(9781788974998 - Understanding The Blockchain Economy) Introduction
(9781788974998 - Understanding The Blockchain Economy) Introduction
Introduction
This book introduces a new field of economic inquiry. What we call
‘institutional cryptoeconomics’ is the application of the transaction cost
economics of Ronald Coase, James Buchanan, Oliver Williamson, and
Elinor Ostrom to blockchains; the distributed ledger technology first
invented by the pseudonymous Satoshi Nakamoto for the development
of the Bitcoin cryptocurrency. Where cryptoeconomics is the study of the
economics of blockchain consensus mechanisms – a field of game theory
and mechanism design – institutional cryptoeconomics is the study of how
blockchains interact with our existing and future social institutions, from
the nature of contracts, to the shape of the firm, to the structures of global
trade, all the way to the dynamics of capitalism and geopolitics.1
An economic analysis can be called institutional if it studies the social
institutions that coordinate and govern exchange. Adam Smith discov-
ered the function of markets in arranging production and distribution
through incentives.2 Friedrich Hayek uncovered the function of dispersed
information and its relationship to prices.3 Ronald Coase revealed the role
of the firm, pioneering the transaction cost tradition which informs this
book.4 Duncan Black and Anthony Downs conceptualised the role of
democratic government.5 James Buchanan discovered the role of clubs.6
Elinor Ostrom revealed the commons as a mechanism for economic coor-
dination.7 Institutional cryptoeconomics adds another institutional form
to this schema: blockchains. Blockchains are an economic infrastructure,
alongside markets, the firm, governments, clubs, and the commons, for
Foundation (2017).
2 Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (University
no. 4 (1945).
4 Ronald H. Coase, ‘The problem of social cost’, Journal of Law and Economics 56, no. 4
(1960); Ronald H. Coase, ‘The nature of the firm’, Economica 4, no. 16 (1937).
5 Duncan Black, Theory Committees and Elections (Cambridge University Press, 2011);
8
Davidson, Filippi, and Potts.
9
The Economist, ‘The trust machine’, 31 October 2015.
10
J.L. Morrow Jr, Mark H. Hansen, and Allison W. Pearson, ‘The cognitive and affective
antecedents of general trust within cooperative organizations’, Journal of Managerial Issues
16, no. 1 (2004). See the discussion in Sinclair Davidson, Mikayla Novak, and Jason Potts,
‘The cost of trust: a pilot study’, Journal of the British Blockchain Association 7 (2018).
11 Oliver E. Williamson, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (Free Press, 1985).
12 Kevin Werbach, The Blockchain and the New Architecture of Trust (MIT Press, 2018);
SSRN (2018).
14 Rainer Böhme et al., ‘Bitcoin: economics, technology, and governance’, Journal of
Economic Perspectives 29, no. 2 (2015); Joseph Abadi and Markus Brunnermeier, ‘Blockchain
economics’, 2018, https://scholar.princeton.edu/sites/default/files/markus/files/blockchain_pa
per_v3g.pdf.
15 We refer to this as Satoshi’s Bitcoin rather than Nakamoto’s Bitcoin following the
naming convention of the fundamental unit of a bitcoin as a Satoshi, not as a Nakamoto. The
Satoshi identity went silent after 2010. Satoshi’s last post is on the Bitcoin forum is https://
bitcointalk.org/index.php?topic=2228.msg29479#msg29479. Despite much effort by journal-
ists and amateur internet detectives, his, her, or their true identity is still unknown.
16 Timothy C. May, ‘The crypto anarchist manifesto’, 22 November, https://www.activism.
net/cypherpunk/crypto-anarchy.html.
17 Timothy C. May, ‘Libertaria in cyberspace, or cyberspace more hospitable to ideas
18 A good overview of the state of electronic payments at the turn of the century is
N. Asokan, Phillipe A. Janson, Michael Steiner, and Michael Waidner, ‘The state of the art
in electronic payment systems’, Computer 30, no. 9 (1997). See also Jaap-Henk Hoepman,
‘Distributed double spending prevention’ (paper presented at the International Workshop on
Security Protocols, 2007).
