are related to points 1', 2',
and 3'.
30. How does the aggregate expenditures analysis differ from the aggregate
demand-aggregate supply analysis?
31. Why does aggregate demand shift outward by a greater amount than the
initial change in spending?
32. Explain the relationship between the aggregate expenditures model in graph
(A) below and the aggregate demand-aggregate supply model in graph (B)
below where aggregate demand is shifting while the price level remains
constant.
(A) (B)
D. Answers to Appendix Questions
28. How can the aggregate demand curve be derived from the aggregate
expenditures model?
Note that for the aggregate-expenditure model that a decrease in the price
level: (1) increases the value of wealth; thus increasing the consumption
schedule. A decrease in the price level decreases the interest rate, thus
increasing the investment schedule. A decrease in the price level decreases
imports and increases exports, thus increasing net exports expenditures. Thus a
decrease in the price level will increase aggregate expenditures (and real
domestic output) because of these changes in wealth, interest rates, and net
exports. These three effects are also the ones that define the inverse
relationship between the price level and real domestic output in the aggregate
demand curve. [text: E pp. 211-212; MA pp. 211-212]
29. Explain the relationship between the aggregate expenditures model in graph
(A) below and the aggregate demand-aggregate supply model in graph (B)
Graph Graph
below. In other words, explain how points 1, 2, and 3 are related to points 1', 2',
and 3'.
Through the real-balances, interest-rate, and foreign purchases effects, the consumption, investment, and
net exports schedules and therefore the aggregate expenditures schedule will rise when the price level
declines and fall when the price level increases. If the aggregate expenditure schedule is at (C + Ig + Xn)2
when the price level is P2, we can combine that price level and the equilibrium output, GDP2, to determine
one point (2') on the aggregate demand curve. A lower price level such as P1 shifts aggregate
expenditures to (C + Ig + Xn)1, providing us with point 1' on the aggregate demand curve. Similarly, a
higher price level at P3 shifts aggregate expenditures down to (C + Ig + Xn)3 so P3 and GDP3 yield another
point on the aggregate demand curve at 3'. [text: E pp. 211-212; MA pp. 211-212]
30. How does the aggregate expenditures analysis differ from the aggregate
demand-aggregate supply analysis?
The aggregate expenditures analysis assumes a constant price level. Output measures are in terms of real
GDP and real income. The aggregate demand-aggregate supply model shows the relationship between
real GDP and the price level. The Keynesian model ignores price level effects of increased aggregate
expenditures. In contrast, the AD-AS model indicates that the price level will rise as aggregate demand
rises in the intermediate or vertical ranges of aggregate supply. [text: E pp. 211-212; MA pp. 211-212]
31. Why does aggregate demand shift outward by a greater amount than the
initial change in spending?
32. Explain the relationship between the aggregate expenditures model in graph
(A) below and the aggregate demand-aggregate supply model in graph (B)
below where aggregate demand is shifting while the price level remains
constant.
(A) (B)
CHAPTER 16
1. What is the basic difference between the short run and long run as these terms
relate to macroeconomics? Why does this difference occur?
The short run is a period in which nominal wages (and other input prices) do not
fully adjust as the price level changes. The long-run is a period in which nominal
wages are fully responsive to changes in the price level. Nominal wages tend
to remain fixed in the short run as the price level increases because workers may
not be fully aware of how inflation has eroded real wages. Also many workers
are under fixed contracts for several year periods. As a consequence of these
factors, nominal wages do not change immediately with changes in the price
level. [text: E pp. 292-293; MA pp. 292-293]
Per hour
97 10 _____
94 10 _____
91 10 _____
88 10 _____
85 10 _____
Per hour
97 10 10.31
94 10 10.64
91 10 10.99
88 10 11.36
85 10 11.76
Per hour
103 10 _____
106 10 _____
109 10 _____
112 10 _____
115 10 _____
Price Index Nominal Wage Real Wage
Per hour
103 10 9.71
106 10 9.43
109 10 9.17
112 10 8.93
115 10 8.70
4. Assume that one year the nominal wage for a worker is $12 per hour and there
is no inflation. The next year the nominal wage stays the same but the rate of
inflation is 10 percent. What is the new real wage after taking inflation into
account? What nominal wage would workers ask for to keep their real wage
equal to what it was the first year?
