Microeconomics Ii Bcom 4 Semester (Hons & Gen) Koyel Chakraborty Oligopoly Market
Microeconomics Ii Bcom 4 Semester (Hons & Gen) Koyel Chakraborty Oligopoly Market
2. Advertising:
3. Group Behaviour:
(i) The firms constituting the group may not have a common goal
(ii) The group may or may not have a formal or informal organization
with accepted rules of conduct
(iii) The group may be dominated by a leader but other firms in the
group may not follow him in a uniform manner.
4. Competition:
(c) High capital requirements due to plant costs, advertising costs, etc.
6. Lack of Uniformity:
In oligopoly situation, each firm has to stick to its price. If any firm tries
to reduce its price, the rival firms will retaliate by a higher reduction in
their prices. This will lead to a situation of price war which benefits
none. On the other hand, if any firm increases its price with a view to
increase its profits; the other rival firms will not follow the same. Hence,
no firm would like to reduce the price or to increase the price. The price
rigidity will take place.
(i) It is possible that other maintain the prices they had before. In this
case, an oligopolist can hope that its demand would increase
substantially as the prices are lowered,
(ii) When an oligopolist reduces his price, the other sellers also lower
their prices by an equivalent amount. In this situation although demand
of the oligopolist making the first move will increase as he lowers his
price, the increase itself would be much smaller than in the first case.
(iii) When a firm reduces its price, the other sellers reduce their prices far
more. Under the circumstances the demand for the product of the
oligopolistic firm which makes the first move may decrease. Thus
uncertainty under oligopoly is inevitable, and as a result, the demand
curve faced by each firm belonging to the group is necessarily
indeterminate.
The kink in the demand curve stems from the asymmetric behavioural
pattern of sellers. If a seller increases the price of his product, the rival
sellers will not follow him so that the first seller loses a considerable
amount of sales. In other words, every price increase will go unnoticed
by rivals.
On the other hand, if one firm reduces the price of its product other
firms will follow the first firm so that they must not lose customers. In
other words, every price will be matched by an equivalent price cut. As
a result, the benefit of price cut by the first firm will be inconsiderable.
As a result of this behavioural pattern, the demand curve will be kinked
at the ruling market price.
Suppose, the prevailing price of an oligopoly product in the market is
QE or OP of Fig. 5.19. If one seller increases the price above OP, rival
sellers will keep the prices of their products at OP. As a result of high
price charged by the firm, buyers will shift to products of other sellers
who have kept their prices at the old level. Consequently, sales of the
first seller will drop considerably.
That is why demand curve in this zone (dE) is relatively elastic. On the
other hand, if a seller reduces the price of his product below QE, others
will follow him so that demand for their products does not decline.
Thus, demand curve in this region (i.e., ED) is relatively inelastic. This
behavioural pattern thus explains why prices are inflexible in the
oligopoly market — even if demand and costs change.
(v) Each firm knows the market demand for the product.
(vii) Both the firms have the same expectations about the prices and
productivities of the inputs which they use.
(viii) The price of the product is the sole parameter of action of each
firm.
(ix) The two firms are contemplating whether or not to form a cartel
and agree upon a price that will promise the maximum
maximorum of profits per period to both of them jointly
Always, every firm has the inclination to achieve more strength and
power over the rival firms. As a result, in the oligopolist industry, one
finds the emergence of a few powerful competitors who cannot be
eliminated easily by other powerful firms.
Under the circumstance, some of these firms act together or collude with
each other to reap maximum advantage. In fact, in oligopolist industry,
there is a natural tendency for collusion. The most important forms of
collusion are: price leadership cartel and merger and acquisition.
Suppose, the dominant firm sets the price at OP1 (where DT and MCs
intersect each other at point C). The small firms meet the entire demand
P1C at the price OP1. Thus, the dominant firm has nothing to sell in the
market. At a price of OP3, the small firm will supply nothing. It is
obvious that price will be set in between OP1 and OP3 by the leader.
The demand curve faced by the leader firm of the oligopoly industry is
determined for any price—it is the horizontal distance between industry
demand curve, DT, and the marginal cost curves of all small firms, MCS.
In Fig. 5.20, DL is the leader’s demand curve and the corresponding MR
curve is MRL.
Since basically the difference between cartel and merger is a legal one,
we won’t consider mergers and acquisitions. The marginalistic principle
applied in the case of profit maximizing cartel is also applicable in the
case of merger.
Conclusion: