Escritos de Economía
Escritos de Economía
Preliminaries
“If economy fluctuates for whatever reason, then it is almost always possible
to neutralize these cyclic motions by means of anti-cyclic demand policies”
1
Chapter 2
Goodwin Model
ȧ(t)
= α, (2.1)
a(t)
Ṅ (t)
=β (2.2)
N (t)
L(t)
λ(t) = (2.5)
N (t)
2
In order not to move away from the optimal allocation of resources we take
on full capital utilization
K(t)
Y (t) = = a(t)L(t) (2.6)
ν
Next, we assume that the real-wage rate is increasing around full employ-
ment. If we denote w(t) as the real-wage function the latter can be expressed
by
ẇ(t)
= Φ(λ(t)) (2.7)
w(t)
for an increasing Phillips curve, Φ(λ(t)).
The model also embraces Say’s law which states that real investment is
equal to real profits and real consumption is equal to real earnings from labor.
This is
and
Y (t)ν = K(t)
3
then
Ẏ (t) (1 − ω(t))
= −δ
Y (t) ν
we define µ as the rate of growth of the product for later analysis
Ẏ (t)
µ(ω) = .
Y (t)
Taking logarithm to equation 2.9, deriving and taking equation 2.7 into ac-
count we have
ω̇(t) ẇ(t) ȧ(t)
= − = Φ(λ(t)) − α
ω(t) w(t) a(t)
From the definition of employment rate in equation 2.5 and full capital uti-
lization we get
2.1.1 Equilibrium
The non-trivial equilibriums of the system 2.10 are equal to
0 Φ0 (λ̄)
J(ω̄, λ̄) =
− λ̄ν 0
4
2.1.2 Interpretation
We can write the previous system 2.10 in terms of rate of growth as follows
ω̇(t)
= Φ(λ(t)) − α
ω(t)
λ̇(t) 1 − ω(t)
= −α−β−δ
λ(t) ν
If product growth rate rises faster than the constant rates of labor produc-
tivity and total labor force, equations 2.3 and 2.4, then employment growth
rate rises and labor share shrinks. Assuming an increasing behavior of em-
ployment this yields a raise in labor, because of the assumed increasing form
of the total labor force, meaning that firms hire more workers so that em-
ployment grows faster than unemployment. By the full capital utilization
assumption, as labor and labor productivity rises so does product thus by
constant capital-to-output assumption capital increases so showing a trade-
off between capital and labor. The demand for employers pushes the growth
rate of wages up. This is a result of considering an increasing Phillips curve.
Labor share growth will only increase if wage growth is greater than that
of labor productivity. As employment continues rising the rate of growth of
wages star receding and so labor growth. In this way product and capital
decay and labor share appreciates.
5
0.06
0.02 a⋅ (t)/a(t): Productivity growth
a⋅ (t)/a(t)
−0.06 −0.02
Figure 2.1
Source: WDI, own elaboration.
⋅
N(t)/N(t): Total labor force growth
0.06
N(t)/N(t)
0.02
⋅
−0.02
Figure 2.2
Source: WDI, own elaboration.
6
ratio is not constant and has a decreasing trend.
ν
8
capital−to−output
7
6
5
4
Figure 2.3
Source: WDI, own elaboration.
Φ1 = φ1 λ + φ2
φ1
Φ2 = + φ2
(1 − λ)2
table A.3 provides the results. We see that the linear model explains more
than the cuadratic inverse model.
7
Linear Phillips curve
●
0.00 0.05
●
● ●
● ●
●
● ●
● ●
w⋅ (t)/w(t)
●
● ●●
● ●
● ●
● ●
●
−0.10
λ(t)
Figure 2.4
Source: WDI, own elaboration.
●
0.00 0.05
●
● ●
● ●
●
● ●
● ●
w⋅ (t)/w(t)
●
● ●●
● ●
●
●● ●
●
−0.10
1/(1−λ)2
Figure 2.5
Source: WDI and PWT, own elaboration.
The following plot let us notice the trade-off between lambda and omega,
when lambda increases omega decreases and vice versa.
8
0.970
0.45 ω(t)
λ(t)
0.960
0.40
ω(t)
λ(t)
0.950
0.35
0.940
0.30
Figure 2.6
Source: WDI and PWT, own elaboration.
The following omega and lambda parametric plot unveils what seems to
be a clockwise cycle behavior
(ω(t),λ(t))
0.970
2014
2012
2013
2011
2010
0.960
2009
2008
2007
2006
λ(t)
0.950
2005 2003
2004 1994
1995
1997
1993
0.940
2000
2002 1996 1991
1999
2001
1998 1992
ω(t)
Figure 2.7
Source: WDI, own elaboration.