The first year the nominal wage and the real wage are the same: $12 per hour.
The second year the nominal wage is $12, but the real wage is now $10.91. (To
obtain this number you take the $12 nominal wage and divided it by 1.10, which
is the 10 percent inflation expressed as price index in hundredths.) To
compensate for inflation, workers would want the nominal wage of $12 to
increase by 10 percent, or rise to $13.20 [$12 + ($12 x 1.10) = $13.20]. This
increase in the nominal wage to $13.20 would make the new real wage
($13.20/1.10 = $12) equal to the original $12 real wage. [text: E p. 293; MA p.
293]
5. Assume that one year the nominal wage for a worker is $15 per hour and there
is no inflation. The next year the nominal wage stays the same but the rate of
inflation is 8 percent. What is the new real wage after taking inflation into
account? What nominal wage would workers ask for to keep their real wage
equal to what it was the first year?
The first year the nominal wage and the real wage are the same: $15 per hour.
The second year the nominal wage is still $15, but the real wage is now $13.76.
(To obtain this number you take the $15 nominal wage and divided it by 1.08,
which is the 8 percent inflation expressed as price index in hundredths). To
compensate for inflation, workers would want the nominal wage of $15 to
increase by 8 percent, or rise to $16.20 [$15 + ($15 x 1.08) = $16.20]. This nominal
wage of $16.20 would make the new real wage ($16.20/1.08 = $15) equal to the
original $15 real wage. [text: E p. 293; MA p. 293]
The short-run aggregate supply curve will be an upsloping curve with the price
level on the vertical axis and real domestic output on the horizontal axis. The
initial level of output will be the full-employment level of output.
As the price level increases from the full-employment level of output, revenues
to the firm increase because nominal wages are fixed, and the profits for firms
will rise. Firms will have an incentive to increase output and employment (hiring
temporary or part-time workers or paying for overtime), so real GDP will increase
and unemployment will fall below its natural rate.
As the price level decreases from the full-employment level of output, revenues
to the firm decrease and because nominal wages are fixed, the profits for firms
will decrease. Firms will have an incentive to decrease output and
employment, so real GDP will decrease and employment will fall below its
natural rate. [text: E pp. 293-294; MA pp. 293-294]
7. Suppose the potential level of real domestic output (Q) for a hypothetical
economy is $250 and the price level (P) initially is 100. Use the following short-run
aggregate supply schedules below to answer the questions.
P Q P Q P Q
(a) What will be the short-run level of real GDP if the price level rises
unexpectedly from 100 to 110 because of an increase in aggregate demand?
Falls unexpectedly from 100 to 90 because of a decrease in aggregate
demand? Explain each situation.
(b) What will be the long-run level of real GDP when the price level rises from
100 to 110? Falls from 100 to 90? Explain each situation.
(c) Show the circumstances described in (a) and (b) on the graph below and
derive the long-run aggregate supply curve.
(a) In the short run, the table reports that real GDP will rise to 280 when the
price level rises from 100 to 110. If it were to fall unexpectedly, then the real
GDP would fall to 220 temporarily. (a) In other words, short-run changes are
only temporary responses to changes in aggregate demand.
(b) In the long run, the wages and resource prices adapt to the changes in
the price level so that business profits will return to their original level and the
motivation to expand or contract output will disappear. The long-run real GDP
will be 250 according to the figures listed in the above table.
(c) See graphs below. [text: E, pp. 293-294; MA pp. 293-294]
8. Suppose the potential level of real domestic output (Q) for a hypothetical
economy is $160 and the price level (P) initially is 200. Use the following short-run
aggregate supply schedules to answer the questions.
P Q P Q P Q
(a) What will be the short-run level of real GDP if the price level rises
unexpectedly from 200 to 210 because of an increase in aggregate demand?
Falls unexpectedly from 200 to 190 because of a decrease in aggregate
demand? Explain each situation.
(b) What will be the long-run level of real GDP when the price level rises from
200 to 210? Falls from 200 to 190? Explain each situation.
(a) In the short run, the table reports that real GDP will rise to 190 when the
price level rises from 200 to 210. If it were to fall unexpectedly, then the real
GDP would fall to 130 temporarily. (a) In other words, short-run changes are
only temporary responses to changes in aggregate demand.
(b) In the long run, the wages and resource prices adapt to the changes in
the price level so that business profits will return to their original level and the
motivation to expand or contract output will disappear. The long-run real GDP
will be 160 according to the figures listed in the above table. [text: E, pp. 293-
294; MA pp. 293-294]
With the short-run aggregate supply curve, as the price level increases from the
full-employment level of output along the curve, revenues to the firm increase
because nominal wages are fixed, and the profits for firms will rise. Firms will
have an incentive to increase output and employment (hiring temporary or
part-time workers or paying for overtime), so real GDP will increase and
unemployment will fall below its natural rate. This situation is a short-run one
because nominal wages (and other input prices) will eventually increase and
shift the short-run aggregate supply curve to the left. The new equilibrium will
return to the full-employment level of output, but at a higher price level.
The equilibrium GDP and price level occur at the intersection of the aggregate
demand curve, the long-run aggregate supply curve, and the short-run
aggregate supply curve. The output level will be at the full-employment level of
output. [text: E p. 294; MA p. 294]
11. Describe the process that occurs with demand-pull inflation in the extended
aggregate demand and aggregate supply model.
If the government takes no action to counter the inflation, then a recession will
occur that will lead to higher levels of unemployment. At some point, the price
of the major resource that caused the inflation will decline along with nominal
wages (because of the recession), so that the short-run aggregate supply curve
shifts back to its original position.
If the government tries to counter the cost-push inflation and recession by using
stimulative monetary and fiscal policies, it will shift the aggregate demand
curve to the right. The action will increase employment and real output to its
full-employment level, but the price level will now be even higher. The higher
price level is likely to kick off another round of demands to increase nominal
wages that will cause another leftward shift in the short-run aggregate supply
curve. Thus, an inflationary spiral can result from government actions to
increase aggregate demand to counter cost-push inflation. [text: E p. 296; MA
p. 296]
14. Explain what happens in the extended aggregate demand and aggregate
supply model when there is a recession.
With a recession, the aggregate demand curve will decrease or shift left. As the
price level decreases from the full-employment level of output, revenues to the
firm decrease, and because nominal wages are fixed, the profits for firms will
decrease. Firms will have an incentive to decrease output and employment (to
reduce labor cost), so real GDP will decrease and employment will fall below its
natural rate. This situation is a short-run one, however, because nominal wages
(and other input prices) will eventually decrease and shift the short-run
aggregate supply curve to the right. The new equilibrium will return to the full-
employment level of output but be at a lower price level. [text: E pp. 296-297;
MA pp. 296-297]
15. What are three significant generalizations supported by results from the
extended AD-AS model?
First, under normal circumstances, there is a short-run tradeoff between the rate
of inflation and the rate of unemployment. Second, aggregate supply shocks
can cause both higher rates of inflation and higher rates of unemployment.
Third, there is no significant tradeoff between inflation and unemployment over
longer periods of time. [text: E p. 297; MA p. 297]
The Phillips Curve shows the relationship between the unemployment rate and
the rate of inflation. The relationship is an inverse one, so there is a short-run
tradeoff between the unemployment rate and the rate of inflation. For
example, if the unemployment rate increases by 1% then the inflation rate might
decline by .5%. The concept was developed by A.W. Phillips in Great Britain
based on empirical observation of the relationship between unemployment
and inflation in that nation. Modern economists reject the idea of a stable,
predictable Phillips Curve, although many economists do agree that there is a
short-run tradeoff between unemployment and inflation. [text: E pp. 297-298;
MA pp. 297-298]
17. Explain the Phillips Curve concept and construct an example of the curve on
the below graph.
The Phillips Curve concept shows a stable inverse relationship between the rate
of unemployment and the rate of inflation. It is based on the idea that as
aggregate demand increases in the horizontal range of the aggregate supply
curve, unemployment will decline as real GDP rises without an inflationary
effect. However, as aggregate demand continues to grow and the
unemployment rate approaches full-employment, the price level and real GDP
will increase. Finally, at the point of full capacity, only the price level will rise as
potential real GDP has been achieved. See graph below. [text: E pp. 297-298;
MA pp. 297-298]
18. If the Phillips Curve exists in reality, what dilemma does this create for fiscal and
monetary policies? Explain.
19. What is stagflation and what was one of its causes in the 1970s and early 1980s?
20. Assume the following information is relevant for an advanced economy over a
three-year period. Describe in detail the macroeconomic situation faced by
this society. Is cost-push inflation evident? What corrective policies would you
recommend and why?
21. What contributed to stagflation's demise between 1982 and 1989? How did
these events affect aggregate supply and the Phillips Curve?
There was a deep recession from 1981 to 1982 that reduced the pressure for
workers to increase wages and for firms to increase prices. Increased foreign
competition also restrained domestic wage and price increases in the United
States. The U.S. economy also underwent deregulation in many basic industries
that stimulated more competition and further restrained price and wage
increases. In addition, the monopoly and pricing power over oil by the OPEC
cartel was weakened, thus reducing energy prices for consumers and
businesses. These factors worked to reduce the per-unit cost of production and
shift the economy's short-run aggregate supply curve to the right and shift the
Phillips Curve back to the left. [text E p. 300; MA p. 300]
22. Compare and contrast the short-run Phillips Curve and the long-run Phillips
Curve.
(c) Based on this diagram, what would the prediction be for the natural (full-
employment) rate of unemployment?
(a) In the short run, the unemployment rate will fall to C1, or 5% from its original
level of 7% as firms increase prices, obtain more revenues, and thus can afford
to hire more workers at the fixed nominal wage. In the long run, as workers and
firms adapt to the higher price level, the unemployment rate will return to 7% as
indicated by point B2 at the annual rate of inflation.
(b) Essentially the same answer as in (a). In the short run, the unemployment
rate will fall to C2, or 5% from its original level of 7%. In the long run, as workers
and firms adapt to the new higher price level, the unemployment rate will return
to 7%, as indicated by point B3.
(c) According to the diagram 7% is the natural rate. [text: E pp. 301-302; MA
pp. 301-302]
24. Why is the difference between the actual and expected rates of inflation
important for explaining inflation?
When the actual rate of inflation is higher than the expected rate of inflation,
profits temporarily rise because prices that firms charge for their products are
rising faster than wage rates. (The nominal wage rates were based on a lower
expected rate of inflation than actually exists.) With more revenues, firms can
afford to employ more workers so the unemployment rate temporarily falls. In
the long run, firms and workers adjust their expectations to the new higher rate
of inflation. This means that there will be an increase in the nominal wages rate,
so the profits decrease. The firm cannot afford to hire as many workers so some
workers get laid off. The unemployment rate rises and returns to its natural rate.
[text: E pp. 301-302; MA pp. 301-302]
26. Why is the difference between the actual and expected rates of inflation
important for explaining disinflation?