19 John P. Conley, ‘Encryption, Hashing, PPK, and Blockchain: A Simple Introduction’
20
Alex de Vries, ‘Bitcoin’s growing energy problem’, Joule 2, no. 5 (2018).
21
For the academic progenitors of Bitcoin see Arvind Narayanan and Jeremy Clark,
‘Bitcoin’s academic pedigree’, Communications of the ACM 60, no. 12 (2017). For peer-to-
peer networking see A. Oram, Peer-to-Peer: Harnessing the Power of Disruptive Technologies
(O’Reilly Media, 2001).
22 The problem was named in Leslie Lamport, Robert Shostak, and Marshall Pease, ‘The
Tolerance for computer-flown aircraft, see Leslie Lamport, ‘My writings’, 20 September,
https://lamport.azurewebsites.net/pubs/pubs.html.
23 Our contribution to this is Chris Berg, Sinclair Davidson, and Jason Potts, ‘Beyond
Ivy Vecna, and Forrest Stonedahl, ‘Data insertion in Bitcoin’s blockchain’, Ledger 3 (2018).
Hyperledger, control who can validate new blocks and who can access the
ledger. While guaranteeing much faster transaction times, these private
blockchains trade off decentralisation for efficiency, resulting in a hybrid
between traditional shared databases and fully distributed ledgers.
One of the most significant innovations in the blockchain space is the
addition of fully operational scripting languages into the blockchain.
Bitcoin is built around a highly constrained programming language
called Script, which allows developers to impose restrictions (such as
multi-signature keys) on how individual tokens are spent. But if any
arbitrary data can be placed into the Bitcoin blockchain, why not entire
computer programs? Ethereum, which was released in July 2015, claims
to be fully ‘Turing complete’ programming language, a criteria for general
purpose computing derived from the work of the computer scientist Alan
Turing.25 Ethereum programs execute as written everywhere that the
Ethereum blockchain is stored; the result being distributed, censorship-
proof algorithms that underpin Ethereum’s goal to be a ‘world computer’.
Where Bitcoin was designed with the intention of an un-censorable global
payments system, Ethereum generalises that to all digital algorithms. There
are now a number of blockchains that offer comparably complex program-
ming languages, whether those languages are hosted ‘on-chain’ (such as
NEO and EOS) or ‘off-chain’ (such as NEM).
These features allow for the implementation of what the computer
scientist and legal scholar Nick Szabo first conceptualised in 1994 as
‘smart contracts’. A smart contract, wrote Szabo, is a ‘computerized trans-
action protocol that executes the terms of a contract’.26 Smart contracts
are algorithms with contractual conditions built in, such as automatic
transfers of value when conditions are triggered. Smart contracts are
arguably an ironic misnomer. They execute precisely as written under any
circumstances, even when unanticipated events might mean that all parties
to the contract would rather they did not do so. Once a contract is pub-
lished onto a blockchain, it will execute, even if it has been written poorly
featuring coding bugs. Researchers have found numerous contracts on the
Ethereum blockchain that might lock funds indefinitely or leak funds to
unauthorised users.27 With no central authority to appeal to, contractual
terms are irrevocable even in circumstances of error. But this is a feature,
25 There is some dispute as to whether Ethereum is genuinely Turing complete, given it
is restricted by the amount of Ethereum tokens Ether (ETH) in the network. See Andrew
Miller, ‘Ethereum isn’t Turing complete, and it doesn’t matter anyway’ (Consensys, 2016).
26 Nick Szabo, ‘Smart contracts’, http://www.fon.hum.uva.nl/rob/Courses/Infor mationIn
Speech/CDROM/Literature/LOTwinterschool2006/szabo.best.vwh.net/smart.contracts.html.
27 Ivica Nikolic et al., ‘Finding the greedy, prodigal, and suicidal contracts at scale’, arXiv
not a bug. As we shall see, a smart contract self-executes – that is, triggers,
transfers payments, and enforces terms – without the need for any external
agent, such as a court. Smart contracts are one of the central underlying
technologies of the blockchain economy.
Blockchain innovation has been intense since Satoshi published the
Bitcoin White Paper in 2008, and cryptocurrencies are merely the first
use-case for this new technology. While a complete survey of the applica-
tions of blockchain is neither possible or necessary here, blockchains are
being used to manage supply chains in fields as diverse as agriculture
and advanced manufacturing, to coordinate trade finance, for identity,
certification and licence management, banking, registries for land, water
energy, and intellectual property, for medical records, to organise data for
smart cities, and to register legal documents such as wills.28
More ambitious applications exploit the possibilities of smart contracts
to coordinate activity without the need for hierarchy, even human agency.29
Distributed autonomous organisations (DAOs) are organisations built
around smart contracts and a blockchain, controlled in a decentralised
manner by its owners. The Ethereum game CryptoKitties, which allows
users to breed and exchange unique digital cats, represents an entirely new
category of intellectual property.30 Cellarius, also built on the Ethereum
network, is an ambitious attempt to build a collective storytelling plat-
form, where users coordinate around a sci-fi world building and narrative
creation structure. Throughout this book we shall explore some blockchain
applications in depth. But for now, the remarkable breadth of applications
that have already been developed, and the extraordinary diversity of fields
in which blockchains are being trialled and applied, suggests, at a first
instance, that this technology has particular economic properties that
make it institutionally significant.
28 Jason Potts, Ellie Rennie, and Jake Goldenfein, ‘Blockchains and the crypto city’,
it-Information Technology 59, no. 6 (2017); E. Ganne, ‘Can blockchain revolutionise inter-
national trade?’, 2018, https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/blockchainrev18_e.pdf;
Evangelos Benos, Rod Garratt, and Pedro Gurrola-Perez, ‘The economics of distributed
ledger technology for securities settlement’, SSRN (2017); Michael Casey et al., ‘The impact
of blockchain technology on finance: a catalyst for change’, Geneva Report on the World
Economy, no. 21 (2018); Amy Whitaker and Roman Kräussl, ‘Blockchain, fractional owner-
ship, and the future of creative work’, CFS Working Paper Series 594, Center for Financial
Studies (CFS), 2018.
29 Anthony J. Casey and Anthony Niblett, ‘Self-driving contracts’, Journal of Corporation
Law 43 (2017); Richard Holden and Anup Malani, ‘Can blockchain solve the holdup prob-
lem in contracts?’, University of Chicago Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics
Research Paper, 2017; Joshua S. Gans, ‘The fine print in smart contracts’, NBER Working
Paper No. w25443, 2019.
30 Chris Berg, Sinclair Davidson, and Jason Potts, ‘KodakOne could be the start of a new
Blockchains are an early stage technology. While Bitcoin now has a dec-
ade-long history, many of the blockchain innovations which have led to the
field of institutional cryptoeconomics are only a few years old. Ethereum
was only released in July 2015. The zero knowledge proof privacy coin
Zcash was only released in October 2016. There are many uncertainties
about the future of blockchain development as we write this book. Public
blockchains tend to have low transaction throughput, at least compared
to centralised systems. The proof of work algorithm used by Bitcoin and
many other second and third generation blockchains is highly energy
intensive, and has created many environmental concerns. Alternative
mechanisms that might solve scaling problems and environmental costs –
such as proof of stake, distributed proof of stake, and practical Byzantine
fault tolerance – are in an earlier experimental stage of development.
Even if the technical challenges are worked out, the user experience for
blockchains leaves something to be desired: it is time consuming and tedi-
ous to convert fiat currency into cryptocurrency; key management can be
complex and brings security risks; and there is still a non-trivial amount of
technical knowledge necessary to interact with blockchains.