9
2.3 Calibration for Peru
The purpose of this section is to provide details on how we handled data to
estimate the parameters of the model and how we validate it.
We worked with the World Development Indicator (WDI) database from
the World Bank and the Penn World Table (PWT) which are more complete
for our purposes compared to BCRP and INEI databases. There is data
available from 1950 to 2019, but not for all variables (e.g employment rate).
The parameters of the Goodwin model we need to estimate are the fol-
lowing: growth rate of productivity and labor, the capital-to-output ratio
and the deprecation rate of capital.
The details of the estimation are found in table 3.4. We obtain α̂ = 0.0129
and β̂ = 0.0315.
−13.1
ln(a(t))
−13.3
−13.5
t
25.8
ln(N(t))
25.4
25.0
Figure 2.8
Logarithm of productivity and labor respectively
10
For capital-to-output constant ν we notice that the variation is significant
before 1990. From 1990 the average is 7 and from 2004 on is 5 and the trend
is downwards. Taking into account (Carranza, Fernandez-Baca, & Morón,
2005) which states that the capital-to-output constant is going up during the
period 1968-1990 we have the set of possibilities ν̂ ∈ {3, · · · , 7}.
ν
8
capital−to−output
7
6
5
4
Figure 2.9
Capital-to-output rate
From PWT we get δ̂ = 0.051 which is a value closed to the one used in
(Céspedes & Ramı́rez-Rondán, 2014).
δ
0.050
0.045
delta
0.040
0.035
Figure 2.10
Capital depreciation
11
Parameter value
α̂ 0.0129
β̂ 0.0315
ν̂ {3, · · · , 7}
δ̂ 0.051
We replace the values of the parameters in the set of equations 2.10 and
obtain the following model for Peru:
Φ1 = 2.4935λ(t) − 2.37
12
we solve the system for the initial values ω(0) = 0.34 and λ(0) = 0.95 and
obtain the following the following plots:
1.5
1.0
1.0
Lambda
Lambda
0.5
0.5
0.0
0.0
0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5
Omega Omega
1.5
1.0
1.0
Lambda
Lambda
0.5
0.5
0.0
0.0
Omega Omega
0.5
0.0
Omega
13
nu=3, w_0=0.34, lambda_0=0.95 nu=4, w_0=0.34, lambda_0=0.95
1.5
1.5
Omega Omega
Lambda Lambda
Omega, Lambda
Omega, Lambda
1.0
1.0
0.5
0.5
0.0
0.0
0 20 40 60 80 100 0 20 40 60 80 100
Time Time
1.5
Omega Omega
Lambda Lambda
Omega, Lambda
Omega, Lambda
1.0
1.0
0.5
0.5
0.0
0.0
0 20 40 60 80 100 0 20 40 60 80 100
Time Time
Omega
Lambda
Omega, Lambda
1.0
0.5
0.0
0 20 40 60 80 100
Time
T = 7.864 ≈ 8 years
14
Regressing from the data we have that the model is the following
9 ∗ 10−5
Φ2 = − 0.04
(1 − λ(t))2
15
nu=3, w_0=0.34, lambda_0=0.95 nu=4, w_0=0.34, lambda_0=0.95
1.5
1.5
1.0
1.0
Lambda
Lambda
0.5
0.5
0.0
0.0
0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5
Omega Omega
1.5
1.0
1.0
Lambda
Lambda
0.5
0.5
0.0
0.0
Omega Omega
0.5
0.0
Omega
16
nu=3, w_0=0.34, lambda_0=0.95 nu=4, w_0=0.34, lambda_0=0.95
1.5
1.5
Omega Omega
Lambda Lambda
Omega, Lambda
Omega, Lambda
1.0
1.0
0.5
0.5
0.0
0.0
0 20 40 60 80 100 0 20 40 60 80 100
Time Time
1.5
Omega Omega
Lambda Lambda
Omega, Lambda
Omega, Lambda
1.0
1.0
0.5
0.5
0.0
0.0
0 20 40 60 80 100 0 20 40 60 80 100
Time Time
Omega
Lambda
Omega, Lambda
1.0
0.5
0.0
0 20 40 60 80 100
Time
17
nu=6, w_0=0.34, lambda_0=0.95
1.5
1.0
Lambda
0.5
0.0
Omega
Figure 2.11
Theoretical and real ω and λ
18
Chapter 3
Keen Model:
We assume that capitalists do not invest the total of the profits this way we
introduce the finance sector. We have a new variable D which is the amount
of debt in real terms
U = (1 − ω − rd)Y
where d = D/Y is the debt ratio in the economy. Reinvesting all the profits
lead to constant debt levels which differ from reality according to Minsky 82.