When the actual rate of inflation is lower than the expected rate of inflation,
profits temporarily fall because the prices that firms charge for their products are
falling faster than wage rates. (The nominal wage rates were based on a higher
expected rate of inflation than actually exists.) With less revenue, firms cannot
afford to employ more workers so the unemployment rate temporarily rises. In
the long run, firms and workers adjust their expectations to the new lower rate of
inflation. This means that the increase in nominal wages falls and the profits of
firms rise. Firms can afford to hire more workers, so the unemployment rate falls
and returns to its natural rate. [text: E p. 302; MA p. 302]
New29. (Consider This) How did Arthur Laffer use Robin Hood and Sherwood Forest to
explain the advantage of supply-side economics?
30. What is the Laffer Curve? Explain the relationship that is shown in the curve.
The Laffer Curve indicates that the relationship between tax rates and tax
revenues is not a clear one. At the extreme, both a zero rate and 100% tax rate
will produce zero revenue. In between the two extremes there is an optimal tax
rate in terms of maximizing revenue. If tax rates are above the optimal level,
then tax revenues will rise as tax rates are cut. If tax rates are below the optimal
level then tax revenues will fall as tax rates are cut. Laffer argued that tax rates
were above the optimal level and that by lowering tax rates, the government
could increase tax revenue and increase economic output at the same time.
[text: E p. 303; MA p. 303]
31. Use the following diagram to answer the next three questions.
(a) What is this diagram called and what does it say about the relationship
between tax rates and tax revenues?
(b) If tax rates are at level c, should the government raise or lower tax rates to
increase revenues? Explain.
(c) What does tax level b represent? Could policy makers find the actual
rate that b represents? Discuss this point.
(a) This diagram is called the Laffer Curve, named after the economist who
first used the diagram to illustrate the hypothesized relationship between tax
rates and tax revenues shown. It illustrates that there is an optimal rate of taxes
in terms of maximizing tax revenues and that rates above or below that level will
cause revenue to decline. At the extreme, a zero rate and a 100% rate of tax
have the same zero revenue.
(b) If rates are at level c, the government could increase revenue by lowering
the tax rate to any rate between levels c and b. Tax revenues rise according to
the diagram as rates fall from c to b, but below level b, revenues fall again.
Draw a curve similar to Figure 16.10 from the text. The following curve suggests
that up to point b higher tax rates will result in larger tax revenues, but beyond
that any increase in rates will have adverse effects on incentives, result in tax
avoidance or tax evasion, and generally reduce overall tax revenues. The
New33. What is supply-side economics? What is the rationale for it? Is it effective?
Some economists argue that a reduction in taxes will expand aggregate supply.
From this perspective, fiscal policy can be used to increase real GDP with little or
no rise in the price level, as would be the case if tax cuts expanded aggregate
demand.
There are three possible reasons for the supply-side effect of tax cuts. First, lower
taxes increase disposable income that may increase household saving. They
may also stimulate businesses’ investments because they increase the after-tax
profitability of businesses. Second, lower taxes also give people more incentive
to work because they keep more of their income. Third, lower taxes will
encourage more risk-taking and entrepreneurship in society because the after-
tax reward has been increased.
Many economists are skeptical about the supply-side effect of tax cuts based
on the experience with them during the 1980s. The positive effects on incentives
to save, invest, or work may not be very large, and therefore the stimulus to the
supply-side may be minor. In other words, the demand-side effects of tax cuts
appear to be far greater, and more immediate than any of the supply-side
effects. [text: E pp. 302-305; MA pp. 302-305]
34. What are the major criticisms of the Laffer curve and supply-side economics?
35. (Last Word) Has the effect of oil prices increases on the economy been
diminished? Cite evidence to support the case for a diminished effect.
An increase in oil prices has been thought to contribute to stagflation. Oil prices
are a major input into the cost of producing many products. If this price
increases, then the AS curve would decrease, driving up the price level and
reducing real output.
Several reasons are cited as to why the oil price increase in the late 1990s has
been less severe than would be expected. First, some firms that used oil-related
products for production may have thought that any oil price increases would
be temporary, and thus did not change their production plans or prices.