These limitations are what might be expected from a technology just a
decade old, but it is also possible that there is some as yet undiscovered
limiting condition around a critical blockchain characteristic. For example,
Zooko’s triangle, suggested by the developer of Zcash, Zooko Wilcox-
O’Hearn, suggests that there is a trade-off between three desirable proper-
ties of identities on a network protocol: that they are human-readable, that
they are secure, and that they are distributed (that is, no central authority
has control over identities). Wilcox-O’Hearn suggested that identity man-
agement systems can only have two of these three properties.31 There is
a chance that researchers or developers will discover constraints around
decentralisation, consensus, availability, and persistency that prevent limit-
ing the potential of blockchain as an economic institution.
Alternatively, it is possible that blockchains might be superseded by new
distributed ledger technologies. Nakamoto’s data structuring technique –
grouping transactions into blocks that include hash pointers to previous
blocks – is unlikely to be the end state of distributed ledger development.
For example, there are a number of distributed ledger protocols built
around directed acyclic graphs (DAGs) which store transactions in nodes
rather than blocks. Richard Goldschmidt described the first consequential
12 October, https://web.archive.org/web/20011020191610/http://zooko.com/distnames.html.
32 Richard Goldschmidt, ‘Some aspects of evolution’, Science 78, no. 2033 (1933);
Richard Goldschmidt, The Material Basis of Evolution (Yale University Press, 1940); Joel
Mokyr, The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress (Oxford
University Press, 1990).
33 Gwern Branwen, ‘Bitcoin is worse is better’, 2 January, https://www.gwern.net/Bit
coin-is-Worse-is-Better.
34 See Primavera De Filippi and Aaron Wright, Blockchain and the Law: The Rule of Code
(Harvard University Press, 2018); Darcy W.E. Allen, Aaron M. Lane, and Marta Poblet, ‘The
governance of blockchain dispute resolution’, SSRN (2018).
conditions that are otherwise far removed from the observable, low-energy
world. High-energy physics seeks to understand the fundamental building
blocks of the universe – space, time, matter, and energy – by exaggerating
the conditions of normal existence. A particle accelerator recreates on
Earth conditions that otherwise pertain at the core of a star, or in the very
early universe. High-trust economics offers a similar experimental method.
It allows us to explore conditions in an economy in which trust is maxim-
ised. A high-trust economy is one in which contracts are self-enforcing. To
reveal the fundamental nature of the economy, we do high-trust economics
– we crank up the trust – which permits near perfect promise and trust.
Institutional cryptoeconomics is the study of a new technology and its
implications, but it is also a methodology, based on the exploration of the
nature of a high-trust economy using a tool as both an actual technology
in the world, and as an ideal type, a ‘perfect ledger’.
The difference of course between a particle accelerator and a block-
chain is that blockchains now exist in the real world. We do not have to
construct them as experimental domains, or theorise about their exist-
ence. Blockchains have been brought into the world and now coordinate
economic activity. Much of this book is based on our observation of the
development of this technology over the last decade. But institutional
cryptoeconomics does not actually depend upon the success of blockchain
technologies. It is sufficient for our purpose that blockchains exist as a
concept: a concept of a trustless technology of governance and coordina-
tion, a new technology of trust. The idea of a blockchain is sufficient to
establish institutional cryptoeconomics as a theoretical field. That they
exist – that they are being built, that entrepreneurs, engineers and enthusi-
asts are investing enormous resources into their success – makes the study
of institutional cryptoeconomics urgent.
This book has two distinct audiences: economists and students of econom-
ics on the one side, and those who work or are interested in the blockchain
industry on the other. We hope that the book will offer the tools that will
allow these two audiences to communicate and share ideas. We proceed,
therefore, as follows. In Chapters 2, 3, and 4 we spell out the basic founda-
tions of institutional cryptoeconomics. Chapter 2 presents a straightfor-
ward analytical framework to understand the properties of blockchains
through Oliver Williamson’s transaction cost framework. Blockchains
reduce opportunism and offer a institutional technology for governing spe-
cific assets. In Chapter 3 we fold out some of the broader consequences of
35 Paul A. Strassmann, Information Payoff: The Transformation of Work in the Electronic