The real behavior is that high net profits lead to more borrowing whereas
low net profits lead to deleveraging of the economy. Accumulation of capital
is
K̇ = κ(1 − ω − rd)Y − δK
where the rate of new investment is a nonlinear increasing function of the
net profit.] As before we have
ω̇ = ω [Φ(λ) − α]
κ(1 − ω − rd)
λ̇ = λ −α−β−δ
ν
we assume the following behavior of debt:
Ḋ = κ(1 − ω − rd)Y − (1 − ω − rd)Y
so we have the
ω̇ = ω [Φ(λ) − α]
κ(1 − ω − rd)
λ̇ = λ −α−β−δ
ν
κ(1 − ω − rd)
d˙ = d r − + δ + κ(1 − ω − rd) − (1 − ω)
ν
19
Appendices
20
Appendix A
Estimations
Table A.1
Results
Dependent variable:
growth.prodty growth.lf
(1) (2)
YEAR 0.002∗∗ −0.001∗∗∗
(0.001) (0.0003)
Observations 23 27
R2 0.217 0.448
Adjusted R2 0.180 0.426
Residual Std. Error 0.031 (df = 21) 0.013 (df = 25)
F Statistic 5.832∗∗ (df = 1; 21) 20.328∗∗∗ (df = 1; 25)
∗ ∗∗ ∗∗∗
Note: p<0.1; p<0.05; p<0.01
21
Table A.2
Results
Dependent variable:
nu
YEAR −0.457∗∗∗
(0.036)
Constant 920.719∗∗∗
(71.744)
Observations 55
R2 0.751
Adjusted R2 0.746
Residual Std. Error 4.251 (df = 53)
F Statistic 160.018∗∗∗ (df = 1; 53)
∗ ∗∗ ∗∗∗
Note: p<0.1; p<0.05; p<0.01
22
Table A.3
Results
Dependent variable:
growth.w
(1) (2)
lambda 2.494∗∗∗
(0.705)
invcuadl 0.0001∗∗
(0.00003)
Observations 23 23
R2 0.373 0.275
Adjusted R2 0.343 0.240
Residual Std. Error (df = 21) 0.035 0.038
F Statistic (df = 1; 21) 12.499∗∗∗ 7.957∗∗
∗ ∗∗ ∗∗∗
Note: p<0.1; p<0.05; p<0.01
ln a = ln a0 + αt
ln N = ln N0 + βt
23
Table 3.4
Results
Dependent variable:
lnprodty lnlabor DELTA
(1) (2) (3)
YEAR 0.013∗∗∗ 0.032∗∗∗ −0.0003∗∗∗
(0.002) (0.001) (0.0001)
Observations 24 28 65
R2 0.621 0.965 0.219
Adjusted R2 0.604 0.964 0.206
Residual Std. Error 0.073 (df = 22) 0.050 (df = 26) 0.009 (df = 63)
F Statistic 36.022∗∗∗ (df = 1; 22) 720.535∗∗∗ (df = 1; 26) 17.646∗∗∗ (df = 1; 63)
Note: ∗ p<0.1; ∗∗ p<0.05; ∗∗∗ p<0.01
24
References
Carranza, E., Fernandez-Baca, J., & Morón, E. (2005). Markets, government,
and the sources of growth in peru. Sources of Growth in Latin America.
What is Missing.
Céspedes, N., & Ramı́rez-Rondán, N. (2014). Total factor productivity
estimation in peru: Primal and dual approaches. Peruvian Economic
Association.
Costa Lima, B. R. (2013). The dynamical system approach to macroeco-
nomics (Published doctoral dissertation). McMaster University, Hamil-
ton, Ontario.
Gabish, G., & Lorenz, H. (1987). Bussines cycle theory: A survey of methods
and concepts (Vol. 283). Berlin-Germany: Springer-Verlag.
Goodwin, R. (1967). Socialism, capitalism and economic growth: Essays
presented to Maurice Dobb. In C. Feinstein (Ed.), (p. 54-58). Cambrige:
Cambridge University Press.
Harvie, D. (2000, May). Testing Goodwin: Growth cycles in the oecd coun-
tries. Cambridge Journal of Economics.
Herrera-Medina, E., & Garcia-Molina, M. (2010). Are there Good-
win employment-distribution cycles? international empirical evidence.
Cuadernos de economı́a.
25