Second, and perhaps most important, other factors affecting aggregate supply
may have offset the negative effects of the oil price increase. One such factor
would be an increase in productivity due to investments in new technology.
Third, the nation is less sensitive to changes in oil prices than in past decades
because it uses less energy to produce GDP. The Federal Reserve has also
become more adept using monetary policy to respond to short-term changes in
energy prices so that they have less of an effect on the core inflation rate. [text:
E p. 305; MA p. 305]
CHAPTER 12
1. Give a brief definition of fiscal policy? What are its economic goals?
Fiscal policy is the use of the federal budget to achieve full employment, control
inflation, and stimulate economic growth. The changes to the federal budget
can be made through increases or decreases in government spending or
through increases or decreases in tax revenues. [text: E p. 214; MA p. 214].
The Council of Economic Advisors is responsible for assisting and advising the
president on economic affairs. One of its principal responsibilities is to prepare
an annual report for the president that is submitted to Congress that describes
the state of the economy and recommends economic policies to achieve full
employment, control inflation, and encourage economic growth. [text: E pp.
214-215; MA pp. 214-215].
4. Explain the effect of a discretionary cut in taxes of $40 billion on the economy
when the economy’s marginal propensity to consume is .75. By how much is
output likely to expand if the economy is operating in the horizontal range of its
aggregate supply curve and there are no complications to this fiscal policy?
How does this discretionary fiscal policy differ from a discretionary increase in
government spending of $40 billion?
If MPC is .75, the multiplier is 4. A tax cut of $40 billion will result in initial increase
in consumption of $30 billion (.75 × $40 billion). This initial increase in spending
will ultimately result in an increase in consumption spending of $120 billion
because of the multiplier process. In contrast, an initial increase in government
spending of $40 billion will ultimately increase consumer spending by $160 billion
(4 × $40) because none of the initial increase is siphoned off as savings as would
be the case with a $40 billion tax cut. [text: E pp. 215-216; MA pp. 215-216]
Expansionary policy would most likely be used during a recession (or trough)
phase. A contractionary policy would most likely be employed near the peak
of the business cycle as the economy reaches full-employment GDP and the
potential for inflation accelerates. [text: E pp. 215-217; MA pp. 215-217]
8. Describe two ways the Federal government can finance a deficit and explain
which would have the more expansionary effect.
The government can borrow money from the private sector in which case it will
be competing with private business borrowers for funds. If planned investment
spending is “crowded out,” the impact of expansionary deficits will be offset by
the decline in investment spending.
The government can also finance a deficit by issuing new money which
essentially means that the Federal Reserve has financed the deficit. This type of
financing would be more expansionary than borrowing from the private sector.
[text: E pp. 217-218; MA pp. 217-218]
9. Describe two ways the Federal government could retire debt in the event of a
budget surplus and explain which would have the most contractionary impact.
The government could use a budget surplus to pay off existing debt which
would “recycle” funds back into the economy and potentially offset the decline
in government spending. Alternatively, the government could impound the
surplus funds, or allow them to stand idle, which means these funds are not
injected into the economy and would have a more contractionary effect than
the first alternative. [text: E p. 218; MA p. 218]
This could be the unlikely result of what the government decides to do with the
surplus. If it is used to retire existing debt, then the surplus is pumped right back
into the economy and with the multiplier effect this additional liquid wealth in
the hands of individuals could lead to an increase in aggregate demand and
GDP. [text: E p. 218; MA p. 218]
13. Explain what is meant by a built-in stabilizer and give two examples.
15. Explain how the below graph illustrates the built-in stability of a progressive tax
structure.
The graph illustrates how net taxes are negative as GDP declines which will add
to aggregate demand. When GDP expands, tax revenues increase which
dampens aggregate demand. [text: E pp. 219-220; MA pp. 219-220]
16. In Year 1, the full-employment budget showed a deficit of about $100 billion
and the actual budget showed a deficit of $150 billion one year. In Year 2, the
full employment budget showed a deficit of about $125 billion and the actual
budget showed a deficit of $150 billion. Based on these data, what can be
concluded about the direction of fiscal policy?
Fiscal policy was expansionary because the full-employment budget deficit
increased from one year to the next. The actual deficit is composed of the full-
employment portion and the cyclical portion. The full-employment portion of
the actual budget deficit rose from $100 to $150 billion. The cyclical portion is
determined by taking the actual deficit and subtracting the cyclical portion
from it. The cyclical portion of the actual deficit fell from $50 billion to $25 billion.
The actual budget deficit did not change, but it does not provide a good
indication of the direction of fiscal policy. Only the full-employment budget tells
the direction of fiscal policy. [text: E pp. 220-221; MA pp. 220-221]
17. What is the difference between the actual deficit, the full-employment deficit,
and the cyclical deficit?
The actual budget deficit for any year consists of the full-employment and the
cyclical deficit. The full-employment deficit is the difference between
government expenditures and tax collections which would occur if there were
full employment output. The cyclical deficit is the portion of the actual deficit
that arises because the economy is in recession and is produced by this
downturn in the business cycle. During a recession, a cyclical deficit often
occurs because tax revenues fall as incomes fall and government expenditures
increase as more is spent for government transfer payments and other
programs. The cyclical deficit occurs because of the operation of these
automatic stabilizers. [text: E pp. 221-222; MA pp. 221-222]
18. What does the “full-employment budget” measure and of what significance is
this concept?
The full-employment budget refers to the budget deficit or surplus that would
result with existing tax and spending programs if the economy were operating
at full-employment. In other words, tax revenues and government spending are
estimated at the level that would result if full employment existed.
19. Complete the table below by stating whether the direction of discretionary
fiscal policy was contractionary (C), expansionary (E), or neither (N), given the
hypothetical budget data for an economy.
Actual budget
1 – 3.9% – 2.1%
2 – 4.5 – 2.6 E
3 – 4.7 – 3.0 E
4 – 3.9 – 2.6 C
5 – 2.9 – 2.0 C
6 – 2.2 – 1.9 C
New22. Explain the six problems, criticisms, or complications that arise in the
implementation of fiscal policy.
First there is a timing problem. Three lags are identified under the “timing
problem” category. There is a lag in recognizing the phase of the business
cycle; there is an administrative lag in deciding which policies to follow; there is
an operational lag in terms of the impact of the policy once it is implemented.
Second, there are political considerations in the adoption of fiscal policy. There
is some evidence of a political business cycle where particular expansionary
policies are followed in election years whether or not economic conditions merit
them.
Fourth, the taxing and spending decisions of state and local governments may
counteract or reduce the effectiveness of fiscal policy decisions at the federal
level. The U.S. government may enact an expansionary fiscal policy by
increasing its budget deficit, but state and local governments often have to
balance a budget and economic conditions may force them to adopt a
contractionary policy that partially offset what the federal government is
seeking to achieve.
Sixth, there are complications to domestic fiscal policy from the national
economy’s connection to the world economy. Economic shock from abroad
can have an effect on the nation’s imports and exports. The net export effect
can reduce the intended effects of fiscal policy. [text: E pp. 223-226; MA pp.
223-226]
New23. Explain the problems giving rise to this statement: “You would think the
government would want to do something to improve economic conditions
when the economy is in trouble, but the government is slow to act.”
Fiscal policy is subject to timing problems. There are three timing lags that limit
the speed with which fiscal policy can be enacted and effective. First, there is
a lag in recognizing the phase of the business cycle to determine when the
government might want to provide help. Second, there is an administrative lag
in decision-making that involves deciding which specific policies should be
adopted. Third, there is an operational lag because the adoption of policies
takes time to have an effect on output and employment. [text: E p. 223; MA p.
223]
New24. How do expectations about the future by households and businesses affect the
effectiveness of fiscal policy? Cite examples.
If households or businesses expect that the fiscal policy changes are only
temporary, they may not change their behavior in the expected way. For
example, if tax cuts are enacted to stimulate consumer spending, some
consumers may not change their spending habits if they think the tax change is
only temporary. In the future, they will have to pay more in taxes, so they might
increase their saving. Similarly, businesses may not invest in new plants and
equipment if they get a tax cut, if they expect taxes in the future to rise or the
fiscal policy to be ineffective. [text: E pp. 223-224; MA pp. 223-224]
25. “If economic forecasting was a more exact science, the business cycle could
be entirely corrected by fiscal measures.” Do you agree?
Exact forecasting, if possible, would still not solve all of the problems
encountered in trying to correct the business cycle. There is also the problem of
timing the enactment and application of fiscal policy, not to mention the
coordination of monetary policy and international economic policies, or
reduced private spending (“crowding out”). [text: E pp. 223-225; MA pp. 223-
225]
27. Using the below graph, illustrate the possible impact of a crowding-out effect of
a fiscal policy by drawing in the relevant aggregate demand shifts. Label and
Expansionary fiscal policy increases demand from AD1 to AD2, but this crowds
out some private investment spending that offsets the increase to some extent
causing AD2 to decrease to AD3. See graph below. [text: E pp. 224-225; MA pp.
224-225]
28. Explain how the net-export effect would reduce the effectiveness of fiscal
policy.
If an expansionary fiscal policy brings with it higher interest rates, this could
increase the demand for American dollars by foreign investors seeking to earn
the higher U.S. returns. This appreciation of the dollar makes U.S. goods and
services more expensive to foreigners and foreign imports less expensive to
Americans. The net export category of aggregate demand will be reduced
which would reduce the impact of expansionary fiscal policy. A contractionary
fiscal policy could have the opposite effect causing net exports to increase that
again reduces the desired effect of the contractionary fiscal policy. [text: E pp.
225-226; MA pp. 225-226]
New29. What fiscal policy is most likely to be invoked during a period of recession and
high unemployment? A period of rapid inflation? What political, investment,
and international problems might the U.S. Congress encounter in enacting these
policies and putting them into effect?
During recession and high unemployment, the government would most likely
initiate an expansionary fiscal policy. A contractionary fiscal policy would most
likely be called for during a period of rapid inflation, especially if it seems to be
demand-pull inflation.
Several problems are likely to arise in enacting either of these policies. Timing
lags in recognition, implementation, and impact are one concern. Another has
to do with political realities. A contractionary policy has many unpopular
aspects to it because it calls for raising taxes and for cutting government
spending. There are also unique problems associated with expansionary policy:
crowding out is one potential result that would reduce the expansionary effect
of the policy. In both cases, the net-export part of aggregate demand is likely
to move in a direction that would tend to offset the policy. [text: E pp. 223-226;
MA pp. 223-226]
30. (Last Word) What is the purpose of the Conference Board’s index of leading economic indicators?
The index of leading indicators is a monthly index of economic statistics that are used to forecast the
direction of real GDP. Changes in the index provide an indication of the future direction of the economy
and are useful to policy makers in developing responses to deteriorating conditions in the economy. The
rule of thumb is that three successive decreases or increases in the index indicate a change of direction in
the economy. [text: E p. 227; MA p. 227]
31. (Last Word) Why is the index of leading economic indicators a composite index of ten economic statistics
and not just one?
Each of the economic statistics used to prepare the index may increase or decrease in any month and thus
give false or contradictory signals about the direction of the economy. It is less likely that all these
economic indicators, taken together, will give as many false signals about the direction of the economy as
one indicator will. Thus the composite index is more reliable than any one indicator. The composite
index, however, is not infallible and can also give false indications about the direction of the economy
because of changes in the structure of the economy or developments that are not covered by the indicators
that make up the index. [text: E p. 227; MA p. 227]