Montgomery The Past and Future of Workers' Control
Montgomery The Past and Future of Workers' Control
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Temple University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access
to Workers' Struggles, Past and Present
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CHAPTER TWENTY-ONE
The Past
and Future
of Workers' Control
by David Montgomery
389
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Militancy, Union Politics, and Workers' Control
which guides that activity has correspondingly become separated from the
actual carrying out of the work. It has increasingly become codified in the
form of engineering of scientific knowledge, which is in the heads of special-
ists hired by the owners to manage the works, rather than in the heads of the
workers themselves. This process appeared in manufacturing even before
the development of high level machine technology, and it has continued on
ever rising levels since the emergence of factories, reaching its highest peak
in today's automated firm. Science and technology themselves have been
appropriated by capital and confront ordinary working people as alien,
inanimate, hostile forces.
The second fundamental characteristic of our economic life is that the
bottom line in determining what production methods are to be used and
what is to be produced is neither the quality of working life nor the utility of
the articles created, but rather the profitability of the enterprise. What is
quintessential in capitalism is not simply its historically unique manner of
turning out unprecedented quantities of goods, but also that the production
of goods is not the basic motive of those who own and direct the factories.
The production of profit is their basic motive. Thus how we work and what
we are producing are both determined by standards of profitability, accu-
mulation, and cash flow—not by the standard of making life more satisfying
during our brief stint on this earth. This distinction was neatly identified by
Carter Goodrich, when he wrote in his classic study of coal miners' control
struggles in 1926:
390
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Past and Future of Workers' Control
391
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Militancy, Union Politics, and Workers' Control
rollers falling off, or pipes breaking." The "standard size of single strength
rollers" was fixed at "45 x 58 to cut 38 x 56." In other words, it was the
union that standardized the size of windows in late nineteenth-century
America. Poor glass, absenteeism, and drinking which interfered with pro-
duction were punished by union fines. To help secure obedience to union
rules and to decisions of the shop committees, the foremen were obliged to
belong to the union and submit to its discipline.2
The important point is not just that these rules were elaborate, but that
they embodied a moral code for which glass workers were prepared to fight.
Consider this description from John SwintorCs Paper in 1884 of the strike
which ensued when the employers tried to compel blowers to produce more
than the 48 boxes of glass per week prescribed by their union. The language
of the report reveals clearly what glass blowers thought of themselves and of
their rules.
The lastfightof the manufacturers was made on the "forty-eight box limit."
The reduction of wages was only the excuse. This is no secret. How the
high-rolling manufacturer did splutter over this! His gouty limbs stumbled
across it, and he broke his grip. He knew that if the limit was taken off, the
men could work ten or twelve hours every day in the week; that in their
thirst for the mighty dollar they would kill themselves with labor; they
would "black sheep" their fellows by doing the labor of two men; they
would employ apprentices innumerable to help them through; in their
individual reach for that which governs the country [the dollar], they would
ruin their association. The men said no. They thundered out no. They even
offered to take a reduction that would average 10 per cent all around, but
they said, "We will keep the forty-eight box limit." Threats and curses
would not move them to make more than forty-eight boxes of window glass
a week, andfinally,in despair, the grasping dollar-lover gave way and said,
"Keep it and be d d." They have it still and they won't be damned by
any but their employers.3
Two aspects of this late nineteenth-century experience should be
emphasized. First, even in the setting of modern technology and large-scale
production it was possible to have collective direction of the way in which
jobs were performed. Moreover, such direction required not only a struggle
against management's efforts to control the work, but also a rejection of
individualistic, acquisitive behavior. The practical and ideological aspects of
this contest were inseparable from each other.
Second, this control by the crafts was the primary target of attack for
managerial reformers in the early twentieth century. Scientific manage-
ment—which might properly be described by paraphrasing today's lan-
guage, as a systematic job impoverization program—emerged out of a drive,
evident in every advanced industrial country as corporate enterprise waxed
larger and international competition grew more intense at the turn of the
century, to increase labor productivity. In England, France, Germany, and
392
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Past and Future of Workers' Control
393
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Militancy, Union Politics, and Workers' Control
394
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Past and Future of Workers' Control
over, will be harmonized, just like the musical pitches are the same all over
the world."9 O'Shea depicted Barth's dream this way:
The demonstrator sat in his easy chair,
And as he smoked his cigar dreamed a dream so fair,
In the haze of the rings of smoke he blew,
A picture he saw of which I'll tell you:
In fancy he saw a building grand
Of which he was in supreme command;
There were lathes and planers and milling machines, too;
Of wheel presses and bolt cutters there were quite a few;
Horizontal and vertical mills by the score;
Of slotters and shapers a great many more.
While the shop—my, what a marvelous place!
Men moved like as though they were running a race.
And he thought of what a great change he'd wrought
Since he the other machinists had taught
To do their work so quick and fast
And not to be loafing over their task,
But make all the money for the company, then
They'll be treated like cattle instead of like men.
O'Shea continues by contrasting the new lust for speed with his trade's
traditions of quality production.
And he smiled as he thought of the old slow way
When a man would turn up one axle a day.
First he'd center it up so good and true,
Then take a roughing cut or two,
And a finishing cut so nice and fine,
And then roll the bearings to make them shine,
Square up the ends, then make the fits,
Take it out of the lathe, and that was it.
But just look how he had changed this way—
A man had to do twelve of them now a day.
They simply wheel them into the lathe,
Turn the whole thing up in one might shave,
Throw it out again and then it was done,
And the lathe man would say, well, that's going some.
The same contrast is repeated through different departments of the
plant. But the poem ends in a delightfully unexpected way, by portraying the
"demonstrator" as an offender against working-class morality and as
hopelessly outclassed in technical knowledge by those to who he is issuing
commands.
395
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Militancy, Union Politics, and Workers' Control
396
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Past and Future of Workers' Control
building trades and many tool and die makers could simply demand stan-
dard craft rates and craft rules of the old form. But others, among whom
scientific management had already wrought extensive changes, developed
novel sets of demands and new forms of self-organization.
Consider the machinists, helpers, and tool makers at the vast Mesta
Machine Company near Pittsburgh. They struck in 1917 and again in 1918
for the abolition of the time-study and premium pay schemes, the establish-
ment of three or four standard wage rates, the eight-hour day, and recogni-
tion by the company of a shop committee to deal with all grievances from the
plant. This pattern of demands was commonplace by the end of the war, and
it deserves attention. First of all, a demand for standardization was arising in
this instance not from the managers, but from the workers. The new pay-
ment plans had generated a proliferation of individual wage rates, and
employers openly defended having "as many hourly rates as there are
human beings"12 in the factory as necessary for the efficient operation of
the works. The workers realized that the old standard craft rate was now
hopelessly obsolete, but they did try to create a determinate set of classifica-
tions to cover everyone, and one with a narrow spread between the highest
and the lowest rates.
Second, strikers virtually everywhere demanded the standard work day
of eight hours, and they enjoyed considerable success on this front. The
struggle for a shorter work week made more headway between 1910 and
1920 than in any other decade of this century, despite adamant employer
resistance. Third, new forms for organizing the collective power of workers
were developed. Sometimes craft unions were coordinated through metal
trades councils, and many unions opened their doors to unskilled workers,
but virtually everywhere some form of shop committee or stewards' body
assumed the task of directly representing the rank and file. Workers of this
epoch were keenly aware that to speak of "workers' control" without
effectively organizing workers' power is to drift into fantasy land.
Finally, as these struggles became more intense, they were increasingly
often linked to far-reaching political demands. The munitions workers of
Bridgeport, who had been seasoned by four years of chronic industrial battle
by 1919, for example, held huge rallies to protest post-war layoffs. From
these rallies they petitioned the president of the United States for the
"creation of National Labor Agencies to assure in all industries a living wage
and every right to union organization; collective bargaining and collective
participation of the workers in control of industry;" a reduction of hours;
"extensive necessary public works" to create jobs; and finally, the "aboli-
tion of competition, criminal waste and profiteering in industry and substi-
tuting co-operative ownership and democratic management of industry and
the securing to each of the full product of his toil."13
This was the age of the Plumb Plan on the railroads, the miners'
pamphlet How to Run Coal, and the convention of delegates from 30,000
397
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Militancy, Union Politics, and Workers' Control
398
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Past and Future of Workers' Control
This covert style of struggle from the 1920s and 1930s is still very much
with us today, but the rapid spread of union contracts during the late 1930s
brought some significant changes, and a new challenge to management.
With union protection came both a resurgence of the audacity and self-
confidence among workers that had been evident during the war years and
an eagerness among the rank and file to settle old scores and to change the
conditions under which they worked forthwith. Consequently both manage-
ment and governmental agencies sought to limit the influence which the new
unions would have over work relations and production processes and to
develop machinery for dealing with grievances which would leave the initia-
tive in production and personnel questions with management. The task was
not an easy one, as employers' laments from the late 1930s about their
"unmanageable" workers make clear. But the goals toward which sophisti-
cated managers were striving were neatly summed up by Sumner Slichter in
a study published by the Brookings Institution in 1941, Union Policies and
Industrial Management.
Convinced that unionism had become too securely established in Amer-
ican industry to be uprooted once agian, Slichter set out to study in detail the
practices and arrangements which affected the ability of workers and of
managers to control what happened in their plants. He concluded that from
management's vantage point, the ideal form of union would be industrial in
399
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Militancy, Union Politics, and Workers' Control
400
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Past and Future of Workers' Control
plant in 1954, American workers have often declared that they have a right
to a voice in corporate decisions about where work is to be carried on. Most
such struggles since that time have employed political strategies: the work-
ers have mobilized their communities to demand that their Congressional
representatives or the Department of Defense force the company to con-
tinue operating at the old site. A few have used the pressure of strikes and
boycotts. In every case the objective has been to force management to
bargain over what it always claimed as its exclusive and ultimate authority
under "free enterprise," to decide what it wanted to produce where.
In some recent instances workers have sought ways to reopen a plant
which has been abandoned by a multiplant corporation under their own
management, or some sort of community ownership. For example, when
Youngstown Sheet and Tube announced that it would close its Campbell
Works, local union members enlisted the aid of a ministers' council to
promote a movement for acquisition of the plant by the community. The
implications of this effort are profound. As the project's economic consul-
tant, Gar Alperowitz, has made clear, community ownership of the mill
cannot succeed without new governmental purchasing policies for steel
wares that are directed primarily at the needs of urban America, in mass
transit, housing development, et cetera. In other words, if a community-
operated plant with any degree of workers' control is going to function, it
must have its output determined by the nation's need for use values—by the
real and sorely neglected needs of the American people—not by the rule of
maximum profitability in the marketplace.17
The Youngstown idea has not been carried to fruition, but it has caught
on elsewhere. In Buffalo, when the Heat Transfer Division of American
Standard threatened to close down, the Buffalo AFL-CIO Council voted to
take over the plant, if necessary, and operate it under union direction.
Several plants in Jamestown and Dunkirk, New York, have already been
kept alive by their workers' assuming ownership.
This is the setting of the most important discussions of workers' control
today. And outstanding example of what is now possible has been provided
by the birth and survival of Wisconsin's worker-controlled newspaper, the
Madision Press Connection. Its origins lie in a long strike of the employees of
Madison's major newspapers, provoked when their owners undertook to
cripple or destroy their craft unions. Having gone out on strike and realizing
that all the skills needed to put out a newspaper were to be found among the
people walking the picket line, these workers decided to start their own
newspaper as a rival to their scab-operated former employers. The Press
Connection soon developed a network of readers such as few papers could
boast, because in order to get subscriptions and operating funds, newspaper
workers had to solicit support from union and farmers' organizations all
over Wisconsin. As they did so, the people with whom they talked told them
401
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Militancy, Union Politics, and Workers' Control
that they thought of and wanted from the newspaper. Responding to read-
ers' suggestions and criticisms (that is, creating something useful for the
people of Wisconsin) became essential to the survival of the paper.
Moreover, on my own first visit to the Press Connection's offices and
composing room, I saw a workplace that looked more businesslike—in the
true sense of the term—than anything I had seen before in my life. Each
department had been physically designed by the people who worked in it, to
make their work as efficient, easy, and accurate as they could make it, while
it was also equipped with the flowers, pictures, et cetera necessary to make
the setting congenial. These journalists, bookkeepers, layout artists and
printers were not socializing: they were putting out a newspaper of value to
the local residents. And they were running it by their own collective deci-
sions. (See Chapter 20.)
A group of these workers told me that they had gone to a seminar held
by industrial relations experts on the question of workers' participation in
management. They had listened to all the projects and experiments de-
scribed there, saying nothing until close to the end of the day, when one of
them put up his hand. He said: "I'm sorry. We can't quite relate to this
discussion. You see, we found in the Press Connection that we don't need
management's participation."
The control struggles which involve nothing but the immediate partic-
ipation of those involved are those which emerge out of small groups of
workers in direct relationship with each other. An example is the decision of
cam shaft turners among themselves as to how many shafts they will pro-
duce. Nobody from outside the group is needed for that sort of control—
though we must remember that the parameters within which workers make
such a decision are decisively fixed by the boss.
When we think in terms of operating a plant, however, two aspects of
the question must be clearly confronted. First, it is not possible to build a
fully participatory management within the existing economic framework.
One cannot make socialism in one factory. Even if The People's Campbell
Works was opened in Youngstown, it would still be enmeshed in an econ-
omy governed by market rules and oriented infinancialand sales practices,
as well as in known management techniques, toward the logic or profit.
Those who are thinking of producing use values under collective direction
within that system are facing an uphill battle every day.
The significance of that uphill battle depends on other developments
connected with it, and this is where the political side of the struggle comes in.
One factory by itself will sink or—if it survives—will not be self-managed
very long. In Jamestown, New York, where six factories boast their "self-
management," I found that three of them were impossible to distinguish
from any other factory, except that the managerial group may have included
as many as a dozen members.
The second point follows from the first. What matters is the connection
402
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Past and Future of Workers' Control
we make (in thought and deed) between struggles to change work relations
and struggles to change the purpose for which we work. In recent years our
fascination with the challenge of participatory democracy to hierarchy and
bureaucracy has sometimes obscured the related, and more fundamental,
challenge of popular economic needs to production for profit. A move-
ment which aims to link collectively directed production to collectively
determined economic needs cannot be confined to the workplace alone.
Will we then end up with nothing but another ruling bureaucracy? The
crucial point is not to pose this question in either-or terms. Our thinking on
this matter may be helped by the study, recently published by Andrew
Zimbalist and Juan Espinoza, of 420 publicly operated factories in Chile
during the Popular Unity government. They found that the actual level of
participation of workers in plant management varied greatly from one
factory to another. Where the plant had been nationalized by government
decree and a governing structure introduced from the outside, the workers
assumed actual collective direction very slowly, if they did so at all. On the
other hand, where the plant had a long history of organized struggle and the
workers themselves were active in its nationalization, their level of involve-
ment was impressive. Their official representatives in those instances
reflected an active base among the rank and file, which made "self-
management" a living reality—in determining the product line, as well as in
work relations. In other words, the dynamics of real political struggle do not
allow us to treat action "from below" and "from above" as mutually
exclusive.
There are two important differences between the early kind of worker
control and today's experiments in worker participation and worker man-
agement. First, the struggle for workers' control in the nineteenth century
began with the production process—or rather, with discrete elements of the
production process. Molders, for example, collectively regulated the tech-
nique and the relations among themselves and between themselves and their
helpers in the foundries of many different enterprises. At the high point of
their craft struggle, they fought for a single set of rules regulating molding in
many competing enterprises at once. But those molders did not contest their
owners' ownership and direction of the enterprise as a whole. Even when
they were socialists, they envisaged the transfer of the industry to their
complete control as an ultimate objective, not as the immediate goal of
direct action. Like the legendary British machinist, they drew a chalk line
around "their" territory within the boss's factory, and they demanded that
the boss deal with them from the other side of that line.
Today's struggles around plant closings begin with the front office,
rather than with the foundry or some other segment of the production
process. They aimfirstand foremost atfinancialcontrol of the enterprise, to
keep it in business. Although some accounts from plywood or asbestos firms
indicate that the advent of workers' self-management made personal rela-
403
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Militancy, Union Politics, and Workers' Control
tions between workers and supervisors less authoritarian and more relaxed,
very seldom has the basic pattern of decision-making and supervision inher-
ited from private ownership been quickly and drastically modified. The John
Brown Shipyard, occupied by its workers, the Madison Press Connection,
set up by strikers, and the British and Irish Steam Packet Company of
Dublin, where an imaginative works council "advised" the new managers
after nationalization so effectively as actually to take command, are three
instances in which control of the shop floor and control of the front office
were inseparably connected. Nevertheless, the different starting points of
the two forms of struggle are crucial. The primary objective of struggles
against plant closings is to keep a job, not to change it.
The second difference is closely related to the first. The point of depar-
ture for workers' control struggles in the nineteenth century was the supe-
rior knowledge of production processes possessed by some workers. To-
day's struggles begin with the scientifically managed factory. That means
that battles against plant closings, or against take-back bargaining, must
embrace much, or even all, of the plant's workforce. They must also devise
new styles of organization, just as their predecessors in the epoch of World
War I had to do. Today the problem is to cross the lines of the "bargaining
units" defined by the NLRB, so as to mobilize technical and clerical em-
ployees (and possibly even portions of the local management facing con-
glomerate owners), along with the production workers. Also like their
predecessors of sixty years ago, they must undertake, through self-
education, to learn the whole business, so as to overcome the gulf between
mental and manual labor, which scientific management has spawned.
But finally, there is an important similarity between the earlier and the
present struggles. Craftsmen battling for control of their trades were keenly
aware, as I have pointed out, that to formulate and enforce their own rules
meant to repudiate and do battle with the ethic of acquisitive individualism.
The more far-sighted workers of that epoch also knew that to achieve
workers' control meant to uproot the jungle of capitalism itself, along with
its ethical code. It is equally evident today that corporations milk branch-
plants dry and abandon them, heap "take-back" demands on the bargaining
table in the name of productivity, and—ironically—even experiment with
"job enrichment" schemes, not to create more of the goods people need,
but to maximize their cashflowand their accumulation of still more capital.
The struggles of workers and of communities for control over their own
destinies in this setting becomes a battle to change the rules of the economic
game itself.
NOTES
1. Carter L. Goodrich, The Miner's Freedom: A Study of the Working Life in a
Changing Industry (Boston, 1925), pp. 5-6.
404
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Past and Future of Workers' Control
2. By-Laws of the Window Glass Workers, L.A. 300, Knights of Labor (Pitts-
burgh, 1899), pp. 26-36.
3. John Swinton's Paper, March 23, 1884.
4. Horace L. Arnold and Fay L. Faurote, Ford Methods and Ford Shops (New
York, 1919), p. 42.
5. Ibid., pp. 45^6.
6. F.W. Taylor, "Testimony Before the Special House Committee," in Scien-
tific Management, Comprising Shop Management, Principles of Scientific Manage-
ment, Testimony Before the Special House Committee (New York, 1947), p. 49.
7. U.S. Congress, Hearings before the Special Committee of the House of
Representatives to Investigate the Taylor and Other Systems of Shop Management
(Washington, D.C., 1912), p. 1000.
8. For discussion, of these incidents, see D. Montgomery, "Quel Standards?
Les Ouvriers et la Reorganisation de la Production aux Etats Unis, 1900-1920" Le
Mouvement Social, 102 (Jan.-March 1978), pp. 101-127.
9. U.S. Commission on Industrial Relations, Final Report and Testimony
(Washington, D.C., 1916), vol. 1, p. 889.
10. Machinists' Monthly Journal 20 (July 1908): 609.
11. Milton J. Nadworny, Scientific Management and the Unions, 1900-1932
(Cambridge, Mass., 1955).
12. Attorney for the Bridgeport manufacturers, quoted in Alexander M. Bing,
War-Time Strikes and Their Adjustment (New York, 1921), p. 200 n.
13. "Petition for the Creation of National Labor Agencies," National War
Labor Board, Case File 132, Box 22, R.G. 2, National Archives.
14. Loyall A. Osborne to William H. Taft, May 31, 1918, in Records of the
National War Labor Board, E 15 Administrative Files, R.G. 2, National Archives.
15. F. F. Corcoran to M.K. Hovey, "Suggestions and Information," Henry
Kraus Papers, Box 9, Archives of Labor History and Urban Affairs, Wayne State
University. I am grateful to Steven Sapolsky for bringing this document to my
attention.
16. Editor's note: As this article was going to press, the courts seemed to have
overruled the Eazor case, declaring in Carbon Fuel Co, v. UMW (1979) that unions
were not "vicariously liable" for the independent actions of wildcat strikers.
17. Editor's note: See Staughton Lynd, The Fight Against Shutdowns (San
Pedro, 1982).
405
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
This content downloaded from 190.16.93.205 on Fri, 06 Sep 2019 13:52:23 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms